Sie sind auf Seite 1von 22

This article was downloaded by: [Moskow State Univ Bibliote] On: 11 December 2013, At: 16:04 Publisher:

Routledge Informa Ltd Registered in England and Wales Registered Number: 1072954 Registered office: Mortimer House, 37-41 Mortimer Street, London W1T 3JH, UK

Journal of Contemporary Asia


Publication details, including instructions for authors and subscription information: http://www.tandfonline.com/loi/rjoc20

Backward capitalism, primitive accumulation and modes of production


Jairus Banaji
a a

Jawaharlal Nehru University Published online: 02 May 2008.

To cite this article: Jairus Banaji (1973) Backward capitalism, primitive accumulation and modes of production, Journal of Contemporary Asia, 3:4, 393-413 To link to this article: http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/00472337308566901

PLEASE SCROLL DOWN FOR ARTICLE Taylor & Francis makes every effort to ensure the accuracy of all the information (the Content) contained in the publications on our platform. However, Taylor & Francis, our agents, and our licensors make no representations or warranties whatsoever as to the accuracy, completeness, or suitability for any purpose of the Content. Any opinions and views expressed in this publication are the opinions and views of the authors, and are not the views of or endorsed by Taylor & Francis. The accuracy of the Content should not be relied upon and should be independently verified with primary sources of information. Taylor and Francis shall not be liable for any losses, actions, claims, proceedings, demands, costs, expenses, damages, and other liabilities whatsoever or howsoever caused arising directly or indirectly in connection with, in relation to or arising out of the use of the Content. This article may be used for research, teaching, and private study purposes. Any substantial or systematic reproduction, redistribution, reselling, loan, sub-licensing, systematic supply, or distribution in any form to anyone is expressly forbidden. Terms & Conditions of access and use can be found at http:// www.tandfonline.com/page/terms-and-conditions

393

Articles Backward Capitalism, Primitive Accumulation and Modes of Production


Jairus Banaji
"Marxism takes its point o f departure from world economy, not as a sum o f national parts but as a mighty and independent reality which has been created by the international division o f labour and the world market, and which in our epoch imperiously dominates the national markets" Trotsky, The Permanent Re v ol ut i on "Historic belatedness and the subjection or-China by the imperialists deprived the Chinese bourgeoisie o f that progressive role which had been played by its European forerunners in the bourgeois revolutions o f the West" Trotsky, 'The War in the Far East and the Revolutionary Perspectives' "What can the most demagogic petty bourgeoisie set against capitalist penetration? Mere words; nothing more. They can offer no more than a temporary nationalist orgy . . . Our mission is to explain and show the masses how only the socialist revolution can present a real and effective barrier to the advance or imperialism" Jose Carlos Mariategui, 'The Anti-imperialist Perspective' " T h e nationalist model could be negated only by one o f two radical means: socialist revolution or reintegration into world capitalim" Octavia lanoi, Crisis in Brazil

Downloaded by [Moskow State Univ Bibliote] at 16:04 11 December 2013

To the bourgeoisie in the imperialist as well as in the dependent countries it is axiomatic that given certain conditions, backward capitalism can sooner or later achieve a rate of industrialization sufficiently rapid to absorb the mass of redundant peasant labour in the villages. I For over sixty years now revolutionary marxists have argued the opposite position: that in the conditions which characterise backward capitalism development can at best assume a purely sporadic and combined character, with a relative and partial industrialization superimposing itself on a disintegrating peasant economy which it cannot reintegrate rapidly enough. Whatever its specific stature or the degree of its relative autonomy vis-a-vis imperialism, and regardless of its political and ideological past, the bourgeoisie of the backward countries cannot carry through the tasks associated historically with the bourgeois revolutions in Europe and Japan. In particular, it has no final solution to the agrarian problem, which remains an enormous burden to backward capitalism and an aid to the revolutionary party. 2 In this historic sense "the democratic tasks of the backward bourgeois nations lead directly in our epoch to the dictatorship of the proletariat", that is, to socialist revolution. 3

1.

Combined Development in WorldEconomy

In the epoch of colonial imperialism the formation of a unified international


]aims Banaji teaches at Jawaharlal Nehru University.

394

JOURNAL OF CONTEMPORAR Y ASIA

market transfigured world economy as the old system of scattered national modes of production disintegrated under its impulse. Behind the characteristic figures of this epoch - early industrialization, expansion of trade, acquisition of colonies and the migrations of labour and capital - lies the essential,fact that the national components of world economy were increasingly bound together through a hierarchy of forms of dependence and domination into a unified international structure. The unity of world economy, hence the relative dependence of the 'parts' of world economy on the 'whole', is the necessary point of departure in any discussion of imperialism and economic backwardness. But this unity acquired a specific historical expression in the fact that within world economy capitalism coexisted with non-capitalist modes of production both nationally and internationally, and while capitalist development overcame this unevenness in some sectors of world economy, in world economy as a whole it greatly intensified it. The combined character of world economic development, which was the essential reflection of i t s unevenness, was an internal and necessary characteristic of capitalist expansion on a world scale. "By drawing the countries ecorlomically closer to one another and levelling out their stages of development, capitalism operates by methods of its own, that is to say, by anarchistic methods which constantly undermine its own work, set one country against another, and one branch of industry against another, developh~g some parts o f world economy while hamperh~g and throwblg back the development of.others': hnperialism unified world economy, but "by such antagonistic methods, such tigerleaps and such raids upon backward countries and areas that the unification and levelling of world economy" which it effected was upset by it "even more violently and convulsively than in the preceding epochs". 4 Following Lenin we could describe the major historical forms of capitalist expansion as firstly "the development of capitalism in depth, ie, the further growth of capitalist agriculture and industry in the given, definite and enclosed territory, and secondly - the development of capitalism in breadth, ie, the extension of the sphere of the capitalist domination to new territory", s Elsewhere Lenin wrote that such a division "would include the whole process of the historical development of capitalism: on the one hand, its development in the old countries, where for centuries the forms of capitalist relations up to and including large-scale machine industry have been built up: on the other hand, the mighty drive of developed capitalism to expand to other territories, to populate and plough up new parts of the world, to set up colonies... ,,.6 But while both colonisation and colonialism were the effects of a certain 'horizontal' development of capitalism, its development "in breadth", the historic tendencies which they embodied were quite different, in the colonies which capitalism subjugated as opposed to the others which it merely populated, the extension of the sphere of capitalist domination assumed a complex and indirect aspect. In these colonies unlike the others capitalism did not eradicate tribal modes of production and fill the vacant spaces with industries and markets. The populations it encountered consisted largely of peasants and far from uprooting their existing forms of production through their expropriation and conversion into wagelabourers, so as to lay the foundations for an internal expansion of its own mode of production, capitalism imparted a certain solidity to those forms and even extended
-

Downloaded by [Moskow State Univ Bibliote] at 16:04 11 December 2013

BACKWARD CAPITALISM

395

them to new territories not previously inhabited. By the closing decades of the last century the unevenly developed world economy comprised - apart from the areas of established capitalist development concentrated in northern Europe - on the one hand, areas of nascent capitalist development and on the other, areas in which there were no signs of capitalist development due to the complete preponderance within them of a colonial mode of production.*

Downloaded by [Moskow State Univ Bibliote] at 16:04 11 December 2013

Primitive A ecumulation and Forms of Developmeltt As we know, Marx described the initial mechanism of capitalist expansion as 'primitive accumulation'. He did not, however, construct a concept of primitive accumulation so much as describe a particular historical form of it, the distinctive feature of which was a wholesale expropriation of the peasantry and its conversion into a class of outlawed proletarians. Against the persistent later confusion of these levels of analysis his own indications make it clear that primitive accumulation in the specific form charactedsing capitalist development in England is not a generalized model of capitalist industrialization valid for all sectors of world economy:
the chapter on primitive accumulation does not pretend to do more than trace the path by which, in Western Europe, the capitalist order of economy emerged from the womb of the feudal order of economy. It therefore describes the historical movements which by divorcing the producers from their means of production converts them into wage-workers.., while it converts those who possess the means of production into capitalists... Now what application to Russia could my critic make Of this historical sketch. Only this: if Russia is tending to become a capitalist nation after the example of the teestcrt~ Europear~ c'o~c,tries she will not succeed without having first transformed a good.part of her peasants into proletarians |
. . .

2.

