Sie sind auf Seite 1von 8

Synopsis

This paper aims to critically examine Positive Accounting Theory (PAT) since its emergence in the 1970s. PAT has been one of the most influential accounting theories in the past four decades as it has attracted divergent opinions from accounting theorists and researchers. Watts and Zimmerman (1978), both were the advocates of PAT, propose that the objective of PAT is to predict accounting practices. What is more, PAT is an economics-based theory, since all individuals make decisions on the basis to maximise their own wealth (Watts & Zimmerman, 1978). The five factors affecting management wealth are taxes, information production costs, compensation plans, regulations and political costs, and the incentives for various groups of individuals to adjust accounting standards vary (Watts and Zimmerman, 1978). Despite owing some merits, this paper aims to identify the drawbacks of PAT based on the research and opinions sourced from various accounting theorists and researchers.

Introduction
For over decades, Positive Accounting Theory (PAT) has elicited a heated discussion among various groups of accounting theorists and researchers, which is not uncommon because each party has its own grounds and points of view. PAT was advocated and popularised by Watts and Zimmerman (1978) and such theory of accounting seeks to explain and predict the selection of particular accounting practices and their possible impacts. This contrasts with the Normative Accounting Theory (NAT), which aims to develop and prescribe optimal accounting standards for reporting entities to adopt (Kabir, 2011). Accordingly, PAT possesses a totally different emphasis from NAT. Since its emergence in the 1970s, PAT has been subject to numerous endorsements and criticisms from accounting theorists and practitioners, therefore it is essential to examine how far PAT has been successful in accounting world and what the limitations have been. Based on such reason, this paper aims to give a critical examination and evaluation on PAT. The paper is organised into several sections. First, the discussion will focus on the findings and theoretical arguments derived from the article written by Watts and Zimmerman (1978) Towards a

Page 1 of 8

Positive Theory of the Determination of Accounting Standards. Second, the articles research hypotheses will be discussed and analysed. Third, this section will identify and discuss the theoretical frameworks being applied. The forth section will look into the limitations of PAT, as well as its criticisms. This paper will finish up by briefly summarizing the main finding and conclusions.

Summary of the Article


The advocates of PAT, Watts and Zimmerman (1978) and others, argue that PAT is considered an economics-based accounting because the theory is based primarily on the central assumption of economics, that is, the actions and decisions of all individuals are strongly driven by self-interest, hence each individual has the tendency and willingness to act in an opportunistic manner in order to augment his or her wealth and benefits (Boland & Gordon, 1992). Furthermore, Watts and Zimmermans empirical studies (1978) critically examine the relationships between various individuals and groups involved in providing resources to an organisation, including managers, outside directors, shareholders and politicians. This is supported by Henderson, Peirson and Brown (1992) who further state that an organisation is a collection of self-interest individuals who have agreed to cooperate based on sufficient incentives or mutual benefits. The purpose of PAT, according to Watts and Zimmerman (1990), is to discover not only individuals incentives, but also their reasons to affect the accounting standards to maximise their own wealth. Watts and Zimmerman (1978) propose five factors affecting management wealth, including taxes, information production (e.g. bookkeeping) costs, management compensation plans and political costs. A change in accounting standards which increases an organisations reported earnings will result in higher taxes, thus reducing management wealth. Other than that, any changes made to the accounting procedures will definitely involve some costs to the firms such as training expenses (to inculcate new standards to existing employees), purchase of new software, increase of bookkeeping fees and etc. As for management compensation plans, managers could potentially be rewarded on fixed salary (regardless of performance), incentive compensation based on performance or result achieved (e.g. cash bonuses and stock options) or a combination of both methods above (Watts and Zimmerman, 1978). If Page 2 of 8

