Sie sind auf Seite 1von 35

Chapter 12 MONOPOLY AND MONOPSONY QUESTIONS & ANSWERS Q12.1 Q12.

1 Describe the monopoly market structure and provide some examples. ANSWER Monopoly is a market structure characterized by a single seller of a highly differentiated product. Because a monopolist is the sole provider of a desired commodity, the monopolist is the industry. Although the producer of every product faces at least some competition in the sense of competing for a share of the consumer's overall market basket of goods, monopolists face no effective competition from either established or potential rivals able to offer the same product. This allows the monopolist to simultaneously determine price and output levels for the firm (and the industry). Substantial barriers to entry or exit are often present, thereby deterring potential entrants and offering both efficient and inefficient monopolists the opportunity for excess profits, even in the long-run. Examples of monopoly markets include: local telephone service (or basic hook-up); municipal bus companies; and gas, water and electric utilities, among others. Q12.2 Q12.2 From a social standpoint, what is the problem with monopoly? ANSWER The problem with monopoly from a social standpoint is that it leads to an inefficient allocation of productive resources and an inequitable allocation of income. From an efficiency perspective, monopolies produce too little output at too high a price. As a result, the demands of consumers are only partially met. Because P > MC, the marginal value of output (P) exceeds marginal production costs, and social welfare would rise with an increase in production. From an equity perspective, the excess profits that can arise due to unregulated monopoly are often criticized as unwarranted and thus unfair. Q12.3 Q12.3 Why are both industry and firm demand curves downward sloping in monopoly markets? ANSWER

In monopoly, the firm is the industry. Thus, firm and industry demand and supply curves are identical. The monopoly demand curve will be downward sloping, like all industry demand curves, because this output must, to a greater or lesser degree, compete with all goods and services for a share in the consumer's market basket. The diminishing marginal utility associated with the consumption of all goods and services will ensure that the industry demand curve is downward sloping for all products. Q12.4 Q12.4 Give an example of monopoly in the labor market. monopoly's effect on wage rates and on inflation. ANSWER With industrialization came a growing concentration on the purchase of labor services, and in some instances, this growing concentration was sufficient to create buyer (monopsony) power. Labor laws in the United States granted workers the right to unionize in order to create countervailing seller (monopoly) power in the market for labor services. The advantage of countervailing power is that markets characterized by monopsony-monopoly confrontation can sometimes lead to more efficient price-output combinations than markets characterized by uncontested buyer or seller power. Q12.5 Given the difficulties encountered with utility regulation, it has been suggested that nationalization might lead to a more socially optimal allocation of resources. Do you agree? Why or why not? ANSWER This question is, of course, very subjective. However, experience suggests that economic efficiency is best served by vigorous competition in the marketplace. With utilities such competition is certainly limited, but private utilities must still compete for capital resources. This no doubt aids in the efficient allocation of scarce economic resources. With nationalization, even this role of competition in determining efficient resource use would be removed, and it seems unlikely that a nationalized firm with no profit incentive would operate at either an optimal output level, or facilitate an efficient allocation of resources. Q12.6 Antitrust statutes in the United States have been used to attack monopolization by big business. Does labor monopolization by giant unions have the same potential for the misallocation of economic resources? ANSWER Economically speaking, the monopolization of labor can be as harmful as is the monopolization of big business. Both lead to a misallocation of economic Discuss such a

Q12.5

Q12.6

Q12.7

resources. From an efficiency standpoint, monopolization of both labor and business should be vigorously prosecuted. When will an increase in the minimum wage increase employment income for unskilled laborers? When will it cause this income to fall? Based on your experience, which is more likely? ANSWER Demand analysis indicates that an increase in price will increase total revenue so long as demand is inelastic (| P| < 1). Similarly, an increase in the minimum wage will increase employment income for unskilled workers so long as the demand for unskilled labor is inelastic. Unfortunately, the demand for unskilled labor may be quite elastic, given the propensity of consumers to substitute self-service labor for high-priced unskilled labor. Declining job opportunities for unskilled workers such as bus boys, caddies, gas station attendants, movie theater ushers, waitresses, and so on, suggest that increasing the minimum wage can hurt, rather than help, unskilled workers.

Q12.7

Q12.8 Q12.8

Explain why state tax rates on personal income vary more on a state-by-state basis than do corresponding tax rates on corporate income. ANSWER In considering state tax rates, it is interesting to note a greater variance from state to state in personal as opposed to corporate tax rates. This phenomena can be explained by the fact that corporations, more so than individuals, are willing to relocate to take advantage of state tax rate differentials. Individuals become attached to geographic locations and value geographic proximity to family and friends. As a result, individuals are often reluctant to move; the coal miners stayed in West Virginia long after the mines shut down. Corporations, on the other hand, exhibit few such ties to geographic location. This implies a higher tax revenue elasticity for corporate tax rate schedules than for personal tax rate schedules.

Q12.9 Q12.9

Do the U.S. antitrust statutes protect competition or competitors? What is the difference? ANSWER U.S. antitrust statutes are meant to protect competition (the fight), rather than currently active competitors (the fighters). Vigorous competition sometimes results in bankruptcy and exit for previously viable competitors. Moreover, there is not necessarily a close link between fewness in the number of competitors and the lack of competition. This point is sometimes overlooked in antitrust analysis. The important point to consider is that competition

requires viable competitors. With substantial economies of scale in an industry, for example, viable firms are going to be large. However, even a handful of firms can still be, and often are, vigorous competitors. Q12.10 Q12.10 Describe the economic effects of countervailing power, and cite examples of markets in which countervailing power is observed. ANSWER Countervailing power exists in a market when buyer market power is used to offset the effects of seller market power, and vice versa. The effect of countervailing power is to reduce market prices and/or expand output in the case of new monopsony (buyer) power created to challenge established monopoly (seller) power. Similarly, new seller power created to challenge established buyer power has the effect of raising market prices and/or expanding output. In defense procurement, the monopsony (buyer) power of the federal government is often used to offset the monopoly (seller) power of singlesource defense contractors. Similarly, local governments use their buyer power to offset the seller power of local road and building contractors. The effects of countervailing power are also sometimes observed when large retail chains buy major appliances, car rental companies buy automobiles, and in several labor markets. SELF-TEST PROBLEMS & SOLUTIONS ST12.1 Capture Problem. It remains a widely held belief that regulation is in the public interest and influences firm behavior toward socially desirable ends. However, in the early 1970s, Nobel laureate George Stigler and his colleague Sam Peltzman at the University of Chicago introduced an alternative capture theory of economic regulation. According to Stigler and Peltzman, the machinery and power of the state are a potential resource to every industry. With its power to prohibit or compel, to take or give money, the state can and does selectively help or hurt a vast number of industries. Because of this, regulation may be actively sought by industry. They contended that regulation is typically acquired by industry and is designed and operated primarily for industry's benefit. Types of state favors commonly sought by regulated industries include direct money subsidies, control over entry by new rivals, control over substitutes and complements, and price fixing. Domestic "air mail" subsidies, Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC) regulation that reduces the rate of entry into commercial banking, suppression of margarine sales by butter producers, price fixing in motor carrier (trucking) regulation, and American Medical Association control of medical training and licensing can be interpreted as historical examples of control by regulated industries. In summarizing their views on regulation, Stigler and Peltzman suggest

