Sie sind auf Seite 1von 19

American Politics Research

http://apr.sagepub.com Bureaucratic Capacity and Bureaucratic Discretion: Does Congress Tie Policy Authority to Performance?
Jason A. MacDonald and William W. Franko, JR American Politics Research 2007; 35; 790 DOI: 10.1177/1532673X07301654 The online version of this article can be found at: http://apr.sagepub.com/cgi/content/abstract/35/6/790

Published by:
http://www.sagepublications.com

Additional services and information for American Politics Research can be found at: Email Alerts: http://apr.sagepub.com/cgi/alerts Subscriptions: http://apr.sagepub.com/subscriptions Reprints: http://www.sagepub.com/journalsReprints.nav Permissions: http://www.sagepub.com/journalsPermissions.nav Citations (this article cites 12 articles hosted on the SAGE Journals Online and HighWire Press platforms): http://apr.sagepub.com/cgi/content/refs/35/6/790

Downloaded from http://apr.sagepub.com by marta pohrib on November 27, 2007 2007 SAGE Publications. All rights reserved. Not for commercial use or unauthorized distribution.

Bureaucratic Capacity and Bureaucratic Discretion


Does Congress Tie Policy Authority to Performance?
Jason A. MacDonald William W. Franko Jr.
Kent State University

American Politics Research Volume 35 Number 6 November 2007 790-807 2007 Sage Publications 10.1177/1532673X07301654 http://apr.sagepub.com hosted at http://online.sagepub.com

This article assesses whether the managerial capacity of agencies influences the volume of policy authority that lawmakers delegate. Examining a sample of agencies whose managerial capacities were assessed along the same criteria, and allowing for the comparison of performance across agencies, we observe that poorly performing agencies are more likely to lose policy authority. Our findings suggest that lawmakers promote effective policymaking by giving agencies the incentive to perform well and that models of discretion that do not account for performance underestimate the effect of another factorpolicy conflict between the legislative and executive brancheson how much discretion agencies receive. Keywords: bureaucracy; Congress; public policy; bureaucratic discretion; agency capacity; delegation; policy authority

odern democracies confront complex problems, often employing policies that combine scientific knowledge across disciplines from the natural sciences and engineering to economics and policy analysis. Given this complexity, it is unlikely that modern lawmakerswith their backgrounds in law, business, and public servicewill ever be the most well-equipped individuals in government to design policy mechanisms to pursue favorable outcomes for these problems. Yet electoral status confers on lawmakers both the legitimacy to make policy decisions and the incentive to balance competing societal values and interests successfully. In part, lawmakers manage this responsibilitycapacity mismatch by delegating
Authors Note: The authors would like to thank Steve Balla and anonymous reviewers for American Politics Research for comments that improved this manuscript. This research was supported in part by the University Research Council of Kent State University. 790
Downloaded from http://apr.sagepub.com by marta pohrib on November 27, 2007 2007 SAGE Publications. All rights reserved. Not for commercial use or unauthorized distribution.

MacDonald, Franko / Bureaucratic Capacity and Bureaucratic Discretion

791

authority to make policy decisions to the bureaucracy, as has been documented in diverse research traditions from the political economy of institutional design (e.g., McCubbins, Noll, & Weingast, 1987; Moe, 1989) to American political development (e.g., Carpenter, 2001; James, 2000). A major area of research on delegation involves assessing why lawmakers vary the level of discretion provided to agencies, where discretion is defined as bureaucratic freedom to make policy decisions free from constraints, such as rulemaking-requirements, and other tools used by lawmakers to influence the substance of bureaucratic decisions (Epstein & OHalloran, 1999, chapter 5). A central finding of this research is that as policy disagreement between lawmakers and agencies increases lawmakers reduce the volume of discretion that agencies receive (Epstein & OHalloran, 1999; Huber & Shipan, 2002; Huber, Shipan, & Pfahler, 2001; Lewis, 2003; Potoski, 1999; Wood & Bohte, 2004). The theoretical basis for this finding is that policy disagreement prevents lawmakers from trusting agencies to render policy decisions consistent with lawmakers priorities. In the language of the transaction cost approach taken by these studies, such disagreement increases the costs of delegation to lawmakers to the point at which it becomes less costly for them to make policy themselves by writing detailed laws (see especially Epstein & OHalloran, 1999 and Huber & Shipan, 2002). These studies constitute significant theoretical and empirical progress in understanding why agencies receive discretion to make policy. However, this literature does not address the question of whether lawmakers vary discretion based on the capacity of agencies to make policies that are effective in meeting policy goals. This issue is central to understanding whether lawmakers decisions in delegating policy authority contribute to the capacity of democratic governments to solve problems. Some agencies perform the tasks delegated to them effectively, solving problems that the architects of legislation place in their hands, whereas other agencies flounder (Ingraham, Joyce, & Donahue, 2003). To be sure, theories of delegation stress that lawmakers provide greater discretion to agencies as policy complexity increases (Bawn, 1995; Epstein & OHalloran, 1999; Huber & Shipan, 2002). For any number of equally complex policy areas, though, the capacity of agencies to make effective policy can vary. Do agencies with greater/ lesser capacities receive higher/lower levels of discretion? If the answer is in the affirmative, then there is reason to believe that democratic governments can create effective solutions to important problems; however, if lawmakers do not tie bureaucratic authority, at least in part, to bureaucratic capacity, students of government should be more sanguine about the ability of democracies to solve many problems.
Downloaded from http://apr.sagepub.com by marta pohrib on November 27, 2007 2007 SAGE Publications. All rights reserved. Not for commercial use or unauthorized distribution.

