Sie sind auf Seite 1von 7

Land tenure policies in the Near East http://www.fao.org/docrep/005/y8999t/y8999t 0f.

htm
N. Forni Nadia Forni is an FAO Consultant The Near East covers a vast and diverse area. The predominance of Islam, in its various streams, is one of the unifying factors in the region. The egalitarian traditions of Islam informed the early systems of land tenure with tenets of social justice and equality. In the nineteenth century, the Ottoman administration codified the prevailing land tenure systems into a set of regulations that are still followed in much of the region, but many of the independent states that emerged in the twentieth century embarked upon redistributive land reforms without first examining the land privatization trends prevailing elsewhere. At the same time, historically developed customary tenure continues to regulate a large part of access to, and use of, the land. Current land tenure systems are failing to address age-old problems: landless households and small farmers continue to compete for limited and fragmented cropland, and pastoralists are losing control of their traditional grazing areas. Access to water is becoming an increasingly important issue as the number of users grows. Major issues such as these are often perceived differently by governments on the one hand and citizens on the other. It is therefore essential that efforts are made to ensure a participatory approach to decision-making that involves the rural populations concerned. BACKGROUND A comprehensive overview of the theoretical and descriptive aspects of land tenure in the Near East region has been prepared for the Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations (FAO) (Rae, 2002). It outlines the historical background and major arguments in the land-tenure debate; implicitly (and sometimes explicitly) it leads to policy conclusions. The present article will therefore focus directly on some major policy issues without analysing in detail all of the conditions related to land tenure in the Near East, which may facilitate discussions on policies and programmes. For ease of reference, a working definition of tenure is provided here, keeping in mind that in this region, one is always speaking of both land and water tenure. Water and access to water are vital factors not only in the arid zones, but also in the most fertile cropping areas of the region, which are often dependent on irrigation. Land tenure can be defined as the group of rights of individuals, households or communities with respect to land. Water also can be accessed under different types of rights. Tenure includes not only property rights, but also use rights of a permanent or seasonal nature. A tenure system may

include rights sanctioned both by law and by custom. That is, alongside the formal legal systems, following defined administrative procedures, there also exist customary rules accepted by the majority of users (Forni, 2001). Communal land and its management were a peculiarity of many parts of the region, where erratic climatic conditions made production risky and therefore the community was used as security. Jointly owned villages practising crop farming were known as musha when the whole territory was undivided. When individual holdings were defined, they were known as mafruz. In general, the cadastres for musha villages followed a system of registering each villager's share of the land as a fraction of the total, while those who occupied land sometimes continued to exchange their shares. As a consequence, although the system is rapidly disappearing in most countries, there is considerable confusion regarding actual ownership rights. Pastures are also largely managed as communal land operations. Common property resources are managed and customarily owned by a certain community according to sets of rules and rights, including individual usufruct but not individual disposal (Forni, 1999). The definition of common property is, however, sometimes confused with state or public property by the authorities, whether deliberately or not. Today's systems of land tenure are thus the inheritance of a long historical tradition, but they have also been heavily influenced by European legislation during the twentieth century, and are currently in full evolution (for a comprehensive and well-documented view of agricultural history in the Near East, see Batatu, 1999, which deals with Syrian agriculture, but is also pertinent for other countries in the region). The sections that follow look more specifically at land tenure as it applies in arid areas used mainly for pastoral production, water tenure and, finally, tenure in farming areas. Arid-land tenure: pastoral production and marginal farming The importance of pastoral tenure is related not so much to the number of people involved which is usually imperfectly known and often statistically underestimated for political reasons but more to the large size of the territories pastoralists traditionally control and its relation with political and ecological issues. Pastoral land tenure presents a special case where producers are often seen by governments as a political threat. Hence the rules and regulations proposed by governments are often intended to control rather than to support the producers. This partly explains the reluctance of many pastoralists in the region to participate in public programmes, because they suspect hidden motives. Traditionally among the nomads, land lies outside commercial transaction, whereas private property is recognized for tents and animals. Land is the property of the tribe; it is available to individuals temporarily, even when it is cultivated. Within the tribal area, dirah, land is allocated among clans and the chief of the clan usually allocates land temporarily among members. There is a contextual concept of tenure that distinguishes between rights of access and rights of disposal, and the emphasis is on the kinship network rather than on individuals (Patrick, in Rae, 2002, Part II, Jordan Country Profile).