that regulators should be criticized for pro-industry policies no more than politicians for seeking popular support. Current methods of enacting and carrying out regulations only make the pro-industry stance of regulatory bodies more likely. The only way to get different results from regulation is to change the political process of regulator selection and to provide economic rewards to regulators who serve the public interest effectively. Capture theory is in stark contrast to more traditional public interest theory, which sees regulation as a government-imposed means of privatemarket control. Rather than viewing regulation as a "good" to be obtained, controlled, and manipulated, public interest theory views regulation as a method for improving economic performance by limiting the harmful effects of market failure. Public interest theory is silent on the need to provide regulators with economic incentives to improve regulatory performance. Unlike capture theory, a traditional view has been that the public can trust regulators to make a good-faith effort to establish regulatory policy in the public interest. A. B. The aim of antitrust and regulatory policy is to protect competition, not to protect competitors. Explain the difference. Starting in the 1970s, growing dissatisfaction with traditional approaches to government regulation led to a global deregulation movement that spurred competition, lowered prices, and resulted in more efficient production. Explain how this experience is consistent with the capture theory of regulation. Discuss how regulatory efficiency could be improved by focusing on output objectives like low prices for cable or telephone services rather than production methods or rates of return.

C.

ST12.1 A.

SOLUTION Entry and exit are common facts of life in competitive markets. Firms that efficiently produce goods and services that consumers crave are able to boost market share and enjoy growing revenues and profits. Firms that fail to measure up in the eyes of consumers will lose market share and suffer declining revenues and profits. The disciplining role of competitive markets can be swift and harsh, even for the largest and most formidable corporations. For example, in August, 2000, Enron Corp. traded in the stock market at an all-time high and was ranked among the 10 most valuable corporations in America. Nevertheless, Enron filed for bankruptcy just 16 months later as evidence emerged of a failed diversification strategy, misguided energy trading, and financial corruption. Similarly, once powerful telecom giant WorldCom quickly stumbled into bankruptcy as evidence came to light concerning the companys abuse of accounting rules and regulations. In both cases, once powerful corporations were brought to their knees by competitive

capital and product markets that simply refused to tolerate inefficiency and corporate malfeasance. In evaluating the effects of deregulation, and in gauging the competitive implications of market exit by previously regulated firms, it is important to remember that protecting competition is not the same as protecting competitors. Without regulation, it is inevitable that some competitors will fall by the wayside and that concentration will rise in some previously regulated markets. Although such trends must be watched closely for anticompetitive effects, they are characteristics of a vigorously competitive environment. Bankruptcy and exit are the regrettable costs of remedying economic dislocation in competitive markets. Though such costs are regrettable, experience shows that they are much less onerous than the costs of indefinitely maintaining inefficient production methods in a tightly regulated environment. B. Although it is difficult to pinpoint a single catalyst for the deregulation movement, it is hard to overlook the role played by George Stigler, Sam Peltzman, Alfred E. Kahn, and other economists who documented how government regulation can sometimes harm consumer interests. A study by the Brookings Institution documented important benefits of deregulation in five major industries--natural gas, telecommunications, airlines, trucking, and railroads. It was found that prices fell 4-15% within the first two years after deregulation; within 10 years, prices were 25-50% lower. Deregulation also leads to service quality improvements. Crucial social goals like airline safety, reliability of gas service, and reliability of the telecommunications network were maintained or improved by deregulation. Regulatory reform also tends to confer benefits on most consumers. Although it is possible to find narrowly defined groups of customers in special circumstances who paid somewhat higher prices after deregulation, the gains to the vast majority of consumers far outweighed negative effects on small groups. Finally, deregulation offers benefits in the sense of permitting greater customer choice. Although many industries have felt the effects of changing state and local regulation, changing federal regulation has been most pronounced in the financial, telecommunications, and transportation sectors. Since 1975, for example, it has been illegal for securities dealers to fix commission rates. This broke a 182-year tradition under which the New York Stock Exchange (NYSE) set minimum rates for each 100-share ("round lot") purchase. Until 1975, everyone charged the minimum rate approved by the NYSE. Purchase of 1,000 shares cost a commission of ten times the minimum, even though the overhead and work involved are roughly the same for small and large stock transactions. Following deregulation, commission rates tumbled, and, predictably, some of the least efficient brokerage firms merged or otherwise went out of business. Today, commission rates have fallen by 90% or more, and the industry is noteworthy for increasing productivity and innovative new product introductions. It is also worth mentioning that since brokerage rates

were deregulated, the number of sales offices in the industry, trading volume, employment, and profits have skyrocketed. This has lead some observers to conclude that deregulation can benefit consumers without causing any lasting damage to industry. In fact, a leaner, more efficient industry may be one of the greatest benefits of deregulation. In Canada, the deregulation movement led to privatization of government-owned Air Canada. Trucking, historically a regulated industry, also was deregulated. Specialized telecommunications services industries were deregulated and thrown open to competition. In other areas where the government considered continued regulation desirable and necessary, regulatory agencies were pressured to reform and improve the regulatory decision-making process to reduce inefficiencies, bureaucratic delays, and administrative red tape. C. A significant problem with regulation is that regulators seldom have the information or expertise to specify, for example, the correct level of utility investment, minimum transportation costs, or the optimum method of pollution control. Because technology changes rapidly in most regulated industries, only industry personnel working at the frontier of current technology have such specialized knowledge. One method for dealing with this technical expertise problem is to have regulators focus on the preferred outcomes of regulatory processes, rather than on the technical means that industry adopts to achieve those ends. The FCC's decision to adopt downward-adjusting price caps for long-distance telephone service is an example of this developing trend toward incentivebased regulation. If providers of long-distance telephone service are able to reduce costs faster than the FCC-mandated decline in prices, they will enjoy an increase in profitability. By setting price caps that fall over time, the FCC ensures that consumers share in expected cost savings while companies enjoy a positive incentive to innovate. This approach to regulation focuses on the objectives of regulation while allowing industry to meet those goals in new and unique ways. Tying regulator rewards and regulated industry profits to objective, output-oriented performance criteria has the potential to create a desirable win/win situation for regulators, utilities, and the general public. For example, the public has a real interest in safe, reliable, and low-cost electric power. State and federal regulators who oversee the operations of utilities could develop objective standards for measuring utility safety, reliability, and cost efficiency. Tying firm profit rates to such performance-oriented criteria could stimulate real improvements in utility and regulator performance. Although some think that there is simply a question of regulation versus deregulation, this is seldom the case. On grounds of economic and political feasibility, it is often most fruitful to consider approaches to improving existing methods of regulation. Competitive forces provide a persistent and socially desirable constraining influence on firm behavior. When vigorous competition is absent, government regulation can be justified through both efficiency and equity criteria. When regulation is warranted, business, government, and the public must work together to ensure that regulatory processes represent the public interest. The unnecessary costs of antiquated regulations dictate that regulatory reform is likely to remain a significant

social concern. ST12.2 Deadweight Loss From Monopoly. The Las Vegas Valley Water District (LVVWD) is a not-for-profit agency that began providing water to the Las Vegas Valley in 1954. The District helped build the city's water delivery system and now provides water to more than one million people in Southern Nevada. District water rates are regulated by law and can cover only the costs of water delivery, maintenance, and facilities. District water rates are based on a four-tier system to encourage conservation. The first tier represents indoor usage for most residential customers. Rate for remaining tiers becomes increasingly higher with the amount of water usage. To document the deadweight loss from monopoly problem, allow the monthly market supply and demand conditions for water in the Las Vegas Water District to be: QS QD = 10P = 120 - 40P (Market Supply) (Market Demand)