792

American Politics Research

Agency Capacity and Bureaucratic Discretion


Research on discretion, bureaucratic autonomy, and agency termination provides a basis for the hypothesis that agency capacity affects the latitude agencies receive to make policy decisions, though no empirical research employs a systematic indicator of capacity that varies across agencies to assess the relationship. With respect to discretion, formal models predict that lawmakers provide greater discretion to agencies as policy complexity increaseseven when lawmakers expect that agencies will make policy decisions that stray from lawmakers priorities (Bawn, 1995; Epstein & OHalloran, 1999; Huber & Shipan, 2002). The basis for this result is that lawmakers need for policy solutions trumps the loss of utility they experience from bureaucratic shirking. The implication of this research for the relationship between capacity and discretion is clear. If lawmakers did not care about effective policy solutions, there would be no reason to delegate when agencies are likely to make decisions that stray from lawmakers priorities. Of course, if agencies reputations for effective policymaking are poor, then lawmakers have reason to doubt that agencies will produce effective solutions, undercutting the rationale for ceding discretion. This literature, therefore, suggests that agency capacity to perform the tasks delegated effectively is positively related to discretion. Research on bureaucratic autonomy suggests the same relationship, though the causal mechanism differs. Examining the histories of three agencies during the late 19th and early 20th centuries, Carpenter (2001) argues that elected institutions cede policy authority after agencies evidence the capacity to solve policy problems. Briefly, this capacity was created by middle-level managers, whose career longevities and institutional positions fostered policy learning and the ability to build support for policies they favored among diverse sets of interest groups. After securing interest group support for the policies they wanted to pursuein part because of sound reputations for the capacity to solve problems effectivelythese managers were able to place electoral pressure on members of Congress to give managers authority to create policies that they favored. Bureaucratic autonomy, then, was largely the result of sound policy performance engineered by managerial leadership. Research on agency termination also provides a basis for the hypothesis that discretion is because of the capacity to make policies effectively. Carpenter (2000) and Carpenter and Lewis (2004) argue that failure by an agency, accompanied by media coverage of the negative consequences of its bungling of the tasks to which it was assigned, imposes political fallout on the legislators that delegated authority. Such costs might include the loss
Downloaded from http://apr.sagepub.com by marta pohrib on November 27, 2007 2007 SAGE Publications. All rights reserved. Not for commercial use or unauthorized distribution.

MacDonald, Franko / Bureaucratic Capacity and Bureaucratic Discretion

793

of electoral support from key constituencies, the provision of an election issue to an opponent who could trace the lawmaker to the failure (Arnold, 1990) by credibly arguing that the lawmaker presided over the fiasco, and having to allocate scarce time on the legislative calendar in the future to revisit the policy. These costs increase the likelihood that legislators will exercise the ultimate act of political control (Carpenter & Lewis, 2004, p. 202), eliminating the agencyan act that, to understate the point, reduces discretion. In summary, various research traditions on the authority that agencies receive either suggest, or explicitly state, that discretion increases with agency capacity. The basis for this relationship is that lawmakers observe the capacity of agencies to perform the policymaking tasks delegated to them through a variety of means, including media reports (Carpenter & Lewis, 2004) and information from interest groups and constituents dissatisfied with agencies (McCubbins & Schwartz, 1984) and react by manipulating discretion in the future. Yet empirical support for this hypothesis is wanting. Neither research on discretion nor agency termination incorporates variables into empirical models of these phenomena to assess the influence of capacity on bureaucratic policy authority. Although Carpenter (2001) shows that the authority of the three agencies was due in large part to their reputation for effective policymaking, this finding has not been extended to contemporary politics.

Data and Methods


One reason why the relationship between capacity and discretion is not well understood empirically is because of the difficulty of calibrating capacity/performance in a valid manner and comparing it systematically across agencies. We take advantage of the availability of such a measure for a sample of 27 federal agencies. This sample was created by a joint effort of the Federal Performance Project (FPP), teamed by scholars in the Department of Public Administration at The George Washington University (GW) and correspondents for Government Executive, a biweekly periodical that provides specialized coverage of federal agencies. The project evaluated how well all agencies managed the tasks to which they were assigned, grading agencies in 1999, 2000, and 2001. To be clear, the FPP did not assess how well agencies achieved the policy goals assigned to them by laws enacted in the past. Rather, the project assessed how well agency managers managed for results based on the criteria employed by the researchers.1 Managing

Downloaded from http://apr.sagepub.com by marta pohrib on November 27, 2007 2007 SAGE Publications. All rights reserved. Not for commercial use or unauthorized distribution.

