Sie sind auf Seite 1von 16

Orbital Economics: Engineering Growth

Terry Bain.

Twentieth Space Congress


Cocoa Beach, Florida

Private Enterprise in Space


April 26, 1983.

Copyright 1983, Terry Bain


Orbital Economics: Engineering Growth

Terry Bain.

Twentieth Space Congress


Cocoa Beach, Florida

Private Enterprise in Space


April 26, 1983.

Copyright 1983, Terry Bain

Abstract

Government funding is usually too irregular and inefficient to sustain Orbital


Industrial Operations. Economic history indicates that America's Moon landing
was probably engineered by the Kennedy Tax Rate Reductions of 1964-66.
Taxation, directly and indirectly, has always affected the aerospace industry: rate
cuts engineer growth.

Economic "Bad Medicine" is the primary causation of most problems delaying


Private Enterprises’ expansion into space. Rate cuts increase government
revenues: tax hikes seem to precipitate budget cuts that can kill projects, or
people. Unnecessarily high tax rates almost always force private sources of
capital "underground". Mankind needs access to its "second worlds". One-
world, "fractional economics" is obsolete.

Introduction: the Malthus Mistake

Aviation people understand the crashes are usually the result of an uncorrected
chain of small mistakes. Each isolated error often seems far too minor to be
singled out as an accident’s cause. A long train of minor errors, however, can
have results that are fatal.

America's economy "stalls out "occasionally.” Any good pilot knows how to
recover from a stall; they simply nose their ship down, and trade off a little
altitude for airspeed to regain lift. If the machine isn't damaged, a stall should
only be a relatively minor problem - unless, of course, it happens a little too close
to the ground.

Good economic "navigation" is essential, if the captains and crews of American


commerce choose to avoid "pilot error". Today's economists, for the most part,
are not navigating effectively: their tools still work, but their charts are out of date.
All forms of Malthusian, or controlled growth economics (Mercantilism) are
dangerously obsolete - since July 20, 1969, Earth's expanding population has
had potential access to a "second world.” Mercantilism is too slow; economic
"bad medicine" is the only barrier, in 1983, to unrestrained frontier growth.

Mercantilism became obsolete in 1776, when Adam Smith published Wealth of


Nations. (Figure 1). Smith advocated minimum governmental intervention, free
enterprise, and free trade, based on the assumption that the labor of individuals
(rather than the national hoard of gold) was, and is, the only real source of all
wealth. Smith felt that the interests of society, as a whole, are best served by
allowing every individual to pursue his own self–interests.

Classical economics began veering off course in 1798, when Thomas Malthus
published An Essay on the Principle of Population. He observed, correctly, that
unrestrained populations tend to grow geometrically, while resources seem only
to rise at an arithmetical rate. Malthus feared that more and more people,
competing more each year, for ever-smaller per-capita shares of the planet,
would someday leave Earth hip-deep in hungry people.

Later European economists, including Jeremy Bentham and David Ricardo,


attempted to deal with the projected Malthusian "evils" of unrestrained growth.
Classical economics became the "gloomy science," and mainstream economic
philosophy gradually began reverting back towards controlled growth.

Income redistribution and social reform were advocated, in the 19th century, to
ration out the alleged "dwindling resources" of the planet. John Stuart Mill
advocated "progressive taxation,” socialization of land rent, and compulsory
education, while paradoxically insisting on limited governmental power, to
preserve individual freedom. Karl Marx pondered Ricardo's "gloomy science"
and came to the conclusion that only political revolution could save society.

John Maynard Keynes wrote The End of Laissez-Faire, in 1926. Later, he


became the first economist to argue that increased government spending
(Monetarism) would solve the Great Depression of the 1930s. Monetarists were
"... all Keynesians"; but by the 1970s, severe inflation had forced a few
economists to begin having second thoughts. Milton Friedman, in Free to
Choose, re-examines Smith's classical economics to find solutions that
government spending, alone, couldn't seem to cure.

While working as an editorial writer for the Wall Street Journal, Jude Wanniski
noticed two economists, who seemed to be "navigating" correctly. Wanniski
observed, in The Way the World Works that Robert Mundell and Arthur Laffer
foretold the rapid inflation of 1973, and correctly predicted the recession of 1974-
75.