where Q is water and P is the market price of water. Water is sold in units of one thousand gallons, so a $2 price implies a user cost of 0 .2 cents per gallon. Water demand and supply relations are expressed in terms of millions of units. A. Graph and calculate the equilibrium price/output solution. How much consumer surplus, producer surplus, and social welfare is produced at this activity level? Use the graph to help you calculate the quantity demanded and quantity supplied if the market is run by a profit-maximizing monopolist. (Note: If monopoly market demand is P = $3 - $0.025Q, then the monopolists MR = $3 - $0.05Q) Use the graph to help you determine the deadweight loss for consumers and the producer if LVVWD is run as an unregulated profit-maximizing monopoly. Use the graph to help you ascertain the amount of consumer surplus transferred to producers following a change from a competitive market to a monopoly market. How much is the net gain in producer surplus?

B.

C.

D.

ST12.2 A.

SOLUTION The market supply curve is given by the equation

QS = 10P or, solving for price, P = 0.1QS The market demand curve is given by the equation QD = 120 - 40P or, solving for price, 40P = 120 - QD P = $3 - $0.025QD To find the competitive market equilibrium price, equate the market demand and market supply curves where quantity is expressed as a function of price: Supply = Demand 10P = 120 - 40P 50P = 120 P = $2.40 To find the competitive market equilibrium quantity, set equal the market supply and market demand curves where price is expressed as a function of quantity, and QS = QD: Supply = Demand $0.1Q = $3 - $0.025Q 0.125Q = 3 Q = 24 (million) units per month Therefore, the competitive market equilibrium price-output combination is a market price of $2.40 with an equilibrium output of 24 (million) units. The value of consumer surplus is equal to the region under the market demand curve that lies above the market equilibrium price of $2.40. Because the area of such a triangle is one-half the value of the base times the height, the value of consumer surplus equals:

Consumer Surplus =

[24 ($3 - $2.40)]

= $7.2 (million) per month In words, this means that at a unit price of $2.40, the quantity demanded is 24 (million), resulting in total revenues of $57.6 (million). The fact that consumer surplus equals $7.2 (million) means that customers as a group would have been willing to pay an additional $7.2 (million) for this level of market output. This is an amount above and beyond the $57.6 (million) paid. Customers received a real bargain. The value of producer surplus is equal to the region above the market supply curve at the market equilibrium price of $2.40. Because the area of such a triangle is one-half the value of the base times the height, the value of producer surplus equals: Producer Surplus = [24 ($2.40 - $0)]

= $28.8 (million) per month At a water price of $2.40 per thousand gallons, producer surplus equals $28.8 (million). Producers as a group received $28.8 (million) more than the absolute minimum required for them to produce the market equilibrium output of 24 (million) units of output. Producers received a real bargain. In competitive market equilibrium, social welfare is measured by the sum of net benefits derived by consumers and producers. Social welfare is the sum of consumer surplus and producer surplus: Social Welfare = Consumer Surplus + Producer Surplus = $7.2 (million) + $28.8 (million) = $36 (million) per month

B.

If the industry is run by a profit-maximizing monopolist, the optimal priceoutput combination can be determined by setting marginal revenue equal to marginal cost and solving for Q: MR = MC = Market Supply $3 - $0.05Q = $0.1Q $0.15Q = $3 Q = 20 (million) units per month

At Q = 20, P = $3 - $0.025Q = $3 - $0.025(20) = $2.50 per unit C. Under monopoly, the amount supplied falls to 20 (million) units and the market price jumps to $2.50 per thousand gallons of water. The amount of deadweight loss from monopoly suffered by consumers is given by the triangle bounded by ABD in the figure. Because the area of such a triangle is one-half the value of the base times the height, the value of lost consumer surplus due to monopoly equals: Consumer Deadweight Loss = [(24 - 20) ($2.50 - $2.40)]

= $0.2 (million) per month The amount of deadweight loss from monopoly suffered by producers is given by the triangle bounded by BCD. Because the area of a such a triangle is one-half the value of the base times the height, the value of lost producer surplus equals: Producer Deadweight Loss = [(24 - 20) ($2.40 - $2)]

= $0.8 (million) per month The total amount of deadweight loss from monopoly suffered by consumers and producers is given by the triangle bounded by ACD. The area of a such a triangle is simply the amount of consumer deadweight loss plus producer deadweight loss: Total Deadweight Loss = Consumer Loss + Producer Loss = $0.2 (million) + $0.8 (million) = $1 (million) per month D. In addition to the deadweight loss from monopoly problem, there is a wealth transfer problem associated with monopoly. The creation of a monopoly results in a significant transfer from consumer surplus to producer surplus. In the figure, this amount is shown as the area in the rectangle bordered by PCMPMAB: Transfer to Producer Surplus = 20 ($2.50 - $2.40) = $2 (million) per month

Therefore, from the viewpoint of the producer, the change to monopoly results in a very favorable net increase in producer surplus: Net Change in Producer Surplus = Producer Deadweight Loss + Transfer = -$0.8 (million) + $2 (million) = $1. 2 (million) per month From the viewpoint of consumers, the problem with monopoly is twofold. Monopoly result in both a significant deadweight loss in consumer surplus ($0.2 million per month), and monopoly causes a significant transfer of consumer surplus to producer surplus ($2 million per month). In this example, the cost of monopoly to consumers is measured by a total loss in consumer surplus of $2.2 million per month. The wealth transfer problem associated with monopoly is seen as an issue of equity or fairness because it involves the distribution of income or wealth in the economy. Although economic profits serve the useful functions of providing incentives and helping allocate resources, it is difficult to justify monopoly profits that result from the raw exercise of market power rather than from exceptional performance. PROBLEMS & SOLUTIONS P12.1 Monopoly Concepts. Indicate whether each of the following statements is true or false, and explain why. A. The Justice Department generally concerns itself with significant or flagrant offenses under the Sherman Act, as well as with mergers for monopoly covered by Section 7 of the Clayton Act. When a single seller is confronted in a market by many small buyers, monopsony power enables the buyers to obtain lower prices than those that would prevail in a competitive markets. A natural monopoly results when the profit-maximizing output level occurs at a point where long-run average costs are declining. Downward-sloping industry demand curves characterize both perfectly competitive and monopoly markets. A decrease in the price elasticity of demand would follow an increase in monopoly power.

B.

C. D. E. P12.1

SOLUTION

A.