In the first place, then, the historic process of primitive accumulation, the process as it appears from the standpoint of world economy, has never assumed the abstract and fictitious form of a repetition of the earlier forms of development by different nations, but the true form of a combination of the stages of develop* A. Gunder Frank breaks with bourgeois theories o f backwardness in approaching the phenomenon historically, and moreover from a marxist standpoint, but his system of concepts remains crude and confused, and no specific theory o f backwardness is prolx~sed beyond the simple assertion that backward economies have historically formed part o f the capitalist world market. The chief expression of the inadequacy of F'rank's work is that he refuses to explore concretely the forms in which imperialism achieved this integration; in other words, the relationship between 'development' and 'underdevelopmenl' is not structured so much as merely asserted. "thus Frank constantly confuses the concepts o f integration into the capitalist world economy and expansion o f capitalist production relations within the integrated unit. The point is made brilliantly by E.C. Laclau (7) whose own position, like the positions o f those who mediate the relationship between imperialism and the colonies in terms o f a specific mode of production (8) embodies a more rigorous marxist understanding. Elements o f this half-formed and still unelaborated theory were already present at various points in the work o f Lenin and Trotsky. eg in the distinction Lenin drew between invo|vement in capitalist exchange relations and involvement in capitalist production relations, or in Trotsky's view that in China o f the 1920s the social relations o f serfdom and semi-serfdom were not merely historical residues but in part constituted a "new formation, that is, the regeneration o f the past on the basis o f the retarded development of the productive forces, surplus agrarian population, the activities of merchants' and userers' capilal".(9) That is, to Trotsky such relations were partly the effects o f imperialism's domination o f the Chinese economy, a domination which, as Trotsky maintained elsewhere, kept the country's productive forces in a political straitjacket.

396

J O U R N A L OF CONT"EMPORA R Y A S I A

ment, of interdependent and mutually conditioning processes of primitive accumulation defined by their own specific methods and rhythm o f accumulation. Thus the different modes of primitive accumulation which were distributed chronologically across the histories of Spain, Portugal, Holland, France and England, arrived in England at the end of the 17th century

at a systematical combination, embracing the colonies, the national debt, the modern mode of taxation, and the protectionist system I l Secondly, as Preobrazhensky insisted, 12 any process of primitive accumulation implies an articulation of modes of production. The early phases of the process of expanded reproduction derive their dynamism from certain relationships between the nascent capitalist mode of production and an established capitalist or pre-capitalist mode of production. Historically the dominant form of these relationships was the subordination of pre-capitalist modes of production to capitalism, though it would be wrong to see in this a simple process of outright destruction, for the latter was only one of the historical forms of the former. On the contrary, as Bettelheim notes in a brilliant debate with Emmanuel 13 capitalism's subordination of non-capitalist modes of production tended not only to dissolve them but also to conserve them. in social formations wher.e capitalism was already the dominant mode of production, this "conservation-dissolution" of non-capitalist modes of production was a secondary historical tendency. On the other hand, inside social formations in which capitalism was not directly predominant but which were subordinated to capitalism through the world market, this dual process emerged as the main tendency. In these social formations, mainly tile colonies and semi-colonies, capitalist subordination of the traditional modes of production required a certain restructuring of the latter, which by its very nature led to the disintegration of certain of their characteristic forms and to the conservation and intenslfication of others. We can thus define the colonial modes of production as the historical effects of a worldwide process of subordination of pre-capitalist modes of production to capitalism, that is, of an epoch of primitive accumulation, but where subordination itself least assumed the simple aspect of a destruction. If we pose the question of colonial social formations in these terms, we are compelled to draw one further conclusion. The modes of production which came to predominate in these formations were not autonomous modes of production in the sense that they grew organically out of the contradictions of some former mode and with laws of development determined independently of world economy. Thus they were not 'non-capitalist' in the specific sense that their internal laws of development remained identical with those defining earlier modes of production. On the contrary, their character as dependent modes of production was expressed chiefly in the fact that the laws which governed their reproduction derived from their subordination to imperialism. The restructuring of former modes of production through which this process of subordination was accomplished imposed on them new laws of development which were basically determined by the fact that the colonial peasantdes were drawn into the sphere of world commodity circulation on pre-capitalist foundations - servile or feudal relations of exploitation, backward technique and low levels of productivity.

Downloaded by [Moskow State Univ Bibliote] at 16:04 11 December 2013

BACKWARD CAPITALISM

397

3.

Primitive Accumulation and the Sectors of Nascent Capitalist Development To grasp the real peculiarities of backward capitalism or the type of capitalism which came to characterize the colonial and semi-colonial social formations, we need to carry the analysis forward on two levels. Firstly, to analyse the mechanisms which stifled capitalist development in the period of the colonial modes of production. Secondly, to determine the concrete forms which the process of primitive accumulation assumed in different sectors of world economy and on this basis establish the differences between backward capitalism and earlier forms of development.

Late Capitalist Development As we know, in those sectors of world economy in which industrialization was a relatively late phenomenon and, perhaps for this reason, one largely dominated by the State, eg. Italy, Japan and, to some extent, Germany, the bourgeois revolution acquired and retained a semi-abortive character due to the fact that in them the process of primitive accumulation required a compromise between the capitalists and the feudal elements, one of the chief foundations of which was an enhanced rate of exploitation of the peasantry and agricultural proletariat, t 4 ! n both Japan and Italy primitive accumulation was directly linked to sharp increases in agricultural productivity which were absorbed in rents and profits and which the State channelled into industrial expansion through fiscal mechanisms. In Germany the alliance between the landowners and industrialists which Bismarck cemented through the policy of protective tariffs set the framework for a period of rapid intensified accumulation characterised by the growth of monopoly and a concentrated banking system. Japan's capitalist development was closer to that of Germany in that due to its belated character and the relative backwardness of its bourgeoisie, the leading personnel of the State came to be constituted by elements of the old feudal classes, and the capitalist industrialisation thus preserved a certain bureaucratic and semi-feudal integument. Js Here capitalism had to be erected on the basis of fusion rather than conflict with absolutism, t 6 Against this background Russian capitalism showed two specific peculiarities. In sharp contrast to both Germany and Japan, the indigenous bourgeoisie of Russia was overwhelmed by a massive inflow of foreign capital into its national-economic terrain. By 1900 foreign investments had come to represent about one half ofjointstock company investment in Russia and were concentrated precisely in tire sectors which spearheaded primitive accumulation in this period. 17 Here the chief basis of absolutism was not the alliance of native capitalists with the old feudal elements, but this relative preponderance of European capital. "German and French money is rolling to Petersburgh to feed a regime tha't would long ago have breathed its last without this life-giving juice", wrote Rosa Luxemburg in 1915. "Russian czarism is today no longer the product of Russian conditions; its root lies in the capitalist conditions of Western Europe". Is But secondly, in Russia far more than either in Italy or in Japan and certainly more so than in Germany, France and Britain, the process of primitive accumulation took on a protracted but discontinuous and recurrent character. Phases of intensified primitive accumulation were followed by periods of relative stagnation and decline. Together these peculiarities of Russia's capitalist development made the objective conditions for a proletarian revolution far riper here than

Downloaded by [Moskow State Univ Bibliote] at 16:04 11 December 2013

A.

398

J O U R N A L OF CONTEMPORAR Y ASIA

in Germany or Britain - a weak and compromising bourgeoisie, a working class built up in concentrated units of production by the foreign investment boom, a fiercely repressive comprador autocracy and a peasantry crushed by the fiscal policies of primitive accumulation.* In the sectors of world economy which lacked any domestic economic base for such a process in the form of a peasantry subjugated by non-capitalist or semi-capitalist modes of exploitation, primitive accumulation was characterized chiefly by advantageous exchanges on the capitalist world market and by the intensified immigration of capital and labour. Here the early industrial upsurge was coincident with export booms induced by sudden favourable shifts in the terms of trade, eg. Denmark in the 1850's and 1860s, Sweden in the 1870s or Canada and Argentina in the 1900s. The accumulations originating in these booms were sustained on an expanding scale within and outside the export sector through the operation of linkage effects, while the accelerated expansion of the home market which the latter determined tended to displace the economic centre of gravity to industries producing primarily for this market. 2t Moreover, the periods of rapid primitive accumulation derived additional impulses from the influx of capital and labour which the booms attracted from the countries of developed or nascent capitalism, the latter mainly from those countries of Europe, such as I taly, in which capitalist industry had still to reintegrate the labour exuded by the disintegrating modes of production in the towns and countryside. (One expression of the close interdependence of economic processes under world capitalism is the fact that such migrations were an important source of primitive accumulation for the home country in the form.of emigrants' remittances. For example, in Italy in 1901-1913, against a commercial deficit of 10,230 million lire, invisible items showed a credit of 12,291 million, over half of which derived from emigrants' savings. 22) The rapid expansion of Argentine, Canadian or Swedish exports occurred within the framework of a capitalist economy, and moreover of a capitalist social formation in which the persistence of pre-capitalist modes of production was of little or no importance even as a secondary tendency - a fact distinguishing these formations from others which were experiencing nascent capitalist development in that period. On the other hand, in the export-dependent colonial and semi-colonial social formations such 'as Egypt, Burma or lndochina sharp increases in production for the world market' throughout this period were made possible and sustained on the foundations of pre-capitalist economy, and within the framework of modes of production whose laws of development were determined entirely by the subordination of those territories to imperialism. That the rising curves of commodity production for the world market failed to finance primitive capitalist accumulation in the colonies and semi-colonies appears
* The process which Peter the Great initiated early in the I 8th century within the framework of mercantilist policies (19) was onJy finally accomplished two centuries later by the primitive capitalist accumulation of the Stalinist bureaucracy. Through tile programme of coUectivisation an embryonic state bourgeoisie under Stalin's leadership subordinated and totally destroyed the forms o f production coexisting among the peasantry. As nettelheim writes, "'within the space of eight years the great mass of Soviet peasants were uprooted.from their former conditions o f e x i s t e n c e . . . " But in the particular conjuncture in which the bureaucracy found itself primitive capitalist accumulation also required certain political conditions: a wholesale depoliticisation o f the working class and rapid destruction of the forces inside party and state which still fought for a proletarian class programme, mainly the Left Opposition.(20)

Downloaded by [Moskow State Univ Bibliote] at 16:04 11 December 2013

B A C K W A R D CAPITALISM

399

problematic 23 only as long as we misrecognize the structure of world economy an0 imagine its fundamental constituents to be countries rather than modes of production mutually linked in relations of hierarchy, subordination and dependence.

