Sie sind auf Seite 1von 11

May 20, 2005

Capital Ideas RevisitedPart 2


Thoughts on Beating a Mostly-Efficient Stock Market






















The paradox of efficient markets says whenever researchers find
meaningful anomalies, practitioners exploit them, thus eliminating them
and leaving the market even more efficient than before.

Informationally efficient markets are highly unlikely because unearthing
information is costly and investors expect some benefit to compensate
them for their efforts.

If noise creates a set of expectations that are inconsistent with the long-
term signal, theres an opportunity for time arbitrage.

Slow traveling ideas are a long-term investors best bet for delivering
superior results.





Legg Mason Capital
Management
mmauboussin@lmfunds.com
Michael J. Mauboussin
Mauboussin
!llustration by Sente Corporation - www.senteco.com

LHGG MABON CAI1AL MANAGHMHN1 2
Introduction

In the first part of this essay (Capital Ideas Revisited: The Prime Directive, Sharks, and the Wisdom of
Crowds, March 30, 2005) we argue that active investors need to carefully consider market efficiency. We
view understanding how and why markets are efficient, or inefficient, essential to providing thoughtful
investors with a roadmap to superior results.

Standard theory offers three approaches to explain market efficiency: rational agents, heterogeneous
investors with independent errors, and the no-arbitrage assumption. We claim that the two most widely
used arguments, rational agents and no-arbitrage, dont have realistic assumptions andmore
importantlyoffer predictions that do not comport with the empirical facts.

We make the case for viewing markets as a complex adaptive system, where efficient prices emerge from
the interaction of heterogeneous investors. This approach doesnt rely on agent rationality and offers
stylized predictions that fit well with the empirical record. The wisdom of crowds approach, however, only
works under certain conditions; all efficiency bets are off when markets violate those conditions.

We provide a slew of collective problem-solving examples, including social insects, experimental
economics, and decision markets. We cant extrapolate these results to assert stock market efficiency
state-estimation and prediction problems are a good deal simpler because they have measurable outcomes
and finite time horizonsbut they do provide evidence for the prowess of collectives.

Behavioral finance also plays a central role in investor heterogeneity. While researchers often dwell on how
individuals behave sub-optimally (Daniel Kahneman and Amos Tversky, 1979), we argue that only analysis
at the collective level can unearth inefficiencies. Even if investors deviate from rationality in the same way
(e.g., overconfident) they still may err independently.

The first essay also examined the statistical properties of markets, noting that markets deviate from the
assumption of normal, bell-shaped price change distributions and prices often exhibit a memory effect. Both
observations violate the most basic market theory.

Why do markets fail? Most simply, investor heterogeneity breaks down and everyone acts in unison,
leading to excessive optimism (greed) or pessimism (fear). Social psychology teaches us that we like to
imitate one another, and we often place greater weight on being part of the group than on our own
observations. These diversity breakdowns, albeit rare, provide investors with significant opportunities to
earn excess rates of return.

The foremost conclusion from our discussion is that markets are largely efficient, but for different reasons
than the standard theory argues. The interaction of diverse investors, not a rational few or many, leads to
prices that reasonably reflect expectations. No matter how we arrive at prices, though, a key question
remains: How do you beat the market?

Here are the areas we cover:

We start in a logical placea quick review of the literature on market anomalies. Anomalies are
empirical findings that appear to contradict the core principles of the efficient market hypothesis.
Naturally, the critical question is whether or not these deviations are sufficiently significant and
stable for investors to profit from them.

We then look at informational efficiency, which basically suggests that todays prices reflect all
relevant information. Of course, investors cant believe markets are perfectly informationally
efficient; otherwise they would have no incentive to collect information. Many investors, however,
delegate their investment decisions to agents. Because the goals of the agents and investors are
not always aligned, many professional investors get paid to simply take part in the game. Perhaps
the most egregious result of this agency problem is shrinking investment time horizons. When
short-term noise creates a set of expectations inconsistent with the long-term signal, an opportunity
for time arbitrage arises.