True. Generally speaking, the Justice Department concerns itself with significant or flagrant offenses under the Sherman Act, as well as with mergers for monopoly covered by Section 7 of the Clayton Act. False. When a single buyer is confronted in a market by many smaller sellers, monopsony power enables the buyer to obtain lower prices than those that would prevail in a competitive markets. False. A natural monopoly occurs in a market when the market clearing price, or price where Demand (Price) = Supply (Marginal Cost), occurs at an output level where long-run average costs are declining. True. Downward sloping demand curves follow from the law of diminishing marginal utility and characterize both perfectly competitive and monopoly market structures. True. A decrease in the price elasticity of demand would result following an increase in monopoly power. Natural Monopoly. On May 12, 2000, the two daily newspapers in Denver, Colorado, filed an application with the U.S. Department of Justice for approval of a joint operating agreement. The application was filed by The E.W. Scripps Company, whose subsidiary, the Denver Publishing Company, published the Rocky Mountain News, and the MediaNews Group, Inc., whose subsidiary, the Denver Post Corporation, published the Denver Post. Under the proposed arrangement, printing and commercial operations of both newspapers were to be handled by a new entity, the Denver Newspaper Agency, owned by the parties in equal shares. This type of joint operating agreement provides for the complete independence of the news and editorial departments of the two newspapers. The rationale for such an arrangement, as provided for under the Newspaper Preservation Act, is to preserve multiple independent editorial voices in towns and cities too small to support two or more newspapers. The Act requires joint operating arrangements, such as that proposed by the Denver newspapers, obtain the prior written consent of the Attorney General of the United States in order to qualify for the antitrust exemption provided by the Act. Scripps initiated discussions for a joint operating agreement after determining that the News would probably fail without such an arrangement. In their petition to the Justice department, the newspapers argued that the News had sustained $123 million in net operating losses while the financially stronger Post had reaped $200 million in profits during the 1990s. This was a crucial point in favor of the joint operating agreement application because the Attorney General must find that one of the publications is a failing newspaper and that approval of the arrangement is necessary to maintain the independent editorial content of both newspapers. Like any business,

B.

C.

D.

E. P12.2

newspapers cannot survive without a respectable bottom line. In commenting on the joint operating agreement application, Attorney General Janet Reno noted that Denver was one of only five major American cities still served by competing daily newspapers. The other four are Boston, Chicago, New York, and Washington, D.C. Of course these other four cities are not comparable in size to Denver; theyre much bigger. None of those four cities can lay claim to two newspapers that are more or less equally matched and strive after the same audience. A. Use the natural monopoly concept to explain why there is not a single city in the U.S. that still supports two independently owned and evenly matched, high-quality newspapers that vie for the same broad base of readership. On Friday January 5, 2001, Attorney General Reno gave the green light to a 50-year joint operating agreement between News and its longtime rival, the Post. Starting January 22, 2001, the publishing operations of the News and the Post were consolidated. At the time the joint operating agreement was formed, neither news organization would speculate on job losses or advertising and circulation rate increases from the deal. Based upon your knowledge of natural monopoly, would you predict an increase or decrease in prices following establishment of the joint operating agreement? Would you expect newspaper production (and employment) to rise or fall? Why?

B.

P12.2 A.

SOLUTION Economies of scale in production explain why few cities can support more than one local newspaper. Local newspapers are the classic example of natural monopoly. Almost all production and distribution costs are fixed. Marginal production and distribution costs are almost nil. Once the local news stories and local advertising copy are written, there is practically no additional cost involved with expanding production from, say, 200,000 to 300,000 newspapers per day. Once a daily edition is produced, marginal costs may be as little as 5 per newspaper. When marginal production costs are minimal, price competition turns vicious. Whichever competitor is out in front in terms of total circulation simply keeps prices down until the competition goes out of business or is forced into accepting a joint operating agreement. This is exactly what happened in Denver. Until 2001, the cost of a daily newspaper in Denver was only 25 each weekday and 50 on Sunday at the newsstand, and even less when purchased on an annual subscription basis. The smaller News had much higher unit costs and simply couldnt afford to compete with the Post at such ruinously low prices. Starting January 22, 2001, the publishing operations of the News and the Post were consolidated. The Denver Newspaper Agency, owned 50/50 by the

B.

owners of the News and Post, is now responsible for the advertising, circulation, production and other business departments of the newspapers. Newsrooms and editorial functions remain independent. Therefore, the owners of the News and Post are now working together to achieve financial success, but the newsroom operations remain competitors. Under terms of the agreement, E.W. Scripps Co., parent of the struggling News, agreed to pay owners of the Post $60 million. Both newspapers publish separately Monday through Friday. The News publishes the only Saturday paper and the Post the only Sunday paper. At the time the joint operating agreement was formed, neither news organization would speculate on job losses or advertising and circulation rate increases from the deal. Both proclaimed that neither job losses nor rate increases would be substantial. In fact, the company announced significant job cuts and steep advertising rate increases in the period following formation of the joint operating agreement. For example, Jake Jabs, who owns the American Furniture Warehouse chain in Denver, said his contract came up for renewal in February, 2001, and joint operating agreement executives said theyd keep his rates the same until they could negotiate a new agreement in March, 2001. However, in March, 2001, newspaper officials proposed a new fouryear contract for Jabs that required ads in both papers, with a 100% rate increase the first year, and 25% per year for the following three years. Jabs and other major local advertisers were so incensed that they sued in federal court. They lost. In early 2001, U. S. District Judge John Kane Jr. rejected a preliminary injunction sought by Jabs and a coalition of retailers called Coloradans Against Newspaper Monopolies. They wanted to roll back new ad rates at the News and the Post, and accused the papers of violating advertisers free speech rights by raising ad rates too high. Kane found no authority in support of the alleged constitutional violation, and the suit was dismissed. Kane said antitrust laws prohibiting business monopolies dont apply to newspapers in joint operating agreements. The circulations of the Post and the News fell sharply after the two newspapers dropped deep discounts on subscription rates. In the first two months after the two papers combined business operations and began sharing profits, the News lost 17.9 percent of its Monday through Saturday circulation and the Post lost 11.9 percent. The News Monday-through-Saturday circulation dropped from 446,465 to 366,499, and Post circulation dropped from 413,730 to 364,451. Sunday circulation for the News dropped from 552,085 to 448,032, and the Posts Sunday circulation dropped from 558,560 to 522,903. Despite the losses, both papers remain among the top 20 largest weekday papers in the nation. Combined circulation places the Sunday Post as the fifth-largest Sunday paper in the nation, with 970,935. The top four Sunday papers are The New York Times, The Washington Post , the Los Angeles Times and the Chicago Tribune. P12.3 Price Fixing. An antitrust case launched more than a decade ago sent tremors throughout the academic community. Over the 1989 -91 period, the

Department of Justice (DOJ) investigated a number of highly selective private colleges for price fixing. The investigation focused on overlap group meetings comprised of about half of the most selective private colleges and universities in the United States. The group included 23 colleges, from small liberal arts schools like Colby, Vassar, and Middlebury to larger research universities like Princeton and MIT. DOJ found that when students applied to more than one of the 23 institutions, school officials met to coordinate the exact calculation of such students financial need. Although all of the overlap colleges attempted to use the same need formula, difficult-to-interpret information from students and parents introduced some variation into their actual need calculations. DOJ alleged that the meetings enabled the colleges to collude on higher tuition and to increase their tuition revenue. The colleges defended their meetings, saying that they needed coordination to fully cover the needs of students from lowincome families. Although colleges want able needy students to add diversity to their student body, no college can afford a disproportionate share of needy students simply because it makes relatively generous need calculations. Although the colleges denied DOJs price-fixing allegation, they discontinued their annual meetings in1991. A. B. P12.3 A. How would you determine if the overlap college meetings resulted in price fixing? If price fixing did indeed occur at these meetings, which laws might be violated?

