Sie sind auf Seite 1von 35

Tax and Spending Limits:

Theory, Analysis, and Policy

by Barry W. Poulson
Professor of Economics
University of Colorado at Boulder

IP-2-2004
January, 2004

14142 Denver West Parkway • Suite 185 • Golden, Colorado 80401-3119


www.IndependenceInstitute.org • 303-279-6536 • 303-279-4176 fax
Executive Summary

This study surveys the literature on tax and spending will redistribute income from those who paid the
limits (TELs). The recent literature includes more excess taxes to those benefiting from government
rigorous econometric analysis, and more thorough spending. Special interest groups are often success-
case studies of TELs in individual states. These stud- ful in earmarking revenue that is then exempt from
ies provide important insights into the design and the TEL limit and used finance expenditures ben-
implementation of TELs. efiting their constituents

Recent empirical studies support the ‘public choice’ Some TELs mandate tax cuts and tax rebates when
view that budget institutions significantly affect fiscal revenue exceeds the TEL limit. One approach
policy. TELs, as well as other budget rules, can sig- would return the surplus revenue to those who paid
nificantly reduce state and local spending. However, the excess taxes. Rarely is this achieved; the tax cuts
decision makers must pay attention to the design of and tax rebates have the effect of redistributing
TELs if they are to have a significant impact in con- income from those who paid the excess taxes to oth-
straining government spending. The most effective ers who may have paid little or no taxes.
TELs are ones that:
a. are constitutional rather than statutory Some economists have explored case studies of
b. limit the growth of government spending to TELs in individual states. In each of these cases we
inflation and population growth rather than find evidence that political and legal institutions
other aggregate measures of economic activity have eroded the effectiveness of TELs. In some
c. provide for immediate refunds of surplus rev- states this influence was apparent in the original
enue above the TEL limit design of a weak and ineffective TEL. In other
d. are linked to other budget rules, most impor- states erosion in the effectiveness of the TEL was
tantly to balanced budget requirements. the result of legislative actions and court decisions
that weakened various provisions of the TEL.
Budget rules also affect the way that states respond
to revenue shortfalls by cutting expenditures and/or The next generation of TELs is designed to achieve
raising taxes. States with TELs experience lower tax an optimum tradeoff between constraining the
increases in periods of recession than states without growth of government and stabilizing government
TELs. budgets over the business cycle. These TELs link
a stringent tax and spending limit to a budget sta-
State response to a deficit is also affected by the bilization fund. New TELs embodying elements of
general fund balance. The general fund balance is this design have now been proposed in half a dozen
a broad measure of the total reserves available to states in recent years.1 A model TEL with this design
stabilize the budget. States with low general fund is included as an appendix to this study.
balances must make larger spending cuts in response
to budget deficits. In some states these reserves are
allocated to a budget stabilization. There is also evi-
dence that tax increases as a fraction of the deficit
are larger in states with low general fund balances.

When surplus revenue is generated above the TEL


limit some states simply return the revenue to the
general fund to finance expenditures. The allocation
of surplus revenue to finance government spending

Page 1
I. INTRODUCTION responded differently to deficits in their budgets:
some states cut spending; other states raised taxes;
Tax and spending limits (TELs) are budgetary rules and a few states, such as California, have accumulat-
that determine how much taxes and/or expenditures ed debt of a magnitude greater than that which has
can increase from one year to the next. TELs can occurred in any previous recession. Sorting out the
be statutory or constitutional rules. Statutory TELs impact of TELs and other budget rules as an expla-
can be modified by legislative action, while constitu- nation for the different response of states to revenue
tional TELs can only be modified by a majority vote shortfalls has emerged as a major research question.
of citizens. TELs may originate through a legislative
statute or referendum, or they may be initiated by In this study we will survey the literature on TELs.
citizens in states that provide for this form of direct The recent literature includes more rigorous econo-
democracy. metric analysis, and more thorough case studies of
TELs in individual states. These studies provide
TELs are now in place in 26 states (Rafool 1996). important insights into the design and implementa-
Empirical evidence indicates that well designed tion of TELs.
TELs impose fiscal discipline on elected officials;
poorly designed TELs do not. TELs introduced The most comprehensive survey of this literature
through citizen initiatives tend to be better designed was that conducted by James Poterba (1994). In that
than TELs developed by elected officials. The most survey Poterba explored the fiscal impact of a wide
effective TELs are ones that are constitutional, range of budget rules and institutions, including
that limit the growth of government TELs. His survey included international, national,
spending to inflation and popula- and state experience with budget rules. Poterba con-
At least some
tion growth, and that provide for cluded that budget rules do affect fiscal policy, how-
states with TELs
immediate refunds of surplus rev- ever, he reached an agnostic conclusion regarding
appear to have
enue to the citizens who paid the the impact of specific rules such as TELs:
been more suc-
excess taxes. TELs are most effective
cessful than other
when linked to other budget rules, “ The existing evidence is not refined enough, how-
states without
most importantly to balanced budget ever, to provide detailed advice on how narrowly
TELs in con-
requirements. However, the available defined changes in budget rules might affect policy
straining the
evidence indicates that political and outcomes.”(Poterba 1996: Abstract)
growth of
legal institutions can (and have) erod-
government.
ed the effectiveness of TELs through Poterba’s conclusion reflected the narrow and lim-
legislation and court decisions. ited scope of research on TELs a decade ago. Most
empirical studies lumped TELs together as a single
Two recent developments have stimulated renewed homogeneous fiscal constraint, and then proceeded
interest in TELs in the U.S. The first is divergence to test whether they had a significant impact in con-
in levels and long-term rates of growth in state straining the growth of government. The literature
revenue and spending in the states. At least some on TELs focused almost exclusively on the impact
states with TELs appear to have been more success- these budget rules have in constraining the growth
ful than other states without TELs in constraining of government. However, TELs have much broader
the growth of government. Whether or not this fis- impacts about which we knew very little.
cal discipline is a result of the impact of TELs has
been the subject of a large and growing empirical Research on TELs over the past decade has
literature. The second development is the diverging explored a wider range of issues, including:
response of the states to the revenue shortfalls that
have accompanied the recent recession. States have

Page 2
A. The Political Economy of TELs D. The Impact of TELs on Governance

Anyone familiar with TELs is aware of the complex From the outset, when TELs were first introduced
issues of political economy that have influenced the to constrain local property taxes, people worried
design and implementation of these budget rules.2 that the financing of government programs would be
Beyond the complexities of the TEL legislation shifted to the state. When states began introducing
itself, are the institutions that have influenced the TELs, people worried that the tax burden would be
implementation of TELs. Even the most stringently shifted to local governments. Most TELs contain
designed TEL will have little fiscal impact if the leg- provisions precluding states from mandating local
islature and the courts do not enforce the provisions government functions without providing the financ-
of the TEL. ing to support those functions. This issue of the
impact of TELs on fiscal federalism and the rela-
B. The Impact of TELs on State Budgets Over the tions of local, state, and federal government remains
Business Cycle largely unexplored.

