Sie sind auf Seite 1von 106

ECONOMIC REPORT

ECONOMIC REPORT

BURMA
BURMA
March - 2008

March - 2008
ECONOMIC REPORT

BURMA

March - 2008
Published by

Copyright © National Council of Union of Burma

March 2008

Contact information:
MAUNG
MR. MAUNG
MAUNG MAUNG
(gensec@ncub.org)

MR. DAVID
DAVIDOSOLNICK
OSOLNICK
(dosolnick@gmail.com)

MR.AUNG
AUNG THIN
THIN
(rangsi24@yahoo.com)

MR. IAN
IANHOLLINGWORTH
HOLLINGWORTH
(ianh68h@yahoo.co.uk)
ffff KO THET
MR. KHUN KYAW
(kyawkothet@yahoo.com)

www.ncub.org
www.ftub.org

Printed in Thailand
Contents:

Summary - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -- - 1

Burma Facts and Figures - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -- - 3

I. Introduction - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - --- 7

II. Burma Country Profile 2007 ----------------- 11


Population ----------------- 11
Workforce Distribution by Sector ----------------- 13
Informal Sector Employment ----------------- 15
Unemployment ----------------- 17
Labor Force Breakdown ----------------- 18

III. Present Status of the Economy ----------------- 23


Caveat ----------------- 23
Economic Growth ----------------- 23
Per Capita GDP ----------------- 28
Purchasing Power Parity ----------------- 31
Inflation ----------------- 32
Standard of Living in Burma ----------------- 34
( Existing situation of wages and consumer spending )
Migrants Contribute National Income ----------------- 37
Exchange Rate ----------------- 39
External Sector ----------------- 41

IV. Structural Reforms ----------------- 49

V. Development Divide ----------------- 57


Development Gap at the National Level ----------------- 57
Development Gap at the Regional Level ----------------- 60

VI. Future Prospects ----------------- 67

VII. Economic Sanctions ----------------- 71


Setting the Stage ----------------- 71
Arguments Against Sanctions ----------------- 72
Burma is Unique ----------------- 72
Economic Engagement, Where the Money Goes ----------------- 73
Pinpointing the Deception ----------------- 74
Impact beyond Sanctioned Burma ----------------- 76

VIII. Conclusion ----------------- 83

Annex: Saffron Revolution (a) Golden Revolution ----------------- 89


(Economic Protests in 2007 for Poverty Alleviation)
: ASEAN Statistics ----------------- 93

References: ----------------- 95

List of Abbreviations: ----------------- 97

Co - ordination : Maung Maung, David Osolnick, Aung Thin, Ian Hollingworth


Cover and design lay out : Khun Kyaw Ko Thet
Summary:

Critical reporting of the existing status of Burma’s economy as the cause for poor
development is quite important for pro democratic movement. Burma is heavily
dependent on agriculture, which constitutes about half of the economy. Industry accounts
for roughly 15% with services and trade making up the rest. Reasons for what has been a
colossally failed effort to industrialize will be expanded upon later in one of our policy
papers: “The Failure of MNCs - FDI and the State Level Corruption in Burma”.
(Expected publication date late December 2008). Suffice it to say, that the principal/agent
problem is a large contributor to the economic maladies in Burma, as government
officials can become personally wealthy by making policy decisions that are bad for the
country.

An objective assessment of account performance and trends is naturally made difficult by


fundamental weakness in data. The cushion provided by gas exports makes now an
opportune time to establish new capital of Kyat Pyay - Nay Pyi Taw, located in central
Burma (The dictators are treating it as a Royal City and have included a Zoological
Garden which will be housed in a 200 – acre facility). Deforesting has been seen
everywhere. The junta also spends heavily on other mega projects like the development
of the new capital. Agriculture still suffers from poor technology, and manufacturing is
constrained by shortages of capital, lack of access to imported products and a lack of
competitiveness with regard to imports from Thailand and China, according to the EIU.

The high growth rates of over 7% per year achieved during the Fourth – Year Plan period
(1992/93 to 1995/96) were accepted by most observers as there were plausible reasons
behind the achievement. Indeed, no one doubted that Burmese economy was doing well.

Economic forecasts of the Government’s 5 – year plan for 2006-2010 calls for average
GDP growth rates of 10%, to be achieved through higher agricultural production, new
gas fields, and increases in hydropower generation. The economy would be fortunate to
achieve even half that over the medium term. In addition to the trade and investment
sanctions by the United States and some others, the investment climate, outside the
energy sector, remains poor for policy and infrastructure reasons.

Critical analysis of the status of Burma’s economy lies in composing GDP and its growth
in the context of ASEAN development divide (restated from Myat Thein, 2004) and the
comparison of GDP among member states. There are no reliable estimates of Burma’s
per capita GDP in US $. The progress of ASEAN Economic Community (AEC) and the
status of Burma indicate the development gap between rich and poor neighboring
countries. The greatest challenge for ASEAN is to narrow the development divide and
ensure that Burma, Cambodia, Laos and Vietnam can catch up to the six more developed
ASEAN states.

1
Thailand's estimated 1.8 million migrant workers earned $2 billion in wages last year but
may have contributed $11 billion, or 6.2 % to the gross domestic product, the ILO
(International Labor Organization) has revealed. According to the ILO report - Thailand
Economic Contribution of Migrant Workers - the kingdom is getting a better deal off its
migrant workers than it is giving them. "If migrants are as productive as Thai workers in
each sector, their total contribution to output should be in the order of $ 11 billion or
about 6.2 % of Thailand's GDP," said Manola Abella, the ILO's chief technical advisor in
Thailand, summing up the report's findings. The total number of migrants in Thailand
rose from about 700,000 in 1995 to 1.8 million in 2006, according to the report. Last year
about 75% of the migrant laborers came from neighboring Burma, who now represents 5
% of Thailand's total labor force of 36 million. On the other side, it is assumed that – The
Military Government of Burma allows its people some consumption space outside the
control of the government. And it allows Burmese people a degree of freedom from the
state – stated by Prof Sean Turnell, Macquarie University, Australia. Migrant laborers
are limited to certain sectors such as agriculture, fisheries, construction and as domestics.
Nearly half of Thailand's domestics are now believed to be migrants, said the ILO report.
It found that migrants, on average, earn about half the minimum wage and are not eligible
for state services such as medical care and education for their children.

Burma’s inflation rate will be 30 to 40 % in the next two years, a decrease from the 50%
rate of inflation at the end of 2007, after the junta increased fuel prices in mid-August,
said the EIU. The Burmese currency exchange rate against the US $ will be 1,400 kyat in
2008, said the EIU, and the US $ will be 1,500 Kyat in 2009. (The EIU is one of the most
influential sources of regional analyses among policymakers and intellectuals). The
national currency has depreciated and the gap between the official rate and market rate
determined parallel exchange rate has come to be wider and wider. The dual exchange
rate system in Burma will be analyzed in more detail in our forthcoming policy paper:
"The Dual Exchange Rate System and State Level Corruption in Burma". (Expected
publication date late December 2008).

The fact that the study identifies bad governance on poor monetary policy (which is an
appendage of governance among ASEAN countries) as the cause of poor infrastructural
development in Burma is quite important. .Chronically high inflation in military dictator
ruled Burma has soared to 35% a year, the highest in Asia, while its economy is slowing
because of the poor investment climate and business confidence, as already reported by
the IMF. The UN also described that most Burmese as struggling to survive, and that
worsening hardship and rising prices were at the root of many protests like GOLDEN
REVOLUTION in 2007 (see Annex one). A detail analysis of Inflation in Burma will be
presented in our policy paper: “Inflation and State Level Corruption in Burma”.
(Expected publication date late December 2008).

2
Burma Facts & Figures
Age distribution (as % of total population) GDP (PPP)

♦ 21.26 Billions of US D (2006) (3.00 %)


♦ 21.19 Billions of USD (2007) (2.40 %)
GDP
GDP per head (US $ at PPP) 11.95 Billons of US $
[ Current Market Price 2006 ]
♦ $ 439 (2006) 3.9% GDP per head
♦ $ 434 (2007) 3.3% $ 208.6 (US $ at Market Price 2006)
$ 2060.1 ( at PPP 2006 )
5.3%
65 years and over ♦ $ 428 (2008) 3.4%
FDI Inflow
235.9 US $ Millions ( 2005 )
Source : EIU 2007 143.0 US $ Millions ( 2006 )
15 - 64 years 68.6 %
Source : ASEAN Trade Database 2007
26.1% 0 - 14 years
Demography ( 2007)
Population ( million ) 47.3 ( CIA ),55.4 ( GOM ) 56.5 ( ADB ) 57.28 ( ASEAN )
Population Growth (%) 0.815 % ( CIA ) 2.0% ( ADB ) 2.3 % ( ASEAN)
Urban Population 30.6%
Males = 23.45 (CIA)
Females = 23.90 (CIA)
Crude Birth Rate (per 1,000 person) 20
Crude Death Rate (per 1,000 person) 10
Infant Mortality Rate (per 1,000 live births) 76.0
Life expectancy = 64 (female) 58 (male)
Adult Literacy = 84.7 % (officially)

Religious affiliation
Buddhists (85.0 % ), Animists (5.0 %)
Christians (4.5 %), Muslims (4.0 %)
Hindus (1.0 %) Others (0.5 %)
Source: ADB, CIA World Factbook, CSO, UNICEF, WHO , ASEAN Trade Database 2007

East Asia economic growth (%)


2005 2006 2007 2008
-------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
Emerging East Asia 7.7 8.3 8.4 8 .2

Developing East Asia 9.2 9.8 0.1 9.7

Southeast Asia 5.1 5.4 5.7 5.8

Indonesia 5.7 5.5 6.3 6.4


Labor Force Breakdown (Burma)
Malaysia 5.0 5.9 5.7 5.9
Unemployment
Philippines 4.9 5.4 6.7 6.2
Agriculture 25% 10%
Thailand 4.5 5.0 4.3 4.6
Industry 2% Transition economies
Services 8%
China 10.4 11.1 11.3 10.8

India 9.4 8.5 8.7


55% Informal Sector
Vietnam 8.4 8.2 8.3 8.2

Korea 4.2 5.0 4.8 5.1

Japan 1.9 2.2 2.0 1.8

Source: ADB, 2007 Source: World Bank: East Asia Region, October 2007, Dow Jones Newswires

3
Introduction
I. Introduction:
Burma, formerly envied by its neighbors in Asia, has seen its economic status fall
immeasurably in recent history. In fact, one need only look as far back as 1948 to find a
vibrant Burmese economy, with strong prospects for the future. Boasting a stable
agricultural base, abundant natural resources, and an enduring export sector, Burma was
truly poised to emerge as a premier Asian economy. As the top exporter of rice in the
world, Burma had a means of ensuring its long term economic development through
cultivating an agricultural product which was demanded the world over.

While Burma’s initial post-colonialist trajectory looked promising, the years since 1948
have delivered increasing misery to the majority of its citizens. Inept yet forceful
authoritarian leadership has been the genesis of consistent policy missteps and egregious
human rights abuses. Since the public uprisings of 1988, the government has changed
twice – in name only – to assuage public outrage, but has been consistently worsening in
terms of policy choice and human rights violations.

In recent years, Burma has changed course from a staunchly isolationist, economically
autarkist state to a more market-oriented system. Economies making the progression
away from isolation and central direction, to the more market-driven approach are
referred to as transitional economies or economies in transition. The rationale and
inspiration for economic reform movements is proved not only by the failure of formerly
centrally-planned economies (CPEs) to generate growth and sustain development, but
also by the success of market-oriented East Asian countries – the newly industrializing
economies (NIEs) of Hong Kong, South Korea, Singapore and Taiwan – as well as the
next-tier miracles of East and Southeast Asia – Indonesia, Malaysia and Thailand.

The reform process started in Burma (renamed Myanmar by the present sham
government, the State Peace and Development Council or SPDC on June 20, 1989) and
1
Vietnam in the late 1980s, and a little later in Cambodia and Laos. While undertaking
economic reforms, first Vietnam became a member of the Association of Southeast Asian
2
Nations (ASEAN) in 1995. Then, Burma followed suit in 1997 . Then Burma became a
member of the ASEAN. According to a number of Burmese scholars and observers, the
reasons behind Burma’s decision to enter ASEAN were both political and economic.
Politically, Burma joined ASEAN as a way out from its isolation and marginalization by
the Western bloc and EU. Economically, Burma hoped to gain from the benefits of
economic cooperation with ASEAN members countries. Cambodia was the last of the so
called CLMV countries (Cambodia, Laos, Myanmar, and Vietnam) to become a member
of ASEAN in 1999 to complete ASEAN 10. Ever since then, ASEAN has come to be

1
For more details of the rationale behind the economic reforms in Burma see Myat Thein and Mya Than,
“Transitional Economy of Myanmar: Performance, Issues, and Problems”, 1995.
2
According to a number of Burma’s scholars and observers, the reasons behind Burma’s decision to join
ASEAN were both political and economic. Politically, Burma joined ASEAN as a way out from its
isolation and marginalization by the Western bloc and the EU. Economically, Burma hoped to gain from
the benefits of economic cooperation with ASEAN member countries.

7
viewed as consisting of two tiers: the more developed ASEAN -6, that is, the founding
member nations (Indonesia, Malaysia, the Philippines, Singapore and Thailand) plus
Brunei; and the less developed CLMV countries.

While economic reforms in Burma sound promising, the junta’s predilections for forced
labor and unprincipled monetary decisions have mired the Burmese population in an
abysmal socio-economic situation. Grinding poverty – exacerbated by runaway inflation
rates – has marred the hopes of homespun growth. Many are forced by a depressing lack
of options to send a member of their family abroad, as a migrant worker, to send wages
back home. Without migrant wages sent home, many could not survive at all in Burma.

Today, the ruling SPDC utilizes a simplistic and devastating export system for gaining
revenue, with which to keep its military in power, and its populace cowed. Be it natural
gas or precious gems (begotten with the toil of forced laborers), or illegal drugs
channeled through surrounding countries into international markets, the SPDC finds
ample money from export revenues to continue its national reign of tyranny and
oppression.

Though Burma is moving toward a market-oriented system, the SPDC’s practices are still
largely clandestine, exploitive of its own citizenry (for the sole benefit of the military
leaders), and functioning poorly. Burma currently finds that “rice production,
traditionally a big export-earner, is now barely keeping pace with population growth.”3
While the move to a market economy may hold certain solutions to current problems,
there is ample evidence that changes must also occur in other areas of Burma, namely,
removal of its illegitimate leadership.

The intent of this report is to provide an accurate and fair detailing of the very sparse
available data regarding the Burmese economy, with the ultimate goal of imposing
transparency upon the murky dealings of a very secretive government. Through
extrapolating the origin of the SPDC’s revenue, this report hopes to conclude not only
that the SPDC is bolstering the wealth of its leaders ahead of the interests of its own
citizens through its economic policies, but reveal also the countries and companies which
are complicit partners.

3
“Burma in general disarray; Reform falls victim to military junta's off-the -cuff policy decisions” South
China Morning Post (Hong Kong), June 28, 1999.

8
Burma Country Profile
II. Burma Country Profile 2007:
Population-

Estimates of Burma’s population for 2006 were at 56.5 million people, according to the
ADB (Asian Development Bank), with 30.6% of the population living in urban areas, as
of 2005. Graph 1 illustrates the recorded growth from 1990 until 2006, which has held
steady at around 2% according to the ADB which receives most of its data from its
member countries.

Graph 1 Burma Population

60.00

50.00

40.00
Population in Millions

Population

30.00
Urban Population as a
% of Total Population
20.00

10.00

0.00
90 95 00 02 03 04 05 06
19 19 20 20 20 20 20 20

Year

Source: Asian Development Bank: Key Indicators/Myanmar 2007

Other sources which derive their data independently of the government of Burma, such as
CIA Factbook, maintain that the 2006 population of Burma is around 47 million, or 17%
less than the ADB estimate. CIA Factbook explains the reason for the lower figure as
“estimates for this country take into account the effects of excess mortality due to AIDS;
this can result in lower life expectancy, higher infant mortality and death rates, lower

11
population growth rates, and changes in the distribution of population by age and sex
1
than would otherwise be expected.”

The population of Burma is also broken down by age group in Graph 2 and further
broken down by age group and gender in Graph 3. Utilizing these two graphs it is
expressed that the population aged: 0-14 years old represents 26.1% of the total
population with 6.28 million males and 6.08 females; 15-64 years old represents 68.6%
of the total population with 16.09 million males and 16.42 million females; and 65+ years
old representing 5.3% of the population with 1.08 million males and 1.4 million females.

Graph 2 Burma Population Breakdown

70.00

60.00
% of Population

50.00

40.00

30.00

20.00

10.00

0.00
0 - 14 15 - 64 65 +

Age Groups

Source: Asian Development Bank: Key Indicators/Myanmar 2007

1
ADB, 2007

12
Graph 3 Population in Thousands

18000.000
16000.000
Population in Thousands

14000.000
12000.000
10000.000
Male
8000.000
Female
6000.000
4000.000
2000.000
0.000
0 - 14 15 - 64 65 +

Age Groups

Source: Asian Development Bank: Key Indicators/Myanmar 2007

Workforce Distribution by Sector-

Looking at the distribution of a nation’s workforce by sector can be helpful, as it provides


a snapshot of where the productive members of an economy find themselves. Graph 4
shows a workforce allocation in Burma that has been largely unchanged, as the SPDC’s
attempts at industrialization have been largely a failure.

One study rightly identifies a lack of infrastructural investment as a key contributor to


Burma’s acute inability to spur industrial development.
All over the world, firms with access to modern telecommunications services,
reliable electricity supply, and efficient transport links stand out from firms without
them. As regards the infrastructure, private firms in Burma lack almost everything,
compared even to poor countries such as Cambodia and the Lao PDR. Private firms in Burma
themselves recognize the bad influence of poor infrastructure on economic activity within the
country. The survey indicated that the need to improve an inadequate infrastructure is one of the
most important items on the agendas of Burma's businessmen.2

2
Kudo, Toshikiro. Discussion Paper 38: “Stunted and Distorted Industrialization in Myanmar.” Institute of Developing
Economies. October, 2005.

13
Graph 4 ASEAN Countries' Workforce % by Sector 2007

0.80
0.70
0.60
% of Workforce

0.50
Agriculture
0.40
0.30 Industry
0.20 Services
0.10
0.00
ia
a

m
ia

s
sia

e
l

d
os
ne

ine
m

or

an
d

ys

na
La
ne
bo
u

ap
ala
Bu

ail
ili p

et
Br

do
m

ng

Th

Vl
Ph
M
Ca

In

Si

Source: ADB, ASEAN Statistics 2007

It is interesting to note that the study particularly highlights Cambodia and Laos as being
comparatively ahead of Burma in terms of infrastructural development which caters to,
and thus attracts private industry. Referring back to Graph 4, the 2007 workforce
distributions reveal both Cambodia and Laos as having a greater percentage of their
workforce devoted to the agricultural sector, than does Burma. It will be interesting to
follow the changes in workforce distribution within the three CLMV countries
(Cambodia, Laos, Myanmar/Burma and Vietnam) with regard to how quickly Burma is
overtaken in terms of percentage of workforce working in industry.

While it is always preferable to see a country succeed in its goals, rather than make
consistent policy errors, the projection that Burma will be outdone by its CLMV
counterparts is likely. Infrastructural investment is a long-term endeavor, which won’t
pay immediate dividends. So it becomes particularly ominous when the Institute of
Developing Economies study reveals that “little if any progress has been made in
improving the infrastructure during the last 15 years. There must be serious faults in
either policy or governance for infrastructure development to be so poor in Burma.”3

3
Kudo, Toshikiro. Discussion Paper 38: “Stunted and Distorted Industrialization in Myanmar.” Institute of Developing
Economies. October, 2005.