SOLUTION The effects of the DOJ overlap group inquiry has become the subject of an interesting study by the National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc. The NBER study found no evidence that the overlap colleges were colluding to raise tuition, raise net tuition revenue, or to save expenditures on grants. Both the overlap colleges and the control colleges raised tuition about 4 percent a year both before and after the antitrust action. However, as a result of the suit, financial aid at the overlap colleges became less progressive with respect to parents income and more sensitive to the merit of individual students, as measured by standard aptitude tests. In other words, financial aid became less sensitive to parents income and more able students obtained more aid. As a consequence of the DOJ case, the apparent trend in overlap colleges is to have a student body with proportionately more well-off students and relatively fewer black and Hispanic students. Apparently, DOJ found it difficult to apply standard economic analysis to college education. Although students are consumers of education, they are also producers in sense that peers affect the student experience. Many students would like colleges to maintain need-based aid for others, but make exceptions for them if they fail to qualify. (Note: Founded in 1920, NBER

is a private, nonprofit, nonpartisan research organization dedicated to promoting a greater understanding of how the economy works. NBER research is conducted by more than 600 university professors around the country.) B. P12.4 If price-fixing is indeed the intent and logical result of the financial-aid overlap meetings, a violation of Section 1 of the Sherman Act could be involved. Tying Contracts. In a celebrated case tried during 1998, The Department of Justice charged Microsoft Corporation with a wide range of anti-competitive behavior. Among the charges leveled by the DOJ was the allegation that Microsoft illegally bundled the sale of its Microsoft Explorer Internet browser software with its basic Windows operating system. DOJ alleged that by offering a free browser program Microsoft was able to extend its operating system monopoly and substantially lessen competition and tend to create a monopoly in the browser market by undercutting rival Netscape Communications, Inc. Microsoft retorted that it had the right to innovate and broaden the capability of its operating system software over time. Moreover, Microsoft noted that Netscape distributed its rival Internet browser software Netscape Navigator free to customers, and that it was merely meeting the competition by offering its own free browser program. A. Explain how Microsofts bundling of free Internet browser software with its Windows operating system could violate U.S. antitrust laws, and be sure to mention which laws in particular might be violated. Who was right in this case? In other words, did Microsofts bundling of Microsoft Explorer with Windows extend its operating system monopoly and substantially lessen competition and tend to create a monopoly in the browser market?

B.

P12.4 A.

SOLUTION Section 3 of the Clayton Act forbids tying contracts that reduce competition. A firm, particularly one with a patent on a vital process or a monopoly on a natural resource, could use licensing or other arrangements to restrict competition. One such method was the tying contract, whereby a firm tied the acquisition of one item to the purchase of another. For example, IBM once refused to sell its business machines. It only rented machines to customers and then required them to buy IBM punch cards, materials, and maintenance service. This had the effect of reducing competition in these related industries. The IBM lease agreement was declared illegal under the Clayton Act, and the company was forced to offer machines for sale and to separate leasing arrangements from agreements to purchase other IBM products. Clearly, in the 1998 case, The Department of Justice argued that

Microsoft had engaged in a similar pattern of anticompetitive behavior. If the market for Internet browser software can indeed be seen as distinct from the market for desktop PC software, then DOJ would appear to have a case that Microsoft illegally bundled the sale of its Microsoft Explorer Internet browser software with its basic Windows operating system. If the market for Internet browser software is not distinct from the market for desktop PC software, then the DOJ case would appear to be meddling in software design, as critics allege. B. As stated in part A, if the market for Internet browser software can indeed be seen as distinct from the market for desktop PC software, then the DOJ would appear to have a case that Microsoft illegally bundled the sale of its Microsoft Explorer Internet browser software with its basic Windows operating system. On the other hand, if the market for Internet browser software is not distinct from the market for desktop PC software, then support would be gained for Microsofts contention that it has the right to innovate and broaden the capability of its operating system software over time. The governments case seems to have been weakened by Microsofts observation that Netscape distributed its rival Internet browser software Netscape Navigator free to customers. This suggests that Microsoft may indeed have merely moved to meet the competition in the browser market. It is also worth noting that Netscape Navigator continues to have an important share of the browser market, and the profits of Netscapes parent-company AOL-Time Warner continue to flourish. Monopoly Price/Output Decision. The Hair Stylist, Ltd., has a monopoly in the College Park market because of restrictive licensing requirements, and not because of superior operating efficiency. As a monopoly, the Hair Stylist provides all industry output. For simplicity, assume that the Hair Stylist operates a chain of salons and that each shop has an average costminimizing activity level of 750 hair stylings per month, with Marginal Cost = Average Total Cost = $20 per styling. Assume that demand and marginal revenue curves for hair stylings in the College Park market are P = $80 - $0.0008Q MR = $80 - $0.0016Q Where P is price per unit, MR is marginal revenue, and Q is total firm output (stylings). A. B. Calculate the competitive market long-run equilibrium activity level, and the monopoly profitmaximizing price/output combination. Calculate monopoly profits, and discuss the monopoly problem from a

P12.5

social perspective in this instance. P12.5 A. SOLUTION The competitive market long-run equilibrium activity level is obtained by setting marginal revenue equal to marginal cost at the average-cost minimizing output level. In this case, the competitive market long-run equilibrium price is where P = MC = ATC = $20. Setting P = MR = MC and solving for Q: P $80 - $0.0008Q $0.0008Q = MC = $20 = $60

Q = 75,000 hair stylings per month. The competitive market long-run equilibrium price is equal to marginal cost at the average-cost minimizing activity level P = $20

The monopoly profitmaximizing activity level is obtained by setting marginal revenue equal to marginal cost, or marginal profit equal to zero (M = 0), and solving for Q: MR $80 - $0.0016Q $0.0016Q = MC = $20 = $60

Q = 37,500 hair stylings per month. Under monopoly, the optimal market price is P = $80 - $0.0008(37,500) = $50 B. At the Q = 37,500 monopoly activity level, the Hair Stylist will operate a chain of 50 salons (= 37,500/750). Although each outlet produces Q = 750 hairstylings per month, a point of optimum efficiency, the benefits of this efficiency accrue to the company in the form of economic profits rather than to consumers in the form of lower prices. Economic profits from each shop

are = TR - TC = P Q - AC Q = $50(750) - $20(750) = $22,500 per month With 50 shops, the Hair Stylist earns total economic profits of $1,125,000 (= 50 $22,500) per month. As a monopoly, the industry provides only 37,500 units of output, down from the 75,000 units provided in the case of a perfectly competitive industry. The new price of $50 per hairstyling is up substantially from the perfectly competitive price of $20. The effects of monopoly power are reflected in terms of higher consumer prices, reduced levels of output, and substantial unwarranted economic profits for the Hair Stylist, Inc. P12.6 Deadweight Loss From Monopoly. The Onondaga County Resource Recovery (OCRRA) system assumed responsibility for solid waste management on November 1, 1990, for thirty-three of the thirty-five municipalities in Onondaga County, New York. OCRRA is a non-profit public benefit corporation similar to the New York State Thruway Authority. It is not an arm of county government. Its Board of Directors is comprised of volunteers who develop programs and policies for the management of solid waste. The OCRRA Board is responsible for adopting a budget that ensures there will be sufficient revenues to cover expenditures. It does not rely on county taxes. OCRRA has implemented an aggressive series of programs promoting waste reduction and recycling where markets exist to create new products. While a number of communities struggle to surpass the 20% recycling mark, Onondaga County's households and commercial outlets currently recycle more than 67% of the waste that once was buried in landfills. Converting non-recyclable waste into energy (electricity) is also a top priority. To show the deadweight loss from monopoly problem, assume that monthly OCRRAs market supply and demand conditions are: QS QD = -2,000,000 + 10,000P = 1,750,000 - 5,000P (Market Supply) (Market Demand)

where Q is the number of customers served, and P is the market price of annual trash hauling and recycling service. A. Graph and calculate the equilibrium price/output solution. How much consumer surplus, producer surplus, and social welfare is produced at

this activity level? B. Use the graph to help you determine the deadweight for consumers and the producer if the market is run by unregulated profitmaximizing monopoly. (Note: If monopoly market demand is P = $350 - $0.0002Q, then the monopolists MR = $350 - $0.0004Q.)

