Discover millions of ebooks, audiobooks, and so much more with a free trial

Only $11.99/month after trial. Cancel anytime.

Market Menagerie: Health and Development in Late Industrial States
Market Menagerie: Health and Development in Late Industrial States
Market Menagerie: Health and Development in Late Industrial States
Ebook560 pages9 hours

Market Menagerie: Health and Development in Late Industrial States

Rating: 0 out of 5 stars

()

Read preview

About this ebook

Market Menagerie examines technological advance and market regulation in the health industries of nations such as India, Brazil, South Africa, Nigeria, and Japan. Pharmaceutical and life science industries can reinforce economic development and industry growth, but not necessarily positive health outcomes. Yet well-crafted industrial and health policies can strengthen each other and reconcile economic and social goals. This book advocates moving beyond traditional market failure to bring together three uncommonly paired themes: the growth of industrial capabilities, the politics of health access, and the geography of production and redistribution.

LanguageEnglish
Release dateApr 4, 2012
ISBN9780804781916
Market Menagerie: Health and Development in Late Industrial States

Related to Market Menagerie

Related ebooks

Business Development For You

View More

Related articles

Reviews for Market Menagerie

Rating: 0 out of 5 stars
0 ratings

0 ratings0 reviews

What did you think?

Tap to rate

Review must be at least 10 words

    Book preview

    Market Menagerie - Smita Srinivas

    Stanford University Press

    Stanford, California

    ©2012 by the Board of Trustees of the Leland Stanford Junior University. All rights reserved.

    No part of this book may be reproduced or transmitted in any form or by any means, electronic or mechanical, including photocopying and recording, or in any information storage or retrieval system without the prior written permission of Stanford University Press.

    Special discounts for bulk quantities of Stanford Economics and Finance are available to corporations, professional associations, and other organizations. For details and discount information, contact the special sales department of Stanford University Press. Tel: (650) 736-1782, Fax: (650) 736-1784

    Printed in the United States of America on acid-free, archival-quality paper

    Library of Congress Cataloging-in-Publication Data

    Srinivas, Smita, author.

    Market menagerie : health and development in late industrial states / Smita Srinivas.

    pages   cm

    Includes bibliographical references and index.

    ISBN 978-0-8047-8054-4 (alk. paper)

    ISBN 978-0-8047-8191-6 (ebook)

    1. Pharmaceutical industry— Government policy— India. 2. Pharmaceutical industry— Technological innovations— India. 3. Health services accessibility— India. 4. Medical policy— India. 5. Pharmaceutical industry— Government policy— Developing countries. 6. Pharmaceutical industry— Technological innovations— Developing countries. 7. Health services accessibility— Developing countries. 8. Medical policy— Developing countries. I. Title.