14
The fact that the study identifies governance or policy (which is an appendage of
governance) as the cause for poor infrastructural development in Burma is quite
important. Reasons for what has been a colossally failed effort to industrialize will be
expanded upon later in the policy paper of “Failure of MNCs and the State Level
Corruption in Burma” which is going to be issued on late December 2008. Suffice it to
say, that the principal/agent problem is a large contributor to the economic maladies in
Burma, as government officials can become personally wealthy by making policy
decisions that are bad for the country.

Informal Sector Employment-

Consistent with the lack of internal transparency is the lack of robust, available data on
the informal sector employment in Burma. Despite the internal inconsistencies, there
have been attempts to estimate and record the status of the informal sector in Burma, by
outside organizations. The ILO (International Labor Organization) had conducted a
survey of the informal sector of economies throughout Asia, in a working paper. In the
paper, the informal sector was defined for each country, according to its own definition,
including the following definition for Burma:

A person is said to be employed in the formal sector when he or she is working in public
service or in an enterprise which is formally constituted. An individual is said to be
employed in informal sector when he or she is giving services or labor which is not
formally instituted with formalities.4

The definition laid out above retains a degree of ambiguity which is consistent with
SPDC declarations. It would serve the purposes of identifying the informal sector to
know explicitly what is meant by “formally instituted with formalities.” The grey-area is
quite pronounced in such a classification, as formal sector employees in Burma face
many of the same hardships as do employees in informal sectors (e.g. low wages,
dangerous work, few if any legal rights, etc.)

Despite the unfortunate similarities of the formal and informal sectors in Burma (relative
to other developing nations) the fact remains that informal sector analysis within Burma
can give a better picture of what conditions labor is facing. That is to say, even though
many workers in the formal sector face harsh conditions, it is still comparatively worse
for informal sector workers.

4
Shwe, U. H.: Country paper on Myanmar. Presented to an ILO/ARPLA/Turin Centre Regional Seminar on Labour
Administration for Urban Informal Sector. Yogyaharta, Indonesia, February 4-8 1991.

15
Graph 5 ILO Study: Informal Sector Employment by Gender

60.00
Employment as% 0f Total Employment

50.00
% of Informal Sector

40.00 Men and Women

Men
30.00
Women

20.00

10.00

0.00
5 96 8 4
ia 199 a r 19 e s 198 d 199
ne s nm in ila n
In d o Mya i pp Tha
Phil

Source: Amin, Nurul. “The Informal Sector in Asia from the Decent Work Perspective.” ILO 2002/04.

Graph 5 illustrates the results from one of the very few surveys of Burma’s informal
sector, which was conducted by the ILO. Though this graph does not provide much depth
in terms of a range of Southeast Asian nations with which to compare Burma, it does
include neighboring Thailand, which will help expand earlier comparisons made in this
paper. Burma’s informal sector is larger than Thailand’s as a percentage of total
employment, but what is perhaps more telling is the changing distribution of employment
by sectors for both.

Consider graph 6 which displays Burma and Thailand labor force distributions by gender
and sector, as a percentage of all economically active participants, from 1980-1998. Here
it is clear to see that Thailand’s economy is making a faster transition from an
agriculturally-based economy to a more diversified and industrialized economy. This is
no doubt due (in part) to trade liberalization coupled with appropriate infrastructural
investment. There is no guarantee that such measures will necessarily reduce the number
or percentage of jobs located in the informal sector, in fact poorly planned liberalization
of markets can accelerate the formal to informal trend.

16
Graph 6 % Burma / Thailand Labor Force by Gender and Sector

90

80

70
1980
60

50
1990
40

30 1998
20

10

0
en en en en en en en en en en en en
u r e M Wo m re M W om try M Wom try M Wo m es M Wom es M es M
lt ltu us us ic c c
cu ltu
re cu ltu
re
nd str
y
nd
y
s tr S erv ce
s rvi rvi
gri icu gri icu BI n du TI ndu er vi T Se T Se
A r A r I I B
B g T
TA
g B T BS
BA

Source: Amin, Nurul. “The Informal Sector in Asia from the Decent Work Perspective.” ILO 2002/04.

Unemployment-

Current unemployment in Burma is measured at around 10.4%, which translates to


approximately 2.96 million workers. Graph 7 reveals that among ASEAN members, only
Indonesia currently has a higher unemployment rate. On the other side, migrant issues
among neighboring countries are discussing several times as important things. ASEAN
also needed to solve a number of issues to avoid the “ASEAN Way” being a stumbling
block. It is needed to be more flexible on the concept of national sovereignty to get
people’s welfare. (Thailand’s estimated 1.8 million migrant workers earned $2 billion in wages last year but may
have contributed $11 billion, or 6.2%, to the gross domestic product, the International Labour Organization (ILO)
revealed. According to the ILO report - Thailand Economic Contribution of Migrant Workers - the kingdom is getting a
better deal off its migrant workers than it is giving them. "If migrants are as productive as Thai workers in each
sector, their total contribution to output should be in the order of 11 billion dollars or about 6.2 % of Thailand's
GDP," said Manola Abella, the ILO's chief technical advisor in Thailand, summing up the report's findings. The total
number of migrants in Thailand rose from about 700,000 in 1995 to 1.8 million in 2006, according to the report. Last
year about 75% of the migrant labourers came from neighbouring Burma, who now represents 5% of Thailand's total
labour force of 36 million. The remainder came from Laos and Cambodia, Thailand's neighbours to the north and east
[Bangkok Post, 18/12/2007]).

17
Graph 7 ASEAN Member Unemployment Rate 2007

14.00%
12.00%
Unemployment Rate

10.00%
8.00%
6.00%
4.00%
2.00%
0.00%

ia

m
ei

os

ore

nd
dia

s
sia
rm

ine
un

ys

na
La

ila
e

ap
o
Bu

la
Br

t
il
on
mb

Vie
a
Ph
Ma

Th
Ind

Sin
Ca

Source: ASEAN Statistics, 2007

Labor Force Breakdown-

Graph 8 combines information on Burma’s labor force as discussed in the sections above.
Aggregating all of the key dimensions of the Burmese labor force helps to better visualize
the nature of the economy being analyzed. For instance, the fact that over half of the
working population is concentrated in the informal sector (which provides highly
competitive jobs, and thus low wages, in the absence of a viable formal sector) is a
revealing statistic for why poverty is so rampant.

Graph 8 Burma Labor Force Breakdown

Agriculture 25%

Industry 2%

Services 8%

Unemployment 2006 10 %

Informal Sector 1996 55%

Source: ASEAN Statistics, 2007

18
Add the unemployed to the informal sector and you have 2/3 of the total Burmese labor
force. If you were to add to the unemployed and informal totals the agricultural sector,
which consists largely of subsistence farmers, you would now have 80% of the Burmese
labor force. That is to say that 80% of people in Burma’s labor force are either
unemployed, face wage rate far below a livable standard, or are subsistence farmers who
often are denied access to export markets, due to an irresponsible government strategy to
keep domestic food prices down, at the expense of impoverished farmers.

Industry and services round out the labor force and hold interesting implications in terms
of their value to the labor they support, versus their revenue value to the government. In
terms of employment, industry and services represents 10% of the labor force or about 3
million workers. With regard to wages, as will be revealed in subsequent areas of this
paper, many Burmese workers fail to earn enough money in industry or services to
support themselves, let alone a family. Due to the already minimal stake that workers
have in the viability of either sector, the upcoming section of this paper discussing
economic sanctions will elaborate on how most of the hardships will befall the profligate
SPDC, rather than worsen conditions for the already downtrodden workers.

19
Present Status of the Economy
III. Present Status of the Economy:
Caveat-

Though it has been stated to some degree in this report already, it is worth reiterating that
most of the data released by the SPDC is suspect at best, as they still function with the
tendencies of a centrally-controlled, dictatorial state. An ASEAN statistical workshop put
it succinctly stating, “Burma’s Statistical System is basically a decentralized one. In
Burma, every ministry has its own planning and statistical units. Those units are
compiling their own data independently to serve their own purpose.”1 Therefore, the
authors of this paper have made a concerted effort to collect data from a variety of
sources, to reveal more about the Burmese economy than members of the SPDC might
prefer.

Economic Growth -

One of the frequently cited indicators of economic performance is the rate at which an
economy grows as measured by the annual growth of Gross Domestic Product (GDP).
Since many economies have adopted open-market strategies, wherein maximizing growth
is regarded as the barometer for the strategy’s success, GDP can be viewed as a blunt
instrument at best. Since GDP is measured using an expenditure approach, all it really
reveals is how much an economy consumes, invests, purchases and its net exports. As a
figure it merely reflects the relative speed at which an economy is growing, yet it is really
devoid of any specific information.

While economic growth does not necessarily guarantee prosperity, or describe the nature
of who in an economy is benefiting from the growth, negative growth tends to reveal
more about a broken economy. The reasoning here is that macroeconomic policies tend to
reflect a largely agreed upon, pro-growth strategy. Thus, when an economy experiences
negative growth, there are opportunities to investigate what is malfunctioning.

1
Maung, U Zaw Win. “The Government of the Union of Myanmar.” ASEAN Statistical Classification Workshop
Hanoi, Vietnam. 10-14 June, 2002.

23
Graph 9 Burma's GDP Growth

12

10

8
Percentage

6
GDP
4

0
2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007
-2
Year
Source: UNESCAP, Economic and Social Survey of Asia and the Pacific, 2005
Source: Index Mundi: FTUB Compiled Data 2008

Graph 9 gives a linear depiction of Burma’s GDP growth rates from 2001 until the
present. The values of 11.3 % and 10 % for 2001 and 2002 respectively are likely inflated
values which overstate the performance of Burmese economy. Regardless of how close to
accurate the figures for those years are, the real amount of GDP was buoyed by
increasing natural gas sales, which does less for public welfare than would industrial
production.

For 2003-2005, the GDP growth rates of 0, -0.5, and -1.3 respectively, shows an accurate
economy-wide readjustment to the banking collapse in 2003, which tightened up credit
throughout Burma, stymied private sector growth. The IMF seems to concur with this
view when it noted that – the severe contraction in Bank loans is another indicator that is
at odds with the officially reported high GDP growth (IMF 2005). It is important to add
here that in Burma private sector contributes over 75 % of GDP. Also, 2003 saw an
increase in sanctions against garment exports from Burma, brought on by the United
States. The large successive upswing in GDP performance in 2006 was again, the product
of increased gas sales, particularly to Thailand.

Graph 10 compares the 2006-2007 GDP growth rates of all ASEAN members. Compared
to the rest of ASEAN, Burma is second to last in GDP growth rates, and its 2007 rate of
3% growth was actually Burma’s second best out of the 5 year (2003-2007) period. Note
also, the higher growth rates of the other CLMV countries, which can in part be attributed
to their more successful infrastructural development, as mentioned prior.

24
Graph 10 ASEAN Member GDP Real Growth Rates

12.00%

10.00%
Growth Rate

8.00%

6.00%

4.00%

2.00%

0.00%
ia

ia

d
es
a

m
re
s ia
ei

os

an
rm

od

es
un

tna
po
i li n
La

l ay

ail
Bu

mb

on
Br

ga

Vi e
Ph

Th
Ma
Ind
Ca

Si n
Source: FTUB Compiled Data 2008

Annual growth of GDP in recent years is shown side by side with the plan targets of the
Second Five-Year Short Term Plan (1996/97-2000/2001) and Third Five Year Short
Term Plan (2001/02) – (2005/06) in Table 1.It is worthy of notes, that up to 1997/98,
estimates of yearly GDP growth rates by international organizations such as ADB, IMF,
UNESCAP and EIU were the same as official estimates by the Government of Myanmar
2
(GOM) / Burma. Indeed, no one then doubted that Burmese economy was doing well.
The high growth rates of over 7% per year achieved during the Fourth – Year Plan period
(1992/93 to 1995/96) was accepted by most as there were plausible reasons behind the
achievement.

2
Perhaps it is pure coincidence, but from the time – around 1998 – the top leadership came to realize the importance of
GDP growth as an indictor of economic performance, Burma’s GDP growth rates have been in double digit figures
while China is playing an increasing role in the world economy with 10% to 11% growth rate ( the Economist,
September,29, 2007) and India with an average of 8.0% growth rate over the last three years (CIA Factbook) and 9.4%
in 2006-2007. India’s GDP is likely to grow 8.7% in 2008.

25
Table 1- Plan targets of GDP Growth and Performance %
Year GDP Growth GDP Growth GDP Growth
Targets Performance Performance
Official EIU/ESCAP
1996/1997 6.1 6.4 6.4
1997/1998 6.4 5.7 5.7
1998/1999 6.2 5.8 4.4
1999/2000 6.6 10.9 4.6
2000/2001 6.6 13.7 5.3(6.2)
2001/2002 11.3 10.5 5.3 (11.3)
2002/2003 12.5 10.0 -2.0 (10.0)
2003/2004 11.3 13.8 -2.7 (0.0)
2004/2005 11.3 12.6 2.9 (3.6)
2006 10.0 3.9
2007 10.0 3.3
2008 10.0 3.4
2009 10.0 3.6
Source- 1) Ministry of National Planning and Economic Development booth at Defence Services Museum;
2) Economist Intelligence Unit (EIU) Country report- Myanmar (Burma) 2005-06 -07; UNESCAP, Economic and
Social Survey of Asia and the Pacific. 3) Compiled data from Economic Department, FTUB /NCUB. Economic
Department compiled data from various libraries, news from website and for the other lists, look back references.
Notes – perhaps it is pure coincidence, but from the time – around 1998, the top leadership came to realize the
importance of GDP growth as an indicator of economic performance, Burma's GDP growth rates have been in double
digit figures. The Government’s 5 year plan for 2006- 2010 calls for average GDP growth rates of 10% to be achieved
through higher agricultural production, new gas fields, and increases in hydropower generation. (ADB Outlook 2007)

Graph 11 Plan targets of GDP Growth and Performance %


14

12

10

8
By GOM
6

4
EIU
2

-2

-4
2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009

Source: EIU Dec 2007, ESCAP 2006, CSO

26
Economic prospects of the Government’s 5 – year plan for 2006-2010 calls for average
GDP growth rates of 10%, to be achieved through higher agricultural production, new
gas fields, and increases in hydropower generation. The economy would be fortunate to
achieve even half that over the medium term. In addition to the trade and investment
sanctions by the US and some others, the investment climate, outside the energy sector,
remains poor for policy and infrastructure reasons. One of the few bright spots is the
expanding trade relationship with fast- growing neighbors the People’s Republic of China
and India. Growth and investment could also be constrained by inflationary expectations.

As a number of scholars had pointed out, the good performance was made possible by a
number of factors; such as private sector development (and especially the tremendous
increase in the production and exports of pulses and beans), strong growth in the
agricultural sector due chiefly to the introduction of double cropping of rice with pump
irrigation under summer paddy, a sizable inflow of FDI following the introduction of
Foreign Investment Law, growth of the nascent tourist industry, and a mini- construction
boom. In other words, the observed growth may be the legitimate result of viable,
growth-enabling engines.

According to official data in the third column of Table 1, Burma has been consistently
posting double – digit GDP growth rates since 1999/2000. Unlike in the past however, a
number of international organizations came to have doubts about these double –digit
GDP growth rates; and more importantly, ordinary Burmese citizens have little to show
for them by way of improvements in their standard of living. (There are no reliable
estimates of Burma’s per capita GDP in US $. However, according to household
expenditure surveys by Central Statistical Organization (CSO), an average household in
Rangoon was found to be spending a larger proportion of its total expenditure on rice
and food in 2001 (68.36%) than in 1986 (64.93%), which suggests a decline in
nutritional quality and standard of living in 2001 as compared to 1986. In general, as
incomes rises the share of food declines while there is a corresponding increase in the
share of other items such as consumer durables, recreation and so on. In comparison, the
share of household consumption on food in Singapore is 14%, in Thailand it is 32% and
in Malaysia 37%).

As noted in the review of Burmese economy by Asian Development Outlook:

An objective assessment of economic development in Burma is made difficult


by poor quality data. Often, information is available only with a long lag, is
complete, and is difficult to reconcile. Furthermore, many indicators are based
on application of outdated statistical standards. 3

The IMF echoes this view as it reports “the data quality, comprehensiveness, and
4
timelines are weak, making it difficult to assess economic developments.” This situation
naturally forces us to devote a considerable space to the consideration of Burma’s GDP
as it influences the structure of GDP, rates of saving and investment, relative amount of
exports and imports and so on.

3
Asian Development Outlook, 2003
4
IMF 2005, Pg 6

27
Note that since 1998/1999, estimates of GDP growth rates by UNESCAP are consistently
lower than the official estimates. Estimates of GDP growth rates by UNESCAP also
correlate better with the sector growth rates computed by the organization shown in
Graph 12. This is because for a developing country like Burma, it is not possible for the
agriculture sector to grow at 8% or more per year on a sustained basis as implied by
official GDP growth rates. In other words, 3 or 4 % growth rates for the agriculture sector
estimated by UNESCAP are much more realistic than the Burma official estimates.

Graph12 Burma GDP Growth Rates and Sector Growth Rates

35
30
25 Agriculture
Percentage

20 Industry
15
Services
10
5
GDP

0
-5
01

02

03

04
20

20

20

20

Year

Source – UNESCAP, Economic and Social Survey of Asia and the Pacific, 2005.

Per Capita GDP-

Perhaps another instance of the inaccuracy of GDP as a descriptive measure (shown by


one of its frequently used derivatives) can be found in the use of per capita GDP. While
the fundamental idea of dividing a nations net output by the number of its citizens does
produce a relatively more explanatory economic variable than does GDP alone, it is none
the less a vague proxy to economic health at best. Consider the subsequent series of
graphs for a better illustration of this point.

28
Graph 13 Per Capita GDP in Kyats

180000
160000
140000
120000
Burmese Kyats

100000

80000
60000
40000
20000
0
1990 1995 2000 2002 2003 2004

Year

Source: ADB http://www.adb.org/Documents/Books/Key_Indicators/2007/pdf/MYA.pdf

Visually, per capita GDP for Burma from 1990 to 2004 appears to express a favorable
trend for the citizens of Burma. Having their relative wealth multiplied nearly 49 times in
14 years would be quite a boon, if only it were true of all citizens. Unfortunately, due to
poor fiscal and economic policies enacted by the SPDC, many Burmese are
simultaneously facing rampant inflation, and stagnant wages.

Additionally, there has been a vast overstatement of the worth of the Burmese kyat, as
expressed by the official rate. Since 1993 the junta has drastically overvalued its currency
at 6.23 kyat to US$1, facilitating a black market rate that fluctuates from 1,250-1,350
kyat to US$1.5 Considering further that the CIA Factbook valued the kyat at 1,280 per
US$1 for the year 2006, the use of 1,300 kyat per US$1 as an average is consistent and a
fair proxy, given the inconsistent recording of the market value for the kyat.

5
Altsean Key Issues – Economy. http://www.altsean.org/Key%20Issues/KeyIssuesEconomy.htm

29
Graph 14 Per Capita GDP in US Dollars
30000

25000
Per Cap GDP in US $
20000
Official Rate
US $

15000 Per Cap GDP in US $


Market Exchange Rate
10000

5000

0
1990 1995 2000 2002 2003 2004

Year
Source: ADB http://www.adb.org/Documents/Books/Key_Indicators/2007/pdf/MYA.pdf

*Note: the use of 1,300 kyat as the average market-determined exchange rate was arrived at by information
provided by Altsean Key Indicators – Economy, and FTUB Compiled Data 2008.

