Sie sind auf Seite 1von 7

APPLIED STOCHASTIC MODELS IN BUSINESS AND INDUSTRY Appl. Stochastic Models Bus. Ind.

, 2005; 21:397402 Published online in Wiley InterScience (www.interscience.wiley.com). DOI: 10.1002/asmb.577

The proper interpretation of sales promotion eects: supplement elasticities with absolute sales eects
Harald J. van Heerde*,y,z
Faculty of Economics and Business Administration, Tilburg University, P.O. Box 90153, 5000 LE Tilburg, The Netherlands

SUMMARY Sales promotions such as temporary price reductions are frequently used by managers to stimulate sales in the short run. Marketing academics and practitioners tend to rely on price elasticities to summarize sales promotion eects. Although elasticities have some attractive benets such as the invariance to measurement units, they have led to three misinterpretations in the marketing literature, as described in this paper. The proper theoretical and managerial interpretation of sales promotion eects is obtained by expressing eects in terms of absolute sales. Copyright # 2005 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.
KEY WORDS:

sales promotions; elasticities; sales eects

1. INTRODUCTION Sales promotions are frequently used by managers to stimulate sales in the short run. The sales eects tend to be huge [1]. Over the past decades, a substantial part of the marketing literature has been devoted to sales promotion eect measurement [2]. The claim in this paper is that despite this vast literature, our understanding of sales promotion eects is incomplete, and that this has been caused by misinterpretations of price elasticities. We dene price elasticities as the percentage change in a criterion variable as the result of a 1% temporary price cut.} Elasticities have attractive properties, such as their invariance to measurement units, and their comparability across brands, categories, and markets if they are based on the same dependent and independent variables. However, if elasticities refer to dierent dependent and independent variables, the comparison of elasticities can be misleading, as we demonstrate in this paper. To enhance the comparability, we propose to use absolute sales eects. Absolute sales eects are dened as the change in unit

*Correspondence to: Harald J. van Heerde, Department of Marketing, Tilburg University, P.O. Box 90153, 5000 LE Tilburg, The Netherlands. y E-mail: heerde@uvt.nl z Professor of Marketing. } From now on, we use the term elasticities instead of price elasticities. Contract/grant sponsor: Netherland Organization for Scientic Research

Copyright # 2005 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.

398

H. J. VAN HEERDE

sales for a criterion variable as a result of a sales promotion. Unit sales eects are preferable since sales promotions are by denition instruments to promote sales. Therefore, any measurement tool or marketing model that is intended to measure the eectiveness of sales promotions should ultimately report the results in terms of absolute sales eects. In addition, absolute sales eects are more tightly connected to prots than elasticities are [3]. That is, incremental prot calculations require the combination of absolute sales eects with margin and cost data. Elasticities have to be transformed to absolute sales eects before prots can be computed [3]. Among marketing academics, the use of elasticities has led to three misunderstandings. One goal of this paper is to briey summarize these misunderstandings (Sections 24). A second goal is to translate their resolutions into managerial implications (Section 5). Third, we present directions for future research (Section 6), and we end with some concluding remarks (Section 7).

2. ASYMMETRY IN BRAND SWITCHING In a seminal paper in sales promotion research [4], the authors nd that the cross-price elasticity of high price, high quality brands on low-price, low quality brands is much stronger than the reverse cross-price elasticity. Thus, consumer switching is asymmetric, in the sense that higherquality brands attract more switchers if these are promoted than low-quality brands. Various rationales for the asymmetric switching eect have been provided in References [48]. Several empirical studies have validated the eect (e.g. Reference [9]). Despite the apparently strong theoretical and empirical support for asymmetric brand switching eects, Sethuraman et al. [10] show that the asymmetries tend to favour the higher priced brand simply because of scaling eects. They demonstrate that the asymmetries largely vanish if one uses absolute cross-price eects. Based on 1060 cross-price eects between 280 brands from 19 dierent grocery product categories, they conclude that a 10 cents price cut of a high-tier brand takes away as much market share points of a low-tier brand as is the case in the reverse situation. The study by Sethuraman and Srinivasan [3] goes one step further by showing a reversal of the commonly assumed asymmetry. That is, they show that low market share brands gain more share at promotions than high-share brands when absolute cross-price eects are considered. A similar phenomenon is shown in Reference [11]. The cross-price elasticity of Amazon.com on BarnesandNobles.com (3.5%) is much larger than the reverse cross-price elasticity (0.2%). However, the asymmetry is strongly reduced if one accounts for the fact that the sales of Amazon.com are much higher. The conclusion from References [3, 10, 11] is that in order to assess cross-price eects, one should use absolute eects rather than elasticities, since scaling eects can distort the conclusions from elasticities. These scaling eects occur both in the independent variable (price) and in the dependent variable (market share, sales).