In the summer of 1974, Wanniski writes, President Ford proposed a 5% surtax on


personal income. (1) The nation's economy. "stalled and crashed". At first
glance, the cause of that crash might be dismissed as a coincidence. Ford's
surtax and the "Crash of ’75,” probably wasn't the only time in economic history
that bad economics had "grounded" the aviation industry.

Mellon's Medicine: Engineered Growth

Small-scale air-transport experimentation, wrote Hugh Knowlton in Air


Transportation in the United States, was just getting underway from 1911 to
1921. In 1916, Congress authorized funds to the Post Office Department to
advertise for private enterprise contracting bids. “No bids were received,
because those who would have liked to bid found it impossible to obtain suitably
constructed planes for such a service." (2) During World War I, the War
Department started the first experimental air-mail route, in May of 1918. After the
war, the Post Office Department took over the entire operation in 1919, operating
three routes. Congress authorized funds for the first transcontinental route, and
it made its debut flight in February, 1921. (3) Early progress was slow;
necessary venture capital was only available from the government.

Wanniski writes that Warren G. Harding won the 1920 presidential elections,
following a severe post-war recession, by the largest landslide victory in history;
his platform urged a "Return to Normalcy". (4) His predecessor, Woodrow
Wilson, had signed a $6 billion surtax into law, February 24, 1919, to pay off the
nation's war deficit. (5) America's economy "stalled"; the League of Nations and
many Democratic reelection bids "crashed". Harding appointed Andrew Mellon
as Secretary Of Treasury. In 1921, they urged Congress to eliminate the excess-
profits surtax, and the economy began a slow recovery. (6) Following Harding's
death in office, in 1923, President Calvin Coolidge called for further income tax
rate reductions in February, 1924 - the stock market began responding
immediately. (7).

On Mellon's advice, rates were reduced from 57% on upper-income tax brackets,
towards a maximum rate of not more than 25%. (8) Between 1921 and 1929,
Mellon's tax rate cuts increased government revenue enough to reduce the
national debt by more than 20%. (9) Wanniski writes, "It had taken four years for
the New York Times index to rise from 90 to 106." By December of 1924, it rose
to 134, and by the end of 1925, it reached 181. After a plateau through 1926, it
got to 245 by the end of 1927. The Times Industrials peaked on September 19,
1929, at 469 - the index, Wanniski notes, had quadrupled in five-and-a-half
years. (10)

Commercial aviation "took off" too; Mellon’s medicine was the perfect prescription
for Commercial Air Transport growth. "The Post Office had demonstrated the
practicability of mail by air...", wrote Knowlton, "but it did not wish permanently to
perform the role of operator. "Rather, it wanted to turn over the operation of
airmail service to private enterprise as soon as possible". (11) In February, 1925,
one year after Mellon's income tax rate reductions began, Congress passed the
Kelly act, which made provision for the transportation of airmail by private
contractors. Ford Motor Company was first to enter the field. They had begun
building airplanes in 1924, and in 1926 they began operating routes. By 1927,
the Post Office Department was able to turn over its last route to private
contractors. (12)

"Once placed on a private contract basis expansion of the airmail service was
rapid, and more and more private capital came into the field," Knowlton wrote,
"New lines were established all over the country." (13) on May 20, 1927, Charles
Lindbergh flew to Europe. "New companies sprang up, and the securities of
existing companies soared to fancy heights...by 1929 there were 44 listed
operators of scheduled routes in the United States, nearly 2 1/2 times the
number that are in existence….,” Knowlton wrote, in 1941. (14)

Wanniski writes, "None of the prevailing theories could explain the 1929 crash
any better than they could explain the preceding boom. "Until this writing, no one
has linked the crash with the breakdown of the anti-tariff coalition in the Senate in
the last days of October of ‘29." (15) "The stock market crash of ’29, writes
Wanniski, "... and the Great Depression ensued because of the passage of the
Smoot-Hawley Tariff Act of 1930." (16)

Knowlton wrote "... 1929 began a period of mergers and consolidations, which
became necessary with the collapse of the boom late that year." (17) In April,
1930, Congress passed the McNary-Watres act that paid contractors by weight,
instead of mileage: bonuses had to be instituted to "stimulate" passenger service.
(18)