Utilizing the above graph, we can compare the official exchange rate – touted by the
SPDC – to the market exchange rate which is more reflective of the true diminished value
of the kyat. The blue line denoting GDP per capita according to the official rate of
exchange in graph 13 resembles the upward progression of the kyat per capita from graph
12. The reason is that the official exchange rate has pegged the value of the Burmese
currency to a fixed value relative to dollars, which (though the dollar has also been
sliding in value) is a more stable currency. There are no reliable estimates of Burma’s per
capita GDP in US $.

The pink line, however, is a more accurate barometer for the per capita GDP. The market
exchange rate factors in the effects of the exorbitant inflation which has resulted from the
economic mismanagement of the SPDC, and the unlivable wages that have spurred the
mass exodus of migrant workers to bordering nations in search of unsafe, demeaning, yet
higher paying jobs. It is worth mentioning that the authors of this paper first intended the
above line graph to be expressed as a column graph, but the market exchange rate values
were comparatively so low that no columns could be distinguished!

According to the market-determined exchange rate, GDP per capita has improved from
$2.87 in 1990 to a paltry $128.61 in 2004. These figures are consistent with the assertion
that “an increase of between 15-20% in food prices would leave more than half the
population under the poverty line. Most people have an income estimated of less than
6
US$200, but the price of an average meal is about US$0.45.” (For more comparison
among ASEN countries with Burma see Annex: Two)

6
Altsean Key Issues – Economy. http://www.altsean.org/Key%20Issues/KeyIssuesEconomy.htm

30
Purchasing Power Parity-

For a more robust calibration of living standards in a country, a more revealing measure
is purchasing power parity or PPP. Purchasing power parity is “the idea that similar
foreign and domestic goods or baskets of goods should have the same price in terms of
the same currency.”7 Compared to the per capita GDP discussion above – where we
found that a certain number of kyat had a certain value in dollars per the rate of exchange
– PPP helps us to determine how much “stuff” a certain amount of kyat enables a citizen
in Burma to buy, as compared to someone in the United States (or anywhere) with an
equivalent value in dollars (or any agreed upon common currency).

Using PPP we are able to determine how much someone in Burma is able to buy, relative
to someone in any other country, once the two currencies have been converted into a
common currency for comparison. In the first issue of Burma Economic Watch for 2004
Wylie Bradford conducted a comparison of PPP for Burma, as compared to the US and
Thailand. While the study concludes in the year 2000 (due to a lack of data released by
the SPDC) it provides a cogent example of how the purchasing power for citizens of
Burma was greatly reduced between 1980 and 2000.

Graph 15 GDP Per Capita PPP


8000

6000 Burma
US $

4000
Thailand

2000

0
1980 1983 1985 1989 1992 1995 1998

Year

Source: Bradford, Wylie.“Purchasing Power Parity (PPP) Estimates for Burma.” Burma Economic Watch. 2004.

Graph 15 illustrates the essence of PPP analysis, as it compares Burmese kyat to Thai
baht, given their respective worth in a common currency (here international $1, which
Bradford explains has “the same purchasing power everywhere as $US1 has in the USA
8
in the year of comparison.” ) While exchange rates merely describe how much of one
currency can be obtained for a given amount of another, the PPP analysis depicted in
graph 15 shows how much actual buying power citizens in Burma have compared to
those in Thailand.

7
Abel, Andrew B. and Bernanke, Ben S. Macroeconomics, Fifth Edition. 2005.
8
Bradford, Wylie.“Purchasing Power Parity (PPP) Estimates for Burma.” Burma Economic Watch. 2004.

31
Burma’s purchasing power was consistently diminished relative to Thailand’s, despite the
fact that Thailand was not without its own economic hardships, including inflation and
the Asian financial crisis of 1997 (which affected more advanced economies like
Thailand decisively more than less advanced economies such as Burma, and thus in part
explains the modest marginal increase Burma made relative to Thailand from 1997 to
2000).

Since Thailand’s inflation over this time period was higher than that of the United States,
the comparison of Burma to the US would reveal even lower purchasing power for the
Burmese than in the Burma/Thailand graph above. Perhaps even bleaker is that since
2000 Burma has gone on to have numerous years of double-digit inflation, which has
only worsened the purchasing power for people in Burma.

Inflation -

According to official data, inflation in the 1990s average around 25 % per annum. The
highest rate of 58% was recorded in 2002/03 and the lowest rate of – 1.7 % in 2000/01.
Table 2 shows average annual rates of inflation in Burma and other CLMV (Cambodia,
Lao, Myanmar, Vietnam) countries along with average annual rates of GDP growth,
savings, investment and one of the indicators of financial development – M2/ GDP ratio.

Table 2 - Inflation and related variables in CLMV countries


…………………………………………………………………………………………

Inflation
GDP Growth Gross Domestic Investment to M2/ GDP
(Annual %) Saving GDP
…………………………………………………………………………………………
1991 1998 1991 1998 1991 1998 1991 1998 1991 1998
1997 2004 1997 2004 1997 2004 1997 2004 1997 2004
………………………………………………………………………………………
Cambodia 4.8 3.7 5.5 5.8 7.0 8.5 17.0 19.6 8.0 14.8

Lao PDR 13.8 41.3 6.6 5.8 10.8 15.2 n.a 22.8 12.9 18.4

Myanmar 25.9 25.4 5.9 10.1 12.5 10.0 13.3 13.3 29.6 27.4

Vietnam 4.5 3.5 8.3 6.6 15.8 28.1 23.7 31.6 21.2 45.5
………………………………………………………………………………………………
Source- International Financial Statistics (IMF) and World Development Indicators (WDI 2006)
Notes – the figures are annual average

As in most developing countries, the root cause of inflation in Burma is the budget
9
deficits. As one scholar has observed, the underlying factor behind inflation in Burma is

9
According to the World Bank there could even be inflation – deficit spiral. Excessive reliance on money creation is
particularly risky if inflation worsens the deficits, because expenditures keep pace with rising prices while revenues do

32
the fact that the demand for resources by the state by far exceeds the state ability to raise
taxation revenue, as a result of which the state finances its spending by the simple
expedient of printing money.

Moreover, it may be seen from Table 2 that Burma with the highest rate of inflation
amongst CLMV countries has the second lowest rate of savings, whereas Vietnam with
the lowest rate of inflation has the highest rate of savings. In general, expectation of high
rates of inflation encourages consumption but discourages savings and investment.
Macroeconomic instability arising from inflation could also prevent a sizable inflow of
foreign direct investments (FDIs) needed for development. Therefore, there could be a
connection between the variables that we are observing in Table 3.

Indeed, according to the results of regressions over the period 1976/77 – 1996/97, Myat
Thein found (among other things) the relationship between gross domestic savings (GDS)
and consumer price index (CPI) in Burma to be negative and significant.10 With regard to
CLMV countries, it is again revealed that Burma is the most erratic economy in the group
with regard to inflation rate, which in turn negatively affects investment. Yet again the
failure of the SPDC, to make appropriate policy decisions, is abundantly clear.

Continuing with the discussion of Burma’s rampant inflation, Graph 16 compares the
2007 inflation rates among members of ASEAN, with Burma yielding the highest rate.
Since the long-term goal for Burma is, and rightly should be, to become a strong
economic player in Southeast Asia, the economic policy needs to reflect that goal. The
frivolous printing of money to fill gaps in the economy will only further destabilize the
true market value of their currency, and mire the would-be consumers in a situation
where they cannot spend.

Much of the investment decision for FDI (in terms of manufacturing or production) is,
largely, some combination of wage/productivity. Yet, there are also steep considerations
given to a production operation’s ability to supply a robust home market that can provide
a perennial customer base. This is an important part of the consideration because picking
such locations tends to alleviate the need for export to world markets in times of
unfavorable, global macro conditions.

Insofar as the SPDC thinks it can continue to attract producers in search of cheap
operating costs by keeping workers rights and environmental standards outside of the
equation, ultimately, there will come a time when other countries who have fostered
homespun markets which will attract FDI projects, and represent more appealing
locations to send production. Thus, sustainable macro policies (including not foolishly
printing money and crippling consumer buying power) would be a vital first step to
curbing inflation, spurring meaningful growth, and encouraging outside investment.

not. This means still more money creation becomes necessary – future worsening the inflationary spiral. - WB 1988,
Pg 57).
10
Myat Thein, Improving Domestic Resource Mobilization in Myanmar, ISEAS Working Papers, Economics and
Finance No. 1(99), January 1999.

33
Graph 16 ASEAN Member Inflation % 2007
25.00%

20.00%
Inflation

15.00%

10.00%

5.00%

0.00%
ia

si a

nd
re

m
i

es
ia

os
a
ne

es
rm

tna
po
od

aila
i lin
La

lay
Bru

on
Bu

mb

ga

Vie
Ph
Ma

Th
In d

Sin
Ca

Source: International Financial Statistics ( IMF, 2007 ) and World Development Indicator ( WDI, 2007)

Standard of living in Burma


(Existing situation of wages and consumer spending)

It's also a fact that Burma is one of the world's lowest living standards. Formal sector
wages in Burma (similar to the informal sector) are insufficient, and by themselves, make
living in Burma impossible for many people. Table 3 lists the food and shelter costs
facing a family of four, living in the city of Rangoon. With no other cost considerations
(e.g. clothing, school fees, healthcare, etc), an average family of four faces a monthly
expense of 108,800 kyat, or $83.69 in US dollars. These prices reflect the most basic
level of subsistence one can attain in terms of diet (rice with minimal egg) and quality of
living residence.

34
Table 3 - Basic Living Expenses for Families in Rangoon

Amount ( Ks )
No Particular 2007 2008 2008
Dec Jan Feb
1 Rice (2kg) for 4 persons/ day
1000 1000 1000
Main Dish for two meals
2 (8 eggs for 4 people for a less expensive alternative to eating meat like pork
or others ) 960 1040 1040
3 Cooking oil and other in sundry necessities
1000 1000 1000

Cost for one day of food for a 4 person family


2960 3040 3040

4 Food for a month (family size is 4 persons) 30 days


88800 91200 91200
5 Room for rent in Rangoon for a month ( 1 bed room )
20000 25000 25000

Total Cost for food and Rent for a family of 4 in Rangoon


108800 116200 116200

*Note: The above cost calculations are only for Food and Shelter. It does not include the cost of clothes, school
fees for children, healthcare, or any other cost-of-living expenses.

Source: The Myanmar Times News Vol. 18, No. 350

While the partial living expenses listed above might not seem overwhelming, consider
that most working individuals could not afford to eat and maintain a residence by
themselves at those prices, which represent the lowest available means of subsistence.
Graph 17 illustrates the monthly incomes of three different private sector wage earning
professions, which are representative of most wage earners in Burma.

In the private sector, none of the three professionals (carpenter, carpenter foreman, or
vegetable seller) earn enough money to support a family of four on the very basic rice
and egg diet, plus maintain a livable residence. In fact the highest paid out of the three
groups, the carpenter foreman, earns only 55% of what it would require just to feed
his/her family and have a room to live in.

35
Graph 17 Private Monthly Wages in Burma

70000
Burmese Kyats

60000
50000
40000
30000 Kyats / Month
20000
10000
0
Carpenter Carpenter Foreman Vegetable Seller

Sample Occupations

Source: Migrant Dept of FTUB 2008

Graph 18 displays the wages of government workers in Burma, at various levels.


Recalling that it requires 108,800 kyat to support a family of four for one month in
Rangoon, only a Director for the government is able to successfully clear the most basic
living costs, for a family of four. The reason for such stifling living expenses is that
wages do not adjust quickly enough in response to inflation.

Graph 18 Private Monthly Wages in Burma

160000
140000
Burmese Kyats

120000
100000
Kyats / Month
80000
60000
40000
20000
0
y k k r r
Bo C ler C l er trato ecto
d nis r
ran nio
r
n io
r Di
Er Ju Se d mi
A
ffice
O
Sample Occupations
Source: Migrant Dept of FTUB 2008

36
Migrants contribute national income for both original and host countries:

To cope with exorbitant living expenses, many families in Burma are forced to send one
or more member abroad to neighboring countries, as migrant workers. Estimates done in
2003 approximated the number of migrant workers in Thailand at around two million,
with the majority having come from Burma. Thailand’s Tak province alone had recorded
200,000 migrant workers from Burma. Since the SPDC has continued its streak of bad
policy, macroeconomic instability, forced labor violations, the number of migrant
workers leaving Burma has continued to rise.

Among the biggest contributory reasons for the dramatic outpouring of migrant workers
from Burma to Thailand is wages. Table 4 lists the average daily wages being paid to
migrant workers from Burma in the Thai provinces. The wage rates, still below the Thai
minimum wage (sometimes by as much as half), is still dramatically more than what
could be earned in Burma.

"If migrants are as productive as Thai workers in each sector, their total contribution to
output should be in the order of $ 11 billion or about 6.2 % of Thailand's GDP," said
Manola Abella, the ILO's chief technical advisor in Thailand, summing up the report's
findings. The total number of migrants in Thailand rose from about 700,000 in 1995 to
1.8 million in 2006, according to the report. Last year about 75% of the migrant laborers
came from neighboring Burma, who now represents 5 % of Thailand's total labor force of
36 million.

Thailand has been registering migrant workers since 1992, but many stay unregistered to
avoid the relatively expensive and time-consuming process. In 1995, some 45 % of the
estimated 700,000 migrants were registered, while only 26 % of the 1.8 million were
registered last year. Migrant laborers are limited to certain sectors such as agriculture,
fisheries, construction and as domestics. Nearly half of Thailand's domestics are now
believed to migrants, said the ILO report. It found that migrants, on average, earn about
half the minimum wage and are not eligible for state services such as medical care and
education for their children. "What worries the ILO is that migrants are not receiving
equal treatment," stated Manola Abella.

The ILO called on the Thai government to abide by fundamental principles is dealing
with their migrant labor and to make procedures flexible. "If the government were to
acknowledge that the Thai economy is likely to continue to employ migrants over the
medium term, create mechanisms to involve social partners in development of a
transparent migrant policy, and promote cooperation with migrant countries of origin,
Thailand could reap the benefits of migration while protecting the rights of migrants in
Thailand," concluded the report. { For another one instance regarding one ASEAN
member country : millions of Filipinos working overseas sent home US $1.4 billion in
December 2007—the most in a single month—pushing total remittances in 2007 to a
record US $14.45 billion. The funds accounted for 10% of annual gross domestic
product, said Amando Tetangco, the central bank governor. He said the 2007 amount
was 13 % higher from the previous year because of "continued demand abroad for

37
Filipino workers and enhanced remittance service provided by banks and nonbank
remittance agents." About 8 million of the Philippines' populations of 90 million work
abroad, sending money that provides a backbone of the economy. (AP)}

Minimum Wage Rates increased for 2008 in Thailand - Mr. Apai Junlaka, the Labor
Minister, disclosed on October 15, 2007 that the Ministerial Regulation of Minimum
Wage Rate (No. 8) dated on November 12, 2007 proposed by the Ministry of Labor was
acknowledged and approved by the Cabinet. The Regulation will come into force on
January 1, 2008. The enforcement of the new minimum wage rate will be made in
January 1, 2008. The wage-rates detailed as follows;

Table 4 – Migrant Workers’ Daily Wages in Thai Provinces


Minimum Wage Areas
Rate (Baht)
194 Bangkok Metropolis, Nonthaburi, Pathum Thani, Nakhon Pathom, Samut Sakhon
and Samut Prakarn
193 Phuket
175 Chonburi
170 Saraburi
165 Nakhon Ratchasima, Chachoengsao, Nakhon Si Ayutthaya and Rayong
163 Ranong
162 Pangnga
160 Krabi, and Phet Buri
159 Chiang Mai
158 Chanthaburi, and Lopburi
157 Karnchanaburi
156 Ratchaburi and Sing Buri
155 Prachinburi, Samutsongkram and Sra Keow
154 Trang, Loei, and Ang Thong
152 Prachuab Khiri Khan,,Lamphun and Songkha
150 Khon Kaen ,Chumphon, Trad, Nakhon Nayok, Nakhon Si Thammarat, Nakhon
Sawan, Burirum, Phattalung, Phetchabun, Satun Surat Thani, Nong Khai, Udon
Thani, and Uthai Thani
149 Kamphaeng Phet, Chai Nath, Lampang, Sukhothai, and Supan Buri
148 Kalasin, Nakhon Panom, Narathivas, Pattani, Phitsanuloke, Mukdaharn, Yala,
Sakon Nakhon, and Nong Bua Lumpoo,
147 Tak, Mahasarakram, Mae Hong Son, Yasothon, Roi Et, Surin and Utaradit
146 Chaiyaphum, Chiang Rai, Pichit , Prae,and Si Sa Ket
145 Ubon Ratchathani, and Amnaj Charoen
144 Nan and Payao,

Source: Migrant Dept of FTUB 2008

Table 5 lists the earlier private and a government sector job depicted in graphs 17/18 and
converts their wages into an equivalent amount of Thai baht. Comparing the daily Thai
baht column in Table 5 from the workers in Burma to those in Table 4 for migrant
workers in Thailand, and the need to migrate becomes quite clear. Out of the sample of
jobs in Burma, only the Director level government official earns enough money to
support (modestly) a family living in Burma. However, not even the relatively lofty
wages of the government Director can match any of the average daily salaries paid to
migrant workers in any Thai province.

38
Table 5 – Private and Public Sector Wages in Burma
Thai
Kyats/Month Thai Baht/Month Baht/Day
Errand Boy 15,000 400.00 13.33
Junior Clerk 23,000 613.33 20.44
Vegetable Seller 24,000 799.87 26.66
Senior Clerk 27,000 720.00 24.00
Carpenter 30,000 919.77 30.66
Carpenter Foreman 60,000 1999.00 66.63
Office Administrator 80,000 2,133.00 71.10
Director 160,000 4,266.66 142.22
Source: Migrant Dept of FTUB 2008

The fact that many people in Burma cannot even feed their families, let alone consider
sending children to school or saving money for unexpected needs, truly explains the mass
migration of workers into surrounding countries. “Burma is now the largest source of
refugees in East Asia.”11 The need for labor to migrate is very revealing, not just of
Burma’s economic illnesses, but of the SPDC’s genuine lack of concern for its own
citizens.

Despite a clear need for changes in direction, the illegitimate government has allowed
Burma’s macroeconomic situation to get progressively worse. Failure to act responsibly
in spite of its many opportunities reveals the corrupt nature of the individuals ruling over
the people of Burma. The ways in which the SPDC has utilized economic policy to make
its generals and their family members rich at the expense of greater social welfare will be
explored in subsequent sections of this paper.

Exchange Rate-

Burma practices a dual or multiple exchange rate system with the use of strict foreign
exchange controls.12 The exercise of foreign exchange controls is to this day based on
the foreign Exchange Regulation Act 1947. The official exchange rate of the kyat has
been pegged to the IMF special drawing rights (SDR) at a fixed rate of kyat 8.50847 or at
approximately kyat 6 per US $ since 1977. Since 2001, the official exchange rate has
varied between 5.57 and 6.70 kyats per US$ (8.20 to 7.00 kyats per Euro€). However, the
street rate ( black market rate), which more accurately takes into account the standing of
the national economy, has varied from 800 kyats to 1350 kyats per US $ ( 985 to 1475
kyats per Euro€). External trade by the private sector is conducted at the much weaker
market-valued exchange rate, which is hurt by inflation. (Table 6)

11
Boot, William. “China’s Burma Trade Soars with ‘Cooperative Ties.’” Irrawaddy: Weekly Business Roundup.
December 2007.
12
Currently, Burma is conducting 6 categories of exchange rate systems.
(1) Foreign exchange coupon (FEC) rate of approximately $1= US 1 $.
(2) The official exchange rate of 1US$ = MK 6 , which is pegged to the IMF's " SDR"
(3) The market rate of approximately US1$ = MK 1300 (updated 2007-2008)
(4) The government rate of US1$ = MK 100 to 200 , used for assessing tariffs and taxes:
(5) The government money changer rate of 1$ = MK 250
(6) The illegal and variable “Hundi " rate, this is one method of illegal money changer exchange rates, used by trading
houses and, nobody is willing to hold or deal with FEC.