794

American Politics Research

for Results refers to administrating agencies, so that they can realize the outcomes they are charged with achieving by law. The researchers employed surveys of agency managers and employees, external reports on agency effectiveness, and interviews with experts on the agencies inside and outside government to gauge performance.2 Researchers at George Washington University and correspondents for Government Executive then evaluated this information across agencies and assigned grades based on the performance of agencies in relation to one another. Hence, according to the collective judgment of the researchers, agencies receiving As performed better than agencies receiving Bs on these criteria and so on. As such, the grades constitute assessments of the managerial capacity of agencies. A presence/ lack of capacity indicates the success/failure of managers to facilitate the realization of policy results desired by political principals. Although the sample of agencies is small, it represents the best data on agency capacity that are comparable across multiple agencies.3 Hence, in evaluating the connection between capacity and discretion, it makes sense to use this data as a starting point. Twenty-seven agencies were selected by FPP researchers because of their close interaction with the public. Therefore, the agencies do not represent a random sample of all federal agencies and our findings cannot be so generalized. Appendix A itemizes these agencies. The unit of analysis is the agency, that is, each agency has one observation and includes information on the grade received in the year that it was graded, as well as the other independent variables and the dependent variable described below. In evaluating the agencies management of their tasks, the FPP employed a grade range from F to A. However, no agency received F to D grades, limiting the range of the variables created to measure performance. Below, we assess the relationship between how much Congress limits the agencies discretion in the year after the grades were assigned and these grades. We do so by measuring capacity in three ways. First, we employ the plus/minus grades on a 1-13 scale with a grade of F coded as 1 and an A coded as 13 (in practice, the scale ranged between 4 and 13). Second, we employ a collapsed, traditional grade version of this variable ranging from F (1) to A (5) to guard against the possibility that there is little difference between, for example, a B and B (in practice, this scale ranged between 2 and 5). Finally, to account for the possibility that performance affects discretion in a nonlinear manner, we create dummy variables for whether the agencies received grades of D, C, or B (1 if the agencies received these grades; 0 otherwise), with A as the reference category (because no agency received an F, no dummy variable for this grade was

Downloaded from http://apr.sagepub.com by marta pohrib on November 27, 2007 2007 SAGE Publications. All rights reserved. Not for commercial use or unauthorized distribution.

MacDonald, Franko / Bureaucratic Capacity and Bureaucratic Discretion

795

created). The basis for this variable is that Congress may not view the difference between an A and B performance as it does a C and D performance. For example, Congress may take no action to limit the discretion of an agency when it receives a B instead of an A; although the agencys performance is not excellent, its mere good performance probably will not cause a political fallout. However, once an agencys performance becomes lackluster, for example, if the agencys performance is worthy of a D, political principals may limit discretion. Calibrating performance in this way allows us to observe such nonlinear effects. To be clear, we offer no theory that specifies precisely how poorly an agency must perform to lose discretion; rather, we note that it makes sense theoretically that Congress will limit discretion after performance has become sufficiently poor. How low capacity must be to reach this tipping point will remain an empirical question.4 To measure discretion, we create a variable that is the count of the number of limitation riders (LRs) attached to agencies appropriations in the year after their managerial capacities were assessed by the FPP. LRs forbid agencies from spending money for specific purposes. Importantly, agencies possess the authority to use funds for these purposes from past laws. However, when an LR is included in an appropriations bill that becomes law, agencies are prohibited from exercising that authority during the next fiscal year, limiting their discretion. For example, the fiscal year 2001 Labor, Health and Human Services, and Education appropriations bill mandated that none of the funds . . . may be used by the Occupational Safety and Health Administration to promulgate, issue, implement, administer, or enforce any proposed, temporary, or final standard on ergonomic protection. Congress includes hundreds of such LRs in appropriations bills annually (MacDonald, 2007), giving it an annual opportunity to reign in agency authority. As such, LRs constitute a tool that Congress employs to constrain agency authority regularly, making these tools of political control a valid indicator of the limitation of discretion.5 To measure how much Congress impinged on discretion, we counted the number of LRs in Congresss annual appropriation acts that applied to each of the 27 agencies in the year after their performances were evaluated by the FPP.6 We examined LRs in the subsequent year because that was Congresss first opportunity to limit discretion after performance was assessed during the period for which grades were assigned.7 Therefore, for agencies whose performances were assessed in 1999/2000/2001, we counted LRs imposed on these agencies in the appropriations bills passed in 2000/2001/2002. If discretion is reduced because of low capacity, the relationship between this

Downloaded from http://apr.sagepub.com by marta pohrib on November 27, 2007 2007 SAGE Publications. All rights reserved. Not for commercial use or unauthorized distribution.