ColonialStagnation The colonial modes of production 24 assumed several historical forms whose peculiarities were determined in general by whether imperialism restructured the former modes of production in a given territory or h~stalled a mode of production where none existed, and in particular by the specific form of restructuring of the previous mode of production. The most important of these forms of restructuring the given mode of production were (a) incorporation of the peasantry into big estates such as those prevailing in the Andes, Mexico, Cochin China, Central Luzon or parts of India, 2s (b) tile peasant's rapid integration into the world market and subjugation to the dominance of merchant and usurer capital, as in Egypt, Burma or Cambodia, 26 and (c) rapid destruction of the productivity of the traditional mode of production by economic and legal mechanisms as part of an internal process of primitive capitalist accumulation, eg. Rhodesia. 2"7 The installed mode of production invariably assumed a servile or semi-servile form, that is. it was based chiefly on servile relations of exploitation, in most cases forcibly importing its labour from outside the given territory. 2s On the other hand, where incorporation of the peasantry into large estates was the dominant mechanism of imperialist restructuring of the traditional mode of production, the colonial mode assumed a distinctly semi-feudal character. Where the basis of imperialist exploitation was the peasant's relation to the world market and where this relation was structured and sustained mainly outside the economic and juridical framework of big property through the peasant's bondage to local merchant and usurer capital, the colonial mode of production took on the character of a semi-cohmialism. As the exah~ple of Egypt suggests, direct installation of a colonial state apparatus was not, in these instances, essential to the process of exploitation. Finally, in the settler colonies in Africa the colonial mode of production emerged as a purely transitional and subordinate phenomenon, fuelling an internal expansion of the capitalist mode of prodt, ction. Due to its peculiarities the slave-based colonial mode of production requires a separate and specific analysis of the mechanisms retarding primitive capitalist accumulation 29 and for this reason the semi-feudal and semi-colonial forms of colonial production are the only objects of analysis here. To begin with, behind the retarded primitive capitalist acct, mt, lation of territories subjected to these specific forms of imperialist exploitation lay the retarded expansion of their home markets. Such expansion required not primarily a sufficient level of personal consumption, as the Narodniks argued when assessing the prospects of capitalist development in Russia, but advances in the sphere of productive consumption or investment, as Lenin emphatically pointed out. Therefore it would be wrong to argue that the continuous impoverishment of the colonial peasantries or the deterioration of their prodl,ctive capacities made industrialization in the colonies and semi-colonies "impossible". In Lenin's early writings on the market question two spheres of expansion of the home market are isolated. "On the problem of interest to us, that of the home

4.

Downloaded by [Moskow State Univ Bibliote] at 16:04 11 December 2013

400

J O U R N A L OF C O N T E M P O R A R Y A S I A

market, the main conclusion from Marx's theory of realisation is the following: capitalist production, and, consequently, the home market, grow not so much on account of articles of consumption as on account of means of p r o d u c t i o n . . . For capitalism, therefore, the growth of the home market is to a certain extent 'independent' of the growth of personal consumption". 3 Again, "production does indeed create a market for itself: production needs means of p r o d u c t i o n . . , to expand that department of social production which manufactures means of production, it is necessary to draw into it workers who immediately present a demand for articles of consumption". 31 On the other hand, "the 'impoverishment of the masses of the people' not only does not hinder the development of capitalism, but on the contrary, is the expression of that development, is a condition of capitalism and strengthens i t . . . the 'impoverished' peasant who formerly lived by his own farming now lives by 'earnings', ie. by the,sale of his labour power; he now has to purchase essential articles of consumption . 32 Despite their apparent equivalence, however, these tendencies are of unequal weight in determining the expansion of the home market for capitalism: in the first place, the extent to which differentiation of the peasantry creates a home market for capitalism depends fundamentally on the specific form which the process of differentiation assumes: (i) on tile character of the social formation as a whole - colonial or transitional to capitalism? (ii) on the particular type of bourgeois revolution which differentiation signifies in social formations of the latter type - landlord-bourgeois or peasant-bourgeois revolution? 33 Secondly, the growth of a ru'ral market for capitalism depends as much on the formation of a peasant bourgeoisie and its demand for means of production as on the peasant's conversion into a proletarian; the degree to which this tendency predominates is determined mainly by the mode of transition to capitalism in agriculture, ie. by whether peasant capitalism develops autonomously or is compelled to grow within the constricting framework of a landlord-bourgeois revolution. Nevertheless, even if we confine ourselves to proletarianisation, it is clear that the specific colonial form of differentiation of the peasantry could lead at best to a sporadic and purely relative expansion of the market for articles of consumption. In the colonial and semi-colonial social formations the separation of the peasantry from its former means of production, ie. its expropriation, did not signify a transition from simple commodity production to capitalist production. The mass of colonial peasants were not transformed into a class of allotment-holding wage-workers, and even where a purely proletarian peasantry tended to predominate the special characteristics of its class situation, eg. the low level of wages, the relative preponderance of payment in kind and the,retention 01' its links with peasant economy ruled out a rapid expansion of the rural market for foodgrains. In fact, as long as the process of accumulation atrophied, the disintegration of collective forms of property before the expansionist tendencies of the colonial latifundia, the numerous episodes of an abrupt expropriation of the lower peasantry by usurer capital or by an embryonic class of big landowners as well as the tendencies which intensified the fragmentation of its means of subsistence could lead at most to a semt-proletarianisation of the peasantry, that is, its conversion into a class still partially in possession of the means of production. Thus the tree role of the colonial process of differentiation in thwarting the expansion of the market for capitalism be-

Downloaded by [Moskow State Univ Bibliote] at 16:04 11 December 2013

BACKWARD CAPITALISM

401

comes apparent only when we consider its effects on the dominant forms of that expansion, ie. on the process of accumulation itself. Among the many 'factors' retarding the expansion of the market in Russia Lenin gave special importance to "the retention of obsolete institutions which hh~der the det~elopment of agricultural capitalism", a4 In the colonies and semi-colonies capitalism failed to penetrate agricultural production on any significant scale either in the form of a landlord-bourgeois revolution or through the capitalist differentiation of the peasantry. For the lower strata of the colonial peasantry, both middle and semi-proletarian, the mechanisms which imperialism utilised in restructuring the former modes of production (the installation of big property and the enforced dominance of merchant and usurer capital) drained away the surplus which might have revolutionised the conditions of production. In most Asian colonies few tenants-at-will appear to have been in a position ofdirect relation to the market, as the majority of those engaged in commodity production were compelled to contract loans on the 'advance system', that is, according to agreements binding tile peasant to sell the produce of his crop to the lender at a price fixed in advance and "invariably below that obtaining in the open market", as On the other hand, the well-to-do strata which were economically in a position to resist the encroachments of usurer capital and of rent exploitation, on the whole tended to reinvest the profits of commodity production in pre-capitalist modes of exploitation or to hoard them or to convert them into gold. These ten. dencies of colonial rural economy imparted to the process of differentiation its main peculiarity, namely, that the pauperisation of the peasantry and its conversion into a semi-proletarian class was an expression of factors which retarded its differentiation along capitalist lines and which, in general, blocked other possible modes of transition to capitalism in agriculture. In the final analysis, however, the atrophy of accumulation on the plane of hzdustry played a far more decisive role in constricting the expansion of the home market and shaping the mechanism of colonial stagnation. In contrast to earlier processes of primitive capitalist accumulation, the relative lateness of Russian, German and Japanese industrialization determined the special importance of the State in starting and accelerating the process of expanded reproduction. That is to say, in certain social formations of late capitalist development capitalism was "an offspring of the State". 36 On the other hand, the condition on which the possibility of this type of intervention and hence of the whole process of primitive accumulation rested, namely, the national autonomy of the State, was historically absent in the colonies, and semi-colonies. In social formations of the latter type the State was either directly controlled and dominated by imperialism, as in India or Indochina, or indirectly dominated by it through more distant mechanisms of control, mainly financial and diplomatic, as in Egypt before the British Occupation or in Peru after Independence. In the formations directly subjugated by imperialism, the latter's refusal to grant protection or formulate policies to encourage accumulation decisively delayed the emergence of a colonial bourgeoisie by several decades, while in the semi-colonies where domination assumed an indirect aspect, the class alliance between imperialism and the agrarian interests producing for the world market and dependent on the exportimport house controlled by foreigners 37 crippled the early development of bourgeois nationalism. Though it would be wrong to ignore a certain ideological overdeter-

Downloaded by [Moskow State Univ Bibliote] at 16:04 11 December 2013

402

JOURNAL OF CONTEMPORA R Y ASIA

Downloaded by [Moskow State Univ Bibliote] at 16:04 11 December 2013

mination by theories of free trade, notions about international division of labour, racialism and so on, in the last instance it was the relative contradiction between the class interests of the imperialist bourgeoisie and any future colonial bourgeoisie which compelled imperialism to stifle the process of primitive capitalist accumulation. To sum up, we can say that the expansion of the market for colonial capitalism was doubly constricted, firstly, by the continuing predominance of pre-capitalist forms of exploitation in the countryside, by the fact that differentiation of the peasantry did not reflect changes in productive organization or the formation of a peasant bourgeoisie;secondly, by the very fact of imperialist domination which consciously maintained tile colonies in a position of iridustrial backwardness through direct and indirect mechanisms of control.*

5.