39
FEC (Foreign Exchange Certificate), equivalent to the US$ on a one to one basis, was
introduced in February 1993 as an instrument to legalize the market rate and initially in
order to promote tourism. The introduction of FEC in effect amounts to partial de facto
devaluation of the kyat. However, no changes or amendments were made to the Foreign
Exchange Regulation Act (FERA) of 1947.

Over the years, the kyat has depreciated and the gap between the official rate and the
market determined parallel exchange rate came to be wider. In addition, more and more
transactions came to be conducted at the market – determined parallel exchange rates in
what may be considered as the dollarization process. At present, the parallel exchange
rate of about kyats 1300 to one US $ is over 200 times the official rate; and the volume of
transactions in the economy with that rate is estimated to be about 80 - 90 % of the total
transactions (based on the share of private sector in GDP). The Burmese currency
exchange rate against the US dollar will be 1,400 kyat in 2008, said the EIU, and the US
dollar will be 1,500 Kyat in 2009.The EIU is one of the most influential sources of
regional analyses among policymakers and intellectuals. (Table 6)

Table 6 – Monthly data of Exchange rate in 2007 (kyat: US$)


Jan Feb Mar Apr May Jun Jul Aug Sep Oct Nov Dec
--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

2007 (official) 5.69 5.68 5.67 5.60 5.61 5.63 5.56 5.56 5.55 n/a n/a n/a

2007 (free market) 1,300 1,300 1,270 1,250 1,250 1,250 1,280 1,300 1,350 1,300 n/a n/a
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
Source: EIU December 2007

As expected by most economists, changes in Burma parallel exchange rates over time
(from kyats 42 per dollar in 1988 to the present rate of around kyats 1300 to a $) were
found to be determined largely by changes in relative price levels or the inflation
differential between Burma and its trading partners.

In other words, the percentage depreciation of the parallel exchange rate in Burma is
equal to the inflation rate differential between Burma and its trading countries. Then
again, changes in CPL, as noted earlier, were mainly caused by increases in money
supply, which in turn was caused by budgetary deficits.

In the past, on November 10, 1985, 75 kyat notes were introduced, the ODD
DENOMINATION ( it can be observed on the cover design of this book) possibly chosen
because of Dictator Ne Win’s predilection for numerology; the 75 kyat note was
supposedly introduced to commemorate his 75th birth day. It was also followed by the
introduction of 15 and 35 kyat notes on August 1, 1986. Only two years later, on
September 5, 1987, the military dictator demonetized the 25, 35 and 75 kyat notes
without warning or compensation, rendering some 75% of the country’s currency
worthless. The resulting economic disturbances led to serious riots (8-8-88 uprising) and
2nd military coup again. On September 22, 1987, banknotes for 45 and 90 kyat were
introduced, both of which incorporated Ne Win’s favorite number, NINE.

40
Following the change of the country’s name to Myanmar on June 20, 1989, new notes
began to be issued. This time, the old notes were not demonetized, but simply allowed to
fall into disuse through inflation as well as wear and tear. On March 27, 1994, 1 kyat
notes were issued followed by 200 kyat notes on March, 1990. On March 27, 1994, notes
for 50 pya, 20, 50, 1000 and 500 kyats were issued, followed, on May 1, 1995, by new 5
and 10 kyat notes. 1000 kyat notes were introduced in November 1998.

In 2003, rumors of another pending demonetization swept through the country, resulting
in the junta issuing official denials, but this time the demonetization did not materialize.
In 2004, the sizes of the 200, 500 and 1,000 kyats were reduced in size (to make all
Burmese national banknotes uniform in size likes American national currency notes) but
larger notes remain in circulation. 50 pya, 1, and 5 kyat banknotes are now rarely seen,
because of their low value. This is arbitrarily ruling of monetary system in Burma under
the military dictatorship controls. (For more in- depth study, it is going to analyze in our
policy papers, “The Dual Exchange Rate System & the State Level Corruption in
Burma).

External Sector-

Burma has had perennial deficits in the balance of trade and the current account for at
least the past decade. For example, during the First Short Term Four – Year Plan Period
(1992/93 – 1995/96), and the Second Short Term Five – Year Plan Period (1996/97 –
2000/2003), Burma has had surplus balance of trade (Table 7). This was largely due to
exports of Natural Gas to Thailand.

Table 7 – Balance of Payments Summary 2001/02 – 2005/06 (US $ million)


Year Exports Imports Balance of Current A/C
Trade Balance
2001/02 2544 2735 -191 -157
2002/03 3063 2300 763 12
2003/04 2357 2240 117 - 100
2004/05 2928 1973 955 251
2005/06 3558 1984 1574 489
Average annual 12.7 - 3.1
growth
Source – 1) Ministry of National Planning and Economic Development;
2) IMF (International Monetary Fund)

As may be seen from the table, yearly export earnings increase from US $ 2544 million
in 2001/02 to 3588 million in 2005/06 or by about US $ 1000 million in the course of 4
years. This increase in export earnings must largely be attributed to the discovery and
exports of natural gas. Imports on the other hand, decreased from US $ 2757 million in
2001/02 to US $ 1984 million in 2005/06. This is due partly to the government
quantitative restrictions on imports, and partly to the weakening of the kyat and domestic
demand. As a result, Burma came to have trade surplus from 2002/03 onwards. The trade
surplus in fact grew from US $ 763 million in 2002/03 to US $ 1574 in 2005/06.

41
Graph 19 displays the percentage breakdown of Burma’s imports for 2007. China’s
growing influence with the Burmese economy is clear as it represents over a third of all
Burma’s recorded imports. It is important to note that Burma’s imports are actually much
higher, due to unrecorded border trade of military armaments. Regardless, the recorded
statistics show that imports are primarily machinery and transport equipment, minerals,
base metals and manufactures, fabrics and electrical machinery.13 These imports reflect
the absence of consumer durables purchasing, which is consistent with the fact that most
consumers in Burma spend the majority of their income on food.

Graph 19 Origin of Imports Purchased by Burma 2007

Malaysia 5%

Other 22%

China 35%

Thailand 22%

Singapore 16%

Source: FTUB Compiled Data, 2008

Regarding Burma’s direction of trade, it remained as in the past, very much concentrated
with Asian countries. Of the total volume of trade of US $ 5542 million in 2005/06, as
much as US $ 4985 million or nearly 90 % of it was with ASEAN plus 3. However, only
US $ 2844 million or a little over 50 % of the total was with ASEAN.

The SPDC has been generating money from exports (including unrecorded illegal trade,
such as drugs) to pay for what are mostly military imports. The majority of the money
comes from sales of natural gas, an industry in which the SPDC has consistently used
forced laborers, which in turn yields negative net social welfare. As one escaped victim

13
Altsean Key Issues – Economy. http://www.altsean.org/Key%20Issues/KeyIssuesEconomy.htm

42
[name withheld] reported to FTUB, “the [regime] uses us like animals as forced laborers,
porters and human shields. I myself was forced by the soldiers to work on the
Total/Unocal pipeline.”

Graph 20 shows Thailand as the single biggest customer for Burma’s exports. “Burma
earned $2.16 billion by selling gas, mainly to Thailand, in 2006, Human Rights Watch
estimates. And that amount accounted for half the country’s total exports”14 Referring
back to the earlier import discussion, it is clear that the SPDC is using the proceeds from
its gas revenues to purchase more military hardware for its army, the Tatmadaw.

Graph 20 % of Exports Purchased From Burma 2007

Japan 5%

Other 28%

Thailand 49%

India 13%

China 5%

Source: FTUB Compiled Data 2008

Burma’s leadership finds itself in a very optimal strategic position, as they are able to sell natural gas to either of their
mammoth, resource-hungry neighbors.

Weapons and military equipment purchases by Burma’s ruling junta, the State Peace and
Development Council (SPDC), have substantially increased in recent years as the generals have
gained significant earnings from the sale of natural resources to energy-hungry countries in the
region. Claiming to have the world’s 10th largest gas reserves, with an estimated 90 trillion cubic
feet of natural gas, Myanmar is strategically situated between two of the world’s fastest growing
economies. In efforts to meet their growing energy needs, India and China are vying for leverage
with Burma’s generals. It comes as no surprise that both countries have been offering attractive
military assistance packages to the junta.15

14
Cherian, Thomas. “Asian Leaders, Seeking Myanmar’s Gas, May Go Soft on Sanctions.” Bloomberg. Wednesday
November 21, 2007.
15
Black, Michael and Couchaux, William. World Politics Watch: “Myanmar finds willing arms suppliers in energy-
hungry neighbors.” January 2007.

43
Graph 21 illustrates the continuous upward trend in Burma’s natural gas production,
which has been the biggest single contributor to their increased exports.

Graph 21 Burma Dry Natural Gas Production


0.4

0.35

0.3
Trillion Cubic Feet

0.25

0.2

0.15

0.1

0.05

0
80 82 84 86 88 90 92 94 96 98 00 02 04
19 19 19 19 19 19 19 19 19 19 20 20 20

Year
Source: US Energy Information Administration

Gas and oil production will likely continue to grow for Burma, as the two sectors
represented 98% of all Foreign Direct Investment or $471.5 million in fiscal year 2006-
2007.16 Much of this money will be used to increase the volume of gas extraction, and to
expand the pipeline network necessary for its transit. The sources of the gas and oil FDI
will be discussed in greater detail in the upcoming section on sanctions.

Graph 22 reflects the changing dimensions of oil production, consumption, and exports
for Burma, from 2003-2007. The abrupt drop in domestic oil consumption, which was
highest in 2007, can be attributed to the SPDC slashing domestic fuel subsidies which
caused prices to spike dramatically. Almost overnight, consumers faced a 500% jump in
the price of fuel, which affected the entire economy, from public transit, to food.

Immediately after the fuel price leaped, it was reported that “rice had risen by nearly
10%, edible oils by 20%, meat by about 15% and garlic and eggs by 50%.”17 Considering
that the majority of peoples’ income in Burma is spent on food, the dramatic jump in
food and commodity prices weighed heavily on consumers. An economist from Burma
responded to the increases by saying, “They could hardly afford food before. Now their
weekly budget for essential foodstuffs is going to buy even less - their purchasing power
has been reduced by more than 25% virtually overnight.”18

16
The Associated Press. “Foreign Investment in Burma Dominated by Oil, Gas, Power.” November 27, 2007.
17
Jagan, Larry. Asia Times: “Fuel price policy explodes in Burma.” Thursday August 23, 2007.
18
Jagan, Larry. Asia Times: “Fuel price policy explodes in Burma.” Thursday August 23, 2007.

44
Graph 22 Oil Industry in Burma

70000

60000
Barrels Per Day

50000

40000 Oil Production

30000 Oil Consumption

20000 Oil Exports

10000

0
03 04 05 06 07
20 20 20 20 20
Year

45
Stuctural Reforms
IV. Structure Reforms:

Many economists are of the opinion that structural reforms should accompany
stabilization programs (requiring mainly monetary and fiscal adjustments) in order for an
economy to achieve sustained development. Indeed, it is this belief which has led IMF to
expand its mandate since the early 1980s to promote “structural reforms,” that is, changes
in the structure of the economy. Likewise, the WB too has moved beyond just lending for
development projects (like roads and dams) to providing broad based support in the form
of “structural adjustment loans”.
But, as we have seen in the proceeding section, Burma has not even progressed to the
stage of achieving stability. It is clear from what has transpired to date that the GOM’s
over-riding objective since it took over civil power in 1988, has been to build roads,
bridges, irrigation dams and other physical ( and visible) infrastructure and to achieve
high rates of growth.
If the officially recorded GDP growth rates are taken at face value then one would be led
to believe that there is no need for “structural reforms” in Burma. But as we have seen
above, the fact that high GDP growth rates are not corroborated by other indicators of
development and in the way the problems are linked to one another, Burma in fact needs
structural reforms together with usual stabilization measures in order to achieve growth
with stability. Indeed, having professed to adopt a market-oriented system, the GOM did
initiate a number of economic reforms.
Major economic reform measures taken up to 1997 and directly affecting macro-
economic stability and growth may be summarized as follows:

1) Price and Trade Sector Liberalization – liberalization of agricultural trade;


liberalization of domestic and foreign trade, allowing private sector’s participation in the
business previously under the monopoly of state of Economic Enterprises (SEE’s);
resumption of Myanmar’s Chamber of Commerce and Industry, (renamed Union of
Myanmar Federation of Chamber of Commerce and Industry –UMFCCI) regularization
of border trade.

2) Introduction of Foreign Investment Law - to attract foreign direct investment


(FDI),to enhance technical know-how and investments in all sectors except those
reserved for the State; issuance of foreign exchange certificate-FEC to promote tourism

3) Tourism sector reforms – allowing private sector participation in hotels and tourism
business.

4) Fiscal reforms – taxation reforms to restructure the tax and tariff systems and to
streamline tax collecting and customs procedures to be in line with market-oriented
system; gradual depreciation of exchange rate for custom evaluation; and more stringent
scrutiny of government expenditures to tackle the problem of deficits.

5) Financial sector reforms –establishment of Myanmar Investment Commercial Bank


(MICB); building legal framework; restructuring the financial sector; and allowing
private sector participation in banking and insurance.

49
6) Legal system reforms – the combination of Common Law and Civil Law Legal
Systems which Burma already had and which had been kept intact during the past 25
years before 1988 were reactivated with some new legal injection and revocation of the
Law of Establishment of Socialist Economic System.

7) Privatization – establishment of Privatization Committee; privatization of cinema


halls under the Ministry of Information.

As a result, the share of the private sector (including cooperatives) in gross domestic
product (GDP) increased from approximately 69% in 1986/87 to 78% in 1996/97, while
that of the state sector declined slightly from 31% to 22%. In foreign trade, private
sector’s share of exports increases from 36.5% in 1989/90 to 62.9% in 1996/97, while the
state sector share correspondingly declined form 63.3% to 34.9% during the same period.
And between 1989/90 and 1996/97, the share of private sector participation in total
investment in the economy increased form 38.8% to 50.1% while that of the state
declined from 60.1% to 49.1%. In addition, there was also a sizable inflow of foreign
direct investment (FDI), although it paled in comparison to Vietnam which introduced its
own Investment Code only a few months earlier.

But as will be seen below, the contribution of GDP by private sector and cooperatives
have not progressed beyond 91% since2002/03 (Table 8).

Table 8: Structure of GDP by Ownership


1986/87 1996/97 2001/02 2002/03 2003/04 2004/05 2005/06
GDP 100 100 100 100 100 100 100
State Produced 31 22 16 0.09 0.09 0.09 0.09
GDP
Private Sector 69 78 84 0.91 0.91 0.91 0.91
and
Cooperatives
Source: ADB 2001: IMF 2006.

The large share of private sector and cooperatives in GDP was mainly due to the large
share of the agricultural sector in GDP, which is considered as a private sector. Table 8
fails to show however, recent gains in the share of private sector at the expense of the
cooperatives sector. Nonetheless, the data reflects the slow pace of privatization of State
Owned Enterprises (SEEs).

After the Asian economic crisis of 1997 however, there was hardly any more reforms of
significance. On the contrary, government intervention in the market has been on the
increase. And the government’s command and control over the economy has become
more pervasive. Privatization program continue to languish in limbo. Thus, many
scholars see the government as retreating back to old style command economy.

In spite of official denial that the impact of the Asian crisis on Burmese economy would
be serious, the crisis, as it turned out, seems to have pushed Burma back to the command

50
economy and old ways of doing things. To elaborate, the indirect fall out led to drastic
decline in the inflow of FDI and exports to ASEAN.1 The value of the kyat tumbled in
the parallel market, external imbalances widened, and foreign exchange reserves fell.
More importantly, while the actual impact of the crisis on Burma is a contentious issue,
as suggested by some, psychologically, the crisis appears to have dampen the enthusiasm
for reform and hence, to slowing down the momentum of the reform process.

In order to contain further deterioration of the macroeconomic situation the authorities


imposed new restrictive measures on foreign trade without warning, such as regulation by
the Central Bank which limits foreign remittances of FECs purchased by the kyat to US$
50,000 per month; replaced the 5 % commercial tax by an extra income tax of 2 % and an
8 % commercial tax (payable in foreign exchange); tightened import controls and
suspended the foreign licenses of private banks.

No doubt, some of these new restrictive measures were forced upon the government by a
shortage of foreign exchange. At the same time, they also suggest a retreat back to the
command economy. This is also evident in the way the government tackled the banking
crisis of February 2003. Private banking was looked upon by the government as making
money with other people’s money, and private banks were subjected to the most stringent
2
conditions to operate. Because of interest rate regulation by the Central Bank, real
interest rates remained negative. More importantly, as evidenced by the decline in
M2/GDP ratios from 35.0 in 1995 and 28.1 in 1998 to 18.6 in 2004, its financial sector
has in fact regressed.3

Political factors may also be responsible for pushing the government, which had changed
its name from SLORC to SPDC (State Peace and Development Council), back into its
own shell (or bunker). That is, the international pressure exerted by the ban on new
investment by the US since May 1997. On the home front, student unrest forced the
government to suspend undergraduate classes in 1997, and as it turned out, up to 2000
(comparable to the shut down of schools and universities between 1974 and 1976 during
the socialist period). This could also have been a factor in the decision of the government
to revert back to its command-oriented approach to the economy. See figure 1.

1
The cumulative amount of FDI approvals during the eight year period between 1989/90 and 1996/97 of slightly over 6
billion US dollars was more than three times the amount of less than 2 billion US dollars in the following eight years
between 1997/98 and 2004/05. As argued by a number of scholars, the decline in FDI could equally be due to internal
factors such as Burma’s unattractive investment environment (including amongst others, dual exchange rates and
cumbersome administrative procedures) as to the Asian crisis.
2
Besides being forced to call back loans on short notice, private banks were also ordered to strictly adhere to two new
regulations. As reported in The Myanmar Times, “loans cannot account for more than 80 percent of total deposits,” and
the ratio of paid-up capital to deposits must be at 1:7 (The Myanmar Times, July 19-25, 2004). While these two new
regulations by the Central Bank may insure against bank runs, they also make legal banking barely profitable (and that
in financial terms only). As a result, many became reluctant to take on new deposits, something unheard of in the
banking world. The 1:7 ratio has lately been relaxed to 1:10 ratio.
3
In contrast, M2/GDP ratios of Vietnam had increased from 23.0 to 75.2 during the same period.

51
Figure 1
Economies in Transition

Less Government Intervention


(Free Market Economy)
Hong Kong*
Singapore*
(M’97)
*
(V’97)
(M’99) (V’02)
* *
* (L’02)

(M’87)* *(L’97)

(V’87)*
(L’87)*

More Government Intervention


(Controlled Economy)

M=Myanmar
L=Laos
V=Vietnam
87,’97,’99, and ‘02=1987, 1997. , 1999 and 2002

Source: Myat Thein, 2004.