    HD9672.I42S67 2012

    338.4'761510954—dc23       2011043735

    Typeset by Westchester Book Composition in 10/14 Minion

    MARKET MENAGERIE

    Health and Development

    in Late Industrial States

    Smita Srinivas

    Stanford Economics and Finance

    An Imprint of Stanford University Press

    Stanford, California

    To my parents, Nirmala and Srinivasa Murthy,

    for their inspiration and example

    Contents

    Cover

    Copyright

    Illustrations

    Acknowledgments

    PART I: Market Menagerie: Planning the Health of Late Industrial Development

    Introduction

    Health and Development in Late Industrial States

    Barbarians at the Gate: Late Industrial Supply

    Data, Methods, and Structure

    The Chapters Ahead

    Appendix: Sample Questions

    1   Well Beyond Market Failure

    A Time for Integration: Evolution of States and Markets

    Technology’s Insights for Markets

    Extant Systems and the Weakness of Ideology for Reform

    Beyond Minimalism

    Bringing an Evolutionary Perspective to Development

    The Fine Touch

    PART II: 1950–2000: Indian Market Menagerie

    2   The First Market Environment: Trouble in the Making

    Phase I, 1950–1970s: Coveted Universalism, Controlled Markets

    A Crucible for Learning: The Public-Sector Effort

    Nehruvian Efforts in the Manufacture of Medicines

    The Public-Sector Legacy Today

    3   Essential Markets, Public Health, and Private Learning

    The 1970s and 1980s

    Process Patents

    Price Controls

    Monopolies, MNCs, and Accelerated Indian Learning

    Trouble in the Making: The New Drug Policy and Production

    Taking Stock

    4   Demand and Democracy

    The Institutional Unraveling of Industrial Planning

    Planning for the Nation’s Heartland and Outposts

    Demand and the Health of Health-Care Financing

    Industrial Slowdown and Fiscal Inertia

    Universalism and Demand Identities: From Control to Dissipation

    The Reemergence of Nonmarket Institutions

    The Ragged Edges of Consumption and Delivery

    5   The Second Market Environment: Learning by Proving in Global Regulatory Harmonization

    National Universalism and Global Nationalism:

    The State’s Loosening Hold on the Domestic Market

    Institutional Shifts to Global Nationalism

    Expansionist Market Tiers

    Growing Innovation, but Not Access?

    Looking Ahead

    6   Demand as Necessary but Not Sufficient: Vaccine Procurement Markets

    Vaccines

    Health for Some: The Development Mandate

    International Procurement Markets: Beyond Government Failure

    Procurement’s Effect

    Fine-Tuning Demand Policy Instruments

    Learning by Proving: Health Policy as Industrial Policy

    7   The Third Market Environment: Uncertain State of New Technologies

    Bringing the State Back into the Process

    Process, Process: New Technologies Ahoy!

    Advances Nevertheless

    New Technology Maps and Blurred Market Signposts: Organizational Vignettes

    Finally, Niches and Local Relevance

    New Interactions for Old Players

    PART III: The Institutional Basis for Industry and Health

    8   Health Technologies in Comparative Global Perspective

    Instituting Welfare Regimes: Building the Double Movement

    Pharmaceutical’s Historical Advance: Early Capabilities, Early Welfare

    Private Property Markets

    Collective Rights and Markets in Welfare Institutions

    Varieties of Health-Care States

    Late Industrial Suppliers: Marrying Late Capabilities with Later Welfare

    Revisiting the Institutional Triad

    Moving Forward: Transitioning Developmental States

    9   Markets and Metropolis

    The Design of (Re)distribution

    Nation and City in Development

    Universalism in Federalism: Between Capitalism and Commune

    Industrial Welfare and the City in Context

    Cities, Antibiotics, and Universalism

    From Poor Law to Welfare Paternalism in England and India

    Ahmedabad, circa 1915

    The Body Corporal and Politic: Utopias in Universalism

    The Quest for Healthy Places

    Nations and Cities: An Evolving Social Contract?

    Limited Double Movement: Contractualism and Bo(u)nds of Exchange

    Conclusion: Soft Determinism in the Market Menagerie

    Infusing Evolution into Economic Plans

    Planning Process and Outcomes

    Soft Determinism in a New Pharmaceutical World

    Intervening in Variety

    Evolution and Orchestration of the Social Contract

    Market Variety and Morality: Planning with Small and Large P

    Notes

    Index

    Illustrations

    Figures

    I.1 Institutional triad of health care

    6.1 Evolution and specialization of Indian vaccine capabilities

    7.1 Culture challenges

    7.2 CRO learning

    Tables

    I.1 Global pharmaceutical companies by 2009 global sales

    I.2 Share of top 10 Indian firms in domestic market

    2.1 Major pre-and postindependence changes

    2.2 The link between public health and manufacturing technology

    3.1 Reluctance of foreign firms in bulk drugs

    3.2 Public health histories of several leading companies in 2002

    3.3 Subphases of the first market environment

    5.1 Development timelines for selected Indian generics

    5.2 Regulations and tiered markets

    5.3 Sample Ranbaxy export product launches by 2000–2003

    5.4 Examples of Ranbaxy’s technology and infrastructure milestones

    6.1 The second market environment’s three Ws

    7.1 Market challenges in synthetic and biopharmaceutical generics

    7.2 Lateral learning paths

    7.3 Niche research opportunities

    8.1 The coevolution of the Japanese triad

    8.2 Early and late industrial nations and their health sectors

    9.1 Biotechnology city-regions

    9.2 Market scales

    Acknowledgments

    THIS WORK DERIVES FROM RESEARCH AND PROFESSIONAL OPPORTUNITIES over the past 15 years and from the generosity of many. My gratitude must first extend to all my Indian and overseas interviewees, and to participants in several prior pieces of research who were essential to this book. It was at least in part through their enthusiasm that the value of this endeavor and the need for integration became especially apparent.