3. MAGNITUDE OF BRAND SWITCHING A major breakthrough in sales promotion research was the application of the multinomial logit model for brand choice based on household-level purchase data obtained by scanning in
Copyright # 2005 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Appl. Stochastic Models Bus. Ind., 2005; 21:397402

INTERPRETATION OF SALES PROMOTION EFFECTS

399

supermarkets [1]. During the 1980s this model gained importance in the marketing literature and it became the dominant model in the 1990s. In his seminal paper in sales promotions research, Gupta [12] supplements the brand choice model with purchase incidence and purchase quantity models. He demonstrates that the sales elasticity due to promotions for coee can be decomposed into a brand choice elasticity (84%), a purchase incidence elasticity (14%), and a purchase quantity elasticity (2%). Bell et al. [13] analyse 173 brands from 13 categories with household-level panel data and conclude that on average the brand choice elasticity is 74%, the purchase incidence elasticity 11%, and purchase quantity elasticity is 15%. They also demonstrate that these percentages are dependent upon category characteristics such as the stockpileability of products. In the marketing literature, these ndings have been interpreted to mean that the main source contributing to the sales promotion eect (about 75%) is brand switching (see Table I in Reference [14]). Thus, if the promoted brand gains 100 units, the other brands in the category lose 75 units. However, Van Heerde et al. [14] show that this interpretation is incorrect. They transform the elasticity result into unit sales eects, and conclude that in the promotional week, the other brands only lose on average about 33 units, and that the category as a whole gains 67 units. This conclusion is based on the same set of 173 brands as in Reference [13] plus eight newly analysed brands using household panel data. In this case elasticities are incomparable because they refer to dierent dependent variables: purchase incidence probability, brand choice probability, and purchase quantity. Other research [15] shows that store-level data conrm that cross-brand eects in unit sales are about 1/3 of the own eect. Thus, this result seems independent of the data source (household or store). Recent research using time-series models also demonstrates the importance of short-term (one week) category expansion eects of sales promotions [16]. Long-term eects of sales promotions are nearly absent [16, 17]. Relatively strong category demand eects are consistent with theories that explain why retailers use promotions in the rst place. The theory by Blattberg et al. [18] says that promotions shift holding costs from the retailer to the consumer, whereas Jeuland and Narasimhan [19] consider sales promotions as price discrimination tools between high- and lowholding cost consumers. Both theories only consider temporary category demand eects of promotions and no brand switching eects.
Table I. Illustration of sales promotion eect measurement (tuna data).
Elasticity-based Unit sales D own fraction based fraction brand D cross-brand D category cross-brand cross-brand salesy eects eects salesy salesy 0.87 0.82 0.93 0.92 0.89 60 118 40 79 74 10 58 0 52 30 50 60 40 27 44 0.16 0.49 0.00 0.66 0.40

Brand 1 2 3 4 Average
n

Salesy # 1 90:8P2:28 S 1 # 2 220:9P1:92 S 2 3:09 # S 3 39:9P 3 1:87 # S 4 152:3P 4 2.29z #1 MS #2 MS #3 MS #4 MS

Market sharen
1:99 0:12P 1 1:57 0:28P 2 2:86 0:05P 3 1:71 0:20P 4

Category salesn # CS # CS # CS # CS
0:29 750:0P 1 0:35 750:0P 2 0:23 750:0P 3 0:16 750:0P 4

2.03z

0.26z

The model shows only the focal brands price index variable. All other marketing mix instruments are put equal to their non-promotional levels, and the intercept represents an average store and week. All parameter estimates are signicant (p50.05). Standard errors and p-values are available on request. y The column shows the eect of a 20% price cut for the focal brand. z The number represents the average price elasticity. Copyright # 2005 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Appl. Stochastic Models Bus. Ind., 2005; 21:397402