LHGG MABON CAI1AL MANAGHMHN1 3
Next, we look at dramatic diversity breakdowns, where positive feedback causes booms and
crashes. Here, the breakdown stems from imitative behavior. We consider some of the signatures
of these breakdowns.

Finally, we turn to a more subtle form of diversity breakdown, investment ideas that Jack Treynor
(1975) says, travel slowly. These ideas require reflection and judgment, which many investors do
not exercise because of incentive-caused biases.

Anomalies

These [research] findings raise the possibility that anomalies are more apparent than real. The notoriety
associated with the findings of unusual evidence tempts authors to further investigate puzzling anomalies
and later try to explain them. But even if the anomalies existed in the sample period in which they were first
identified, the activities of practitioners who implement strategies to take advantage of anomalous behavior
can cause the anomalies to disappear (as research findings cause the market to become more efficient).

G. William Schwert
Anomalies and Market Efficiency
1


Using the word anomalydeviation from the normal orderto describe market behavior embeds an
assumption about what is normal for the market. In finance, anomalies are market behavior inconsistent
with the predictions of the efficient market hypothesis. In particular, these anomalies appear to violate
assumptions of mean-variance efficiency or no-arbitrage. If a complex adaptive system approach better
describes markets, the so-called anomalies researchers have identified may not be anomalous after all.

Despite voluminous literature on anomalies, the major findings tend to fall into one of four areas:

1. Calendar effects. Donald Keim (1983) and Marc Reinganum (1983) showed that small
capitalization stocks tend to do better in January than the capital asset pricing models (CAPM)
prediction.
2. Size effects. Rolf Banz (1981) and Reinganum (1981) found that small companies generate
higher returns than what is consistent with the CAPM.
3. Value effects. Around the same time researchers identified size effects, Sanjoy Basu (1977 and
1983) established that companies with low price-earnings generate higher-than-expected
returns relative to the CAPM. Eugene Fama and Kenneth French (1992) extended the thinking,
arguing that size and value effects are risk factors the CAPM does not capture.
4. Momentum effects. Werner DeBondt and Richard Thaler (1985) found that past stock price
losers have higher average returns than past winners; investors overreact to bad news,
creating an opportunity for the contrarian.
2
Narasimhan Jegadeesh and Sheridan Titman
(1993) presented contradictory research showing that recent stock price winners outpace
recent losers.

Many apparent anomalies cant deliver excess returns after considering practical constraints like
transaction costs and liquidity issues. Ultimately, benefiting from anomalies is difficult because of the
paradox of efficient markets: whenever researchers find meaningful anomalies, practitioners immediately
try to exploit them, thus eliminating the anomalies and leaving the market even more efficient than before.
Unlike some other probabilistic fields, when you act on your predictions in markets you can actually change
the outcomes of your predictions.

A pair of studies on technical trading rules provides one example of the efficient markets paradox. In the
first paper, William Brock, Josef Lakonishok and Blake LeBaron (1992) showed that certain simple
technical rules, applied to 100 years of daily data for the Dow Jones Industrial Average, generated returns
that outperformed appropriate benchmarks. (This conclusion violates the weak form of market efficiency.) In
a follow up paper, Ryan Sullivan, Allan Timmerman and Halbert White (1997) tested the findings, and
discovered that the best technical trading rule does not provide superior performance when used to trade
in the subsequent 10-year post-sample period.
3
In other words, the best trading rule worked until the
professors published their findings.


LHGG MABON CAI1AL MANAGHMHN1 4
In his detailed survey of anomalies, William Schwert (2003) tracked the performance of two funds explicitly
created to exploit size and value effects. They met limited success. Schwert noted, the small-firm anomaly
has disappeared since the initial publication of the papers that discovered it, and added, the apparent
[value] anomaly that motivated the funds creation seems to have disappeared, or at least attenuated.
4

Once again, the strategy practitioners used to capitalize on the anomaly failed.