“In Figure 1, Burma/Myanmar in 1987 is placed at the right of both Vietnam and Laos,
meaning less macroeconomic stability, chiefly but not only because of its lower rate of
inflation. As for placing Burma/Myanmar above Vietnam and Laos in 1987 with regard
to the degree of government intervention, it is because most would consider the latter two
countries to be more socialistic and centrally planned economies. However, for reasons
mentioned above, since 1997 Burma / Myanmar has moved further away from
transforming its controlled economy into a market economy whereas Laos and Vietnam
appears to be continuing their progress towards a market economy.” (Myat Thein, 2004,
pp 167-168)

52
It is important to note that the observations being made above by Myat Thein and a
number of other scholars are not just about stop/go, ad hoc, contradictory policies which
Governments with short-term horizons are prone to take. They are concerned with the
general direction of policy developments away from the regression of a market-oriented
economy and back to the command type of economy.

But it is by no means permanent or irreversible. Another turn is now under consideration.


In the manner of a sleepy driver zigzagging along the road towards a market- oriented
destination, the GOM, according to the latest news report, is once again said to be
considering a major restructuring of the economy.4 According to that news report,

Burma’s military rulers are planning a major economic reform program which is
expected to be rolled out in the next few months. The plans involve liberalizing the
economy and attracting more investment into the country. The reforms include
privatizing many of the government’s economic entities, improving the government’s tax
collection and reforming the banking system.5

In fact, early this year the military government announced that eleven government
businesses, including beer, bicycle, cosmetic, glass, soft drink, textile and paint factories
in Rangoon and Mandalay were to be privatized. A newly formed Privatization
Commission is charged with the responsibility of overseeing the sale of these government
companies; and according to the report cited above; nearly a thousand states- owned
enterprises are to be partially privatized.

For a country transforming its economy from centrally directed command system to a
market – oriented system, privatization should (or could) be one of the main pillars of
structural reform. Therefore, the latest news, if true, is indeed welcome news. But, before
being carried away one needs to ask why the privatization process in the past simply
languished in limbo, and why the way the privatization process now may possibly
succeed.

A number of reasons have been given for the failure of the privatization process in the
past.6 (For more details see Myat Thein 2004). But, the main reason may simply be the
fact that the military regime, accustomed to direct command and control, was not
comfortable with the idea of “ letting go” a large chunk of the economy into the hands of
private enterprise.7 In addition, the Privatization Commission itself may not really be
aware of the tremendous costs to the country and the society of not privatizing SEEs or
privatizing them very slowly. Although a lot of details of the new privatizing plans still
remain to be worked out thoroughly, the announcement that the government intends to
hold 51% of shares (and that it will act as both operator and investor) strongly suggest
that the ‘command and control’ attitude of the GOM has not changed one little bit. And

4
Jagan, Larry. “Economic Reform in Burma?” The Daily Star (Bangladesh). Tue 22 August, 2006.
5
Ibid
6
For details see Myat Thein 2004.
7
Besides the direct budgetary costs, there are indirect costs stemming from budgetary deficits caused by SEEs such as
increases in money supply, inflation, hardships for the poor and needy and so on. The fact that the essence of
privatization is greater efficiency and competitiveness may also be a forgotten factor. (Myat Thein 2004).

53
this makes a lot of businessmen very nervous. Add to it, the unpredictable regulatory
environment and capricious policy making, there may not be any takers at all.

On the other hand, to the extent that the new privatization plans have been prompted by
the government’s need to raise finances, especially to fund the building of the new capital
at Naypyitaw, the new Privatization Commission (with possible less resistance) may try
hander to make a success of it this time around. As mentioned above, the problem this
time around could be reluctance on the part of the businessmen in the private sector to
work with the government holding 51% of the shares.

On other front, propelled perhaps by the realization of impending economic crisis, the
GOM is moving forward with plans to set up a number of special economic zones
(SEZs) with the assistance of China at Thilawa, and with the assistance Thailand along
the Burma/Thai border.

54
Development Divide
V. Development Divide:
In this section, the report is trying to reanalyze from Myat Thein, 2004 and his comments
and future prospects on ASEAN with Burma ( Myanmar) in his study, “Transition
Economy of Myanmar, 2007”. The development gap would be defined as “difference in
development level between one entity and other or among entities – in terms of quality of
life”. Development gap could be expressed from different perspectives- among different
geographical areas or different demographical groups (age groups) or different races or
ethnic groups or religious groups, countries with different political (or economic)
systems, or administrative levels (national, regional, household).

Development gap has impact not only traditional security issues (violence, war, etc.), but
also on non-traditional security issues (migration, human trafficking, HIV/AIDS, etc.) In
other words, development gap has negative impact on human security.1 Here, for the
purpose of this study, human development gap in Burma will be analyzed at the regional
level (between states and divisions or between ethnic groups); and national levels (urban
and rural areas); and within urban and rural areas in terms of economic, social and
political aspects. With these concepts in mind, Burma’s development will be assessed.

Development gap at the National level-

We begin with a look at the development gap Burma at the regional level within the
country. Here what we need to look for, first and foremost, is the development divide
between divisions where most Bamar (comprising some70% of total population) are
living and states where most ethnic groups (Kachins, Kayin, Rakhines, Shans, etc.)
inhibit.

According to Mya Than’s study, three divisions and three states are in the higher income
group, while four divisions and four states belong to four states belong to the lower
income group.2 In other words, it is difficult to conclude that the states where most ethnic
groups reside are poorer than the divisions where most Bamars inhabit or the other way
round. Hence, we can breathe with a sigh of relief that recent developments do not seem
to have (inadvertently or otherwise) discriminated any one group in favour of another.
However, what is of interest here is to find those states and divisions, which shares
borders with more developed neighbors such as Thailand and China to have higher
income than others. As noted by Mya Than, this is presumably because they are better
placed to derive higher income from cross-border informal and formal trade.

Looking at the poverty headcount index by states and divisions, it may not come as a
great surprise that all the state and divisions in higher income group with the exception of
Ayeyarwady division, also have lower incidence of poverty (less than the national
average of 22.9). The exception from the other end of the income spectrum is the Shan
State with a low headcount index of 11.9.

1
Human security has 7 components: economic security, food security, health security, environmental security, personal
security, community security, and political security. For details, see Human Development Report 1984.
2
Mya Than 2005. Average monthly household income of kyats 10,000 is used for separating the two groups.

57
Next, if we look at the development gap between rural and urban areas, it comes as a bit
of a surprise to find that rural areas have less poor people than urban areas-in terms of
poverty headcounts and poverty gap (Table 9).

Table 9 - Development Gap between Rural and Urban Areas

Poverty Estimates for Urban Rural Households by Headcount Index (HI) and by Distribution for Poor

Urban Rural Total


------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
Headcount Index (% of population) 23.9 22.4 22.9
Poverty Gap (%) 30.4 69.6 100
------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
Source: World Bank, August 1999.

This is consisted with Mya Than’s earlier research findings where Gini Coefficient is less
in rural areas (0.41) than in urban areas (0.56) (1985, p.76). This means, income gap
within the urban is wider than that of in rural areas. In other words, the gap between the
rich and poor is quite large in urban areas than in rural areas.

Burma is, in fact, an outlier amongst ASEAN countries in that poverty headcount index is
slightly higher in urban areas (23.9%) than in rural areas (22.4%). In this respect, Burma
is the only outlier amongst ASEAN countries. The World Bank (1999, p. 13) gave the
following reasons for this result:

• Average family size, which is generally correlated with poverty, is approximately the
same in rural and urban areas.

• The cost of food is higher in urban areas, with the cost of the minimum food basket
about 16 % higher than in rural areas.

• The distribution of expenditure (and income) is more skewed in urban areas.

• National averages for urban and rural household expenditures conceal considerable
regional variation; rural poverty rates are significantly higher than average in some
states and divisions.

• Access to subsistence levels of production keeps more rural families out of poverty.

It could also be because high rises, modern supermarkets, classy restaurants and gleaming
new apartment buildings in Rangoon, Mandalay and many other urban centers that a
casual observer see, are owned by a handful few, while the majority live in less well-
furnished places or urban slums. Then again, huge supermarkets and new departmental
stores stocked with all kinds of imported goods cater chiefly to what are locally known as

58
3
‘$ earners’, while the majority, the have-nots, just pass them by. Thus, as noted a decade
ago by Thein and Than, “many people feel that inequality of income has increased
rapidly from the relative equality of earlier years in a short span of time” (Ibid., p. 238).

On the other hand, the World Bank’s findings could be some what out of date. This is
because the latest increase in the nominal wages and salaries of government servants in
April 2006 by 5.5 to 12.5 times the previous levels of pay could close the gap between
the haves and have-nots in the urban centers.4 While the increase was very regressive
(with the lowest ranked workers wages increasing by about five times as compared to
increases in the salaries of high ranking officers by 12.5 times) it must certainly have
narrowed the income gap between fixed income earners in government service and those
private sectors whose pay tend to increase gradually with inflation.

The downside of this move was however the impoverishment of pensioners and the poor
(often the forgotten people) who where left out of consideration but who must, like
others, face the erosion in their real income from the consequential inflation. Soon after
the news of pay hike broke, the prices of basic commodities such as rice, edible oil, meat
and fish, other daily necessities as well as fuel were said to have risen by 10 to 25%,
according to informal market survey.

Another way of investigating the development gap inside the country is by comparing
development indicators between rural and urban areas (Table 10).

Table 10: Household Access and Ownership Levels in Rural and Urban areas, 1997
(Percentage of Household)
Items Urban Rural Total
Access
Piped water 2 17 19
Sanitation 20 -- 20
Electricity 10 32 42
Ownership
Radio 24 35 59
Car 1 8 9
Motorcycle 1 6 7
Bicycle 38 54 92
Source: World Bank, 1999 August

Thus, the fact that poverty headcount index is lower in rural areas than in urban centers
does not mean that rural residents are generally better off. In fact they are worse off alone
key dimensions of human development. Moreover, in terms of levels of ownership of
basic durable assets (eg, radio, car, motorcycle, & bicycle), are very low. At the same

3
Although there are some domestic dollar earners who work in some foreign companies, the majority are parents of
sons and daughters working abroad as illegal immigrants in menial jobs.
4
According to a number of observers, the move was by way of celebration for relocating the administrative capital
from Yangon to Naypyitaw (Royal City) in the vicinity of Pyinmana.

59
time, levels of access to some basic utilities (eg, piped water, sanitation, & electricity) in
rural areas are very low compared to urban areas.

Nonetheless, on average, consumption levels estimated by CSO (1999) suggest that they
are better able to obtain minimum subsistence needs than are urban households.

Development Gap at the Regional level-

Table 11 shows the economic gap between Burma and other ASEAN members countries
in terms of GDP growth rates and GDP per capita. Before the Asian economic crisis of
1997, old ASEAN member countries with the exception of Brunei were having higher
rates of GDP growth than the new member CLMV countries. However, since the crisis
this situation was reversed with CLMV countries enjoying higher rates of growth than the
old ASEAN countries. This was mostly because, unlike the old member countries, Burma
(Myanmar) and other new member countries had relatively minimum impacts from the
regional crisis. By 2004 most of the old member countries had recovered from the crisis
and were performing as well as the new member countries.

As a result, the large per capita income gap between the old members and the new
members persisted as in the past. As for Burma, despite the fact that its GDP/cap is the
lowest among the grouping, it grew by about 50% between 1996 and 2004.

Table11: GDP Growth Rate and GDP Per/cap in ASEAN


Country GDP Growth Rate% GDP/ cap(US$)
2004 1996 2004
Brunei 2.9 17,096 13,879
Indonesia 5.1 1,115 1,193
Malaysia 7.1 4,817 4,625
Philippines 6.0 1,184 1,042
Singapore 8.4 25,107 25,207
Thailand 6.1 3,035 2,537
Cambodia 7.7 317 358
Laos 5.5 396 423
Myanmar(Burma) 12.2(5.0)* 109 166
Vietnam 7.7 337 554
Source: ASEAN Finance and Macroeconomic Surveillance Unit (FNSU) Database, 2005.* FMSU Source for its GDP
growth rates: Ministry of National Planning and Economic Development, Yangon.

Development trends in the structure of production generally indicate the economic


progress of an economy. In general, as the economy develops over time the share of
industry in GDP grew and that of agriculture declined. In Burma, paradoxical as it may
seem, in spite of high GDP growth rates officially recorded over the past decade, the
structure of the economy or the share of GDP by major sectors has remained substantially
unchanged (Table 12).

60
Table 12 shows the economic structure of ASEAN economies which in turn suggest the
development stage of each and every country. Almost all of old member’s economic
structure shows that their economies have already changed from the agriculture-depended
stage to an industrialization stage and then to services sector dominated stage.
Meanwhile, with the exception of Vietnam, all three new members still remain as
agriculture-based economies. This reflects the large quality gap in the economic
structures between the two groups or the large gap in development levels between these
two groups.

Table 12: ASEAN Economic structure, 1980 and 2003


Country Agriculture Industry Services
1980 2003 1980 2003 1980 2003
Brunei n.a 2.1 n.a 58.4 n.a 39.5
Indonesia 24.4 15.4 41.3 45.0 34.3 39.6
Malaysia 22.9 8.1 35.8 42.1 41.3 49.8
Philippines 23.5 19.8 40.5 33.5 34.3 46.7
Singapore 1.1 0.1 38.8 31.1 60.0 68.8
Thailand 20.2 10.2 30.1 45.8 49.7 44.0
Cambodia n.a 36.8 n.a 27.9 n.a 35.4
Laos n.a 51.3* n.a 23.1* n.a 25.6*
Burma(Myanmar) 47.9 57.2* 12.3 10.5* 39.8 32.4*
Vietnam 42.7 22.7 26.3 36.9 31.0 40.4
Source: ADB, 2002, UNDP 2003. ASEAN Finance and Macroeconomic Surveillance Unit (FMSU) Database, 2005.*
For 2001.
Foreign trade plays an important role in economic development of the country and its
integration with the region and / or the world. Total foreign trade (exports and imports
together) as per cent of GDP shows the degree of the country’s economic openness which
can also suggest the development level of the country. According to Table 13, there is a
big gap between the new members and the old members in terms of degree of openness
as well as that of per capita value of foreign trade. These data also suggest the large
development gap between these two groups.

Table 13: Degree of Openness and Export per capita: ASEN


Country Degree of Openness Exports/Cap (US$)
Brunei n.a n.a
Indonesia 58.6 231
Malaysia 187.3 231
Philippines 110 479
Singapore 312 28,672
Thailand 94 945
Cambodia 71 62
Laos 65 74
Myanmar(Burma) 32 22
Vietnam 95 151
Source: FEER Yearbook 2000. Note: Some numbers are rounded.

61
The level of infrastructure such as airports, seaports, transportations, energy,
telecommunication also indicate the level of a particular country and these indicators also
can be used in comparing the level of development among groups of countries. Table 14
suggests that there exist bid gaps between the CLMV and the original members of
ASEAN.

Table 14: Infrastructure in ASEAN Countries (Lowest=1 & Highest=5)


Country Airport Seaport Transport Energy Telecoms Average

Brunei 3.3 3.0 3.3 3.6 3.5 3.3


Indonesia 3.0 2.4 2.3 2.6 2.7 2.6
Malaysia 3.1 3.1 2.7 2.6 3.2 2.9
Philippines 2.3 2.5 1.9 2.2 2.7 2.3
Singapore 4.9 4.9 4.6 4.4 4.7 4.7
Thailand 3.1 3.1 1.6 2.7 3.0 2.6
Cambodia 1.6 1.5 1.81.4 1.4 1.4 1.5
Laos 1.5 1.5 1.5 1.7 1.5 1.5
Myanmar 1.6 2.0 1.6 1.4 1.4 1.5
Vietnam 1.9 2.4 1.9 1.9 2.2 2.0
Source: Tam et al, 2004 quoting Daily Economic News, Taiwan, 14/8/1997

Table 15 shows the levels of mass media and information and telecommunications
infrastructure of all ASEAN countries. Even at the first glance, it is obvious that between
CLMV countries and the old ASEAN members, there are great differences in populations
‘access to information (in terms of newspapers per thousand population, number of radios
and TVs per thousand population) and telecommunications technology (in terms of
telephone lines per thousand people, number of personal computers and internet users per
thousand population). Singapore, Thailand and Malaysia are most advanced countries
among the ASEAN members whereas Cambodia, Laos and Myanmar (Burma) are far
behind other fellow members.

Table 15: ICT Infrastructure of ASEAN Members (per thousand people)


Country Newspaper Radios TVs Tel Personal Internet
Computers Users
Brunei n.a n.a n.a n.a n.a n.a
Indonesia 24 156 136 27 8.2 420
Malaysia 158 420 166 198 58.6 -
Philippines 79 159 108 37 15.1 1,000
Singapore 360 822 348 562 458.4 141,200
Thailand 63 232 236 84 21.6 1,950
Cambodia 2 127 123 2 0.9 0.005
Laos 4 143 4 6 1.1 0.005
Myanmar 10 95 7 5 5.0 1.0
Vietnam 4 107 47 26 6.4 1.0
Source: FEER Year Book, 1999, World Development Report 1999-2000, Vietnam Investment Review, various issues.

62
The most visible indicators expressing the development gap among the nations or
between groups are obviously the poverty level and Human Development Index (HDI) –
measured in terms of life expectancy, literacy rate and income level. Many of the old
member countries, except Philippines, have fewer people under poverty line whereas
most of new member countries have more poor people. Regarding ranks in term of HDI
index, in general, all new members are far behind the old ones with the exception of
Indonesia and Vietnam where Vietnam is ranked two places above Indonesia (Table16).

Table 16: Poverty and Human Development Index (HDI) in ASEAN Countries
Country Poverty Headcount Index HDI
Rank(2003)
Whole Urban Rural
Country
Brunei* n.a n.a n.a 33
Indonesia(1990) 19.6 10.7 23.6 110
Malaysia(1987) 18.6 7.3 24.7 61
Philippines(1991) 49.7 34.2 67.8 84
Singapore* n.a n.a n.a 25
Thailand(1992) 13.1 2.4 15.5 73
Cambodia* 36 25.4 40 130
Laos(1992/93) 53.0 23.9 54.9 133
Myanmar(1997) 22.9 23.9 22.4 129
Vietnam* 37 9.0 45 108
Source: World Bank, 1999, August, 18, Tam et al, 2004, Human Development Report 2005.

Table 17 shows the knowledge gap or education gap between the two groups inside
ASEAN. At the secondary and tertiary levels, the new member countries are behind the
old member countries in terms of enrolment ratios and expenditure on education as
percentage of GDP. At the primary level enrolment ratio and expenditure and expenditure
in education, Vietnam is at par with some of the old member countries.

Table 17: Educational Enrolment Ratio (% of age group) of ASEAN countries


Country Educational Enrolment Ratio Expenditure
(% 0f GDP)
Primary Secondary Tertiary
Brunei* n.a n.a n.a n.a
Indonesia(1990) 113 56 11 1.4
Malaysia(1987) 101 64 11 4.9
Philippines(1991) 117 78 35 3.4
Singapore* 94 74 39 3.0
Thailand(1992) 89 59 21 4.8
Cambodia* 113 24 1 2.9
Laos(1992/93) 112 29 3 2.1
Myanmar(1997) 121 30 11 1.2
Vietnam* 114 57 7 3.0
Source: World Development Report 2000, World Development Indicators 2000

63
Table 18 shows the gap in health indicators between the two groups of ASEAN member
countries. As may be expected, the more development ASEAN 6 generally spend more
on health (per/capita US$) and has better health indicators than the new members. That
is, they have fewer infant mortality (per 1000 births), longer life expectancy, greater
access to improved water resources.