    Several stimulating academic venues, departmental colleagues, and librarians allowed me to think through different elements of the book even when large portions of it were still in mind rather than on paper. Before I had even set foot in New York City, others had helped me. I am a poor socializer when I am working intensely. Although several people have kindly remarked on my high productivity, it has come during times of unfortunate close proximity to the health-care system and health technologies, which spurred the topics covered here. Many of those friends mentioned here were especially able at engaging a reticent colleague who had many responsibilities; they have continued to be wonderfully supportive to the present day. Academic scholarship rarely emerges and thrives without social networks, and I must thank mine for solidifying around me when I was unable and unwilling to seek them out. I express special thanks to Richard Lester and Anita Kafka, who made me welcome over the years at MIT’s Industrial Performance Center (IPC) from 2001 to 2006. Richard made me an active team member on Finland’s biotech sector, and I owe several ideas and articles to the IPC’s collegial climate and to Richard’s friendship. Frank Levy and Mike Piore provided a good community to think through organizational relationships between employment and innovation. Frank, I owe you a special debt on several fronts. So too, thanks are due to Bish Sanyal, who has remained a quiet, steady voice of support and encouragement on both aspects of my work—political and technological—that are evident in this book. Marty Rein encouraged me to rethink policy incoherence in ways that I continue to appreciate now as I return to other research. Alok Chakrabarti, Elena Grela, Jean-Jacques de Groof, Ambuj Sagar, Markku Sotarauta, and Judith Sutz have remained especially solid colleagues and friends on innovation, and I would be hard pressed to replace such individuals with anyone better. Charles Cooney in MIT’s biochemical engineering department and Calestous Juma at the Belfer Center at Harvard University provided other contacts and forums for further exploration and comparative work in health technologies. Calestous provided one venue at the Science, Technology, and Globalization project over several years, and John Holdren, now with President Obama’s policy team, provided other opportunities and long-standing support within the wider program at Harvard’s Kennedy School. As with Columbia and MIT, Harvard’s support meant that my papers and ideas reached wide audiences. It also permitted different scales of policy involvement. While at Harvard I assisted in the UN’s newly instituted Science, Technology, and Innovation Task Force (TF 10) of the Millennium Development Goals, interacted briefly in a coordinating role for the task force’s report with innovation scholars on genomics and public health. This solidified some of the comparative context for the health industry and supported insights of private-sector interviewees who emphasized the importance of physical infrastructure and manufacturing costs.

    I wish to acknowledge support in grants and other assistance that have added in various ways to this work from 2000 to the present, among others: from the MIT Center for International Studies, the MIT Department of Urban Studies and Planning, the MIT Industrial Performance Center, the Harvard Kennedy School’s Science, Technology, and Globalization project (Science, Technology, and Public Policy program), the Center for Business and Government, the UN Industrial Development Organization, Columbia’s Institute for Social and Economic Research and Policy, and the Graduate School of Architecture, Planning, and Preservation at Columbia University. Materials from the empirical chapters have drawn directly and indirectly from doctoral research at MIT, and I thank Craig Thomas and Peter Bebergal for their help in using the materials here.

    The Institute for Biotech and Bioinformatics, Bangalore, hosted me in 2003–2004; Harvard’s Sustainability Science program (then at the Center for International Development in 2005–2006) hosted me as an associate; and the Department of Management Studies and the Centre for Sustainable Technologies at the Indian Institute of Science, Bangalore, hosted me as a visiting scientist in the summer of 2008–2009. I thank them for the opportunities to discuss and present my research and for invitations graciously extended.

