Sie sind auf Seite 1von 17

No.

420 December 13, 2001

Limiting Government through


Direct Democracy
The Case of State Tax and Expenditure Limitations
by Michael J. New

Executive Summary

Defenders of individual freedom and limited prehensive data set of state government spending
government have often favored representative shows that TELs enacted by citizen initiatives
government over direct democracy. Since 1978, cause per capita public spending to decrease; TELs
however, activists have proposed and passed ini- enacted by state legislatures are associated with an
tiatives limiting taxing and spending by state increase in government expenditures.
governments in the United States. State legisla- Some TELs are more effective at limiting gov-
tures have occasionally imposed tax and expen- ernment than others. TELs that limit govern-
diture limitations (TELs) on themselves. ment spending to the inflation rate plus popula-
TELs passed by initiative are more restrictive tion growth and mandate immediate rebates of
and contain fewer loopholes than those enacted government surpluses are more effective at limit-
by state legislatures. Regression analysis of a com- ing government outlays than are other TELs.

_____________________________________________________________________________________________________
Michael J. New, a Ph.D. candidate at Stanford University, was a data analyst and research assistant at the Cato
Institute in 2001.
Initiatives can be tion, discord, and a violent death of the polit-
an effective tool Introduction ical association.
Madison thought the new American Republic
for limiting Direct democracy is on the rise again in overcame the ills of pure democracy. In part, his
government. the United States. Since 1978 the initiative confidence came from the scope of the American
has been used more and more in the 24 states Republic: by including more people and interests
that permit direct legislation by voters. 1 In in the nation, the Constitution made it harder for
California, for example, 9 voter initiatives dangerous majorities to form. Madison praised
made it to the ballot in the 1960s; 22 made it also the representative character of the new
in the 1970s, 45 in the 1980s, and 62 in the Constitution. Delegating power to legislators
1990s. In the 1996 general election, American would “refine and enlarge” public opinion, there-
voters were confronted with more than 90 by avoiding majority tyranny and perhaps attain-
statewide initiatives, plus an estimated 200 ing higher goals: “It may well happen that the
local initiatives and referenda on environ- public voice pronounced by the representatives of
mental and land-use issues alone.2 As infor- the people, will be more consonant to the public
mation technology develops, direct and good, than if pronounced by the people them-
immediate rule by the people may become a selves convened for the purpose.”4
real possibility. The Progressives turned to the initiative
Proponents of individual liberty and limit- because they rejected both Madison’s belief in
ed government have traditionally been skepti- representative institutions and his desire for
cal about direct rule by a majority of voters. limited government. They thought that, far
The reasons for that skepticism can be found from refining and enlarging public opinion,
in The Federalist Papers and in the Progressive legislatures “enact[ed] laws for the special
Era’s push for bigger government through advantage of a few and refuse[d] to enact laws
direct democracy. The revival of direct democ- for the welfare of the many.”5 Progressives saw
racy began, however, with a 1978 California direct legislation as a way to bypass corrupt
initiative to reduce property taxes, the famous legislatures and to expand the ambit of gov-
Proposition 13 put on the ballot by Howard ernment. Benjamin Parke DeWitt in 1915 said
Jarvis and Paul Gann.3 Many subsequent suc- Progressives share “the rapidly growing con-
cessful initiatives imposed tax and expendi- viction that the functions of government are
ture limitations (TELs) on state governments. too restricted and that they must be increased
This paper will show that initiatives can be an and extended to relieve social and economic
effective tool for limiting government. Theory distress.”6 Progressives expected the initiative
notwithstanding, direct democracy seems to to weaken corrupt politicians, empower the
be a good friend of liberty in some cases. people, and thereby expand government to
reform society. The initiative was instrumental
for attaining their larger goal of expanding
Legislatures or the People? government.
Government did expand enormously dur-
James Madison had little faith in pure ing the 20th century, but economic crisis and
democracy, “a Society, consisting of a small war, not the initiative, were the most impor-
number of citizens, who assemble and tant factors driving its growth.7 With govern-
administer the Government in person.” He ment growth came more and higher taxes at
believed that direct democracy meant a all levels of government. Harry Hopkins’ dic-
tyranny of a majority over minorities, the rule tum “tax and tax, spend and spend, elect and
of passion over reason. Pure democracy is elect” became the practical wisdom of
thus “incompatible with personal security, or America’s political class.
the rights of property.” The direct rule of the In 1978 Proposition 13 in California tried to
people, Madison concluded, ended in fac- change that. The initiative concerned mostly