Equilibrium had almost been recovered, according to Wanniski, when President


Hoover tried to "balance the budget" by increasing income tax rates for fiscal
year 1932. As usual, the economy stalled - and this time the banks crashed. As
the March 15, 1933 income tax payment deadline approached, taxpayers all
across the country were forced, simultaneously, to withdraw their savings, and
the banking. "Panic of ’33” was the result. Roosevelt's famous "Bank Holiday,"
which he announced at his inauguration on March 4, 1933, merely enabled the
Fed to reflow tax receipts to the nation's “overtaxed” banking system. (19)

In 1934, all airmail contracts were suddenly canceled by Presidential decree.


Milton noted that charges of "collusion” between operators and the Post Office
Department were cited. "The Army, forced overnight to carry the mail, a task for
which it was technically unprepared, attempted to rise to the occasion and made
a gallant effort to fill the bill, but the tragic results to many of its personnel are
well-known." (20) Subsequent contracts were set at prices that bidders knew in
advance were inadequate to pay for the service. Knowlton observed that, "...
revenues did not keep up with expenses. We thus have the spectacle of an
industry growing by leaps and bands in volume of traffic, but losing money in the
process - a sort of profitless prosperity." (21)
By 1926, Robert Goddard had successfully demonstrated the liquid fuel rocket.
Further developments, however, were slowed by the Depression. Major General
Walter Dornberger, formerly the commanding officer of the Peenemunde Rocket
Research Institute, writes in V-2, "As so often before in the history of technology,
necessity in Germany after the first world war had forced a great invention to
proceed by way of weapon development. (22) "Neither industry nor the technical
colleges were paying any attention to the development of high powered rocket
propulsion. There were only individual inventors who played about without
financial support, assisted by more or less able collaborators... as we did not
succeed in interesting heavy industry. There was nothing left to do but to set up
our own experimental station for liquid propellant rockets...." (23) Lacking
venture capital from any source other than the government, Dornberger noted
that, "Research workers were obliged to serve the ends of war." (24) The road to
the stars was open, but the moon was still a tax cut away.

Camelot: Ticket to the Moon

Twenty years ago, in April of 1963, former President Dwight Eisenhower wrote,
"The space program, in my opinion, is downright spongy. This is an area where
we particularly need to demonstrate some common sense. "Specifically, I have
never believed a spectacular dash to the moon, vastly deepening our debt, is
worth the added tax burden it will eventually impose upon our citizens... I suggest
that our enthusiasm here be tempered in the interest of fiscal soundness." (25)

Ken Hechler writes, in towards the endless frontier, "the very size and steep
increases in the NASA budget alarmed many Congressmen...." (26) "Selling the
space program to Congress was no easy task....up to 1962, this was
comparatively easy; the shock of Sputnik and Gagarin's flight had not yet worn
off, and John Glenn, and the other Mercury astronauts had made the program
easy to sell. "Congress in 1963 was reflecting incipient dissent from many
groups in areas throughout the country, and this dissent expressed itself in
several different ways." Hechler notes that in FY 1963, the NASA budget was
"trimmed" by $500 million. (27) Budget cuts always have hidden costs; the
Mercury program concluded by 1963, but the Gemini program slipped back a
year. (28)

In February of 1964, President Johnson signed the Kennedy Tax Cut Bill.
Increased revenues, as always, poured into the treasury from the expanding
economy. Wanniski notes that the stock market slid up steadily until February 9,
1966. (29)

"1965...," Hechler writes, "was a banner year." Early in 1966, however, funding
for future planning and post-Apollo programs were severely slashed by the
Bureau of the Budget. (31)
"Instead of recommending return of the (revenue) surpluses via further rate
reductions, Republicans watched in dismay as Johnson Democrats not only
spent revenues in hand, but also committed anticipated future receipts to Great
Society’s spending programs," Wanniski writes. (32) "In the Decade 1964 to
1974, not a single Republican advocated tax-rate reductions. Instead, as Great
Society and Vietnam spending increased in 1966, the Republican leadership
pressured Johnson into proposing a 10% surtax on personal incomes in March of
‘66." (33).