Import Substitution and the Colonial Bourgeoisie In contrast to earlier forms of development, primitive capitalist accumulation in the major colonies and semi-colonies derived its main impulse from consecutive crises in world economy which, by interrupting the flow of commodities to and from the metropolis, simultaneously shattered the base of the landowners producing for the world market and loosened the grip of foreign capital on the economy. As long as the conditions of world economy had remained stable, the colonial bourgeoisie had no room to manouevre agaiust either of these forces, and the small

* The e x a m p l e o f E g y p t is o f c o n s i d e r a b l e i n t e r e s t in this r e s p e c t , for u n d e r M u h a m m a d All early in the 19th century,the State made a conscious attempt to engage in primitive accumulation. This was both before Egypt had become a major cotton producer, ie. before her wholesale integration into the w o r l d market in a subordinate colonial position, and befoke imperialism had established any decisive relation o f domination over the Egyptian State. Like Peter the Great a century earlier, Muhammad All made the peasantry shoulder the burden o f financing his industrial schemes and providing manpower for his factories. Exploitation o f the peasantry through heavy taxation and the fixing o f monopoly prices for agricultural produce led to a progressive shrinkage o f Ali's fiscal base as more and more peasants fell into arrears or fled to the towns. By 183"/ conditions in the countryside were worse than they had been for a long time. "This destitution was largely the result o f the system o f monopolies", writes Owen (38). To further expand the country's industrial base and t o increase government revenues Muhammad All introduced the cultivation o f c o t t o n and was eventually forced, in the 1840s, t..~ reintroduce semi-feudal property and relations o f exploitation to make the task o f collecting taxes fall on the new estate holders. In Egypt the process o f primitive accumulation which All started rapidly came t o a halt. On his death his factories were dismantled, and by this stage c o t t o n more and more came to dominate the whole o f Egypt's economic life. Moreover, the disintegration o f the State's economic hegemony "was hastened by the Anglo-Turkish Commercial Convention o f 1838 which outlawed state monopolies and established a low external t a r i f f o f 8 per cent . . . further industrialization was made very much more d i f f i c u l t " . (39) Under Muhammad Ali strenuous efforts had been made to replace European imports w i t h locally manufactured goods. "This policy came to an end in the 1840s, however. As a result o f European political pressure, first at Islanbul, then on Egypt ilself, the country was rapidly opened up to foreign t r a d e . . . Increasing trade w i t h Europe was followed by a rapid growth in the import o f capital . . . by 187$ Egypt had borrnwed a nominal sum o f nearly 100 million f r o m Europe". (40) In Peru exactly in this period, despite the emergence o f a liberal-nationalist programme seeking a national Peruvian market defended f r o m the world market by tariffs and eager to promote peasant capitalism in agriculture, it was the system k n o w n as compradorisrno which finally triumphed. " T h e creole leadership was in debt; it was diplomatically dependent upon other countries; its political legitimacy at home and abroad was still weak. In these conditions it literally turned over the economy o f the country to the export-import businesses controlled by f o r e i g n e r s . . . With compradorismo in certain branches o f the export trade - products such as w o o l a n d g u a n o - t h e d e v e l o p m e n t o f a g r i c u l t u r e was i n h i b i t e d , a n d t h i s in t u r n led t h e creole elites m o r e and m o r e i n t o eompradorismo... " ( 4 I).

BA CK WAR D CAPITA LISM

403

industrial nucleus which emerged before World War I, mainly in Argentina and Brazil, was forced to adapt its structure to the dominant exporter sector. On the other hand, due to the possibilities of import-substitution and to the role of the latter in transforming the dimensions of the market, even the least disruption in world economy could shift the balance of class forces in favour of colonial capitalism. Regardless of the specific elements determining the initial possibilities of expansion - import restrictions, war demand, tariffs, the Japanese Occuption - once lhe process of expanded reproduction was established, it could move forward, within certain limits, through the dynamism constituted internally by its own linkages and the additional flow of income brought about by this expansion. 4z At, most certain political conditions were required to ensure a certain relative continuity in the process of primitive accumulation and these the industrial bourgeoisie in the main colonies and semicolonies sought chiefly through its struggle to control the state apparatus and maintain its hegemony within the ruling class through alliances with the urban middle class and sections of the peasantry (India) or proletariat (Brazil, Argentina). But the determining role of world economy was revealed in two opposite ways: not only in the fact that only in conditions of world crisis could the colonial bourgeoisie find room for expansion, but equally in the fact that the limits on the further progress of accumulation in the backward countries, ie. the conditions which formed the basis for their reintegration into the orbit of imperialism after the early phases of import-substitution and for the emergence of new modes of international dependence subjugating the backward countries to imperialism,43 were inseparably bound up with the basic characteristics of colonial social formations - in other words, with their entire past historical evolution within the framework of the world market and with the innermost tendencies of the old mode of production. Colonial capitalism emerged within a social formation characterized economically by the following basic features: (i) by a retarded development of capitalist production relations in agriculture, hence by a low productivity of peasant labour and stagnant output levels; (ii) by a structure of industry whose backward and one-sided character sprang directly from the policies of delayed primitive accumulation; (iii) by a concen, tration of exports on the products of agriculture. But far from eliminating and overcoming these features the peculiarities of the colonial process of industrialization only i:ztensified them. In the first place, because early industrialization drew on more archaic sources of primitive accumulation in trade (India) or the profits of production for the world market (Brazilian coffee), no sharp conflicts opposed the nascent industrial bourgeoisie to the classes whose fortunes were bound up with colonial production. Moreover, as long as industrialization derived its main dynamisms from a diversion of existing demand to local producers, ie. from the conquest of a pre-existing market by local industry, no historic basis existed for a radical bourgeois assault on semi-feudalism. Thus while the urban market for capitalism expanded rapidly throughout this period, the dimensions of the rural market for industry were left untouched. 44 Secondly, as most of the h~dustrialization during the Depression was confined to the consumer industries, the colonial bourgeoisie remained dependent on imports for the bulk of its machinery, capital equipmeilt and intermediate goods. At the particular stage of development which the most developed colonial capitalisms had reached by the 50s, this dependence assumed two

Downloaded by [Moskow State Univ Bibliote] at 16:04 11 December 2013

404

J O U R N A L OF C O N T E M P O R A R Y A S I A

Downloaded by [Moskow State Univ Bibliote] at 16:04 11 December 2013

aspects - due to a shortage of foreign exchange to finance the needed capital equipment, a financial dependence, and due to the progressively advanced character of substitution in this stage, a teclmological dependence. As the limiting force of these effects came into play, backward capitalism rapidly ran into sporadic but intense deficits on current account which it could only finance by depleting its past accumulations of foreign exchange and by recourse to foreign capital. Thus the curve of import substitution was determined in the most general sense by the conditions in which capitalism was forced to develop in the backward sectors of world economy. Despite its intensely nationalist and genuinely anti-imperialist ideology and political traditions, 4s the colonial-bourgeois State was driven by the objective contradictions of its class situation into deeper and deeper dependence on imperialism. On the political plane the transition to this new period of accumulation determined one of two types of evolutions: either a relative displacement of the industrial bourgeoisie by realignments within the ruling class, eg. renewed dominance of tile landowners (Argentina) or a progressive readjustment of the forms of its relationship with imperialism, varying from attempts to break with the West and go over to Russia (Egypt) or to balance between Russia and the West (India) to whol~ sale capitulation to foreign monopoly capital (Brazil after Goulart). 46 But regardless of the specific type of evolution, hence of the specific political character of the regime, military-oligarchic, bourgeois-democratic, bourgeois-nationalist and so on, these shifts in the balance of class forces were important mainly in establishing tile political conditions for the transition to dependent primitive accumulation, or in carrying the process to a more advanced stage. 6 Phases of Dependent Primitive Accumulation From a different but overlapping perspective the fundamental characteristic of this conjuncture of transition inaugurated by the more and more severe exchange deficits was the role of imperialism in utilising its programmes of 'official assistance' to restructure the forms of its domination over the backward countries. Against the historical background of analogous shifts in world economy at earlier stages of development, this process of restructuring was especially rapid and lacking in unevenness, for it took imperialism at most ten years to complete (1950-60). The real causes of this peculiarity lie only partly in those elements of the international conjuncture which concentrated and centralized imperialist domination in the period between the Wars and just after: the shifting balance of power in favour of US capital and the formation of new financial superstructures of imperialism (IBRD, IDA, IMF). In part they spring from the fact that export of capital to the backward countries engaged in a primitive capitalist accumulation is a phenomenon overdetermined by two class standpoints. For the colonial bourgeoisie capital imports from the West, imports of machinery, transport equipment, intermediate chemical products and so on, become, at a certain stage, a condition of its own further relative expansion. On the other hand, from the standpoint of imperialism, the renewal of capital exports in the specific form of grants, official loans, export credits, etc. becomes a necessary prelude to a more massive penetration of the backward countries in the form of direct investment. Thus depending on the national conjuncture and its relative weight vis-a-vis the given bourgeoisie, either

