Sie sind auf Seite 1von 92

A

GRAND PROJECT PROPOSAL


ON

A STUDY ON MICRO-FINANCE AS BUSINESS


PROPOSITION FOR BANK FROM THE PERSPECTIVE
OF NABARD
TABLE OF CONTENT

Preface…………………………………………………………………………………1
Acknowledgement……………………………………………………………………..2
Executive Summary…………………………………………………………………...3

1. Overview of microfinance………………………………………………………...10
2. Micro-Finance and Poverty Alleviation…………………………………………..10
3. The system and procedure of microfinance ………………………………………10
4. Microfinance in India ……………………………………………………………..10
5. Microfinance in Gujarat through SHG…………………………………………… 10
6. Role of NABARD in microfinance………………………………………………..10
7. Problems of banks, SHGS, microfinance institutions in micro financing…………
10
8. THE FUTURE OF MICROFINANCE IN INDIA:
9. Finding and Suggestions…………………………………………………………..10

Conclusion……………………………………………………………………………10

Abbreviations
Bibliography
EXECUTIVE SUMMARY

The project here we have taken is the "_______________"

The first part gives an introduction of infrastructure sector in India. Followed by


information on road sector. It gives an overview of various sector like port, Railways,
Power, Airports, Roads etc. In the in infrastructure of India. It also studies the current

Microfinance may be defined by the as "provision of thrift, credit and


other financial services and products of very small amounts to the poor
in rural, semi-urban or urban areas for enabling them to raise their
income levels and improve living standards"
OBJECTIVES

 To study microfinance infrastructure and its usefulness to poor in India in


general and in Gujarat in particular.
 To know the system and procedure of linking and financing of microfinance
 To know the functioning and management of microfinance beneficiary group
 To find problems of banks, SHGS, microfinance institutions, NGOs and SHG
Members.
 To suggest the various measures to improve the micro credit system
OVERVIEW OF MICROFINANCE

Concept of microfinance

To most, microfinance means providing very poor families with very small loans
(microcredit) to help them engage in productive activities or grows their tiny
businesses. Over time, microfinance has come to include a broader range of services
(credit, savings, insurance, etc.) as we have come to realize that the poor and the very
poor who lack access to traditional formal financial institutions require a variety of
financial products.

Microfinance is the provision of a broad range of


financial services such as

• deposits
• loans
• payment services
• money transfers
• insurance to poor and low-income households and their micro
enterprises

The important difference of microcredit was that it avoided the pitfalls of an earlier
generation of targeted development lending, by insisting on repayment, by charging
interest rates that could cover the costs of credit delivery, and by focusing on client
groups whose alternative source of credit was the informal sector. Emphasis shifted
from rapid disbursement of subsidized loans to prop up targeted sectors towards the
building up of local, sustainable institutions to serve the poor. Microcredit has largely
been a private (non-profit) sector initiative that avoided becoming overtly political,
and as a consequence, has outperformed virtually all other forms of development
lending.

Traditionally, microfinance was focused on providing a very standardized credit


product. The poor, just like anyone else, need a diverse range of financial instruments
to be able to build assets, stabilize consumption and protect themselves against risks.
Thus, we see a broadening of the concept of microfinance--our current challenge is to
find efficient and reliable ways of providing a richer menu of microfinance products.

Definition of microfinance:

The ‘TASK FORCE’ on Micro-finance constituted by National Bank for Agriculture


and Rural Development (NABARD) suggested a working definition of micro-finance
as “provision of thrift, credit and other financial services and products of very small
amounts to the poor to enable them to raise their income and improve their living
standards”. The upper limit of amount is fixed at Rs.25000 to be categorised as micro-
finance.

Thrift implies savings created by postponing almost necessary consumption while


savings imply the existence of surplus wealth.
Outreach and sustainability have often been cited as the twin pillars for successful
micro-finance. Sustainable microfinance requires good social intermediation and
prudent financial intermediation.

The micro-finance movement has gained acceptability and momentum in the


developing community largely due to the recognition that the nature of financial
markets in most developing countries creates a credit gaps for the poor. Most formal
financial institutions do not serve the poor because they are perceived as high risk and
high cost involved in small transactions relative to profitability and inability of the
poor to provide the physical collateral required by MFIs.

Early efforts to provide financial services to the poor tied those services to specific
economic activity. For example, between the 1950s and 1970s, governments and
donors focused on providing subsidised agricultural credit to small and marginal
farmers, in hopes of raising productivity and incomes. During the 1980s micro
enterprise credit concentrated on providing loans to poor women to invest in tiny
businesses, enabling them to generate and accumulate assets and raise household
income and welfare.

The success of some micro enterprise credit programs led to bold experiments with
product design, delivery methods, and institutional structures, performed mainly by
practitioners in developing countries. These experiments resulted in the emergence of
microfinance institutions (MFIs), specialised financial institutions that serve the poor.
MFIs are called "micro" because of the small size of their transactions (with loans as
small as Rs.2500 and savings deposits as small as Rs.50), and "finance" because they
provide safe and reliable financial services to the poor.

“microfinance may be defined by the as "provision of thrift, credit and other financial
services and products of very small amounts to the poor in rural, semi-urban or
urban areas for enabling them to raise their income levels and improve living
standards".

The difference between microfinance and microcredit

Microfinance refers to loans, savings, insurance, transfer services and other financial
products targeted at low-income clients. Microcredit refers to a small loan to a client
made by a bank or other institution. Microcredit can be offered, often without
collateral, to an individual or through group lending.

The clients of microfinance

The typical microfinance clients are low-income persons that do not have access to
formal financial institutions. Microfinance clients are typically self-employed, often
household-based entrepreneurs. In rural areas, they are usually small farmers and
others who are engaged in small income-generating activities such as food processing
and petty trade. In urban areas, microfinance activities are more diverse and include
shopkeepers, service providers, artisans, street vendors, etc. Microfinance clients are
poor and vulnerable non-poor who have a relatively stable source of income.
The Role of microfinance in helping the poor

Experience shows that microfinance can help the poor to increase income, build
viable businesses, and reduce their vulnerability to external shocks. It can also be a
powerful instrument for self-empowerment by enabling the poor, especially women,
to become economic agents of change.

Poverty is multi-dimensional. By providing access to financial services, microfinance


plays an important role in the fight against the many aspects of poverty. For instance,
income generation from a business helps not only the business activity expand but
also contributes to household income and its attendant benefits on food security,
children's education, etc. Moreover, for women, who, in many contexts, are secluded
from public space, transacting with formal institutions can also build confidence and
empowerment.

Recent research has revealed the extent to which individuals around the poverty line
are vulnerable to shocks such as illness of a wage earner, weather, theft, or other such
events. These shocks produce a huge claim on the limited financial resources of the
family unit, and, absent effective financial services, can drive a family so much
deeper into poverty that it can take years to recover.

Why do MFIs charge such high interest rates to poor people?

Providing financial services to poor people is quite expensive, especially in relation to


the size of the transactions involved. This is one of the most important reasons why
banks don't make small loans. A Rs.5000 for example, requires the same personnel
and resources as a Rs.100000 one thus increasing per unit transaction costs. Loan
officers must visit the client's home or place of work, evaluate creditworthiness on the
basis of interviews with the client's family and references, and in many cases, follow
through with visits to reinforce the repayment culture. It can easily cost Rs.500 to
make a micro loan. While that might not seem unreasonable in absolute terms, it
might represent 10% of the value of the loan amount, and force the institution to
charge a “high” rate of interest to cover its cost of loan administration.

The microfinance institution could subsidize the loans to make the credit more
"affordable" to the poor. Many do. However, the institution then depends on
permanent subsidy. Subsidy-dependent programs are always fighting to maintain their
levels of activity against budget cuts, and seldom grow significantly. They simply
aren't sustainable, especially if other microcredit operations have shown that they can
provide credit and grow on the basis of “high” rates of interest—and along the way
serve far greater numbers of clients.

Evidence shows that clients willingly pay the higher interest rates necessary to assure
long term access to credit. They recognize that their alternatives—even higher interest
rates in the informal finance sector (moneylenders, etc.) or simply no access to credit
—are much less attractive for them. Interest rates in the informal sector can be as high
as 5 percent per month among some urban market vendors. Many of the economic
activities in which the poor engage are relatively low return on labor, and access to
liquidity and capital can enable the poor to obtain higher returns, or to take advantage
of economic opportunities. The return received on such investments may well be
many times greater than the interest rate charged.

Aren't the poor too poor to save?

The poor already save in ways that we may not consider as "normal" savings---
investing in assets, for example, that can be easily exchanged to cash in the future
(gold jewelry, domestic animals, building materials, etc.). After all, they face the same
series of sudden demands for cash we all face: illness, school fees, needs to expand
the dwelling, burial, weddings.

These informal ways that people save are not without their problems. It is hard to cut
off one leg of a goat that represents a family's savings mechanism when the sudden
need for a small amount of cash arises. Or, if a poor woman has loaned her "saved"
funds to a family member in order to keep them safe from theft (since the alternative
would be to keep the funds stored under her mattress), these may not be readily
available when the woman needs them. The poor need savings that are both safe and
liquid. They care less about the interest rates that they can earn on the savings, since
they are not used to saving in financial instruments and they place such a high
premium on having savings readily available to meet emergency needs and
accumulate assets.

These savings services must be adapted to meet the poor’s particular demand and
their cash flow cycle. Most often, the poor not only have low income, but also
irregular income flows. Thus, to maximize the savings propensity of the poor,
institutions must provide flexible opportunities--- both in terms of amounts deposited
and the frequency of pay ins and pay outs. This represents an important challenge for
the microfinance industry that has not yet made a concerted attempt to profitably
capture tiny deposits.

The meaning Microfinance Institution (MFI)

Quite simply, a microfinance institution is an organization that offers financial


services to low income populations. Almost all of these offer microcredit and only
take back small amounts of savings from their own borrowers, not from the general
public. Within the microfinance industry, the term microfinance institution has come
to refer to a wide range of organizations dedicated to providing these services: NGOs,
credit unions, cooperatives, private commercial banks and non-bank financial
institutions (some that have transformed from NGOs into regulated institutions) and
parts of state-owned banks, for example.

A great many NGOs that offer microcredit, perhaps even a majority, do many other
non-financial development activities and would bristle at the suggestion that they are
essentially financial institutions. Yet, from an industry perspective, since they are
engaged in supplying financial services to the poor, we call them MFIs. The same sort
of situation exists with a small number of commercial banks that offer microfinance
services. For our purposes, we refer to them as MFIs, even though only a small
portion of their assets may actually be tied up in financial services for the poor. In
both cases, when people in the industry refer to MFIs, they are referring only to that
part of the institution that offers microfinance.

There are other institutions, however, that consider themselves to be in the business of
microfinance and that will certainly play a role in a reshaped and deepened financial
sector. These are community-based financial intermediaries. Some are membership
based such as credit unions and cooperative housing societies. Others are owned and
managed by local entrepreneurs or municipalities. These institutions tend to have a
broader client base than the financial NGOs and already consider them selves to be
part of the formal financial sector. It varies from country to country, but many poor
people do have some access to these types of institutions, although they tend not to
reach down market as far as the financial NGOs.

Microfinance Can be profitable

Data from the MicroBanking Bulletin reports that 63 of the world's top MFIs had an
average rate of return, after adjusting for inflation and after taking out subsidies
programs might have received, of about 2.5% of total assets. This compares favorably
with returns in the commercial banking sector and gives credence to the hope of many
that microfinance can be sufficiently attractive to mainstream into the retail banking
sector. Many feel that once microfinance becomes mainstreamed, massive growth in
the numbers of clients can be achieved. Others worry that an excessive concern about
profit in microfinance will lead MFIs up-market, to serve better off clients who can
absorb larger loan amounts. This is the “crowding out” effect. This may happen; after
all, there are a great number of very poor, poor, and vulnerable non-poor who are not
reached by the banking sector.

It is interesting to note that while the programs that reach out to the poorest clients
perform less well as a group than those who reach out to a somewhat better-off client
segment, their performance is improving rapidly and at the same pace as the programs
serving a broad-based client group did some years ago. More and more MFI managers
have come to understand that sustainability is a precursor to reaching exponentially
greater numbers of clients. Given this, managers of leading MFIs are seeking ways to
dramatically increase operational efficiency. In short, we have every reason to expect
that programs that reach out to the very poorest micro clients can be sustainable once
they have matured, and if they commit to that path. The evidence supports this
position.

Government’s role in supporting microfinance

Governments have a complicated role when it comes to microfinance. Until recently,


governments generally felt that it was their responsibility to generate development
finance', including credit programs for the disadvantaged. Twenty years of insightful
critique of rural credit programs revealed that governments do a very bad job of
lending to the poor. Short term political gain is just too tempting for politically
controlled lending organizations; they disburse too quickly (and thoughtlessly) and
they collect too sporadically (unwillingness to be tough on defaulters). In urban areas,
governments never really got into the act, and subsidized micro enterprise credit is
still relatively rare when compared to its rural counterpart
Now that microfinance has become quite popular, governments are tempted to use
savings banks, development banks, postal savings banks, and agricultural banks to
move microcredit. This is not generally a good idea, unless the government has a clear
acceptance of the need to avoid the pitfalls of the past and a clear means to do so.
Many governments have set up apex facilities that channel funds from multilateral
agencies to MFIs. Apex facilities can be quite complicated and there are few
successful examples in microfinance. Successful apex organizations in microfinance
tend to be built on the backs of successful MFIs, not the other way around. Finally,
governments can also get involved in microfinance by concerning themselves with the
regulatory framework that impinges on the ability of a wide range of financial actors
to offer financial services to the very poor. This topic is treated below.

The financial regulator in supporting the development of microfinance

Many feel that the most important role of a financial regulator in supporting the
development of microfinance is to create an alternative institutional type that allows
sound financial NGOs, credit unions, and other community-based intermediaries to
obtain a license to offer deposit services to the general public and obtain funds
through apex organizations. In a few countries, this may be an appropriate strategy. In
most countries, however, the general level of development of the microfinance
industry does not yet warrant the licensing of a separate class of financial institutions
to serve the poor. And, in most countries, budgetary restrictions faced by bank
regulators make it very unlikely that they will be able to supervise a whole host of
small institutions; these institutions' total assets may make up a tiny percent of the
total financial system, but the cost of adequate supervision could eat up between 25
and 50 % of the total budget of the agency.

Rather, regulators can work with the nascent microfinance industries of most
countries on issues such as modifying usury limits as stated in the commercial code to
allow appropriate levels of interest, generating credit information clearinghouses to
share information on defaulting borrowers to limit their ability to go from one MFI to
another, working with civil authorities to ensure that private loan contracts can be
recognized by courts in those transition economies that lack even basic legislative
infrastructure, and reporting requirements that will prepare MFIs to eventually
become regulated.

Regulators can also examine the laws, executive decrees, and internal regulations that
limit the ability of traditional banking institutions to do microfinance. These
regulations include limits on the percent of a loan portfolio that can be lent on an
unsecured basis, limits on group guarantee mechanisms, reporting requirements,
limits on branch office operations (scheduling and security), and requirements for the
contents of loan files. Not least, banking regulators may need to look at the way in
which they would evaluate micro loan portfolios with in large banks.
MICRO-FINANCE AND POVERTY ALLEVIATION
Most poor people manage to mobilize resources to develop their enterprises and their
dwellings slowly over time. Financial services could enable the poor to leverage their
initiative, accelerating the process of building incomes, assets and economic security.
However, conventional finance institutions seldom lend down-market to serve the
needs of low-income families and women-headed households. They are very often
denied access to credit for any purpose, making the discussion of the level of interest
rate and other terms of finance irrelevant. Therefore the fundamental problem is not
so much of unaffordable terms of loan as the lack of access to credit itself.

The lack of access to credit for the poor is attributable to practical difficulties arising
from the discrepancy between the mode of operation followed by financial institutions
and the economic characteristics and financing needs of low-income households. For
example, commercial lending institutions require that borrowers have a stable source
of income out of which principal and interest can be paid back according to the agreed
terms. However, the income of many self-employed households is not stable,
regardless of its size. A large number of small loans are needed to serve the poor, but
lenders prefer dealing with large loans in small numbers to minimize administration
costs. They also look for collateral with a clear title - which many low-income
households do not have. In addition bankers tend to consider low-income households
a bad risk imposing exceedingly high information monitoring costs on operation.

Over the last ten years, however, successful experiences in providing finance to small
entrepreneur and producers demonstrate that poor people, when given access to
responsive and timely financial services at market rates, repay their loans and use the
proceeds to increase their income and assets. This is not surprising since the only
realistic alternative for them is to borrow from informal market at an interest much
higher than market rates. Community banks, NGOs and grassroot savings and credit
groups around the world have shown that these microenterprise loans can be
profitable for borrowers and for the lenders, making microfinance one of the most
effective poverty reducing strategies.

To the extent that microfinance institutions become financially viable, self-sustaining,


and integral to the communities in which they operate, they have the potential to
attract more resources and expand services to clients. Despite the success of
microfinance institutions, only about 2% of world's roughly 500 million small
entrepreneur is estimated to have access to financial services. Although there is
demand for credit by poor and women at market interest rates, the volume of financial
transaction of microfinance institution must reach a certain level before their financial
operation becomes self-sustaining. In other words, although microfinance offers a
promising institutional structure to provide access to credit to the poor, the scale
problem needs to be resolved so that it can reach the vast majority of potential
customers who demand access to credit at market rates. The question then is how
microenterprise lending geared to providing short term capital to small businesses in
the informal sector can be sustained as an integral part of the financial sector and how
their financial services can be further expanded using the principles, standards and
modalities that have proven to be effective.
To be successful, financial intermediaries that provide services and generate domestic
resources must have the capacity to meet high performance standards. They must
achieve excellent repayments and provide access to clients. And they must build
toward operating and financial self-sufficiency and expanding client reach. In order to
do so, microfinance institutions need to find ways to cut down on their administrative
costs and also to broaden their resource base. Cost reductions can be achieved through
simplified and decentralized loan application, approval and collection processes, for
instance, through group loans which give borrowers responsibilities for much of the
loan application process, allow the loan officers to handle many more clients and
hence reduce costs.

Microfinance institutions can broaden their resource base by mobilizing savings,


accessing capital markets, loan funds and effective institutional development support.
A logical way to tap capital market is securitization through a corporation that
purchases loans made by microenterprise institutions with the funds raised through
the bonds issuance on the capital market. The Foundation for Cooperation and
Development of Paraguay issued bonds to raise capital for microenterprise lending.

Savings facilities make large scale lending operations possible. On the other hand,
studies also show that the poor operating in the informal sector do save, although not
in financial assets, and hence value access to client-friendly savings service at least as
much access to credit. Savings mobilization also makes financial institutions
accountable to local shareholders. Therefore, adequate savings facilities both serve the
demand for financial services by the customers and fulfill an important requirement of
financial sustainability to the lenders. Microfinance institutions can either provide
savings services directly through deposit taking or make arrangements with other
financial institutions to provide savings facilities to tap small savings in a flexible
manner.

Convenience of location, positive real rate of return, liquidity, and security of savings
are essential ingredients of successful savings mobilization.

Once microfinance institutions are engaged in deposit taking in order to mobilize


household savings, they become financial intermediaries. Consequently, prudential
financial regulations become necessary to ensure the solvency and financial
soundness of the institution and to protect the depositors. However, excessive
regulations that do not consider the nature of microfinance institution and their
operation can hamper their viability. In view of small loan size, microfinance
institutions should be subjected to a minimum capital requirement, which is lower
than that applicable to commercial banks. On the other hand, a more stringent capital
adequacy rate (the ratio between capital and risk assets) should be maintained because
microfinance institutions provide uncollateralized loans.

Governments should provide an enabling legal and regulatory framework, which


encourages the development of a range of institutions and allows them to operate as
recognized financial intermediaries subject to simple supervisory and reporting
requirements. Usury laws should be repelled or relaxed and microfinance institutions
should be given freedom of setting interest rates and fees in order to cover operating
and finance costs from interest revenues within a reasonable amount of time.
Government could also facilitate the process of transition to a sustainable level of
operation by providing support to the lending institutions in their early stage of
development through credit enhancement mechanisms or subsidies.

One way of expanding the successful operation of microfinance institutions in the


informal sector is through strengthened linkages with their formal sector counterparts.
A mutually beneficial partnership should be based on comparative strengths of each
sector. Informal sector microfinance institutions have comparative advantage in terms
of small transaction costs achieved through adaptability and flexibility of operations.
They are better equipped to deal with credit assessment of the urban poor and hence
to absorb the transaction costs associated with loan processing. On the other hand,
formal sector institutions have access to broader resource-base and high leverage
through deposit mobilization.