This system becomes problematic when several groups hold access rights, and in places where settled and semi-settled groups engaged in crop farming share access rights with mobile pastoralists. This happens, for instance, in Iran, where peasants and nomads share certain territories and landlords' flocks are often farmed out to shepherds on contracts similar to those used for crop sharing. It also occurs in Jordan, in recently urbanized land on the desert fringes that was originally under customary pastoral tenure. It has been reported, for instance, that the state, tribes and Palestinian refugees all claim rights to the same periurban land (Patrick, op. cit.). What need to be examined are tenure relations in different contexts in terms of both area and time. Pastoralists may be entering into tenure agreements in many different locations, and the tenure systems applicable to them will also vary between summer, autumn and winter; finally, traditional rights of passage and interrelations with settled agriculturalists' tenure systems must also be taken into consideration. Historically, nomadic groups tended to have more egalitarian practices, even if the consultation involved primarily the more privileged layers of society. Today, however, the most common element in policymaking at the state level is a lack of participation by the population in devising the policies that will affect them directly. In the badia, it is the community that sanctions legitimacy when state-legislated tenure usurps customary law: the state is seen as an external actor, as Patrick has noted with respect to Jordan (ibid.). A typical recent case involving government intervention to break pastoral communal tenure occurred in Iran, where government interference from the 1920s until the Islamic revolution in the late 1970s was often accompanied by violence. The government's basic objective in the 1920s was to reduce the power and mobility of nomadic tribes in areas where border relations were fragile and the nomadic pastoralists did not readily observe the existence of modern state borders. Measures included blocking mountain passes and interfering with seasonal migration, along with more personally vexing restrictions such as forbidding the use of certain types of tent or enforcing a dress code. Also in Iran, in the 1960s, land reform attempted to settle the nomadic pastoralists, thus interfering with their tenure rights as well as with their traditional social organization, in order to break down their independence (Mortensen and Marcouiller, in Rae, 2002). The current situation is a mixture, with the Jihad Ministry in charge of coordination between different pastoral groups and with formal encouragement to participatory development (FAO, 1992).

Types of Land Ownershiphttp(://www.professor-frithjofkuhnen.de/publications/man-and-land/1-1-1-1.htm)


Various systems of land ownership have developed throughout the world under the influence of historical, cultural, and economic factors. These systems are exposed to a continual process of change.

State Ownership of Land


As a consequence of conquest, purchasing, gifts, and seizure, land belongs to the state in many countries in the same way as other areas belong to private people. In the USSR, the majority of the land has been turned into state property.In other socialist countries, only a part until now.

This was done to prevent exploitation resulting form private ownership of the land as well as unearned income derived from ground rent. Otherwise, state ownership plays a large role if public interests cannot be satisfied by private ownership, or if the land is not of interest to private people from an economic standpoint (catchment areas, waste land, forest, frontiers, experimental farms, etc,). The state partially cultivates its own land (government farms, government forests) and also partially leases it out. In some countries, the church likewise has a great deal of landed property. The process by which the church gained possession of the land and its function is similar to that in the case of state land.

Land Grants
In Islamic countries, land is granted to schools, ,mosques, orphanages, and similar institutions. This type of grant is often called a "waqf." The beneficiary receives an irrevocable right of use that is carried out by government organizations, generally in the form of being leased out. The institution that is granted the right of use receives the profit. The lands are frequently in very bad condition as hardly any investments are made. Land is sometimes established as a private waqf. The irrevocability of the grant, that is established in court, prevents eventual changes in ownership and protects the family against property losses. The family receives the income derived from the yield. This type of grant is also found in the south of Europe and existed in Eastern Germany until 1945 where it was called "Fideikommis."

Collective and Communal Ownership


In this type of ownership, the right of disposition is in the hands of kinship or political groups that are larger than a single family. In the forms of communal ownership found in Africa (a widespread phenomenon south, of the Sahara), the land rights are generally controlled by the tribe, and the use of the land is regulated by the chieftain or priest serving the land and earth deities. Every member that is born into the group has a lifelong right to a piece of land for his own usage. The tribes regard themselves as custodians of the land for future generations rather than proprietors. In Mexico, former latifundia were transferred into a form of communal. land called "ejido." The members of the community are granted land on a heritable basis for their usage, while pasture land and waste land are used commonly. In various countries such as Taiwan, India, and Jamaica, land belongs to minorities in the form of common land. The purpose behind this is to give protection against loss of the land. In socialistic countries, land was collectivized in accordance with the political doctrine in order to prevent exploitation resulting from private ownership of land. At the same time, this measure simplifies controlling agricultural production and the process of adapting to the goals of rapid industrialization and overall development.Based on a different ideology, but with similar motives, various religious communities have also abolished private ownership of land and collectivized it. Physical and/or psychological coercion and pressure or a critical situation have always played a great role in collectivization.