2
property taxes, which had been rising 30 per- Writers on the left have also lamented the
cent annually in California in the 1970s. It lim- restraints on taxation brought by initiatives
ited the assessed value of property, increases in and suggested that the traditional American
assessed property value, and the tax rate for skepticism of government has become “an
property. The proposition also required a unhealthy distrust.”13
supermajority in the legislature to raise proper- This brief history provides defenders of lim-
ty tax rates. At the time, experts thought that ited government no clear guidance about initia-
the initiative would cut government revenue by tives. James Madison’s concerns about majority
$7 billion in 1978–79. Approximately 69 per- rule and his aspirations for representative
cent of registered voters turned out in a June democracy are persuasive, especially consider-
primary for Proposition 13; 65 percent of them ing the Progressive hope to expand government
voted in its favor.8 through direct democracy. Yet the initiative
Like the Progressives, the originators of movement has done much to revive hopes for
Proposition 13 believed the California legis- limited government in the states.
lature and state government in general had This study informs the larger debate by
ignored the desires of citizens. They may have offering an empirical analysis of the effects of
been correct. A contemporary public opinion initiatives in the states. The evidence shows
poll showed that all subgroups of that initiatives have been more effective than Proposition 13
Californians supported Proposition 13, with state legislatures at limiting the growth of reflected the will
the exception of blacks and “strong liberals.” state and local government spending. That of a broad major-
The legislature had not responded to the experience points to some recommendations
broad-based desire for lower property taxes, for activists seeking to limit government ity of voters in
though it did pass a property tax cut after through the initiative. California in
Proposition 13 reached the ballot.9 In retro-
spect, Proposition 13 reflected the will of a 1978.
broad majority of voters in California in Do TELs Work?
1978, a desire ignored by the state legislators.
As tax cutters warmed to the idea of direct During the tax revolt in the 1970s, a num-
rule of the people, the ideological heirs to ber of states adopted TELs as a mechanism
progressivism criticized the initiative. to limit the growth of government. TELs
Washington Post columnist David Broder place a limit on how much taxes, revenues, or
warned about the danger posed to represen- expenditures can increase in a state each year.
tative government by initiative campaigns.10 By 1982 TELs had been enacted in 17 states.
He lamented the power of money in initiative TEL enactment slowed along with the fervor
efforts and concluded that powerful and of the tax revolt in the prosperous 1980s;
wealthy special interests had taken over the only 3 states enacted TELs between 1983 and
initiative process. 11 Similarly, the liberal jour- 1990. However, during the early and mid-
nalist Peter Schrag noted: 1990s, TELs enjoyed a resurgence of sorts; by
1996, 6 additional states had enacted TELs.
In big states like California, it’s impos- Currently, 26 states operate under some kind
sible to even get to the table without $1 of TEL (Table 1).
million or more to pay the lawyers, Many people have questioned the effective-
consultants, media experts, and, most ness of TELs. Some argue that loopholes and
important, the signature collectors. accounting tricks will inevitably limit the abil-
Conversely, the political consultants ity of these measures to reduce government
who run initiative campaigns also spending.14 Others say that TELs’ lack of sanc-
guarantee that with enough money tions for noncompliance raises serious ques-
behind it, almost any measure can at tions about their enforceability. Several stud-
least qualify for the ballot.12 ies that analyze the impact of TELs on state

3
Table 1
State Tax and Expenditure Limits, 1976–96
Immediate Expenditures Held to
Refunds of Inflation Rate
State Year Passed Surpluses Plus Population Growth

TELs Enacted through Citizen Initiatives

Michigan 1978 Yes No


California 1979 a No No
Washington 1979 No No
Missouri 1980 Yes No
Massachusetts 1986 No No
Colorado 1992 Yes Yes
Washington 1993 No Yes

TELs Passed by State Legislatures

New Jersey 1976 b No No


Colorado 1977 No No
Louisiana 1979 No No
Oregon 1979 Yes No
Idaho 1980 No No
Montana 1981 No No
Utah 1989 No No
New Jersey 1990 No No
Colorado 1991 No No
North Carolina 1991 No No
Iowa 1992 No No
Mississippi 1992 No No

TELs Enacted through Constitutional Conventions

Hawaii 1978 No No
Tennessee 1978 No No

TELs Enacted through Referenda

Arizona 1978 No No
Delaware 1978 No No
Texas 1978 No No
South Carolina 1980 No No
Alaska 1982 No Yes
Oklahoma 1985 No No
Louisiana 1993 No No
Connecticut 1992 No No
Rhode Island 1992 No No
Florida 1994 No No

Source: Mandy Rafool, “State Tax and Expenditure Limits,” National Conference of State Legislatures Legislative
Finance Paper no. 104, 1996, p. 6.

Notes: The TEL that New Jersey passed in 1976 and the TEL that Colorado passed in 1977 are included even though
neither appears in the 1996 NCSL survey. In addition, the TEL that Nevada passed in 1979 is excluded because it
applies only to the governor’s budget proposal, not actual spending and taxing. Referenda differ from initiatives.
Citizens and interest groups can place initiatives directly on the ballot for voter approval. Referenda must be approved
by the state legislature before they appear on the ballot.
a New Jersey’s first TEL expired in 1983.
b In 1979 California passed a TEL that limited per capita appropriations of state tax revenues to the inflation rate.
However, this limit did not pertain to total state expenditures. Additionally, this limit was increased in 1988.

4
budgetary outcomes argue that these mea- make sure a TEL contained loopholes so that TELs passed by
sures do not have a statistically significant they would be able to avoid cutting popular initiative do
influence on state expenditures. programs in the long term.
Those studies, however, have three main Conversely, fiscal discipline measures passed restrain spending
shortcomings. First, the studies often examine by citizen initiative should be more effective in and taxing and
a small number of states15 for a short time, limiting state spending. Such initiatives would
sometimes as little as a year.16 It is difficult to likely be drafted by groups interested in reduc-
are more effective
draw conclusions from a limited sample; in ing spending and would be less likely to contain than those passed
any case, the effects of TELs may become loopholes that would benefit elected officials. by legislatures.
apparent only over an extended time. Second, TELs enacted by initiative should serve as an
the existing studies of TELs often do not take external constraint on legislatures. Indeed,
into account all the factors affecting a state’s TELs passed by initiative do restrain spending
budget.17 Third, previous work does not take and taxing and are more effective than those
into account the differences among TELs.18 passed by legislatures.
Some TELs limit taxes, some expenditures;
some have strict limits, others looser ceilings
including waiver provisions; some are statuto- Why the Initiative
ry, others constitutional. Analyzing the vari- Is Effective
ous features of TELs might well inform future
efforts to limit spending and taxing. An examination of the characteristics of
Table 1 shows that more than two-thirds various TELs suggests why TELs passed by
of current TELs were enacted either by initia- citizen initiative might be more effective than
tive or by a state legislature. A comparison of those passed by legislatures. This can be seen
TELs enacted by initiative with those enacted in four ways. First, TELs differ in the sorts of
by state legislatures might prove instructive. limits they set on revenues and expenditures
Public choice analysis would suggest that leg- (Table 2). A vast majority of the TELs that
islators lack the incentive to constrain their have been passed in this country hold
own behavior. They might pass some kind of increases in expenditures or revenues to
fiscal discipline measure to claim credit in growth in personal income. However, a small
the short term. However, legislators would number of states have adopted TELs that

Table 2
Limits TELs Impose on Spending and Revenue

Method of Enactment

Citizen Initiative Legislative Vote


Limit (7 TELs) (12 TELs)

Inflation rate
plus population
growth 2 (29%) 0 (0%)
Income growth 5 (71%) 5 (42%)
Other 0 (0%) 7 (58%)

Source: Author’s calculations based on Mandy Rafool, “State Tax and Expenditure Limits,” National
Conference of State Legislatures Legislative Finance Paper no. 104, 1996, pp. 28–33.