Therefore, formal sector finance institutions could form a joint venture with informal
sector institutions in which the former provide funds in the form of equity and the
later extends savings and loan facilities to the urban poor. Another form of partnership
can involve the formal sector institutions refinancing loans made by the informal
sector lenders. Under these settings, the informal sector institutions are able to tap
additional resources as well as having an incentive to exercise greater financial
discipline in their management.

Microfinance institutions could also serve as intermediaries between borrowers and


the formal financial sector and on-lend funds backed by a public sector guarantee.
Business-like NGOs can offer commercial banks ways of funding microentrepreneurs
at low cost and risk, for example, through leveraged bank-NGO-client credit lines.
Under this arrangement, banks make one bulk loan to NGOs and the NGOs packages
it into large number of small loans at market rates and recover them. There are many
on-going research on this line but context specific research is needed to identify the
most appropriate model. With this in mind we discuss various possible alternatives of
formal-informal sector linkages in India.

In this context, following strategic, institutional and connectivity issues related to


micro-finance arise.

Strategic Issues

• Is there a prevailing paradigm for micro-finance?


• Are there clearly visible pattern across the country?
• Is there a clearly defined foundation building blocks such as organizing
principles, gender preferences and operational imperatives?
• What are methodological issues?

Institutional Issues

• Is there a need for a new institution?


• Should it operate all India or in a state?
• Where should it be located?
• Who can lead an institution of this sort?
• What will its contextual interconnections be?
• Who will be its beneficiaries?
Connectivity Issues

• How should the Corporate Financial Sector be involved?


• What is the role of donor agencies?
• How should communities be involved?
• Are there political issues that should be explicitly considered?
• Are there government policy issues?

The Formal Sector Institutions:

Traditionally, the formal sector Banking Institutions in India have been serving only
the needs of the commercial sector and providing loans for middle and upper income
groups. Similarly, for housing the HFIs have generally not evolved a lending product
to serve the needs of the Very LIG primarily because of the perceived risks of lending
to this sector.

The formal sector financial institutions generally perceive following risks:

• Credit Risk
• High transaction and service cost
• Absence of land tenure for financing housing
• Irregular flow of income due to seasonality
• Lack of tangible proof for assessment of income
• Unacceptable collaterals such as crops, utensils and jewellery

As far as the formal financial institutions are concerned, there are Commercial Banks,
Housing Finance Institutions (HFIs), NABARD, Rural Development Banks (RDBs),
Land Development Banks Land Development Banks and Co-operative Banks (CBs).

As regards the Co-operative Structures, the Urban Co.op Banks (UCB) or Urban
Credit Co.op Societies (UCCS) are the two primary co-operative financial institutions
operating in the urban areas. There are about 1400 UCBs with over 3400 branches in
India having 14 million members.

Few of the UCCS also have external borrowings from the District Central Co.op
Banks (DCCBs) at 18-19%. The loans given by the UCBs or the UCCS are for short
term and unsecured except for few, which are secured by personal guarantees. The
most effective security being the group or the peer pressure.

The Government has taken several initiatives to strengthen the institutional rural
credit system. The rural branch network of commercial banks has been expanded and
certain policy prescriptions imposed in order to ensure greater flow of credit to
agriculture and other preferred sectors. The commercial banks are required to ensure
that 40% of total credit is provided to the priority sectors out of which 18% in the
form of direct finance to agriculture and 25% to priority sector in favor of weaker
sections besides maintaining a credit deposit ratio of 60% in rural and semi-urban
branches. Further the IRDP introduced in 1979 ensures supply of credit and subsidies
to weaker section beneficiaries. Although these measures have helped in widening the
access of rural households to institutional credit, vast majority of the rural poor have
still not been covered. Also, such lending done under the poverty alleviation schemes
suffered high repayment defaults and left little sustainable impact on the economic
condition of the beneficiaries.

The Existing Informal financial sources:

The informal financial sources generally include funds available from family sources
or local moneylenders. The local moneylenders charge exorbitant rates, generally
ranging from 36% to 60% interest due to their monopoly in the absence of any other
source of credit for non-conventional needs. Chit Funds and Bishis are other forms of
credit system operated by groups of people for their mutual benefit, which however
have their own limitations.

Lately, few of the NGOs engaged in activities related to community mobilization for
their socio-economic development have initiated savings and credit programmes for
their target groups. These Community based financial systems (CBFS) can broadly be
categorized into two models: Group Based Financial Intermediary and the NGO
Linked Financial Intermediary.

Most of the NGOs like SHARAN in Delhi, FEDERATION OF THRIFT AND


CREDIT ASSOCIATION (FTCA) in Hyderabad or SPARC in Bombay have adopted
the first model where they initiate the groups and provide the necessary management
support. Others like SEWA in Ahmedabad or BARODA CITIZEN's COUNCIL in
Baroda pertain to the second model.

The experience of these informal intermediaries shows that although the savings of
group members, small in nature do not attract high returns, it is still practiced due to
security reasons and for getting loans at lower rates compared to that available from
money lenders. These are short-term loans meant for crisis, consumption and income
generation needs of the members. The interest rates on such credit are not subsidised
and generally range between 12 to 36%. Most of the loans are unsecured. In few cases
personal or group guarantees or other collaterals like jewellery is offered as security.

While a census of NGOs in micro-finance is yet to be carried out, there are perhaps
250-300 NGOs, each with 50-100 Self Help Groups (SHG). Few of them, not more
than 20-30 NGOs have started forming SHG Federations. There are also agencies,
which provide bulk funds to the system through NGOs. Thus organizations engaged
in microfinance activities in India may be categorized as Wholesalers, NGOs
supporting SHG Federations and NGOs directly retailing credit borrowers or groups
of borrower.

The Wholesalers will include agencies like NABARD, Rashtriya Mahila Kosh-New
Delhi and the Friends of Women's World Banking in Ahmedabad. Few of the NGOs
supporting SHG Federations include MYRADA in Bangalore, SEWA in Ahmedabad,
PRADAN in Tamilnadu and Bihar, ADITHI in Patna, SPARC in Mumbai, ASSEFA in
Madras etc. While few of the NGOs directly retailing credit to Borrowers are SHARE
in Hyderabad, ASA in Trichy, RDO Loyalam Bank in Manipur.

Mechanisms Adopted in Other South Asian Nations In Targeting Programmes


for the Low Income Groups
The Grameen Bank in Bangladesh

The concept is the brainchild of Dr Muhammad Yunus of Chittagong University who


felt concern at the pittance earned by landless women after a long arduous day's work
labouring for other people. He reasoned that if these women could work for
themselves instead of working for others they could retain much of the surplus
generated by their labours, currently enjoyed by others.

Established in 1976, the Grameen Bank (GB) has over 1000 branches (a branch
covers 25-30 villages, around 240 groups and 1200 borrowers) in every province of
Bangladesh, borrowing groups in 28,000 villages, 12 lakh borrowers with over 90%
being women. It has an annual growth rate of 20% in terms of its borrowers. The most
important feature is the recovery rate of loans, which is as high as 98%. A still more
interesting feature is the ingenious manner of advancing credit without any "collateral
security".

The Grameen Bank lending system is simple but effective. To obtain loans, potential
borrowers must form a group of five, gather once a week for loan repayment
meetings, and to start with, learn the bond rules and "16 Decisions" which they chant
at the start of their weekly session. These decisions incorporate a code of conduct that
members are encouraged to follow in their daily life e.g. production of fruits and
vegetables in kitchen gardens, investment for improvement of housing and education
for children, use of latrines and safe drinking water for better health, rejection of
dowry in marriages etc. Physical training and parades are held at weekly meetings for
both men and women and the "16 Decisions" are chanted as slogans. Though
according to the Grameen Bank management, observance of these decisions is not
mandatory, in actual practice it has become a requirement for receiving a loan.

Numbers of groups in the same village are federated into a Centre. The organization
of members in groups and centers serves a number of purposes. It gives individuals a
measure of personal security and confidence to take risks and launch new initiatives.

The formation of the groups - the key unit in the credit programme - is the first
necessary step to receive credit. Loans are initially made to two individuals in the
group, who are then under pressure from the rest of the members to repay in good
time. If the borrowers default, the other members of the group may forfeit their
chance of a loan. The loan repayment is in weekly installments spread over a year and
simple interest of 20% is charged once at the year-end.

The groups perform as an institution to ensure mutual accountability. The individual


borrowing member is kept in line by considerable pressure from other group
members. Credibility of the entire group and future benefits in terms of new loans are
in jeopardy if any one of the group members defaults on repayment.

There have been occasions when the group has decided to fine or expel a member
who has failed to attend weekly meetings or willfully defaulted on repayment of a
loan. The members are free to leave the group before the loan is fully repaid, however,
the responsibility to pay the balance falls on the remaining group members. In the
event of default by the entire group, the responsibility for repayment falls on the
centre.
The Grameen Bank has provided an inbuilt incentive for prompt and timely
repayment by the borrower i.e. gradual increase in the borrowing eligibility of
subsequent loans.

A survey has shown that about 42% of the members had no income earning
occupation (though some may have been unpaid family workers in household
enterprises) at the time of application of the first loan. Thus, the Grameen Bank has
helped to generate new jobs for a large proportion of the members. Only insignificant
portion of the loans (6 per cent) was diverted for consumption and other household
needs.

About 50 per cent of the loans taken by male members were for the purpose of trading
and shop keeping. 75 per cent of loans given to female members were utilized for
livestock, poultry raising, processing and manufacturing activity.

Savings Programme

It is compulsory for every member to save one Taka per week, which is accumulated
in the Group Fund. This account is managed by the group on a consensual basis, thus
providing the members with an essential experience in the collective management of
finances. Amounts collected from fines imposed on members for breach of discipline
is also put into this account. The amount in the Fund is deposited with Grameen Bank
and earns interest. A member can borrow from this fund for consumption, sickness,
social ceremony or even for investment (if allowed by all group members). Terms and
conditions of such loans, which are normally granted interest free, are decided by the
group.

Factors behind success of the Grameen Bank are : participatory process in every
aspect of lending mechanism, peer pressure of group members on each other, lending
for activities which generate regular income, weekly collection of loans in small
amount, intense interaction with borrowers through weekly meetings, strong central
management, dedicated field staff, extensive staff training willingness to innovate,
committed pragmatic leadership and decentralized as well as participatory style of
working.

The Grameen Bank experience indicates the vital importance of credit as an entry
point for upliftment programme for rural poor. If a programme is to have an appeal for
people living in abject poverty, it must offer them clear and immediate prospects for
economic improvement. Thereafter, it is easier to sell other interventions of social
development, however unconventional they may appear, once improvements in
standard of living are demonstrated.

The Grameen Bank clearly shows that lack of collateral security should not stand in
the way of providing credit to the poor. The poor can utilize loans and pay them if
effective procedures for bank transactions with them can be established. In case of the
Grameen Bank, formation of groups with a small group of like-minded rural poor has
worked well, and group solidarity and peer pressure have substituted for collateral
security.

Linking Banks with Self-Help Groups: A Pilot Project from Indonesia


In Indonesia, financial liberalization since 1988, disenchantment with traditional
subsidised credit programs and an openness to innovative approaches led the Central
Bank to support a pilot project in which 13 participating banks, with the assistance of
12 NGOs, have lent to about 420 self-help groups (SHGs) in the first phase, to be
onlent to their members.

Some of the principles underlying the project and the guidelines that were issued to
the implementing groups are listed below:

• The SHGs are to use part of their funds (almost 60%) for lending to
their members and the rest for depositing in a bank to serve as the basis
for refinancing from the bank.
• Savings are to come first: no credit will be granted by the SHG without
savings by the individual members of the SHG. These savings are to
serve as partial collateral for their loans.
• The joint and several liability of the members is to serve as a substitute
for physical collateral for that part of loans to members in excess of
their savings deposits.
• Credit decisions for onlending to members are to be taken by the group
collectively.
• Central Bank refinance is to be at an interest rate equal to the interest
rate at which the savings are mobilized.
• All the intermediaries (the Central Bank, banks, NGOs and SHGs) will
charge an interest margin to cover their costs.
• Interest rates on savings and credit for members are to be market rates
to be determined locally by the participating institutions.
• Instead of penalties for arrears, the banks may impose an extra
incentive charge to be refunded in the case of timely repayments.
• The ratio of credit to savings will be contingent upon the
creditworthiness of the group and the viability of the projects to be
implemented, and is to increase over time with repayment
performance.
• SHGs may levy an extra charge on the interest rate for internal fund
generation (which would be self-imposed forced savings).

Within the first ten months of the implementation period, by March 1990, 7 private
banks and 11 branches of government banks had made 229 group loans to SHGs,
which had retailed them to about 3500 members. Loans totaling about $0.4 million
had been disbursed, on an average of about $2000 per group and $118 per member.
SHG savings deposits with the bank amounted to about $400 per group, giving a
credit to savings ratio of about 5. NGOs have received loans from the banks at 22 to
24 per cent, which is only slightly higher than the refinancing rate of large to small
banks. Rates to end users have been between 30 to 44 per cent after the NGOs and
SHGs have added their margins to cover costs and build funds to cover joint and
several liability. Only one of the participating banks had sought a guarantee under the
scheme from the Central Bank.

Pag IBIG Fund - Philippines


Pag IBIG Fund, is one of the most financially stable Government owned -and-
controlled Corporations in Philippines today. Pag - IBIG, is an acronym for
Pagtulungan sa Kinabukasan (Partnership for the Future), Ikaw (You), Banko (Bank)
Industriya (Industry) Gobyerno (Government). To date, it has a total of 1.2 million
members with a fund base of US $ 800 million. The fund is a provident savings fund
and a housing credit system for the wage earners.

To make the fund a better instrument for the National Shelter Program (NSP) a
Presidential Decree was signed in December 1980 establishing the Home
Development Mutual Fund (HDMF) as a separate entity to administer the provident
fund for housing.

The main objectives of the HDMF are:

• To promote self-reliance and self-determination among workers


through membership in an integrated nationwide savings system
• To invest the provident savings of its members taking into
consideration the profitability and safety of the funds as a means of
providing them provident benefits upon termination of their
membership in the Fund.
• To promote home ownership through the establishment of an
affordable and adequate housing credit system for its members
• To provide small and short loans and other benefits to its members.

For the effective working and success of the Fund it was decided to make membership
to the Fund mandatory and it was also based on the conviction that people deserve
higher incomes and in the process they themselves must be savers and as savers they
themselves be the capital base of the nation. Waivers were granted to employers who
prior to the creation of the Fund already had superior retirement and provident plans
for their employees or employers whose plans are similar to those of the fund or who
are incapable of paying counterpart contribution due to financial losses.

Savings and Housing are closely intertwined and the first step was to take care of the
member’s basic need for housing. The Fund instituted a systematic, regular and easy
savings system and tapped new groups of savers who could not be reached by
commercial banks and became a major source of funds for developing the economy.

Membership to the fund was made voluntary in 1987. A member could withdraw his
accumulated savings upon maturity of his membership after 20 years, permanent
departure from the country, total disability, retirement or separation from service due
to health.

Housing loans were the Fund's greatest attraction, for which reason, a Trust Fund
Agreement with the National Housing Mortgage and Finance Corporation (NHMFC)
was entered into. The agreement allows the Fund to direct its lending through the
NHMFC Secondary Mortgage Market System, where mortgage instruments are traded
by NHMFC. The Fund was guaranteed a fixed return making it possible for the Fund
to lend to its members at 9% p.a. and declare dividends.
The Government also established the Housing and Urban Development Coordinating
Council (HUDCC) as the sole authority and policy making body on housing, to take
charge of identifying and redefining the mandates of housing agencies. The HUDCC
was to act as the lead funding agency and extend funding commitments to financial
institutions who could act as loan originators for the home buyers'.

To meet its major objective of assisting low and middle income families in meeting
their housing requirements through the provision of appropriate and affordable
housing loan packages, the HUDCC offers loan packages with interest rates ranging
from 9% to 16% per annum depending upon the loan amount. Maximum loan amount
per borrower is 46 times his monthly income, consisting of his monthly basic salary
plus cost of living allowance plus the monthly equivalent of the weighted average of
other income during the last three years. Maximum loan repayment period is 25 years
but shall not go beyond the age of 70 for the principal borrower.

There was also an Appliance and Furniture Loan Programme (AFLP) that granted
short term loans . The loan amount was computed based on the length of the
membership and the applicant's salary. The 2-year loan carries an interest of 10.75%
p.a. Later the AFLP was expanded into the Multi Purpose Loan Program (MPL),
which covers various needs: educational, medical & hospitalizations, livelihood,
minor home improvement, purchase of appliances and furniture etc. To qualify for a
Multi Purpose Loan, a member must have made at least 24 monthly contributions,
must be an active Fund member and there must be a commitment from both employer
and employee to continuously remit contributions at least for the term of the loan. The
loan bears an interest of 10.75% p.a., paid in advance for the first year of the loan
period. The second year interest is spread and paid equally over the 24-month term of
the loan. The MPL continues to lend to members on a regular basis, it enables a
member to borrow again after 50% of the outstanding loan has been repaid.

Thus Pag-IBIG helps every Filipino to have his own house by pooling the savings of
its members and channeling them for the long term financing requirement of housing.
Urban Community Development Office of Thailand: The People's Bank

Urban Community Development Office (UCDO) was established in 1992 as a


government sponsored organization with the mandate of enhancing the capacity of
slum dwellers and urban poor, through credit provision process, to generate income
on a stable basis and to obtain adequate housing with secure rights and improved
living environment. UCDO facilitates the formation and strengthening of savings and
credit organizations in urban poor communities through technical assistance and
training on organization and management of the savings groups.

The office provides wholesale loans to these member organizations to on-lend to


individuals to support community development. Therefore, it serves as a bank for
urban poor. To be eligible for UCDO loan, the saving group must have been engaged
in savings activities for at least three months and demonstrate a clear management
structure. Credit is provided as a tool to unleash communities' potential for self
improvement.

The credit from UCDO consists of general purpose revolving loans to meet immediate
household or community needs with a maximum three year, income enhancement
loans for up to five years to support equipment purchase and working capital, and
housing loans of a maximum 15 year maturity to finance group housing projects
including land purchase and non-project housing loans for up to 5 years. As of Mach
1996, $ 17.8 million of credit was disbursed to the benefit of about 3000 families in
62 communities. Housing loans accounted for $12.6 million, followed by income
enhancement loans ($3.8 million) and general-purpose loans ($1.4 million).

All committee members of a community group must sign their names as guarantors
for a loan. In the case of housing projects, land titles or the housing may have to be
put as collateral as well. The lending rate is set based on cost of funds and provision
for bad debts and a markup for community organizations. Current rates are kept below
commercial rates thanks to UCDO's access to low cost funds. The community can
decide upon the loan amount and the repayment period within the prescribed
maximum terms. The community or savings group may repay daily, weekly,
fortnightly or monthly. The method of repayment is flexible and arranged according to
the needs and process decided by the community. The repayment rate stands at 98.7%.

Credit Mechanisms Adopted by HDFC (India) for Funding the Low Income Group
Beneficiaries

HDFC has been making continuous and sustained efforts to reach the lower income
groups of society, especially the economically weaker sections, thus enabling them to
realize their dreams of possessing a house of their own.

HDFCs' response to the need for better housing and living environment for the poor,
both, in the urban and rural sectors materialized in its collaboration with Kreditanstalt
fur Wiederaufbau (KfW), a German Development bank. KfW sanctioned DM 55
million to HDFC for low cost housing projects in India. HDFCs' approach to low-
income lending has been extremely professional and developmental in nature.
Negating the concept of dependence, HDFCs' low cost housing schemes are marked
by the emphasis on people’s participation and usage of self-help approach wherein the
beneficiaries contribute both in terms of cash and labour for construction of their
houses. HDFC also ensures that the newly constructed houses are within the
affordability of the beneficiaries, and thus promotes the usage of innovative low cost
technologies and locally available materials for construction of the houses.

For the purpose of actual implementation of the low cost housing projects, HDFC
collaborates with organizations, both, Governmental and Non-Governmental. Such
organizations act as coordinating agencies for the projects involving a collective of
individuals belonging to the Economically Weaker Sections. The projects could be
either in urban or rural areas.

The security for the loan is generally the mortgage of the property being financed.

The construction work is regularly monitored by the coordinating agencies and


HDFC. The loans from HDFC are disbursed depending upon the stages of
construction. To date, HDFC has experienced 100% recovery for the loans disbursed
to various projects.
THE SYSTEM AND PROCEDURE OF MICROFINANCE
In the development paradigm, micro-finance has evolved as a need-based policy and
programme to cater to the so far neglected target groups (women, poor, rural,
deprived, etc.). Its evolution is based on the concern of all developing countries for
empowerment of the poor and the alleviation of poverty. Development organizations
and policy makers have included access to credit for poor people as a major aspect of
many poverty alleviation programmes.