Private Ownership of Land


In non-socialistic countries, the right of disposition is often in private hands regarding agricultural land, less so in the case of forests. In face of the positive experience in European history and its great ability to adapt to changing economic and technological systems, private ownership of land was introduced in many of the former colonies. In the process, however, it became obvious that the positive outgrowth of private ownership were dependent upon certain specific preconditions that were not always present. The decrease in the size of the farms resulting from population increase and the differences in the success achieved in the process of adaption to changing conditions especially of an economic nature led in part to property losses, whereas other people were able to gain control of large areas and, thus, economic and consequently political power. As a result of this process, today there are several widely differing forms of private ownership. Small scale agricultural property, or smallholdings, is a widespread form throughout the world and is the target of most of the non socialistic agrarian reforms. Family farms have proved to be an expedient form of agricultural organization, both regarding agrarian production as well as the social conditions, as long as the farm size is large enough. The incentive ensuing from the farmers freedom to make his own decisions and the knowledge that he will receive the fruits of all his labour and investments have always been a tremendous inducement, especially if the attitude towards work and investments was positive and the concomitant institutions (extension services, credit system) were advantageous. In order for family farms to guarantee the continuation of yields from their land, it is necessary for them to observe the preservation of the ecological balance. As soon as the precondition of sufficient farm size no longer exists, the situation becomes less favourable and the living standard of the farmers' families drops, the farms become indebted, property is lost, and the ecological balance is endangered. Large holdings are in many cases not farmed by the owner himself. If there is a large demand for land, the owner is in a position to let others work for him and still receive a sufficient income. He, therefore, leases the land out, and, although he exercises his influence regarding farm management, this is more to control the farm rent payments than to foster agricultural production. The rent is usually not reinvested, but rather used by the owner to cover his own living expenses as well as other purposes. Thus landed property becomes a source of rent while the agricultural economy remains static. As soon as the owner becomes more interested in the cultivation of his land, he generally switches to centrally controlled farming as this makes it possible to control the cropping vote closely and, thus, guarantee economic success. This form is not only found on plantations and commercial farms. In the course of the Green Revolution, many former lessors started cultivating the land themselves as this appeared to them to be more profitable under the new circumstances than the traditional forms of leasing the land to tenants.

Systems of Land Tenure (Social Agrarian Structure)

The system of land tenure governs the traditional or legal rights individuals or groups have to land and the resulting social relationships among the rural population. Its components are the system of land ownership and system of labour organization. In accordance with the existing conditions, many different land tenure systems have developed throughout the world, whereby both natural conditions (climate, soil conditions, topography) as well as social factors (sociocultural values, political ideology, level of technological development, population trend, changes in the cost price relationships, etc.) played a role. Systems of land tenure are not immutable. On the contrary, they are subjected to a continual process of change. Changes in the natural growing conditions and economic factors, technological innovations, changes in the size of the population, and influences emanting from the political power structures bring about changes in the land tenure system. As in recent times these factors have been changing more and more rapidly, the system of land tenure frequently lags behind the new situation and does not adjust to it on time. Land tenure systems are institutionally established and are, therefore, difficult to alter. Political power structures; cooperative ties and class, cultural, and ethnic interests and motives all work towards maintaining the established forms. As a result of the continual changes in the factors that govern and form the land tenure system, an ideal land tenure system cannot exist. The momentary, specific land tenure system is the institutional framework within which the agrarian production and way of life are carried out under the existing circumstances and conditions. It is interrelated with the natural, economic, social, and political conditions. As these change, the land tenure system has to continually adapt itself to the changing situation.
Foragers (the

Toba of the western Argentinean Gran Chaco

Foragers and others RICHARD B. LEE AND RICHARD DALY Mobility is another characteristic of band societies. People tend to move their settlements frequently, several times a year or more, in search of food, and this mobility is an important element of their politics. People in band societies tend to "vote with their feet;' moving away rather than submitting to the will of an unpopular leader. Mobility is also a means of resolving conflicts that would be more difficult for settled peoples. land tenure system based on a common property regime (CPR). These regimes were, until recently, far more common world wide than regimes

based on private property. In traditional CPRs, while movable property is held by individuals, land is held bya kinship based collective. Rules of reciprocal access make it possible for each individual to draw on the resources of several territories. Rarer is the situation where the whole society has unrestricted access to all the land controlled by the group. The Hadza area huntergatherer people in northern Tanzania
The Caribou Inuit of Eskimo speaking people The Ju/honsi of Botswana and Namibia kung speaking people

The Tiwi of Melville and Bathurst Islands, north Australiav aborigines speaking people

Agriculture resources became more plentiful, social classes became more divisive. Those who had more resources could afford better living and developed into a class of nobility. Difference in social standing between men and women increased. As cities expanded, ownership and preservation of resources became a pressing concern.

Das könnte Ihnen auch gefallen