Richard Roll, a leading finance researcher and money manager, is one of the best-positioned individuals to
judge the merit of anomalies. His view is unambiguous:

I have personally tried to invest money, my clients and my own, in every single anomaly and
predictive result that academics have dreamed up. That includes the strategy of DeBondt and
Thaler (that is, sell short individual stocks immediately after one-day increases of more than 5%),
the reverse of DeBondt and Thaler which is Jegadeesh and Titman (buy individual stocks after they
have decreased by 5%), etc. I have attempted to exploit the so-called year-end anomalies and a
whole variety of strategies supposedly documented by academic research. And I have yet to make
a nickel on any of these supposed market inefficiencies. (Emphasis original.)

Roll goes on to underscore the importance of finding systematic opportunities. He also offers a nod to the
complex adaptive systems approach:

. . . A true market inefficiency ought to be an exploitable opportunity. If theres nothing investors can
exploit in a systematic way, time in and time out, then its very hard to say that information is not
being properly incorporated into stock prices. In fact, information is being incorporated into the price
through the filters of the millions of people evaluating that information. (Emphasis original.)

He ends with a clear-cut verdict:

Real money investment strategies dont produce the results that academic papers say they should.
5


Naturally, markets evolve. This suggests that anomalies will come and go, and the chase to exploit
anomalies will continue. Consistent anomalies, should they exist, likely find root in psychology (and perhaps
evidence of a diversity breakdown). Practitioners are likely to quickly compete away any anomaly that can
be exploited with an algorithm.

Notwithstanding Rolls comments some investment firmsmost notably LSV Asset Management and Fuller
& Thaler Asset Managementhave enjoyed success employing behavioral-finance-based investment
processes. These results add balance to the poor fund performance Schwert found.



LHGG MABON CAI1AL MANAGHMHN1 5
Informational Efficiency

When a price system is a perfect aggregator of information it removes private incentives to collect
information. If information is costly, there must be noise in the price system so that traders can earn a return
on information gathering . . . When many individuals attempt to earn a return on information collection, the
equilibrium price is affected and it perfectly aggregates information. This provides an incentive for
individuals to stop collecting information.

Sanford Grossman
On the Efficiency of Competitive Stock Markets Where Traders Have Diverse Information
6


When academics discuss efficient markets, they almost always mean informational efficiencythe idea that
todays stock prices fully reflect all relevant information. In such a market, investors cannot use available
information to earn excess risk-adjusted returns. The paucity of investment managers who have generated
above-market returns over time supports this view.

Informational efficiency has some noteworthy ancillaries. First, researchers often connect informational
efficiency to the random walk theory, which says stock price changes are random. The idea is since prices
reflect all available information, price changes result only from new information, which comes randomly by
definition.
7
While the link between the random walk theory and the efficient market hypothesis is technically
incorrect, many financial economists still implicitly associate the two.
8


Second, informational efficiency does not say that prices are fundamentally correct. The theorys main
claim is there are no achievable excess returns. Informational efficiency offers no assurance that an
economy allocates resources in an efficient manner, only that asset prices are not mispriced relative to one
another.

Finally, markets become more efficient as investors face falling costs to access, and act on, information.
The advance of technology, regulations assuring all investors receive material information simultaneously,
and ever-declining transaction costs likely contribute to greater efficiency.

Still, informational efficiency is an ideal. In fact, Sanford Grossman (1976) and Grossman and Joseph
Stiglitz (1980) argue that informationally efficient markets are impossible. Since unearthing information is
costly, investors expect some benefit to compensate them for their efforts. Without the promise of some
excess returns, investors would have no incentive to gather information in the first place.

Even giving full weight to the Grossman and Stiglitz argument, the number of investors trying to beat the
market dwarfs the number trying who actually will. Alfred Rappaport (2005) addresses this puzzle, noting
the Grossman and Stiglitz case holds only in a world of investors acting on their own behalf. Principals,
however, increasingly defer to agents for their investment decisions.