Most states have mandated growth in state expen- As this brief introduction suggests, the reader
ditures for education K-12, Medicaid, and prisons. should not expect a synthesis of a well-developed
If the TEL ratchets down the revenue the state can literature; but rather a discussion of conceptual and
spend during a recession, the only way to satisfy theoretical issues, a review of the relevant empirical
these mandates is to drastically reduce spending analysis and case studies, and an exploration of pol-
in other state programs, such as higher education, icy issues. We conclude with a summary of recom-
transportation, and social welfare. The combination mendations in designing and implementing a TEL,
of an effective TEL and mandated growth in state and an appendix with a model TEL that embodies
expenditures may result in a structural deficit in the these recommendations.
budget in the long run.
II. THEORETICAL ISSUES
C. The Impact of TELs on the Distribution of
Income Underlying every study of TELs is a theory of gov-
ernment, whether that theory is made explicit or not.
When TELs do impact revenue and expenditures In his literature survey Poterba contrasted the ‘insti-
they will have direct and indirect impacts on the tutional irrelevance’ view with the ‘public choice’
distribution of income. The direct impact occurs perspective of budget rules. In the ‘institutional
when surplus revenue is returned to taxpayers in irrelevance’ view, TELs, as well as other budget
tax rebates and tax cuts. Some TELs require that rules, have no impact on fiscal policy. The problem
these tax rebates and tax cuts be in some propor- from this perspective is the interdependent nature of
tion to the excess taxes paid. However, some TELs budget rules. Riker (1980), for example, maintains
leave wide discretion to the legislature, which that all political institutions result from the prefer-
opens opportunities for privilege seeking through ences of the electorate. ‘Institutional irrelevance’
targeted tax rebates and tax cuts to benefit special means that the institutional structure of a nation or
interests. Indirect effects of TELs on the distribu- state contains no information beyond the aggregate
tion of income occur through budgetary changes as of information of voter preferences. If institutions
some state programs expand and others contract in no longer suit the majority of the electorate they will
response to the constraints imposed by the TEL. be overcome.

From this ‘institutional irrelevance’ perspective,


states with TELs may be ones with a conservative

Page 3
electorate that would have constrained revenue and level this bias may result in excessive ratcheting up
spending, even in the absence of the TEL. On the of government revenue and spending over the busi-
other hand, some states with TELs may have a more ness cycle. Faced with a revenue shortfall, states
profligate electorate that will find ways to evade and frequently increase taxes in order to balance the
avoid the constraints imposed by the TEL. In either budget. The higher taxes then generate higher reve-
case TELs, as well as other budget rules, are nothing nue growth as the economy recovers from recession,
more than a summary statement of voter prefer- ratcheting up revenue and spending in the long run.
ences. Some econometric studies have attempted to
resolve this interdependence problem, as discussed In the ‘public choice’ view, TELs and
later in this paper. other budget rules can provide a fis- In the ‘public
cal discipline that constrains the dis- choice’ view,
In contrast to the ‘institutional irrelevance’ view, cretion of decision makers, offsetting TELs and other
some economists argue that TELs and other bud- the bias toward expansionary govern- budget rules can
get rules are exogenous. The leading group of ment inherent in the democratic pro- provide a fis-
economists identified with this view are referred cess. Different ‘public choice’ models cal discipline
to as ‘public choice’ economists.3 They point to the are designed to capture this fiscal that constrains
durability of many of these budgetary institutions. decision process in a democratic the discretion of
For example, every state but one, Maine, has a writ- society. We will explore the design of decision makers,
ten constitution requiring a balanced budget. These TELs using several of these ‘public offsetting the bias
balanced budget rules emerged from constitutional choice’ models. toward expan-
conventions in which, as Buchanan and Wagner sionary govern-
(1977) argue, citizens believed in the ‘old time fiscal A. Leviathan Model of TELs ment inherent in
religion’ of balanced budgets. Politicians have often the democratic
found ways to circumvent these balanced budget Most studies that test the impact of process.
rules in the short run, but they have tended not to TELs implicitly assume a Leviathan
violate them in the long run. There has been no model of state government. In the
attempt to rescind balanced budget rules in the way Leviathan model, introduced by Brennan and
that TELs have been rescinded in some states. TELs Buchannan (1980) TELs are viewed as part of the
are more recent budgetary rules that have emerged social contract. Politicians are assumed to maximize
from a different decision process. Nonetheless, we revenue and expenditures within the constraints
now have several decades of experience with TELs, imposed by TELs.
and in some states they are acquiring an acceptance
and durability of their own. Even a cursory look at the experience with TELs
in different states reveals a more complex decision
From this ‘public choice’ perspective, TELs and process than that assumed in the Leviathan model.
other budget rules can have significant impacts on The design and implementation of TELs reflects
fiscal policy. Further, ‘public choice’ economists interaction between citizens, special interest groups,
challenge the view that social planners are capable and politicians. Some economists have attempted to
of designing optimum tax and expenditure policies capture this more complex decision process in other
over the business cycle as well as in the long run. ‘public choice’ models.
Their assumption is that the democratic decision
process may inherently bias fiscal policy. In the long B. Median Voter Model of TELs
run a bias toward excessive spending may result in
too much growth in government. This is especially Some models attempt to capture the response of
true at the national level where government can politicians to different influences. One approach is
incur deficits and accumulate debt. At the state based upon the median voter principle: the median