Microfinance programmes have, in the recent past, become one of the more promising
ways to use scarce development funds to achieve the objectives of poverty alleviation.
Furthermore, certain micro-finance programmes have gained prominence in the
development field and beyond. The basic idea of micro-finance is simple: if poor
people are provided access to financial services, including credit, they may very well
be able to start or expand a micro-enterprise that will allow them to break out of
poverty.

There are many features to this seemingly simple proposition, which are quite
attractive to the potential target group members, government policy makers, and
development practitioners. For the target group members, the most obvious benefit is
that microfinance programmes may actually succeed in enabling them to increase
their income levels. Furthermore, the poor are able to access financial services, which
previously were exclusively available to the upper and middle-income population.
Finally, the access to credit and the opportunity to begin or to expand a micro-
enterprise may be empowering to the poor, especially in comparison to other
development initiatives, which often treat these specific target group members as
recipients.

For development practitioners, the success of microfinance programmes is


encouraging. Too often in the past, costly large-scale development initiatives have
failed to achieve any sustainable benefits, especially after funds have dried up.

Thus, microfinance has became one of the most effective interventions for economic
empowerment of the poor.

Understanding the Development Process through Micro-finance

Microfinance is expected to play a significant role in poverty alleviation and


development. The need, therefore, is to share experiences and materials that will help
not only in understanding successes and failures but also provide knowledge and
guidelines to strengthen and expand microfinance programmes.

In India, a variety of micro-finance schemes exist and various approaches have been
practiced by both GOs and NGOs. In the development sector, credit has been viewed
as one of the missing inputs and therefore, a growing emphasis on re-formulating and
re-strengthening micro credit programmes is observed. There are examples of
spectacular successes and there are also examples of not-so-successful programmes,
which experienced high default rates and were unable to provide financial services in
the long run. Ultimately the aim is to empower the poor and mainstream them into
development. Amongst different approaches of micro-finance schemes, the process
and stages remain more or less the same.

The development process through a typical micro-finance intervention can be


understood with the help of Chart - 2. The ultimate aim is to attain social and
economic empowerment. Successful intervention is therefore, dependent on how each
of these stages have been carefully dealt with and also the capabilities of the
implementing organizations in achieving the final goal, e.g., if credit delivery takes
place without consolidation of SHGs, it may have problems of self-sustainability and
recovery. A number of schemes under banks, central and state governments offer
direct credit to potential individuals without forcing them to join SHGs. Compilation
and classification of the communication materials in the directory is done based on
this development process.
Classifying Micro-Finance Interventions

There are several Micro-Finance implementing organizations, which provide small


loans in India. Some of them have successfully expanded their services to thousands
of borrowers. Given the fact that most of these borrowers would not have had access
to formal financial institutions, that many of the borrowers utilize the loans to enter
and/or expand their informal sector micro enterprises, and that the informal sector
continues to be an important source of livelihood for many poor people, these
microfinance Organizations (MFOs) may very well have had a major impact on
improving the living standards of millions of poor persons as well as on promoting
economic growth. The term MFO has been used for all types of implementing
organizations facilitating savings and credit and financial activities at individual
and/or group level, not going into details of legal and technical aspects of MFOs.

Some of these organizations have evolved from small NGOs to become important
providers of financial services. Realizing the potentially important role that MFOs
play in deepening the benefits of economic growth, it is necessary that providing them
experience-sharing opportunities, materials and training, should strengthen these
MFOs. Furthermore, the relative success of many MFOs soundly refute the claims of
some that "the poor are non-bankable" or that MFOs are a waste of scarce
development funds. In fact, it would be difficult to find another type of developmental
initiative which has been relatively effective on such a large scale in recent years.

In India, there exist a variety of microfinance organizations in government as well as


non-government sectors. Leading national financial institutions like the Small
Industries Development Bank of India (SIDBI), the National Bank for Agriculture and
Rural Development (NABARD) and the Rashtriya Mahila Kosh (RMK) have played
a significant role in making micro credit a real movement. In India, the size and types
of implementing organizations range from very small to moderately big organizations
involved in savings and or credit activities for individuals and groups. These groups
also adopt a variety of approaches. However, most of these organizations tend to
operate within a limited geographical range. There are a few exceptions like
PRADAN, ICECD, MYRADA, SEWA who have been successful in replicating their
experiences in other parts of the country and act as Resource Organizations. Also,
many organizations are involved with SHGs, not only for credit, but for other
purposes like watershed, agriculture, etc.

Micro-finance interventions can be identified based on their span of activity, source of


funds, route through which it reaches the poor or the coverage. However, it seems that
one of the most common practices and approaches prevalent is providing credit
through Self-Help Groups. The approach is to make SHGs the main focal point to
route all credit to members. Almost all national funding organizations (NABARD,
RMK) as well as other Government schemes advocate forming of Self-Help Groups
and thus providing or linking with credit. However, many organizations providing
individual finance directly also exist. It has been explained in Chart - 3.
MICRO FINANCE IN INDIA
Background

The post nationalization period in the banking sector witnessed substantial amount of
resources being earmarked towards meeting the credit needs of the poor. The banking
network underwent an expansion phase without comparables in the world. The branch
expansion1 was synergized with massive manpower recruitment drive for manning
such branches. Credit came to be recognized as a remedy for many of the ills of the
poverty. Credit packages and programmes were designed based on the perceived
needs of the poor. Programmes also underwent qualitative changes based on the
experiences gained. Besides the state governments with large resource allocations
introduced the programmes initiated by the Central Government, a large number of
credit-based programmes.

While the underlying objectives were laudable and substantial progress was achieved,
credit flow to the poor, and especially to poor women, remained low. This led to
initiatives that were institution led, that attempted to converge of the existing
strengths of rural banking infrastructure and leverage this to better serve the unbanked
poor. The pioneering efforts at this were made by National Bank for Agriculture and
Rural Development (NABARD), which was vested with an enviable task of framing
appropriate policy for rural credit, provision of technical assistance backed liquidity
support to banks, supervision of rural credit institutions and other development
initiatives.

NABARD during the early eighties conducted a series of research studies in


association with MYRADA (a leading NGO from South India) and also
independently which showed that despite having a wide network of rural bank
branches that implemented specific poverty alleviation programmes and self-
employment opportunities through bank credit for almost two decades, a very large
number of the poorest of the poor continued to remain outside the fold of the formal
banking system. These studies also showed that the existing banking policies, systems
and procedures, and deposit and loan products were perhaps not well suited to meet
the most immediate needs of the poor. It also appeared that what the poor really
needed was a better access to these services and products, rather than cheap
subsidised credit. Against this background, a need was felt for alternative policies,
systems and procedures, savings and loan products, other complementary services,
and new delivery mechanisms, which would fulfill the requirements of the poorest,
especially of the women members of such households. The emphasis therefore was on
improving the access of the poor to microFinance (mF) rather than just micro-credit.

The launching of its Pilot phase of the SHG (Self Help Group) Bank Linkage
programme in February 1992 could be considered as a landmark development in
banking with the poor. The SHG-informal thrift and credit groups of poor came to be
recognised as bank clients under the Pilot phase.

1
The strategy involved forming small, cohesive and participative groups of the poor,
encouraging them to pool their thrift regularly and using the pooled thrift to make
small interest bearing loans to members, and in the process learning the nuances of
financial discipline. Subsequently, bank credit also becomes available to the Group, to
augment its resources for lending to its members. It needs to be emphasized that
NABARD sees the promotion and bank linking of SHGs not as a credit programme
but as part of an overall arrangement for providing financial services to the poor in a
sustainable manner and also an empowerment process for the members of these
SHGs. NABARD, however, also took a conscious decision to experiment with other
successful strategies such as replicating Grameen, wholesaling funds through NGO-
MFIs.

The NABARD led Pilot Project commenced with the support of the Central Bank of
the country, i.e., Reserve Bank of India, from 1992 onwards aimed at promoting and
financing 500 SHGs across the entire country, the SHG- bank linkage strategy has
come a long way. The strategy includes financing of SHGs promoted by external
facilitators like NGOs, bankers, socially spirited individuals and government
agencies, as also promotion of SHGs by banks themselves and financing SHGs
directly by banks or indirectly where NGOs and similar organizations act as financial
intermediaries as well.

Mainstreaming of SHG Bank linkage programme

The Pilot phase was followed by setting up of a Working Group on NGOs and SHGs
by the Reserve Bank of India in 1994, which came out with wide ranging
recommendations on internalization of the SHG concept as a potential intervention
tool in the area of banking with the poor. The Reserve Bank of India accepted most of
the major recommendations and advised the banks to consider landings to the SHGs
as part of their mainstream rural credit operations. Based on very successful feedback
of the pilot run of the Programme, NABARD in 1998 crystallised its Vision for
providing access to one third of the rural poor through linking of 1million SHGs by
20072. What followed was massive scaling up of the training and capacity building
awareness programmes by NABARD covering a large number of officials and staff of
NGOs, banks, government agencies and rural volunteers in SHG promotion,
nurturing, appraisal and financing

Shift to the New Paradigm

i) The poor

• Perceived thrift as their strength as also as the bonding factor among


themselves
• Realized that timely and adequate credit was preferable and productive than
subsidies and doles.
• They needed hassle-free delivery mechanisms.
ii) NGOs

• Acted as catalysts of change


• Combined social and economic agenda with synergistic effect
2
• Recognized sustainability as the core factor in development.

iii) Banking system

• Accepted SHG-bank linkage as a cost effective means of reaching the poor


• Accepted peer pressure as collateral substitute for excellent recovery of loans

iv) Government

• Formulated supportive policy framework


• Encouraged routing of social programmes through SHGs

v) Reserve Bank of India

• RBI policy pronouncements on microfinance led to increased involvement of


banks.
• Liberalized interest rates and deregulated interest rate structure for micro
credit, leading to flexibility in lending rates.

vi) NABARD

• Provided inputs in capacity building for banks and partner agencies


• Promoted the idea of organizing thrift and credit groups among the NGOs as
an add-on activity and encouraged linking them with banks.
• Provided loanable funds to banks and financial support to eligible MFIs, to
ease the fund flow position to the sector.

A range of institutions in public sector as well as private sector offers the


microfinance services in India. They can be broadly categorized in to two categories
namely, formal institutions and informal institutions. The former category comprises
of Apex Development Financial Institutions, Commercial Banks, Regional Rural
Banks, and Cooperative Banks that provide microfinance services in addition to their
general banking activities and are referred to as microfinance service providers. On
the other hand, the informal institutions that undertake microfinance services as their
main activity are generally referred to as microfinance Institutions (MFIs). While both
private and public ownership are found in the case of formal financial institutions
offering microfinance services, the MFIs are mainly in the private sector.

MICROFINANCE INSTITUTIONS IN INDIA

The micro-finance movement has gained acceptability and momentum in the


developing community largely due to the recognition that the nature of financial
markets in most developing countries creates a credit gaps for the poor. Most formal
financial institutions do not serve the poor because they are perceived as high risk and
high cost involved in small transactions relative to profitability and inability of the
poor to provide the physical collateral required by such institutions.
In India there are broadly three types of Micro-finance organizations

1. Not for profit MFIs

 Societies registered under Societies Registration act 1860


 Public Trusts registered under the Indian Trust Act 1882
 Non-profit companies registered under Section 25 of the Companies Act
1956
 Self Help Groups / Federations

2. Mutual benefit MFIs

 State Credit Co-operatives


 National Credit Co-operatives
 Mutually aided Co-operative Societies (MACS)
 Self Help Groups (SHGs) and Federations

3. For Profit MFIS

 Non-Banking Financial Companies (NBFCs) registered under the Companies


Act 1956.
 Banks which provide MF along with their usual banking service

More than subsidies poor need access to credit. Absence of formal employment make
them non `bankable'. This forces them to borrow from local moneylenders at
exorbitant interest rates. Many innovative institutional mechanisms have been
developed across the world to enhance credit to poor even in the absence of formal
mortgage. This chapter discusses conceptual framework of a microfinance institution
in India.

Microfinance Service Providers

The microfinance service providers include apex institutions like National Bank for
Agriculture and Rural Development (NABARD), Small Industries Development Bank
of India (SIDBI), and, Rashtriya Mahila Kosh (RMK). At the retail level, Commercial
Banks, Regional Rural Banks, and, Cooperative banks provide microfinance services.
Today, there are about 60,000 retail credit outlets of the formal banking sector in the
rural areas comprising 12,000 branches of district level cooperative banks, over
14,000 branches of the Regional Rural Banks (RRBs) and over 30,000 rural and semi-
urban branches of commercial banks besides almost 90,000 cooperatives credit
societies at the village level. On an average, there is at least one retail credit outlet for
about 5,000 rural people. This physical reaching out to the far-flung areas of the
country to provide savings, credit and other banking services to the rural society is an
unparalleled achievement of the Indian banking system. In the this paper an attempt is
made to deal with various aspects relating to emergence of private microfinance
industry in the context of prevailing legal and regulatory environment for private
sector rural and microfinance operators.
The Emergence of Private Microfinance Industry

The microfinance initiative in private sector can be traced to the initiative undertaken
by Ms.Ela Bhat for providing banking services to the poor women employed in the
unorganised sector in Ahmedabad City of Gujarat State. Shri Mahila SEWA (Self
Employed Women’s Association) Sahakari Bank was set up in 1974 by registering it
as a Urban Cooperative Bank. Since then, the bank is providing banking services to
the poor self-employed women working as hawkers, vendors, domestic servant etc. As
on March 2003, the mFI had a membership of 30,000, seventy per cent of whom are
from urban area. The deposit and loan portfolio stood at Rs 623.9 million ($ 13.86
million) and Rs133.6 million ($2.97 million) respectively. Though the mFI is making
profit, yet the SEWA bank model of mFI has not been replicated elsewhere in the
country.

In the midst of the apparent inadequacies of the formal financial system to cater to the
financial needs of the rural poor, NABARD sponsored an action research project in
1987 through an NGO called MYRADA. For this purpose a grant of Rs. 1 million
($22,222) was provided to MYRADA for an R&D programme related to credit
groups. Encouraged by the results of field level experiments in group based approach
for lending to the poor, NABARD launched a Pilot Project in 1991-92 in partnership
with Non-governmental Organizations (NGOs) for promoting and grooming self help
groups (SHGs) of homogeneous members and making savings from existing banks
and within the existing legal framework. Steady progress of the pilot project led to the
mainstreaming of the SHG-Bank Linkage Programme in 1996 as a normal banking
activity of the banks with widespread acceptance. The RBI set the right policy
environment by allowing savings bank accounts of informal groups to be opened by
the formal banking system. Launched at a time when regulated interest rates were in
vogue, the banks were expected to lend to SHGs at the prescribed rates, but the RBI
advised the banks not to interfere with the management of affairs of SHGs,
particularly on the terms and conditions on which the SHGs disbursed loans to their
members.

The uniqueness of the microfinance through SHG is that it is a partnership based


approach and encouraged NGOs to undertake not only social engineering but also
financial intermediation especially in areas where banking network was not
satisfactory. The rapid progress achieved in SHG formation, which has now turned
into an empowerment movement among women across the country, laid the
foundation for emergence of MFIs in India.

MFIs and Legal Forms

With the current phase of expansion of the SHG – Bank linkage programme and other
mF initiatives in the country, the informal microfinance sector in India is now
beginning to evolve. The MFIs in India can be broadly sub-divided into three
categories of organizational forms as given in Table 1. While there is no published
data on private MFIs operating in the country, the number of MFIs is estimated to be
around 800. However, not more than 10 MFIs are reported to have an outreach of
100,000 microfinance clients. An overwhelming majority of MFIs are operating on a
smaller scale with clients ranging between 500 to 1500 per MFI. The geographical
distribution of MFIs is very much lopsided with concentration in the southern India
where the rural branch network of formal banks is excellent. It is estimated that the
share of MFIs in the total micro credit portfolio of formal & informal institutions is
about 8 per cent.

Table 1: Legal Forms of MFIs in India

Types of MFIs Estimated Legal Acts under which Registered


Number*
1. Not for Profit MFIs 400 to 500 Societies Registration Act, 1860 or
similar Provincial Acts
a.) NGO - MFIs Indian Trust Act, 1882
b.) Non-profit Companies 10 Section 25 of the Companies Act, 1956
2. Mutual Benefit MFIs 200 to 250 Mutually Aided Cooperative Societies
a.) Mutually Aided Cooperative Act enacted by State Government
Societies (MACS) and similarly
set up institutions
3. For Profit MFIs 6 Indian Companies Act, 1956

a.) Non-Banking Financial Reserve Bank of India Act, 1934


Companies (NBFCs)
Total 700 - 800

* The estimated number includes only those MFIs, which are actually undertaking
lending activity.

NGO MFIs: There are a large number of NGOs that have undertaken the task of
financial intermediation. Majority of these NGOs are registered as Trust or Society.
Many NGOs have also helped SHGs to organize themselves into federations and these
federations are registered as Trusts or Societies. Many of these federations are
performing non-financial and financial functions like social and capacity building
activities, facilitate training of SHGs, undertake internal audit, promote new groups,
and some of these federations are engaged in financial intermediation. The NGO
MFIs vary significantly in their size, philosophy and approach. Therefore these NGOs
are structurally not the right type of institutions for undertaking financial
intermediation activities, as the byelaws of these institutions are generally restrictive
in allowing any commercial operations. These organizations by their charter are non-
profit organizations and as a result face several problems in borrowing funds from
higher financial institutions. The NGO MFIs, which are large in number, are still
outside the purview of any financial regulation. These are the institutions for which
policy and regulatory framework would need to be established.

Non-Profit Companies as MFIs: Many NGOs felt that combining financial


intermediation with their core competency activity of social intermediation is not the
right path. It was felt that a financial institution including a company set up for this
purpose better does banking function. Further, if MFIs are to demonstrate that
banking with the poor is indeed profitable and sustainable, it has to function as a
distinct institution so that cross subsidization can be avoided. On account of these
factors, NGO MFIs are of late setting up a separate Non-Profit Companies for their
microfinance operations. The MFI is prohibited from paying any dividend to its
members. In terms of Reserve Bank of India’s Notification dated 13 January 2000,
relevant provisions of RBI Act, 1934 as applicable to NBFCs will not apply for
NBFCs (i) licensed under Section 25 of Companies Act, 1956, (ii) providing credit
not exceeding Rs. 50,000 ($1112) for a business enterprise and Rs. 1,25,000 ($2778)
for meeting the cost of a dwelling unit to any poor person, and, (iii) not accepting
public deposits.

Mutual Benefit MFIs: The State Cooperative Acts did not provide for an enabling
framework for emergence of business enterprises owned, managed and controlled by
the members for their own development. Several State Governments therefore enacted
the Mutually Aided Co-operative Societies (MACS) Act for enabling promotion of
self-reliant and vibrant co-operative Societies based on thrift and self-help. MACS
enjoy the advantages of operational freedom and virtually no interference from
government because of the provision in the Act that societies under the Act cannot
accept share capital or loan from the State Government. Many of the SHG
federations, promoted by NGOs and development agencies of the State Government,
have been registered as MACS. Reserve Bank of India, even though they may be
providing financial service to its members, does not regulate MACS.

For Profit MFIs (Non Banking Financial Companies)

Non Banking Financial Companies (NBFC) are companies registered under


Companies Act, 1956 and regulated by Reserve Bank of India. Earlier, NBFCs were
not regulated by RBI but in 1997 it was made obligatory for NBFCs to apply to RBI
for a certificate of registration and for this certificate NBFCs were to have minimum
Net Owned funds of Rs 25 lakhs and this amount has been gradually increased. RBI
introduced a new regulatory framework for those NBFCs who want to accept public
deposits. All the NBFCs accepting public deposits are subjected to capital adequacy
requirements and prudential norms. There are only a few MFIs in the country that are
registered as NBFCs. Many MFIs view NBFCs more preferred legal form and are
aspiring to be NBFCs but they are finding it difficult to meet the requirements
stipulated by RBI. The number of NBFCs having exclusive focus on mF is negligible.

Capital Requirements

NGO-MFIs, non-profit companies MFIs, and mutual benefit MFIs are regulated by
the specific act in which they are registered and not by the Reserve Bank of India.
These are therefore not subjected to minimum capital requirements, prudential norms
etc. NGO MFIs to become NBFCs are required to have a minimum entry capital
requirement of Rs. 20 million ($ 0.5 million). As regards prudential norms, NBFCs
are required to achieve capital adequacy of 12% and to maintain liquid assets of 15%
on public deposits.

Foreign Investment

Foreign investment by way of equity is permitted in NBFC MFIs subject to a


minimum investment of $500,000. In view of the minimum level of investment, only
two NBFCs are reported to have been able to raise the foreign investment. However, a
large number of NGOs in the development - empowerment are receiving foreign fund
by way of grants. At present, over Rs.40, 000 million ($ 889 million) every year flows
into India to NGOs for a whole range of activities including microfinance. In a way,
foreign donors have facilitated the entry of NGOs into microfinance operations
through their grant assistance.