In most cases, agents get paid whether or not the principals do well. John Bogle estimates hedge fund
fees, direct mutual fund costs, and pension management fees amounted to a combined $110 billion in
2004.
9
Despite the good intentions and hard work of most professional money managers, in reality they get
paid to play, not necessarily to win.

Current incentives encourage agent behavior that is not always consistent with maximizing long-term
shareholder returns (Bradford Cornell and Roll, 2005). In recent decades many large investment firms have
emphasized marketing (often at the expense of the investment process), increased the number of funds
they offer (selling whats hot), and boosted the number of stocks they hold in order to minimize tracking
error versus the benchmark.

But perhaps the most significant incentive-caused behavior, and most relevant for a discussion of how to
beat the market, is the reduction in investment time horizons. According to Bogle (2005), average equity
portfolio turnover rose from 20% in the mid-1960s to 112% in 2004. And fund managers arent the only
ones with shorter time horizons; Bogle documents that mutual fund owners redeem shares at a rate four
times higher than a few decades ago.


LHGG MABON CAI1AL MANAGHMHN1 6
Time horizon is a crucial consideration in any probabilistic field.
10
In these systems, short-term results
show mostly noisethe noise-to-signal ratio is very high. But over time, the signal reveals itself, and the
noise-to-signal ratio drops.

Short-term investors dwell mostly in the world of noise.
11


A very simple coin-tossing example demonstrates this point. Exhibit 1s left panel is the result of a 20-toss
trial, and shows that 35% of the tosses came up heads. (Simulated with a random number generator). The
panel on the right continues with the next 80 tosses in the series, and shows that the ratio settles very close
to 50% over 100 flips. Even though we know the long-term signal is 50%, short-term noise can deviate
substantially from long-term signal.

Exhibit 1: Noise versus Signal















Source: LMCM analysis.

Asset prices reflect a set of expectations. If investors chasing noise create a set of expectations
inconsistent with the long-term signal, an opportunity for time arbitrage arises. This arbitrage works only if
the short-term focus creates a diversity breakdowntoo few investors focused on the signaland the
signal becomes clear over time.

Still, benefiting from time arbitrage is difficult for a couple of reasons. First, even when we know what the
underlying system looks like, we see patterns where none exist. The reason is were wired to expect that
the characteristics of chance show up not just in a total sequence, but also in small parts of the sequence.
Psychologists Tversky and Kahneman (1971) call this the belief in the law of small numbers.
12
Guillermo
Baquero and Marno Verbeek (2005) show that even sophisticated investors fall into this trap when
evaluating portfolio managers.

Second, the incentives for important constituencies, including brokers, investors, and plan sponsors,
increasingly encourage a short-term approach. For example, more trading means higher commissions for a
sell-side broker. Innumeracy and rising impatience create meaningful institutional barriers to exploiting time
arbitrage.

Recent research documents the importance of time horizon. Using experimental economics, Shinichi Hirota
and Shyam Sunder (2004) find that prices converge to fundamental values when set by long-term investors
but become indeterminate with short-term investors. They note that long-term investors can use backward
induction based on future dividends, while short-term investors use forward induction using trend
processes. Because short-term investors dont focus on a dividend anchor, markets dominated by short-
term investors will more likely see booms and crashes.

Taking a different tack, Brian Bushee (2001) classifies investors based on their time horizon and shows that
investors with the shortest time horizons prefer near-term earnings to long-term value. This preference
leads to significant misvaluations, or a time arbitrage opportunity.

Bushees findings are consistent with what Shlomo Benartzi and Thaler (1995) call myopic loss aversion.
This concept combines loss aversionthe human tendency to weigh losses more heavily than gainsand
0
0.1
0.2
0.3
0.4
0.5
0.6
0.7
0.8
0.9
1
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20
Trial Number
P
e
r
c
e
n
t
a
g
e

o
f

H
e
a
d
s
0
0.1
0.2
0.3
0.4
0.5
0.6
0.7
0.8
0.9
1
1 21 41 61 81
Trial Number
P
e
r
c
e
n
t
a
g
e

o
f

H
e
a
d
s

LHGG MABON CAI1AL MANAGHMHN1 7
myopia, a form of mental accounting, which shows investors are more sensitive when they evaluate their
portfolios frequently. Myopic loss aversion suggests that long-term investors will pay more than short-term
investors for the same risky asset because they can largely sidestep loss aversion.