400

H. J. VAN HEERDE

4. MODELLING MARKET SHARES A common way of modelling at the aggregate level (store, chain) is to write brand sales as the product of market share and category sales: S MS * CS: It is easy to demonstrate that the sales elasticity can be decomposed into a market share elasticity and a category sales elasticity: @S P @MS P @CS P ZS ZMS ZCS @P S @P MS @P CS Perhaps one of the consequences of seemingly strong (yet overstated) cross-brand eects is that many studies in marketing at the aggregate data level (store, chain) use market share models without category sales models. In contrast, we suggest that even if market share elasticities dominate category sales elasticities, using market share models without category sales models leads to incomplete conclusions. To illustrate this point, let us consider the example in Table I. We specify constant elasticity models for sales, market shares, and category sales for four brands in the tuna category. The log of these three variables are used as dependent variables. These are separately explained by a set of independent variables: log price indices (actual over regular price), dummies for feature-only, display-only, feature and display, store and week.} In Table I, we show the OLS results based on store-level scanner data from 28 stores and 104 weeks. The average ZS 2:29; ZMS 2:03; and ZCS 0:26: Since the market share elasticity is 89% of the sales elasticity, this expression could suggest that cross-brand eects are dominant. However, the calculations in Table I show this conclusion is highly erroneous. We compute absolute sales eects of a 20% temporary price cut (one price index going from 1.00 to 0.80 during one week). All independent variables stay at their non-promotional values, which is 1.00 for price index variables and 0 for feature, display dummies.k The calculations show an average own brand sales increase of 74 units, which is for 40% attributable to a cross-brand sales loss and for 60% to an increase in category sales. For brand 3 we nd a particularly strong change. Whereas its strong market share elasticity (2.86, 93%) might suggest that its competitive impact is strong, actually competing brands do not lose sales if brand 3 is promoted. Thus, a strong market share elasticity does not imply that cross-brand eects are strong.

5. MANAGERIAL IMPLICATIONS There are important managerial implications from the assertions that brand switching is primarily symmetric and that the primary source of the sales promotion bump is not brand switching. For retailers symmetric switching means better news than asymmetric switching to high-tier brands, since their private labels are typically in low tiers. Conversely, for manufacturers of national brands symmetry is worse than asymmetric switching favouring high-tier brands. For retailers, the decomposition result also is good news. That is, promotions do not just redistribute purchases in the category, but can really make categories grow temporarily. For
}

Using the same set of independent variables and functional form for all three dependent variables ensures that the elasticities add up exactly. An attraction model is more common for market shares, but that model does not ensure exact additivity. k One may study interaction eects by simulating sales eects while manipulating two or more variables at the same time. Copyright # 2005 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Appl. Stochastic Models Bus. Ind., 2005; 21:397402

INTERPRETATION OF SALES PROMOTION EFFECTS

401

manufacturers, temporary category growth is also better than brand switching, since it implies less strong brand competition and also more opportunities to convince retailers to participate in sales promotions. However, one important caveat applies here, since part of the temporary category growth may be borrowed from other time periods due to e.g. stockpiling eects. Van Heerde et al. [15] nds that the borrowing eect is half of the temporary category growth.

6. FUTURE RESEARCH Future research on sales promotion eects could focus on the following question: if a promoted brand gains X units, where do these units come from? Some possible sources are brand switching, store switching, stockpiling, and increased consumption. To provide such a complete decomposition an elaborate household-level should be developed that includes all consumer responses corresponding to these sources. By simulating consumer behaviour with the model in the presence and absence of a sales promotion for one brand, it should be possible to quantify the magnitude (in unit sales) of all sources. Hitherto, no such model is available in the literature. Future research could also focus on the question whether household and store-level data yield similar conclusions on the magnitude of the decomposition eects in unit sales. In particular, it seems that cross-brand eects are about 1/3 in both cases [14, 15], but it is unclear to what extent equality holds for other decomposition eects. One would expect that store-level data give correct estimates of the magnitude of these eects, but that household-level data gives additional insights into consumer responses driving them. Another fruitful avenue for future research is on what really happens with buyers of nonpromoted brands. The elasticity decomposition suggests that buyers of non-promoted brands are drawn to the category by the promotion of the competing brand, and decrease their conditional choice probability of non-promoted brands to a large extent. An alternative scenario is that customers of the non-promoted brands are not drawn to the category due to the competing brands promotion. For managers, the rst scenario suggests that buyers of nonpromoted brands do consider the promoted brand, whereas in the second scenario they (almost) do not. Future research should show which scenario is more correct.