    Columbia University’s Urban Planning program has been my professional home for the last six years. Dean Mark Wigley at the Graduate School of Architecture, Planning, and Preservation (GSAPP) generously funded the Technological Change Lab (TCLab) and my research at Columbia University and heartily welcomed the cross-cutting nature of my interests in planning, technological advance, and political philosophy. Seed funding by a research grant from Columbia’s Institute for Social and Economic Research and Policy on a related project on legal entitlements, TCLab support from GSAPP, and the understanding of Elliott Sclar, Bob Beauregard, and Lance Freeman, past and present chairs, allowed me time to reflect, a generous yearlong leave of absence from June 2009 to mid-2010 to finish writing the initial manuscript in Bangalore (now Bengaluru). My Columbia colleagues are collegial and have made writing painless, even pleasurable. I am very fortunate to have frequent good intellectual engagements with Richard Nelson, a pioneer in the economics of innovation, and with the immense richness of other scholars here at the university. Janet Foster extended innumerable small acts of understanding and managerial kindness, as did Leigh Brown and Mark Taylor. Students Matthew Crosby, Sonal Shah, Victoria Ruiz, Joseph Matuk, Alejandro de Castro Mazarro, and especially Lauren Racusin provided cheerful assistance on various small but valuable items. Gordon Sauer and Kate Daloz at Columbia’s Writing Center have made writing more pleasurable and provided a guaranteed refuge.

    Several international organizations were also vital to the shaping of this book. These included officials at the World Health Organization, the United Nations Children’s Fund (UNICEF), and the United Nations Industrial Development Organization (UNIDO) and Francisco Sercovich’s support of a Harvard fellowship. A paper that I wrote in that context for UNIDO, Industrial Development Report 2005, allowed me to crystallize my thoughts on export markets and technical standards. The International Labor Organization, the United Nations University and the University of Maastricht, the United Nations Conference on Trade and Development (UNCTAD), the United Nations Educational, Scientific, and Cultural Organization (UNESCO), the International AIDS Vaccine Initiative, and others provided invitations to speak, commissioned my research, and extended related resources for studying the comparative institutional and organizational challenges of health, R&D, and manufacturing in vaccines and biotechnologies. More recently, Shyama Ramani’s international collaboration on Access to Medicines and her invitation to participate in a book project on Indian innovation and inclusion, and invitations and panel presentations at the American Collegiate Schools of Planning and the American Political Science Association have offered other generous opportunities for continued intellectual exchange on the role of industry in a nation and a city’s well-being.

    The integrative basis for this work, and several other related papers, has been presented over the years to diverse audiences. Although much has not made its way into this book, I have benefited from economists, urban historians, biochemists, and engineers as much as from labor scholars and health policy experts. I have been a bridge in many instances across these communities, a responsibility not always comfortably taken on at the time, but one I now recognize as unusual good intellectual and social fortune. Colleagues and audiences included those at Globelics, the American Collegiate Schools of Planning, Sloan Foundation Industry Studies meetings, the American Association of Geographers, Catch-Up projects, the American Political Science Association, invited inputs to the Indian Journal of Labour Economics, and invitations and opportunities too numerous to mention here in urban and regional planning, economics of innovation, science and technology policy, political economy, and economics workshops and lecturing opportunities. Although some scholars may read this book more narrowly as one on pharmaceuticals or biotech, the motivations for this and other research derive in no small part from my past opportunities with organizations such as the Aga Khan Health Services, the Self-Employed Women’s Association, Mahila Samakhya, the Belaku Trust, and several others that I have visited or where I have conducted research to understand the Indian economy and the state of employment and health politics. Exceptionally talented organizers and activists there have provided me forums to speak, think, and understand India’s dilemmas.

    Stanford University Press’s Margo Beth Crouppen was enthusiastic about this book and its ambitions from the start and has been wise in her counsel since. Jessica Walsh has been a patient and generous production team member, along with John Donohue of Westchester Book Services, who coordinated the copyediting. They have made this easy.

    Frederick, Meghana and Achintya, and Harry and Nellie Weber have supported me in ways too difficult to describe. Smriti Srinivas and James Heitzman have been inspirations as family scholars, and I only wish that James and Harry could have seen this book in print. Frederick, inspirer of titles and husband extraordinaire, no one could be as lucky as I am. This book could not have happened without you.

    Nirmala and Srinivasa Murthy are truly remarkable parents and personify the building blocks of that elusive word community. The world is better because of them, and so am I. This book is dedicated to them.

    Introduction

    Health and Development in Late Industrial States

    Market Menagerie uses an industrial lens to analyze technological advances in the health sector of industrializing nations today. These nations are often termed late or even late, late industrial economies. A multifaceted conceptualization of their developmental states and market variety is vital, for it can better configure their industrial policies in the provision of health-related products and processes.