Dramatic Diversity Breakdowns

Information cascades, during which individuals in a population exhibit herd-like behavior because they are
making decisions based on the actions of other individuals rather than relying on their own information
about the problem . . . display two striking qualitative features: they occur rarely, but by definition are large
when they do.

Duncan J. Watts
A simple model of global cascades on random networks
13


Inefficiency most likely occurs in one of two ways, which share a common root: diversity breakdowns. The
first, a dramatic breakdown, is typically accompanied by an abrupt stock price movement.

A dramatic diversity breakdown occurs when positive feedback launches sentiment about a particular stock
(or the market) to extreme optimism or pessimism, increasing the likelihood of a significant and sharp
reversal. In most cases, the positive feedback emanates from a kernel of legitimately good or bad
fundamentals. The breakdown occurs when the fundamental view is overstretched, creating a set of
expectations substantially out of sync with the fundamentals. If most everyone is bullish, demand dries up
and the markets most likely path is down.

How can you recognize a dramatic diversity breakdown? There are various measures to consider, including
sentiment indicators, funds flow data, and valuation levels.
14
Other possible signatures of dramatic diversity
breakdowns include large price changes, stocks or industries at 52-week highs or lows, and statistically
expensive or cheap valuations.

One broad indicator is what appears on magazine covers: by the time an investment sentiment makes the
cover of a national periodical, its almost always time to take the opposite side of the trade. Among the most
famous examples is the The Death of Equities cover story in the August 13, 1979 issue of BusinessWeek
that proclaimed, the death of equities looks like an almost permanent condition. In the twenty-five years
following 1979, the stock market has generated a 12.9% compounded annual return in contrast to the
negative real return the market offered in the ten years ended 1979.
15


In contrast, the cover of the September 1999 issue of The Atlantic Monthly featured a story called Dow
36,000: The Right Price for Stocks, within months of the markets high. The Nasdaq Composite Index,
emblematic of the heady times, is still 60% below its March 2000 peak.

Slow Traveling Ideas

I see nothing in the arguments of Professor Eugene Fama or the other efficient market advocates to
suggest that large groups of investors may not make the same error in appraising the kind of abstract ideas
that take special expertise to understand and evaluate, and that consequently travel relatively slowly.

Jack L. Treynor
Long-Term Investing
16

The second type of diversity breakdown, articulated by Jack Treynor nearly 30 years ago, is less dramatic
and only requires an investor to interpret the same investment information differently than the consensus of
other investors. Treynor distinguishes between two kinds of investment ideas: (a) those whose implications
are straightforward and obvious, take relatively little special expertise to evaluate, and consequently travel
quickly (e.g., hot stocks); and (b) those that require reflection, judgment, special expertise, etc., for their
evaluation, and consequently travel slowly. He adds, Pursuit of the second kind of idea . . . is, of course,
the only meaningful definition of long-term investing.
17

Treynor, who uses a wisdom-of-crowds-type argument, suggests that if investors differ in their assessments
of a security value when they have the same information, their differences stem from errors in their analysis

LHGG MABON CAI1AL MANAGHMHN1 8
of the second idea type. If their errors are independent (satisfying the diversity condition), the error implicit
in the consensus will be small.

Treynor continues:

As the key to the averaging process underlying an accurate consensus is the assumption of
independence, if allor even a substantial fractionof these investors make the same error, the
independence assumption is violated and the consensus can diverge significantly from true value.
The market then ceases to be efficient in the sense of pricing available information correctly.

To explain why this type of diversity breakdown can occur, Treynor turns to John Maynard Keynes, who
adds two crucial elements to the case. First, he argues that most investors:

. . . are in fact largely concerned not with most superior long term forecasts of the probable yield of
an investment over its whole life, but with foreseeing changes in the conventional basis of
evaluation a short time ahead of the general public. They are concerned . . . with what the market
will evaluate it at under the influence of mass psychology three months or a year hence. (Emphasis
original.)