P12.6 A.

SOLUTION The market supply curve is given by the equation QS = -2,000,000 + 10,000P or, solving for price, 10,000P = 2,000,000 + QS P = $200 + $0.0001QS The market demand curve is given by the equation QD = 1,750,000 - 5,000P or, solving for price, 5,000P = 1,750,000 - QD P = $350 - $0.0002QD To find the competitive market equilibrium price, equate the market demand and market supply curves where quantity is expressed as a function of price: Supply = Demand -2,000,000 + 10,000P = 1,750,000 - 5,000P 15,000P = 3,750,000 P = $250 To find the competitive market equilibrium quantity, set equal the market supply and market demand curves where price is expressed as a function of quantity, and QS = QD: Supply = Demand

$200 + $0.0001QS = $350 - $0.0002QD $0.0003Q = $150 Q = 500,000 Therefore, the competitive market equilibrium price-output combination is a market price of $250 with an equilibrium output of 500,000 customers served. The value of consumer surplus is equal to the region under the market demand curve that lies above the market equilibrium price of $250. Because the area of such a triangle is one-half the value of the base times the height, the value of consumer surplus equals: Consumer Surplus = [500,000 ($350 - $250)]

= $25 million In words, this means that at a competitive market price of $250 the quantity demanded is 500,000, resulting in total revenues of $125 million per year. The fact that consumer surplus equals $25 million means that customers as a group would have been willing to pay an additional $25 million per year for this amount of service. This is an amount above and beyond the $125 million paid per year. Customers received a real bargain. The value of producer surplus is equal to the region above the market supply curve at the market equilibrium price of $250. Because the area of such a triangle is one-half the value of the base times the height, the value of producer surplus equals: Producer Surplus = [500,000 ($250 - $200)]

= $12.5 million At a competitive market price for trash hauling and recycling service of $250, producer surplus equals $12.5 million per year. Producers as a group received $12.5 million per year more than the absolute minimum required for them to produce the market equilibrium output of 500,000 customers served. Producers received a real bargain. In competitive market equilibrium, social welfare is measured by the sum of net benefits derived by consumers and producers. Social welfare is the sum of consumer surplus and producer surplus: Social Welfare = Consumer Surplus + Producer Surplus = $25 million + $12.5 million = $37.5 million per year

B.

If the industry is run by a profit-maximizing monopolist, the optimal priceoutput combination can be determined by setting marginal revenue equal to marginal cost and solving for Q: MR = MC = Market Supply $350 - $0.0004Q = $200 + 0.0001Q $0.0005Q = $150 Q = 300,000 At Q = 300,000, P = $350 - $0.0002Q = $350 - $0.0002(300,000) = $290 per barrel Under monopoly, the amount supplied falls to 300,000 and the market price jumps to $290 per year for trash hauling and recycling service. The amount of deadweight loss from monopoly suffered by consumers is given by the triangle bounded by ABD in the figure. Because the area of such a triangle is one-half the value of the base times the height, the value of lost consumer surplus due to monopoly equals: Consumer Deadweight Loss = [(500,000 - 300,000) ($290 - $250)]

= $4 million per year The amount of deadweight loss from monopoly suffered by producers is given by the triangle bounded by BCD. Because the area of a such a triangle is one-half the value of the base times the height, the value of lost producer surplus equals: Producer Deadweight Loss = [(500,000 - 300,000) ($250 - $230)]

= $2 million per year The total amount of deadweight loss from monopoly suffered by consumers and producers is given by the triangle bounded by ACD. The area of a such a triangle is simply the amount of consumer deadweight loss plus producer

deadweight loss: Total Deadweight Loss = Consumer Loss + Producer Loss = $4 million + $2 million = $6 million per year P12.7 Wealth Transfer Problem. The Organization of the Petroleum Exporting Countries (OPEC) was formed on September 14, 1960 in Baghdad, Iraq. The current membership is comprised of five founding members plus six others: Algeria, Indonesia, Iran, Iraq, Kuwait, Libya, Nigeria, Qatar, Saudi Arabia, the United Arab Emirates and Venezuela. OPECs stated mission is to bring stability and harmony to the oil market by adjusting their oil output to help ensure a balance between supply and demand. At least twice a year, OPEC members meet to adjust OPECs output level in light of anticipated oil market developments. OPEC's eleven members collectively supply about 40 per cent of the world's oil output and possess more than three-quarters of the world's total proven crude oil reserves. To demonstrate the deadweight loss from monopoly problem, imagine that market supply and demand conditions for crude oil are: QS QD = 2P = 180 - 4P (Market Supply) (Market Demand)

where Q is barrels of oil per day (in millions) and P is the market price of oil. A. Graph and calculate the equilibrium price/output solution. How much consumer surplus, producer surplus, and social welfare is produced at this activity level? Use the graph to help you ascertain the amount of consumer surplus transferred to the monopoly producer following a change from a competitive market to a monopoly market. How much is the net gain in producer surplus?

B.

P12.7 A.

SOLUTION The market supply curve is given by the equation QS = 2P or, solving for price, P = 0.5QS

The market demand curve is given by the equation QD = 180 - 4P or, solving for price, 4P = 180 - QD P = $45 - $0.25QD To find the competitive market equilibrium price, equate the market demand and market supply curves where quantity is expressed as a function of price: Supply = Demand 2P = 180 - 4P 6P = 180 P = $30 To find the competitive market equilibrium quantity, set equal the market supply and market demand curves where price is expressed as a function of quantity, and QS = QD: Supply = Demand $0.5Q = $45 - $0.25Q $0.75Q = $45 Q = 60 (million) barrels per day Therefore, the competitive market equilibrium price-output combination is a market price of $30 with an equilibrium output of 60 (million) barrels per day. The value of consumer surplus is equal to the region under the market demand curve that lies above the market equilibrium price of $30. Because the area of such a triangle is one-half the value of the base times the height, the value of consumer surplus equals: Consumer Surplus = [60 ($45 - $30)]

= $450 (million) per day

In words, this means that at a competitive market price of $30 per barrel, the quantity demanded is 60 (million barrels per day), resulting in total revenues of $1,800 (million) per day. The fact that consumer surplus equals $450 (million) per day means that customers as a group would have been willing to pay an additional $450 (million) per day for this level of market output. This is an amount above and beyond the $1,800 (million) paid per day. Customers received a real bargain. The value of producer surplus is equal to the region above the market supply curve at the market equilibrium price of $30. Because the area of such a triangle is one-half the value of the base times the height, the value of producer surplus equals: Producer Surplus = [60 ($30 - $0)]

= $900 (million) per day At a competitive market price for oil of $30 per barrel, producer surplus equals $900 (million) per day. Producers as a group received $900 (million) per day more than the absolute minimum required for them to produce the market equilibrium output of 60 (million) barrels of oil per day. Producers received a real bargain. In competitive market equilibrium, social welfare is measured by the sum of net benefits derived by consumers and producers. Social welfare is the sum of consumer surplus and producer surplus: Social Welfare = Consumer Surplus + Producer Surplus = $450 (million) + $900 (million) = $1,350 (million) per day

B.