    Why market menagerie? A menagerie was an enclosure that housed exotic varieties of birds and animals for royal pomp and plea sure, seen as early, it is said, as 3500 BC in Egypt and from the eighth century onward in parts of Europe. Such exotica for royal amusement displayed the court’s power because they were not only difficult to obtain but expensive to retain. Unlike zoological gardens (zoos), which appeared later and often had science and education as goals, early menageries displayed variety but were rarely studied systematically.

    Development similarly is a menagerie that houses many institutional varieties—especially of states and markets. However, scholars very often pose development as mediated through the market, as if there were only one of that species, while those who advocate state intervention similarly discuss the state versus the market. Neither approach captures the ever-changing varieties of markets that developmental states may have to structure and rein in, and choices that they must make as they plan. Let us push the metaphor further. Early menageries tended to be more for royal pomp and plea sure than for the populace’s enjoyment. Markets too risk becoming exclusive and exclusionary rather than catering to more universal or democratic ideals. The less we study their variety, the less we know about how they might be differently planned. Phrased differently, the task is to make the menagerie rather more like a zoological garden: to open it up and to look more closely at species variety and the geographic context in which species thrive. We can then consider what developmental states can or cannot do and whether market failure assists us in considering when the state should regulate.

    Although nation-states and local states fail often, especially in the face of rapid technological advance, this book attempts a more sympathetic retheorizing of states attending to the market menagerie. Even when dysfunctional or outright malevolent, and despite its limitations and contradictions, the state (and its governments) is inevitably the most important planning institution in these economies. Theorizing sector cases rich in industrial capabilities—in pharmaceuticals, biotech, and vaccines—allows us an especially nuanced context for the industrializing world today, comprising markets, democracy, participation, employment, and health politics. Seen as such, the health sector is a story about planning citizen and democratic entitlements and, in India’s case, the special context of religious, labor, language, and other spatial and political discriminations woven into the idea of the nation. Universalism in India has special weight for which a simple cosmopolitanism or multiculturalism will not do. In another sense, the growth of urban life sciences has everything to do with economic development strategies and with urban restructuring, the rise of industry megaprojects and private hospitals, and the pressures on land and investments. In yet another sense, science and technologies change; not surprisingly, therefore, so does the health sector. The state often decides both the politics of entitlements and the urban transformation, but it simultaneously plays a crucial role in technological advance that places bounds on state actions. Much if not most of this occurs outside voting cycles and insidiously changes urban landscapes. Therefore, how should we think about the state, its contingent influence, and the markets that drive the health sector? The concern here is with both the process and the outcomes of health distribution, although studying the evolution of outcomes over 50 years may make them more comprehensible, and a focus not exclusively on the nation-state may make the urban contradictions that manifest themselves more visible. In this era of national health reform and global governance, we must be able to grapple with this peculiar contrast of advancing life-science concentrations amid health deprivation. How do policy and the state (with several governments that have come and gone) actually mediate in the health sector over time, and how does technological advance make this mediation more contingent?

    Technological advance in specific sectors acts as the kernel of immense economic transformation precisely because it imposes sizable learning challenges for industrializing countries and the social changes to see them through. The health sector’s advances represent a crucial economic and physical transformation of national and urban economies from Bangalore, India, and Turku, Finland, to Cambridge, Massachusetts, and Cambridge, england. The sector comprises not only pharmaceuticals and biotech firms but also myriad other research, production, demand, and delivery organizations and infrastructure. Visualize cities that have distributed diagnostic labs, hospitals, clinics, university labs, other R&D units, insurance firms, computation-intensive buildings, medical equipment firms, biohazard containment zones, and industrial recycling. These often exist despite health access being far from an assured right.

    Most studies of pharmaceuticals and biotechnology, especially from an innovation standpoint, have been concerned almost exclusively with the supply side. Most analyses of the developmental state’s role have similarly focused on health planning and have tended to take technological capability and firm-level constraints for granted. Three sets of questions therefore lie at the heart of this book: How can industrializing nations satisfy developmental mandates and promote access to medicines produced at home? What market varieties shape this access? What are the institutional implications for nation-states and urban and regional life-science growth paradigms today?