Page 4
voter is defined such that he equates his value of an Politicians may also co-opt TELs in order to benefit
additional public service with the tax price of that one interest group at the expense of other interest
service (Flowers 1997; Sjonquist 1981, and Chicoine groups (Spindler 1990). The constraints imposed
and Walzer 1986). In a median voter model politi- by TELs rarely impact interest groups uniformly.
cians support TELs when at least a majority of citi- The TEL limits may be imposed on a subset of state
zens incur net benefits from the TEL. expenditures, but not on other expenditures. Some
interest groups may be successful in earmarking
C. Rent Seeking Model of TELs revenue used to finance their expenditures, shift-
ing those revenues outside the TEL limit. In effect
An alternative approach is based on the assump- these interest groups are removed from the rent
tion that a self- interested politician will attempt to seeking battles that accompany the budget process.
minimize the political costs associated with raising a Politicians can appear to be fiscally prudent in sup-
given budget or revenue (Hettich and Winer 1984). porting TELs, when in fact they are benefiting rent
In these models taxpayers are on opposite sides of seeking groups.
the budget constraint from special interest groups.
In the ‘public choice’ literature privilege seeking by The ability of rent seeking groups to protect what
these special interest groups is referred to as rent they perceive as their entitlements to rents depends
seeking, and models designed to capture this privi- upon the response of politicians. The special interest
lege seeking are called rent seeking models. To the effect occurs when politicians pursue policies that
extent that taxpayers can impose costs on profligate benefit special interests at the expense of the public
politicians we would expect TELs to be designed interest. Politicians may design TELs that are weak
and implemented to impose a stringent budget con- and ineffective in constraining the fiscal powers of
straint. government. Even with a well-designed TEL, politi-
cians may successfully evade or erode these fiscal
Some TELs are constitutional amendments that constraints to permit a more rapid growth in rev-
originate through the citizen initiative process. Such enue and spending.4
TELs tend to impose more stringent constraints on
the fiscal powers of government than statutory TELs Once we recognize that TELs emerge from a com-
that emerge from a legislative decision process. In plex decision process involving citizens, special inter-
either case it is unrealistic to assume that rent seek- est groups, and politicians, the impact of TELs on
ing groups will simply sit back and accept new rules fiscal policy is uncertain. If there is a bias toward
of the game designed to limit their rent seeking excessive levels of revenue and spending over the
activities. We expect rent seeking groups to become business cycle and in the long run, then TELs have
actively involved in the design and implementation the potential to enhance the welfare of citizens. A
of TELs in order to protect what they perceive to be TEL can be designed and implemented to constrain
their entitlements to such rents. the growth of government in the long run. TELs
may also be designed to provide for greater stability
We expect self interested politicians to respond of government budgets over the business cycle.
to rent seeking groups in the design of TELs.
Politicians may design a TEL which is completely On the other hand, TELs may be designed and
ineffective in constraining government revenue and implemented that have little impact on fiscal policy.
expenditure. They can appear to be fiscally prudent At worse, poorly designed TELs can result in ineffi-
to appease taxpayer groups, when in fact they intro- ciencies and inequities in fiscal policies that diminish
duce a weak and ineffective TEL to preempt a more the welfare of citizens.
stringent TEL from being introduced through citi-
zen initiative.

Page 5
III. EMPIRICAL ANALYSIS get stabilization fund to provide greater stability to
revenues and expenditures over the business cycle,
Most empirical studies have focused on the issue of and to limit the ratchet down effect in the long run.
TELs as constraints on government revenues and This combination of a TEL and budget stabilization
expenditures. This is consistent with the perception fund permits citizens to achieve an optimum trad-
that TELs are designed and implemented to impose eoff between stabilizing the budget over the business
fiscal discipline on governments. However, it is not cycle and constraining the growth of government in
always clear what is meant by fiscal discipline. the long run.

Some people might argue that fiscal discipline Whether or not we perceive TELs to have been suc-
means decreasing the absolute size of government. cessful in constraining the growth of government
Indeed a recent failed TEL initiative in Colorado depends upon what we mean by fiscal discipline.
called for decreasing the absolute size of local gov- With this caveat in mind we turn to the empirical lit-
ernment by a fixed dollar amount each year. erature that has attempted to answer this question.

Others might argue that TELs are designed to A. TELs as Constraints on Government Revenue
constrain the growth of government. Few would and Spending
disagree that an effective TEL should hold the
growth of government below the double digit rates A number of studies have tested whether TELs con-
of increase in revenue and spending that occurred strain government revenue and spending. The wide
during the inflationary period of the 1970’s. It was divergence in the results of these empirical studies
that inflationary expansion, in which government at reflects the use of different methodologies and data
all levels increased relative to the private sector, that sets. Early empirical studies focused on different
triggered the tax revolt, with TELs designed to con- political units, and analyzed the impact of TELs
strain the growth of local and state government. over different time periods.

If fiscal discipline is interpreted to mean constrain- Cross section studies of the impact of TELs on state
ing the growth of government relative to the private and local spending tended to find TELs ineffective
sector, then tax and spending limits may be linked in constraining government spending. Bails (1983)
to a measure of aggregate economic activity such as conducted one of the earliest cross section studies
state income. The problem with these TELs is that and found that in the majority of states TELs had an
they permit a rapid growth in government in peri- insignificant impact on state spending. An extension
ods of prosperity that cannot be sustained when the of this work essentially confirmed this finding (Bails
economy enters a recession with falling revenues. As 1990). Cross section studies by Abrams and Dougan
noted earlier, such TELs may result in a ratcheting (1986) and Cox and Lawry (1990) also found TELs
up of government spending over time, if govern- to be ineffective in constraining state spending.
ments respond to falling revenues by increasing
taxes. Time series studies have found mixed results for the
impact of TELs on state and local spending. A study
A more stringently designed TEL is linked to infla- by Kenyon and Benker (1984) compared the growth
tion and population growth. In the long run this type of state spending relative to personal income in TEL
of TEL has the potential to constrain the growth states with that in non TEL states and found no sig-
of government below the growth of the private sec- nificant difference. A study by Dougan (1988) exam-
tor. The criticism of this type of TEL is a ratchet ined time series data from 1960 to 1984 for 16 states.
down effect as revenue falls in periods of recession. He found that in 7 of these states the TEL had a
However, this type of TEL can be linked to a bud- significant negative impact on government spending.