The amount of deadweight loss from monopoly suffered by the monopoly producer is given by the triangle bounded by BCD. Because the area of such a triangle is one-half the value of the base times the height, the value of lost producer surplus equals: Producer Deadweight Loss = [(60 - 45) ($30 - $22.50)]

= $56.25 (million) per day

The creation of a monopoly also results in a significant transfer from consumer surplus to producer surplus. In the figure, this amount is shown as the area in the rectangle bordered by PCMPMAB: Transfer to Producer Surplus = 45 ($33.75 - $30) = $168.75 (million) per day Therefore, from the viewpoint of the producer, the change to monopoly results in a very favorable net increase in producer surplus: Net Change in Producer Surplus = Producer Deadweight Loss + Transfer = -$56.25 (million) + $168.75 (million) = $112.5 (million) per day The wealth transfer problem associated with monopoly is seen as an issue of equity or fairness because it involves the distribution of income or wealth in the economy. Although economic profits serve the useful functions of providing incentives and helping allocate resources, it is difficult to justify monopoly profits that result from the raw exercise of market power rather than from exceptional performance. P12.8 Monopoly Profits. Parvati Fluid Controls, Inc., (PFC) is a major supplier of reverse osmosis and ultrafiltration equipment, which helps industrial and commercial customers achieve improved production processes and a cleaner work environment. The company has recently introduced a new line of ceramic filters that enjoy patent protection. Relevant cost and revenue relations for this product are as follows: TR = $300Q - $0.001Q2 MR = TR/Q = $300 - $0.002Q TC = $9,000,000 + $20Q + $0.0004Q2 MC = TC/Q = $20 + $0.0008Q where TR is total revenue, Q is output, MR is marginal revenue, TC is total cost, including a risk-adjusted normal rate of return on investment, and MC is marginal cost. A. As a monopoly, calculate PFCs optimal price/output combination.

B. P12.8 A.

Calculate monopoly profits and the optimal profit margin at this profitmaximizing activity level.

SOLUTION Set MR = MC to find the optimal price/output combination: MR = MC $300 - $0.002Q = $20 + $0.0008Q 0.0028Q = 280 Q = 100,000 P = TR/Q = ($300Q - $0.001Q2)/Q = $300 - $0.001Q = $300 - $0.001(100,000) = $200

B.

Because the cost of capital is already included in the total cost function, any excess of revenues over total cost represents economic profits. = TR - TC = $300Q - $0.001Q2 - $9,000,000 - $20Q -$0.0004Q2 = -$0.0014Q2 + $280Q -$9,000,000 = -$0.0014(100,0002) + $280(100,000) - $9,000,000 = $5,000,000 And finally, the optimal profit margin is: Profit Margin = /TR = $5,000,000/$200(100,000) = 0.25 or 25%

P12.9

Monopoly versus Competitive Market Equilibrium. During recent years, MicroChips Corp. has enjoyed substantial economic profits derived from patents covering a wide range of inventions and innovations for microprocessors used in high-performance desktop computers. A recent introduction, the Penultimate, has proven especially profitable. Market demand and marginal revenue relations for the product are as follows: P = $5,500 - $0.005Q MR = TR/Q = $5,500 - $0.01Q Fixed costs are nil because research and development expenses have been fully amortized during previous periods. Average variable costs are constant at $4,500 per unit. A. Calculate the profit-maximizing price/output combination and economic profits if MicroChips enjoys an effective monopoly because of patent protection. Calculate the price/output combination and total economic profits that would result if competitors offer clones that make the market perfectly competitive.

B.

P12.9 A.

SOLUTION The profit-maximizing price/output combination is found by setting MR = MC. Because AVC is constant, MC = AVC = $4,500. Therefore: MR = MC $5,500 - $0.01Q = $4,500 0.01Q = 1,000 Q = 100,000 P = $5,500 - $0.005(100,000) = $5,000 Economic Profits = P Q - AVC Q = $5,000(100,000) - $4,500(100,000) = $50,000,000 (Note: As a monopolist, the company is the industry).

B.

In a competitive market, P = MC. In this instance, AVC is constant and, therefore, MC = AVC. Competitive market equilibrium occurs where: P $5,500 - $0.005Q 0.005Q Q P = MC = AVC = $4,500 = 1,000 = 200,000 = $5,500 - $0.005(200,000) = $4,500 Economic Profits = P Q - AVC Q = $4,500(200,000) - $4,500(200,000) = $0 In words, the transformation from monopoly to perfect competition has brought a $1,000 reduction in price and a 100,000 unit expansion in output. At the same time, economic profits have been eliminated.

P12.10

Monopoly/Monopsony Confrontation. Safecard Corporation offers a unique service. The company notifies credit card issuers after being informed that a subscriber's credit card has been lost or stolen. The Safecard service is sold to card issuers on an annual subscription basis. Relevant revenue and cost relations for the service are as follows: TR = $5Q - $0.00001Q2 MR TC MC = TR/Q = $5 - $0.00002Q = $50,000 + $0.5Q + $0.000005Q2 = TC/Q = $0.5 + $0.00001Q

where TR is total revenue, Q is output measured in terms of the number of subscriptions in force, MR is marginal revenue, TC is total cost, including a risk-adjusted normal rate of return on investment, and MC is marginal cost. A. If Safecard has a monopoly in this market, calculate the profitmaximizing price/output combination and optimal total profit.

B.

Calculate Safecard's optimal price, output, and profits if credit card issuers effectively exert monopsony power and force a perfectly competitive equilibrium in this market.

P12.10 A.

SOLUTION The profit-maximizing monopoly price/output combination is found by setting MR = MC and solving for Q: MR $5 - $0.00002Q 0.00003Q Q P = MC = $0.5 + $0.00001Q, = 4.5 = 150,000 = TR/Q = $5 - $0.00001Q = $5 - $0.00001(150,000) = $3.50 = TR - TC = -$0.000015(150,0002) + $4.5(150,000) = $287,500 (Note: Profit is falling for Q > 150,000.)

$50,000

B.

