Sie sind auf Seite 1von 8

ohan.

balian Page 1 04/08/2009


DRAFT - STRICTLY NOT FOR QUOTATION

On the Economics of Art and the Art of Economics

Whittier College, May 16, 2003

by

Ohan S. Balian

Thank you all for coming and thank you professor Thomas for your introduc-

tion. Most of you have been taking exams in recent days and are probably fed up from

economics – what I like to call ‘economics fatigue’ - synonymous with ‘donor fatigue’

experienced by multilateral organizations. So today I’ll try to use as little mathematics

and graphs as possible and approach economics from an ‘artistic’ perspective.

Today’s talk is a modified version of a talk I gave a few years ago at a sym-

posium on the political economy of art. ‘Modified’ in the sense that I have toned

down political economy issues and have tried to be more in-tune with the core values

of a liberal arts college. When I first came to Whittier, I had no idea what a liberal arts

college was and thought it was just another fancy Californian name. I soon realized

that most of my colleagues weren’t sure either, which was evidenced through my dis-

cussions in faculty meetings and curriculum development committees. So I thought

this would be the perfect setting to give this talk, especially given the high degree of

uncertainty surrounding the relationship between the arts and the sciences.

It is important to point out at the outset that by ‘economics’ I do not mean the

science of economics alone. Economics encompasses all the social sciences, mathem-

atics, model building, and more. Similarly, by ‘art’ I mean all forms of art, visual, fine

arts, performing arts, music, and literature. So we see that both disciplines are very

general, and it is very difficulty to determine the influence of one discipline on the

other. The motivation for today’s talk is to tease out the differences and similarities
ohan.balian Page 2 04/08/2009
DRAFT - STRICTLY NOT FOR QUOTATION
between these two wide disciplines in the hope of determining the influence of one on

the other.

Let me start with the ‘Economics of Art’. If you type in the word ‘economics

of art’ in any search engine on the Internet, you get hundreds of results, but almost all

deal with how auction houses operate, what is the type of the art market structure

(monopoly, duopoly, oligopoly), what is the power of the buyer (monopsony), but

very few articles deal with using economics for valuation purposes. I am interested in

using economics to determine the price of a painting or a piece of art. Why are some

paintings sold for millions while others are sold for a few hundred dollars? Why do

governments, in using contractionary fiscal policies, reduce government expenditure

on the arts and education – the current Bush plan. (As we will see later in the talk, this

is only one interpretation of the ‘economics’ of art).

This takes us back to a very simple question posed by Adam Smith in 1776:

“Why are diamonds more expensive than water?” It is also known as the water/dia-

mond paradox – a paradox in the sense that water is a necessity (hence, should be ex-

pensive). The immediate response would be “what a silly question. Of course water is

cheap and diamonds expensive because there is a lot of water and diamonds are

scarce”. That’s fine. But diamonds are also ‘forever’. Once we realize this, we can ex-

plain the price differential between diamonds and water using the Diminishing Mar-

ginal Returns hypothesis. In other words, the value or ‘price’ of a good is determined

by the marginal (extra) satisfaction one gets from consuming an extra unit of that

good. As an example, suppose you’re in the desert and haven’t drank for a few days.

(This reminds me of the Clint Eastwood movie: ‘The Good, the Bad, and the Ugly’).

How much would you pay for the first cup of water? The answer, of course, is a lot.

As you drink the second cup, you would still pay a lot but not as much as the first cup,
ohan.balian Page 3 04/08/2009
DRAFT - STRICTLY NOT FOR QUOTATION
and less and less for consecutive cups of water until you have quenched your thirst.

So how much would you pay for the ‘last’ cup of water. The simple answer would be

by the amount of the marginal or extra satisfaction that you get from drinking that last

cup of water. In other words, the price of a cup of water is determined by the extra sat-

isfaction from drinking that ‘last’ or marginal cup. If we apply the same reasoning to

diamonds and ask the question: “How much would we pay for a diamond?” The an-

swer would be: a lot. And how much would we pay for the second diamond? It de-

pends on the extra satisfaction that you get from ‘consuming’ that second diamond.

Would it be more or less than the first? The answer would be at least the same, or

even more. Hence, we would assume that since we get more satisfaction from the

second diamond (unlike the second cup of water), its price would still be high, and

even higher than the first diamond. Applying this reasoning to a ‘luxury’ good like a

famous Renoir, we would see that the consumer would get a higher utility from a

second Renoir than the first, and hence pay a higher price.