managers are solely rewarded on a fixed salary, assuming self-interest, the central tenet of PAT, it is possible that they can be induced to manipulate the accounting numbers (e.g. augment reported earnings) to improve their apparent performance and contribution, and more importantly, their wealth and rewards (Healy, 1985). A research conducted by Lewellen, Loderer and Martin (1987) confirms such hypothesis because their studies show that a larger percentage of managers who are approaching retirement are less likely to undertake research and development expenses if their rewards are solely based on accounting-based performance measures. This is because incurring R&D costs will directly lead to a reduction in profits, and hence affecting their wealth negatively. As a consequence, Positive Accounting Theorists argue that it is more efficient and appropriate to reward managers with incentive compensation other than fixed salary, such as offering cash bonuses or stock options when the companys profits and shares increa se (Watts and Zimmerman, 1978). Therefore, both the owners (and shareholders) and managers will benefit, more importantly, the managers are given extra incentives to boost the value of the firm. Deegan (2012) also claims that under incentive based remuneration; it is highly possible to motivate managers to take actions and act in the best interests of the owners, thereby, aligning the interests of the managers and owners together. The last factor affecting management wealth is political costs. Whittington (1987) refers political costs to the costs that external groups or parties may impose on the company, such as increased taxes, product boycotts, and higher wages claims. Companies, especially those of large organisations, will directly or indirectly be affected by governments, unions, consumer groups and others (Deegan, 2012). Several studies indicate that a companys accounting results or reported earnings might affect the demands placed on firms by interest groups external to the firm (Watts & Zimmerman, 1978; Deegan & Hallam, 1991). Take the unions for example, if a company reports high profit, it is possible that the trade unions will use the reported accounting profit as a justification or excuse to take further actions in improving their members wealth in the form of higher wages (Deegan, 2012). Such wages increased, although it seems equitable, could be costly to the firms involved. Perhaps with a lower reported profit, there would be less chance for the demand of increased wages. Page 3 of 8

Watts and Zimmermans research in 1986 illustrates that US oil companies in the 1970s had drew unwanted attention from politicians and publics as they were making excessive reported earnings, therefore the companies were subject to the imposition of increased taxes and reduced subsidies. Similarly in Australia, Clarke (2011) claims that Australian mining companies such as Rio Tinto and BHP Billiton have been reporting high profits in recent years, and this has triggered the calls for mining resource tax by the governments. PAT theorists claim that politicians, similar to the managers and shareholders of a firm, are motivated to take action on the basis of self-interest, that is, to increase their power or wealth (Watts and Zimmerman, 1978). Therefore, targeting firms with excessive profits may help to boost their support from voters and thus increasing their chances of winning the election. Based on the discussion above, this paper has provided some insights on how various interest groups may use a firms reported earnings as a justification for particular actions. It can be seen that with a lower reported earnings, it may reduce the possibility of demands from interest groups, such as increased taxes or wages. Several studies shows that companies with high reported earnings choose to adopt income-decreasing accounting methods, in order to avoid great attention and scrutiny from the publics (Watts & Zimmerman, 1978; Jones, 1991). Similarly, Lim and Matolcsys research (1999) reveals that companies that are subject to price scrutiny are likely to apply accounting standards that reduce their reported profits significantly.

Research Question
Watts and Zimmerman (1978) outline three basic hypotheses underlying PAT which include bonus plan hypothesis, debt-equity hypothesis and political cost hypothesis. To begin with, the bonus plan hypothesis predicts managers in firms with incentive plans, have the tendency to adopt accounting standards that boost the reported income in current period. As for debt-equity hypothesis, it predicts that the higher the debt-equity ratio, the more likely that the managers of the firm will use reporting standards that increase the income. Next, political cost hypothesis forecasts larger firms rather than smaller firms have the incentives to use accounting methods that reduce incomes due to government

Page 4 of 8

and public scrutiny (Sinha, 2008). Watts and Zimmerman (1978) further state that the magnitude of political cost is greatly dependent on the size of the firm. Watts and Zimmerman (1978, pp. 118-121) develop a model of Firms Submission to the FASB regarding the selection of accounting standards. They further argue that the benefits and costs of proposed accounting standards are expected to vary with firm size. The research result demonstrates that larger firms are more likely to make favourable submission to FASB if their reported incomes are reduced by the proposed accounting methods. In contrast, smaller firms will either not submit or make unfavourable submissions. This is due to the fact that smaller firms are subject to less political pressure and public scrutiny; hence the managers do have incentives to oppose the proposed standards since their incentive compensation plan will be affected and adjusted, which is a costly process.