5
have more stringent limitations; they hold likely to include provisions that mandate
increases in spending or revenue to the infla- automatic changes in the limits when
tion rate plus population growth. Table 1 responsibility for government programs is
clearly indicates that TELs passed by initia- transferred.
tive are more likely to contain this more Another structural difference between
stringent limitation. Twenty-nine percent of TELs that are passed by legislatures and
the TELs passed by initiative hold increases those that are passed by initiative involves
in spending or revenues to the inflation rate whether the TELs are constitutional or statu-
plus population growth, while none of the tory (Table 4). Constitutional TELs should
TELs enacted by legislatures do. be more effective than statutory TELs
The second important difference between because they are more difficult to change.
TELs passed by legislatures and those passed Statutory TELs leave open the possibility
by citizen initiative concerns transferring that the legislature will change the definition
government responsibilities. One frequent of the item limited, often by excluding cer-
method of circumventing the limits estab- tain areas of spending or revenue. In other
lished by a TEL is to devolve various func- cases, the legislators can simply increase the
tions of government to the localities. limit. By definition, all TELs passed by legis-
TELs passed by Although this practice may keep the state latures are statutory. However, 56 percent of
initiative are more budget within the limits of the TEL, it will TELs passed by citizen initiative are constitu-
stringent than result in budget increases at the local level tional. This provides further evidence that
and will fail to effectively limit overall taxing TELs passed by initiative are more stringent
those enacted by or spending. However, some TELs include than those enacted by legislatures.
legislatures. provisions that would remedy this problem. The final structural difference between
They include a provision that would man- TELs that are enacted by legislatures and
date automatic reductions in the limit when- TELs that are passed through citizen initia-
ever a state devolves a function of govern- tives is their provisions for handling surplus-
ment to the localities (Table 3). Elected offi- es. Most TELs mandate that surpluses go
cials would have no incentive to circumvent into a reserve fund or call for taxpayer rebates
TELs though devolution in states where such only if surpluses persist for a number of
provisions were in place. As can be seen from years. However, a limited number of TELs
Table 3, TELs passed by initiative are more require that all surplus revenues, above a crit-

Table 3
TELs and Their Provisions for Changing Their Limits: Does Limit Automatically
Change When Responsibility for Government Programs Is Transferred?

Method of Enactment

Citizen Initiative Legislative Vote


Change (7 TELS) (12 TELs)

Yes 5 (71%) 4 (33%)

No 2 (29%) 8 (67%)

Source: Author’s calculations based on Mandy Rafool, “State Tax and Expenditure Limits,” National Conference
of State Legislatures Legislative Finance Paper no. 104, 1996, pp. 28–33.

6
Table 4
Legal Status of TELs

Method of Enactment

Citizen Initiative Legislative Vote


Legal Status (7 TELs) (12 TELs)

Constitutional 4 (56%) 0 (0%)

Statutory 3 (44%) 12 (100%)

Source: Author’s calculations from Mandy Rafool, “State Tax and Expenditure Limits,” National
Conference of State Legislatures Legislative Finance Paper no. 104, 1996, pp. 28–33.

ical threshold, be immediately returned to immediate taxpayer refunds (Table 5). TELs passed by
the taxpayers in the form of tax credits. TELs From the analysis above, it appears that citizen initiative
requiring such refunds make it difficult for TELs that are passed by citizen initiative are are more likely to
state governments to generate revenues that likely to possess a variety of structural fea-
exceed the limit and give taxpayers and tures that render them more effective than have provisions
watchdog groups a greater incentive to see TELs passed by legislatures. The next step that mandate
that TELs are enforced. Once again, we see will be to empirically test whether initiative
that TELs passed by citizen initiative are TELs are more effective by analyzing the rele-
immediate tax-
more likely to have provisions that mandate vant budgetary data. payer refunds.

Table 5
TELs and Their Provisions for Handing Surpluses

Method of Enactment

Provision Citizen Initiative Legislative Vote


for Refund (7 TELs) (12 TELs)

Immediate
taxpayer refunds 3 (44%) 1 (8%)
taxpayer refunds not
immediate 4 (56%) 11 (92%)

Source: Author’s calculations based on Mandy Rafool, “State Tax and Expenditure Limits,” National Conference
of State Legislatures Legislative Finance Paper no. 104, 1996, pp. 28–33.

Note: This provision varies in stringency. Colorado’s TEL mandates that all revenues above the limits be returned
to the taxpayers. Missouri’s and Michigan’s require that revenues exceeding the limit by 1 percent be refunded to
taxpayers. Oregon’s TEL requires that excess revenues above 2 percent of the forecast be returned to the taxpay-
ers. Oregon, whose refund provision is the least restrictive of the four, is the state that passed its TEL by legisla-
tive vote.