If credit card issuers effectively exert monopsony power and force a perfectly competitive equilibrium, P = MR and, therefore, P = MC at the average cost minimizing output level. To find the output level where average cost is minimized, set MC = AC and solve for Q: MC $0.5 + $0.00001Q $0.5 + $0.00001Q 50,000Q-1 50,000Q-2 = AC = ($50,000 + $0.5Q + $0.000005Q2)/Q = $50,000Q1 + $0.5 + $0.000005Q = 0.000005Q = 0.000005 = 0.000005

= = 100,000

AC $0.000005(100,000)

= $50,000/100,000 = $1.50

$0.5

At the average-cost minimizing output level, MC = AC = $1.50. Because P = MR in a perfectly competitive industry, at the profit-maximizing output level: P $0.000005(100,0002) = $0 (Note: Average cost is rising for Q > 100,000.) CASE STUDY FOR CHAPTER 12 Effect of R&D on Tobins q The idea of using the difference between the market value of the firm and accounting book values as an indicator of market power and/or valuable intangible assets stems from the pioneering work of Nobel laureate James Tobin. Tobin introduced the so-called q ratio, defined as the ratio of the market value of the firm divided by the replacement cost of tangible assets. For a competitive firm in a stable industry with no special capabilities, and no barriers to entry or exit, one would expect q to be close to one (q 1). In a perfectly competitive industry, any momentary propensity for q > 1 due to an unanticipated rise in demand or decrease in costs would be quickly erased by entry or established firm growth. In a perfectly competitive industry, any momentary propensity for q < 1 due to an unanticipated fall in demand or increase in costs would be quickly erased by exit or contraction among established firms. In the absence of barriers to entry and exit, the marginal value of q would trend towards unity (q 1) over time in perfectly competitive industries. Similarly, a firm that is regulated so as to earn no monopoly rents would also have a q close to one. Only in the case of firms with monopoly power protected by significant barriers to entry or exit, or firms with superior profit-making capabilities, will Tobins q ratio rise above one, and stay there. In the limit, the theoretical maximum Tobins q ratio is observed in the case of a highly efficient monopoly. If q > 1 on a persistent basis, one can argue that the firm is in possession of market power or some hard-to-duplicate asset that typically escapes measurement using = MR = MC = AC = $1.50 = P Q - TC = $1.50(100,000) $50,000 $0.5(100,000) -

conventional accounting criteria. Tobins q ratio surged during the 1990s, and some made the simple conclusion that monopoly profits had soared during this period. In the early 1990s, however, the overall economy suffered a sharp recession that dramatically reduced corporate profits and stock prices. By the end of the 1990s, the economy had logged the longest peacetime expansion in history, and both corporate profits and stock prices soared to record levels. Corporate profits, stock and Tobins q ratios for major corporations took a sharp tumble over the 2000-03 period as the country entered a mild recession. Therefore, much of the year-to-year variation in Tobins q ratios for corporate giants can be explained by the business cycle. At any point in time, more fundamental changes are also at work. Leading firms today are characterized by growing reliance on what economists refer to as intangible assets, like advertising capital, brand names, customer goodwill, patents, and so on. Empirically, q > 1 if valuable intangible assets derived from R&D and other such expenditures with the potential for long-lived benefits are systematically excluded from consideration by accounting methodology. The theoretical argument that q 1 over time only holds when the economic values of both tangible and intangible assets are precisely measured. If q > 1 on a persistent basis, and Tobins q is closely tied to the level of R&D intensity, one might argue successfully for the presence of intangible R&D capital. Table 12.3 here In Table 12.3, q is approximated by the sum of the market value of common plus the book values of preferred stock and total liabilities, all divided by the book value of tangible assets, for a sample of corporate giants included in the Dow Jones Industrial Average (DJIA). To learn the role played by R&D intensity as a determinant of Tobins q, the effects of other important factors must be constrained, including: current profitability, growth, and risk. Current profitability is measured by the firms net profit margin, or net income divided by sales. Positive stock-price effects of net profit margins can be anticipated because historical profit margins are often the best available indicator of a firms ability to generate superior rates of return during future periods. Stock-price effects of profit margins include both the influences of superior efficiency and/or market power. Because effective R&D can be expected to enhance both current and future profitability, the marginal effect of R&D intensity on Tobins q becomes a very conservative estimate of the total short-term plus long-term value of R&D when such impacts are considered in conjunction with the stock-price effects of current net profit margins. Revenue growth will have a positive effect on market values if future investments are expected to earn abovenormal rates of return and if growth is an important determinant of these returns. While growth affects the magnitude of anticipated excess returns, a stock-price influence may also be associated with the degree of return stability. Influences of risk are estimated here using stock-price beta. With an increase in risk, the market value of expected returns is anticipated to fall. A. B. Explain how any intangible capital effects of R&D intensity can reflect the effects of market power and/or superior efficiency. A multiple regression analysis based upon the data contained in Table 12.3 revealed the following (t statistics in parentheses):

q 9.046 R&D/S (3.10)

= 1.825 + 7.358 Profit Margin + 0.220 Growth - 0.711 Beta + (3.79) (2.77) (0.08) (-2.42)

R2 = 55.3%, F statistic = 7.73 Are these results consistent with the idea that R&D gives rise to a type of intangible capital? CASE STUDY SOLUTION A. Intangible R&D capital can be derived from the value obtained from patents and other monopoly protections offered to firms making significant new discoveries and innovations. Alternatively, significant R&D capital can result from the nonpatented advantages gained from effective basic research and applied development. In economic terminology, superior rewards earned from exceptional productive capability or superior effort are called Ricardian rents after the early British economist David Ricardo. Monopoly rents which are usually regarded as unjust compensation for the antisocial exercise of market power through high prices. Richardian rents are conventionally regarded as fair compensation for superior productive capability that results in higher revenues or lower production costs. To the extent that the firm possesses factors which increase revenues or lower costs relative to the marginal firm, it will persistently display q > 1. To the extent that productive R&D allows the firm to increase revenues and/or lower costs, and thereby persistently display q > 1, the firm can be said to possess significant unmeasured intangible R&D capital. It is worth noting that this study compares a stock measure, the market value of the firm, with the flow of R&D expenditures. On a theoretical basis, it would seem more appropriate to compare market values with the stocks of intangible capital tied to R&D. However, if economic amortization of the exponential decay type can be assumed, along with constant percentage rates of growth in R&D expenditures, then the magnitude of intangible capital equals annual expenditures on R&D multiplied by a constant. Given these assumptions, the stock of intangible R&D capital is strictly proportional to the flow of R&D expenditures, and the net income and stock-price effects of R&D expenditures can be taken as indicative of intangible capital influences. Yes, these results are consistent with the idea that R&D gives rise to a type of intangible capital. On an overall basis, the simple model estimated here explains more than one-half (55.3%) of the variation in Tobins q ratio seen for the giant corporations included in the DJIA. This is a statistically significant explanation ( F = 7.73) of a meaningful share of q variation.

B.

Positive and statistically significant stock-price effects of net profit margins reflect the effects of superior efficiency and/or market power. Because effective R&D can be expected to enhance both current and future profitability, the marginal effect of R&D intensity on Tobins q is a very conservative estimate of the total short-term plus long-term value of R&D when such impacts are considered in conjunction with the stock-price effects of current net profit margins. For this sample of firms, revenue growth fails to exhibit the expected positive effect on market values, but influences of risk are found using stock-price beta. With an increase in risk, the market value of expected returns appears to fall, as anticipated. Interestingly, R&D intensity appears to have a consistently positive effect on the Tobins q, even after allowing for the market value-effects of current profit margins. These results are consistent with the hypothesis that R&D makes an important contribution to the long-term profitability of the firm, and gives rise to a type of intangible capital with long-lived influences. In considering the economic determinants of Tobins q it is important that the effects of superior efficiency or capability be separated from the simple influences of market power. More detailed consideration of the favorable long-term effects of R&D is a small step in this direction.

Das könnte Ihnen auch gefallen