During NASA authorization debates on the House floor on May 3, 1966,


Congressman Olin Teague said, "The war in Vietnam has already forced a
substantial reduction in the NASA budget for the coming fiscal year. "Fortunately,
however, thanks to our abundance of resources, it has not yet forced us to
abandon our goals and our national requirements in space." (34).

Hechler writes that the "... budget for NASA had already passed its peak, and it
was touch and go whether the spending plateau could be maintained high
enough to enable a successful moon landing by the end of the decade." (35).

"Camelot" was beginning to stall, in July of 1966, when the House science
committee published the results of its future planning studies under the title of
"Future National Space Objectives." Hechler notes, "The most important single
recommendation made in the committee report was the opening gun which the
committee fired in support of the space shuttle." (36).

Stall Warning: Budget Cuts Kill

Less than one year after Johnson's surtax (March ‘66), an accidental fire claimed
the lives of astronauts Virgil "Gus" Grissom, Edward White, and Roger Chaffee
on January 27, 1967. Hechler reports that NASA was "stunned" by
Congressman Teague's initial reaction to the NASA Review Board report on the
cause of this accident. (37).

"On the opening day of the committee hearing (at Cape Kennedy on April 21,
1967) Science Committee members clashed with (NASA's) Webb over his
allegation that appropriation cuts had caused the deficiencies which the Board of
Review pointed out," Hechler writes. ‘(Congressman) Daddario, in particular,
documented the fact that there was no evidence to bear this out, and
furthermore, that the most severe reductions had occurred at the Bureau of the
Budget level." (38)

"The high-water mark for NASA appropriations had been reached in calendar
year 1964," Hechler notes, “... when NASA was furnished with $5.25 billion, and
ever since then (as of 1979) the funds have dwindled every year." (39).
Following the successful Moon landing, on July 20, 1969, surtax "stalls" (and the
budget cuts that almost inevitably follow) have slowed aerospace developments
to a crawl. Tight budget constraints (Design to Cost Approach) create very tight
safety margins: additional funds taxed out from under private-sector contractors
seem to sharply increase the possibility of an operational mission problem.

It seems less than coincidental that a broad spectrum of orbital hardware,


ranging from large manned vehicles like Apollo, down to smaller vehicles, like
Vought's Scout; seem to show a lower operational success rates following
periods of tax hikes, and/or budget cuts. (Figure 2) Extra quality-assurance
might well prove cost-effective during periods of overtaxation.

Capitol Reformation: Freedom Works

Recent changes in the tax code, have given the IRS vastly expanded powers to
police returns of "... the millions who each year cheat the government out of
estimated $90 billion of taxes on some $250 billion of undeclared income,"
according to a Newsweek article, dated April 11, 1983. "The IRS estimates that
15% of all dividends and 11% of interest income are never declared." Newsweek
reports that, starting this month, bar and restaurant owners are required to
withhold taxes on tips declared by their employees; the IRS says, "... short of
criminals, waiters and bartenders are the most chronic under reporters of
income." (40).

Tax evasion problems in 1924 with a specific economic problem that the Mellon
tax rate cuts were designed to solve. Mellon knew that fairly taxed upper-
incomes (on dividends and interest, for example) would obviously yield far
greater revenues than any nationwide crackdown on tips from "outlaw waiters."
Mellon Bill supporters perceived that, then as now, when tax rates become too
high-the wealthy simply stop paying. (Figures 3 and 4).

"It is, of course, impossible to accurately determine what rate of tax (a) taxpayer
will submit to, rather than (to) avail himself of means of evasion. But experience
has demonstrated very clearly that a 50% surtax cannot be collected, and that it
results in a steadily diminishing revenue.... it becomes clear beyond dispute that
we would actually collect more at a low rate upon a broad base then at the
present high rate upon an extremely restricted and steadily narrowing one,"
according to a New York Times article from 1924, in support of the Mellon plan.
(41) The historic results of commercial aviation, from 1924-29 seem to verify that
Mellon's plan was economic advice worth listening to.