7
Per capita state by a constitutional convention, or by referen-
and local expendi- Analysis dum.21 This will allow me to determine if TELs
passed by citizen initiative are indeed more
tures will decrease The empirical test of effectiveness of initia- effective at limiting the growth of spending
by $16.29 every tive TELs involves a regression analysis of a new than are TELs enacted by state legislatures.
data set that includes budgetary data from 49 The results of my analysis can be found in
year after a state of the United States for every fiscal year from the Appendix to this paper as Regression 1.
has passed a 1972 through 1996, inclusive.19 Regression This regression lends support to my hypoth-
TEL by citizen analysis allows us to examine the effects of var- esis. The regression explains over 41 percent
ious factors on the central concern of this of the variation in the dependent variable,
initiative. paper, the level of spending at the state and state and local spending. From the regression
local level. Regression analysis allows us to sort results, we see that increases in the percent-
out the effects of a single variable by holding age of state residents aged 5 to 17 lead to
constant the effects of all other variables. increases in per capita state and local direct
Annual per capita state and local direct general expenditures. This finding is statisti-
general expenditures in constant 1996 dollars cally significant.22 In addition, as a state’s real
will be used as the dependent variable in this per capita personal income grows and as its
regression analysis.20 I examine per capita state unemployment rate declines, there is evi-
and local direct general expenditures because dence that per capita state and local expendi-
doing so best demonstrates how TELs affect tures will decrease. Surprisingly, there is evi-
the amount that state and local governments dence that per capita expenditures decrease
spend on individual taxpayers. as the percentage of state residents over the
My regression analysis includes several age of 65 goes up. However, this finding fails
variables that might affect state and local to achieve statistical significance.
spending. Spending might go up, for exam- Of more interest in this study are the effects
ple, because a state experienced growth in its of the different kinds of TELs. These results are
population of young people who require summarized in Figure 1. The model predicts
more state services and hence more spend- that, if other factors are held constant, per capi-
ing. I have included a variable measuring ta state and local expenditures will decrease by
growth in the proportion of people between $16.29 every year after a state has passed a TEL
the ages of 5 and 17. Similarly, since the elder- by citizen initiative. Conversely, the model pre-
ly use state services at a disproportionately dicts that TELs enacted by state legislatures will
high rate, an aging population might put actually cause per capita expenditures to
upward pressure on the budget. Therefore, I increase by $14.00. This finding lends support to
have included a variable that measures the the hypothesis that TELs enacted by citizen ini-
growth in the percentage of people over the tiative are more effective at limiting state spend-
age of 65. It is also possible that increases in ing than are those passed into law by state leg-
population may place a strain on state ser- islatures.
vices and result in budgetary increases. Still, some TELs may be more effective
Hence a variable measuring state population than others. Perhaps the answer lies in the
growth is included as well. Finally, state provisions of the TELs themselves. Earlier I
spending may also increase because of an demonstrated that TELs passed by initiative
economic slowdown. Hence I include vari- are more likely to have properties that would
ables indicating each state’s growth in real make them more effective; however, not all
per capita personal income and the annual TELs passed by citizen initiative have those
change in each state’s unemployment rate. properties. If we can isolate TELs that have
I also include in the regression analysis four desirable properties, perhaps we can deter-
separate variables that indicate whether a state mine if a well-designed TEL can place even
has passed a TEL by initiative, by the legislature, further limits on state spending.

8
Figure 1
Effectiveness of TELs by Method of Enactment

30

24
25

20
InitiativeTEL: A TEL that is enacted by a citizen initiative
LegislativeTEL: A TEL that is enacted by a state legislature
15

10

-5

-10

-15
-16.29
-20
InitiativeTEL LegislativeTEL

Two Properties That and 1990 the ratio of state and local direct gen-
Strengthen TELs eral expenditures to personal income actually
fell in 27 of the 49 states considered in this
Property 1: Limiting the Growth of analysis.24 As a result, TELs that limit growth in
Expenditures and Revenues to the revenues and expenditures to the inflation rate
Inflation Rate Plus Population Growth plus population growth might be more effec-
An overwhelming majority of the TELs that tive at limiting state and local spending.
have been passed since 1976 limit growth in Refund provi-
state expenditures and revenues to state per- Property 2: Refunding Surpluses to
sonal income growth. However, two states, Taxpayers Immediately sions create a
Colorado and Washington, have recently enact- Another feature that is worth examining strong incentive
ed TELs that limit growth in state expenditures is the provision that mandates immediate for state legisla-
to the inflation rate plus population growth. refunds of any surpluses to the taxpayers.
This is a more stringent limit. Over the years the Thus far, four states (Colorado, Michigan, tors to cut taxes
rate of growth in personal income has been sig- Missouri, and Oregon) have enacted TELs when it appears
nificantly greater than the inflation rate. that mandate immediate refunds of revenues
Between 1980 and 1990 growth in real person- that exceed the limit established by the TEL.
that revenues are
al income exceeded the inflation rate plus pop- Three of those four TELs were passed going to exceed
ulation growth by more than 38 percentage through citizen initiatives; only one the limit.
points.23 It should also be noted that holding (Oregon’s) was enacted by the state legisla-
increases in expenditures to increases in per- ture. As indicated earlier in this paper, such a
sonal income, as most TELs do, sets a relatively provision would strengthen any TEL because
low limit for a state to maintain. Between 1980 it would make it difficult for the state gov-

9
TELs that limit ernment to collect or spend excess revenues. a TEL. From this regression it appears that
increases in In addition, it would give citizens and watch- TELs that limit increases in spending and
dog groups a greater incentive to see that the revenue to the inflation rate plus population
spending and provisions of the TEL were enforced. An growth have the most promise for reducing
revenue to the examination of the recent budgetary history spending. If a state passes a TEL that limits
of these four states indicates that such expenditures to the inflation rate plus popu-
inflation rate refund provisions enhance the effectiveness lation growth, the regression equation pre-
plus population of TELs in another way. Namely, they create a dicts that every year the TEL will reduce per
growth have the strong incentive for state legislators to cut capita state and local direct general expendi-
taxes when it appears that revenues are going tures by approximately $114.84. The t-statis-
most promise to exceed the limit. tic indicates that we can be more than 98 per-
for reducing If a state enacts a TEL that mandates cent confident that these TELs have a nega-
spending. immediate refunds of surplus revenues, state tive effect on state and local direct general
legislators have the option of allowing rev- expenditures. Likewise, if a state passes a TEL
enues to exceed the limit and then subse- that does not limit state expenditures to the
quently refunding the revenue. However, there inflation rate plus population growth but
are logistical and political problems with includes a refund provision, the regression
doing this. First, it is nearly impossible to equation predicts that the TEL will reduce
refund the sales tax. Also, although it is possi- per capita direct general expenditures by
ble to enact refunds of income or property $39.80 annually.
taxes, legislators dislike doing so. This is Finally, the regression analysis suggests
because high-income citizens would obtain a that other TELs that neither limit expendi-
high percentage of the refunds, and legislators tures to inflation nor have immediate refund
do not like to be charged with favoring the provisions appear ineffective at reducing
rich over everyone else. As a result, this creates state expenditures. The model predicts that if
a powerful incentive for legislators to cut taxes a state passes a TEL that has neither of these
so that revenues or expenditures will no longer two provisions, that state’s per capita direct
exceed the limit. Indeed, case studies indicate general expenditures will actually increase by
that Michigan, Missouri, and Colorado (three $14.59. Overall, this analysis provides strong
of the four states that mandate taxpayer evidence that TELs can be effective tools for
refunds) have enacted tax cuts in response to limiting the growth of state expenditures,
the prospect of having revenues exceed the but only if they are designed properly.
limit mandated by their TELs.25 Moreover, since state legislatures generally
To further study these provisions, I have lack incentives to constrain their own behav-
constructed another regression model. Once ior, TELs passed by citizen initiatives are far
again, the dependent variable is the annual more likely to contain the sorts of provisions
change in per capita state and local direct that are going to place effective limits on
general expenditures in 1996 dollars. The state spending.
analysis examines the effects of TELs with
provisions for immediate refunds and TELs
that limit growth in expenditures to the A Closer Look at
inflation rate. The demographic and eco- Washington and Colorado
nomic variables included in the first regres-
sion are included in this regression as well. In general, these results seem very promising.
The regression results can be found in the It appears that the two TELs passed by
Appendix as Regression 2. Washington and Colorado that limit the
These results, which are summarized in growth of expenditures to the inflation rate
Figure 2, support the idea that certain fea- have been especially effective at reducing per
tures can greatly enhance the effectiveness of capita government expenditures. Unfortunate-