Keynes goes on to underscore how hard it is to be a long-term investor:

It is the long term investor, he who promotes the public interest, who will in practice come in for the
most criticism . . . For it is the essence of his behavior that he should be eccentric, unconventional
and rash in the eyes of the average opinion. If he is successful, that will only confirm the general
belief in his rashness; and if in the short run he is unsuccessful, which is very likely, he will not
receive much mercy. Worldly wisdom teaches that it is better for reputation to fail conventionally
than to succeed unconventionally.
18


In effect, the Treynor-Keynes commentary adds up to time arbitrage: long-term investors are in a much
better position to assess and act on the non-obvious investment opportunities, although at a psychological
toll. Evidence suggests that investors and companies remain very focused on the short term, in large part
reflecting significant agency costs.
19


An expectations approach offers a viable way to distinguish between fundamentals and the expectations an
asset price reflects. The process has three steps: understand market-embedded expectations for future
financial performance; assess the likelihood of expectations revisions using strategic and financial analysis;
and make an investment decision. Rather than asking investors to forecast explicitly, the expectations
approach instead asks investors to seek gaps between likely outcomes and the markets collective forecast.
This approach complements Treynors idea and addresses the main concern investors have about
forecasts.
20


Conclusion

The efficient market hypothesis offers a practically sound prescription: most investors are best served
investing in low cost, passive index funds. Overwhelming evidence, accumulated over many decades,
shows a consistent inability of most active investment managers to add value.

Active investment managers seeking to earn excess returns should have a thoughtful investment process
that logically starts with a view on how and why market mispricings can occur. Of the three approaches to
explain market efficiency, only the complex adaptive systems perspective comfortably accommodates what
we see in the real world: heterogeneous investors create markets that are efficient most of the time but that
periodically go to excesses. The rational agent and no-arbitrage approaches, while valuable constructs, are
not true mechanisms and fail to explain real market behavior in many important respects.

The ultimate goal of an active investor is to buy securities in anticipation of an expectations revision. Abrupt
diversity breakdowns offer potential investment opportunity, but at a significant psychological cost. Slow
traveling ideas provide a long-term investors best bet for delivering superior results.


LHGG MABON CAI1AL MANAGHMHN1 9


Endnotes

1
G. William Schwert, Anomalies and Market Efficiency, in The Handbook of The Economics of Finance,
Constantinides, Harris, and Stulz, eds. (Amsterdam: Elsevier, 2003), 941.
2
Richard H. Thaler, The Winners Curse: Paradoxes and Anomalies of Economic Life (Princeton, NJ:
Princeton University Press, 1992, 157-158.
3
Ryan Sullivan, Allan Timmerman, and Halbert White, Data-Snooping, Technical Trading Rule
Performance, and the Bootstrap, UCSD Working Paper, December 8, 1997.