796

American Politics Research

dependent variable and the independent variables measuring capacity using the plus/minus and traditional grade scales should be negative and significant, whereas its relationship with the dummy variables indicating the presence of low capacity (e.g., the dummy variable for agencies who received the grade of D) should be positive and significant. Because research demonstrates that Congress limits discretion when faced with a president of the opposite party (Epstein & OHalloran, 1999), a finding that holds for state governments (Huber & Shipan, 2002; Huber et al., 2001), we control for partisan conflict between the legislative and executive branches. To do so, we employ a dummy variable assuming the value of 1 when there is pure divided government, meaning that the presidency was controlled by one party and both chambers of Congress were controlled by its rival. Therefore, observations for agencies graded in 1999, for which we counted LRs applied in 2000 (under Democratic control of the presidency and Republican control of the House and Senate), were coded 1. Observations for agencies graded in 2000 and 2001, for which we counted LRs applied in 2001 and 2002, respectively (under Republican control of the presidency and House and Democratic control of the Senate), were coded as 0. Although the Democratic Senate had the opportunity to influence the substance of appropriations bills during these years, its capacity to do so was limited to a greater degree than was the case for the Republicans who controlled both chambers in 2000. We expect this variable to be positively and significantly related to the number of LRs imposed on agencies. We also account for congressional and presidential policy disagreement with agencies missions. Carpenter and Lewis (2004) show that agencies are more likely to be eliminated when the same party controls the U.S. House and the presidency but held minority status in the House and did not control the presidency when the agency was created. Agencies in this situation are in a precarious position because the current majority party is likely to object to the policy priorities embodied in the agencies missions. This conditiona unified governments hostility toward agencies missionsmakes it more likely for such agencies to lose discretion. Therefore, following Carpenter and Lewis (2004), we create a variable assuming the value of 1 when this hostility condition holds, 0 otherwise, and expect this variable to be positively and significantly associated with the imposition of LRs. Additionally, because research shows that the public salience of policies increases the likelihood that members of Congress make, rather than delegate, policy (Epstein & OHalloran, 1999, chap. 8; Gormley, 1986, 1989) and that Congress tries to influence bureaucratic policy decisions to a greater extent in salient policy areas (Ringquist, Worsham, & Eisner, 2003), we control

Downloaded from http://apr.sagepub.com by marta pohrib on November 27, 2007 2007 SAGE Publications. All rights reserved. Not for commercial use or unauthorized distribution.

MacDonald, Franko / Bureaucratic Capacity and Bureaucratic Discretion

797

for the salience of the policy area over which agencies have jurisdiction. This variable is a count of the number of stories appearing in the New York Times in which the agency was mentioned during the year before the agency was graded.8 In general, the Timess coverage is followed by other media outlets (Page, 1996). As such, this count approximates the degree to which the agencies missions are made salient to the public. We expect that it will be positively and significantly related to the imposition of LRs.9 Finally, we control for the size of the appropriation bill in which the agencies were funded, because bigger bills may contain a higher volume of LRs. Appendix B provides summary statistics for all variables employed in the analysis.10 Because the dependent variable is a count, we employ the Poisson maximum likelihood estimator to assess the effects of the independent variables on the volume of LRs using the traditional grade-scale specification and the dummy variable grade specification. In using the plus/minus grade scale specification, likelihood ratio tests indicated that the variance of the dependent variable exceeded its mean; therefore, we employed the negative binomial maximum likelihood estimator for this model.

Findings
Models 1, 2, and 3 of Table 1 present estimates for the influence of the independent variables on the volume of LRs, employing the traditional grade scale variable (Model 1), the plus/minus grade scale variable (Model 2), and dummy variables for agency grades (Model 3). The hypothesis that Congress limits discretion as capacity declines is supported in all three models. Measuring capacity using the traditional and plus/minus grades assigned to the agencies yields a negative and significant association between the number of LRs imposed on agencies and the coefficient for agency grades. Additionally, in Model 3, the coefficients of the dummy variables indicating that the agency received Cs and Ds are positively and significantly associated with the number of LRs with which agencies were burdened. This specification supports the interpretation that once agency performance drops below some adequate level at which Congress is willing to leave agencies alone, Congress will reduce discretion. Empirically, Model 3 identifies this threshold level as the performance that merits a C based on the FPPs criteria. Table 2 provides information on the magnitude of the influence of performance, as measured by the traditional grade scale, on LRs use, as estimated by Model 1. Setting the values of the independent variables to

Downloaded from http://apr.sagepub.com by marta pohrib on November 27, 2007 2007 SAGE Publications. All rights reserved. Not for commercial use or unauthorized distribution.

798

American Politics Research

Table 1 Poisson Regression Models of the Imposition of Limitation Riders on the FPP Sample of Agencies in the Year After Agency Performance Was Graded
Independent Variables Traditional grade scale Plus/minus grade scale B C D Divided government Unified and hostile government No. of New York Times stories No. of pages in bill Constant Log likelihood Chi-square N .188 (.144) .298* (.141) .0010* (.0005) .005* (.002) 3.254 (.270) 86.181 31.30*** 27 .107 (.132) .321* (.179) .0010 (.0007) .006* (.003) 3.120 (.320) 85.57 14.49*** 27 Model 1 .191*** (.056) .060*** (.024) .127 (.145) .277* (.141) .784*** (.230) .193 (.121) .358** (.152) .0010* (.0005) .004* (.002) 2.636 (.188) 85.02 33.63*** 27 Model 2 Model 3

Note: Coefficients are unstandardized. Standard errors are in parentheses. The estimates for Models 1 and 3 are Poisson maximum likelihood estimates, because likelihood ratio tests did not reject the null hypothesis that the mean and variance of LRs were equal. The estimates for Model 2 are negative binomial maximum likelihood estimates, because the null hypothesis that the mean and variance of LRs were equal could be rejected (p < .05) and the alpha statistic was positive. Models 1 and 3 were also analyzed using the negative binomial estimator; the only change in the significance of the coefficients was that, for both models, the no. of New York Times stories variable was significant at the .1, rather than at the .05, level. p < .10. *p < .05. **p < .01. ***p < .001 (one-tailed tests).

the modal or mean values, the model predicts that about 20 LRs will be imposed on agencies receiving a B.11 However, when agencies receive an A, this prediction drops to approximately 17 LRs. Conversely, when agencies managerial capacities are graded at the C and D levels, the model predicts that agencies will be saddled with about 25 and 30 LRs,

Downloaded from http://apr.sagepub.com by marta pohrib on November 27, 2007 2007 SAGE Publications. All rights reserved. Not for commercial use or unauthorized distribution.