B A C K W A R D CAPITALISM

405

simultaneously with or shortly after the inception of official assistance, Ioreign monopoly capital begins to monopolize the most dynamic sectoi's of import-substitution: fertiliser, petrochemicals, and chemical products, automobiles, iron and steel, machine tools, heavy electrical goods, electronics, transport equipment at~d the like. Finally, depending on the forms and intensity of this penetration, that is, depending on whether, in its new role of import-substitution, foreign monopoly capital tends to displace the old industrial bourgeoisie with its base in earlier stages of substitution, as in Argentina or Brazil (the phenomenon called 'denationalization'), or, on the contrary,is kept within bounds and utilised by that bourgeoisie for its own expansion, as in India, the first phase of dependent primitive accumulation comes to be characterized, to a greater or lesser degree, by the emergence of new social strata within the ruling classes, composed of comprador capitalists and a middle and lower bourgeoisie of technical, managerial or clerical salaried staff employed by the foreign monopolies.* In the last instance, accumulation based on continual inflows of capital to finance chronic and periodically severe exchange deficits reflects neither the political dominance of the comprador strata within the ruling class nor any particular ideology inherited by the bourgeoisie from its colonial past. In fact, neither of these conditions properly conforms to historical reality, for at both levels of the superstructure compradorism is merely an effect of neo-imperialist penetration. In the last instance, this mode of primitive accumulation reflects tile structure and tendencies of world economy. Even where it has been able to establish its own independent base in the national economy by utilising the crisis of the world market, the backward bourgeoisie cannot carry industrialization beyond certain narrow limits except through the further collaboration of imperialist capital. From this springs the basic dilemma of colonial capitalism - while dependent primitive accumulation by its very nature threatens the backward bourgeoisie with economic disintegration should the flow of capital cease abruptly and for a long period, perpetuation of its bonds of dependence offers no means of escape from the circle of primitive accumulation. On the contrary, when it feels strong enot, gh to do so due to the conquests of the first phase, the imperialist bourgeoisie inaugurates a new and specific phase of dependent accumulation with the programmes of devaluation, import liberalization and further encouragement of foreign capital which it compels the backward bourgeoisie to adopt - either through IMF 'stabilization programmes' (Argentina 1958-63, Philippines 1962) or through World Bank pressure (India 1966). 4g As the bourgeoisie emerges from this conjuncture stunned or crippled, it moves into a phase of dependent accumulation characterized principally by the
* One of the most clearly discernible phenomena associated with foreign~dominated importsubstitution is the emergence of a certain neo.endavism within the industrial sector of the backward countries to which the bulk of foreign private capital is attracted. The tatter tends to be concentrated in the most rapidly growing industrial sectors (such as transport equipment, electrical machinery, chemical products, etc.) which due to their specific technological characteristics, and the effects they produce, both directly and through backward linkages, block the expansion of industrial employment and deepen the vertical structure of the market. While it condemns the mass of" the population to unemployment and underconsumption, colonial capitalism is compelled to cultivate the sectors of bourgeois consumption more and more feverishly.(47)

Downloaded by [Moskow State Univ Bibliote] at 16:04 11 December 2013

406

J O U R N A L OF CONTEMPORA R Y ASIA

stranglehold of debt servicing and the rapid conversion of former surpluses on capital account into net outflows of capital. The dilemma of colonial capitalism is reproduced on a higher scale.*

* From the standpoint o f the necessary theoretical and strategic tasks o f revolutionary parties in the backward countries the notion o f dependent primitive accumulation is, o f course, insufficient because too abstract. The concrete analyses which these parties will have to make of their own specific situations require a further, but still preliminary, step - differentiating the unity of dependent capitalism into its concrete forms and the particular contradictions characterising each form. For example, imperialism's subjugation of Ceylon and her domination of India could be reduced to a single 'model' only at the cost of eliminating precisely those peculiarities in each of these relationships which are, after all, the main object of marxist analysis. The bulk of external capital for rapid industrialization has gone only to a few countries, in which three groups stand out: (a) the ultra-dependent accumulation of Pakistan, S. Korea, Taiwan and some other countries and territories. In the 1950s and the 1960s the three economies mentioned achieved the highest rates of growth of manufacturing o u t p u t , far exceeding the average for Asia. The basic characteristic o f industrial growth in this group was an abnormally high rate of investment sustained mainly by massive inflows of foreign, chiefly US, capital. Eg. in 1960-64, net assistance as a proportion of gross domestic capital formation was 58% for S. Korea, 30% for Pakistan and 2t % for Taiwan. Pakistan and Taiwan experienced the highest income elasticities o f demand for imports, 2.6 and 1.9 respectively, and around 1965-67 attracted the largest flows of net foreign private capital in Asia as a whole - S. Korea topped the list with ~1409 million, Pakistan was second with [ 1 9 5 m and Taiwan third with ~192m. (49) (h) the semi-dependent accumulation of Argentina, Brazil and India which in 1963 accounled for about half the total manufacturing output o f the backward economies and were, with Mexico, in the industrial vanguard of the 'third world'. This group experienced much lower rates of growth in the 1960s. Despite lower import-elasticities, the combination of their much higher levels of industrial development (vertically integrated import-substitution) with stagnant or declining export levels induced chronic dependence on inflows of capital (in gross terms they attracted the bulk of official assistance in their respective 'regions'). In Argentina the Prebisch Plan of 1955 explicitly linked any potential acquisition of machinery and equipment for expanding industrial capacity to the outcome of efforts to attract foreign capital; importation of most capital goods was prohibited unless financed by foreign capital. Due to the efforts of the Frondizi regime, heavy imports of such goods during 1960-61 enabled many import-substituting and some export industries In expand. The bulk of foreign capital attracted to Argentina in this period went into chemicals, automobiles, non-ferrous metals, oil refining and machinery. (50) In Brazil much of the substitution in capital goods was carried through by foreign subsidiaries o f General Electric, Siemens, Brown-Boveri (heavy electricals), and Schneider (heavy n=achinery) etc. By 1968 foreign capital controlled 80% of the pharmaceutical industry, 39% of engineering production, 62% of car component production, 4 8 % o f aluminium.(5 I) Finally, in India the build up of Dept. I industries was totally bound up with official flows. However, in this group unlike the previous one, industrialization was already fairly advanced before the transition to dependent accumulation in the 1950s: Vargas, Peron and Nehru embodied, in this sense, the uppermost limits of the potentialities of colonial capitalism. (c) the type of dependent accumulation which lran today represents with her rapid and, in some ways, quite advanced industrialization closely bound up with government receipts from the profits of foreign oil monopolies and with the projection of forward linkages from petroleum to the rest of the economy. (52) To these three basic types we can add: (d) countries like Bolivia or Thailand which appear to have attracted US assistance for military or 'strategic' reasons (53) (el countries like Cuba, Egypt and those in E. Europe which form or formed part of a system of dependency dominated by Russian state capitalism. (54) A complete analysis of 'nan-colonialism' would require a study of the complex relationships between the particular forms of dependent accumulation - however we choose to determine these - and variations in the form o f state power and in the politico-ideological superstructure. One link that is immediately apparent is the relation between monopoly capital, chiefly US, and the neo-fascist regimes of the third world - Brazil, Turkey, Indonesia and so on; but what are the specific interrelations between imperialism, dependent capitalism and formations of the