Page 6
Poulson and Kaplan (1994) used time series analysis impact state spending. More recent empirical stud-
to examine the impact of Colorado’s first statutory ies use panel data, cross sectional time series data,
TEL, and found that it significantly reduced state which can produce more reliable estimates because
spending in the short run, but not in the long run. they include other variables besides TELs that can
Joyce and Mullins (1991) also found evidence that influence government revenue and spending. For
TELs significantly reduce state revenues in the short example empirical evidence suggests that govern-
run, but not the long run. ment expenditure, in both levels and growth rates,
is closely related to income, population, and other
One of the problems in all of these empirical stud- economic variables.
ies is that they do not account for the interdepen-
dent nature of TELs. If states that experience rapid One of the first studies to utilize panel data control-
increases in spending are more likely to adopt TELs, ling for the effects of population and income on
then the empirical analysis of the impact of TELs on the public sector is a study by Elders (1992). Elders
state spending will be biased. A few empirical stud- found that when he controls for the effects of these
ies have addressed this interdependence problem. economic variables, TELs have a significant effect in
reducing the growth of government.
One approach to this problem is to control for some
measure of voter preference, such as the political Shadbegian (1996) also uses panel data to test the
party of elected officials. This can reduce the pro- impact of TELs on the size and growth of state
clivity that observed correlation between budget government. He includes three control variables,
rules and fiscal outcomes simply reflects correlation population, income, and federal intergovernmental
between these variables and an omitted variable for grants. Shadbegian finds that TELs reduce the size
voter preferences. But, if this approach does not of government, and lower government spending
fully capture the impact of voter preferences it may growth in states with low income growth. However,
still lead to spurious results. he finds that TELs increase government spending
growth in states with high income growth. In states
An alternative approach to this problem is to solve with high income growth TELs provide cover for
for interdependence using variables that affect bud- politicians who appear to be fiscally prudent, but
get rules but not fiscal policy. Reubens (1995) uses who in fact are increasing government spending
this approach to estimate the impact of TELs. In more than their counterparts in states without TELs.
some states, laws provide for the initiative process
that allows citizens to directly propose and vote on A criticism of all the studies mentioned above is that
TELs. These laws should be positively correlated they treat all TELs alike. The only study to take into
with the passage of TELs, but unrelated to current account differences in TELs is that of New (2001).
expenditure levels. Substituting this variable for New uses panel data to analyze the impact of TELs
the TEL variable in her model enables Reubens to on the level of state and local spending. As in other
separate the effects of the TEL from the effects of panel data studies he controls for other economic
changes in voter preferences for TELs. When this and demographic variables that could impact state
model is run with the TEL variable the results show and local spending. He includes variables indicat-
a positive relationship between TELs and govern- ing whether the TEL was passed by initiative, by
ment spending. When the model is run using the ini- the legislature, by constitutional convention, or by
tiative variable the effect of the TELs is to reduce referendum. He finds that TELs passed through
state spending 1.8%. the initiative process significantly reduce state and
local spending; but, TELs enacted by state legisla-
Another criticism of these empirical studies is that tures actually increase spending. Further, he finds
they do not account for other variables that could that states in which TELs limit increases in revenue

Page 7
and spending to the sum of inflation and popula- enue above the TEL limit. TELs are most effective
tion growth, i.e. Colorado and Washington, reduce when linked to other budget rules, most importantly
government spending more than states in which the to balanced budget requirements.
TEL limit is linked to state personal income. Finally,
he finds that states in which the TEL mandates B. TELS and Budget Stabilization Over the
immediate refunds of surplus revenue to taxpayers, Business Cycle
i.e. Colorado, Michigan, Missouri, and Oregon, are
more successful in reducing government spending. When Governor Owens of Colorado recently
encouraged Governor Schwarzenegger of California
A study by Bails and Tieslau (2000) is unique in to adopt a TEL, he argued that this would enable
using panel data to analyze the impact of a compre- him to stabilize the state budget over the business
hensive set of budget institutions on state and local cycle (Owens 2003). Owens maintained that the
spending. These include; tax and spending limits, TABOR Amendment limited increases in govern-
line item veto, balanced budget requirements, and ment revenue and spending in the 1990’s, so that it
term limits. As in other panel data studies they con- was easier for Colorado to cope with the revenue
trol for other economic and demographic variables. shortfalls in the current recession. When California
They find that the following budgetary institutions essentially abandoned their TEL in the late 1980’s
significantly reduce the rate of growth of state and this permitted unconstrained growth in revenue and
local spending: tax and spending limits, balanced spending to unsustainable levels in the 1990’s. The
budget requirements in the presence of tax and question raised by this exchange between Governor
spending limits, supermajority vote Owens and Governor Schwarzenegger is whether
The most effective requirements in the presence of bal- states with effective TELs have been subject to less
TELs are ones anced budget requirements, term volatility in revenues and spending over the business
that are constitu- limits, and the initiative process. Real cycle compared to states without effective TELs.
tional, that limit per capita state and local spending This question remains largely unexplored in the lit-
the growth of gov- in states with TELs, is estimated to erature.
ernment spend- be $42 lower than in states without
ing to inflation TELs. In states with both TELs and One of the few studies to analyze this question is
and population balanced budget requirements spend- a study by Poterba (1994) that explores how states
growth, and that ing is reduce by nearly $135. In states adjust their budgets to unexpected shocks. Poterba’s
provide for imme- with the comprehensive budgetary approach is to measure how changes in state spend-
diate refunds of institutions tested, they find that real ing and taxes are influenced by fiscal institutions.
surplus revenue per capita expenditures are reduced He examines the impact of balanced budget rules,
above the TEL nearly $473. TELs, and general fund balances. Most state con-
limit. stitutions prevent state governments from running
Thus, recent empirical studies support deficits. After a budget is passed, however, actual
the public choice view that budget revenues and expenditures may deviate from pro-
institutions significantly affect fiscal policy. TELs, as jections, resulting in unexpected deficits. States
well as other budget rules, can significantly reduce differ in the stringency of balanced budget rules
state and local spending. Decision makers must pay that require elimination of the deficit. Some states
attention to the design of TELs if they are to have require elimination of the deficit in the current fis-
a significant impact in constraining government cal year; while others allow the deficit to be carried
spending. The most effective TELs are ones that are forward into the next fiscal year; and a few states do
constitutional, that limit the growth of government not require the deficit to be eliminated in the fol-
spending to inflation and population growth, and lowing fiscal year.
that provide for immediate refunds of surplus rev-