The article noted, "The only way that the income tax as applied to large incomes
can be made an actuality, and not a pretense is by reducing the rate of tax to a
sound level, thus lessening the incentive to taxpayers to avoid the tax."
"The present rates interfere with the normal course of business and credit, and
so, indirectly affects the great mass of the people who do not pay income taxes.
A sound tax is one that can be collected with a minimum of economic
disturbance. The income tax today does not conform to this rule."

"We have noted the unfortunate effect upon revenue collections occasioned by
the disappearance of taxable income under the pressure of higher rates. There
are, however, other consequences arising from this avoidance of taxes, which, if
they cannot be actually measured, should not be minimized. If the capital
normally available for new investment in productive enterprise is diverted to
unnecessary governmental expenditure under the stimulus of the tax-exempt
privilege, an artificial restriction has been placed upon economic development."

"In addition, the cost of production and distribution has been adversely affected
by increasing the interest rate on capital actively employed. When men refuse to
put their capital to its most productive use, because the risk appears too great in
view of the limitation by taxation of profits; when, rather than divide with the
government, they fail to take actual realizable profits, and so slow up the turnover
of liquid assets; when the first instead of the last question to be considered in any
new business transaction is that of taxes -- then there are foreign forces at work
in the economic field, which, if incalculable, are unquestionably potent...."

"Finally, while taxes on net profits or not, as a general rule, passed on, this
general observation is subject to modification. The effort will always be made to
pass on a tax, and when conditions are favorable, it will succeed....one fact is
undeniable. Any influence which high taxes exert on the price structure must be
in an upward direction; and this is true, whether they are actually paid or whether,
in order to evade them, business and credit are diverted from their normal
channels." (42)

Frontier Economics: "Expectations Rise."

Economies grow only through increased freedom, not legislative control. Lower
individual tax rates motivate individuals to produce by allowing them to keep
more of what they earn. Technological progress is neither the result of
governmental good intentions, or even massive corporations: only inventors
invent. In 1924, several professional organizations actively endorsed the Mellon
plan. (Appendix A.).

In the 1960s, it wasn't massive government spending that got us to the moon.
Congressman Teague's, "... abundance of resources," were generated by private
enterprises, and efficiently invested private venture capital, generated by
comparatively reasonable tax rates.

Thomas Paine, in Common Sense, forewarned frontier Americans of 1776, "as to


government matters,... the business of it will soon be too weighty and intricate to
be managed with any tolerable degree of convenience by a power so distant
from us, and so very ignorant of us;...waiting four or five months for an answer,
which, when obtained, requires five or six more to explain it in, will in a few years
be looked upon as folly and childishness -- there was a time when it was proper,
and there is a proper time for it to cease." The American Revolution was,
(naturally) a revolt against British war taxes. Mercantilism, then and now, moved
far too slowly to keep up with an open frontier.

Malthus was wrong. Mankind has access to "second worlds": we need no longer
fear growth. The Malthusian population to resource growth ratio need not remain
a fraction – “War Taxes” seem to be the mysterious, cyclical force that historically
retards the rate of growth of mankind's resources. Perhaps Wanniski has
discovered a "universal history".

Dr. Laffer offers an excellent "navigational plot" for reengineering frontier


economic growth. "I would like to see taxes in real terms, not just schedules. I
would like to see them as they were in 1965....," Laffer said. (43) (figure 5),
Private Enterprise in Space "will never fly" without another tax cut. America, and
the aerospace industry deserve "Rising Expectations". A healthy growing world
badly needs a little extra room.