MacDonald, Franko / Bureaucratic Capacity and Bureaucratic Discretion

799

Table 2 The Predicted Number of Limitation Riders by Agency Characteristics (Model 1 Estimates)
Agency Characteristics Performance A B (baseline) C D Policy disagreement with agencies Agency has support in at least one branch (baseline) Unified and hostile government No. of New York Times stories Mean (baseline) + 1 Standard deviation Predicted Values for Model 1: Traditional Grade Scale

16.62 20.30 24.65 29.98 20.30 27.93 20.30 21.61

Note: Predicted values were calculated using Clarify (Tomz et al., 2003). The predicted values are compared with a hypothetical, or baseline model, where the variables are set to the modal or mean categories. The baseline was calculated using an agency operating under divided government that received a B, was created during a period when the presidency and the House were not controlled by a unified and hostile party, and was covered by the New York Times at the mean level for all agencies (58.63 stories). The bill in which the baseline agency was funded spanned 65.85 pages.

respectively. Hence, a decline in performance from the maximum to minimum grades assigned by the FPP leads to almost a 2 standard deviation increase in the number of LRs that Congress is expected to impose on agencies. Simulationsnot presentedbased on the coefficients from Model 2 present a similar story. Simulations using the coefficients from Model 3 paint a more nuanced picture of the relationship between managerial performance and discretion. Setting the independent variables to their mean and modal values with the dummy variable for a B grade equal to 1, Model 3 predicts that Congress will impose about 21 LRs on agencies, a prediction that decreases to 18 if agencies receive As, and increases to 24 if agencies receive Cs. However, Model 3 predicts that Congress will attach about 41 LRs to appropriations language funding agencies programs during the next fiscal year if a D is assigned to their managerial performance. This finding suggests that there is a nonlinear relationship between performance and discretion. It is also consistent with a bounded rationality explanation of political institutions (Jones & Baumgartner, 2005). Specifically, the finding suggests that Congress underreacts to information

Downloaded from http://apr.sagepub.com by marta pohrib on November 27, 2007 2007 SAGE Publications. All rights reserved. Not for commercial use or unauthorized distribution.

800

American Politics Research

stressing that the performance of agencies is merely average (C grades), limiting discretion slightly. However, when Congress learns that agency performance is poor (D grades), it decreases discretion greatly. The hypothesis that divided government reduces discretion receives some support for the models presented in Table 1. The coefficient for the divided government variable is positively and significantly related to the number of LRs imposed on agencies in Models 1 and 3, albeit at the .1 level. Turning to the hypothesis that a unified and hostile government leads to less discretion, the coefficient for a hostile and unified government is positive and significant in all three models, providing support for the hypothesis. Table 2 provides information on the magnitude of this relationship, showing that Model 1 predicts about eight additional LRs (approximately 1 standard deviation of the dependent variable) for an agency supervised by a U.S. House and a president controlled by the opposite party that created the agency. Additionally, the number of stories in the New York Times mentioning agencies is positively and significantly related to the number of LRs imposed on agencies in all three models presented in Table 1. Table 2 shows that Model 1 predicts two additional LRs for agencies mentioned by the Times at a standard deviation above the mean of that variable. This finding supports the hypothesis derived from the work of Gormley (1986, 1989) by Ringquist et al. (2003) that Congress will try to influence the bureaucracys policy decisions to a greater degree in policy areas that the public views as salient. Ringquist et al. (2003) find that Congress both introduces and passes a greater number of new bills to reverse agency decisions when agencies preside over policy areas of salience to the public. The positive and significant coefficients for this variable, though not the main focus of the research presented in this article, reinforce this finding. One objection to the analysis presented above involves the ability to draw conclusions based on this small sample of agencies. What if the few agencies receiving very low grades happened to be burdened with relatively high numbers of LRs for idiosyncratic reasons, and these reasons led to the significant relationships between performance and discretion observed in the models? If this is the case, a sample with more agencies, or an analysis including the entire population of federal agencies, would make it less likely that we would make a Type I error and reject the null hypothesis that performance does not influence discretion when it is in fact true. To respond to this very real concern, we reestimated Models 1 and 2 without the one observation for which an agency received a D. In Model 1, the coefficient for the Traditional Grade Scale variable remained positive and

Downloaded from http://apr.sagepub.com by marta pohrib on November 27, 2007 2007 SAGE Publications. All rights reserved. Not for commercial use or unauthorized distribution.