Deposit Mobilization

Not for profit the Reserve Bank of India, from mobilising any type of savings, bars
MFIs. Mutual benefit MFIs can accept savings from their members. Only rated NBFC
MFIs rated by approved credit rating agencies are permitted to accept deposits. The
quantum of deposits that could be raised is linked to their net owned funds.

Borrowings

Initially, bulk of the funds required by MFIs for on lending to their clients were met
by apex institutions like National Bank for Agriculture and Rural Development, Small
Industries Development Bank Of India, and, Rashtiya Mahila Kosh. In order to widen
the range of lending institutions to MFIs, the Reserve Bank of India has roped in
Commercial Banks and Regional Rural Banks to extend credit facilities to MFIs since
February 2000. Both public and private banks in the commercial sector have extended
sizeable loans to MFIs at interest rate ranging from 8 to 11 per cent per annum. Banks
have been given operational freedom to prescribe their own lending norms keeping in
view the ground realities. The intention is to augment flow of micro credit through the
conduit of MFIs. In regard to external commercial borrowings (ECB) by MFIs, not-
for-profit MFIs are not permitted to raise ECB. The current policy effective from 31
January 2004, allows only corporate registered under the Companies Act to access
ECB for permitted end use in order to enable them to become globally competitive
players.

Interest Rates

The interest rates are deregulated not only for private MFIs but also for formal baking
sector. In the context of softening of interest rates in the formal banking sector, the
comparatively higher interest rate (12 to 24 per cent per annum) charged by the MFIs
has become a contentious issue. The high interest rate collected by the MFIs from
their poor clients is perceived as exploitative. It is argued that raising interest rates too
high could undermine the social and economic impact on poor clients. Since most
MFIs have lower business volumes, their transaction costs are far higher than that of
the formal banking channels. The high cost structure of MFIs would affect their
sustainability in the long run.

Collateral requirements

All the legal forms of MFIs have the freedom to waive physical collateral
requirements from their clients. The credit policy guidelines of the RBI allow even the
formal banks not to insist on any type of collateral and margin requirement for loans
upto Rs 50,000 ($1100).
Regulation & Supervision

India has a large number of MFIs varying significantly in size, outreach and credit
delivery methodologies. Presently, there is no regulatory mechanism in place for
MFIs except for those that are registered as NBFCs. As a result, MFIs are not required
to follow standard rule and it has allowed many MFIs to be innovative in its approach
particularly in designing new products and processes. But the flip side is that the
management and governance of MFIs generally remains weak, as there is no
compulsion to adopt widely accepted systems, procedures and standards. Because the
sector is unregulated, not much is known about their internal health. Following
Committees have examined the road map for regulation and supervision of MFIs

o Task Force (appointed by NABARD) Report on Regulatory and


Supervision Framework for MFIs, 1999. (Kindly see publications
Section for a complete report
o Working Group (constituted by Government of India) on Legal &
Regulation of MFIs, 2002
o Informal Groups (appointed by RBI) on Microfinance which studied
issues relating to (i) Structure & Sustainability, ii) Funding (iii)
Regulations and (iv) Capacity Building, 2003
o Advisory Committee (appointed by RBI) on flow of credit to
agriculture and related activities from the Banking System, 2004

To address the issue of need for a differential regulatory framework, the latest
committee sought answers to the following questions and concerns facing private
MFIs in the Country:
(i) Is non-existence of a separate differential regulatory framework a critical
bottleneck hindering the growth of the sector?
(ii) Will MFIs be sustainable in medium term? If so, will they continue to focus on the
poor?
(iii) Is access to public / member deposit the key issue for their sustainability?
(iv) Can MFIs finance loans for income generation at interest rates, which are
sustainable by the rural poor?
(v) Is it possible to evolve commonly agreed standards for MFI sector covering
performance, accounting and governance issues, which can open up possibilities of
self-regulation?
(vi) Has the sector reached a critical mass where regulation becomes important?

The Committee observed that while a few of the MFIs have reached significant scales
of outreach, the MFI sector as a whole is still in evolving phase as is reflected in wide
debates ranging around (i) desirability of NGOs taking up financial intermediation,
(ii) unproven financial and organizational sustainability of the model, (iii) high
transaction costs leading to higher rates of interest being charged to the poor clients,
(iv) absence of commonly agreed performance, accounting and governance standards,
(v) heavy expectations of low cost funds, including equity and the start up costs, etc.

The current debate on development of a regulatory system for the MFIs focuses on
three stages. Stage one - to make the MFIs appreciate the need for certain common
performance standards, stage two - making it mandatory for the MFIs to get registered
with identified or designated institutions and stage three - to encourage development
of network of MFIs which could function as quasi Self-Regulatory Organizations
(SROs) at a later date or identifying a suitable organization to handle the regulatory
arrangements. The Committee recommended that while the MFIs may continue to
work as wholesalers of microCredit by entering into tie-ups with banks and apex
development institutions, more experimentation have to be done to satisfy about the
sustainability of the MFI model. Such experimentation needs to be encouraged in
areas where banks are still not meeting adequate credit demand of the rural poor.

In regard to offering thrift products, the Committee felt that, while the NGO-MFIs can
continue to extend micro credit services to their clients, they could play an important
role in facilitating access of their clients to savings services from the regulated banks.
As regards allowing NGO-MFIs to access deposits from public / clients, the
Committee considers that in view of the need to protect the interests of depositors,
they may not be permitted to accept public deposits unless they comply with the
extant regulatory framework of the Reserve Bank of India. As no depositors' interest
is involved where they do not accept public deposits, the Reserve Bank of India need
not regulate MFIs.

As regards the high interest rates being charged by the MFIs, the Committee felt that
the lenders to MFIs may ensure that these institutions adopt a ‘cost-plus- reasonable-
margin’ approach in determining the rates of interest on loans to clients.

Conclusions

Private MFIs in India, barring a few exceptions, are still fledgling efforts and are
therefore unregulated. Their outreach is uneven in terms of geographical spread. They
serve microfinance clients with varying quality and using different operating models.
Regulatory framework should be considered only after the sustainability of MFI
model as a banking enterprise for the poor is clearly established. Experimentation of
MFI model needs to be encouraged especially in areas where formal banks are still
not meeting adequate credit demand of the rural poor.
MICROFINANCE IN GUJARAT

Gujarat State Profile

Gujarat ranks amongst the top states in terms of fresh investments attracted. Over 8.5
per cent of the total fresh investments are directed towards
Gujarat. Most of the investment in the state is by private sector.

Location

Gujarat is the seventh largest state of the country having a


geographical area of 1,96,024 Sq.Kms. The state is boundaries
on northwest by Pakistan, on north by Rajasthan, on west by
MP, on south and southeast by Maharastra. The plains of
Gujarat are watered by big rivers like Sabarmati, Mahi, Narmada, and Tapi and by
smaller rivers like Banas, saraswati and Damanganga.

Gujarat has 25 revenue districts by 2001. The number of Class I (cities with
population more than 1 lakh) are 26 and Class II (median town with population
50,001 to 1 lakh) and 132 Class III and Class IV towns with population less than
50,000.According to Gujarat Nagar Palika Act, 1963, at present there are seven
municipal corporations and 142 municipalities.

As the 13th agro climatic zone, the state ha 6% of the geographic area where as 4.93%
of the population of the country with 25 districts as administrative units. Out of 5.07
crore population of the state, 21.7% is agriculture work force and 13.2% of rural
population is below poverty line. There are wide variations in the rainfall varying
2642mm in Dangs to 283 mm in Kutch. The 50.15% of geographic area is net sown
area (NAS) with 111.27% cropping intensity with assured irrigation facilities from all
sources. There are 182 regulated markets and cold storage/cold chain capacity around
2.59 crore metric tones. However, the share of agriculture in state GDP is only 18.9%.
There are 2.93 lakh registered SSI units and 47.95% of population is depended on
Non-Farm Sector activities. In past state has been severely affected by natural and
man made calamities, Viz 2001 earthquake, 2002 drought, 2003 floods.

The State, which enjoys a 1,600 kms long coastline, has been witnessing substantial
activities in the development of ports. Kandla port, one of the major ports of the
country, is located in the Kachchh district in the north of Gujarat. Around 67 per cent
of the total foodgrain port traffic of the country passes through the Kandla port. The
State also has 18 minor ports. Mundra port, the first privately developed port in the
country is located in the State.

Districts of Gujarat State.


Districts
01. AHMEDABAD 14. MAHESANA
02. AMRELI 15. NARMADA
03. ANAND 16.NAVSARI
04. BANASKANTHA 17. PANCHMAHALS
05. BHARUCH 18. PATAN
06. BHAVNAGAR 19. PORBANDAR
07. DAHOD 20. RAJKOT
08. DANGS 21. SABARKANTHA
09. GANDHINAGAR 22. SURAT
10. JAMNAGAR 23. SURENDRANAGAR
11. JUNAGADH 24. VADODARA
12. KACHCHH 25. VALSAD
13. KHEDA

Demographic profile

Particulars Unit State


Administrative units
No. of Districts Nos. 25
No. of Taluka/Blocks etc. Nos. 222
No. of Villages Nos. 18539
Population(Provisional)
Total Million 50.7
Rural Million 31.8
Urban Million 18.9
Male Million 26.3
Female Million 24.4
Density of population Million 258 per sq. KM
Decadal Growth of Population % of pa 22.66
Literacy Total
Total % 69.14
Male % 79.66
Female % 57.80
Workforce engage in Agriculture % of total 52.05
Population below poverty line Lakh 71.36
Rural poor % 13.17
Urban poor % 15.59

Banking Profile

The state has 53 commercial Banks (26 privet banks), 9 RRBs (Region Rural bank),
18 DCCBs (district central co-operative banks) and 1 State Co-operative Bank,
1Gujarat State Co-operative Agriculture & Rural Development Bank. The total
branches of all banks in the state were 5124 at the end of March 2005. The population
per bank was 9945. The deposit with schedule commercial bank was Rs.82083 crores
and advances was Rs. 35418 crores constituting credit deposit ratio of 43.15 as at end
of March 2005.

As on 31 March 2005, the number of rural and semi urban branches of CBs were
3153, that of DCCBs 1145 branches, RRBs 408 branches and GDCARDB 181
branches. The statistic highlights relating to the banking profiles are given in last of
the report.

Apart from these, urban cooperative banks also play a supplementary role in
cooperative credit structure. As on 31.3.2005 there were 351 urban cooperative banks
in Gujarat having 779 branches.

Key Economic Indicators

Gross State Domestic Product (GSDP) at factor cost at constant (1993-94) prices in
2003-04 has been estimated at Rs.103951 crore as against 90068 crore in 2003-04
The Microfinance channel in Gujarat

However we have seen earlier there are so many micro financial institutes in Gujarat.
These organizations are classified in the following categories to indicate the
functional aspects covered by them within the microfinance framework. The aim,
however, is not to "typecast" an organization, as these have many other activities
within their scope:

1. Organizations implementing micro-finance activities

2. Resource organizations or support agencies

3. Formal financial institutions - Banks and development organizations, like


NABARD, SIDBI, Association of MFOs etc.

1. Organizations Implementing Microfinance Activities

Organizations implementing micro-finance activities can be categorized into three


basic groups.

I) Organizations which directly lend to specific target groups and are carrying out all
related activities like recovery, monitoring, follow-up etc. Some of these organizations
are graduating to become exclusive MFOs, but such cases are few.

II) Organizations who only promote and provide linkages to SHGs and are not
directly involved in micro lending operations.

III) Organizations which are dealing with SHGs and plan to start micro-finance
related activities.

2. Resource Organizations or Support Agencies

These are the organizations that provide support to implementing organizations. The
support may be in terms of resources or training for capacity building, counseling,
networking, etc. They operate at state/regional or national level. They may or may not
be directly involved in micro-finance activities.

A few associations to bring such MFOs on one platform have also been initiated in
India. Experiences sharing through newsletters and/or meetings/ seminars/training are
the methods adopted by the associations/collectives to support implementing
organizations.

3. Formal Financial Institutions - Banks

Commercial Banks, Grameen Banks and Rural Banks provide funds to SHGs and also
operate their accounts. Funding agencies and development institutions chanelise credit
through these FIs. Building gender sensitivity and developmental dimensions amongst
these agencies is a major need. Banks prefer to route credit through SHGs, though
they directly lend to individuals also.
Development Agencies/Nodal Agencies in India, development agencies like
NABARD, SIDBI and RMK provide funds for credit. They support MFOs and have
separate allocations for SHGs and micro-credit. These organizations have developed
guidelines and training materials to help MFOs implement micro-credit activities
covered under their preview.
MICROFINANCE THROUGH SHG

Introduction

In most developing countries, the policies concerning rural credit were, by and large,
based on certain assumptions, some of which were: commercial banks were reluctant
to provide for the credit needs of the rural poor for reasons that were neither
commercial nor economic; the rural poor did not have any capacity to save; they
needed credit on concessionary rates of interest and relaxed terms for taking up
income generating activities, more so for development works on their farms; the rural
people needed external assistance for organizing themselves into groups and later
close watch and regulatory measures to ensure that they work together; many of the
target group borrowers would graduate after some doses of concessional credit and
would start taking credit on normal terms and that informal finance did a positive
developmental role and it was an evil that should be eliminated. Based on these
assumptions, the policy framework which developed included setting up of credit
oriented development banks and special credit programmes; generous credit guarantee
schemes to induce banks to enlarge their lending operations; fixation of sectoral
targets for credit dispensation; loans to rural borrowers on subsidised interest rates,
easy loan terms including very low or nil down payment, long loan maturities and
long grace periods, relegation of savings as a source of funds and reliance of the rural
credit system on concessionary refinance from financial institutions and international
donors.

Resulting consequences of the policy framework did not contribute to self-sustained


growth of the rural credit system and it also did not adequately serve the rural poor. It
is well known that people who were not poor captured a part of the subsidies and
concessions involved in rural credit and substantial number of very poor could not be
reached under this dispensation. Further, the rural credit delivery system in most of
the developing countries was weakened by poor credit discipline among the
borrowers resulting in low recovery of dues. High operating (intermediation) costs,
burden of subsidised interest rates, non-viability of operations and heavy dependence
on concessionary outside funding or refinance support were some of the other
constraints in the development of self-sustaining systems. Many credit programmes
started with support from the State or a donor agency operated as per their dictates
and were abandoned due to poor results.

The erosion in credit discipline has been a fall out of the system of 'targeted credit'
where loans were often made in a rush, carried a certain political aura, the lending
institutions were identified by borrowers with the Government, and relationships
between the lender and borrower rarely developed. In such systems, prospective
borrowers were often identified by extension workers who assisted in sanction of
grants (where applicable) from the state and generally escorted them to the bank who
sanctioned the loan. While the involvement of the extension agents upto this stage
was visible and common, their involvement in the recovery of loans so granted was
most uncommon.

The Core Issue


The core problem of rural finance is high transaction costs to the banks in financing a
large number of small borrowers who require credit frequently and in small quantities.
The same holds true of costs involved in providing saving facilities to small, scattered
savers in rural areas. The rural savers and borrowers also face high transaction costs
while dealing with banks due to distances, small value of financial transactions etc. In
a recent study [unpublished] in India, the transaction cost to a small rural borrower
raising a loan from a commercial bank under a poverty alleviation programme was
placed at 24.6 %. Further, the transaction costs of operating a saving account with a
bank was placed as high as 10% of the saving, on the assumption of only one
transaction per month.

Besides the high transaction costs, the perception of risks in financing small
borrowers who are unable to offer physical collateral, articulate their case or submit
proper loan proposals, the urban orientation and the lack of flexibility in their
operations are the other constraints which restrict the out reach of the formal banking
system for the poor. The poor also often perceive banks as alien institutions, which
exist to serve the needs of "others". The physical and social distance [in stratified
societies] constrain their approaches to bank branches which, for them, do not appear
to be functioning with their needs in mind. Credit needs of the poor are determined in
a complex socio-economic milieu where the dividing line between credit for
'consumption' and 'productive' purposes is rather blurred making it difficult to adopt
the traditional banking approach to lending. The result is that financial services of the
formal banking system have remained unaccessible to majority of the poorer sections
of the rural population in most developing countries and their reliance for credit is
mainly on the informal credit channels. Informal channels include moneylenders who
operate outside the legal and policy framework of banks, market vendors,
shopkeepers and others including friends and relatives. Credit in the informal system
is usually available immediately, when and where required and often without
collateral and lengthy documentation formalities, since the lender usually relies on
personal knowledge of borrowers and their circumstances. However, interest rates are
not only extremely high, but sanctions often include conditions, verbal or written,
which are heavily loaded in favour of the lender and are sometimes carefully guised
and are detrimental to the interests of borrowers. Often credit is associated with other
transactions, for example, the purchase of raw material from a supplier, with deferred
payment or pre-harvest sale of a crop with immediate payment.

Availability of alternative financial services could do much to improve the welfare of


rural poor and their families. In most developing countries, attempts have been made
to develop cooperatives by bringing together people of small means for fostering thrift
and mutual help for their economic betterment. However, cooperatives have achieved
only a limited success in selected pockets. On account of their large size, and the
heterogeneous economic status of their members, the decision-making gets invariably
delegated to a small number of usually well-off and influential members. Such
influential members are often also able to corner benefits at the cost of those who are
poor and do not command ownerships of productive assets or influence. Besides,
since their resource base is often weak, the cooperative by and large depend on
resources handed down vertically from higher financing agencies. With dependence
for financial assistance and the role which most governments play in their
development, growth and monitoring, cooperatives are sometimes seen by people as a
"government agency" and not as their own institution.
Against this background, evolving mechanisms for meeting the economic aspirations
and credit needs of the rural poor in the form of self-help groups (SHGs) seem
another possibility.

The SHG Concept

Self-Help Groups (SHGs) or Thrift and Credit Groups are mostly informal groups
whose members pool savings and relend within the group on rotational or needs basis.
These groups have a common perception of need and impulse towards collective
action. Many of these groups got formed around specific production activity,
promoted savings among members and uses the pooled resources to meet emergent
needs of members, including consumption needs. Sometimes the internal savings
generated were supplemented by external resources loaned/donated by the Voluntary
Agency, which promoted the SHGs. Since SHGs were able to mobilize savings from
the poor who were not expected to have any savings and could also recycle effectively
the pooled savings among members, they succeeded in performing/providing banking
services to their members, may be ina primitive way, but in a manner which was cost
effective, simple, flexible at the door step of the members and above all without any
defaults in repayment by borrowers

Involvement of SHGs with banks could help in overcoming the problem of high
transaction costs in providing credit to the poor, by passing on some banking
responsibilities regarding loan appraisal, follow-up and recovery etc. to the poor
themselves. In addition, the character of SHGs and their relations with members
offered ways of overcoming the problem of collateral, excessive documentation and
physical access, which reduced the capacity of formal institutions to serve the poor.

Based on local conditions and requirements, the SHGs have evolved their own
methods of working. Some of the common characteristics of functioning of these
groups are indicated below:

• The groups usually create a common fund by contributing their small savings
on a regular basis.
• Most of the groups themselves, or with help of NGOs, evolve flexible systems
of working and managing their pooled resources in a democratic way, with
participation of every member in decision-making.
• Request for loans are considered by the group in their periodic meetings and
competing claims on limited resources are settled by consensus.
• Loaning is done mainly on trust with a bare minimum documentation and
without any security.
• The amounts loaned are small, frequent and for short duration.
• The loans cover a variety of purposes, some of which are non-traditional and
rather un-conventional.
• Rate of interest differs from group to group and even with purpose. Interest
charged is generally higher than that charged by banks and lower than that
charged by moneylenders.
• Periodic meetings of members also serve as a forum for collecting dues from
members.
• Defaults are rare mainly due to group pressure and intimate knowledge of end
use of credit.
SHGs are ‘small economical homogenous affinity groups of rural poor,
voluntarily formed to save and mutually contribute a common fund to be lent to
its members as per group decision’ [NABARD, 1997].

Singh and Jain [1995] have defined SHGs as ‘voluntary association of people
formed to attain goals both social and economical’. Local saving groups and
SHGs have as many names as languages. They are called Rotating Savings and
Credit Associations [ROSAs], Revolving Funds, Chit Funds and even Merry Go
Rounds. [Malcolm Harper, 1998].

Self Help groups find their financial resources inadequate due to their lower saving
capacities while on the other hand; profitable investments are limited by social
restrictions and lack of marketable skills amongst group members. In order to help
groups to grow in terms of volume and socio-economic development external help
becomes necessary.

A formal recognition and aid to these groups however came only in 1990s, when SHG
bank linage program was introduced by NABARD. NABARD had outlined specific
requirements amongst SHGs for becoming eligible for bank credit under SHG - Bank
Linkage program.

The requirements were:

 SHGs with not more than 20 members.