Downloaded by [Moskow State Univ Bibliote] at 16:04 11 December 2013

BACKWARD CAPITALISM

407

Socialist Revolution and Uneven Development Taken in all its major phases colonial-capitalist industrialization has the distinct character of a recurring and continually frustrated primitive accumulation. In the former colonies and semi-colonies capitalism can only develop fitfully and sporadically "in dependence on the world stock exchanges" ,s6 compelling the colonialbourgeois state to reinforce its links with imperialism, to widen its own sphere of action in the economy, and finally, behind a facade of pseudo-proletarian ideologies and forms of organization (rural cooperatives in Peru, autogestion in Algeria) to develop the productive forces of agriculture. But in contrast to earlier forms of development or in the special historical conditions of backward capitalism, the conversion of landlord or peasant into bourgeois economy moves in a historical space of dependant accumulation and stagnant industrial employment. Rural capitalism is forced to import its means of production at the cost of greater external indebtedness, while the proletariat which it creates out of the reservoir of semi-proletarian peasants has no prospect of being integrated into capitalist industry as a factory proletariat. Backward capitalism combines the stages of the historic process according to its position in world economy, but combined development is not its specific peculiarity. Rather, what principally characterizes social formations of this type is the impossibility of sustained capitalist development, of a successfi, I bourgeois revolution which can accomplish the process of primitive accunrulation. Not combined development but the impossibility of further development within the framework of the combination becomes the principal feature of colonial capitalism. Hence the possibilities and the necessity for proletarian revolution, a revolution aiming at the overthrow of capitalism and the establishment of a workers' republic based on the active support of the peasantry. The tasks of the bourgeois revolution which the bourgeoisie cannot solve, the proletariat is compelled to solve. To be able to do this, it must have its hands free. It must be conscious of its task, and, far from lining up behind the banner of 'progressive national capitalism', it must go out to the peasant masses with its own programme. Its class independence is the first condition of its growth as an organized political force. In this respect two questions arise: a general question regarding the possibilities of proletarian revolution in the backward countries, and a specific question of the forms of articulation of a proletarian programme. Firstly, as in world economy as a whole so in its backward sectors, due to the unevenness of capitalist development the possibilities of a proletarian revolution (a revolution based on working class parties with an internationalist and anti-capitalist programme) are not the same for all countries nor will the forms of that revolution be identical. A failure to understand either of these facls, that is, to grasp the combined and uneven character of the world revolution, determines two types of errors
superstructure such as honapartism, military reformism,(SS) populist democracy, communalism, etc? In the brief and therefore schemalic analysis of sections 5 and 6 what we have called the 'phases' of dependent accumulation should not be interpreted in a mechanical sense as referring In sharply defined and sequentially structured stages. Rather they tend to overlap and merge according to a combined development, thus giving the relations between backward capitalism and world economy a planless and complex character.

7.

Downloaded by [Moskow State Univ Bibliote] at 16:04 11 December 2013

408

J O U R N A L OF C O N T E M P O R A R Y A S I A

on the Left. On the one hand, positions reminiscent of that held by Serrati in the debate on the colonial question at the Second Congress of the Comintern, dismissing peasant struggles against imperialism as scarcely worth support, as irrelevant interventions in a process which, like the movement of Hegel's Idea, fias its only point of culmination in advanced Europe ;sT on the other hand, 'third worldist' positions which confer on those struggles the determining role, dismissing the proletariats of Europe, Japan, America and the backward nations as insufficiently 'revolutionary' (many of the attitudes which Lenin fought against in the Narodniks recur in the latter positions). But between the workers of Birmingham, Chicago, Berlin and Tokyo and the peasants of Laos, Cambodia and Vietnam has not the law of combined development thrown up a whole series of intermediate and transitional types, from the peasantries of southern Europe to the factory proletariat of Cordoba and Bombay, the miners of Bolivia and the labouring peasants of Bengal and Java? After all, did the October Revolution not occur in a country that was neither wholly advanced nor wholly backward? The question of revolution in the backward countries has to be approached from this standpoint, ie. of the internal differences conditioned by their u n e v e n development. Th.e backward countries are neither uniformly backward nor, for that precise reason, of equal weight on the world scale. In sharp contrast to (a) the smaller and most backward nations which in most cases have no industrial proletariat and where revolutions can only take the form of a 'dictatorship of the impoverished peasantry 'sa there are (b) the most advanced of the backward countries which, in their social structures and levels of development as well as in the forms which bourgeois rule is compelled to adopt in them, approach the most backward of the advanced countries such as Spain, Italy and S. Africa: the main countries of this group are Argentina, Brazil, Mexico, Egypt, India. Between these groups lies (c) a whole intermediate zone of relatively industrialized smaller nations and territories in which dependent accumulation has taken extreme forms, in some instances directly reducing the major class contradictions to that between imperialism and the proletariat: Pakistan, S. Korea, the Philippines, Indonesia, Peru, lran, Colombia, etc. In countries of the two latter types revolutionary parties based on working class and proletarian-peasant leadership are a concrete possibility and are the only means of breaking out of the descending spiral of frustrated primitive capitalist accumulation. Here not only has capitalism created a working class in the factories, mines and railways but, in most cases, a large segment of the peasantry is completely proletarianized, ie. forms an agricultural proletariat, "which is a part of the working class ''s9 - Brazil, Mexico, Egypt, India, Pakistan, Philippines, Indonesia, Peru. Revolutions in these countries would be of far more decisive weight in the world arena than others which can at best assume the form of a dictatorship of the poor peasantry. Proletarian revolutions in Brazil and Mexico would have incalculable consequences for the revolutions in Latin America, apart from shattering the whole structure of American dominatmn of the subcontinent, and likewise the revolutions in Egypt, India or Indonesia. Nevertheless, precisely due to the historical absence of working class parties in these countries, it is revolutions based on tile peasantry which are currently forced to confront imperialism in the forms specific to them - protracted struggles sustained mainly by the profound courage, determination and inexhaustible moral energies

Downloaded by [Moskow State Univ Bibliote] at 16:04 11 December 2013

BACKWARD CAPITALISM

409

Downloaded by [Moskow State Univ Bibliote] at 16:04 11 December 2013

of tile rural masses. Secondly, regarding the forms of articulation of a proletarian programme in tile backward countries - unless the working class consciously incorporates the incompleted tasks of the bourgeois revolution into that programme, its struggle for a workers' republic will be doomed by its isolation froln the peasant masses who stand behind the village proletariat. "Democratic slogans, transitional demands, and the problems of the socialist revolution are not divided into separate historical epochs in this struggle, but stem directly from one another". 6 In the consciousness of those social classes and strata which the party must draw into alliance with the working class the path to socialist revolution lies via tile transitional demands - for the abolition of landlord economy and against the incursions of landlord capitalism, for the unionisation of urban and rural workers, for the evacuation of foreign military bases, etc.
FOOTNOTES 1. For reflections of this position in development economics see W.A. Lewis, 'Economic Development with unlimited supplies of labour', Manchester School 1954, J.C. Fei and 0. Ranis, Development o f the Labour Surplus Economy: Theory and Policy (Illinois 1964), the articles by D.W. Jorgenson in Economic Journal 1961, Oxford Economic Papers 1967, or, following a different line of thought, H.B. Chenery, 'Foreign assistance and economic development', J.H. Adler (ed), Capital Movements and Economi'c Development (New York 1967) and the other liberal advocates of foreign assistance criticised by A.K. Bagchi, 'Aid models and inflows of foreign aid', Economic and Political Weekly, January 1970 (Annual Number). This position was argued for Russia by L. Trotsky: The Permanent Revolution and Results and Prospects (Pathfinder Press 1969). See also the opening sections of the History o[ the Russian Revolution. For the agrarian queslion as an aid to the party see 1905 (Allen Lane 1972). L. Trotsky, 'Introduction', The Permanent Revolution. L. Trotsky, The Third International After Lenin (Pathfinder 1970) pp. 19-20. V.I. Lenin, The Development o f Capitalism in Russia, chapter 8, section S. Collected Works (CW) !11 p. S94. V.I. Lenin, 'Once more on the theory of realisation', CW IV p. 91-92. A.G. Frank, Capitalism and Underdevelopment in Latin America (Penguin Books 1969) or the similar position of L. virile, 'Latin America: feudal or capitalist', !. Petras and M. Zeitlin (ed) Latin A merica: Reform or Revolution? A Reader (New York 1968). E. Laclau, 'Feudalism and capitalism in Latin America', N e w Left Review May-June 197 I. It should be empliaslsed that Frank's political position is perfectly correct insofar as it stresses the primacy of socialist revolution. For example, p-p. Rey, Stir I'Articulation des Modes de Production, Centre d'etude de planification soclaliste, Sorbonne (mlmeo.), Bipan Chandra, 'Colonialism and modernization', Indian History Congress i 970, S. Mukherji, 'Institutional rigidities in the agrarian market in early 20th century Bengal', Current Dynamics, September 1970, U. Patnaik, 'Development of capitalism in agriculture', Social Scientist. September ! 972 who all reject the simple characterization of the colonial economy as either 'feudal' or 'capitalist'. Third International After Lenin, p. 209; Lenin's distinction between exchange and production relations was cited by Kuusinen in the concluding stages of the 'decolonisation debate' in the Comintern, t 928. See the International Press Correspondence numbers for luly - November 1928. K. Marx, "To the editors of Otechestvennlye Zapiskl', dated November 187'7. Contrast with M. Dobb, 'Prelude to the Industrial revolution', Papers on Capitalism, Development and Planning (Bombay 1967) w h o proposes exactly the view Marx attacks. K. Marx, Capital 1 (Moscow 1961) p. 751. In these parts of Capital frequent references are found to 'methods' and 'levers' o f primitive accumulation, suggesting that more was involved in the process than the expropriation o f the peasantry. E. Preobrazhensky, The N e w Economics (Oxford 1967). Preobrazhensky, a brilliant Marxist economist and, with Trotsky, one o f the leaders o f the Left Opposition in

2.