7. CONCLUDING REMARKS Importantly, we do not argue against computing elasticities or using constant-elasticity models. If they refer to similar dependent and independent variables, they can enhance our understanding of price (promotion) eects. One excellent example is a meta-analysis of own price elasticities across many studies [20], or within one study [13]. However, for a proper interpretation of sales promotion eects, it is inappropriate to compare elasticities across cases referring to dierent dependent and independent variables. One such example is the comparison of cross-brand elasticities from high- and low-tier brands. This comparison has led to the asymmetric brand switching result that has dominated the marketing literature for at least a decade, until Sethuraman et al. [10] proved it was untrue in absolute terms. A second example is the comparison of purchase incidence, brand choice, and purchase quantity elasticities. This has yielded the result that cross-brand eects are the primary source contributing to the sales promotion eect, until Van Heerde et al. [14] proved it was untrue in absolute sales eects. The
Copyright # 2005 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Appl. Stochastic Models Bus. Ind., 2005; 21:397402

402

H. J. VAN HEERDE

third example in this paper has shown that if market share elasticities are much larger than category sales elasticities, we still can encounter huge temporary category expansion eects. Therefore, we propose to supplement elasticities with absolute sales eects, not only to bridge the gap between academics and practitioners, but also to avoid misinterpretations among academics. We recommend to do this irrespective of what model (sales, market share, choice, incidence, etc.) or data (store level, household level, etc.) are being used.

ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS

The author thanks the Netherlands Organization for Scientic Research for its research support, A.C. Nielsen for providing the data, and the two guest editors, four anonymous reviewers, Tammo Bijmolt, Valentina Melnyk, and Dick Wittink for useful suggestions.

REFERENCES 1. Guadagni PM, Little JDC. A logit model calibrated on scanner data. Marketing Science 1983; 2(3):203238. 2. Neslin SA. Sales Promotion, Relevant Knowledge Series. Marketing Science Institute: Cambridge, MA, 2002. 3. Sethuraman R, Srinivasan V. The asymmetric share eect: an empirical generalization on cross-price eects. Journal of Marketing Research 2002; 39(August):379386. 4. Blattberg RC, Wisniewski KJ. Price-induced patterns of competition. Marketing Science 1989; 8(4):291309. 5. Allenby GM, Rossi PE. Quality perceptions and asymmetric switching between brands. Marketing Science 1991; 10(3):185204. 6. Hardie B, Johnson E, Fader P. Modeling loss aversion and reference dependence eects on brand choice. Marketing Science 1993; 12(4):378394. 7. Bronnenberg B, Wathieu L. Asymmetric promotion eects and brand positioning. Marketing Science 1996; 15(4):379394. 8. Sivakumar K. Asymmetric quality tier competition: an alternative explanation. Technical Working Paper Report No. 97-115. Marketing Science Institute: Boston, MA, July, 1997. 9. Mulhern FJ, Leone RP. Implicit price bundling of retail products: a multiproduct approach to maximizing store protability. Journal of Marketing 1991; 55(October):6376. 10. Sethuraman R, Srinivasan V, Kim D. Asymmetric and neighborhood cross-price eects: some empirical generalizations. Marketing Science 1999; 18(1):2341. 11. Chevalier J, Goolsbee A. Measuring prices and price competition online: Amazon.com and BarnesandNoble.com. Quantitative Marketing and Economics 2003; 1(2):203222. 12. Gupta S. Impact of sales promotion on when, what and how much to buy. Journal of Marketing Research 1988; 25(November):342355. 13. Bell DR, Chiang J, Padmanabhan V. The decomposition of promotional response: an empirical generalization. Marketing Science 1999; 18(4):504526. 14. Van Heerde HJ, Gupta S, Wittink DR. Is 75% of the sales promotion bump due to brand switching? No, only 33% is. Journal of Marketing Research 2003; 40(4):481491. 15. Van Heerde HJ, Leeang PSH, Wittink DR. Decomposing the sales promotion bump with store data. Marketing Science 2004; 23(3):317334. 16. Nijs V, Dekimpe MG, Steenkamp JBEM, Hanssens DM. The category demand eects of price promotions. Marketing Science 2001; 20(1):122. 17. Pauwels K, Hanssens DM, Siddarth S. The long-term eects of price promotions on category incidence, brand choice and purchase quantity. Journal of Marketing Research 2002; 39(4):421439. 18. Blattberg RC, Eppen GD, Lieberman J. A theoretical and empirical evaluation of price deals for consumer nondurables. Journal of Marketing 1981; 45(Winter):116129. 19. Jeuland AP, Narasimhan C. Dealing-temporary price cuts-by seller as a buyer discrimination mechanism. Journal of Business 1985; 58(3):295308. 20. Tellis GJ. The price elasticity of selective demand: a meta-analysis of econometric models of sales. Journal of Marketing Research 1988; 25(November):331341.

Copyright # 2005 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.

Appl. Stochastic Models Bus. Ind., 2005; 21:397402

Das könnte Ihnen auch gefallen