 Registration of SHGs according to the by laws formed by the group
members.
 Member’s monthly savings were to be used for loaning. The repayment
schedule and the loan installments were to be fixed after mutual agreement
amongst members.
 SHGs were required to adopt a democratic way of functioning with each
member having the freedom to express her/his views on functioning of SHGs.
 SHGs had to maintain regular books of accounts, including members, saving
and loan register and meeting register.
 SHGs were also required to open a saving bank account in the nearby Bank
branch.
 Further, SHGs could be established by any organization in village, taluka and
city with the initiative of bank officials or NGO workers.

Linkage programm

BANKS, NGOs AND SHGs: A CONCEPTUAL FRAMEWORK(The Approach)

The present chapter provides a conceptual framework of Banks, NGOs and SHGs and
studies their role in the SHG-Bank-Linkage program. The new micro credit approach
involves the participation of Banks, NGOs and SHGs. In India, the SHG-Bank-
Linkage-Program was first implemented by NABARD though branches of
Commercial, Co-operatives and Regional Rural banks in 16 states. The pilot project
showed encouraging results in terms of increasing accessibility, recoveries, reducing
costs and benefiting SHG members. It also gave banks some experience in working
with NGOs/SHGs. RBI encouraged by this experience recommended, adoption of the
SHG Bank Linkage Program at the national level and asked all the banks to make it a
part of their corporate strategy.

Linkage with The Non Governmental Organizations


[NGOs]/Voluntary Organizations [VOs]

The NGOs/VOs have been the pioneer innovators of the ‘new microfinance
approach’. NGOs terminology itself is not yet well established since NGOs typology
is unmodified. They operate under different ideology and nomenclature. NGOs are
defined by only what they are, which suggest that they can be whatever they need to
be for a particular purpose, has attributed three major functions to NGOs: Provisoners
of services and assistance; creation of self-help capabilities; advocacy / education. As
a developmental organization it mobilizes, utilizes and monitors economic and non-
economic inputs, development culture by making necessary changes in values,
attributes institutions of society.

NGOs encompass a wide spectrum of organizations with different ideologies,


activities and typologies. VOs are a part of a more comprehensive NGO network.
Lord Beveridge defined VOs as, “ an organization initiated and governed by its own
members without external control.” Shivraman Committee in 1978 had suggested
presence of objective conditions for VOs. Viz duly registered, statutory managing
committee, competent staff, proper accounting and monitoring and a master plan for
work. At present, we have VOs varying widely in size, functions, methodology and
motivation.

The process of voluntarism and emergence of NGOs in India, composites of seven


stages this is indicated by a study on NGOs and sustainable development conducted
by the Center of America in 1993. The roots of voluntarism are traced to the
functioning of social institutions in the ancient and the medieval period [1800-1850].
Reform movements during the time let to the recognition of evils of caste, sex and
social status. In the second phase [19th century] after the World War I, a political
awakening was witnessed amongst the intelligent. Consciousness and self-help
emerged as a primary focus of socio –political movement. This voluntary movement
acquired force in the struggle of independence in the third phase.

In the next phase, twenty years were spent in consolidating the nation. Voluntary
action joined together in government responsibilities of education, health care, socio
economic welfare etc. Government program failures in mid-sixties and seventies
were manifested in the ‘trickle down’ approach of overall development. Severe
income disparities between rich and poor led to emergence of the alternative rural
development models.
The real fallout of voluntarism came with the national emergency, J.P. Movement
and the heavy politics. This left many looking for constructive alternatives to canalize
their energies and concerns for more human and just societies. This fall out also led
to an increased voluntary movements both in quantity and quality. It was the period
when ideas of concretization and peoples participation began to emerge. More
focused work with target groups, landless laborers, tribal, small farmers, women,
SC/ST etc., became a base for NGOs/VOs programs.

The seventh phase in the eighties was the reorganization and the visibility of NGOs
work. NGOs in different parts of India were rooted in a specific socio political context
and were inspired by the emergence and continuity of social change and political
movements. Another stream of NGOs established by business industrial houses in
India and religious institutions also surfaced. Since then, NGOs/VOs have grown and
evolved in different forms.

Korten[1992], has classified NGOs into three categories people’s organizations,


public service contractors and NGOs. While John Clark [1991], has identified six
types of NGOs viz: relief and welfare agencies, technical innovation organizations to
pioneer improved methods of progress, public service contractors to implement part
of government programs, popular development agencies concentrating on self help
and grass root level democracy along with education. World Bank on the other hand
has tried to codify the typology of NGOs as philanthropic and self help organizations
are classified into: welfare NGOs, Development NGOs, Donor NGOs and Local
NGOs. Amongst the NGOs in India majority are individual development enterprises,
trusts, co-operatives, voluntary organizations and mahila samagams.

NGOs were not only classified on the basis of typology but were distinguished by size
too. In the Indian context, small organizations are pre dominant. They work in a few
villages within a block of a district or a few slums in one part of the city. There are
small medium sized, third big and large sized organizations too. Medium sized NGOs
cover a block and work with a staff of 2-10 members and project grants unto 1 lakh.
Third big and large sized organizations are relatively larger and work with 25-50 and
even 100 member’s staff.
NGOs have been working in partnerships with donors and government for some time
now. These partnerships have different facets of linkages. NGOs and government
organizations have worked in friendly co existence with freedom and little or no
interference and maximum support from the government. NGOs work for behavioral
and attitudinal change amongst people to support implementation of government
programmers of health, education, technology development and women’s programs.
NGOs also sometimes act as partners in implementation of government programs.

Partnerships however, between banks and NGOs are still at a premature. It all began
when NABARD motivated by experiences of other countries and India, decided to
adopt the SHG approach of lending though NGOs. In order to avail financial
assistance, NGOs had to fulfill certain criteria’s like good track record of consistent
work, maintenance and audition of the books of accounts for at least three years,
capability of handling weak and poor and saving groups with a saving bank account in
banks.

The Banks
Banks have been major purveyors of microfinance in rural areas. “Institutional Fit” is
extremely important for the successful implementation of any program. The ideal
institutions to deliver financial services to smaller users is one which initiates,
develops the activity and carries it on for as long as it is needed. In India, institutions
like commercial banks, RRBs, Co-operatives viz. CCBs. PACS, PLDBs and SLDBs,
have deployed rural credit.

The linkages of SHGs with banks aims at using the intermediation of SHGs between
banks and the rural poor for cutting down the transaction costs for both banks and
their rural clients. The objective of the linkage programme could be:

a. to evolve supplementary credit strategies for meeting the credit needs of the poor
by combining the flexibility, sensitivity and responsiveness of the informal credit
system with the strength of technical and administrative capabilities and financial
resources of the formal financial institutions.

b. to build mutual trust and confidence between bankers and the rural poor.

c. to encourage banking activity, both on the thrift and credit sides, in a segment of the
population that formal financial institutions usually find difficult to reach.

There could be different models of the linkage between SHG and banks:

MODEL 1: The simplest and most direct is a model in which the banks deal directly
with the individual SHGs, providing financial assistance for on-lending to the
individual members.

MODEL 2: Another model, a slight variant of the first, is where the bank gives direct
assistance to the SHG and the SHG promoting institution (SHGI), usually an NGO,
provides training and guidance to the SHG and generally keeps a watch to ensure its
satisfactory functioning.

MODEL 3: The third model places the NGO or SHGI as a financial intermediary
between the bank and a number of SHGs. The linkage between the bank and the
SHGs in this case is indirect. The NGO accepts contractural responsibility for
repayment to the bank.

MODEL 4: The fourth model envisages bank loans directly to individual members of
SHGs upon recommendations of the SHG and NGO. In this case, the NGO assists the
bank in monitoring, supervising and recovery of loans.

It is possible that the linkage may follow an evolutionary process and move from
model three to model two and to model one and finally to model four where
individuals get direct access to the bank. However, the adoption or acceptance of a
particular model would depend on the perception of the bank and the strength of the
SHGs and the NGO. Where the banker is able to have a first hand information on the
working of a SHG which is functioning satisfactorily and has rotated its pooled
resources two/three times, he may well start with model two or even model one.
However, a more conservative banker may like to start with modeling three and
relying on the NGO or SHGI.

The Financial Scheme

The financial scheme under the Linkage Programme could be based on the following
broad principles:

• Savings first, no credit without saving.


• Saving as partial collateral
• Bank loans to the group, for onlending to members
• Credit decisions for onlending to members by the group
• Interest rates and other terms and conditions for loans to
members to be decided by the group
• Joint liability as a substitute for physical collateral
• Ratio between savings and credit contingent upon credit
worthiness of the group; increasing with good repayment
record.

Commercial banks have the necessary outlets, security, equipment, hierarchy of


administrative systems, record keeping, and efficient staff to manage savings and
lending operations.

The co-operatives operate through PACs and SLDBs at ground level, they lend largely
for farm activities in small amounts. PACs lend essentially for crop loans while
undertaking non-crop loan lending on marginal scale. PLDBs/SLDBs are essentially
term lending institutions, which lend for purposes including: minor irrigation, land
development, plantation, horticulture, fisheries, farm mechanization etc. Co-operative
sector financing is in small amounts with exception of financing non-farming
activities. The co-operatives have had a longer experience in delivering microfinance,
but lack resources and dynamism and are subject to frequent interventions from
government functionaries.

Public sector and co-operative banks in India, till liberalization worked with severe
constraints in terms regulations and government interventions. Till date, government
partnerships and priority sector impositions had hampered the banks profitability
levels. The programs of rural development too have had limited success in terms of
achieving income, employment and social benefits to the poor. The SHG approach of
lending was introduced to banks as a new microfinance approach with innovativeness
and flexibility. The SHG approach has been initiated against the backdrop of certain
benefits to the banks. It is anticipated to decrease the banker’s burden of
scruitinization of application, loan disbursals, monitoring and recovery of loan
accounts. Decrease in individual loan procedures is anticipated to reduce the cost to
the banks, increase profits and small savings in rural areas. It is envisaged that this
approach shall bring proximity and affinity between bankers and rural people.

For implementation of SHG’s approach the formal RFIs viz. commercial banks, co-
operatives and RRBs have been asked to deploy credit through SHGs. No specific
targets have been set at, NABARD hopes to cover 50000 SHG linkages with banks by
2000. Banks through circulars have been asking their training centers to cover SHG
bank linkage program as a part of their officers and staff training programs.

In order to enable banks to report their SHG lending without difficulty on account of
divergent purposes in ‘ground level disbursements from SHGs to members’, an
additional component under priority sector lending target has been incorporated.
Banks now report their lending to SHGs or NGOs under a new segment viz., advances
to SHGs irrespective of purposed for which members have been disbursed loans.

The scope for lending to SHGs would depend upon the extent of poverty, presence,
availability, support from NGOs and the need and desire amongst poor to form
groups. Bank branches have been allowed to fix their own programs under the
service area approach. In order to help bank branches get catalytic services of NGOs
the lead bank would indicate the names of NGOs block wise. Service area branch
managers would have a continuous dialogue for effecting linkages with SHGs and
NGOs/VOs. In case an NGO feels comfortable with working with another branch
outside its service area it would be allowed to operate with another bank branch.

The lending to SHG would be included in the LBR system and reviewed at State
Level Bankers Committee [SLBC] level. Banks have been prescribed to use a simple
documentation procedure for lending to SHGs.

The Linkage

The self-help group, bank linkage program has two ways of linkages:

 Directly by identifying or forming SHGs


 Indirectly financing SHGs through NGOs/VOs

In case of direct credit deployment, loans of the group had to be in proportion with the
savings, this ratio was to be increased to 1:2 to 1:4 in a phased manner. Accumulated
savings of SHGs for at least six months were strongly emphasized by banks. The RBI
has also made it imperative for SHGs to deposit their savings in a saving bank
account with the bank branches. The rate of interest was fixed at 12 percent for
lending to SHGs. Repayment installment was to be decided with mutual consultation
of SHG members.

The Linkage Project in India

Despite the vast expansion of the formal credit system in India, the dependence of the
rural poor on moneylenders continues especially for meeting emergent credit
requirements. Such dependence is more pronounced in resource poor areas and in the
case of marginal farmers, landless labourers, petty traders and artisans belonging to
the socially and economically backward classes and the tribal population. With a view
to developing a supplementary credit delivery mechanism to reach the poor in a cost
effective and sustainable manner, the National Bank for Agriculture and Rural
Development (NABARD) introduced a pilot project for linking 500 SHGs with banks
in 1992 after thorough discussion with the Reserve Bank of India (the central banking
authority for India), commercial banks and NGOs.

The operational guidelines from NABARD were deliberately kept flexible to enable
the participating banks and field level bankers to innovate and contribute to building
and strengthening the project concept. Stating the advantages of linkages to the bank,
the guidelines observed:

"A recognition by the formal credit structure of self-management capabilities


of the poor through SHGs and a link up between the two is expected to result
in specific advantages to both systems. Under the linkage project, the main
advantage to banks would be externalization of a part of the work items of the
credit cycle - assessment of credit needs, appraisal, disbursal, supervision and
repayment, reduction in the formal paperwork involved and a consequent
reduction in transaction costs. Improvement in recoveries and also in the
margins would lead to a wider coverage of the target group. A larger
mobilization of small savings would be equally advantageous. For the groups,
advantages lie in the access to a larger quantum of resources as compared to
their corpus generated through thrift, access to better technology and skill
upgradation through different schemes of banking sector and a general
improvement in the nature and scale of operations that would accelerate
economic development"

Besides providing policy input, coordination and 100% refinance facility at 6.5%
interest p.a. to the banks, NABARD has been organizing exposure and dialogue
programmes in the linkage project for banks and NGO officials. These exposure
programmes, which invariably include field visits, have helped in disseminating the
concept and convincing bank officials to participate in the project. So far, 17 such
programmes, covering around 350 officials have been organized in collaboration with
NGOs and reputed bankers training institutes like the College of Agricultural Banking
(CAB) and the National Institute of Banking Management (NIBM).

In order to assess the results of the linkage project, quick studies were taken up by
NABARD in three states viz. Karnataka, Andhra Pradesh and Tamil Nadu and certain
trends in the implementation of this innovative concept have emerged. They are:

a. Larger participation in the project is of women savings and


credit management groups, particularly in resource poor
regions.
b. Membership of SHGs has come mostly from the poorest
sections of the society.
c. Demand for credit is frequent and for small amounts, at
unpredictable times and sometimes not necessariy for purchase
of income generating assets.
d. Even the very poor are able to save and their savings increased
with addition to their incomes.
Further, some good features have come to light such as shift in credit from
consumption purposes to acquisition of income generating assests, use of credit for
non-traditional economic activities, increase in income levels of group members,
development of thrift and self-help among members, reduction in transaction cost for
both banks and SHG members and an almost 100% recovery of loans.

Transaction Costs

The high transaction cost for rural credit is a core problem and viability of the system
is critically affected by it. NABARD has recently conducted a study to quantify the
effect of intermediation by NGOs/SHGs on transaction cost. The initial findings are:

a. The intermediation of SHG led to reduction in time spent by


bank staff on identification of borrowers, documentation,
follow-up and recoveries. This resulted in 40% reduction in
transaction cost which could increase further with increase in
loan sizes.
b. The intermediation also significantly reduced transaction costs
for the borrower due to elimination of cumbersome
documentation procedure and time spent and cost incured on
repeated visits to banks etc. The reduction was place at 85%.
SHG BANK LINKAGE PROGRAMME
Status as on 31 March 2005
Cumulative as
Sl.No. Particulars on 31 March
2005

1 No.of SHGs linked 1,618,476


2 % of women groups 90
3 No.of participating banks : 560
i. Commercial Banks 48
ii. Regional Rural Banks 196
iii.Co-operative Banks 316
4 Bank Branches participating 35,294
5 No. of States/UTs 31
6 No. of districts covered 563
7 No.of Partners 3024
8 Bank Loan (Rs in billion ) 68.98
9 NABARD refinance (Rs. in billion) 30.92
10 No.of poor households assisted (in million) 24.25
11 Average Loan/SHG Rs. 42,620
12 Average Loan/Family Rs. 3,044
13 Model Wise Linkage ( Cumulative) (%)
i. SHGs formed and financed by Banks 21
ii. SHGs formed by other agencies but
directly financed by banks 72
iii. SHGs financed by banks using financial
intermediaries 7
MICROFINANCE IN GUJARAT THROUGH SHG

Gujarat experienced mild economic growth of 2.2 percent in 2001. The overall
performance of the economy has been hurt by the impact of an earthquake in 2001,
social unrest, droughts, increasing energy prices, depreciation of the rupee, and the
general global economic slowdown. GDP per capita in Gujarat is $409, which has
remained virtually unchanged over the last few years in real terms. Inflation is 3.8
percent (as of 2001), up from 3.4 percent in 2000. For Ahmedabad proper, the
inflation rate was 3.9 percent, slightly higher than the 2001 national average.

With a population approaching six million, Ahmedabad is the sixth-largest city in


India, and has experienced fast-paced growth during the last few decades, with its
population increasing by about 22 percent between 1991 and 2001. Ahmedabad’s
economy has suffered from earthquakes, social unrest, and droughts, and as a result its
poverty rate is above the national average. Residents there earn an average of $409
annually, and 34 percent of the population—as compared with just 21 percent for
India as a whole—lives below the poverty line. Given the rapid population growth, a
stagnant economy, and the paucity of housing and basic services, the city has
experienced the swift development of new slums, in which about two-fifths of the
population now lives.

The demand for shelter financing from slum dwellers is outstripping the supply of
loans. Though they are numerous and varied finance programs in Gujarat have not
had a major impact on low-income employed in the informal sector. Most banks do
offer housing loans, but most do not offer it to the informally employed poor, even
though the government requires that 10 percent of all lending go toward the “weaker
sections” of the economy (i.e., the poor). Loans for this group can still be tens of
thousands of dollars, with loan terms approaching 20 years—not the sort of loans that
are likely to be the most effective in improving the living conditions of the area’s
poor. As a result, the economically active poor who work in the informal sector
remain underserved, having to rely on savings and informal moneylenders for
financing.

The state of Gujarat, which has a population of about 5 crore has 33 lakh population
belonging to BPL category. Despite natural and man-made calamities faced by the
state during the last 3 years, it has a vast potential for innovation projects and
programmes, thanks to its hyperactive and highly enterprising population. The state of
govt. is also committed to gearing up the SHG movement under SGSY and other
schemes. The state also implementing swa-shakti project of govt. of India with
assistance from IFAD and world bank in 8 district and about 2000 SHGs have been
covered through the programme.

As far as SHGs formed under NABARD’s SHG-Bank linkage programme is


concerned, the the number stood at 16563 as at the end of march 2002, of which the
number of SHGs creadit linked with Banks stood at 9496 involving Bank loan and
NABARD refinancing of Rs.8.49 Crore and 7.55 Crore respectively. The district
covered is 24, out of 25 and the partnership position is about 35 bank and 80 NGO
partners. The region wise distribution is that the nourth gujrat leading with 4022
SHGs and south Gujarat and saurashtra region creadit liking 3290 SHGs & 836
SHGs respectively. Two RRBs (viz. panchmahal – vadodara gramin bank & surat
Bharuch gramin Bank ), 2 DCCBs snd 5 VVV clubs are acting as selp help promoting
institutions (SHPs).

In our research we have visited some of the Co-operative banks, commercial banks,
NGOs, and SHGs and collected data. On the basis of that we have studied some of the
characteristic of the SHGs client, the fluctuations in the number of SHG district wise
and the relation between geographical area and number of SHGs.the major findig are
as under:-

Characteristic of the SHGs client

SHG’s clientele are poor, most of are self-employed women who mainly work in the
informal sector. A recent study conducted by AIMS on working class women in
Ahmedabad identified the following characteristics of SHGs clients:

Income: SHGs clients are very poor, with 87 percent of the women sampled living on
less than 100 per day. The average annual income was Rs. 42,557.

Employment: Virtually all clients work in the informal sector as micro-entrepreneurs,


dependent sub-contractors, or casual laborers, in that order. (See Table A)

TABLE A

SHGs Clients by Employment (sample average)


Micro entrepreneurs 41%
Dependent Sub-Contractors 36%
Casual Laborers 22%
Salaried Jobs 1%
Debt: Like most women in Gujarat, SHG clients maintain high levels of debt—
roughly 27 percent of household income. The study found that borrowers use SHG to
increase their outstanding debt, rather than to pay off loans from other sources.

Savings: While total savings is quite small among poor households, SHG clients have
two to three times as much savings as non-clients and hold most of these funds in
SHG. Chen and Snodgrass has said “No one in the sample seems to have much to do
with banks other than SHG, either as a source of credit or as a savings vehicle.”

Vulnerability: SHG clients as well as most of the working poor are susceptible to a
variety of financial shocks that interrupt normal income flows or necessitate
extraordinary expenditures. A 2000 study of IDBI about SHG found that 71 percent of
woman questioned experienced at least one significant financial shock over a two-
year period. Their main physical asset is their house, which often also serves as their
place of business.