10
Figure 2
Effectiveness of TELs by Feature

40

20 14.59

-20

-40
-39.80
-60
StrongTEL: A TEL that limits per capita expenditure growth to the inflation rate
RefundTEL: A TEL that is not a StrongTEL but does mandate immediate
-80 refunds during times of surplus
OtherTEL: A TEL that is neither a StrongTEL nor a RefundTEL
-100

-120 -114.84

-140
StrongTEL RefundTEL OtherTEL

ly, however, there are few data to use to analyze due to the collapse of the energy and con-
the impact of these TELs. Colorado’s TEL was struction industries, and revenues were con-
passed in 1992 and took effect in FY94, and sistently below the limit mandated by the
Washington’s TEL was passed in 1993 and took TEL. In 1991 the General Assembly of
effect in FY96.26 Since 1996 is the most recent Colorado adopted another statutory general
year for which the Census Bureau provides data fund appropriations limit. This one reduced
on state and local expenditures, I have only one the existing limit by one percentage point,
year’s data to use to analyze the impact of mandating that general fund expenditures
Washington’s TEL and three years’ data to use could increase by no more than 6 percent. Colorado’s citi-
to examine Colorado’s TEL. As a result, in order However, this legislation included generous
to further this analysis I will have to use anecdo- exemptions for spending on education and zens became
tal evidence in both cases. federal mandates.27 increasingly frus-
Colorado’s citizens became increasingly frus- trated by what
Case Study: Colorado trated by what they believed to be government
In the past 25 years Colorado has enacted inefficiency and the perceived inequities in the they believed to
three separate TELs. In 1977 Colorado was state tax system. Many became involved with a be government
one of the first states to adopt a general fund grassroots movement to reform state and local
appropriations limit. The legislation limited taxes. In 1986, 1988, and 1990 they succeeded in
inefficiency and
increases in state appropriations to 7 percent placing on the ballot initiatives that would limit the perceived
over the previous year’s general fund appro- taxes and spending. Those initiatives lost by nar- inequities in the
priations. Due to expire after FY83, the law rower margins each time. Finally, in 1992, the
was amended in 1979 and extended indefi- Taxpayer Bill of Rights (TABOR), also known as state tax system.
nitely. However, during the mid to late 1980s Amendment One, passed and added Article X,
Colorado’s economy suffered a downturn sec. 20, to the state constitution.28

11
Most people agree TABOR has three primary components. and local government to obtain voter
that the dire First, all tax increases have to be approved by approval to raise taxes. Although many
taxpayers. Second, it mandates that the exist- municipalities have sought and won voter
predictions of ing TELs, passed in 1977 and 1991, cannot be approval to increase taxes, 34 statewide initia-
opponents of weakened without taxpayer approval. Third, tives have fared poorly. In every year from
it includes the most stringent TEL of any 1993 to 1999 a proposal to either increase
TABOR have not state. TABOR limits growth in state spend- taxes or circumvent TABOR was on the
come to pass. ing and tax increases to inflation plus popu- Colorado ballot. Those included a 1993 ini-
lation growth.29 It mandates that any revenue tiative to increase the sales tax, a 1997 gas tax
collected over the limit be refunded to the increase, and a 1999 effort to use part of the
taxpayers. It requires that the limit be adjust- surplus for road and school construction.
ed when responsibility for government pro- Each of those statewide initiatives was defeat-
grams is transferred. Finally, the limit is con- ed.35 However, in 2000 Colorado residents
stitutional, not statutory, which makes it dif- did approve Amendment 23, which increased
ficult to amend. state aid to public education and reduced the
This particular ballot initiative generated a TABOR surplus for both 2000 and 2001.36
firestorm of controversy. Gov. Roy Romer, a Most people agree that the dire predictions
Democrat, sharply criticized the measure on of opponents of TABOR have not come to
numerous occasions. He said that defeating pass. However, many argue that when the
the measure was the “moral equivalent of economy slows down, it will become more
fighting the Nazis at the Battle of the Bulge.” difficult for the state legislature to stay with-
He warned of an economic Armageddon with in the limit.37
passage of TABOR and said that the Colorado
border would soon have to be posted with Case Study: Washington State
signs reading “Colorado is closed for busi- During the past 20 years Washington
ness.”30 Public employee unions and the edu- State has passed two TELs by citizen initia-
cation lobby quickly lined up in opposition to tive. The first one, Initiative 62, was passed in
TABOR. Even the New York Times criticized 1979 and limited increases in state revenues
TABOR, calling it potentially the most radical to the rate of growth in personal income.
change in any state government that year. 31 However, the state suffered a recession short-
Others argued that TABOR was bad policy ly after passage of the initiative, and it never
because the demands for state services, such as became a serious constraint since the limit
schools, prisons, and highways, seemed likely was higher than what the state could spend.
to increase faster than the rate of inflation. In fact, in 1993 the legislature was able to
They also contended that Colorado needed to pass a $1 billion tax increase to balance the
spend more on those services because, in pre- FY94–95 budget and remain within the limit.
vious years, Colorado’s spending increases for However, that tax increase provoked a back-
education and highways had been consider- lash and provided the impetus for putting
ably below the national average.32 Despite another TEL, Initiative 601, on the ballot in
those warnings, TABOR passed with more 1993.38
than 53 percent of the vote in 1992 and took Initiative 601 imposed a limit that was more
effect in FY94. strict than the limit set by Initiative 62. Initiative
Since 1994 the legislature has had to 601 limited increases in state expenditures to
rebate substantial amounts of tax revenues the inflation rate. In addition, it stopped the
to stay underneath the limit. Colorado enact- legislature from circumventing the limit by
ed taxpayer refunds of $139 million in 1997, devolving functions of government to the local-
$563 million in 1998, $679 million in 1999, ities. It explicitly prohibited the legislature to
and $941 million in 2000.33 In addition to its impose on local governments any responsibili-
rebate provisions, TABOR forces both state ty for new programs unless the legislature fully