4
Schwert, 944-948.

5
Comments by Richard Roll in Volatility in U.S. and Japanese Stock Markets, selections from the First
Annual Symposium on Global Financial Markets, Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, Vol. 5, 1, Summer
1992.
6
Sanford J. Grossman, On the Efficiency of Competitive Stock Markets Where Traders Have Diverse
Information, The Journal of Finance, Vol. 31, 2, May 1976.
7
Paul Samuelson, Proof that Properly Anticipated Prices Fluctuate Randomly, Industrial Management
Review, Vol. 6, 1965, 41-49.
8
Andrew W. Lo and A. Craig MacKinlay, A Non-Random Walk Down Wall Street (Princeton, NJ: Princeton
University Press, 1999), 4-5. Lo and MacKinleys research rejects the random walk hypothesis.
9
See http://www.vanguard.com/bogle_site/sp20050210.htm.
10
Michael J. Mauboussin, Decision Making for Investors, Mauboussin on Strategy, Legg Mason Capital
Management, May 24, 2004.
11
See Nassim Nicholas Taleb, Fooled by Randomness, 2
nd
ed. (New York: Thomson Texere, 2004), 64-68.
12
One recent example comes from Yankees owner George Steinbrenner following the teams lackluster 4-
8 start in 2005: "It is unbelievable to me that the highest-paid team in baseball would start the season in
such a deep funk. They are not playing like true Yankees. They have the talent to win and they are not
winning. I expect Joe Torre, his complete coaching staff and the team to turn this around. Not surprisingly,
the Yankees had a similar streak (and one worse one) in their World-Series-winning 2000 season. See
David Ginsburg, Steinbrenner Lashes Out at Stumbling Yankees, Associated Press, April 18, 2005.
13
Duncan J. Watts, A simple model of global cascades on random networks, Proceedings of the National
Academy of the Sciences, April 30, 2002.
14
An Asset Allocation Strategy for the Intelligent Investor, Evergreen Capital Management, LLC. See
http://www.gold-eagle.com/editorials_05/mauldin040505.html.
15
Ned Davis, The Triumph of Contrarian Investing (New York: McGraw Hill, 2004). See
http://www.tilsonfunds.com/DeathofEquities.pdf.
16
Jack L. Treynor, Long-Term Investing, Financial Analysts Journal, May/June 1976, 56-59.
17
Ibid.
18
John Maynard Keynes, The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money (New York: Harcourt
Brace Jovanovich, Inc., 1936), 154-158.
19
Alfred Rappaport, The Economics of Short-term Performance Obsession, Financial Analysts Journal,
May/June 2005.
20
Alfred Rappaport and Michael J. Mauboussin, Expectations Investing (Boston, MA: Harvard Business
School Press, 2001).


Legg Mason Capital Management ("LMCM":) is comprised of (i) Legg Mason Capital Management, Inc.
("LMCI"), (ii) Legg Mason Funds Management, Inc. ("LMFM"), and (iii) LMM LLC ("LMM").

The views expressed in this commentary reflect those of LMCM as of the date of this commentary. These
views are subject to change at any time based on market or other conditions, and LMCM disclaims any
responsibility to update such views. These views may not be relied upon as investment advice and,
because investment decisions for clients of LMCM are based on numerous factors, may not be relied upon
as an indication of trading intent on behalf of the firm. The information provided in this commentary should
not be considered a recommendation by LMCM or any of its affiliates to purchase or sell any security.

Legg Mason Investor Services, LLC, Distributor
Member SIPC

LHGG MABON CAI1AL MANAGHMHN1 10
Resources

Books

Constantinides, George M., Milton Harris and Rene M. Stulz, eds., Handbook of The Economics of Finance
(Amsterdam: Elsevier, 2003).

Davis, Ned, The Triumph of Contrarian Investing (New York: McGraw Hill, 2004).

Grossman, Sanford, The Informational Role of Prices (Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 1989).

Keynes, John Maynard, The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money (New York: Harcourt
Brace Jovanovich, Inc., 1936).

Lo, Andrew W., and A. Craig MacKinlay, A Non-Random Walk Down Wall Street (Princeton, NJ: Princeton
University Press, 1999), 4-5.


Rappaport, Alfred, and Michael J. Mauboussin, Expectations Investing: Reading Stock Prices for Better
Returns (Boston, MA: Harvard Business School Press, 2001).

Schwert, G. William, Anomalies and Market Efficiency, in The Handbook of The Economics of Finance,
Constantinides, Harris, and Stulz, eds. (Amsterdam: Elsevier, 2003).

Taleb, Nassim Nicholas, Fooled by Randomness, 2
nd
ed. (New York: Thomson Texere, 2004).

Articles and Papers

Banz, Rolf W., The Relationship between Return and Market Value of Common Stocks, Journal of
Financial Economics, vol. 9, March 1981, 3-18.

Baquero, Guillermo, and Marno Verbeek, Do Sophisticated Investors Believe in the Law of Small
Numbers? Erasmus University Rotterdam Working Paper, January 2005.