Table 1

Grand total
No. Of SHGs Formed Total since April-99 63033
During the current year 2005-06 upto 4569
the February
No. of SHGs Passed Grade-I Total since 4-99 SHGs-I 18506
During the current year 2005-06 upto 3637
the February
No. of SHGs Passed Grade-II Total since 4-99 5531
During the current year 2005-06 upto 1568
the February
No. of SHGs Taken up Total Since 4-99. 3680
Economic Activities During the current year 2005-06 upto 1122
the February
No. of Women SHGs Formed Total since 4-99 26046
During the current year 2005-06 upto 1372
the February
No. of Women SHGs Taken up Economic Activities up to Feb.- 2006 2445
Table 2

No. of Members of SHGs assisted for No. of Individual Swarozgaris assisted for
Economic Activities Economic Activities
Disable Tota
Total SC ST Women SC ST Women Disabled
d l
2295
5665 941 2120 3109 101 1 3711 6230 6587 431

Table3

No. of Members of SHGs Trained No. Of Individual swarozgaris trained


Total SC ST Women Disabled Total SC ST Women Disabled

10169 1571 2844 5289 56 3778 559 1938 2034 100

(Source: - Gujarat Rural Development Department, Gandhinagar)

Impact of the SHG Bank Linkage Programme

Given these quantitative achievements, what has been the impact of the programme.

The main findings are that:

i. Microfinance has reduced the incidence of poverty through increase in income,


enabled the poor to build assets and thereby reduce their vulnerability.

ii. It has enabled households that have access to it to spend more on education than
non client households. Families participating in the programme have reported better
school attendance and lower drop out rates.

iii. It has empowered women by enhancing their contribution to household income,


increasing the value of their assets and generally by giving them better control over
decisions that affect their lives.

iv. In certain areas it has reduced child mortality, improved maternal health and the
ability of the poor to combat disease through better nutrition, housing and health –
especially among women and children.

v. It has contributed to a reduced dependency on informal moneylenders and other


non institutional sources.

vi. It has facilitated significant research into the provision of financial services for the
poor and helped in building “capacity” at the SHG level.

vii. Finally it has offered space for different stakeholders to innovate, learn and
replicate. As a result, some NGOs have added micro-insurance products to their
portfolios, a couple of federations have experimented with undertaking livelihood
activities and grain banks have been successfully built into the SHG model in the
eastern region. SHGs in some areas have employed local accountants for keeping
their books; and IT applications are now being explored by almost all for better MIS,
accounting and internal controls.

Highlights of Findings
I. SHG per se

1. NGO took 6 months to one year for forming the groups. The
process of evolution of SHG was found to be voluntary.
2. Source of funds to SHG was initially savings and NGO's
contribution. Bank credit came later.
3. Activities financed by the SHGs were need based and the SHGs
were flexible in their approach.
4. The groups adopted flexible approach in charging interest on
loans ranging from 18% to 36%, but the interest was lower that
the rate charged by moneylenders.
5. Shorter repayment periods were fixed and the repayments were
made from all available resources i.e. by also including other
income besides income from activity financed through the SHG
loan. The members were therefore able to take more than one
loan in a year. The general opinion was that long periods of
loan with grace years and infrequent loan installments lead to
overdue as in the case of formal credit delivery system.
6. Conducting regular weekly meetings was one of the hallmarks
of functioning of the groups.
7. Pattern of savings differs from one group to another mainly on
the basis of income generating activities of the members.
8. Flexibility in norms for lending with least importance for
documentation was found in all the groups. While some groups
charge penal interest for delayed payment of principal, some
others waive the same.
9. The groups which kept longer repayment period and high
flexibility in the amount of installment to be repaid show a little
higher percentage of overdues than the groups which keep
more regulated and shorter loan period.
10. Only one loan is generally allowed to a member at a time.
However, in case of emergency, second loan is also considered
if the group agrees for such assistance.
11. Group activities by the SHGs are encouraged b the VA through
its 'Seed Money Assistance' programme.

II. SOCIO-ECONOMIC BENEFITS

1. Income per member had registered a significant increase during


the period of last three years of group formation.
2. Group formation helped the members in attending individual
and common problems more effectively.
3. Some SHGs have started creating common assets owned by all
members. These common assets also provide additional income
to the group.
4. Role of NGO/VA is important for group formation, sustenance
of SHG, fund support, training and advice. The VA had also
helped in providing necessary linkage for economic activities.
5. Some of the members of Women SHG availed of IRDP,
Sericulture loans etc. and were confident of increasing their
activities through bank credit. The groups act as facilitators in
recovering the dues of the members and remit to the banks.
6. Most of the purposes financed by the groups were for
unconventional activities not covered by traditional banking.
7. The new groups show greater awareness of the need to graduate
out of the present level and look for new opportunities through
bank assistance.
8. There was a definate shift in the loan pattern of the members
from non-income generating activities to income generating
activities. 70% of loan availed was for productive purposes,
while only 30% of the loans were for non-income generating
activities.

III. BANK LINKAGE

1. All the SHGs were having savings account with the banks since
inception.
2. After obtaining the loan application, group resolution,
sponsorship letter from the VA and membership list,
commercial banks sanctioned loans at branch level whereas
branches of RRBs forwarded the proposals to their head offices
for sanction.
3. The SHGs were regularly making monthly repayments, and
recovery for banks under SHG lending was to the extent of
98%.
4. The bankers were concerned about sustainability of the groups
in the long run. They were also concerned about the groups
functioning in the event of withdrawal of the NGO.
5. Some branch managers have expressed that groups with
members having defaulters to the banking system should not be
financed.
6. The cost of lending through SHGs on a rough basis showed a
decline of 38% in transaction cost compared to normal lending.
7. Recovery of loans by banks is excellent without any default.
Other loans issued to the members are also repaid without any
delay. Only 4% of the loans was found to be overdue at the
groups level.

IV. ROLE OF VA
1. NGO has been playing a pivotal role in ensuring proper
training, coordination to the groups and putting them on a
scientific approach.
2. VA plans to withdraw from the existing group by creating an
apex body in each of the areas it is operating. This 'Apex body'
was expected to provide umbrella support the SHGs in future.

V. OPERATIONS

1. Before sanction of loans to the VA for on-lending to groups,


bank branch managers had visited the groups and participated
in meetings to satisfy themselves about the functioning of the
group.
2. Satisfied by the excellent recovery under the programme, the
banks have shown interest in extending loans through the VA.
3. Bankers felt that direct lending to groups can be done once the
groups attain maturity.
4. The VA provided training in maintenance of books of accounts
at SHGs level either at its training centre or through the village
animator.

VI. GROUP RESPONSIBILITY

1. The VA had pledged the savings of all the members of the SHG
as collateral for the loans availed even though at the SHG level
only some of the members were financed. This has been done
with the concent of all members to ensure buildup of groups’
pressure. This feature can be emulated by other SHGs.
2. The members have been regular in repayment of loan
installments without any default.
3. Income from other sources such as farm labour was utilized for
repayment of installment during the period where there was no
income from existing milch animals bought through credit from
SHG.

VII. LENDING OF OWN FUNDS

1. The SHGs maintained small amounts as 'emergency funds' to


meet consumption requirement of the members.

VIII. IMPACT OF CREDIT AND ASSET CREATION

1. The weavers expressed that their earnings owning to increased


production consequent to availability of loan for purchase of
raw materials and other input.
2. Most of the SHGs were reported to have undertaken group
activities such as plantation, running of Balwadis (kindergarten
schools) and other community development work with
financial assistance aquired from the VA. However, no bank
finance was involved in undertaking these activities.
ROLE OF NABARD IN MICROFINANCE

History of NABARD

National Bank for Agriculture and Rural Development Act, the Indian Parliament
passed 1981 and NABARD was established on 12 July 1982 with an initial capital of
Rs. 100 crore. The capital is enhanced to Rs.2000 crore subscribed by Govt. of India
and Reserve Bank of India.

NABARD is an apex institution, accredited with all matters concerning policy,


planning and operations in the field of credit for agriculture and other economic
activities in rural areas in India.

NABARD is established as a development Bank, in terms of the Preamble of the


Act, "for providing and regulating Credit and other facilities for the promotion
and development of agriculture, small scale industries, cottage and village
industries, handicrafts and other rural crafts and other allied economic activities
in rural areas with a view to promoting integrated rural development and
securing prosperity of rural areas and for matters connected therewith or
incidental thereto."

NABARD took over the functions of the erstwhile Agricultural Credit Department
(ACD) and Rural Planning and Credit Cell (RPCC) of RBI and Agricultural
Refinance and Development Corporation (ARDC). Its subscribed and paid-up Capital
was Rs.100 crore which was enhanced to Rs. 500 crore, contributed by the
Government Of India (GOI) and RBI in equal proportions. Currently it is Rs. 2000
crore, contibuted by GoI (Rs.550 crore) and RBI (Rs.1450 crore).

NABARD: (i) serves as an apex financing agency for the institutions providing
investment and production credit for promoting the various developmental activities
in rural areas; (ii) takes measures towards institution building for improving
absorptive capacity of the credit delivery system, including monitoring, formulation
of rehabilitation schemes, restructuring of credit institutions, training of personnel,
etc. ; (iii) co-ordinates the rural financing activities of all institutions engaged in
developmental work at the field level and maintains liaison with Government of India,
State Governments, Reserve Bank of India (RBI) and other national level institutions
concerned with policy formulation; and (iv) undertakes monitoring and evaluation of
projects refinanced by it.

NABARD’s refinance is available to State Co-operative Agriculture and Rural


Development Banks (SCARDBs), State Co-operative Banks (SCBs), Regional Rural
Banks (RRBs), Commercial Banks (CBs) and other financial institutions approved by
RBI. While the ultimate beneficiaries of investment credit can be individuals,
partnership concerns, companies, State-owned corporations or co-operative societies,
production credit is generally given to individuals.

NABARD operates throughout the country through its 28 Regional Offices and one
Sub-office, located in the capitals of all the states/union territories.It has 336 District
Offices across the country, one Sub-office at Port Blair and one special Cell at
Srinagar. It also has 6 training establishments.

Vision

To facilitate sustained access to financial services for the unreached poor in rural
areas through various microfinance innovations in a cost effective and sustainable
manner.

Mission Accomplished

Provision of financial access to 16.7 million poor families through formation and
credit linkage of 1,079,091 self help groups as on 31 March 2004.

Mission-Ahead

Formation and credit linkage of 585,000 new self-help groups by the year 2007 with
60% of them coming from 13 priority underdeveloped states of the country. Facilitate
mature SHGs to graduate from microfinance for consumption or production credit to
microenterprise.

MICROFINANCE- NABARD'S STRATEGY

Overall Strategy

• Forming and nurturing small, homogeneous and participatory self-help groups


(SHGs) of the poor has today emerged as a potent tool for human
development. This process enables the poor, especially the women from the
poor households, to collectively identify and analyse the problems they face in
the perspective of their social and economic environment. It helps them to
pool their meagre resources, human and financial, and prioritise their use for
solving their own problems.
• The emphasis on regular thrift collection and its use to solve immediate
problems of consumption and production not only helps to meet their most
urgent needs, but also trains them to handle larger financial resources more
skillfully, prudently and with a more lasting impact.
• Encourage SHGs to become a forum for many social sector interventions.

SHG-Bank Linkage Programme

• Facilitating SHGs to access credit from formal banking channels. SHG-Bank


Linkage Programme has proved to be the major supplementary credit delivery
system with wide acceptance by banks, NGOs and various government
departments.
Region-specific Initiatives

• NABARD has intensified its efforts for roping in new partners for promotion
and linkage of groups in regions where the growth of groups has not been
commensurate with potential.
• Priority has been assigned to awareness- building and for identification of
NGOs and other partners in 13 priority states, which account for 70% of rural
poor in the country.

Capacity Building Initiatives

• NABARD has supports/ sponsors capacity building programmes for various


partners in the field of microfinance to sensitize and equip them with concept
& nuances of SHG bank linkage programme. Upto the end of March 2004
about 687,000 persons have been trained by us through our regional offices,
training establishments, resource NGOs and partner agencies.
• NABARD provides training inputs on SHG financing to training
establishments of participating banks, to help them to internalize the training
requirements at their level.
• NABARD gives technical support to banks to evolve suitable intermediate
structures like Farmers' Clubs (Vikas Volunteer Vahini Programme of the
National Bank) to increase the outreach of their branches in promotion and
linking SHGs
• NABARD supports and helps banking institutions (especially RRBs &
cooperative banks) to take on the role of Self Help Promoting Institutions
(SHPIs )

Support to Governments

• Necessary assistance is provided to the governments by NABARD for


dovetailing mF practices with the poverty alleviation programmes
• NABARD also encourages the association of Panchayati Raj Institutions
( PRIs ) in adopting group processes for maximization of empowerment.
• NABARD , in association with Lal Bahadur Shastry National Academy of
Administration, Mussoorie conducts tailor made exposure programme on self
help group and microFinance for senior and middle level officers of Indian
Administrative Services (IAS) who are posted as district collectors/ Chief
Executive Offices of local administrative set ups (Zilla Parishad)

Support to NGO Partners

• Several steps have been taken by NABARD for capacity building of NGOs
which partner in promotion and nurturing of SHGs. The emphasis is on
involving a large number of NGOs. Special focus is on those NGOs
participating in watershed development, health, literacy and women
development, to encourage them to take up promotion, nurturing and linkage
of SHGs as an 'add-on' activity.
• NABARD has a scheme of part-financing the cost of promotion of groups by
NGOs.
• NABARD has developed specialized programmes for use by CEOs of NGOs
for appropriately envisioning this as an add-on concept. Separate programmes
have also been designed for NGO field staff to appreciate the nuances of SHG
functioning.

Alternate microfinance practices

• The NGOs and other local bodies at village, block and district levels in the
North Eastern States are encouraged to take up alternative micro-credit
delivery mechanisms through direct funding.
• Formation and operation of SHG Federations is supported and encouraged by
NABARD. Similarly, networking of NGOs is also encouraged.

Coordinating microfinance Efforts in India

NABARD coordinates the microfinance activities in India at international/


national/state/district levels. These include organizing international/national
Workshops, Seminars, etc for experience sharing, Organizing National and State
level Meets of Bankers and NGOs etc.

Dissemination of best practices in SHG / microFinance.

Monitoring and Review

Block/district/state level review meetings are organised and/or organised by


NABARD. The relative documentation and database is also carried out by NABARD.
In addition, periodical Monitoring studies are conducted through NABARD/Bank
Officers. Internal Impact Studies and are conducted by NABARD periodically.

Future Agenda for NABARD

1. Presently, there are about 3 lakh credit-linked SHGs that are at least three
years old and could be considered for promotion of micro enterprises. The
number of such mature groups would increase by about 2 lakh SHGs every
year. The target audience, therefore, is huge.
2. There is no 'blue print' in the country for promotion of micro enterprises as the
experience of most of the organizations working in this sector is limited and
still at 'Pilot Stage'.
3. As promotion of micro enterprises is a complex task and involves various
types of interventions, it would be appropriate if NABARD can start off a few
'Pilot' projects with to view to help come out with a 'blueprint' for up scaling.
Since the road map is not clear, the pilot would also provide the flexibility of
changing the approach while learning from the field experience. The strategy
proposed is as under:

a. We could identify 5-6 districts in the country from different


regions for promotion of micro enterprises. The districts
identified would be those, which have a large number of mature
SHGs.
b. Microenterprise promotion is to be taken up only with mature
groups. For the identification of right type of groups, a suitable
mechanism will have to be devised for its use in the identified
districts.
c. Market surveys can be carried out in the identified districts, if
necessary with the help of outside consultants for resource
mapping and identifying the right type of micro enterprises
suiting to these districts.
d. Organizations can be identified in the districts that would be
facilitating the identified groups for promotion of micro
enterprises. NGO sector would be best suited for this task.
However any other suitable agency in the Govt./ quasi Govt.
sector may also be involved if available and found suitable.
e. Capacity building of selected NGOs/ agency SHPIs would be
necessary as many of them though good in promotion of SHGs
may have to build up their own capacity in skill development of
microEnterprises. An organization having expertise or willing
to develop the same in promotion of micro enterprises will be
identified, in each district, and act ultimately as nodal Micro
Enterprise Promotion Agency (MEPA).
f. The role of identified NGO/ MEPA would be:

Identification of mature groups for promotion of microenterprise.

i. Building profiles of identified groups


ii. Identifying groups/members who would like to work with the
on-going enterprises.
iii. Identifying groups/members who would like to set up new
enterprises.
iv. Assessing nature of facilitation required at group level
v. Assessing training needs of group members
vi. Hand holding /escort services required by the group members
vii. Net working with various institutions for provision of
identified facilities including trainings and backward &
forward linkages.
viii. The NGO/ MEPA should aim at empowering the group
members to manage their affair on their own after a reasonable
period of time for ultimate sustainability. In other words, a
withdrawal strategy by NGO/ MEPA should work
simultaneously with implementation of the project.

NABARD could assume the over-all responsibility for implementing the programme
in identified districts.
PROBLEMS IN MICROFINANCING

These are the reasons about why SHGs, NGOs and Banks are sometime not
interested in microfinance.

The SHGs and their members

If a marketing-oriented business is confronted with poor sales, it should look first at


its customers, not to blame them but to find out if there is any way in which the
product or its marketing are failing to satisfy their needs. The long history of
subsidised schemes has, paradoxically, weakened the marketing skills of financial
institutions. If a product is heavily subsidised it is natural, albeit erroneous, to assume
that its beneficiaries will want it. The problem is perceived as one of ensuring that
only those who deserve' it get it, not to market it.

There are in fact a number of reasons why many SHGs do not come forward as
banking customers.

The SHG members have bad experiences of earlier schemes, which promised all
manner of benefits, but which ended in disappointment; they do not wish to waste
their time again.

The SHGs may not know that banks are willing to take their savings, and to lend them
money; the banks have not marketed the new product successfully to them.

The SHG members may resent or be frightened of the intimidating or arrogant


behavior of bankers or even the appearance of their offices. They feel that such places
are not for them.

The SHGs may have sufficient uses for their own savings, and the rate of capital
growth, because of the high interest rates they charge themselves, may build the fund
at a rate which is commensurate with the growth in their investment opportunities;
they do not need the banks.

The NGOs

The NGOs also have their own agenda, and there are good reasons why many of them
too are unwilling to provide the escorting and linking service which is necessary in
most cases.

The NGO staff, like the SHG members, may be disillusioned with schemes, and most
bankers still call SHG linkage a scheme'.

NGOs are under pressure to become self-sustaining. They may prefer to become
financial institutions themselves, rather than to develop customers for the banks.
Many NGOs are welfare oriented. They do not want to become involved in banking
transactions, even as facilitators, but prefer to remain in their traditional fields of
health, education and community development.

The Banks

This are the reasons that banks are not interested in microfinance:

 Lack of knowledge and skills


 Organizational factors
 Negative attitudes
 Doubts to the profitability of the product
 External factors such as government policies

These are the solutions:

 Lack of Knowledge and Skills.

It is dangerously easy to exaggerate what can be achieved by training, but


deficiencies such as the following are susceptible to well designed and well
delivered classroom training, particularly if on-the-job training and effective
communication support it.

In spite of the extensive programme of training and exposure which has been
undertaken by NABARD through a range of institutions for some eight years,
there are still many bankers who are unaware of the existence of the SHG
market, or who believe it to be another scheme, rather than a market
opportunity.

Even those bankers who are aware of the SHG market perceive it to be an
exclusively rural phenomenon; they do not realise the potential in the fast
growing urban areas.

It is possible to assess a SHG just like any other prospective borrower, but it
requires different techniques, closer to those needed for inter-bank business,
although on a much smaller scale.

SHG members and their elected officers are usually women. More than half of
all women in India are illiterate, and a far higher proportion of poorer women
cannot read and write. It is possible to communicate effectively with
illiterates, but it requires different skills.

SHGs, and their members, may have no accounts, or if they do have some
written records they are likely to be very different from what is expected of a
traditional banking customer. Bankers can learn how to deal with such clients,
but it needs training.

 Organization Factors
Banks are usually large and necessarily bureaucratic organizations, with their
own culture and methods of operation. The public sector banks in India have
only survived many decades of political interference and mandated loss-
making activities by building strong walls around themselves. They are thus
even more resistant to change than most large organizations. Present
conditions, however, are conducive to change, and a number of financial and
other institutions are undertaking ambitious programmes of institutional
development which are designed to remedy problems such as those listed
below:

Staffs are punished for mistakes, but are not rewarded for innovation.

Even the most routine decisions are not delegated to branch level, or within
branches. The long hierarchy of decision-making prevents the branches from
offering the kind of service that SHGs need.

Banks, unlike the providers of almost every other product or service, from
toothpaste to insurance or scooters to air travel, do not recognize their need for
marketing intermediaries or middlemen/women, which is what SHGs are.