12
reimbursed the local governments for the cost is a constitutional amendment. This makes TELs that impose
of the programs. Initiative 601 passed by 1 per- Initiative 601 easier to amend, and possibly more stringent
cent of the vote.39 weaken. Indeed, that is precisely what hap-
In 1994 the Washington legislature pened in the spring of 2000 when the limits on expen-
passed a supplemental budget to ensure that Washington legislature wanted to pass a ditures are also
it was in compliance with the TEL that was budget that would have exceeded the limit
scheduled to take effect in FY96. The legisla- mandated by the TEL. The legislature suc-
effective at
ture instituted some targeted budget cuts, ceeded in obtaining the necessary superma- restraining
mostly in administration, social services, and jority to suspend the TEL, and the governor government
prisons, to save more than $120 million in signed the budget into law.43 The long-term
the new biennium. The legislature increased effects on the budgetary practices of the state growth.
spending for some items, such as highways of Washington remain to be seen.
and school construction, on the grounds
that those were one-time-only expenses and
would be off budget in FY96. As a result, the Conclusion
budget base was not swollen from previous
spending levels and would be easier to sus- I have used regression analysis to examine
tain in the new biennium. Finally, some agen- the impact of various TELs on state and local
cies were directed to begin planning for cuts. expenditures. The approach is comprehen-
For instance, public colleges were directed to sive, as budgetary data from 49 states for
trim expenses by $39 million to help pay for more than 25 years are used. Most impor-
faculty and staff pay raises. 40 tant, special attention is paid to the manner
Because of those spending reductions, the in which the TELs were enacted. This pro-
budget was under the TEL’s limit in FY96 vides a number of interesting insights. The
and FY97. In subsequent years the state legis- analysis indicates that TELs passed by citizen
lature took steps to reduce taxes when it initiative procedures are more effective in
appeared that the government was collecting limiting state spending and revenues than
high levels of revenue. In FY98 and FY99 the are TELs passed by legislatures.
legislature instituted modest targeted tax Certain features make some TELs more
cuts of $38.5 million and $19.7 million, effective than others. There is solid evidence
respectively.41 Since spending was being that TELs that require immediate taxpayer
restrained, voters in the state of Washington refunds of surpluses are effective in reducing
desired more substantial tax relief. In 1998 expenditures. There is even stronger evidence
Washington voters passed Initiative 695, that TELs that impose more stringent limits
which reduced the motor vehicle excise tax by on expenditures are also effective at restrain-
$30 and saved taxpayers $256 million. In ing government growth. This is demonstrat-
1999 Washington residents voted to repeal ed by statistical analysis and case studies of
the motor vehicle excise tax. That reduced budgetary outcomes in Colorado and
the tax burden on Washington residents by Washington State. The data indicate that
an additional $1.1 billion.42 activists wishing to restrain government
However, Washington’s Initiative 601 was growth should focus on passing TELs that
weaker than Colorado’s Taxpayer Bill of include immediate taxpayer refunds of sur-
Rights in one important respect. Initiative pluses and hold spending increases to the
601 was a statutory measure whereas TABOR inflation rate plus population growth.

13
Appendix: Regression Results
Regression 1
Technique: WLS, panel corrected standard errors fixed effects model with state and year
indicator variables.
Dependent variable: Annual change in per capita state and local direct general expendi-
tures in 1996 dollars for 49 states from 1972 through 1996.

Multiple R .642
R square .413
Standard error 111.092

coef s.e. t-stat sig t

UnemploymentCH 2.88 4.90 0.76 .4474


Age5to17CH 59.93 27.35 2.19 .0287*
Age65CH -1.67 13.93 0.12 .9045
PopulationGrowth 43.69 5.19 8.91 .0000*
IncomeGrowth -2.67 1.41 -1.89 .0590
InitiativeTEL -16.29 20.05 -0.81 .4181
LegislativeTEL 14.00 16.59 0.84 .4011
ConventionTEL 61.67 38.97 1.58 .1144
ReferendumTEL -1.95 18.59 -0.10 .9204
Constant 165.07 29.23 5.65 .0000*

*Statistically significant.
Regression 2
Technique: WLS, panel corrected standard errors fixed effects model with state and year
indicator variables.
Dependent variable: Annual change in per capita state and local direct general expendi-
tures in 1996 dollars for 49 states from 1972 through 1996.

Multiple R .646
R square .417
Standard error 108.922

coef s.e. t-stat sig t

UnemploymentCH 2.59 3.78 0.68 .4966*


Age5to17CH 63.22 27.48 2.30 .0216*
Age65CH -2.31 13.99 -0.16 .8729
PopulationGrowth 43.29 4.95 8.75 .0000*
IncomeGrowth -2.61 1.41 -1.85 .0645
StrongTEL -114.84 53.57 -2.14 .0326*
RefundTEL -39.80 24.04 -1.66 .0972
OtherTEL 14.59 12.61 1.16 .2463
Constant 172.82 24.37 7.09 .0000*

*Statistically significant.