MacDonald, Franko / Bureaucratic Capacity and Bureaucratic Discretion

801

significant (p < .05). This finding held for Model 2, though the significance slipped to the .1 level.12 In other words, it is not simply one observation driving the finding that Congress imposes a greater number of LRs on agencies as the managerial performance of agencies decreases.13

Conclusions
The Federal Emergency Management Agencys (FEMA) bungling of the federal response to the devastation wrought by Hurricane Katrina and the scurrying by members of Congress and President Bush to avoid the political fallout (e.g., VandeHei, 2005; Weisman & Goldstein, 2005) demonstrate that poor performance on the part of agencies managers can create substantial trouble for elected officials.14 Additionally, formal theories of delegation stress that legislatures are willing to trade control over policy for the technical expertise agencies offer (Bawn, 1995; Epstein & OHalloran, 1999). It should be no surprise, then, that when agencies perform poorly elected officials respond by stripping agency authority. Yet to our knowledge, no prior research has examined the relationship between agency capacity and discretion across a large sample of agencies. To be sure, research on agency termination emphasizes agency failure as a factor that increases the risk of termination (Carpenter, 2000; Carpenter & Lewis, 2004); however, this research does not show a relationship between these phenomena because of the lack of a measure of performance across the sample of agencies it examines. Using a unique data set, we observe that lower levels of performance are indeed associated with the loss of discretion, controlling for the political environment, the salience of the agency, and the size of appropriations legislation through which lawmakers scale back discretion. These findings suggest the need to account for performance for a more complete understanding of why lawmakers grant discretion. Importantly, this emphasis on performance implies that lawmakers give agencies the incentive to make effective policies. If agencies want freedom to design the programs under their direction, as research on bureaucratic policymaking emphasizes (Carpenter, 2001), then convincing lawmakers of their effectiveness is one way to obtain this freedom. Although prior studies of discretion improved the understanding of interbranch policymaking substantially, they provided no evidence as to whether lawmakers rewarded effective agencies by increasing their authority to make policy decisions (or punished ineffective agencies by reducing such authority). Our analysis, however,

Downloaded from http://apr.sagepub.com by marta pohrib on November 27, 2007 2007 SAGE Publications. All rights reserved. Not for commercial use or unauthorized distribution.

802

American Politics Research

implies that lawmakers promote effective policymaking, a hopeful finding in an era in which many problems are complex and require bureaucratic expertise. As such, it is consistent with recent research stressing that Congress sometimes fosters effective policymaking by employing policy research (Esterling, 2004). An additional implication of this study is that models of discretion that do not control for performance risk underestimating the influence of legislative executive policy conflict on discretion. Consider one hypothetical case during unified government when legislativeexecutive conflict is low, and, all else equal, lawmakers are prone to grant discretion (Epstein & OHalloran, 1999; Huber & Shipan, 2002). Nevertheless, the agency that would implement a law under consideration has a poor record of performance, leading lawmakers to scale back the agencys discretion. In contrast, a second case occurs during divided government when lawmakers, all else equal, lean toward slashing discretion. In this case, however, the agency that would receive authority has a record of good performance, enticing lawmakers to take advantage of its technical capacity (Bawn, 1995) by providing more discretion than they would have if the agency had a mediocre reputation. Ignoring considerations about performance, theory would predict a relatively high level of discretion for the former observation and a relatively low level of discretion for the latter. However, considerations about performance attenuate this relationship. Any model using these observations to probe the relationship between legislativeexecutive conflict and discretion that did not control for performance, then, would underestimate the magnitude of the relationship between interbranch policy conflict and discretion. Therefore, the findings of this research suggest that prior studies of discretion that do not control for performance observe a weaker connection than exists. Of course, our findings are based on a relatively small number of agencies whose inclusion in the sample was based on their close interaction with the public. Do lawmakers limit discretion based on performance generally? Or is this relationship conditional on the nature of agencies interaction with the public? Future research on the link between capacity and discretion should focus on developing measures of performance across more, and different types of, agencies to answer these questions. This is especially the case given there is good reason to believe that many of the factors influencing the volume of discretion agencies receive are conditional. For example, Volden (2002) theorizes that interbranch policy disagreement influences how much discretion agencies receive conditional on the existence of an executive veto. Similarly, Huber and Shipan (2002) theorize that the professional capacity of legislatures to craft effective policies conditions

Downloaded from http://apr.sagepub.com by marta pohrib on November 27, 2007 2007 SAGE Publications. All rights reserved. Not for commercial use or unauthorized distribution.

MacDonald, Franko / Bureaucratic Capacity and Bureaucratic Discretion

803

whether interbranch disagreement affects how much discretion agencies receive, and they provide empirical support for this perspective. Additionally, although our findings support the hypothesis that (a lack of) capacity (reduces) increases the policymaking authority that agencies receive, there are several causal mechanisms that can account for this relationship. A goal of future research should be to explore the underlying cause. Do lawmakers cede (reduce) authority based on assessments of how likely the agencys actions are to lead to negative political fallout? Are lawmakers concerned intrinsically about the quality of policies created by agencies when providing authority?

Appendix A
Federal Agencies Graded by the Federal Performance Project
Agency Coast Guard National Weather Service Social Security Administration Postal service Administration for Children and Families Army Corps of Engineers Federal Emergency Management Agency Food and Drug Administration Food and Nutrition Service Food Safety and Inspection Service NASA Veterans Health Administration Environmental Protection Agency Federal Housing Administration Occupational Safety and Health Administration Patent and Trademark Office Veterans Benefits Administration Bureau of Consular Affairs Customs service Federal Aviation Administration Forest service Health Care Financing Administration Internal Revenue Service National Park Service Office of Student Financial Assistance Immigration and Naturalization Service Bureau of Indian Affairs Year of Grade 2000 2001 1999 2001 2001 2000 1999 1999 1999 1999 2001 1999 1999 1999 1999 1999 2000 2001 1999 1999 2001 1999 1999 2000 2000 1999 2001 Grade A A A A B B B B B B B B B B B B B C C C C C C C C C D

Downloaded from http://apr.sagepub.com by marta pohrib on November 27, 2007 2007 SAGE Publications. All rights reserved. Not for commercial use or unauthorized distribution.