Basu, Sanjoy, Investment Performance of Common Stocks in Relation to their Price Earnings Ratios: A
Test of the Efficient Market Hypothesis, Journal of Finance, vol. 32, 1977, 663-682.

Basu, Sanjoy, The Relationship between Earnings Yield, Market Value, and Return for NYSE Common
Stocks, Journal of Financial Economics, vol. 12, 1983, 126-441.

Benartzi, Shlomo, and Richard Thaler, Myopic Loss Aversion and the Equity Risk Premium Puzzle,
Quarterly Journal of Economics, February 1995, 73-92.

Bogle, John C., The Mutual Fund Industry 60 Years Later: For Better or Worse, Financial Analysts
Journal, January/February 2005.

Brock, William, Josef Lakonishok, and Blake LeBaron, Simple technical trading rules and the stochastic
properties of stock returns, Journal of Finance, vol. 47, 5, 1992, 1731-764.

Bushee, Brian J., Do Institutional Investors Prefer Near-Term Earnings over Long-Run Value?
Contemporary Accounting Research, vol. 18, 2, 2001, 207-246.

Cornell, Bradford, and Richard Roll, A Delegated-Agent Asset-Pricing Model, Financial Analysts Journal,
January/February 2005.

DeBondt, Werner F. M., and Richard H. Thaler, Does the Stock Market Overreact? Journal of Finance,
vol. 40, July 1985, 783-805.


LHGG MABON CAI1AL MANAGHMHN1 11
Fama, Eugene F. and Kenneth R. French, The Cross-section of Expected Stock Returns, Journal of
Finance, vol. 47, 1992, 427-465.

Grossman, Sanford J., On the Efficiency of Competitive Stock Markets Where Traders Have Diverse
Information, The Journal of Finance, Vol. 31, 2, May 1976.

Grossman, Sanford J., and Joseph E. Stiglitz, On the Impossibility of Informationally Efficient Markets,
American Economic Review, vol. 70, 3, June 1980, 393-408.

Jegadeesh, Narasimhan, and Sheridan Titman, Returns to Buying Winners and Selling Losers:
Implications for Market Efficiency, Journal of Finance, vol. 48, 1, March 1993, 65-92.

Kahneman, Daniel and Amos Tversky, Prospect Theory: An Analysis of Decision Under Risk,
Econometrica, 47, 1979, 263-291.

Keim, Donald B., Size Related Anomalies and Stock Return Seasonality: Further Empirical Evidence,
Journal of Financial Economics, vol. 12, 1983, 13-32.

Mauboussin, Michael J., Decision Making for Investors, Mauboussin on Strategy, Legg Mason Capital
Management, May 24, 2004.

Rappaport, Alfred, The Economics of Short-term Performance Obsession, Financial Analysts Journal,
May/June 2005.

Reinganum, Marc R., Misspecifications of Capital Asset Pricing: Empirical Anomalies Based on Earnings
Yields and Market Values, Journal of Financial Economics, vol. 9, 1981, 19-46.

Reinganum, Marc R.,The Anomalous Stock Market Behavior of Small Firms in January: Empirical Tests for
Tax-Loss Selling Effect, Journal of Financial Economics, vol. 12, 1983, 89-104.

Samuelson, Paul, Proof that Properly Anticipated Prices Fluctuate Randomly, Industrial Management
Review, Vol. 6, 1965, 41-49.

Sullivan, Ryan, Allan Timmerman, and Halbert White, Data-Snooping, Technical Trading Rule
Performance, and the Bootstrap, UCSD Working Paper, December 8, 1997.

Treynor, Jack L., Long-Term Investing, Financial Analysts Journal, May/June 1976, 56-59.

Tversky, Amos, and Daniel Kahneman, Belief in the Law of Small Numbers, Psychological Bulletin, 76,
1971, 105-110.

Watts, Duncan J., A simple model of global cascades on random networks, Proceedings of the National
Academy of the Sciences, April 30, 2002.

Das könnte Ihnen auch gefallen