14
Explanation of Dependent Variables Campaigns and the Power of Money (New York:
Harcourt, 2000), p. 7.
UnemploymentCH indicates the annual
percentage point change in the state’s unem- 2. Peter Schrag, “Rule by Referendum,” American
ployment rate. Prospect, July 17, 2000, p. 38.
Age5to17CH indicates the annual percent-
3. Properly defined, Proposition 13 is not a state-
age point change in the number of state resi- wide tax and expenditure limitation but a property
dents who are between the ages of 5 and 17. tax limitation. However, its passage did mark the
Age65CH indicates the annual percentage beginning of the tax revolt, which is why it is men-
point change in the number of state residents tioned here.
who are over the age of 65. 4. James Madison, Federalist no. 10 (1787), in The
PopulationGrowth indicates the growth Founders’ Constitution, ed. Philip B. Kurland and
in population in each state. Ralph Lerner. (Chicago: University of Chicago Press,
IncomeGrowth indicates the annual 1978), vol. 1, pp. 128–30. Alexander Hamilton at the
Constitutional Convention was even less favorable
change in per capita personal income in each toward direct democracy: “It has been observed, by
state, adjusted for inflation. an honorable gentleman, that a pure democracy, if it
StrongTEL is an indicator variable that is were practicable, would be the most perfect gov-
scored a 1 if a state has passed a TEL that lim- ernment. Experience has proved that no position in
politics is more false than this. The ancient democ-
its growth in per capita expenditures to the racies, in which the people themselves deliberated,
inflation rate, zero otherwise. never possessed one feature of good government.
RefundTEL is an indicator variable that is Their very character was tyranny; their figure, defor-
scored a 1 if a state has passed a TEL that is mity. When they assembled, the field of debate pre-
sented an ungovernable mob, not only incapable of
not a StrongTEL but does mandate immedi- deliberation, but prepared for every enormity.”
ate taxpayer refunds during times of surplus, Debates on the Adoption of the Federal Constitution, ed.
zero otherwise. Jonathan Elliott (Washington: privately printed,
OtherTEL is an indicator variables that is scored 1836), vol. 2, p. 253.
a 1 if a state has passed a TEL that is neither a 5. David Magleby, Direct Legislation: Voting on Ballot
StrongTEL nor a RefundTEL, zero otherwise. Propositions in the United States (Baltimore: Johns
Hopkins University Press, 1984), p. 22. See also
Notes to Appendix John M. Allswang, The Initiative and Referendum in
The reported statistical significance for California 1898–1998 (Stanford: Stanford Univer-
sity Press, 2000).
the coefficients is two tailed.
Data are weighted to correct for het- 6. Quoted in Magleby, p. 23.
eroskedasticity.
Both a White test and a Breusch Pagan 7. Robert Higgs, Crisis and Leviathan: Critical
Episodes in the Growth of American Government (New
Godfrey test indicate that there is no statisti- York: Oxford University Press, 1987), passim.
cally significant evidence of heteroskedastici-
ty in the residuals. An Asymptotic test indi- 8. Allswang, pp. 105–7.
cates that there is no statistically significant 9. Ibid., pp. 108–9.
evidence of serial correlation in the residuals.
The technique that Nathaniel Beck and 10. Broder, p. 16.
Jonathan Katz describe in “What to Do (And
11. Ibid., chap. 4.
Not to Do) with Time-Series Cross-Sectional
Data,” American Political Science Review 89, no. 12. Schrag, “Rule by Referendum,” p. 38.
3 (September 1995): 634–47, is used to do the
panel corrections. 13. Broder, p. 20. See also Peter Schrag, Paradise
Lost: California’s Experience, America’s Future (New
York: New Press, 1998).

Notes 14. James Bennett and Thomas DiLorenzo, “Off-


Budget Activities of Local Governments: The Bane of
1. David S. Broder, Democracy Derailed: Initiative the Tax Revolt,” Public Choice 39, no. 3 (1982): 333–34.