804

American Politics Research

Appendix B
Descriptive Statistics
Variable Limitation riders Grade dummies B C D Traditional grade scale Plus/minus grade scale Divided government Unified and hostile government No. of New York Times stories No. of pages in bill Minimum 6 0 0 0 2 4 0 0 0 28 Maximum 36 1 1 1 5 13 1 1 304 98 Mean 21.63 0.48 0.33 0.04 3.74 8.96 0.56 0.11 58.63 65.85 Standard Deviation 7.62 0.51 0.48 0.19 0.76 2.24 0.51 0.32 75.65 21.33

Notes
1. Briefly, the criteria included how well managers defined and measured success, managed agency resources, took measures to ensure that managers were held accountable for decisions and performance, communicated effectively and honestly with stakeholders and political principals, ensured that employees possessed information necessary to perform tasks to achieve results, staffed individuals with appropriate skills for the tasks they performed, possessed the physical infrastructure necessary to achieve the results, and provided sound fiscal management. 2. The FPP interviews included groups such as congressional oversight and appropriations committees, the GAO, the OMB, think tanks, the press, client and advocacy groups, academic institutions, and government commissions (Laurent, 1999). More detailed information about the FPP can be found on the projects Web site: http://www.gwu.edu/~fpp/. Also see Ingraham et al. (2003). 3. Another source on agency performance is the Performance Assessment Rating Tool (PART) through which the Office of Management and Budget (OMB) evaluates the performance of federal programs. Using PART data would increase the size of the sample of agencies. However, given that the OMB works directly for the president within the executive office of the president (EOP), and given that presidents politicize the work of the EOP (Lewis, 2005; Moe, 1985), we believe that PART ratings are likely to be endogenous to the political priorities of the president, making them an invalid measurement of agency performance. 4. The grades assigned to agencies by the FPP can be found in Laurent (1999, 2000, 2001). 5. Measuring the volume of authority stripped from agencies in this way has an advantage. It is possible that agencies that possess high levels of discretion develop greater capacities than agencies that possess low levels of discretion. If this were the case, employing a dependent variable that measures the volume of discretion that agencies possess would preclude unbiased estimates of the influence of capacity on discretion because higher levels of discretion also cause high levels of capacity. However, our indicator measures the volume of authority taken away from an agency in year t + 1. Authority taken away in the future cannot

Downloaded from http://apr.sagepub.com by marta pohrib on November 27, 2007 2007 SAGE Publications. All rights reserved. Not for commercial use or unauthorized distribution.

MacDonald, Franko / Bureaucratic Capacity and Bureaucratic Discretion

805

affect agency capacity in the present. Additionally, existing research on the link between agency capacity and authority emphasizes that capacity leads to authority (Carpenter, 2001) rather than the other way around, suggesting that, at any rate, managerial capacity is not endogenous to the volume of discretion agencies possess. 6. All the agencies graded by the FPP receive funding from these bills. We examined the versions of bills that became public lawrather than House/Senate committee passed or House/Senate passed versions. 7. To count LRs, we first identified the bill in which the agency was funded. Next, we counted the number of instances stating no funds or none of the funds could be spent for specific purposes that applied to the agency. LRs applied to the agency if they were located in the specific section funding the agency, or a general provisions section, or title that applied to the agency. Using counts of the number of LRs in the year during which, and the year before, performance was graded did not change the findings reported below. 8. This count was obtained through a Lexis/Nexis search of agency names, as they appear in Appendix A, in the titles and lead paragraphs of New York Times stories in the year before the agencys managerial performance was graded. 9. Ringquist et al. (2003) also examine the relationship between complexity and congressional efforts to direct the bureaucracy, finding no direct relationship between complexity and such efforts even though complexity does condition the relationship between salience and such efforts. We opt not to control for complexity in our analysis because of the following: The primary focus of our analysis does not involve the relationship between policy type and discretion. These authors found no direct relationship between complexity and such efforts. There is no readily available measure of complexity across agencies. The degrees of freedom in our analysis is small to begin with. 10. Huber and Shipan (2002) identify factors, such as legislative capacity that vary across legislatures influencing the level of discretion agencies receive. In the analysis below, we focus on cases in which a single legislature delegates authority. Therefore, these factors are constant and cannot explain variance in our dependent variable. 11. The note in Table 2 provides information on these baseline values. Predictions were calculated using Clarify 2.1 (Tomz, Wittenberg, & King, 2003). 12. These results are available from the authors on request. 13. The results of this estimation are available from the authors on request. 14. The title of VandeHeis article in The Washington Post illustrates the alacrity with which members of Congress and the President sought to avoid the political costs of Federal Emergency Management Agencys (FEMA) failure: Officials Deal with Political Fallout by Pointing Fingers.