The Significance and Limitations of the Article


Since its emergence, PAT has been subject to various criticisms, especially to those normative theorists who perceive the role accounting theory as prescribing, rather than describing. Sterling (1990) argues that a valid accounting theory should be capable of providing guidance. Since PAT does not offer any prescription, hence it has no means of improving the accounting practice. Furthermore, Tinker, Meino and Niemark (1982) criticise PAT since no guidance are given as to what people should do. Nevertheless, PAT theorists have always been justifying such criticism on the basis that they prefer to let people decide for themselves what they should do rather than impose their personal views on others (Watts and Zimmerman, 1990). A third criticism is about the fundamental assumption of PAT, that is, all actions of each individual are driven by self-interest to maximize own wealth and benefits. Many accounting theorists and researchers feel such assumption represents a perspective of humanity that is far too negative (Deegan, 2012). Gray, Owen and Adams (1996) further state in their article that PAT promotes a morally bankrupt view of the world. More ironically, PAT theory has not shown any useful development on the issues being addressed since its inception in the 1970s (Sterling, 1990).

Page 5 of 8

Conclusion
This paper has critically examined PAT from the perspective of those advocates and opponents. Despite being bombarded by numerous criticisms for decades, PAT continues to be used by accounting researchers and theorists around the globe. One should consider the merits and usefulness of PAT, which is to predict and explain the selection of accounting practices made by individuals in particular circumstances. Such information is particularly important to the decision making process of management, owners, or even the groups external to the firms.

Page 6 of 8

Reference List
Boland, LA & Gordon, IM 1992, Criticizing positive accounting theory, Contemporary Accounting Research, vol. 9, no. 1, pp. 142-170 Deegan, C 2012, Australian Financial Accounting, McGraw Hill Education, Australia Deegan, C & Hallam, A 1991, The Voluntary Presentation of Value Added Statements in Australia: A Political Cost Perspective, Accounting and Finance, vol. 31, no. 1, pp. 1-21 Gray, R, Owen, D & Adams, C 1996, Accounting and Accountability: changes and challenges in corporate social and environmental reporting, Harlow: Prentice Hall Europe Henderson, S, Peirson, G & Brown, R 1992, Financial Accounting Theory: its nature and development, Longman Cheshire, Australia Henderson, S, Peirson, G & Brown, R 1992, Financial Accounting Theory: its nature and development, Longman Cheshire, Australia Jones, JJ 1991, Earnings Management during Import Relief Investigation, Journal of Accounting Research, vol. 29, no.2, pp. 193-228 Kabir, MH 2011, Positive Accounting Theory and Science, Journal of Centrum Cathedra, vol. 3, no. 2, pp. 136-149 Lim, S & Matolcsy, Z 1999, Earning management of firms subjected to product price controls, Journal of Finance, vol. 39, pp. 131-150 Sinha, SK 2008, Positive Accounting Theory: A Critique, The IUP Journal of Accounting Research, vol. VII, no. 4, pp. 7-16 Sterling, RR 1990, Positive Accounting: An assessment, Abacus, vol. 26, pp. 97-135 Tinker, T, Merino, B & Niemark, M 1982, The Normative Origins of Positive Theories: Ideology and Accounting Thought, Accounting Organisations and Society, vol. 7, no. 2, pp. 167-200 Page 7 of 8

Watts, RL & Zimmerman, JL 1978, Towards a Positive Theory of the Determination of Accounting Standards, The Accounting Review, vol. 53, no. 1, pp. 112-134. Watts, RL & Zimmerman, JL 1990, Positive Accounting Theory: A Ten Year Perspective, The Accounting Review, vol. 65, pp. 131-156. Whittington, G 1987, Positive accounting: A review article, Accounting and Business Research, vol. 17, pp. 327-336

Page 8 of 8

Das könnte Ihnen auch gefallen