References

(1) Wanniski, Jude. The way the world works, New York: Basic Books. (1978),
p. 288.
(2) Knowlton, Hugh. Air Transportation in the United States, Chicago: University
of Chicago press (1941) p. 2
(3) Knowlton, pp. 1-4.
(4) Wanniski, p. 100.
(5) Halsey, Francis Whiting. History of the world war, New York: Funk and
Wagnalls Co. (1919) volume VI, p.406.
(6) Wanniski, p. 119
(7) Wanniski, pp. 120-122.
(8) Wanniski, p. 119.
(9) American People's Encyclopedia, New York: Grolier Incorporated (1968) p.
329, Vol. 12
(10) Wanniski, p. 122.
(11) Knowlton, p. 4.
(12) Knowlton, pp 4-5.
(13) Knowlton, p.5.
(14) Knowlton, p. 8.
(15) Wanniski, p. 150.
(16) Wanniski, p. 125.
(17) Knowlton, p. 8.
(18), Knowlton, pp. 8-9.
(19) Wanniski, p. 141
(20) Knowlton, p. 8.
(21) Knowlton, p. 11.
(22) Dornberger, Walter. V-2 New York: Bantam Books (1979) p. 290.
(23) Dornberger, p. 21.
(24) Dornberger, p. 20.
(25) Hechler, Ken; Toward the Endless Frontier, Washington: Government
Printing Office (1980)p. 171
(26) ibid
(27) Hechler, p. 170.
(28) Hechler, p. 179
(29) Wanniski, p. 201
(30) Hechler, p. 184
(31) Hechler, p. 190
(32) Wanniski, p. 214.
(33) Wanniski, p. 215.
(34) Hechler, pp. 192-193.
(35) Hechler, p. 193.
(36) Hechler,p. 191.
(37) Hechler, p. 196
(38) Hechler, p. 197.
(39) Hechler, p. 208.
(40) Newsweek, April 11, 1983, p. 54.
(41) New York Times, February 12, 1924, p. 12
(42) ibid
(43) UPI, September 23, 1981
Appendix A.: United Professions, 1924

organizations representing more than 500,000 professional men in the United


States have joined forces to endorse and support the Mellon tax reduction plan
from a non--partisan point of view. At a meeting yesterday in the rooms of the
American Society of mechanical engineers. Their representatives adopted
resolutions to this effect.

The new society is called the national organization for professional cooperation.
Professional societies represented at the meeting included the American
dramatists, the actors equity, American chemical Society, American Institute of
chemical engineers, American Medical Association, American Society of authors,
composers and publishers, artists Guild and the authors league of America. It's
also stated the representatives of other organizations were present. I could not
take formal part in the movement as yet, because the constitutions of their
organizations required action at annual meetings or had similar restrictions on
immediate actions.

Among organizations not listed but said to have expressed sympathy with the
general purpose of the meeting were the American Bar Association, the American
Society of mechanical engineers, American Society of civil engineers....

the meeting adopted the following resolution:

"resolved, that the national organization for professional cooperation approved


and endorsed in principle to build advocated by the Secretary of the treasury for
the revision of income taxes, and respectfully urge upon the Congress of the
United States. Its immediate passage.

"Resolve, that is professional workers, we hereby go on record as insisting that


tax relief be considered from a wholly non--partisan point. Indeed, as a measure
of immediate economic necessity and justice.

"Resolve, that we hereby extend an invitation to all national societies of


professional men and women to cooperate with us... not"

the general attitude of professional interest toward income tax laws in general,
and the Mellon plan in particular, was outlined in a statement by the chairman,
Owen Johnson, given out in connection with the meeting. "This new movement
grew out of the fact that we as professional workers of the country, when the
most important proposals affecting our interests are being discussed down in
Washington, have no organized body to protect our interests," said Mr. Johnson.
We felt the first thing to do was to back a plan which not only struck us as
eminently non-partisan, practical and farsighted, but to emphasize and
somebody that would give his solidarity to the interests of the professional
workers of this country. A grateful appreciation of the recognition that there
should be a total differentiation between earned and unearned income.

As soon as we got together we've realized that there were many very serious
distinctions weighing a particularly heavy upon the professional workers and,
while we felt it our duty to accept the Mellon tax plan as outlined as the best
immediate practical remedy to the abusive taxation, we decided that there were
very important recommendations, which should be made before another tax
program was submitted to the country and protection of the interests of the
professional workers in particular and the great body who earn their incomes in
general.

While capital and labor have been generally represented here to four and similar
class hearings at Washington, the professional workers alone have taken no
steps adequately to present their cases to Congress; but we feel the time is now
her rise when our national representatives should give consideration to this
professional group, which occupies an equally important part in our social,
industrial and economic world...."