References
Arnold, R. D. (1990). The logic of congressional action. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press. Bawn, K. (1995, March). Political control versus expertise: Congressional choices about administrative procedures. American Political Science Review, 89, 62-73. Carpenter, D. P. (2000). Stochastic prediction and estimation of nonlinear political durations: An application to the lifetime of bureaus. In D. Richards (Ed.), Political complexity: Nonlinear models of politics (pp. 209-238). Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

Downloaded from http://apr.sagepub.com by marta pohrib on November 27, 2007 2007 SAGE Publications. All rights reserved. Not for commercial use or unauthorized distribution.

806

American Politics Research

Carpenter, D. P. (2001). The forging of bureaucratic autonomy: Reputations, networks and policy innovation in executive agencies, 1862-1928. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Carpenter, D. P., & Lewis, D. E. (2004, Summer). Political learning from rare events: Poisson inference, fiscal constraints, and the lifetime of bureaus. Political Analysis, 12, 201-232. Epstein, D., & OHalloran, S. (1999). Delegating powers: A transaction cost politics approach to policy making under separate powers. New York: Cambridge University Press. Esterling, K. M. (2004). The political economy of expertise: Information and efficiency in American national institutions. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press. Gormley, W. (1986). Regulatory issue networks in a federal system. Polity, 18(4), 595-620. Gormley, W. (1989). Taming the bureaucracy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Huber, J. D., & Shipan, C. R. (2002). Deliberate discretion: The institutional foundations of bureaucratic autonomy. New York: Cambridge University Press. Huber, J. D., Shipan, C. R., & Pfahler, M. (2001, April). Legislatures and statutory control of the bureaucracy. American Journal of Political Science, 45, 330-345. Ingraham, P., Joyce, P. K., & Donahue, A. K. (2003). Government performance: Why management matters. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press. James, S. C. (2000). Presidents, parties, and the state: A party system perspective on democratic regulatory choice, 1884-1936. New York: Cambridge University Press. Jones, B. D., & Baumgartner, F. R. (2005). The politics of attention: How governments prioritize problems. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Laurent, A. (1999, February 1). Stacking up. Government Executive, 31(2). Retrieved April 30, 2007, from http://www.govexec.com/gpp/0299over.htm Laurent, A. (2000, March 1). Measuring up. Government Executive, 32(3), 10-15. Retrieved April 30, 2007, from http://www.govexec.com/gpp/0300ov.htm Laurent, A. (2001, April 1). Managing for results. Government Executive, 33(4). Retrieved April 30, 2007, from http://www.govexec.com/fpp/fpp01/s1.htm Lewis, D. E. (2003). Presidents and the politics of agency design: Political insulation in the United States government bureaucracy, 1946-1997. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press. Lewis, D. E. (2005, September). Staffing alone: Unilateral action and the politicization of the executive office of the president, 1988-2004. Presidential Studies Quarterly, 35, 496-514. MacDonald, J. A. (2007). Competing agents: Managing policy through competition in the U.S. House of Representatives. Typescript, Kent State University, OH. McCubbins, M. D., Noll, R. G., & Weingast, B. R. (1987). Administrative procedures as instruments of political control. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 3, 243-277. McCubbins, M. D., & Schwartz, T. (1984). Congressional oversight overlooked: Police patrols versus fire alarms. American Journal of Political Science, 2, 165-179. Moe, T. M. (1985). The politicized presidency. In J. E. Chubb & P. E. Peterson (Eds.), New directions in American politics (pp. 235-271). Washington, DC: Brookings Institution. Moe, T. M. (1989). The politics of bureaucratic structure. In J. E. Chubb & P. E. Peterson (Eds.), Can the government govern? (pp. 267-330). Washington, DC: Brookings Institution. Page, B. I. (1996). Who deliberates? Mass media in modern democracy. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Potoski, M. (1999, October). Managing uncertainty through bureaucratic design: Administrative procedures and state air pollution control agencies. Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory, 9, 623-639. Ringquist, E. J., Worsham, J., & Eisner, M. A. (2003). Salience, complexity, and the legislative direction of regulatory bureaucracies. Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory, 13, 141-164.

Downloaded from http://apr.sagepub.com by marta pohrib on November 27, 2007 2007 SAGE Publications. All rights reserved. Not for commercial use or unauthorized distribution.

MacDonald, Franko / Bureaucratic Capacity and Bureaucratic Discretion

807

Tomz, M., Wittenberg, J., & King, G. (2003, January 5). CLARIFY: Software for interpreting and presenting statistical results (version 2.1). Stanford University, University of Wisconsin, and Harvard University. Retrieved March 10, 2006, from http://gking.harvard.edu VandeHei, J. (2005, September 5). Officials deal with political fallout by pointing fingers. The Washington Post, p. A17. Volden, C. (2002, January). A formal model of the politics of delegation in a separation of powers system. American Journal of Political Science, 46, 111-133. Weisman, J., & Goldstein, A. (2005, September 8). Bush requests $51.8 billion more for relief; GOP leaders launch inquiry on Katrina preparation and response. The Washington Post, pp. A1+. Wood, B. D., & Bohte, J. (2004, February). Political transaction costs and the politics of administrative design. Journal of Politics, 66, 176-202.

Jason A. MacDonald is an assistant professor in the Department of Political Science at Kent State University. William W. Franko Jr. is a PhD candidate in the Department of Political Science at Kent State University.

Downloaded from http://apr.sagepub.com by marta pohrib on November 27, 2007 2007 SAGE Publications. All rights reserved. Not for commercial use or unauthorized distribution.

Das könnte Ihnen auch gefallen