    We cannot answer these questions even cursorily until we look at the sector’s dynamics. Markets for health technologies have several unique characteristics, such as limited information and autonomous choice, blurred distinctions between producers and users (especially in clinician roles), risks of use, and particular cultural traits. Furthermore, in health technologies, neither patients nor health professionals but third-party payers (public and private alike) may be the buyers of the end products. As we will see, this collective aspect of consumption and demand shapes late industrial technological advance and constrains how states can reconcile economic and social goals.

    This book brings together three themes that are rarely aggregated in addressing health, industrial development, and developmental states: the building of industrial capabilities in late industrializers, the politics of their access, and their geography of production and redistribution. It situates these themes in terms of two concerns—market varieties and market scales—as challenges to the actions of developmental states and contributions to a new, developmental pragmatism. Therefore, this book is certainly not a health policy or health economics volume, although it analyzes the health industry. It is, however, very much about the health of development itself. As such, it should complement the interests of readers of health policy, those looking to understand its industrial context, as well as those in economic development and urban and regional planning who are concerned with the evolution of essential institutions, such as markets and states.

    An author writes because of his or her certainty that something has been missed or wrapped up too quickly. I write because I am curious about what are termed wicked problems:¹ what can seem overwhelming, intractable problems that specialists rush to dissect and separate into individual strands. This dissection is satisfying to show off one’s specialist tendencies, but it tends to shun the wicked character of the problem, which is a reflection of the real world. Rather than seek a straightforward industry and regional planning approach, or an economics-of-innovation approach, I have chosen to emphasize the multifaceted nature of the state’s planning compass. My choice to bring several themes together stems from my desire to approach the future in an integrative theoretical manner and from my professional world that often collides with the dual realities of supply organizations, on the one hand, and access and demand politics, on the other. Theories of urban and regional planning and economic institutionalism urge reconstruction, not merely theoretical deconstruction.² I agree. They must not merely expose ideologies and generalizations about our world, but must also suggest new ways of approaching older problems and propose new conceptual possibilities for reconstruction and greater well-being. Therefore, in taking on states and markets, my task is partly to look within these institutions and partly to look beyond them to expand our debates. It is also essential that we move beyond complaining about our world, even if our kvetching is buttressed with thorough social science research; rather, we must use deconstruction to reenvision our world when this is possible.

    This book makes two essential points regarding developmental goals. First, it questions the common reading of development as market failure, but also development as production success. It therefore moves beyond the standard focus on market failures and public goods, emphasizing instead an evolutionary market variety and the wider institutional ecology that markets inhabit, which includes other institutions, such as states, firms, technical standards, intellectual property, insurance, and citizenship. Evolution of critical institutions such as markets and states need not mean evolving with no planning interventions (i.e., laissez-faire), but neither does it suggest full social control. What it does suggest is that state autonomy, power, and planning control are technologically and politically contingent. In exposing these contingencies, we can do better in redesigning the institutional scope of industry and health. Neither markets nor states possess absolute power, as we shall see in the forthcoming chapters.

    Second, developmental states are practically synonymous with developmental nation-states. However, the abstract rhetoric of national health reform and global governance distracts us from important shifts occurring in subnational politics, rapidly advancing urban life-science concentrations, and intersecting scales of development and regulation. Therefore, the developmental agenda for states is to regulate in the face of technological evolution by managing the market menagerie, continually demarcating market bounds, health entitlements, and redistribution on multiple stages: international, national, and local.

    On the one hand, the more decentralized the strategies for industrial and technological development become, the more necessary the nation-state is in reining in territories, in economic regulation, and in lowering regional inequalities. On the other hand, supranational globally harmonized standards (intellectual property rights or technical standards of trade, for example) push toward more uniform production, thus forcing nation-states and local states to attend to more customized production and regulation for domestic development needs. Economic plans and policies must combine the political economy of technological advance with federalism, public finance, and urban morphologies of design and distribution. An integrated economics approach, therefore, requires a more evolutionary, dynamic view of institutions and regulation because both national production and health care occur in particular places and need local institutions. Complexity should not scare us; we should embrace it because more systematic understanding allows us to appreciate better why we collectively combine and choose some futures and let others go. Making plans, rather than controlling them, involves not only innovation and agility but also continuously changing course in light of necessary uncertainty. Theory poorly shows us how to do this. Therefore, I extend the discussions toward the end of the book to make some reasoned speculation about health in an industrial, technological age. More traditional health policy and industrial analysts may balk at this more philosophical extension of economics to new areas, metaphorical and literal. Without this engagement, however, I am convinced that we will continue to analyze our world in unhelpful disciplinary and analytic silos.