Banks and bankers are perceived by themselves and by their customers as


operating from fixed premises at fixed hours, which are often inconvenient for
SHGs.

 Attitudes

It is harder and slower to change personal attitudes than to acquire skills, or


even to re-engineer an organization. Such attitudes are even more difficult to
change when they are unarticulated and strongly rooted in cultural tradition.
Nevertheless, a combination of persuasive leadership and role models, realistic
exposure, and the possibility of attractive reward or the threat of
unemployment can change even deeply seated attitudes such as the following:

Bankers have been conditioned to believe that poorer people are weaker
sections', for whom any form of banking service must necessarily be
subsidised, and is only undertaken as an act of charity or because government
regulations require it. They are not seen as potentially profitable customers.

The history of government sponsored and often politicized co-operatives not


unreasonably leads bankers to believe that group activities are necessarily
doomed to fail.

Bankers, if they are aware at all of NGOs, see them as radical activists or
admirable social service organizations, but not as potential business partners.

Bankers are generally drawn from the educated middle class, and are socially,
economically and physically distant' from poorer people.
Bankers are predominantly male, and SHG members are mainly women.
Women are not perceived by men as capable of making business decisions,
still less of managing a micro-bank' such as an SHG.

The banks have been repeatedly battered by a succession of ill-conceived and


unprofitable schemes'; many not unreasonably regard SHG linkage and micro-
finance as more of the same.

 Profitability

There are some quite justified business reasons why bankers should hesitate to
enter this new market, in spite of its apparent attractions. These must be
clearly acknowledged.

Banks are under increasing competitive pressure in the urban corporate


market, particularly as financial chaos elsewhere leads multinational
institutions to look to India for new business opportunities. They may decide
to focus their efforts on fighting this competition, and to withdraw from less
profitable markets as fast as government and public opinion will allow.

A number of new generation' specialist micro-finance institutions are


emerging, with funding from SIDBI and other sources. Some banks may make
a conscious policy decision to leave this market to them in order to
concentrate on their traditional and more familiar clientele..

Recent research (Harper, Esipisu, Mohanty and Rao) showed that the cost of
developing and assessing an SHG is approximately Rs 7000. Although some
groups develop themselves without assistance, and most come to banks ready
made' by NGOs which are funded form other sources, this is clearly a high
cost to acquire even some twenty new customers, since their individual
business is very small, and some bankers are nervous of having to incur this
cost themselves.

The vast majority of bank loans to SHGs are refinanced with heavily
subsidised funds from NABARD. The spread of about 5.5% which this
refinance allows is probably sufficient for traditional operations but may not
be enough to cover the extra costs involved in entering this new and
unfamiliar market.

SHGs cannot offer full collateral for their loans. The high rates of recovery
may make collateral unnecessary, and much collateral is effectively
uncollectible, but nevertheless bankers are always nervous to take on
unsecured advances, particularly form a quite new group of customers.

Many SHG members, or more often their husbands, have defaulted on their
repayments of earlier loans which they took under government sponsored
schemes. Default has often been the norm rather than the exception on such
schemes, but bankers are not unnaturally nervous to lend to people with a bad
credit record.
The legal and position of SHGs is not altogether clear. It may not be possible
to pursue recoveries through the courts, and they may be liable for taxation on
the profits they earn by on-lending bank funds. Bankers rightly dislike
uncertainty.

 Policy Makers.

Bankers prefer to claim that things, which they cannot change, such as
government policies, are responsible for their problems. This is always easier
and less uncommon microfinanceortable than recognizing and then changing
the things, which are under our control. Banking has been substantially
deregulated over the last seven years, but some distortions still survive which
make it more difficult, although by no means impossible, for bankers to start
doing business with SHGs.

SHGs are willing and able to pay 18% or even more for their money, but the
available subsidised refinance is only available if it is on lent at 12%. Banks
are thus prevented from treating SHGs like any other customer, by using their
own money and taking the higher spreads which some may find necessary.
There is nothing, which actually stops them from doing this, particularly on
larger loans to SHGs, but the 12% rate has been widely publicized and it
would be very difficult for a bank to justify charging a higher rate.

Co-operative and Regional Rural Banks are free to charge any rate of interest
they wish on any size of loan, but the commercial banks are still constrained
for the smallest loans. SHG loans, particularly at the early stages, fall into this
class.

Government still operates and indeed widely publicizes subsidised schemes


such as the IRDP, although some of the worst abuses have now been corrected.
Recovery rates on these loans are still low, and this inevitably continues to
pollute the credit culture of the same communities from which SHG members
are drawn.

Political interests in some states continue to promise debt forgiveness at


election time. Such promises may not be fulfilled, but they would clearly
include loans to SHGs.

One strong motivator for rural bankers in particular to do business with SHGs
is their desperate need for new business, in order to make their branches
profitable. Branch closures, as opposed to relocation, and the associated staff
redundancies, however, are still unheard of. This substantially reduces the
incentive to innovate.

The Way Ahead

This list of constraints is somewhat daunting, but it is hoped that it at least to some
extent explains the disappointing progress of the SHG linkage programme. It might
even be argued that the progress has been remarkable, rather than disappointing, given
all these reasons why SHGs, NGOs and banks themselves may be reluctant.
Management has been described as 80% identifying the problems and 20% designing
solutions, but it may be easier in this case to explain why progress has not been faster
than to suggest how it can become so. The title, and the aim, of this paper, is to
explain rather than to remedy, and many of the necessary changes are implied in the
above statements of the problems.

It may nevertheless be useful to conclude with some suggestions as to ways in which


some of the constraints may be removed. It should be stressed, however, that the
present record demonstrates that doing business with SHGs can be and is profitable
business for banks, in spite of the constraints. Bankers who are interested in entering
this new market, or in expanding their present position in it, should not be
discouraged or feel that they can go no further unless these constraints are removed.
Their performance thus far shows quite clearly that it can be done, and the best way to
encourage others to do it is for the pioneers to continue and indeed redouble their
efforts.

The suggested remedies are given under the same four headings that were used to
identify the problems.

 The SHGs and their members.

The customer is king, or in this case more commonly queen, and is always
right. Banks should, however, try to overcome SHG members' well-founded
misconceptions by regarding SHG linkage as a product to be promoted rather
than a scheme to be implemented. New savings and loan products are
vigorously and effectively promoted with posters and in other ways. Why
should the concept of group formation and saving, and eventual borrowing,
not be similarly promoted?

 NGOs

NGOs should decide whether or not they wish to be involved in SHG


development. There is, sadly, far more than enough work for them in the
traditional fields of health, education and community development, and
NGOs, which wish to continue their work in these and other fields should not
be diverted from what they are good at by the promise of donor funds. Donors,
both local and foreign, should also avoid tempting NGOs into micro-finance
when they are more than fully occupied in other work.

Those NGOs which do decide they should be involved should make micro-
finance a major thrust area, rather than regarding it as a peripheral support
activity for their other work. They should decide clearly whether they wish to
evolve into micro-finance institutions themselves, by taking bulk funds and
on-lending them, or whether they wish to focus on developing SHGs and then
introducing them to banks. If they chose the latter course, they should attempt
to share at least part of the cost of group development with the banks, so that
the product can be self-sustaining rather than dependent on donor funding.

They should also themselves become as business-like as they expect their


micro-finance clients to be; they should keep up-to-date records, they should
assess and attempt to reduce the cost of developing clients for the banks, and
should train their staff to perform as efficient and effective client development
staff for the banks.

 Banks

The regulatory environment for banks has been largely liberalized, but the
internal management environment is often as tightly controlled and illiberal as
the external environment used to be. Organizational change is needed not only
for micro-finance, but for the challenge of operating in the new and
competitive market place, whether national or international.

Many of the branch managers and staff who have done business with SHGs
have done it without any encouragement or even recognition from their
superiors, and their initiative is to be congratulated. Senior management
should, however, decide as a matter of policy whether they wish to be
involved in micro-finance as an act of charity or public relations, or whether
they wish to make it a part of their mainstream business. If they decide on the
latter, they should ensure that all their staff, at all levels, receive the necessary
training and support, and should monitor and encourage the growth of this
component of their business as vigorously as any other.

Banks should also attempt on their own or in collaboration with NGOs to


develop less costly and more rapid ways of developing groups, as at least two
Regional Rural Banks are already doing. They should recognize that it costs
money to acquire new customers, even rather poor ones, and should be willing
to pay this cost, whether by contracting the task out to NGOs or by
undertaking it themselves.

 Policy makers.

The policy environment has already been very significantly liberalized, and
the process is unlikely to be reversed, or even much delayed, by political
intervention or for any other reason. Total interest rate liberalization is bound
to come, but the single most positive step, paradoxically, might be for
refinance to be stopped for SHG lending. This would force the banks to look
at micro-finance as a market opportunity and not as a subsidised programme.
Even if some banks decided not to pursue it further, others would almost
certainly realize that there was money to be made from dealing with SHGs,
and would aggressively pursue the market. The eventual result would be that
far more groups would be reached.

As has been already pointed out, large segment of the poor in India still do not have
access to institutional credit. Therefore making credit available and accessible remains
crucial for long-term development strategy to end poverty. The absence of supportive
law and regulation is one of the main constraints in the credit flow to the poor and
needy. Therefore, there is need for creating microfinance specific law for regulation
and supervision of microfinance organizations to facilitate and increase the size of
credit and other finance flow to the poor particularly those in rural areas engaged in
agriculture, allied activities and the non-farm sector. The government must play a pro-
active role in bringing about such policy reforms suitable to the needs and changing
demands of the microfinance industry and the poor in particular.

The government must make efforts to;

1. Encourage the existing mainstream financial institutions to enter micro-finance


seriously by establishing supportive and enabling policy and regulatory
environment
2. Encourage new micro-finance institutions with a supportive policy and financial
resources to enlarge and expand their services and
3. Promote community based development institutions with the help of NGOs/MFIs
and others and facilitate adoption of best practices for micro-finance activities.

There is money available with considerable constraints for microfinance. There is a


huge market but there is clear lack of retail institutions with very thin organizational /
human resource capacity who can get involved and utilize for the emerging
opportunities in social protection finance. Capacity building for the mission
microfinance, for achieving scale, mobilizing resources in the form of borrowings and
equity to ramp up the existing operations and organizations / human resource capacity
that have complementary missions like insurance, social protection finance / housing
is clearly lacking. Strategic recruitment for scale at the current scenario is not possible
as the pool of human resource, who may get involved in this type of work is limited
even though front loaded approach is cost-effective. So strategy that involves capacity
building of organizations/ human resource both from the front-loading and back
loading is important. This will involve anchored efforts of networks to create resource
for social protection finance.

Recognizing that microfinance has impacted the lives and living conditions of the
poor, the need of the hour is to bring a new architecture of building a wide network of
microfinance institutions, NGOs and Self help groups and link them with formal
financial institutions. At present the setting up of SHGs or NGOs/MFIs to support the
microfinance sector is proceeding at a snails pace and a sense of urgency is lacking.
We cannot wait for generations for such networking to emerge autonomously.
Therefore, drawing up of a blue print for a structural transformation of the credit
delivery system mainly targeting the poor and rural areas merits serious consideration.

The poor who have been left out in the development and designs of programs often
meant for their development should be brought into the mainstream by empowering
them through their own institutions. Microfinance programs helps in mobilizing the
poor into groups, building community based, owned and managed institutions.
Therefore, there is need for the establishment and growth of microfinance institutions,
as these subsidiary institutions would provide a link between the rural poor and the
mainstream financial system. Involving the poor in developing and designing
programs for their own development would not only help in tackling the root cause of
poverty but also trickle down the benefit of such development programs to the poorest
of the poor.

In India, agriculture still holds the key to faster and over all GDP growth of the
country because more than 75 percent of the population continues to depend on it. It
also accounts for 60 percent of the total workforce and contributes 20 percent of
exports. Though, considered as a priority sector, it experienced credit squeeze in
recent years. It is said that India could graduate into a high growth league of 9 or 10
percent by ensuring agricultural growth of 4 or 4.5 percent per annum. In order to
make this happen, policies including credit and public investment must be put in place
to facilitate the attainment of 4 to 4.5 percent growths in agriculture and supported by
an explosion in non-farm employment in the rural sector. In addition, identifying and
supporting new ventures such as floriculture, aquaculture, tissue culture and wormy
culture etc. are new options and opportunities available and ensuring institutional
credit flow to these segments is equally important. Similarly, identifying and
promoting economically viable avenues of employment or projects and mobilizing
financial institutions to support such enterprises, either directly or through the linkage
of subsidiary institutions like micro credit institutions is vital in helping the poor.

Often finding donors who could bear the start up costs of forming groups is difficult.
Since start up costs cannot be easily recouped, providing start up costs are under
supplied. Thus there is a role for the Government and other donor agencies to support
such start up schemes and encourage the poor to form their own groups by making
use of the existing SHGs and community based organizations. Government and
donors must also support institutional development programs such as management
training, capacity building of NGOs/MFIs in the category of seed, sapling and trees
etc. This will ensure the healthy growth of each organization in each and every stage
of their growth and development and achieve their aim and objects of helping the poor
as envisaged in their organization’s vision and mission.

A New Paradigm

A new paradigm that emerges is that it is very critical to link poor to formal financial
system, whatever the mechanism may be, if the goal of poverty alleviation has to be
achieved. NGOs and CBOs have been involved in community development for long
and the experience shows that they have been able to improve the quality of life of
poor, if this is an indicator of development. The strengths and weaknesses of existing
NGOs/CBOs and microfinance institutions in India indicate that despite their best of
efforts they have not been able to link themselves with formal systems. It is desired
that an intermediary institution is required between formal financial markets and
grassroot. The intermediary should encompass the strengths of both formal financial
systems and NGOs and CBOs and should be flexible to the needs of end users. There
are, however, certain unresolved dilemmas regarding the nature of the intermediary
institutions. There are arguments both for and against each structure. These dilemmas
are very contextual and only strengthen the argument that no unique model is
applicable for all situations. They have to be context specific.

Dilemmas
Community Based Investor Owned
• Community Managed • Professionally managed
• Community (self) • Accepting outside funds for
financed on-lending
• Integrated (social & • Minimalist (finance only)
finance) • For profit
• Non profit / mutual
benefit • For all under served clients
• Only for poor
• Externally regulated
• 'Self regulated'

The four pillars of microfinance credit system (Fig. 1) are supply, demand for finance,
intermediation and regulation. Whatever may the model of the intermediary
institution, the end situation is accessibility of finance to poor. The following tables
indicate the existing and desired situation for each component.

DEMAND
Existing Situation Desired Situation
• Organized
• fragmented
• Differentiated (for
• Undifferentiated
consumption, housing)
• Addicted, corrupted by
• Deaddicted from capital
capital & subsidies
& subsidies
• Communities not aware of
• Aware of rights and
rights and responsibilities
responsibilities

SUPPLY
Existing Situation Desired Situation
• Grant based • Regular fund sources
(Foreign/GOI) (borrowings/deposits)
• Directed Credit - • Demand responsive
unwilling and corrupt • Part of mainstream
• Not linked with (banks/FIs)
mainstream • Add savings and insurance
• Mainly focussed for
credit • Reduce dominance of
informal, unregulated
• Dominated suppliers

INTERMEDIATION
Existing Situation Desired Situation
• Non specialized • Specialized in financial
• Not oriented to financial services
analysis • Thorough in financial
• Non profit capital analysis
• Not linked to mainstream • For profit
FIs • Link up to FIs

• Not organized • Self regulating

REGULATION
Existing Situation Desired Situation
• Focussed on formal service
providers (informal not
• include/informal
regulated)
recognise e.g. SHGs
• regulating the wrong things
• Regulate rules of game
e.g. interest rates
• Coherence and
• Multiple and conflicting
coordination across
(FCRA, RBI, IT, ROC,
regulators
MOF/FIPB,
ROS/Commerce)
• Enabling environment
• Negatively oriented

Possible Alternatives/Options

The three options that emerge out of above discussion regarding structure of
intermediary institution is discussed below.

Option-I

• One possible option is to increase the flow of funds to informal


lenders to supplement their own funds. The formal sector will
take advantage of the lower transaction costs and risk premia of
the informal sector so as to reach the low income group
borrowers beyond the profitable reach of the formal sector. As
for the beneficiaries, inspite of the transaction cost of the
formal and the informal sector being transferred on to them, the
cost of borrowing will remain low as compared to what exists
through money lenders.

In addition, access to the formal sector funds could promote


competition within the informal sector and check the exhorbitant
profits being made in this sector. It also promotes allocative efficiency
by offering a broader choice for the productive use of savings by
beneficiaries, irrespective of which sector they are mobilised by.
Thus this approach of promoting linkages combines the strengths of
both sectors to supplement the resources of the informal sector. Here it
is imperative to avoid the pitfall of discouraging informal savings by
substituting cheaper formal funds for informal lenders.

The existing modes of borrowing for the low income group through the
Co-operative Societies like Thrift and Credit Co.op Societies are
already gaining momentum. The Formal Financial Institutions can
establish linkages with these co-operative bodies. Funds could be
channelised from the formal financial institutions at market rates to the
low income group beneficiaries through the intermediaries like the co-
operative bodies stated above. The credit worthiness of the
intermediaries would be the basic security for the loans advanced by
the formal financial institutions. However, the savings mobilised by the
intermediaries from the informal sector could also be accepted as
collaterals.

The intermediaries could then lend to groups of beneficiaries. The


transaction cost of the formal sector would be transferred on to the
intermediaries who would pass on the same to the beneficiaries.

In the process, the intermediaries would also charge additional fees to


borrowers to cover their costs. It would also aid them in strengthening
themselves. However, it would be aimed to make the funds reach the
beneficiaries at applicable rates of the two institutions.

The intermediaries would accept the savings from groups as collaterals


and would transfer the same to the formal sector for getting the
deposits serviced better. Thus the two way flow of funds would benefit
both the formal and informal sector.

The beneficiaries would benefit as the cost of borrowing would be low


for them and their savings would be safe and would be serviced better.

An analysis of community-based finance systems highlights the high


establishment costs of NGOs. They suggest that loan service costs are
lower amongst co-operative societies, as compared to NGO-linked
CBFIs, because of decentralized loan administration and availability of
voluntary staff. The NGO-linked CBFI operations are generally
supported by grants from national and international donor agencies.

NGO-linked CBFIs must aim at an adequate scale of operation and


while it may be supported by grants to meet establishment costs in the
initial period, dependency on such grants should be reduced over time.
An adequate interest rate spread must be available to meet the
transactions costs. CBFIs should be able to recover all costs through its
financial operations, by building up their capacity for financial
management, through training and interaction with the Formal sector
institutions.
Option-II

• Since it is now being felt that the existing structures are


inadequate to meet the housing and economic credit needs of
the participating community, an Institution that would combine
the strengths of an NGO and the expertise of a financial
institution, with participation from the community will be
appropriate.

Thus, the concept of Development Association for Savings and Credit


(DASC) could be utilised to address the issue of providing better
access to housing finance and economic loans for the participating
community in the project area. The DASC is built on the strength of
the informal groups to create and improve access to skills, resources
and markets. These Groups mobilize savings from their constituent
members and other formal/informal sources. The funds mobilized are
thus used for meeting the credit needs of the members. The DASC is
proposed to be a registered company which will affiliate the Groups
based on affiliation criteria and have community representation on its
decision making body.

The DASC will be initiated with the objective to create an alternate,


self-sustainable, community based financial organization appropriate
to meet the shelter development and livelihood needs of the weaker
section belonging to the rural community.

The long term perspective of DASC will include :

Establishment of a resource centre for shelter and livelihood


development for the weaker sections of the society.

Demonstration of a viable community based credit system in operation


where the communities have access to and control over financial
resources based on their own strength.

Developing group based approach as a sustainable development


paradigm for community development.

Option-III

• As mentioned before, a review of the cooperatives and NGOs


illustrates a wide variety of arrangements as well as different
stages of development of community-based financial
institutions. In all cases, the strength of the community based
systems is their close rapport and linkages with the community
and its members. The broad arrangement involves a bulk loan
from the Formal Financial Institution to the Community Based
Financial Institution (CBFI) with specified terms and
conditions for lending to households. The CBFI will have the
responsibility for loan origination and servicing and therefore
would also bear the credit risk.

In terms of specific arrangements, two forms of intermediation are


envisaged by the strategy. The multi-tiered structure is one in which
the bulk loans from the Formal Sector are routed through a Federation
or Apex Agency or an NGO, which in turn lends to a primary CBFI. In
the single-tiered structure, the Formal Sector Institution deals directly
with the CBFI. It is felt that the administrative costs incurred with
lending through the multi-tiered model are much higher than under the
single-tier model.