One of the few papers that look at the behavioural relationship between art and

economics is by Lanyon and Smith (1999): “A Portrait of the Artist as a Young,

Middle Aged, and Elderly Man.” They look at the age-value and age-quantity correla-

tion for 53 Western painters whose paintings have been auctioned in the last decade.

They show that the average value of their paintings increases till the age of 32, slowly

declines until the age of 47, and then dramatically falls in old age. They also find a

similar trend when they look at the age-quantity relationship – namely, artists produce

substantially more in the early stages of their careers, then output declines dramatic-

ally in old age. Their main finding is that artists paint significantly more, the higher is

the average value of their paintings. What do these findings suggest? Well, isn’t this

the positively sloped supply curve based on the objective of profit maximization?
ohan.balian Page 4 04/08/2009
DRAFT - STRICTLY NOT FOR QUOTATION
Now let me say a few words on the relationship between economics and liter-

ature. A few years ago, I was watching a program on CNN called Questions & An-

swers (Q&A). This is a truly interactive program in which the host of the show (Riz

Khan) invites guests and people from all over the world call to ask questions. The

guest on the show at the time was Vikram Seth, a Nobel Laureate in English Literat-

ure. I had read somewhere that he had an undergraduate degree in economics, and

started listening very carefully to what he was saying. He was talking about how suc-

cessful he was in his ability to market his books in the US (compared with other au-

thors) and I could detect traces of economics in his argument. So I picked up the

phone and asked the following question: “To what extent your background in eco-

nomics has influenced your writings.” He laughed for a few seconds and said that he

doesn’t even remember his demand and supply curves, and gave an ‘acceptable’ an-

swer but not a very convincing one. Then there was another caller, and then a third

caller who again asked a question about his ability to market his novels, and in his an-

swer to this third question, he subconsciously used the term “Diminishing Marginal

Returns.” He paused for a few seconds, and said: “I guess economics has affected my

thinking after all” – referring to my earlier question. And this made me so happy be-

cause I was so sure that he was one of ‘us’, even though he was a Nobel Laureate in

‘English’.

At the time I was also deep into my dissertation and whenever I needed to

take a break from my ‘equations’, and as if through an ‘invisible hand’, I was drawn

into literature books. (My wife is an English Literature major and we have no short-

age of literature books at home). I could clearly see the close relation between math-

ematics and literature: how equations are formed, and how sentences are structured.

During this period, I also ‘discovered’ William Hazlitt, an 18th century English liter-
ohan.balian Page 5 04/08/2009
DRAFT - STRICTLY NOT FOR QUOTATION
ary critic who wrote about self-interest, imagination in the arts, and ‘gusto’, terms that

are heavily used in economics. (Remember that this was in Adam Smith’s time in

1776). We do not have the time to go into Hazlitt today (also because I don’t know

much about him!) but I was very happy and fulfilled that at least my ‘intuitions’ were

correct.

In concluding my thoughts on ‘The Economics of Art’, we see that there is a

lot of documentation and loose connections between these two very general fields, but

little systematic analysis to scientifically explain this relationship.

Now lets turn to ‘The Art of Economics’, and here by the ‘art’ I mean the

methodology of economics, and the ability and effectiveness to explain complex eco-

nomic phenomena to the general public. Again let me make a few remarks through

real world experience.

I was watching a C-SPAN program a few weeks ago and there were three well

respected economists on the program: Joseph Stiglitz, Lawrence Klein, and Franco

Modigliani, all Nobel laureates, but they couldn’t make a convincing case against the

Bush tax plan. (Remember that C-SPAN is a program for the general public, but even

I, considered an economist, could not follow their argument). They talked about the

‘Term Structure of Interest Rates’, ‘Marginal Propensities’, and other esoteric terms to

make a very simple point: namely, if the government reduces taxes, it must also re-

duce its expenditure, which will cause a lot of problems. And that’s it. Now the dis-

agreement is on what should be ‘cut’ in government spending and what is the effect of

the tax cut on consumer spending (Consumption) and business spending (Investment).

Now regardless of whether you’re for or against the Bush tax plan, if the reduction in

taxes (a source of revenue) is greater than the reduction in government spending (a

source of expenditure), then the budget deficit will deteriorate and the rate of interest
ohan.balian Page 6 04/08/2009
DRAFT - STRICTLY NOT FOR QUOTATION
will eventually rise. If the reduction in taxes is less than the reduction in government

spending, then the budget deficit will improve and the rate of interest will eventually

decline. You don’t have to be an economist to understand this. In other words, if you

spend more than you earn, you are in trouble one way or another. If you earn more

than what you spend, then you’re fine. The disagreement stems from the ‘Supply

Siders’ (pro Bush) who say that as taxes are reduced, it is good for businesses (be-

cause they have lower costs) and therefore will produce more and generate economic

growth. The point that I am trying to make is that economists, even well respected

ones, are sometimes unsuccessful in explaining complex economic phenomena to the

general public.