    Finally, I highlight an important difference about access itself: many institutional economics and health economics volumes assume that the only issue at stake is affordability and the poor. This book emphasizes that planning, regulation, and the state’s roles must encompass both supply and broader concerns of affordability. My concern here, therefore, is with late industrial suppliers and their technological advance,³ not with those nations that have industrialized (with or without a supply base) nor with developing countries. All countries need not have supply bases, but those that do—the focus of this book—are politically and economically distinct from poor or developing countries as categories.

    Of course, development is not only for so-called developing countries. Industrialized countries do provide an important foil in later chapters for debating the timing and contradictions of technological advance. Even in the United States, important developmental goals have reemerged. The national health-reform debate has made world headlines, sharpened the focus of academics and the popular press, and pitted the country’s advanced health technology supply against its large gap in access. It is therefore an excellent time for comparative health debates, judging from the number of books and scholarly articles and the surge in op-eds on health reform worldwide. Similarly, the global governance of health (AIDS, malaria, tuberculosis [TB]) and the growing number of cross-border epidemics and incidents of bioterrorism (swine flu, bird flu, TB, HIV/AIDS, and anthrax) have positioned health technologies as a crucial twenty-first-century issue. The fundamental challenges for nation-states are to wed technological advance to local institutional context, as well as international standardization pressures.

    New influential groupings such as Brazil, Russia, India, China, and South Africa (BRICSA) already have almost half the world’s population, a quarter of the world’s land, and 20% to 25% of current economic output, and it is estimated that they will have over 60% of the world’s gross domestic product (GDP) by 2050.⁴ Most 2000–2008 increases in world output were from developing countries, with estimates of as much as half coming from the growing powers of Brazil, Russia, India, and China (BRICs) alone.⁵ Trade among the BRICs now dwarfs some aspects of the trade between traditional North Atlantic and BRICs countries. China has now become India’s second-largest trading partner, for example.⁶ The institutional climate is doubly crucial because much of this economic surge has come from technology-intensive gains in several city-regions within the BRICs. India alone has 10 or more of the 30 fastest-growing urban regions in the world. These city-regions disproportionately add to the country’s GDP and growth rates. The BRICSA countries require new approaches and scholarship in development debates on both industry and health fronts. Their immense size, growing economic power, politics of federalism, and technological advance are highly distinctive. India’s growth-focused prospects look remarkably promising, but if one focuses on redistribution (and even more conservatively on per capita GDP based on historical growth rates), this future looks far less rosy.⁷

    A point I will reiterate in the chapters ahead is that technological advance in the pharmaceutical and life-science industries can reinforce economic development and industry growth, but not necessarily positive health outcomes. Nevertheless, there are vital reasons to bridge more closely the spheres of the economy that can be self-reinforcing. After all, health policies can be powerful protectionist tools for industrial growth in generics and pricing, for example, while well crafted industrial policies can boost health outcomes in drug safety and supply. A central task for states is to reconcile economic and social goals in their developmental agenda, something that no developmental state to date has arguably been fully able to do.

    The health sector can consequently be seen as a triad consisting of a fragile web of three primary institutional dynamics: industrial production of technologies, medicines, and vaccines; the provision systems of health-care delivery, such as hospitals and clinics; and the consumption (demand) of health care through individual or collective buying systems. Instead of a market of supply and demand, health care is in fact a web of these three interlinked relationships (see Figure I.1).⁸

    FIGURE I.1 Institutional triad of health care

    SOURCE: Created by the author.

    Indeed, despite the economic rhetoric that institutions matter, considering single institutions may be misleading and may altogether miss the genuine importance of institutions in the economy which is of a combinative nature.⁹ This selective combinative nature and its tensions will be evident as we track the challenges to technological advance from 1950 to 2000.