Table 18: Health Indicators in ASEAN


Country Infant Life Access to Health
mortality (per Expectancy Improved Per/cap
1000 births) (years) water (% of US$
population)
Brunei n.a 76.4 n.a n.a
Indonesia 38 66.8 76 44
Malaysia 8 73.2 95 189
Philippines 31 70.4 87 136
Singapore 4 78.7 100 777
Thailand 26 70.0 80 349
Cambodia 86 56.2 30 90
Laos 93 54.7 44 35
Myanmar 79 60.2 68 -
Vietnam 31 70.5 56 81
Source: UNDP 2001; Human Development Report 2005

64
Future Prospects
VI. Future Prospects:
On the basis of the foregoing one cannot but conclude that much greater efforts are
needed to improve the economic situation in Burma. The government’s reform measures,
selective, partial and some reversed, have not been enough to eliminate deep-seated
structural distortions and macroeconomic imbalances. “A renewed commitment to
comprehensive reform is needed to position the economy for recovery and growth and to
1
lay foundation for reducing poverty”

But, Burma is not the only country that is doing poorly. As a former British ambassador
to Burma recently reminded us:

“Many other less developed and even better development countries


suffer from the same symptoms as Burma, such as poverty, corruption,
inequality, unsustainable natural resource exploitation, lack of freedom,
and a growing burden of HIV. Many countries are sicker than Burma
on some or all of these counts. Treatment for systemic problems is
2
never straightforward”.

Any reflection on the future prospect of such a country as Burma must be conditional.
First, it is necessary to know whether the authorities realize as to the true condition of the
economy. On the basis of the official media reporting achievements of the GOM, one
would not think that the authorities are aware of the poor state of the economy. On the
other hand, the objectives of the Third Five – Year Short Term Plan (2001/2002 –
2005/2006) to reduce budgetary deficits, to reduce the inflation rate, to pare down the
current account deficit, etc., suggest that the authorities are aware, however vaguely, of
the need establish macroeconomic stability and undertake structural reforms.

Then again, the Thirty Year Plan (2001/02-2030/31) also indicates that the authorities are
quite serious about fixing the economy and catching up with its neighbors. For example,
the Thirty Year Industrial Development plan envisages a stage of development in Burma
that will:

I. be at the same level as fellow ASEAN countries by the end of the second 5 Year
Plan;
II. be on a similar status as advanced Asian countries, like Japan by the end of the 4th 5
Year Plan; and
3
III. catch up with the industrialized countries by the end of the 6th 5 Year Plan (2030).

The words “fixing the economy” in italics above is used by us because there is no way
that the 30 year vision of the leadership can be realized simply by a wave of the magic
wand and without repairing a badly damaged economy. But then again, recent events cast

1
World Bank, 1999, August, p.9.
2
Vicky Bowman, “The Burmese Patient.” Mimeo. August 2006.
3
Myanmar Industrial Development Committee, Industrial Development of Myanmar: Thirty Year Plan 2001/02-
2030/31. (Yangon, Government of Myanmar, January 2002 [in Burmese]).

67
serious doubts about the seriousness of the authorities regarding their good intentions.
For example, although the budgetary deficit did fall to 2.3 % of GDP in 2002/03, due
mainly to increase in various kinds of taxes, it widened again to 6.0% in 2004/05. But
this did not deter the government from raising the pay of civil servants by a big chunk or
moving its administrative capital from Rangoon to Naypyitaw at great costs. Apart from
the usual double- digit GDP growth officially proclaimed, the only other objective of the
3rd 5 Year Short Term Plan achieved was turning the current account deficit into surplus.
And that was by pure chance being due to the discovery and sale of natural gas to
Thailand.

Given the secretive nature of military regimes, past and present, it is possible of course
that the planners did not know about the plan to raise the pay of civil servants or the
decision to move the administrative capital from Rangoon to Naypyitaw when they were
formulating the plans. On the other hand, it is possible that the regime is made up of at
least two groups of people with varying degrees of authorities those who see a sick
economy as being sick, and those who do not see the economy as sick, but with the
former group pretending not to see anything wrong. Whatever may be the case, if the
GOM goes on making uncoordinated, ad hoc, erratic, and contradictory policies as in the
past, there is little hope for the economy to do well let alone catch up with its neighbors.
It is most likely that the economy will hobble along at some 3 to 5 % yearly rate of
growth.

In such an event, EU style ASEAN Economic Community (AEC) by 2020 (characterized


by free of goods, services, investment, capital, and skilled labor) poses a real danger for a
backward country like Burma. As noted by one knowledgeable scholar, “It will lead to
economic polarization – the most talented and enterprising Burmese people, together with
businesses and capital will leave the country to take advantage of better opportunities and
higher rewards in the more advanced member countries “(Myint, 2006, p 28).

On the other hand, the gas boom could be a silver lining in the cloud. Moreover, the sale
of hydro electricity to Thailand in the near future could also be another silver lining. Then
also there is also talk of setting up a Special Economic Zones (SEZs) in Thilawa with
China, and along the Burma – Thai border with Thailand in the near future. If these
bonanzas could be used wisely, then future prospects for Burma do not look all that
bleak.

68
Economic Sanctions
VII. Economic Sanctions:
Until this point, analysis of Burma’s economy has revealed persistent and ubiquitous
failure which is largely the result of poor policy. The reasons for such abysmal trends
might seem to be that the SPDC has unfortunate luck, or that they are the victims of
circumstance, or perhaps, they are simply inept when it comes to matters economic.
Undoubtedly, each of the aforementioned reasons might be contributory.
However, as the forthcoming section will reveal, the SPDC’s gross mismanagement of
the Burmese economy is the result of rational self-interest. Their manipulation of the
economy (with wanton disregard for the larger consequences) is driven by their interest
in expanding their military might, as well as mulcting great fortunes for their leaders.
Through the creation of conglomerate institutions such as the Union of Myanmar
Economic Holdings Limited (UMEH) and the Myanmar Economic Corporation (MEC),
the generals of the SPDC have found ways to pull money out of the economy, and put it
in their pockets. Thus, as it will be revealed, the SPDC sometimes chooses policy that
will help them to drum up cash through the UMEH or MEC vehicles, rather than making
policy decisions that are best for the economy as a whole.
Setting the Stage-
Discussing the topic of economic sanctions invariably generates impassioned responses
from both economic and political camps. For neo-classical economic purists, the idea of
sanctions – as compared to the preferred free-market scenario – is diametrically opposed
to their institutional thinking. From the political side, though sanctions do not necessarily
run contrary to any ideological currents, they are invariably wielded against one group,
by another, and thus cause great angst.
Fielding the above concerns, it would initially seem tenuous, if not outright suspect, that
an economic report would contain a section on the viability of sanctions as a vehicle for
economic change. The purpose of any economic research undertaking is (ideally) to
present objective information to provide the most accurate and useful tools for the
creation of better policy. Thus, it is not the place of an economic research paper to
suggest a policy route as it pertains to a political situation, or ideological standoff. Such
value judgments are best reserved for those who make policy decisions.
However, in the case of a country that is experiencing prolonged economic malaise due
to the intractability of a repressive government, an honest and objective assessment
(coupled with normative insights) of any policy option becomes germane. Due to the
uniquely contentious situation in which the nation of Burma finds itself, many have
proposed (and others have opposed) the idea of economic sanctions to elicit change.
Where governmental controls might typically provide a remedy, Burma faces increased
challenges. If one cannot rely on genuine economic progress to result from a government
that systematically misrepresents the interests of its people, then the ordained rules of
convention provide implausible and ineffective solutions. The intent of the following
section will be to explore the idea of sanctions objectively, with regard to the specific
dimensions and needs of the Burmese economy.

71
Arguments Against Sanctions-

With varying degrees of severity, governments which mistreat or abuse their nations’
workforces exist in every hemisphere of the globe. The stance against utilizing economic
sanctions as a means of dealing with this problem commonly takes on a “don’t throw the
baby out with the bathwater” approach. The objection is that economic sanctions will hurt
workers in addition to the delinquent government, which is the intended target.

Another frequently employed argument, with particular salience to Burma, is that


economic sanctions will only push an already isolationist-favoring government back into
secrecy, and cause greater hardship. This has been the driving argument behind
ASEAN’s “constructive engagement” and its more recently touted, though functionally
identical “flexible engagement.” The idea is that economic engagement, rather than
isolation, will provide the incentive for Burma to listen to outside voices for change.

While both arguments present seemingly valid concerns for the welfare of the people of
Burma, a closer inspection of the makeup of Burma’s economy and trade habits will
likely assuage such concerns. Both of the key arguments against sanctions: 1) that
economic sanctions will hurt the people of Burma as well as the corrupt government; and
2) that sanctions would remove much more effective inroads to dialogue, through trade
and continued investment, will be addressed.

Burma is Unique-

When making a statement about the effectiveness of economic sanctions, it is important


to identify both what the intended target is, and who will be affected in the process.
Ideally, sanctions would only reach their intended target, and leave the populace of
Burma (who is already being victimized) unharmed. Holistically, this is impossible, yet
there becomes an increasing need to make an economizing decision. That is to say, we
must ask: what are the net benefits and losses from imposing economic sanctions? If we
can do more good than harm, especially in consideration of the long-term benefit of
freeing a country of oppressive leadership, then sanctions make economic sense.

Mitigating the negative effects of sanctions that would be felt by the citizens of Burma
must be a priority. Here it becomes important to point out that economic sanctions will
primarily affect the formal sector, while leaving the informal sector largely unscathed.
Given the heavier reliance of industries in this [formal] sector on external relationships, sanctions will have a
major impact – cutting off access to finance, technology and markets – and thereby severely disrupting
operations. It should be noted, moreover, that most of these negative consequences will largely remain
confined to this sector alone, with little contamination of the informal sector…...there are few systematic
links between the two sectors allowing for the transmission of these negative effects on a wide scale. Further,
it should also be pointed out that the burden of such sanctions will not be borne by the vast majority of
ordinary people, whose lives revolve around the informal sector. Estimates of the negative effects of
sanctions on employment within the formal sector tend to vary considerably, ranging from a low of 75,000
workers (Altsean 2003) up to more than 150,000 (International Crisis Group 2004). While the impact on
those affected certainly should not be dismissed lightly, when set against an overall population of nearly 50
million or a labor force of more than 25 million --- (World Bank 2004).1

1
Oehlers, Alfred. “Sanctions and Burma: Revisiting the Case Against.” Burma Economic Watch, 2004.

72
Accounting for the high-end estimate of formal sector employment, at 150,000 there
would still only be 0.6% of Burma’s workforce affected. Certainly, some informal sector
workers will be affected, insofar as their jobs are connected to parts of the formal sector.
Fortunately, very few informal sector jobs are connected to the formal sector. Most of the
industries in the formal sector are independent of any internal supply from Burma, which
would indicate informal sector connectivity.

In fact, 98% of all foreign investment in Burma went to the oil, gas, and power sectors in
2006-2007, according to the Ministry of National Planning and Development. Oil and gas
investors were largely from the United Kingdom - $240.7 million, Singapore- $160
million, Russia, and South Korea. China also invested $281.2 million, which all went to
the power sector. The remaining 1.6% of foreign investment ($12 million) went to
fisheries.2

Cutting off all future investment in the energy sectors, and sanctioning that which is
currently produced by companies within Burma, will have a devastating effect on the
SPDC’s revenue stream. Concurrently, these industries employ very few Burmese people
(and according to innumerable ILO accounts, actually force people to work for free), so
sanctions would have little negative effect on the population of Burma. Additionally,
little if no informal sector connectivity results from this industry presence.

Referring to the earlier discussion of Burma’s workforce breakdown, it becomes quite


clear that formal sector employment represents a minimal portion of the total workforce.
With the informal, unemployed, and subsistence agricultural portions representing a
combined 90% of the total workforce (see Graph 8), it is logical to utilize economic
sanctions against formal sector industries (such as gas and oil) which represent high-
revenue for the SPDC.

Economic Engagement, Where the Money Goes-

Many have argued against economic sanctions on the merit that they remove viable
inroads for dialogue and positive motivation which would otherwise exist through
investment. “Everybody is entitled to do what they want to do,'’ ASEAN’s Secretary
General Ong Keng Yong said referring to Burma. “If you have a problem child in the
family, what do you do? Do you send the child to a sanatorium? ASEAN’s tradition is
3
different. '’

The ASEAN approach to dealing with injustices within Burma has always been to
maintain viable economic relationships with Burma, ostensibly to maintain a vocal
influence with the SPDC.

Unfortunately, despite increasing investment and trade with Burma, ASEAN’s economic
engagement with the regime has done nothing to spur positive change, and in fact the
situation is getting worse. The SPDC continues to utilize forced labor, allow its army to
2
“Foreign Investment in Burma Dominated by Oil, Gas, Power.” The Associated Press, Nov. 27, 2007.
3
Cherian, Thomas. “Asian Leaders, Seeking Myanmar’s Gas, May Go Soft on Sanctions.” Bloomburg, 2007.

73
abuse and terrorize citizens, and force citizens to work as porters for the military. All of
these and many other atrocities are happening in record numbers, despite the recent focus
on increased economic engagement.

The June 2007 report to the International Labor Conference (ILC) in Geneva documents
3,405 cases of forced labor in Burma only since March 2007. To get a sense of the scale
of the problem, consider that the actual number of instances of forced labor will be
larger—much larger—than the 3,405 that was documented by an organization which
cannot work openly in a police state like Burma.

The unfortunate reality is that economic engagement, rather than sanctions, keeps a
constant flow of money heading into the SPDC’s coffers. To get a sense of where this
money ends up, one need only look at how the regime is spending its revenues. Military
spending represented 53.07% of total expenditures in Burma for 2002, which outpaces
4
the next nearest member of ASEAN by over 30%. Compare Burma’s excessive military
spending to that of infrastructure, education, and health, all of which languish at or near
the bottom among other ASEAN members.

Pinpointing the Deception-

Clearly, there is no mistaking what purpose the SPDC intends for the money it gains from
trade, and outside investment. However, there is still a very critical part of the sanctions
discussion which needs to be heard. There remains an inextricable piece of evidence
which shows how the SPDC would be dealt an economic deathblow, while regular
citizens would mostly avoid harm from the utilization of sanctions.

The SPDC has manipulated internal industry and trade through the development of the
Union of Myanmar Economic Holding (UMEH), the Myanmar Economic Corporation
(MEC), the Union Solidarity and Development Association (USDA), and many other
government-contrived, subsidiary groups. “The creation of United Myanmar Economic
Holdings (UMEH) and the Myanmar Economic Corp (MEC) allowed the military
establishment to lock its claws around whatever new business sectors arose.”5

Through the UMEH, MEC and USDA, the military regime ruling Burma has been able to
dictate what companies or individuals are able to export, and has levied high commission
fees (around 10%) on both imports and exports. The myriad list of transaction fees, and
unofficial bribes from those who had to ‘make a deal’ to gain access to the market place
6
has greatly curbed would-be economic activity.
As Daw Aung San Suu Kyi, the leader of the legitimately elected NLD government of
Burma has said:

4
Burma sources: Defense Budget 2003-2004, Union of Myanmar, Printing & Publication Enterprise, Yangon, 2003
April. [Note: Calculated estimation based on Statistical yearbook 2002-(state administrative organizations), CSO,
Burma & Defense budget 2003/04, Burma by Economics & Research Dept, FTUB]
5
Barnes, William. “Burma in General Disarray; Reform Falls Victim to Military Junta’s off-the-cuff Policy Decisions.”
South China Morning Post, June 28, 1999.
6
Special Report: “Ready, Aim, Sanction.” ALTSEAN, November 2003.

74
“Burma itself is like a huge prison with the military dictatorship holding the keys and locking us
away from freedom. We would like to call on all of you to help us open the door of our prison …
Economic sanctions are good and necessary for the fast democratization of Burma. We would like
the European Community, the United States and the rest of the world to be aware that sanctions do
help the movement for democracy in Burma and …unilateral sanctions are better than no sanctions
at all.”7

It is evident that a very small percentage of the Burmese workforce is employed in the
formal sector. Concurrently, few citizens would in any way find greater (albeit
temporary) personal economic hardships, as a result of outside sanctions against Burma.
Most people in Burma find themselves either: in the informal sector; in a subsistence-
driven agricultural sector; or simply unemployed. In most any sector, few people can
succeed as the SPDC has created such an abysmal market environment.

Ironically, the profligate greed of the SPDC has made a perfect storm scenario, wherein
the regime actually would receive the majority of the intended effects of economic
sanctions. By keeping so many of its citizens out of the formal sector through its own
disastrous economic misdealing, the SPDC has effectively made itself a very vulnerable –
and almost exclusive – target for economic sanctions. While many might hope for reform
from the SPDC, their intent is quite clear, and their agenda is unwavering. In the context
of Burma’s eventual economic success, sanctions (as a catalyst for removing the current
corrupt regime) are a vital first step. The European Union (EU) has urged the new
government of Thailand, which is due to become chairman of the ASEAN group in July,
to work with the international community to promote human rights, democracy and peace
in neighboring Burma.

The EU wants to cooperate with Thailand's government to promote a positive solution in


Burma. Thailand, as the next chairman of ASEAN, could play a major role in moving
Burma towards democracy and human rights as the group has adopted a new charter
promoting both these important issues.

Even where Burmese workers have recently lost their jobs on account of US sanctions,
most have come to Thailand seeking new jobs like garment factory workers and labor at
seafood products. International trade patterns show the importance of Burmese migrants
to the Thai national economy. Labor intensive products from SMEs (Small to Medium
Enterprises) such as garments and canned food, the majority of which are run by
Burmese migrants, form the top ten export sectors of Thailand. (Look back Chapter III,
migrant contributes national income account).

7
A quote from Daw Aung San Suu Kyi, the leader of the National League for Democracy, which won over 80% of the
vote in the fair elections held in 1990. The NLD was not allowed to take office, as the SPDC refused to hand over
power to the rightfully elected government, until such time as it revises Burma’s constitution. The redrafting process of
the Burmese constitution has come under great scrutiny because the SPDC has been dragging the process out through a
bogus National Convention, wherein only what the SPDC has a meaningful say in the drafting process. Additionally,
the SPDC has not hidden the fact that it will use the newest constitution as a means of hardwiring a permanent military
presence in the civilian government. Basically, the SPDC’s constitution will ensure that the military always has a
controlling stake in the country, and cannot be outvoted, as had happened in 1990.

75
Impact beyond Sanctioned Burma -
(Sanctions are a non –violent method.)

“Economic sanctions will not hurt the people of Burma but they will really hurt the
corrupt government.” We can analyze this assumption with two hypotheses. The
alternative action is foreign military attack, and nobody and no country likes this action.
"As one element of our policy to promote a genuine democratic transition, the US
maintains targeted sanctions that focus on the assets of regime members and their cronies
who grow rich while Burma's people suffer under their misrule," Bush said in a
statement. In the past six months (August 2007), the US has tightened existing economic
sanctions and levied new sanctions against the dictators and their financial backers. It has
imposed an expanded visa ban on those responsible for the most egregious violations of
human rights, as well as their family members.
Cronyism and corruption have a corrosive effect, disadvantaging innocent Burmese
businessmen and entrenching a military group that pursues oppressive and destabilizing
politics, the victims of which include pro democracy activists (NLD).
The considerable role that Dictator Than Shwe’s family, their inner circle and the
Burmese security services exert over the economy, coupled with the absence of a free
judicial system and the lack of transparency, concentrates wealth in the hands of certain
classes and individuals. In turn, these classes and individuals depend upon this corrupt
system for their success and fortune. Particular Burmese business men without these
connections are unable to improve their economic standing. Roughly four groups of
existing people are clearly marked in Burma:
1) Military authority group - small proportion of country population – grow rich
2) The tycoons –small proportion of country population – grow rich
3) Ordinary businessmen –small proportion of country population – can operate only
with uncertainty for the long term and fear for the future
4) The public – majority group - staying with low living standard
The new sanctions target the mayor of Rangoon and the ministers of electric power,
health, education, industry, labor, science and technology, commerce, national planning
and economic development, finance and revenue, telecommunication and construction.
These are the ones practicing corruption.
For these reasons, the US action and EU action on Trade and Investment sanctions, arms
embargoes, travel restrictions, military or naval blockade and the like – which are an
essential ingredient of diplomatic pressure, come as the Burmese military economy is
vulnerable. Oil production is starting to fall, with revenue from oil exports up till now
accounting for as much as half of the military government’s budget. The effects of
current sanctions might be insignificant, but only if the regime were economically
competent.
For nearly a decade sanctions have also targeted several businessmen and business
entities close to Dictator Than Shwe and other hard-line military leaders.