Page 8
To offset deficits states may draw down their gen- affect the level of government spending remains an
eral fund balances or rainy day funds. Most states open question.
allow borrowing to offset the deficit. In some states
the borrowing must be repaid in the current fiscal C. TELs and the Distribution of Income
year; while others allow the debt to be repaid in the
following fiscal year, but prevent the use of long A fuller understanding of TELs would extend the
term debt to cover the deficit. In the short run, of analysis to their impact to income distribution.
course, states may rely upon a variety of budgetary When surplus revenue is generated above the TEL
gimmicks to satisfy balanced budget rules: deferring limit some states simply return the revenue to the
expenditures to the following fiscal year, altering the general fund to finance expenditures. In some states
fiscal year, raiding cash and trust funds, etc. the surplus is held in a general fund balance. When
that general fund balance is used to finance a budget
Poterba explores how states respond to revenue stabilization fund then the moneys are expended
shortfalls that accompany recessions. He finds that during revenue shortfalls. In some cases the general
states with TELs experienced lower fund balances are used to finance targeted expendi-
tax increases in periods of recession tures such as education or capital expenditures. As
... states with than states without TELs. In TEL we would expect from our rent-seeking model, gen-
TELs experienced states a $1 increase in the budget eral fund balances may become a target for different
lower tax increas- deficit results in a $0.47 tax increase, special interest groups. The allocation of surplus
es in periods of compared to a $1.03 tax increase in revenue to finance government spending will redis-
recession than states without TELs. He finds no tribute income from those who paid the excess taxes
states without evidence that spending cuts are any to those benefiting from government spending.
TELs. larger in states with TELs.
One of the least understood aspects
Poterba also explores how a state of TEL is the way in which they ... special inter-
response to a deficit is affected by the general fund interact with other statutory and con- est groups are
balance. In some states these reserves are allocated stitutional provisions impacting fiscal often successful
to a budget stabilization or rainy day fund. The gen- policies. As our rent-seeking model in earmarking
eral fund balance is a broader measure of the total suggests, special interest groups are revenue that is
reserves available to stabilize the budget. Poterba often successful in earmarking reve- then exempt from
finds evidence that states with low general fund bal- nue that is then exempt from the TEL the TEL limit
ances must make larger spending cuts in response to limit and used finance expenditures and used finance
budget deficits. In states with general fund balances benefiting their constituents. expenditures
of more than 2% of spending, spending is reduced benefiting their
by $0.25 per dollar of deficit. In states with lower Some TELs mandate tax cuts and constituents.
general fund balances, the spending cuts are more tax rebates when revenue exceeds
than double, $0.55 per dollar of deficit. There is also the TEL limit. One approach would
some evidence that tax increases as a fraction of the return the surplus revenue to those who paid the
deficit are larger in states with low general fund bal- excess taxes. Rarely is this achieved; the tax cuts
ances. and tax rebates have the effect of redistributing
income from those who paid the excess taxes to
Poterba finds that fiscal institutions do affect the others who may have paid little or no taxes. One
way that states respond to revenue shortfalls by cut- of the few studies to explore how tax cuts and tax
ting expenditures and/or raising taxes. However, he rebates impact the distribution of income is Poulson
concludes that the question of how fiscal institutions (1999 and 2001). He finds that in Colorado surplus
revenue above the TABOR limit was not offset by

Page 9
tax cuts and tax rebates that returned the surplus to rather than leaving fiscal decisions to the discretion
those who paid the excess taxes. Most of the surplus of their elected representatives. Surveys often reveal
revenue was generated by the income tax, and some widespread support for TELs; nonetheless, assessing
of the surplus was offset by broad based income and the costs and benefits to citizens of exercising con-
sales tax cuts. But much of the surplus was offset by trols over the fiscal powers of government through
targeted tax cuts and tax rebates benefiting special TELs remains elusive.
interest groups. The impact of this redistribution
was egalitarian, shifting surplus revenue from upper IV. CASE STUDIES
income families who paid most of the excess income
taxes, to lower income families who paid little or no Empirical studies provide important insights into
taxes. TELs. However, the effectiveness of TELs also
depends upon the unique political and legal institu-
D. TELs and Governance tions found in each state. Our public choice models
suggest that the way in which the legislature and
A final set of issues involves the impact of TELs the courts choose to interpret and implement the
on governance. One question is the extent to which TEL is crucial. Surprisingly little research has been
TELs may erode fiscal federalism. In some states conducted into this question, and as a result it is one
TELs may be imposed at the local level but not the of the least understood aspects of TELs, especially
state level, as was the case with Prop 13 in Califonia. by economists. Analysis of the way in which political
A number of states have introduced TELs at the and legal institutions influence TELs does not lend
state level but not the local level. Other states, such itself to econometric analysis, and publication in
as Colorado, introduced TELs designed to constrain economics journal, and so economists have contrib-
fiscal policy at both the state and local level. uted very little to this question.

From the outset a major concern was that TELs Some economists have explored case studies of
imposed at one level of government would simply TELs in individual states, which are usually pub-
shift the financing of programs to another level of lished in state and national think tanks. We will
government. The obvious example is education K- review case studies for several states including:
12 which is often financed from revenues received California, Missouri, Florida, Washington, Michigan,
by both state and local government. Some TELs and Colorado. In each of these cases we find evi-
address this issue by limiting the power of the state dence that political and legal institutions have erod-
to mandate expenditures at the local level without ed the effectiveness of TELs. In some states, such as
financing those expenditures. Florida, this influence was apparent in the original
design of a weak and ineffective TEL. In other
Satisfying the conditions imposed by TELs requires states erosion in the effectiveness of the TEL was
new administrative procedures. For example, when the result of legislative actions and court decisions
TELs require voter approval for increase in taxes that weakened various provisions of the TEL.
and debt, this requires new accounting, reporting,
and election procedures. Litigation surrounding A. California5
TELs may require additional legal resources. These
administrative procedures may be costly, particularly The origins of the tax revolt can be traced to the
for local governments with limited resources. Gubernatorial Administration of Ronald Reagan
in California in the early 1970s. Reagan’s Prop1 set
The costs and other burdens of TELs must be the standard for all subsequent TELs. Prop 1 set a
weighed against the benefits to citizens in exercising limit on state spending equal to the current ratio of
control over fiscal powers of government directly state expenditures as a share of state income, and

Page 10
required that percentage to decrease by .1% each TEL limited the growth in state revenue to the rate
year until it reached 7%, at which time the legis- of increase in personal income. Tax revenue was to
lature (by two thirds vote) could halt the annual be held constant as a share of personal income, with
reduction. To give some idea how stringent this surplus revenue rebated to taxpayers based on state
original TEL was, total spending as a share of state income taxes.
income in California today is approaching 10%.
While Prop 1 lost at the polls in 1973, it launched a The Hancock Amendment was never an effective
tax revolt in California that resulted in initiatives to constraint on the growth of revenue and spen-
introduce TELs at both the local and state level. ding, and no tax rebates were ever made under the
Amendment. The reason is that legislators, aided by
Prop 13 to limit local property taxes wan enacted in the courts, were able to successfully evade and avoid
1978. Prop 13 continues to be one of the most strin- the limits imposed by the Amendment. Legislators
gent limitations on local property taxation in the exempted an increasing share of revenue from the
country. limit. Initially, only 2% of revenue was exempt from
the limit; but a decade later 18% was exempt. Over
Prop 4, the Gann Amendment, that period state revenue grew far in excess of perso-
In 1990 the
was one of the first TELs adopted nal income; in some years the growth in revenue was
Gann amend-
by any state. The Gann amend- more than double the growth in personal income.
ment was dealt a
ment limited increases in state
death blow when
and local appropriations from tax Experience in Missouri demonstrates how the legis-
Prop 111 was
revenues to the sum of population lature and the courts can erode the effectiveness
enacted manda-
growth and inflation. The Gann of a TEL. The Missouri legislature failed to enact
ting increases in
Amendment passed by nearly a enabling legislation to implement the
expenditures for
3 to 1 margin. Initially the Gann Hancock Amendment. As a result Experience in
education K-12,
Amendment was effective in con- there was never agreement on what Missouri dem-
and increasing
straining government expenditures. constituted total state revenue, nor onstrates how
the Gann limit.
In 1987, when revenue exceeded what constituted surplus revenue the legislature
the budget limit, California taxpay- above the limit. Different state agen- and the courts
ers received a $1.1 billion tax rebate. cies came up with their own conflic- can erode the
ting interpretations. effectiveness of a
Over time, however, the Gann Amendment became TEL.
less effective as a constraint on California fiscal Soon after the Hancock amendment
policy. Because the limit was imposed only on was passed the voters passed a 1%
appropriations from tax revenues, legislators relied sales tax increase; half of which was earmarked
increasingly on fees and other non-tax revenues. In for property tax reduction, and half of which was
1990 the Gann amendment was dealt a death blow earmarked for expenditures for education K-12.
when Prop 111 was enacted mandating increases in Both the Missouri Budget Office, and the State
expenditures for education K-12, and increasing the Auditors Office ruled that this earmarked revenue
Gann limit. Since then, the Gann Amendment has was not subject to the Hancock limit. Amazingly,
ceased to be an effective constraint on government the Missouri supreme Court agreed, ruling that
fiscal policy in California. this statutory tax increase preempted the revenue
limit imposed by the Missouri Constitution. Other
B. Missouri6 tax increases soon followed: the legislature enacted
a statutory motor fuel tax increase that was also
One of the first TELs introduced in the states was ruled to be exempt from the revenue limit. Other
the Hancock amendment in Missouri, in 1980. That tax increases were approved by voters with language