Quote Source: New York Times, February 13, 1924; p. 3

Mellon's Medicine: Hard Times for Hitler

(the years from 1925 until the coming of the Depression in 1929 were lean years
for Adolf Hitler and the Nazi movement.... he was confident that the good times
would not last. So far as Germany was concerned, he said, they depended not
on her own strength on that of others-of America, above all, from whose swollen
coffers. Loans were pouring in to make and keep Germany prospers. Between
1924 in 1930 German borrowing managed some $7 billion, and most of it came
from American investors, who gave little thought to how the Germans might make
eventual repayment. The Germans gave even less thought.... its output, which in
1923 had dropped to 55% of that in 1913, rose 222% by 1927. For the first time
since the war, unemployment fell below a million-to 650,019 28. That year.
Retail sales were up 20% over 1925 and the next year. Real wages reached a
figure 10% higher than four years before. The lower middle classes, all the
millions of shopkeepers and small-salaried folk on whom Hitler had to draw for
his mass support, shared in the general prosperity." (Page 117).

"... on October 24, the stock market and Wall Street crashed. Results in
Germany were soon felt-and disastrously. The cornerstone of German prosperity
had been loans from abroad, principally from America, and world trade. When
the flow of loans dried up and repayment on the old ones became due to German
financial structure was unable to stand the strain. When World Trade Center
following the general slump. Germany was unable to export enough to pay for
essential imports of the raw materials for food, which she needed. Without
exports, German industry could not keep its plants going, and its production fell
by almost half from 1929-1932." (Page 136).

"The depression which spread over the world like a great conflagration toward
the end of 1929 gave Adolf Hitler his opportunity, and he made the most of it.
Like most great revolutionaries, he could thrive only an evil times. At first when
the masses were unemployed, hungry and desperate, and later when they were
intoxicated by war." (Page 135).

Quote source: Shirer, William L., the rise and fall of the Third Reich; New York.
Simon & Schuster, 1960.

"... not in time of war, finances, like all else, must yield to national defense and
preservation. In time of peace, finances, like all else, should minister to the
general welfare. Immediately upon my taking office he was determined, after
conference with Secretary Mellon, that the Treasury Department should study the
possibility of tax reduction for the purpose of securing relief to all taxpayers of the
country and emancipating business from unreasonable and hampering
exactions. The result was the proposed bill, which is now pending before the
Congress. It is doubtful if any measure ever received more generous testimony
of approval. Opposition has appeared to some of its details, but to the policy of
immediate and drastic reduction of taxes, so arranged as to benefit all classes
and all kinds of business, there has been the most general approbation.

"These recommendations have been made by the treasury as the expert advisor
of the government. They follow, in their main principle of a decrease in high
surtax is, which is only another name for war taxes, the views of the two
preceding secretaries of the treasury, most of them Democrats have pronounced
ability. They are nonpartisan, well thought out and sound. They carry out the
policy of reducing the taxes of every body, especially people of moderate income.
They give to the country almost $1 million every working day.

"The proposed bill maintains the fixed policy of rates graduated in proportion to
the ability to pay. That policy has received almost universal sanction. It
sustained by sound arguments based on economic, social and moral grounds.
But in taxation, like everything else, it's necessary to test a theory by practical
results. The first object of taxation is to secure revenue. When the taxation of
large incomes is approached with us and view the problem is to find a rate which
will produce the largest returns. Experienced is not show that the higher rate
produces the larger revenues. Experiences all the other way. When the surtax
rate on incomes of $300,000 was but 10%, the revenue was about the same as it
was at 65%.

"There is no escaping the fact that when the taxation of large incomes is
excessive. They tend to disappear. In 1916, there were 206 incomes of $1
million or more. Then the high tax rate went into effect. The next year there
were only 141, and in 1918 at 67. In 1919 the number declined to 65. In 1920.
It fell to 33, and in 1921 it was further reduced to 21. I am not making any
argument with a man who believes the 55% ought to be taken away from the
million-dollar income, or 68% from a $5 million incomes; but when it is
considered any effort to get these amounts. We are rapidly approaching the
point of getting nothing at all. It is necessary to look for more practical method.
That can be done only by reduction of the high surtax is, when viewed solely as a
revenue proposition, to about 25%.