76
1) Tay Za, the CEO of Htoo Trading Company and the owner of Air Bagan operating with
airbus Singapore, Kumming Seoul (2007). Exporting timber and gaining access over to
large areas of virgin forest. He created Myanmar Avia Export, Burma’s sole
representative of Russia’s export Military Industrial Group known as MAOP and of the
Russian helicopter company Rostvertol. When street demonstrations started in late 2007,
Tay Za asked his staff to keep an aircraft on standby at Rangoon airport.
2) Htay Myint, the chairman of the Yuzana Company: involved in Agricultural projects and
has been accused of confiscating land from farmers and ethnic groups.
3) Khin Shwe, the CEO of Zaykabar Company,who hired a US PR firm, Bain and Associates
Inc, in Virginia, in 1997 to promote a favorable international image of Burma. He was
also a member of the junta’s National Convention who actively supported the regime’s
seven –step “Road Map to Democracy”. His daughter is married to a son of Shwe Mann,
the No.3 man in the junta.
4) Tun Myint Naing, aka Steven Law, the son of former drug kingpin Lo Hsing Han,
( Lo Hsing- Han is a key founder of the Golden Triangle opium and heroin trade in the
late 1960s and early 1970s and is also wanted in Thailand – for a notorious case
involving kidnapping and murder as well as drug trafficking). He is the managing
director of Asia World Co.Ltd and Golden Aaron Pte.Ltd., sharing contracts between
MOGE (Myanmar Oil and Gas Enterprise) and CNOOC (China National Offshore Oil
Company).
5) Chit Khaing, the founder of Eden Group Co, was also involved in building the new
capital and his company runs several hotel and construction projects.
6) Zaw Zaw, the director of Max Myanmar, son of Minister Aung Thaung, close friend of the
grandson of the Dictator, chairman of Myanmar Football Federation & Tennis
Federation. His company was involved in building the new capital, Kyatpyay. He runs
IGE Pte.Ltd
7) Kyaw Win , founder and chairman of Shwe Thanlwin Co
8) Nay Win Tun, managing director of Ruby Dragon Jade and Gems Co
9) Aung Ko Win, a former school teacher, closely connected to Maung Aye, the No 2 man in
the junta, president of Kanbawza Bank and involved in Kanbawza Hospital as well as
agricultural businesses like Myanmar Billion Group.
10) Aung Thet Mann, the owner of Ayer Shwe War Co; son of Shwe Mann, he was awarded
the first rice export license to Bangladesh and Singapore.
11) Michael Moe Myint, managing director of Myint & Associates Group Co
12) Serge Pun, Chairman of the multinational SPA Group and Rangoon Yoma Bank.
13) Eike Htun, Owner of Asia Wealth Bank, and Olympic Construction.
14) Maung Weik, founded Maung Weik and Family Co, the biggest importer of steel and
gilding glue—used in the building and maintenance of Burma’s many pagodas. He also
speculated heavily in the futures markets (beans and pulses) for several years. He stirred
up controversy in 2004 with his purchase of 44 acres of Rangoon’s Hlaing Campus
(formerly Regional College No. 2). Former university students and faculty were resentful
of his plan to build a housing development on the site.
15) Minister Aung Thaung & his son – in control of UMEHL (Union of Myanmar Economist
Holding Ltd) since 1994. They also tried to run Myan Gon Myint Co Ltd – investing and
controlling import automobile licenses. Automobile prices in Burma are among the
highest in the world. A new Toyota Land Cruiser costs around 400 million ks (about US $
312,000), five times the website list of US $63,000. It is realized that the automobile
business is an easy way to make money. The cronies have hard currency and can deal
with special ways of importing the Toyota Land Cruiser. High ranking officials getting
150 million ks (US $117,000) for issuing licenses pocket about half that.

77
Hypothesis ONE: Sanctions will not hurt the people of Burma

We do know that sanctions can have an impact, that they help curtail activity and can
help isolate the junta, which is part of getting them to recognize that they need to open
up. The junta will never change unless the generals and their families are hurt. Everybody
from Burma welcomes any change.
Most Burmese people like sanctions because they do not affect them. The gap between
the haves and have-nots has grown so wide that there are only two classes in Burma. We
should refer back to the definitions of sanctions we gave in paragraph one above. The
junta does not understand that military strength, if needed, must be based on economic
strength. Sanctions have other uses such as helping to keep fickle international opinion
focused on Burma. The regime will resist diplomatic pressures to reform. The last
alternative to sanctions is the military strike but we don’t like it because we are people
who support democracy and humanitarian programs and like to save innocent lives.
Hypothesis TWO: Sanctions really hurt the corrupt government.
Banks in Singapore have stopped accepting Letters of Credit (LC) from Burmese banks
since the enactment of tough USA sanctions of financial services. A letter of credit
authorizes a transfer or withdrawal from one bank to another and is an important method
for businessmen to get money out of Burma.
The state- run Burmese Banks at the center of the problems include the Myanmar Foreign
Trade Bank (MFTB), the Myanmar Investment and Commercial Bank (MICB) and the
Myanmar Economic Bank (MEB). The banks are the only institutions that handle foreign
exchange transactions in the country. All Burmese citizens and foreign companies who
deal in other currencies have to deposit their money in one of these three banks.
Those businesses which deal with the dollar have stalled for the time being. Businessmen
are trying to find a way out of the problem. The banks like MFTB don’t know what to do,
that’s why those businesses have stopped trading. Credit card transactions are also barred,
and Burma’s top hotels currently only accept cash.
Targeted sanctions should be gradually focused on restricting the access of military, state
and crony business enterprises to international banking services, including the holding of
foreign bank accounts and the use of the Belgian based SWIFT system for bank transfers.
In addition, sanctions should include limiting the access of selected generals and their
immediate families to personal business opportunities, health services, cars, shopping and
foreign education for their children, including in regional countries. (ICG Report)

Another avenue of approach concerns the Yuan (Renminbi), whose revaluation has had a
great impact on the Burmese dictators’ foreign accounts. In 1994 the Chinese unified the
exchange rates and adopted a managed floating foreign exchange rate regime based on
market conditions, but to help its neighbors overcome the Asian bank crisis current at
time it fixed the Yuan at 8.28 against the $. This helped anchor the struggling Asian
economy.

78
Targeted sanctions should be gradually focused on restricting the access of military, state
and crony business enterprises to international banking services, including the holding of
foreign bank accounts and the use of the Belgian based SWIFT system for bank transfers.
In addition, sanctions should include limiting the access of selected generals and their
immediate families to personal business opportunities, health services, cars, shopping and
foreign education for their children, including in regional countries. (ICG Report)

Another avenue of approach concerns the Yuan (Renminbi), whose revaluation has had a
great impact on the Burmese dictators’ foreign accounts. In 1994 the Chinese unified the
exchange rates and adopted a managed floating foreign exchange rate regime based on
market conditions, but to help its neighbors overcome the Asian bank crisis current at
time it fixed the Yuan at 8.28 against the $. This helped anchor the struggling Asian
economy.

On July 21, 2005, China announced that it was de-pegging the Yuan from the dollar and
shifting it to a market- based exchange rate regime with a basket of foreign currencies.
For these reasons and the fact that the Yuan had become hard currency, the Burmese
military now tries to save Yuan instead of $.

Because of tightening of sanctions recently, the black market rate for the US $ is
fluctuating in Rangoon – falling demand for $ resulting in lower prices for some
foodstuffs, such as rice and cooking oil – the falling prices putting more food on Burmese
dining tables. Seafood such as prawns and crabs are again affordable for many people.
(source from Rangoon business communities). The present section reexamines the above
mentioned paragraphs to the context of "Impact beyond Sanctioned Burma".

Beyond Hypothesis I Hypothesis II


Sanctioned
Burma Ordinary People Military and its Cronies
(No effect) (Directly effect)

1) $ price goes down Not holding $ Money Holding $ Money


1180-ks/$ Nothing to change Change of idea for holding FE
(source on :26.02.08) (Now they wanted to hold Yuan)
as Chinese currencies have come to
be strong.

2) Prices of rice, meat Not so bad for survival Unresponsive to rice price
and fish go down ( look back at table 3 fluctuations because of their
(source on: 19/12/07) of this report) tendency to consume luxury and
imported goods

3) Traveling abroad for dream only Further study for their


restrictions & diplomatic dependent children & effect
pressure on their spouses’ daily/weekly
shopping abroad

79
7) Gems and Jade Domestic price no change Export sales $ 300 million
Trade blocked for 2006-07 but did not
announce for 2007-08.
Expected amount $ 150 million

8) Import nothing total impact- the dictators like to


depend on foreign facilities and
medical care – paid for from
the national budget.

9) Tourism nothing totally impact – because key


(Since 1997, when junta associates & their
Asian financial cronies own the top hotels
crisis hit, 5 star
hotels have remained
empty)

10) ASEAN/ China no change a) non interference policy


India/ Russia b) new ASEAN chair could play
a major role promoting the new
charter

11) UN/INGOs no change a) strong influence of UNSC


but supporting democracy b) on 11/01/08 the military circulated
for the people notes (no permission from
ministry of defense, no travel)
on INGOs to minimize the conduct
of surveys – fearing leakage of true data

12) Military strike - not willing aggressive and stimulated


Other alternative of civil wars already
Sanctions

Notes:
1) Extravagant building while the whole country suffers an acute economic crisis -According to a
municipal source from inside Burma on 22/02/08, the municipal department began plotting land, (4,000
plots) for a satellite town for new capital (Extension to be built near the new capital’s Chin village near
Ywartaw Township, 20 miles northwest of Kyatpyay Naypyitaw – 80 sq feet is being sold for 2 million ks [$
1,680] a 100 square foot plot goes for 3 millions ks [2,520 $] and 120 sq ft sells for 4 millions ks [$ 3,360]
People are being encouraged to buy plots in the new suburb and are guaranteed proper electricity, water
supply and telephone television connections).

[Singapore elder statesman Lee Kuan Yew has scrutinized Burma’s military junta, saying decisions such as
the building of a new capital from scratch were irrational, The Straits Times news paper reported on
08/01/08. He was speaking it at the dinner hosted by the Institute of Southeast Asian Studies on 07/01/08.
Lee also said the military rulers were “people with very fixated minds – quite convinced that they will have
the natural resources to weather any sanctions. Building a new capital from ground zero, what I ask
myself, what rational government would do this” – The members of ASEAN who could influence them will
be Thailand, and beyond that China and India..]

2) They can only withstand sanctions imposed by US and Western democracies because gas revenue in
Burma from Thailand was up $ 2.16 billion in 2006. In part due to higher prices globally, revenues are
likely to have further increased in 2007 as world prices have surged.

80
Conclusion
VIII. Conclusion:
As we have seen in the preceding sections, Burma faces a host of challenges for
narrowing the development gap at the regional level among ASEAN countries and at the
national level among states and divisions. In theory, it is unlikely to narrow the regional
gap from the short or medium term perspective. But according to UNDP, the
development gap among countries can be bridged, in spite of increasing development
gaps among countries in the world (The Human Development Report, 1996). The
possibility of narrowing the gap at the national level is more immediately achievable,
than at the regional level, by introducing economic reforms, institutional reforms,
administrative reforms, human resource development programs, and poverty reduction
programs.

Once Burma is able to exact political change, and follow up with viable and sustainable
economic change, the discussion of strengthened regional integration can begin. To
narrow the development gap at the regional level there needs to be not only policy
reform, but also strengthened regional integration. For that ASEAN has formulated
important programs that could provide the basics for strengthening integration. These
include ASEAN Vision 2020, the Hanoi Plan of Action, Hanoi Declaration on Narrowing
Development Gap for Closer ASEAN Integration, and Initiative for ASEAN Integration
1
(IAI). Moreover, at the economic ministers of ASEAN’s 10 member nations (August
22-23,2006) the ministers agreed to move the deadline for establishment of the proposed
2
ASEAN Economic Community (AEC) forward by five years to 2015. This means that it
has become even more urgent for the CLMV countries, with the possible exception of
Vietnam, to liberalize quickly, to restructure their economies, and to develop fast.

However, it is vitally important that Burma take the necessary steps to ease itself and its
will-be fledgling markets into any sort of regionally or globally integrated systems. Infant
industry will be key contributors to very vital economic and class stratification within a
reformed Burma. The value of protecting this homespun manufacturing will prove
immeasurable. Too much immediate focus on liberalization will likely relegate Burma to
‘bottom of the barrel’ status. In such a scenario, domestic markets, unprepared for
steeped international competition will be held down, and never truly have a chance to
take-off.

To achieve successful development going forward, Burma will have to have meaning
political reform, which in turn, needs to follow with appropriate economic reform.
Following the latest fashion, the so-called “Barcelona Consensus”, Burma could begin by
focusing on one or two binding constraints to development. What constitutes ‘binding
constraint’ for Burma is however, a contentious issue. At the top of our list would be
“low levels of private investment and entrepreneurship” which in turn is caused by the
high cost of finance. As in the decision tree depicted by Hausmann et al., the high cost of
finance in Burma is in turn the caused by ‘bad international finance’ and ‘bad local
finance’ (Hausmann et al. 2006). Finally, dual (or multiple exchange rate) is the

1
For details, see Mya Than, 2005.
2
The Myanmar Times, August 28 – September 3, 2006.

83
underlying factor behind ‘bad international finance’, while ‘bad local finance’ and poor
intermediation are amongst the major causes of low domestic savings and investment.

As we had seen in the foregoing, the financial sector of Burma, as indicated by M2/GDP
ratio, had in fact regressed since 1998; inflation hovered around 25 percent per percent
per annum since the late 1980s; savings and investment remain stunted at just over 10 %
of GDP; and the dual exchange rate continues to poison the investment environment. The
dual exchange rate system in Burma will be analyzed in more detail in our
forthcoming policy paper: "The Dual Exchange Rate System and State Level
Corruption in Burma". Still some might question the ‘high cost of finance’ given the
relatively low nominal rate of interest of around 15 %. To answer this question very
briefly, only the privileged few have access to this credit in the formal financial sector
while the vast majority of small and medium enterprises (particularly farm family
households) have to cope with usurious interest rates of 5 percent or more per month in
the informal sector.

So, there can be no doubt that the cost of finance and lack of development of financial
intermediation constitute one of the most important short-term binding constraints
inhibiting the growth of its economy. We believe that the development of the financial
sector will have the highest growth payoff. Hence, we would recommend the
development of the financial sector as the most important short to medium term reform
measure for its economy. But, it should be remembered that while promoting the
development of the financial sector, inflation needs to be curbed and dual exchange rates
need to be unified as even a strong financial system cannot protect itself against high
inflation and inappropriate exchange rates. Then, once some success is achieved it may
become more politically feasible to introduce other long-term measures for sustainable
development. This, to us, means establishing what may be called the ‘development
fundamentals’.

These include:

(i) Political commitment to Development, i.e.,


(Primacy of economics for the country’s welfare over politics);
(ii) Good governance, good public administration practicing fiscal prudence,
and establishing conditions (such as ledge framework that protects
property, enforces contracts) needed to stimulate private initiatives,
(iii) Continuous investments in both physical and social infrastructures, such as
telecommunications, transportation, research and development, education,
technical and management training and retraining, and so forth;
(iv) Consistency of policy, such as freedom from sudden or arbitrary changes
in tax system and other forms of intervention that make profit uncertain or
precarious:
(v) A relatively independent central bank to check excesses and ensure
rational monetary policies; and
3
(vi) Competent leadership with good character.

3
Ng Chee Yuen and Sueo Sudo edited, Development Trends in the Asia-Pacific, ISEAS, 1991.

84
The implication of the above is clear. Sound economic development cannot depend solely
on markets or solely on government. Both effective market incentives and social
programs supporting health, education, and infrastructure and so on are usually required.
That is to say, all persons who are citizens by birth should be insured by the state leaders
so that from birth to death, also should regard to whom those are children or, ill or
crippled, or incapacitated for work.

Over the past year, Burma has seen amazing events unfold. Citizens took to the streets in
the ‘Saffron Revolution’ in response to outrageous economic policies which hurt all
families. According to the Economist Intelligence Unit, Burma’s inflation rate
approached 50 percent at the end of 2007. As energy, food, transportation cost went
higher, causing money to loose value daily, people rightly responded with outrage.

Yet, one thing remains certain: the fate of Burma’s future cannot be determined by civic
activism alone. People left with no better option, took to the streets, risking their lives and
the lives of their families to send a message to the world. The message was simply ‘help.’
In an ever-integrating global community, how we respond to the needs of our neighbors
will define each of us, as nations, and as individuals. For the people of Burma, the size
and might of the SPDC and its army, the Tatmadaw, is too great to make fighting an
option. For those around the world, economic sanctions, coupled with political pressure,
represents all the ‘muscle’ that is necessary to free a nation from unrelenting brutality and
help it to ascend to economic prosperity.

85
Annex
ANNEX: One
Saffron Revolution (a) Golden Revolution
(Economic Protests in 2007 for Poverty Alleviation)

Inflation and unemployment are serious problems and can have devastating consequences
if left unchecked. One only has to look at the Great Depression of the 1930s and it was
effecting and was leading the Democracies in that period for the United States and Great
Britain. The word "maladjustment" has come into popular use to describe economic,
political, and moral difficulties that have arisen in Burma until now. The uncertainties of
existence are not confined to the poor alone. The people of the middle and wealthy
classes are each and every one of them subject to the same uncertainties in Burma today.

A protest began on February 22, 2007 in the Thingangyun Township in Rangoon. It was
led by a prominent group of about ten and ended peacefully after around seventy minutes.
With slogans such as "Down with consumer prices!” it was one of the demonstrations in
2007 to challenge the dictatorship control and its mismanagement rather than its legal
right to rule. As well as calls for lower prices, demands were made for improved health,
education and better utility services. Protesters were arrested and released after signing an
acknowledgment of police orders that they should not hold any future demonstrations
without first obtaining official permission.

Then, despite this, on August 15, 2007 the Burmese military dictatorship removed
subsidies on fuel causing a rapid and unannounced increase in prices. The fuel is sold by
Myanmar Oil and Gas Enterprise {MOGE}, a state- owned Fuel Company. The military
dictatorship, which has a monopoly on fuel sales, raised prices from about $ 1.40 to $
2.80 a gallon, and boosted the price of natural gas by about 500%. (While the IMF and
World Bank had been recommending the lifting of subsidies for some time to allow for a
free market to determine fuel prices, these organizations did not recommend removing all
of the subsidies unannounced and without a stepped approach).