Page 11
that specifically excluded these revenues from the “This proposal would not affect current state or
revenue limit. Over time special interests and politi- local funds, future effects would depend upon the
cians became more adept at circumventing the reve- actions of the General Assembly and Missouri vot-
nue limit, and the courts sanctioned these acts, even ers.” (McCarty 2003:20)
when this violated the spirit if not the letter of the
constitution. In 1993 the legislature enacted another In contrast to the original Hancock Amendment,
tax increase earmarked for expenditures for educa- this new TEL has significantly reduced state revenue
tion K-12, without voter approval. Corporate taxes and spending. Since 1996 Missouri has offset $2.5
were increased, and corporations, small business, billion in surplus revenue with a combination of tax
and higher income individuals were for the first time cuts and tax rebates.
required to pay state income taxes on the federal
income taxes they paid. C. Florida7

Missouri citizens responded to this increased tax In Florida citizens in 1994 gathered enough signa-
burden by attempting to strengthen the constitu- tures to place an Amendment on the ballot requir-
tional constraints imposed on state fiscal policy. In ing voter approval for any new tax or tax increase;
1994 citizens placed on the ballot an amendment but, the Florida Supreme Court ruled that the initia-
requiring voter approval for new taxes. The opposi- tive could not be placed on the ballot because it did
tion, including the Governor and legislature, were not pass legal muster as a citizen initiative.
able to include in the ballot language the statement
that the proposed Amendment would cause: The response of the Florida Legislature to this
failed citizen initiative was to design an Amendment
“state and local spending cuts ranging from $1 bil- to preempt another citizen initiative. The legisla-
lion to $5 billion annually. Cuts would affect pris- ture placed an Amendment on the ballot to impose
ons, schools, colleges, programs for the elderly, a revenue limit linked to the growth of state per-
job training, highways, public health, and other sonal income. The growth rate of state revenue was
services.”(McCarty 2003:20) capped at a five year moving average
of state personal income growth. Two Florida legisla-
It is not surprising that the proposed Amendment provisions of that TEL would render tors appear to be
was defeated by a two to one margin. it completely ineffective as a con- fiscally prudent
straint on the growth of state govern- when in fact they
In 1996 citizens were successful in enacting a more ment in Florida. designed a TEL
stringent Amendment than the one proposed two sanctioning high-
years earlier. That Amendment requires voter One provisions excluded several com- er levels of rev-
approval for any tax increase that exceeds $50 mil- ponents of revenue from the TEL enue and spend-
lion, or one percent of state revenues, whichever cap, including: Medicaid matching ing than occurred
is less. That Amendment also requires refunds funds, charges imposed by local and before the TEL
of excess tax revenues if growth in state revenue regional governments, and debt ser- was introduced.
exceeds the growth of personal income by one per- vice.
cent or more.
A second provision maintained the growth in the
That Amendment was passed with the support of TEL cap regardless whether the cap was reached in
the new Governor, and the legislature, and the busi- the previous year. The revenue cap increases each
ness community. In contrast to the earlier proposed year with growth in personal income regardless of
Amendment this new Amendment contained the what is happening to actual revenue. As a result the
following language:

Page 12
revenue cap has not and never will constrain the The flaw in the Washington TEL was that it was
growth of state revenue and spending. a statutory rather than a constitutional provision.
Statutory TELs are no safer than the next vote of
Some have described the Florida TEL as a ‘Modern the legislature. In 2000, when the legislature wanted
Day Fairy Tale”. They maintain that the Florida to pass a budget that exceeded the TEL limit, they
Legislature deliberately designed an ineffective simply obtained the supermajority vote required to
TEL to preempt a more stringent TEL from being suspend the TEL limit. Since then the Washington
introduced through citizen initiative. Florida leg- TEL has ceased to be an effective constraint on gov-
islators appear to be fiscally prudent when in fact ernment.
they designed a TEL sanctioning higher levels of
revenue and spending than occurred before the TEL E. Michigan9
was introduced. Clearly the actions of the Florida
Legislature and Courts have left TELs as a mean- The Michigan TEL is unique in several respects.
ingless exercise in that state. The TEL is a constitutional amendment introduced
in 1978 that limits the growth of revenue to a fixed
D. Washington8 ratio of state personal income. That ratio is applied
to either personal income in the prior year, or to
Washington State joined the tax revolt in 1979 average personal income in the prior three years,
enacting a tax and spending limit through the ini- whichever is higher. When actual revenue exceeds
tiative process, Initiative 62. That Amendment the revenue limit by 1% or more, excess revenue
limited increases in state revenue to the rate of is refunded to taxpayers based on the Michigan
growth in personal income. As is often the case with income tax.
TELs linked to the growth in personal income the
Washington Tel was never an effective constraint What is unique in the Michigan TEL is the formu-
on the growth of government. In the years after the laic allocation of surplus revenue to and from a
TEL was enacted the state was able to pass a series budget stabilization or rainy day fund. When annual
of tax increases, and yet remain within the TEL personal income grows more than 2%, the percent-
limit. age in excess of 2% is multiplied by total revenue
to determine the amount to be automatically trans-
In the early 1990s citizens responded to the ferred from the general fund to the rainy day fund.
increased tax burden by passing a more stringent All general fund surpluses are also transferred into
TEL through the initiative process. the rainy day fund. Withdrawals from the rainy day
Statutory TELs Initiative 601 imposed a limit on fund are also automatic. When personal income
are no safer than the growth in state spending equal growth is less than 0%, the deficiency under 0% is
the next vote of to inflation plus population growth. multiplied by total revenue to determine the amount
the legislature. When the new TEL took effect in to be transferred from the rainy day fund to the
1996 legislation was passed to ensure general fund. The legislature can also appropriate
that spending was contained within money from the rainy day fund if unemployment
the TEL limit. Budget cuts of $120 million were rises above 8%. In an emergency the legislature can,
enacted reducing expenditures for administration, by supermajority vote, approve emergency transfers
social services, and prisons. Institutions of higher from the rainy day fund.
education were required to trim their benefits by
$39 million. In subsequent years, when revenue Just prior to the recent recession in 2000 the state
growth exceeded the limit, tax cuts were enacted had accumulated a rainy day fund of $1.2 billion,
to offset the surplus revenue. Washington citizens equal to 13.2% of state spending that year. As you
voted to repeal the motor vehicle tax. would expect with the accumulation of such a siz-