"I agree perfectly with those who wish to relieve the small taxpayer by getting the
largest possible contribution from the people with large incomes. But if the rates
on large incomes are so high that they disappeared. The small taxpayer will be
left to bear the entire burden. If, on the other hand, the rates are placed with a
will produce the most revenue from large incomes, and the small taxpayer will be
relieved. The experience of the Treasury Department and the opinion of the best
experts place the rate which collect most from the people of great wealth, that's
giving the largest relief to people of moderate wealth, at not over 25%.

"A very important social and economic question is also involved in high tax rates.
That's the result taxation has upon national development. Our progress in that
direction depends upon two factors personal ability surplus income. An
expanding prosperity requires that the largest possible amount of surplus income
should be invested in productive enterprises under the direction of the best
personal ability. This will not be done if the rewards of such action are very
largely taken away by taxation.

"If we had attacks whereby on the first working day the government took 5% of
your wages, on the second day 10%, on the third day 20%, on the fourth day
30%, on the fifth day 50%, and on the six Day 60%, how many of you would
continue to work on the last two days of the week? It is the same with capital.
Surplus income will go into tax-exempt securities. It will refuse to take the risk
incidental to embarking in business. This will raise the rate which establish
business will have to pay for new capital, and result in a marked increase in the
cost of living. If new capital will not flow into competing enterprise. The present
concerns tend towards monopoly, increasing again, the prices which the people
must pay.

"The high prices paid and low prices received on the farm are directly do our
unsound method of taxation. I shall illustrate by a simple example: a farmer ship
to steer to Chicago. His tax, attacks on the rare road transporting the animal,
and of the yards were the animal is old, going to the price of the animal to the
Packer. The Packers tax goes into the price of the hide to the New England shoe
manufacturer. The manufactures tax goes into the price to the retailer, who in
turn adds his tax in his price to his purchaser. So maybe said that if the farmer
ultimately wears the she's he pays everybody's taxes from the farm to his feet.
"It's for this reason that high taxes mean a high price level, and a high price level
in its turn means difficulty in meeting world competition. Most of all, the farmer
suffers from the effect of this high price level. In what he buys he meets
domestic costs of high taxes and the high price level. And what he sells he
meets world competition with a low price level. It's essential, therefore, for the
good of all the people as a whole that we pay not so much attention to the tax
paid directly by a certain number of the taxpayers, but we must devote our efforts
to relieving the tax paid indirectly by the whole people.

"Taken altogether, I think it's easy enough to see that I wish to include in the
program. A reduction in the high surtax rates, not the small incomes may be
required to pay less, but that more revenue may be secured from large incomes
in taxes on small incomes may be reduced; not because I wish to relieve the
wealthy, but because I wish to relieve the country got...

"that's the tax measure which has been proposed, and which has my support.
Because I wish to give to all the people all the relief which it contains, I'm
opposed to material alteration and compromise. It's about as far removed as
anything could be from any kind of partisanship. At least, I do not charge if there
is any party or any responsible party leadership that admits it is opposed to
making taxes low and in favor of keeping taxes high. Let the actions and
proposals of some are liable to have just that result. I stand on the simple
proposition that the country is entitled to all the relief from the burden of taxation,
which it's possible to give. The proposed measures gives such relief. Other
measures which have been brought forward do not meet this requirement.

"They had the appearance of an indirect attempt to defeat good measure with a
bad measure. You've heard much of the Garner plan. Brought forward to have
something different, it's purported to relieve the greatest number of taxpayers.
He gave not the slightest heed to the indirect effect of high taxes, or to the
approaching drying up of the source of revenue and consequent failures of the
progress they've income tax, or to the destruction of business initiative. It is
political, in theory. When the effect of its provisions was estimated, it meant a
loss of revenue beyond any expected surplus. It is impossible in practice. The
people will not be misled by such proposals. It's entirely possible to have a first-
class bill. I want the country to have the best there is, I am for it because it will
reduce taxes on all classes of income. I am for it because it will encourage
business. I am for it because it will decrease the cost of living. I am for it
because it is economically, socially, and morally sound.

"But the people must understand this is their fight. They alone can win it. Unless
they make their wishes known to the Congress without regard to party. This bill
will not pass. I urge them to renewed efforts...."

source: New York Times, February 13, 1924, page 2. Partial text of speech
delivered on February 12, 1924, by President Calvin Coolidge.

Das könnte Ihnen auch gefallen