15
15. James Cox and David Lowery, “The Impact of neatly avoided by using data that combine state
Tax Revolt Era State Fiscal Caps,” Social Science and local expenditures.
Quarterly 3 (1990): 492–509; and David Lowery
and Tyson King-Meadows, “The Impact of Tax 21. However, in this paper no hypotheses are going
Revolt Era State Fiscal Caps: A Research Update,” to be posed about TELs passed by constitutional
Public Budgeting and Finance 16, no. 1 (1996): conventions for a couple reasons. First, only two
102–12. states in this analysis, Tennessee and Hawaii, have
passed a TEL though constitutional convention,
16. Burton Abrams and William Dougan, “The and, as a result, there is a paucity of data. Second, I
Effects of Constitutional Restraint on Govern- lack the details about these particular conventions
ment Spending,” Public Choice 49, no. 2 (1986): needed to make an informed hypothesis about the
101–16; and Dale Bails and Margaret Tieslau, strength of the TELs. If most of the delegates to
“The Impact of Fiscal Constitution on State and constitutional conventions are legislators, then I
Local Expenditures,” Cato Journal 20, no. 2 (2000): would expect the TEL to be weak. However, if most
255–77. of the delegates are not elected officials, there exists
a possibility that a more stringent TEL may be
17. Marcia Howard, “State Tax and Expenditure enacted. However, I do not possess the necessary
Limitations: There Is No Story,” Public Budgeting details about these particular conventions to make
and Finance 9, no. 2 (1989): 83–90; Dean Stansel, an informed judgment.
“Taming Leviathan: Are State Tax and Spending Likewise, no hypotheses are going to be posed
Limits the Answer?” Cato Institute Policy about TELs that are enacted through referendum
Analysis no. 213, July 25, 1994; Dale Bails, “The procedures. Since a referendum must be
Effectiveness of Tax and Expenditure Limits: A approved by the legislature before being placed
Re-evaluation,” American Journal of Economics and on the ballot, it is difficult to predict the effec-
Sociology 49, no. 2 (1990): 223; and Daphne tiveness of this sort of TEL. It is reasonable to
Kenyon and Karen Benker, “Fiscal Discipline: assume that a legislature would be unlikely to
Lessons from the State Experience,” National Tax approve a ballot proposal that would impose
Journal 37, no. 3 (1984): 433–46. severe restrictions on its behavior. However, since
there is a possibility that the referendum will fail
18. Phillip Joyce and Dan Mullins, “The to get the necessary majority, legislators might be
Changing Fiscal Structure of the State and Local more willing to place a restrictive TEL on the bal-
Sector: The Impact of Tax and Expenditure lot than to enact a restrictive TEL directly. As a
Limitations,” Public Administration Review 51, no. 3 result, I would anticipate that TELs passed by ref-
(1991): 240–52; Phillip Joyce and Dan Mullins, erendum would be less effective than those
“Tax and Expenditure Limitations and State and passed by initiative but more effective than those
Local Fiscal Structure: An Empirical Assessment,” passed by legislatures. However, a formal hypoth-
Public Budgeting and Finance 16, no. 1 (1996): esis about this kind of TEL will not be put forth.
75–101; and Ronald Shadbegian, “Do Tax and
Expenditure Limitations Affect the Size and 22. Saying that a variable is statistically significant
Growth of Government?” Contemporary Economic means that we can be at least 95 percent certain that
Policy 14, no. 2 (1996): 22–35. the given variable actually has a nonzero effect on state
and local expenditures. In other words, the probability
19. Alaska receives a high percentage of its rev- that chance variation within the data caused an effect
enue from severance taxes on oil produced and as great or greater is 5 percent or less.
minerals mined in the state. Since shifts in the
prices of those commodities cause a great deal of 23. Bureau of the Census, Statistical Abstract of the
fluctuation in Alaska’s budgetary outcomes, United States: 2000 (Washington: Government
Alaska is omitted from this analysis. Printing Office, 2000), p. 485; Bureau of the
Census, Statistical Abstract of the United States: 1992
20. It should also be noted that in this analysis (Washington: Government Printing Office,
combined state and local data will be used instead 1992), p. 438; and Bureau of the Census, Statistical
of state data because the combined data tend to Abstract of the United States: 1991 (Washington:
be more stable. In addition, state and local data Government Printing Office, 1991), p. 22.
provide a more accurate indication of the level of
expenditures in each state. As was mentioned ear- 24. Bureau of the Census, Governmental Finances
lier, some states are able to create phantom reduc- (Washington: Government Printing Office, 1980
tions in taxes and spending without reducing the and 1990).
overall tax burden by simply devolving functions
of state government to the localities. That could 25. Mandy Rafool, “State Tax and Expenditure
yield some potentially misleading results if only Limitations,” National Conference of State
state data were used. However, this problem is Legislatures Legislative Finance Paper no. 104,

16
1996, p. 14; David Webber, “The Missouri www.revenue.state.co.us/refund2000.html;
Experience with State Revenue Limits—The www.revenue.state.co.us/refund99.html;
Hancock Amendment,” Paper presented at Policy www.revenue.state.co.us/refund98.html; and
Collaborative on Tax and Spending Limits in the www.revenue.state.co.us/refund.html.
States, Colorado University, Denver, July 2001, p.
13; and Franklin James, “Tax and Spending 34. John Sanko, “’92 Election Was Fiscal Face Lift,”
Limits on Colorado,” Paper presented at Policy Rocky Mountain News, August 3, 1999, p. 14A.
Collaborative on Tax and Spending Limits in the
States, Colorado University, Denver, July 2001, p. 35. “TABOR Legislative Handbook,” Indepen-
10. dence Institute Paper, 1999, pp. 1–2.

26. Rafool, “State Tax and Expenditure Limits,” p. 18. 36. James, p. 11.

27. Ibid., p. 13. 37. Rafool, “State Tax and Expenditure Limits,” p. 14.

28. Ibid. 38. Ibid., p. 17.

29. Rafool, “State Tax and Expenditure Limita- 39. Ibid., p. 18.
tions,” p. 28.
40. Ibid.
30. Stephen Moore and Dean Stansel, “The Great
Tax Revolt of 1994,” Reason, October 1994, p. 20. 41. Judy Zelio, State Tax Actions 1997 (Denver:
National Conference of State Legislatures, 1998),
31. Dirk Johnson, “Taxpayer Revolt in Colorado p. 15; and Judy Zelio, Scott Mackey, and Mandy
Raises Alarm about Lost Services,” New York Rafool, State Tax Actions 1998 (Denver: National
Times, November 15, 1992, p. 18. Conference of State Legislatures, 1999), p. 11.

32. Nicholas Johnson, “The Taxpayer Bill of Rights 42. Mandy Rafool, State Tax Actions 1999 (Denver, Colo:
and Referendum B: Assessing the Availability of National Conference of State Legislatures, 2000), p. 39.
Public Services and Investment,” Center for Budget
and Policy Priorities, Washington, 1998, p. 3–7. 43. Bob Williams, “House Budget Shreds Spending
Limit (I-601),” Evergreen Freedom Foundation,
33. Colorado Department of Revenue Web sites: Olympia, Washington, Policy Highlighter, 2000.

Published by the Cato Institute, Policy Analysis is a regular series evaluating government policies and offer-
ing proposals for reform. Nothing in Policy Analysis should be construed as necessarily reflecting the views
of the Cato Institute or as an attempt to aid or hinder the passage of any bill before congress. Contact the
Cato Institute for reprint permission. Additional copies of Policy Analysis are $6.00 each ($3.00 each for five
or more). To order, or for a complete listing of available studies, write the Cato Institute, 1000 Massachusetts
Ave., N.W., Washington, D.C. 20001, call toll free 1-800-767-1241 (noon - 9 p.m. eastern time), fax (202) 842-
3490, or visit our website at www.cato.org.

17

Das könnte Ihnen auch gefallen