Page 13
Despite the dis-
sipation of the able rainy day fund, the fund became falls. The TABOR limit is determined by applying
rainy day fund in a target for special interest groups. the sum of inflation and population growth to actual
response to rent There is an ongoing appropriation TABOR revenues or the TABOR limit, whichever is
seeking activities from the rainy day fund over the lower. When revenue falls in a recession, that lower
by special inter- period 2000 to 2008 of $32 million for revenue then sets a new base against which the sum
est groups, it has education K-12, and $25 million for of inflation and population growth is applied.
served to stabilize water pollution control. Legislators
the Michigan have been able to transfer money The TABOR Amendment also placed a procedural
budget over the from the rainy day fund for a variety constraint on the power of government to raise
business cycle. of purposes by simply declaring an taxes. Voter approval is required for any new taxes,
emergency. tax rate increases, extension of an expiring tax, or
tax policy change directly causing a net revenue
Despite the dissipation of the rainy day fund in gain. Voter approval is also required for state and
response to rent seeking activities by special interest local government to retain and spend revenue in
groups, it has served to stabilize the Michigan bud- excess of the limit.
get over the business cycle. In the recent recession
the state was able to transfer close to $1 billion from In a failed attempt to preempt this stringent TEL
the rainy day fund to offset revenue shortfalls. from being introduced through citizen initiative the
legislature enacted a statutory TEL. In 1992 the
F. Colorado10 Arveschaugh-Bird Amendment placed a cap on gen-
eral fund appropriations equal to the lesser amount
Colorado was one of the first states to impose a stat- of 5% of Colorado personal income in the calendar
utory cap on the growth of state spending. In 1978, a year two years prior to the start of the fiscal year or
cap of 7% was placed on the growth of general fund 6% over the previous year’s general fund appropria-
expenditures. In the late 1970s some surplus revenue tion, with exceptions for federal mandates and court
above that limit was rebated to taxpayers. When orders.
recession hit in the early 1980’s Colorado, like other
states, responded by increasing taxes to balance the Over time the Legislature has interpreted the 6%
budget. That increase in taxes ratcheted up govern- statutory cap as a floor rather than a ceiling on the
ment spending at rates in excess of the growth in growth in general fund expenditures. The reason
state income in subsequent years. The Colorado is that the general fund spending in a given year
TEL, like many other statutory TELs, was simply determines the base against which the spending cap
ignored by the legislature. is applied in determining the amount of general
fund spending permitted in the following year. The
In the late 1980s citizens organized to put a more distortions this introduces in state spending have
stringent TEL on the ballot. After several failed become very evident in recent years.
attempts the TABOR Amendment was enacted in
1992 through citizen initiative. Tabor is the most For the foreseeable future the Arveschaugh-Bird
stringent TEL introduced in any state. TABOR amendment will have little if any impact on state
restricts the growth in state revenue and spending to fiscal policies. This is because the 6% limit on the
inflation plus the percentage change in state popu- growth in general fund expenditures will not be a
lation. Surplus revenue above that limit must be binding constraint on the legislature. That limit is
rebated to taxpayers. significantly above the limit
imposed by the Tabor Amendment
The TABOR limit ratchets-down the amount of
revenue the state can keep and spend as revenue
Initially the TABOR Amendment was non-binding tax cuts. Most of the TABOR surplus has been gen-
because the growth in state revenues was less than erated by the income and sales taxes; and some of
the TABOR limit. The first year in which TABOR that surplus has been offset by rebates and reduc-
became a binding constraint was 1997. Over the next tions in the income and sales taxes. However, the
five years more than $3 billion in surplus revenue increased use of targeted tax cuts and tax rebates
was either rebated to taxpayers, or offset by tax to benefit narrow interest groups means that less of
reduction. A referendum to spend a portion of the the surplus is refunded to the people who paid the
surplus revenue was defeated by taxpayers. excess taxes.