    Barbarians at the Gate: Late Industrial Supply

    All democratic supplier countries face special challenges, even industrialized ones. For instance, U.S. President Barack Obama is attempting reforms in areas ranging from orthopedic procedures to diagnostic tests as costs spiral, the economy plummets, and employment-linked health benefits recede. Domestic politics can spur innovation policies, regulate health access, cap prices, or ration services. However, late industrializers are especially complex and presage the state of the world’s economy and its health-care supply in the twenty-first century. Prime Minister Manmohan Singh of India has called health-care access a national priority (national emergency might have been closer to the truth); President Luiz Inacio Lula of Brazil walked a balancing act among strong social policies and family and community support for health care, organizational innovations, bold patent policies for HIV drugs, and a growing industrial and consumption base. It remains to be seen whether his successor, President Dilma Rousseff, can do the same. In general, not only must democratic industrializing supplier nations such as India, Brazil, South Africa, Nigeria, and Indonesia keep industrial momentum humming, but their health-care systems also must work triply hard: to provide healthy citizens (and they have many young ones) for this economic transformation, to manage the politics of redistribution and minimize unrest, and to boost the competitiveness of their health industries.¹⁰ From generics to vaccines and from surgical instruments to testing kits, this triad, especially in late industrializers, encompasses several subrelationships and lends itself to a noisy market menagerie at any time. Its coevolutionary elements indicate that several political economies can be conceptualised, but not all these institutional mixes necessarily complement each other in a well-working health system. Seeing the health sector in these terms is intended only as a broad heuristic to appreciate better how different types of planning and policy analysis tend to pick one or another realm. More important, this view reminds us that the three elements interact and constantly coevolve. Therefore, the goals of development plans, particularly when the goals may be both better supply and healthier populations, are never easy and are rarely simultaneously accomplished. In Chapter 8, for example, we will explore how several countries have emphasized some elements over time.

    The health sector’s several spheres of regulatory influence vie for state attention: competition policies, safety and efficacy policies, or access and equity policies may be peppered throughout the triad of production, delivery, and competition and may have no exact correspondence with them. After all, access and equity are important not only for consumption, but also for the design of delivery. Similarly, competition policies not only affect industrial production but also can, through increased competition, lower prices and increase access or improve quality (and thus safety). There is no comfortable equilibrium; constant state intervention and regulation are required. The heuristic of the triad cannot lead directly to policy prescriptions, but it can remind us of the complexity of development and regulation and thus make the prescriptions more palatable, as well as innovative. It also can make us less ideologically tied to particular institutions and national frames and more attuned to the necessity and challenges of local planning as an essential part of economic theory and practice.

    The story of the Indian pharmaceutical and biotech sectors and the comparative questions I ask about other states in later chapters will repeatedly return to the varieties of market settings and development concerns in a single sector. The simple institutional triad can therefore be only a broad guide to analyzing market changes over time. This is neither a story of successful production states nor of how markets ruled supreme. It is a story of how markets evolved and developmental state learning and challenges grew. Indeed, technological advance (the production success of developmental East Asia, for instance) has exacerbated the challenges to demand for health care and its delivery. The forthcoming chapters and analysis will emphasize the menagerie of markets in one country—India—for health technologies. How the nation-state unevenly governs these to fulfill its developmental task is at the heart of the book.

    Today India is the world’s tenth-largest industrial economy and one of the world’s largest suppliers of vital medicines and vaccines. Médecins Sans Frontières (Doctors without Borders) today calls India the Pharmacy to the World.¹¹ India has some of the world’s most competitive generics suppliers, rapidly growing life-science concentrations, and a booming medical tourism industry, but also one of the highest populations without access to medicines, vaccines, and diagnostics. India’s story is telling because it shows the tensions and political struggles to marry late industrialization and its benefits, with its poorly institutionalized and struggling links to employment and employment-linked health benefits—trends visible across South Asia, Latin America, West Asia, and Africa. To be sure, India has had its share of health successes, from declining infant and maternity mortality rates to a rise in immunization rates and a lower incidence of epidemics than earlier in the twentieth century.

    Certainly, not all countries

    Enjoying the preview?
    Page 1 of 1