In explaining economic phenomena, we use models based on ‘assumptions’. It

is sometimes very frustrating to use unrealistic assumptions to explain real world phe-

nomena. We keep telling our students that assumptions are used to ‘filter’ important

variables from less important ones, and to simplify the real complex world. To ex-

press my frustration, a few weeks ago we were at UCLA with our Whittier College

students to hear a talk by Joseph Stiglitz on Globalization. Although he had some very

interesting things to say (after all he is a Nobel Laureate), for over an hour he bashed

the International Monetary Fund (IMF), and in one of his examples he said that the

privatization policies adopted by the IMF in Argentina were so inappropriate that even

if we assumed that corruption was virtually non-existent, the privatization program

would not have succeeded. After his talk, the audience was given a chance to ask

questions but unfortunately he spent too long on each question and there was no time

for my question. I was going to ask the following question: “Mr. Stiglitz, using your

same analogy, if we assumed that the IMF did not exist, would the world be a better

place?” Now based on how he used his assumption on the non-existence of corruption
ohan.balian Page 7 04/08/2009
DRAFT - STRICTLY NOT FOR QUOTATION
in Argentina, his rational answer should’ve been, yes. But we all know that even with

all the mistakes and imperfection of IMF policies, surely it has had some positive ef-

fect on world economic development.

Let me now say a few words on the ‘art of model building’. In economics, we

build economic models, and in art, we build ‘clay’ (or using some other medium)

models. There are basic ingredients in both, they follow certain predetermined estab-

lished rules, but they are independent of each other. The fundamental difference is that

‘art’ models try to interpret reality, whereas economic models deal with reality. We

call this ‘bounded rationality’ in the sense that economic reasoning is ‘bound’ by cer-

tain assumptions and rational behaviour. In other words, as policy makers, we need to

be very careful of our policy prescriptions (based on our models) because we can af-

fect the lives and well being of millions of people.

One final point on ‘The Art of Economics’ is that this ‘art’ can be modified

and improved. As an example, lets look at the theory of Asymmetric Information and

how it can be modified. This theory basically says that the seller in a market usually

has more information than the buyer, and hence, can extract a larger benefit. When I

was in contact with Professor Steven Overturf at Whittier before my arrival, the good

professor was explaining to me how he ended up buying his dream house, a house to

which they were closely attached since they rented it in the summer vacations. Al-

though he was very happy that they eventually bought the house, he was a little bit

uncomfortable since, as an economist, he ended up paying a higher price than the

market price. To him, this was not a ‘rational’ behaviour. At the time I was working on

an idea at the Hebrew University in Jerusalem on asymmetric information from the

consumption side – Consumption Advantage. The idea is that a brick layer can buy a

house at a lower price than a doctor, who in turn can buy a health service at a lower
ohan.balian Page 8 04/08/2009
DRAFT - STRICTLY NOT FOR QUOTATION
price than an economist, who in turn can buy, say, a financial instrument at a lower

price than a non-economist, and so on. The reason is that consumers have asymmetric

information in consumption depending on their professions and levels of skill. At the

time I related this reasoning to professor Overturf’s experience and I was successful

in convincing him that his behaviour was not ‘irrational’ after all. He knew the house

intimately since they were vacationing in it for the past 20 years, and his Marginal

Utility was very high as he moved to the new house. As he began to ‘consume’ more

and more of the house, his marginal utility began to fall until it was equated to the

market price. Hence, he was acting rationally after all.

In conclusion, let me leave you with two related questions, which also bring

together the differences and similarities between art and economics: Does it help to be

a good economist if you are a good artist? The answer is unambiguously yes. But does

it help to be a good artist if you are a good economist? Here, the answer is ambiguous.

Although there is a lot of documentation on the relationship between art and econom-

ics, much more empirical research is needed to provide a convincing answer. I thank

you for your attendance and hope that I have succeeded in making economics much

more interesting than the ‘dismal’ science for which it is sometimes known.

Whittier College, California,

May 16, 2003

Das könnte Ihnen auch gefallen