The IMF reports that Chronically high inflation in Burma has soared to 35% a year, the
highest in Asia,{ 50% rate of inflation at the end of 2007 by EIU } while its economy is
slowing because of the poor management, poor investment & business confidence, the
IMF also reported. In its annual evaluation of Burma’s energy –rich economy, the IMF
called the Burmese economy’s medium –term outlook “poor”, forecasting slackening
growth of 5.5% in 2007 and 4 % in 2008 where CIA forecasts it as of 3.4%).

While Burma’s military rulers claim robust growth of 12.7 % last year, the IMF report
called such an expansion "implausible", estimating 7 % growth, driven by rising natural
gas exports and government construction projects such as the new capital city. "While the
economy is growing modestly, per capita gross domestic product [of about $250] and
other indicators of social well-being are significantly below those of other low-income
countries in the region, and poverty is widespread", the IMF said in the assessment, a
copy of which was obtained by the Financial Times.

89
The IMF team visited Burma in August, 2007 just weeks before mass protests triggered
by a sharp rise in the government-set price of subsidized fuel. The report, completed after
visited to Burma is not public as the regime has not approved its release by the IMF. The
UN says most Burmese are struggling to survive, and that worsening hardship and rising
prices were at the root of the recent protests. In its report, the IMF called for targeted
subsidies to address "deteriorating social-economic conditions". The IMF said Burma
could rein in inflation, and boost growth to 10 % a year, if it undertook reforms such as
cutting unproductive state spending, unifying a complicated "multiple exchange rate"
system ( see one footnotes 12 in Chapter III), and liberalizing agriculture to give farmers
more freedom to grow and sell their crops.

This increase in fuel prices led to an increase in food prices. The hikes hit Burma's people
hard, forcing up the price of public transport and triggering a knock-on effect for staples
such as rice and cooking oil. Pro-democracy activists led the initial demonstrations in
Burma's main city, Rangoon. When about 400 people marched on August 19, it was the
largest demonstration in the military-ruled nation for several years. Protests continued
around the country. Numbers were small, but demonstrations were held in Rangoon,
Sittwe and other towns. Soon afterwards, protesters took to the streets to protest the
current conditions. In response to the protests, the government began arresting and
beating demonstrators. The government arrested 13 prominent Burmese dissidents
including Min Ko Naing, Ko Ko Gyi, Min Zeya, Ko Jimmy, Ko Pyone Cho, Ant Bywe
Kyaw and Ko Mya Aye and Su Su Nyay. Later the most prominent demonstrator monk,
Ashin Gambira aka U Sandawbartha was arrested in Sint Kine Province, where he had
been a recluse for 3 months after the crisis. Among the 80 people the junta says it is still
holding after the protests are 21 monks, including 27- year - old Ashin Gambira, a leader
of the All- Burmese - Monks- Alliance which played a prominent role in the protests.

The state newspaper “New Light of Myanmar” reported that these individuals' actions
caused civil unrest that "was aimed at undermining peace and security of the State and
disrupting the ongoing National Convention. The US condemned the arrest of these
dissidents on August 22 with the State Department's acting spokesman stating ".The US
calls for the immediate release of these activists and for an end of the regime's blatant
attempt to intimidate and silence those who are engaged in peaceful promotion of
democracy and human rights in Burma. It was calling on the regime to engage in a
meaningful dialogue with the leaders of Burma's democracy movement and ethnic
minority groups and to make tangible steps toward a transition to civilian democratic
rule.

The monks started participating in large numbers after troops used force to break up a
peaceful rally in the central town of Pakokku on September 5. At least 3 monks were
hurt. They gave the government until September 17 to apologize, but no apology was
forthcoming. There were daily protests following the deadline, both in Rangoon and
elsewhere, which got bigger by the day. Tens of thousands of monks and nuns were
involved. The participation of the monks and nuns is significant because there are
hundreds of thousands of them and they are highly revered. The clergy has historically
been prominent in political protests in Burma. Their role in the protests has been

90
significant due to the reverence paid to them by the civilian population and the military.
After these events, protests began spreading across the whole nation, including Rangoon,
Sittwe, Pakokku and Mandalay.

The AABBM (Alliance of All Burmese Buddhist Monks) has vowed to continue the
protests until the military dictator is deposed. Analysts say the fuel price hikes were the
last straw for the monks, who were witnessing the country's grinding poverty first hand.
A group called the AABBM emerged to co-ordinate the protests, and on September 21
they issued a statement describing the military government as "the enemy of the people".
The group pledged to continue their protests until they had "wiped the military
dictatorship from the land of Burma", and called on people across Burma to join them.

On September 22, around 2,000 monks marched through Rangoon and 10,000 through
Mandalay with other demonstrations in 5 townships across Burma. (There are as many
Buddhists monks as soldiers in Burma - an estimated 500,000 of each presently).Those
marching through the capital chanted the "Metta Sutta" (the Buddha’s words on loving
kindness) marching through a barricade on the street in front of Daw Aung San Suu Kyi's
residence. Although still under house arrest, Daw Aung San Suu Kyi made a brief public
appearance at the gate of her residence to accept the blessings of the Buddhist monks. In
Mandalay, estimated to have 200 monasteries, monks were said to have told people not to
join the protests, which ended peacefully.

In the initial days of the protests, the public did not appear to be involved - commentators
suggested that they were too scared of retaliation. But that gradually changed as the
demonstrations grew in size. Footage of one protest showed people lining the route as the
monks marched, forming a chain to protect them from any retaliation from soldiers. On
September 24, thousands of people responded to a call from the monks and joined a
massive protest in Rangoon. Key members of the opposition party, the National League
for Democracy (NLD) also joined the protests, after initially distancing themselves from
the action. On September 25, the junta threatened demonstrators with military force and
placed army trucks at Shwedagon Pagoda, the assembly point for monks leading the
protests. Despite this, 5,000 monks and laypeople still marched into the Shwedagon.
Civilians formed a human shield around the monks. In all there were 50,000 protesters in
Rangoon. Protesters bleeding from beatings by security forces were seen scattering and
fleeing in Sule. Security forces were reported to be preparing to use insect spray to crack
down on protesters. Eyewitnesses said fire engines and insect spray carrier trucks were
seen near Theingyi market in downtown Rangoon

At first, the country's military leaders held back, letting the protests continue. But after a
week of increasingly large protests, they warned they were ready to "take action". A
dawn-to-dusk curfew was introduced and hundreds of troops and riot police moved in to
quell further protests. Despite a crackdown on the internet and mobile phone links to the
outside world, television pictures showed police using baton charges and tear gas on
monks and fellow protesters. At the end of the day, it was reported that the military group
formed new regiments to crackdown on protesters.

91
On the worst day of violence, September 27, the junta said 9 people had been killed, but
the death toll is thought to be far higher. The AABBM recorded that 3 monks died and 9
monks are still missing in this demonstrations. 54 monks and 7 nuns were arrested .The
list of these killed, missing or arrested is not complete, however, the Alliance stressed. In
the evening, the Burmese state television reported that nine people have been killed in a
force crackdown on pro-democracy protestors in Rangoon. It added that eleven
demonstrators and 31 soldiers had been injured. The death of Japanese journalist Kenji
Nagai on the streets of Rangoon in September demonstration was contributing to the
tally.

We join with international organizations in referring to the uprising as a Saffron


Revolution (a) Golden Revolution (Economic Protests for Poverty Alleviation in
Burma). According to sources close to the military dictator Than Shwe, he was directly
commanding soldiers after several commanders refused to use force to crackdown on
protesters.

In an interview with the Financial Times, the UN's representative in Rangoon, Charles Petrie, said, "People
came out (to demonstrate) because the pain they are feeling is too much - they are suffering". Petrie was
expelled from Burma for telling the truth, which the military dictatorship tried to smother with absurd
claims of its own. The authorities maintained that the monks who led the demonstrations were bogus
clergy, and even accused the CIA of involvement.

Barack Obama, Democratic presidential candidate and Illinois Senator also said the world had witnessed
the images of Burmese Buddhist Monks as they courageously and peacefully demands democracy and the
Burmese military dictator’s violent response. He was also pleased that the UN had dispatched special
envoy Ibrahim Gambari to Burma and he had met opposition leaders. He urges all nations, including the
EU and Burma’s neighbors, to cooperate in enforcing the financial sanctions the US has imposed.

UN Secretary General Ban Ki-moon said on 10/03/2008 after returning his special envoy from Burma,
Ibrahim Gambari, had not been able to achieve as much as he had hoped during his last trip to Burma. Still,
he said, the UN would continue to press the military junta to move towards democratization. UN Expert,
Paulo Sergio Pinheiro also reported on 05/03/2008 at the 7th session for Human Rights Council that some
political prisoners are behind bars as of January 2008 in Burma, as the military junta accelerated rather than
stopped unlawful arrests. In economic and social sectors as well, there have been "marked signs of
deterioration," stated the study which also denounced "serious violations of medical neutrality". He also
urged the junta to release all physically vulnerable political prisoners rapidly, saying it would be seen "as a
good - faith gesture that would help to pave the way to democratization and reconciliation." (Dow Jones
Newswires)

The year 2007, which saw protests by monks, nuns, students and democracy activists
throughout Burma, was a prime example of how inflation causes unrest in Asia.

“ - inflation has been a big cause of unrest in Asia many times in the past, most notably
the 8-8-88 uprising in Burma and the 1989 Tiananmen Square demonstrations”{The
Economist, February 2008}

92
ANNEX:Two

Table 7 ASEAN Statistics


Gross domestic product per capita in ASEAN, at current prices (nominal), in US dollars
as of 30 January 2008
In US$; at current market prices
Country 2002 2003 2004 2005 20061/
1/
Brunei Darussalam 25,744.1 30,159.2
17,157.5 18,707.7 21,863.2
2/
Cambodia 450.6 512.2
308.4 347.9 390.8
Indonesia 1,280.5 1,639.4
970.4 1,112.9 1,163.0
3/
Lao PDR 508.7 612.8
368.9 424.7 487.3
4/
Malaysia 5,250.4 5,890.5
3,899.5 4,154.7 4,876.7
5/
Myanmar 199.4 208.6
135.6 219.5 193.3
Philippines 1,157.1 1,348.6
955.3 971.5 1,039.4
Singapore 26,864.3 29,499.6
21,098.3 22,066.4 25,355.4
Thailand 2,823.0 3,289.0
2,020.4 2,264.8 2,604.1
Viet Nam 637.1 724.4
439.8 488.7 555.2
ASEAN 1,603.7 1,898.8
1,211.2 1,333.1 1,468.0
6/ 2,037.4 2,424.2
ASEAN 5 1,546.6 1,693.0 1,868.7
6/ 520.6 588.9
BCLMV 358.1 421.9 460.7

Sources: ASEAN Finance and Macro-economic Surveillance Unit Database and ASEAN Statistical Yearbook 2006 (compiled/computed
from data submission and/or websites of ASEAN Member Countries' national statistical offices, central banks, and other
relevant government agencies
IMF World Economic Outlook Database October 2007
Notes
Data is computed by dividing GDP in US dollar term with the project mid-year population for a given year.
Data in italics means has been revised from previous posting .
1/ Based on rebased/revised series per Brunei Darussalam submission as of 19 June 2007
2/ 2003-2006 data are based on revised series per Cambodia submission as of 16 & 25 July 2007.
3/ 2005 figure is revised while 2006 is the latest official data per Lao PDR submission as of 19 July 2007 (previous figure was
based on IMF WEO Database growth rate)
4/ 2002-2004 figures are based on old series while 2005-2006 data are based on rebased/revised series per Bank Negara Malaysia
Malaysia website as of 31 May 2007.
5/ GDP data from 2002-2005 is based on fiscal year from April to March of following year. Data for 2006 is derived using growth
estimate from the IMF WEO Database October 2007.
6/ ASEAN 5 consists of Indonesia, Malaysia, the Philippines, Singapore and Thailand, while BCLMV is comprised of Brunei Darussalam,
Cambodia, Lao PDR, Myanmar, & Viet Nam

93
94
REFERENCES:
1) ASEAN Statistics, 2007.
2) Asian Development Bank (ADB). Asian Development Outlook, 2000 and
Preceding Issues. New York & Oxford: Oxford University Press.
3) Associated Press. “Foreign Investment in Burma Dominated by Oil, Gas,
Power.” November 27, 2007.
4) Associated Press. “Foreign Investment in Burma Dominated by Oil, Gas,
Power.” Nov. 27, 2007.
5) ADB. Key Indicators of Developing Asian & Pacific Countries, Volume XXVI,
1995. New York & Oxford University Press, 1996.
6) Abel, Andrew B. and Bernanke, Ben S. Macroeconomics, Fifth Edition. 2005.
7) Altsean Key Issues – Economy.
http://www.altsean.org/Key%20Issues/KeyIssuesEconomy.htm
8) Barnes, William. “Burma in General Disarray; Reform Falls Victim to Military
Junta’s off-the-cuff Policy Decisions.” South China Morning Post, June 28,
1999.
9) Black, Michael and Couchaux, William. World Politics Watch: “Myanmar
finds willing arms suppliers in energy-hungry neighbors.” January 2007.
10) Boot, William. “China’s Burma Trade Soars with ‘Cooperative Ties.’”
Irrawaddy: Weekly Business Roundup. December 2007.
11) Bowman, Vicky. “ The Burmese Patient”, mimeo, August 2006
12) Bradford, Wylie. “Purchasing Power Parity (PPP) Estimates for Burma.”
Burma Economic Watch. 2004.
13) “Burma in general disarray; Reform falls victim to military junta's off-the -cuff
policy decisions” South China Morning Post (Hong Kong), June 28, 1999.
14) Central Statistical Organization (CSO), Report of 1997, Household Income &
Expenditure Survey, Yangon: 1999.
15) Cherian, Thomas. “Asian Leaders, Seeking Myanmar’s Gas, May Go Soft on
Sanctions.” Bloomberg. Wednesday November 21, 2007.
16) CIA Factbook. 2007
17) Central Statistical Organization (CSO), Report of 2001, Household Income &
Expenditure Survey, Yangon: 2003.
18) Dow Jones Newswire.
19) FTUB Compiled Wage Data, 2007
20) Hausmann, Ricardo. “A New Approach to Economic Reform,” Finance &
Development, March 2006.
21) Jagan, Larry. Asia Times: “Fuel price policy explodes in Burma.” Thursday
August 23, 2007.
22) Jagan, Larry. “Economic Reform in Burma?” The Daily Star (Bangladesh).
Tue 22 August, 2006.
23) Kudo, Toshikiro. Discussion Paper 38: “Stunted and Distorted
Industrialization in Myanmar.” Institute of Developing Economies. October,
2005.
24) Maung, U Zaw Win. “The Government of the Union of Myanmar.” ASEAN
Statistical Classification Workshop Hanoi, Vietnam. 10-14 June, 2002.

95
25) MRT.Team. " Exchange rate between the US $ & Kyats. 1913 -1999", 2002.
26) Mya Than & Joseph L. H. Tan, (ed), Myanmar Dilemmas & Options: The
Challenge of Economic Transition in the 1990s, Singapore, Institute of
Southeast Asian Studies, 1990.
27) Mya Than 2005. Average monthly household income of kyats 10,000 is used for
separating the two groups.
28) Myanmar Time News Vol.18, No.350
29) Myanmar Industrial Development Committee, Industrial Development of
Myanmar: 30 Year Plan 2001/2 – 2030/31. (Yangon, Government of Myanmar,
January 2002[in Burmese])
30) The Myanmar Times, July 19- 25, 2004, August 28 – September 3, 2006.
31) Mya Than, Myanmar in ASEAN: Regional Cooperation Experience,
Singapore: Institute of Southeast Asian Studies, 2005.
32) Myat Thein, Economic Development of Myanmar: Singapore, Institute of
Southeast Asian Studies, 2004.
33) Myat Thein, “An Analysis of Current Economic Situation in Myanmar”,
mimeo. June 2005.
34) Myat Thein, “Improving Domestic Resource Mobilization in Myanmar”, ISEA
Working Papers, Economics & Finance No. 1 (99), January 1999.
35) Myat Thein & Mya Than, “ Transitional Economy of Myanmar: Performance,
Issues & Problems”, In Seiji Finch Naya & Joseph L.H. Tan edited, Asian
Transitional Economies: Challenges & Prospects for Reform &
Transformation, Singapore: Institute of Southeast Asian Studies, 1995.
36) Myat Thein, “Pattern of Household Consumption Expenditure”, A Rejoinder,
mimeo. 5 October 2003.
37) Myat Thein,” Exchange Rate Movements & other Matters”, mimeo, June 2004.
38) Myint , U, “Myanmar Economy: A Comparative View”, mimeo, July 2006.
39) Ng Chee Yuen & Sueo Sudo edited, Developmemt Trends in the Asia – Pacific,
Singapore: Institute of Southeast Asian Studies, 1991.
40) Oehlers, Alfred. “Sanctions and Burma: Revisiting the Case Against.” Burma
Economic Watch, 2004.
41) Special Report: “Ready, Aim, Sanction.” ALTSEAN, November 2003.
42) Shwe, U. H.: Country paper on Myanmar. Presented to an ILO/ARPLA/Turin
Centre Regional Seminar on Labour Administration for Urban Informal Sector.
Yogyaharta, Indonesia, February 4-8 1991.
43) Vicky Bowman, “The Burmese Patient.” Mimeo. August 2006.
44) Watkins,Thayer." Political and Economics - History of Burma", San Jose State
University. Retrieved on 2006.2007.

96
List of abbreviations

ADB Asian Development Bank


AP Associated Press
ASEAN Association of Southeast Asian Nations
CIA Central Intelligence Agency
CLMV Cambodia, Laos, Myanmar, Vietnam
CPI Consumer Price Index
CPEs Centrally Planned Economies
CSO Central Statistical Organization, - Burma, - India
ESCAP Economic & Social Commission for Asia & the Pacific
EIU Economist Intelligent Unit
FAO Food and Agricultural Organization
FDI Foreign Direct Investment
FEC Foreign Exchange Certificate
FERA Foreign Exchange Regulation Act
FTUB Federation of Trade Unions Burma
GDP Gross Domestic Product
GOM Government of Myanmar
ICG International Crisis Group
ILO International Labor Organization
IMF International Monetary Fund
ISEAS Institute of Southeast Asian Studies
Ks Kyats – Myanmar Currency Notes/Unit
MEB Myanmar Economic Bank
MFTB Myanmar Foreign Trade Bank
MICB Myanmar Investment Commercial Bank
MNCs Multinational Corporations
MOGE Myanmar Oil and Gas Enterprise
NCUB National Council of Union of Burma
NIEs Newly Industrializing Economies
PPP Purchasing Power Parity
SLORC State Law and Order Restoration Council
SPDC State Peace & Development Council
(A brutal military dictatorship)
UMEHL Union of Myanmar Economic Holding Limited
UMFCCI Union of Myanmar Federation of
Chamber of Commerce & Industry
UN United Nations
UNCTAD United Nations Conference on Trade & Development
UNDP United Nations Development Programme
UNICEF United Nations Children & Education Fund
WB World Bank
WHO World Health Organization
WTO World Trade Organization

97
98
Prepared by - Aung Thin
B. Econ (CS), Dip. Ag. Econ (Aus), M.Phil (Economics)
rangsi24@yahoo.com

David Osolnick
Researcher on Trade in the US & Developing Countries.
dosolnick@gmail.com

Language Editor - Ian Hollingworth


Trade Unionist UK
ianh68h@yahoo.co.uk

Publisher - Maung Maung


General Secretary of NCUB
General Secretary of FTUB
gensec@ncub.org

Layout - Khun Kyaw Ko Thet


kyawkothet@yahoo.com

www.ncub.org
www.ftub.org

Das könnte Ihnen auch gefallen