3. 4. 5. 6. 7.

8.

9.

10. It. 12.

410

JOURNA L OF CONTEMPORAR Y ASIA


Russia. was the only one to make a serious intervention on the question of 'primitive accumulation" after Marx. C. Bettelheim, 'Theoretical comments', in A. Emmanuel, Unequal Exchange. A S t u d y o f tire Imperialism o f Trade (New Left Books 1972) p. 29"I-8. For Italy cf. J. Cammett, 'Two recent polemics on the character of the Italian Risorgi. men to ', Science and Society [ 963, and A. Gerschenkron, E c o n o m i c Back wardness in Historical Perspective (Harvard 1962) chap. 5 on Romero's thesis that, had there been an agrarian revolution in this period, the whole pace of Italy's primitive capitalist accumulation would have been dragged hack. Cf. Barrington Moore Jr., Social Origins o f Dictatorship and Democracy (Peregrine Books 1969) on 'labour-repressive forms of capitalist agriculture'. A. Gramsci, Selections From The Prison Notebool~s (Lawrence and Wishart 1971 ) p. 83, pp. 269-70, Cf. Trotsky, 'The war in the Far East and the Revolutionary perspectives', The Founding Conference o f the Fourth International (New York, no date) on Japan: "Emerging from the ranks of the feudal nobility and the warrior caste of samurai, the bourgeoisie adapted the old institutions, with some modifications, to the requirements of the new systems of capitalist exploitation. Thus ancient feudal institutions, including a 'divine' monarchy, a semi-independent military caste, and semi-feudal types of exploitation exist side by side with a 'democratic' parliament and'powerful industrial and financial t r u s t s . . . '" Cf. also the contribution of H.K. Takahashi to the debate on the transition from feudalism to capitalism, Science and S o c i e t y 1967, and .I. Halliday, 'JapanAsian capitalism', N e w Left R e v i e w 44 (! 96"/) who says of the Meiji Revolution: "even the precise class nature of the Revolution is a subject of dispute. The problem seems Io lie in the divorce between the force which brought about the Revolution (the developing capitalist relations of production and distribution) and the main class behind the Meiji Restoration itself (the warriors), and between the strata which controlled state power after the Revolution and the class character o f their policies". Takahashi, loc. cir. cf. M.E. Falkus, The lndustrialisation o f Russia 1 700-1914 (Macmillan 1972) pp. 69-'/3. R. Luxemburg, The Junius Pamphlet. The Crisis in the German Social Democracy reprinted in Rosa L u x e m b u r g Speaks (Pathfinder ! 970). cf. A. Gerschenkron, Europe in the Russian Mirror. F o u r Lecturs in E c o n o m i c History (Ca mbridge 19"/0), lecture 3. B e t t e l h e i m a p u d Rey, op. cir. Cf.T. Cliff, R u s s i a : A Marxist Ailalysis (IS 1972) and R. Banaji, 'Russia from proletarian revolution to social imperialism', E c o n o m i c and Political ICeekly 1973 (forthcoming). see the good articles of L. Jorberg, 'Structural change and economic growth: Sweden in the 19th ce,st ury', F. Crouzet et al ted) Essays in European Economic History 1789.1914 (Edward Arnold 1969), 'The industrial revolution in the Nordic countries', C.M. Cipolla ted) The Fontana Economic History o f Europe: The Emergence o f lnclustrial Societies 2, and cf. R.E. Caves, 'Export-led growth and the new economic history', 1. Bhagwati et al ted) Trade, Balance o f Payments and Growth (Amsterdam and London 1971 ). as pointed out by L. Cafagna, 'The industrial revolution in Italy 1830-1914', The Fontana Economic History o f Europe: The Emergence o f lnclustrial Societies - 1 (Fontana Books 1973), p. 303. It does to C. Kindleberger, E c o n o m i c D e v e l o p m e n t (Tokyo 1965) p. 164, P. EIIsworth, 'The dual.economy'. Economic D e v e l o p m e n t and Cultural Change 1962, R.E. Baldwin, 'Patterns of development in newly settled regions', C. Etcher and L. Wilt ted) Agriculture in Economic D e v e l o p m e n t (Bombay 1970). None of these writers even attempt to differentiate colonial social formations according to the dominant form of the mode of production. Moreover, because they disintegrate the structure of world economy, they can only grasp certain relatively superficial characteristics of these formations and thus finally end by uttering tautologies, eg. "the primitive and stagnant character of underdeveloped economies explains their failure to develop"[ on this concept, cf. C.F.S. Cardoso, 'S.M. Pelaez y el caracler del regimen colonial', Estudios Sociales Centroamericanos 1972, J.L. Herbert, 'F-ssai d'explication theorique de la reallte sociale Guatemalteque', Indianite et L u t t e des Classes (Paris 1972), J. Banaji, 'For a theory of colonial modes of production', E c o n o m i c and Political Weekly, December 23, 19"/2. For s remarkably concrete study of this process of incorporation, cf. C. Gibson, The A z tees under Spanish Rule. A History o f the Indians o f the Valley o f Mexico 1319-1810 (Stanford and Oxford 1964). On the Philippines, see M.S. McLennan, 'Land and tenancy in the Central Luzon Plain', Philippine Studies, October ] 969.

I 3. 14.

l $.

Downloaded by [Moskow State Univ Bibliote] at 16:04 11 December 2013

16. 17. ! g. 19. 20. 21.

22. 23.

24.

25.

BACKWARD CAPITALISM

411

26.

27.

28.

29. 30. 31. 32. 33. 34. 35.

36. 37.

38. 39. 40. 41. 42.

43.

44.

Cf. J. Delvert, Le Paysan Cambodgien (The Hague ! 961 ) pp. 51 I -S I 8 on the articulation of local merchantusurer capital with the big import-export houses on one side and the peasantry on the other. See also the article by S. Mukherji cited in footnote 8 above. In China in the 19th century the older semi-feudal mode of production was combined with a colomal mode o f production of this specific form, ie. characterized by the penetration o f foreign capital through the circuits o f local merchant capital. See the excellent analysis o f this form in G. Arrighi. 'Labour supplies in historical perspective: a study of the I~roletarisation o f the African peasantry in Rhodesia', Journal o f Development Studies 1970; The Political Economy of Rhodesia (The Hague 1967) and S. Trapido, 'South Africa in a comparative study o f industrialization' (paper presented to the seminar on 'the societies o f Southern Africa in the 19th and 20th century', Institute o f Commonwealth Studies, University of London, October 1970). Cf. the early sections o f C. Furtado, The Economic Growth of Brazil (California 1963) who points out that the slave-based sugar industry was profitable enough to self-finance a doubling o f productive capacity every two years. As done by E.D. Genovese, The Political Economy o f Slavery (MacGibbon & Kee 1965) V.I. Lenin, CW III p. 54. V.I. Lenin, 'A characterisatlon of economic romanticism'. CW I! p. 155. V.I. Lenin, 'On the so-called market question', CW I p. ! 02. For a rigorous presentation of this question, cf. B. Hindess, 'Lenin and the Agrarian Question in the first Russian Revolution', Theoretical Practice May 1972. CW Ill p. 592. On the advance system see the various District Gazetteers o f the United Provinces and Oudho and cf. E. Whitcombe, Agrarian Conditions in Northern India. Volume One. The United Provinces under British Rule 1860-1900 (University of California Press 1971 ). For Marx's remarkable 'notes' on the role o f usurer capital in pre-capitalist formations see Capital ill, ch. 36. The phrase is from L. Trotsky, 'Peculiarities of Russian historical development', Restdts and Prospects. Eg. in Brazil, where "coffee interests were usually against tariffs, government loans to industries, crop diversification, land reforms and education. And the British strengthened the plantation interests". R.Graham, Britain and the Onset o [ Modernization in Brazil. 1850-1914 (Cambridge 1968). For imperialist policy to Indian industrialization, see A.K. Bagchi, Private Investment in India, 1900-1939 (Cambridge 1972), especially the concluding sections o f this excellent book. Cf. Bipan Chandra, 'British and Indian ideas o n ! ndia n economic development, ! 858-1905', Studies in Modern Indian History, I (Orient Longman 1972) who points out that " m o r e than any other single factor it was the tariff policy of the Government of India which convinced Indians that British policies in India were basically guided by the interests of the British capitalist class". R. Owen, Cotton and the Egyptian E c o n o m y , 1820-1 914 (Oxford ! 969). R. Owen, 'Egypt and Europe: from French expedition to British occupation', R. Owen and B. Sutcliffe, Studies in the Theory o f Imperialism (Longman t 972). Ibid. In Egypt in 1880, as pointed out by Hasan Riad, L'Egypte Nasserienne (Paris t964) p. 196, the landowning class of recent bureaucratic formation and foreign origin, lined up behind the Khedive in support of British imperialism. The Peruvian example is from J. Piel, 'The place of the peasantry in the national life of Peru in the 19th century', Past and Present. no. 46. On import-substitution, cf. J. Ahmad, 'import substitution and structural change in Indian manufacturing, 1950-66",Journal o f D e v e l o p m e n t Studies 1968, 'The growth and decline of import substitution in Brazil', E c o n o m i c Bulletin f o r Latin America I X (19641 J. Fiahlow, 'Origins and consequences of import substituion in Brazil', L.E. di Marco (ed), International Economics and D e v e l o p m e n t (Academic Press 1972), C. Furtado, Economic Development o f Latin America: A Survey f r o m Colonial Times to the Cuban Revolution (Cambridge 1970) part four, R.B. Sutcliffe, Industry and Under. d e v e l o p m e n t (Addison Wesley 197 I) p. 249f. Modes of international dependence which were a subordinate mechanism of imperialist domination at earlier stages of world economy when imperialism confronted a mass of colonies and semi-colonies, cf. V.I. Lenin, Imperialism. The Highest Stage o f Capitalism, Collected Works XXll p. 362, with reference to Argentina and Portugal and their peculiar place in imperialist domination. On the side of production this failure of capitalist development in agriculture would force the colonial bourgeoisie to become a heavy importer of foodgrains. For the rela-