In promoting these linkages between the Formal Institutions and


CBFIs, directly or through the NGO, it is important that basic financial
principles are developed for giving bulk credit to community-based
financial institutions. The purpose of the loan, credit terms and
underwriting criteria should be clearly defined for the bulk credit that
is provided to the CBFI.

It is essential that a delinquency risk fund (DRF) be placed as a deposit with the
Formal Institution to cover delinquency risk which may draw against the DRF if the
CBFI fails to make a regularly scheduled loan payment. In order to meet the the DRF
requirment, CBFIs should be encouraged to start a savings scheme. An appropriate
legal status for the CBFI to be able to receive the bulk credit is essential. This may
involve a simple registration under the Societies Act. The legal form should permit the
receipt of bulk credit for onlending to the individual members.
JUMPSTARTING INDIA'S RURAL ECONOMY

Can India's rural economy be an engine for growth? If India's economic liberalisation
initiatives haven't delivered the desired results; it is because they have largely
excluded over 700 million people who live in rural India.

Economically empowering India's rural population will have a significant impact on


India's economic growth. Economic empowerment is defined here as access to
inexpensive credit (which Professor Muhammad Yunus, founder of Bangladesh's
Grameen Bank, describes as a fundamental human right) and other microfinance
services, including savings and insurance.

Here we will looks at new ways of encouraging rural enterprise by reducing the
exorbitant interest rates that India's rural population currently pay.

The modern banking system has failed to deliver inexpensive credit to India's 600,000
villages - despite several expensive attempts to do so. Do we need to rethink the
appropriate institutional structure for rural banking in India? Some suggestions for
achieving this are offered here.

The problems of widespread poverty, growing inequality, rapid population growth and
rising unemployment all find their origins in the stagnation of economic life in rural
areas. There can be no national development without rural development.

The economic prospects for rural development are far from bleak (indeed, they show
an astonishing robustness), as can be seen from the following facts:

Small scale and cottage industries (despite their comparatively restricted access to
credit) employ ten times as many workers as heavy industry in India, upwards of 30
million people.

While capital-output ratios have been steadily deteriorating since independence in the
heavier capital intensive industries, they look a lot healthier in small and cottage
industries. Furthermore, heavy industry usually needs to be located in urban areas.

Small scale and cottage industries, on the other hand, can be located almost anywhere
throughout the country, and facilitate the dispersion of economic wealth rather than its
concentration.

Many small scale and cottage industries don't even require access to electricity, the
scarcity of which is a major bottleneck for industrial output. Wide range of output:
Modern small-scale industries produce a wide range of goods from comparatively
simple items to sophisticated products such as television sets electronic control
systems etc.

Among traditional village industries, handicrafts possess the highest labour


productivity, besides making a significant contribution to earning foreign exchange
for the country.
Stemming rural-urban migration: The Industrial Policy Resolution of 1956 notes
that "Some of the problems that unplanned urbanisation tends to create will be
avoided by the establishment of small centres of industrial production all over the
country."

The Lewis-Fei-Ranis model offers us the insight that urban wages would have to be at
least 30 per cent higher than the average rural income to induce workers to migrate
from their home areas. At this urban wage level, the supply of rural labour is
considered to be perfectly elastic. The Todaro migration model, however, postulates
that migration proceeds in response to urban-rural differences in expected rather than
actual earnings.

However, the rural economy's development potential - and with it, the growth
prospects of the entire Indian economy - are not going to be achieved without the
availability of (a) affordable credit, (b) in adequate quantities (c) at the right time.

But how does one go about creating an efficient credit delivery system that offers
affordable credit, in adequate quantities, at the right time, in India's 600,000 villages?

It is known that the organisation and structure of commercial banks are not identical
in all countries. The differences are dictated by a number of local factors like
geographical spread, political factors, economic conditions and traditions, not to
mention population density and dispersion.

Although the branch-banking structure that we adopted from Britain's banking


tradition has served India's urban centres well, all attempts to extend this institutional
structure to India's rural areas have resulted in inadequate coverage, and frequently
proved to be expensive failures.

The earliest form of commercial banking was necessarily unit banking which simply
means that the entire banking operations were conducted from a single office.

Unit banking has already proven its effectiveness for providing an efficient credit
delivery system under conditions similar in several important respects to those
prevailing in rural India today:

Until recently, large areas of the U.S.A. were underpopulated. The considerable
distances between population centres, the difficulties in travel and communication,
and the agrarian nature of the economy all fostered the development of unit banks that
were locally organised, owned and operated.

Unit banks financed the development of the U.S. economy, and are still prevalent
there to this day. They offer many of the advantages of branch banking like providing
remittance facilities through a system of `correspondent banks', not dissimilar to our
own `lead banks'.

Although unit banks today are able to offer the same range of financial services that
branch banks provide, they tend to be closer to the communities they serve, and
understand their needs better.
Another advantage of the unit banking system - not insignificant from the perspective
of a Central Bank and `lender of last resort', is that the `domino effect' of an individual
bank's failure is limited in comparison to that within a branch banking system.

How does one establish Unit Banks in 600,000 Indian villages? The answer is that
`unit banks' already exist in every Indian village, and the RBI doesn't have to spend a
single rupee in capital outlays for establishing them...

It is known that the writings of Manu dating back five thousand years contained
references to banks in India, as did the writings of Kautilya. India's indigenous
bankers have a presence in every Indian village, and supported a thriving rural
economy prior to colonial rule and the onslaught of the industrial revolution which
devastated India's rural economy and marginalized the majority of India's people. The
Industrial Commission Report (1918) notes that "At a time when the West of Europe,
the birth place of the modern industrial system, was inhabited by uncivilised tribes,
India was famous for the wealth of her rulers and for the high artistic skill of her
craftsmen."

Having survived the vagaries of time - famines and floods, colonial policies, and more
recent attempts by the organised financial sector to marginalia them - India's
indigenous bankers continue to occupy a prominent position in India's financial
markets. According to the Shroff Committee on Finance for the Private Sector,
between 75 and 90 per cent of the total internal trade of the country is being financed
by India's indigenous bankers.

The Banking Commission (1972) recognised that the indigenous bankers play a useful
role in as much as they make credit available to those sectors (small-scale business
units and the retail trade) which are productive but which are generally not assisted by
commercial banks either on grounds of cost or the risk involved. The Commission
noted that the indigenous banker's methods of operation are both expeditious and
flexible...

Integration of India's financial markets is essential for effective monetary policy.


Despite the predominant role played by the indigenous bankers in India's economic
life, they have always remained outside the pale of organised banking, and beyond
the influence of the Reserve Bank of India.

Yet an integrated financial market that responds to the guidance and leadership of the
Reserve Bank of India is an essential prerequisite for an effective monetary policy.

As early as 1931, the Central Banking Enquiry Committee emphasised the necessity
of unifying the two sectors of the Indian money market, and recommended the linking
of the indigenous bankers with the Reserve Bank of India, after the Reserve Bank was
established.

Having (with one interesting exception) been treated with undeserved contempt by the
modern, largely westernised financial sector led by the RBI, it's hardly surprising that
the Reserve Bank's influence with India's indigenous bankers has regrettably been
limited.
The key to reversing this unhappy situation lies in cultivating and demonstrating
greater respect for the rich heritage, and continuing contribution, of India's traditional
financial sector.

An important lesson can be learnt from the State Bank of India's predecessor, the
Imperial Bank of India, which achieved a measure of influence in the early years of
this century with the indigenous bankers (even influencing the interest rates they
charged) which had never been achieved before, and hasn't been achieved since.

The Imperial Bank of India achieved its unprecedented influence simply by respecting
the indigenous bankers age-old ways of doing business, and offering them rediscount
facilities without cumbersome conditionalities. The impact of providing refinance to
indigenous bankers, particularly during the busy agricultural season between
November and June, was lower rural interest rates…
THE FUTURE OF MICROFINANCE IN INDIA:

A Long History of Social Banking

India has supported social banking for a long time. Policy directions to rapidly expand
rural branches, mandate credit allocations for priority sectors (including agriculture),
deliver large subsidy oriented credit programmes to serve marginal communities and
poor households and control interest rates have been tried for over 35 years.
The new generation microfinance was slow in coming to India. Low levels of grants
to microfinance institutions, an unfavorable policy environment, substantial
traditional banking infrastructure and a search for context specific solutions has
constrained rapid scale up. The first breakthrough emerged from policy support to
enable informal self help groups of 15-20 members (mainly women) to transact with
commercial banks. These groups build up and rotate savings amongst themselves,
open bank accounts and take responsibility for lending and recovering money
financed by banks. With the missionary zeal of the National Bank for Agriculture and
Rural Development (NABARD), insights gained by NGOs, the increasing enthusiasm
of bankers and politicians and emerging successes in repayment and social impacts,
this national movement now encompasses 1.4 million such groups (over 20 million
members).
At a time when many questioned the need for specialised microfinance institutions
(MICROFINANCEIs) in India, the Small Industries Development Bank of India
recognised the opportunity and started implementation of an ambitious national
programme. Providing loan and capacity building support to MICROFINANCEIs and
capacity building and rating support for sector development, this programme already
supports 70 MICROFINANCEIs and has disbursed US$46 million.

What is Exciting about Indian Microfinance?

A Task Force on Microfinance recognised in 1999 that microfinance is much more


than microcredit, stating: "Provision of thrift, credit and other financial services and
products of very small amounts to the poor in rural, semi-urban and or urban areas for
enabling them to raise their income levels and improve living standards". The Self
Help Group promoters emphasise that mobilising savings is the first building block of
financial services.
For many years, the national budget and other policy documents have almost equated
microfinance with promoting SHG links to the banks. The central bank notification
that lending to MICROFINANCEIs would count towards meeting the priority sector
lending targets for Banks offered the first signs of policy flexibility towards
MICROFINANCEIs. One could argue that MICROFINANCEIs are small and
insignificant, so why bother. The larger point is about policy space for innovation and
diversity of approaches to meet large unmet demand. The insurance sector was
partially opened to private and foreign investments during 2000. Over 20 insurance
companies are already active and experimenting with new products, delivery
methodologies and strategic partnerships.
Since banks face substantial priority sector targets and microfinance is beginning to
be recognised as a profitable opportunity (high risk adjusted returns), a variety of
partnership models between banks and MICROFINANCEIs have been tested. All
varieties of banks - domestic and international, national and regional - have become
involved, and ICICI Bank has been at the forefront of some of the following
innovations:

• Lending wholesale loan funds.


• Assessing and buying out microfinance debt (securitisation).
• Testing and rolling out specific retail products such as the Kissan (Farmer)
Credit Card.
• Engaging microfinance institutions as agents, which are paid for loan
origination and recovery, with loans being held on the books of banks.
• Equity investments into newly emerging MICROFINANCEIs.
• Banks and NGOs jointly promoting MICROFINANCEIs.

The 2005 national budget has further strengthened this policy perspective and the
Finance Minister Mr P. Chidambram announced "Government intends to promote
MICROFINANCEIs in a big way. The way forward, I believe, is to identify
MICROFINANCEIs, classify and rate such institutions, and empower them to
intermediate between the lending banks and the beneficiaries."

What is beginning to happen in microfinance can be seen from the perspective of


what has happened to phones in India. With the right enabling environment, and
intense competition amongst private sector players, mobile phones in India expanded
by 160% during just one year 2003-04 (from 13 to 33 million). Mobile tariffs fell by
74% during the same period. While this is heady progress, there is a less heralded but
even more powerful nationwide success on access. In the late eighties, the phone
infrastructure was the monopoly of public sector institutions. Phones were difficult to
get and even more difficult to use for those lacking ownership. Realisation that users
need not own a phone to access one led to privatisation of the last mile - where a
phone user could interface with a private sector provider using the public sector
telecom infrastructure. Even with this policy change, today there are 2.5 million
entrepreneurs selling local, national and international phone services through the
length and breadth of India. Many of these are now graduating to sell internet services
and could potentially be banking agents - that is the evolving story.
Savings services are needed by many more customers and as frequently as access to
phone services. Many poor households value access to savings services and find new
providers and arrangements, despite hearing of unreliable savings collectors or even
occasionally falling prey to such arrangements. Many customers are rich, literate and
lucky to have banks working for them. But many others lack access to safe, secure
and accessible savings services for the short, medium and long terms.In the past,
many banks sent collectors to gather these savings but problems with monitoring,
inability to tackle misappropriation and the rising aspiration of collectors to become
permanent staff of public sector banks killed a useful service. The central bank has
strictly forbidden commercial banks from using agents in collection of savings
services. This is unfortunate as:

• Effective microfinance delivery is about managing transaction costs for


providers and customers.
• A combination of agents and technology can play a powerful role in rightly
aligning incentives for the collector and customers, while keeping transaction
costs manageable for everyone.
• The banks can only open so many branches, and fixed and operating costs are
high, apart from approvals still needed from the central bank to open new
branches or close existing ones. The appointment of agents can keep costs
manageable and offer greater flexibility to Banks.
• Banking service may not be able to defy the commercial logic pursued by
most other sectors where a variety of retailers provide services to customers,
while companies focus on customer needs, product design, quality control,
branding, logistics and distribution.

Fortunately, the 2005 Budget opened a small window in this area and the central bank
annual policy recently confirmed discussions on this: "As a follow-up to the Budget
proposals, modalities for allowing banks to adopt the agency model by using the
infrastructure of civil society organisations, rural kiosks and village knowledge
centres for providing credit support to rural and farm sectors and appointment of
micro-finance institutions (MICROFINANCEIs) as banking correspondents are being
worked out." But readers may note that between the budget and the annual policy
statement, "credit" has again crept in as the key perceived need.

Challenges Remain

A World Bank study assessing access to financial institutions found that amongst rural
households in Andhra Pradesh and Uttar Pradesh, 59% lack access to deposit account
and 78% lack access to credit. Considering that the majority of the 360 million poor
households (urban and rural) lack access to formal financial services, the numbers of
customers to be reached, and the variety and quantum of services to be provided are
really large. Vijay Mahajan, Managing Director of BASICS, estimated that 90 million
farm holdings, 30 million non-agricultural enterprises and 50 million landless
households in India collectively need approx US$30 billion credit annually. This is
about 5% of India's GDP and does not seem an unreasonable estimate.

A tiny segment of this US$30 billion potential market has been reached so far and this
is unlikely to be addressed by MICROFINANCEIs and NGOs alone. Reaching this
market requires serious capital, technology and human resources. However, 80% of
the financial sector is still controlled by public sector institutions. Competition,
consolidation and convergence are all being discussed to improve efficiency and
outreach but significant opposition remains; for example, the All India Bank
Employees Association has threatened to strike if the Government proceeds with its
policy of reducing its capital in public sector banks, merging public sector banks or
even enhancing Foreign Direct Investments in Indian private banks.

Many speakers at the Microfinance India conference talked about the significant and
growing gap between surging growth in South India, which contrasts with the
stagnation in Eastern, Central and North Eastern India. Microfinance on its own is
unlikely to be able to address formidable challenges of underdevelopment, poor
infrastructure and governance.
The Self Help Group movement is beginning to focus on issues of quality and there
were some interesting discussions on embedding social performance monitoring as a
part of the regular management information systems.
At the time of the conference, a leading and responsible MICROFINANCEI was
being investigated by the authorities for charging "high" rates of interest. Per unit
transaction costs of small loans are high but many opinion leaders still persist with the
notion poor people cannot be charged rates that are higher than commercial bank
rates. The reality of the high transaction costs of serving small customers, their
continuing dependence on the informal sector, the fact that most bankers shy away
from retailing to this market as a business opportunity, and the poor quality of
services currently provided does not figure prominently in this discourse. While the
central bank has deregulated most interest rates, including lending to and by
MICROFINANCEIs, interest rates restrictions on commercial bank for retail loans
below US$5,000 (all microfinance and beyond) remain and caps on deposit rates also
discourage sharing transaction costs with customers.But most conference participants
accepted the imperatives to build sustainable institutions.

There is still lot of policy focus on what activities are and are not allowed and not
enough operational freedom as yet for banks and financial institutions to design and
deliver programmes, and be responsible for their actions. Prescriptions and detailed
circulars often limit organisational innovation and market segmentation. As Nachiket
Mor of ICICI Bank said at the conference, if the right indicators are monitored and
operational freedom and incentives are clear, both public and private banks have the
capacity to rapidly address the remaining challenges.

Closing Remarks

In my view, savings service is the neglected daughter of the family of financial


services. I use this metaphor because of the sustained discrimination against and
frequent disregard for savings services, despite their productive and reproductive role
in financial services.This is evident from different nomenclature used at both the
international (UN International Year of Microcredit, MicroCredit summit) and
national levels (Priority Sector Lending; Annual Credit Policy; Credit/ deposit ratio).
Savings services can be a useful entry point for the unbanked to build up a history
with the formal financial institutions before customers are entitled to other financial
services. With the greater spotlight on knowing the customer and the fact that poor
households do not have a salary slip, utility bills, clear land titles or unique identity
papers, a regular savings record could be the first building block to membership of the
formal financial sector. What is more, with savings services, poor customers need to
trust the financial institution and not the other way round.
Microfinance is not yet at the centre stage of the Indian financial sector. The
knowledge, capital and technology to address these challenges however now exist in
India, although they are not yet fully aligned. With a more enabling environment and
surge in economic growth, the next few years promise to be exciting for the delivery
of financial services to poor people in India.
I would like to congratulate CARE, as the lead organisers, for successfully hosting
this global cross learning event. Unusually, the event ended with a statement of some
objectively verifiable indicators (such as expansion of urban microfinance, increased
conference participation by public sector banks and redressal of North South divide)
on which the sector should track progress in a years' time.
SUGGESTIONS
CONCLUSION
Some valuable lessons can be drawn from the experience of successful Microfinance
operation. First of all, the poor repay their loans and are willing to pay for higher
interest rates than commercial banks provided that access to credit is provided. The
solidarity group pressure and sequential lending provide strong repayment motivation
and produce extremely low default rates. Secondly, the poor save and hence
microfinance should provide both savings and loan facilities. These two findings
imply that banking on the poor can be a profitable business. However, attaining
financial viability and sustainability is the major institutional challenge. Deposit
mobilization is the major means for microfinance institutions to expand outreach by
leveraging equity (Sacay et al 1996). In order to be sustainable, microfinance lending
should be grounded on market principles because large scale lending cannot be
accomplished through subsidies.

A main conclusion of this paper is that microfinance can contribute to solving the
problem of inadequate housing and urban services as an integral part of poverty
alleviation programmes. The challenge lies in finding the level of flexibility in the
credit instrument that could make it match the multiple credit requirements of the low
income borrowers without imposing unbearably high cost of monitoring its end-use
upon the lenders. A promising solution is to provide multi-purpose loans or composite
credit for income generation, housing improvement and consumption support.
Consumption loan is found to be especially important during the gestation period
between commencing a new economic activity and deriving positive income. Careful
research on demand for financing and savings behaviour of the potential borrowers
and their participation in determining the mix of multi-purpose loans are essential in
making the concept work (tall 1996).

Eventually it would be ideal to enhance the creditworthiness of the poor and to make
them more "bankable" to financial institutions and enable them to qualify for long-
term credit from the formal sector. Microfinance institutions have a lot to contribute to
this by building financial discipline and educating borrowers about repayment
requirements.
FINDING
ABBREVIATIONS

ADB Asian Development Bank


AIRCSC All India Rural Credit Review Committee
AMC Ahmedabad Municipal Corporation
CCBs Central Co-operative Banks
DIC District Industrial Center
DCCB District Central Co-operative Bank
DWCRA Development of Women and Children in Rural Areas
FRFI Formal Rural Financial Institutions
GDP Gross domestic product
GSFC Gujarat State Financial Corporation
HDFC Housing Development Finance Corporation
HFI Housing Finance Institutes
HUDCO Housing and Urban Development Corporation
ICAR Indian Council of Agricultural Research
IRDP Integrated Rural Development Program
LIG Low income groups
MAK Mahila Antodaya Kendra
MICROFINANCEI Microfinance Institution
MICROFINANCEO Microfinance Organization
MHT Mahila Housing Trust
NABARD National Bank for Agriculture and Rural Development
NGOs Nongovernmental organizations
PLDBs Primary Land Development Banks
RBI Reserve Bank of India (for cooperative banks)
RRBs Regional Rural Banks
SEWA Self Employed Women’s Association
SC Scheduled Caste
SCBs State Co-operative Banks
SEBC Socially Economic Backward Class
SFT Shroff Foundation Trust
SHG Self-help groups
SLDBs State Level Development Banks
ST Scheduled Tribes
VOs Voluntary Organizations
BIBLIOGRAPHY
www.microfinancegaeway.org
www.nabard.org
www.rbi.gov.in

“MICROFINANCE Emerging Challenges” BY Kishanjit Basu & Kridhan Jindal


“State Focus Paper-Gujarat 2006-07” By NABARD Gujarat Regional Office
“Jumpstarting India's Rural Economy” By Imon Ghosh

Das könnte Ihnen auch gefallen