Downloaded by [Moskow State Univ Bibliote] at 16:04 11 December 2013

412

J O U R N A L OF C O N T E M P O R A R Y A S I A

45.

46.

47. 48.

49.

50. $ t. 52. S3. 54. $5.

$6. 57. 58. 59. 60.

tively close integration between the industrial bourgeoisie and landowners, cf. Bagchi, op.cit., oh. 6.11. As shown for India by Bipan Chandra, 'The Indian capitalist class and imperialism before 194'/', (mimeo, 1972). The anti-imperialism of the Indian bourgeoisie, specifically the National Congress, which A. Gordon poses as a problem in his interesting, 'The theory of the "progressive" national bourgeoisie', Journal o f Contemporary Asia, vol. 3 no. 2 19"/3, is not difficult to grasp when related to the c/ass interests o f a rising colonial bourgeoisie in the phase o f import-substitution within a national framework dominated by by a colonial state apparatus. In this context bourgeois anti-imperialism is neither a facade which the bourgeoisie erects to fool the people nor the kind o f movement which justifies tailism behind the banner o f 'national capitalism'. In Peru in the ! 920s, while APRA tended to have the latter illusion, .lose Carlos Mariategui in his attack on APRA, 'The anti-imperialist perspective', New Left Review, November-December 1971, showed traces o f the former. Mariategui was absolutely right insofar as he denounced and exposed illusions leading to tailism behind bourgeois nationalism, but wrong insofar as he tended to assimilate all bourgeois-nationalist movements to the model o f a quick betrayal a la Chiang Kai-shek. In the Indian context positions similar tO Mariategul's were taken up by the Comintern during its 'third period', with disastrous consequences for the growth o f the Indian CP. On Argentina see E. Laclau, 'Argentina: imperialist strategy and the May crisia',New Left Review, J uly-August 19'/0 ; on Egypt, M. Hussein, La Lutte de C/asses en E&ypre, i 945. 70 (Paris 19"/I ); on Brazil, O. lanni, Crisis in Brazil (Columbia t 9"/0) and J. Quartim, Dictatorship and Armed Struggle in Brazil (New Left Books 19"/I ). A similar analysis o f the relations between imperialism and the Indian bourgeoisie still needs to be made. To begin with, revolutionaries in India will have to abandon the classic myth that because their bourgeois is not a 'national' one, ie. capable o f accomplishing primitive accumulation through its own resources, it must be 'comprador'. Cf. for an analysis of this mechanism, K. Bharadwaj, 'Notes on political economy o f development: The Indian case', Economic and Political Weekly February 1972 (Annual Number). See C. Payer, 'The perpetuation o f dependence: the I M F and the Third World', Monthly Review, Sept. 19'/I, and 'Exchange controls and national capitalism: the Philippines experience',Yournal o f Contemporary Asia, vol. 3 no. I 19'/3. On the background to these interventions, ie. earlier accumulations o f foreign debt. cf. Economic Commission for Latin America, External Financing in Latin America (UN New Y o r k 1965), Economic Commission for Asia and the Far East, lndustridl Developments in Asia and the.Far East, Volume I. Progress and Problems o f Industrialization (UN New York 1966), A. Maizeis, Industrial Growth and World Trade (Cambridge 1965). On this group: International Development Organisation, Industrial Development Survey, Volume I V (UN New York 1972), S.H. Kim, Foreign Capital f o r Economic Development A Korean Case StNdy (Praeger 1970), B. Balassa, 'Industrial policies in Taiwan and Korea', apud di Marco, op.cit. I. Brecher and S. Abbas, Foreign A i d and Industrial Development in Pakistan (Cambridge 1972). C.F. Diaz-Alejandro. Exchange Rate Devaluation in a Semi.Industrialized Country: Tire Experience o f Argentina, 1933.61 (Massachussets 1965). Cf. J. Bergsman, Brazil: Industrialization and Trade Policies (Oxford 1970). .l. Amuzegar and M. All Fekrat, lran: Economic Development under Dualistic Conditions (Chicago 1971). Cf. the A d m i n i s t r a t o r of AID cited in L. Whitehead, The US and Bolivia: A Case o f Neo. Colonialism (London ! 969). For Egypt-Russia relations in terms of this t ype of analysis, cf. M. Hussein, op.cit. On this see E. Mandel, 'Imperialism and national bourgeoisie in L. America', International vol. I no. 5, R. Pumaruna-Letls, Perou: Revolution Socialistee ou Caricature de Revolution? (Paris 1971 ) and Hussein's analysis of Nasserism, op. cir. An image which Trotsky used for Russia, On Lenin (Oxford 1971) p. 144. For Serrati, cf. ll. Carrere d'Encausse and S.R. Schram, Marxism and Asia (Allen Lane 1969) p. 165f. A phrase used by Beta Kun at the Baku Congress in 1920, d'Encausse and Schram, op. cir. p. 177, but not taken up since. The Platform o f the Left Opposition 1927. L. Trotsky, Tire Death Agony o f Capitalism and the Tasks o f the Fourth International. What is referred to, on the Asian Left, as a 'new de moc ra t i c r e v o l u t i o n ' and s ome t i me s a 'people's democratic r e v o l u t i o n ' oft e n means only what T r o t s k y i s t s have always meant

Downloaded by [Moskow State Univ Bibliote] at 16:04 11 December 2013

BACKWARD CAPITALISM

413

by a 'transitional programme'. The main difference is that when these concepts are interpreted in this specific sense rather than as separate 'stages' of revolution in Stalin's sense, the question of alliance with the rich peasantry, or even sections of the bourgeoisie, recedes from the plane of strategy, where the Stalinists put it, to that of tactics, while on the other hand, the problems of socialist revolution receive the main emphasis in the party's propaganda and agitation.

PREACH, BUT DON'T PRACTICE - FIELD MARSHALL PRAPASS CHARUSATHIAR THAi ARMY

Downloaded by [Moskow State Univ Bibliote] at 16:04 11 December 2013

"You cart teach anything you like today. Ten years ago if you taught from a red book with a hammer and sickle sign on the cover chances a r e you might land in jail, but today you can teach anything - provided you stick to teaching and don't DO anything."

Field Marshall Prapass addressing an audience of Chulalongkom Universi~ professors (Bangkok Post, August 31, ] 9 73J.

II

PACIFIC IMPERIALISM NOTEBOOK


A Monthly Report, with Complete Index $7.50 yearly (Institutions $15; Airmail - $8 extra). Nuts & bolts of US, Japanese & European imperialism in the Asia/Pacific region... Capital export & trade, by country, company & business deal.
Typical subjects:

* International runaway shop: US & Japan export auto & electronics production. * Overproduction crisis & rising US-Japan contradictions. * Japan's zaibatsu & rebirth of the Greater East Asia Coprosperity Sphere. Minerals & oil investment... Extent of foreign control, against a background of struggles for national liberation. (Sample on request)
Write to: PACIFIC RIM PROJECT
Box 2 6 4 1 5 San Francisco C A 9 4 1 2 6 .

Free w i t h sub: Who's W h o in Zaibatsu: Guide to Japanese Finance Capital ( $ 1 . 5 0 separately)

Das könnte Ihnen auch gefallen