The Legislature has also chosen to interpret the A major problem emerged when a constitutional
TABOR limit as a floor rather than a provision was introduced requiring constant growth
ceiling on the revenue that the state can keep and in expenditures for education K-12 from income tax
spend. This introduces distortion and revenue earmarked for that purpose and exempt
inefficiency in state finance, and the problem has from the TABOR limit. This Amendment, which
become especially evident in the requires a constant ratcheting up of expenditures
current fiscal crises. Even if it might be prudent for for education K-12, combined with the TABOR
the Legislature to hold revenue and Amendment, which ratchets government revenue
spending growth below that permitted by the down, places the legislature in an untenable posi-
TABOR limit, the Legislature has often failed to do tion. The legislature has discretion over less than
so. one third of the state budget because more than
two thirds is mandated by the required expenditures
The Legislature has interpreted TABOR so as to for education K-12, Medicaid, and prisons. When
erode the constraints imposed by the limit, and to the recession resulted in a revenue shortfall the
exacerbate the fiscal crises resulting from the cur- legislature was required to make draconian cuts in
rent recession. The Legislature chose to retain the higher education and social services. In the long
surplus revenue generated in the current year in the run these provisions in the fiscal constitution will
general fund reserve, and to finance rebates from result in a structural deficit, which is prohibited
the surplus revenue generated in the following year. by the balanced budget provision of the Colorado
This scheme worked fine when revenues were ris- Constitution. The Colorado legislature is now con-
ing in the boom years; but the flaw in this scheme sidering changes in each of these constitutional
became apparent in the current fiscal crises. With provisions in order to avoid a future
recession the TABOR surplus disappeared, and the fiscal crises.11
state had to finance a rebate from reductions in cur- Colorado is cur-
rent state spending. The decision of the Legislature Finally, in Colorado TELs have been rently experienc-
to finance taxpayer rebates from revenues received more effective in constraining local ing the worst
in the year after the TABOR surplus is generated government than state government. fiscal crises in
has exacerbated the fiscal crises. The Legislature has The result is that financing for edu- decades.
also chosen to increase the TABOR limit to adjust cation K-12 has shifted significantly
for undercounting of population growth in the last from local government to the state
decade. This permitted the state to retain and spend government in Colorado. The Tabor Amendment
more revenue over the coming decade. requires the state to backfill local governments
whenever state legislation has a negative impact on
A different set of problems has resulted from the local government revenues. When the state enacted
way in which the legislature has chosen to offset a cut in the business personal property tax it was
surplus revenue More than 20 bills have been passed required to backfill local governments for the loss
offsetting the TABOR surplus with tax rebates and of revenue resulting from this tax cut. Despite these
provisions, the financing and administration of some periods of recession, then the TEL will do little to
programs, such as education K-12, has shifted from constrain government spending in the long run.
local government to the state govern-
While tax and ment. Thus, we can think of a tradeoff in the allocation of
spending limits surplus revenue above the TEL limit. The larger the
have been effec- Colorado is currently experiencing share of that revenue returned to taxpayers through
tive in slowing the worst fiscal crises in decades. tax cuts and tax rebates, the less of that surplus
the growth in While tax and spending limits have revenue is available to stabilize the
state government been effective in slowing the growth budget over the business cycle, and The next gen-
in the long run, in state government in the long run, the more that TEL will constrain the eration of TELs
they have not they have not been very effective in growth of government. The larger the is designed to
been very effec- smoothing the growth of state rev- share of the surplus revenue set aside achieve an opti-
tive in smoothing enue and spending over the business in a Budget Stabilization Fund the mum tradeoff
the growth of cycle. Colorado does not have a true more effective the TEL will be in off- between con-
state revenue and budget stabilization fund. The current setting revenue shortfalls, but, the less straining the
spending over the fiscal crises reveals the need for such effective it will be in constraining the growth of govern-
business cycle. revenue and expenditure smoothing growth of government in the long run. ment and stabi-
in state government during periods Understanding this tradeoff is crucial lizing government
of recession and slower economic in designing a TEL. budgets over the
growth. Legislation has been introduced in Colorado business cycle.
that would link the TABOR limit to both an emer- The next generation of TELs is
gency reserve fund, and a budget stabilization fund. designed to achieve an optimum trad-
This legislation is similar to the model TEL in the eoff between constraining the growth of government
Appendix to this study. and stabilizing government budgets over the busi-
ness cycle. One set of rules is required to introduce
IV. THE NEXT GENERATION OF TELS12 an effective brake on the revenue the government
can spend, i.e. a tax and spending rule (TEL). A sec-
New TELs have been proposed in half a dozen ond set of rules must be introduced governing how
states over the past year.13 This next generation of the surplus revenue above the TEL is allocated to
TELs depart considerably from the TELs now in the budget stabilization fund. A third set of rules is
place. It is possible to introduce a TEL to constrain required for allocating money from the budget sta-
the growth of government in the long run that does bilization fund to the general fund to offset revenue
not serve to stabilize the budget over the busi- shortfalls and stabilize the budget during recession.
ness cycle. That is in fact the nature of Colorado’s
TABOR Amendment. A. Rules Defining the TEL Limit

On the other hand, a TEL designed to stabilize the The states have experimented with a variety of lim-
budget over the business cycle, may or may not con- its in designing their TELs. The most widely used
strain the growth of government in the long run. For limit is a measure of the rate of growth of income
example, Michigan’s TEL has been used to stabilize over some historical period. There are a number
the budget over the business cycle, but it is not clear of criticisms of this type of TEL as a constraint on
that it has constrained the growth of government. the growth of government. This limit tends to be
If all of the surplus revenue generated in periods less stringent compared to other limits, resulting
of rapid growth is returned to the general fund to in a more rapid growth of government. Depending
finance spending and to offset revenue shortfalls in upon how the limit is applied it may have little or no
impact on the growth of government.
In the present context, the criticism of a TEL limit C. Rules Linking the TEL to a Budget Stabilization
based on the growth in personal income over an Fund
historical time period is that it is less effective in
stabilizing the budget over the business cycle. Such a The basic principle of a rules based budget stabili-
limit permits a very rapid rate of growth in revenue zation fund is straightforward. A good analogy is a
and spending in periods of rapid economic growth. hybrid energy vehicle (HEV). An HEV has a brak-
Even when the limit is triggered it does so only with ing system such that surplus energy created by the
some lag. As a result this type of limit is less effec- motor when brakes are applied is stored in a battery,
tive than one that has no lagged impact; indeed it is and then used to power the motor when the car is
possible that such a limit could actually be pro-cycli- operating at a slower speed.
cal.
Rules governing a budget stabilization fund operate
Recent studies have demonstrated that the most much like an HEV. A brake is applied to limit the
stringent TELs define the limit as the sum of infla- amount of revenue the state spends in periods of
tion and population growth. While TEL limits rapid economic growth. The surplus revenue is accu-
defined in terms of the growth of population and mulated in a budget stabilization fund, and used to
inflation have proven effective in constraining the offset revenue shortfalls in periods of recession. The
growth of government, they have proven less effec- rules governing how money is transferred into and
tive in stabilizing the budget over the business cycle. out of the budget stabilization fund are extremely
If such TELs ratchet down revenue and spending in important because they determine the tradeoff
periods of recession, they may also be pro-cyclical. between constraining the growth of government and
stabilizing the budget over the business cycle.
B. Rules Defining the TEL Base.
At this point we assume that the budget stabilization
The states have also experimented with different fund is clearly distinguished from other funds that
revenue and expenditure bases against which the might be created. The money set aside in the budget
TEL limit is applied. In general it is fair to say that stabilization fund is used for only one purpose and
the broader the base the more effective the TEL. If that is to stabilize the budget over the business cycle.
interest groups are able to exempt portions of the The TEL limit is held constant whenever there is a
revenue and or expenditures from the TEL limit it revenue shortfall, and becomes a binding constraint
becomes less effective both in constraining govern- only when revenue recovers to that limit.
ment and in stabilizing the government budget over
the business cycle. A broader base also limits the D. Rules for Allocating Surplus Revenue Into the
economic distortions introduced by such privilege Budget Stabilization Fund
seeking.
If we assume that an effective TEL is in place, then
It is also fair to say that the use of actual historical the opportunity cost of setting aside surplus revenue
measures of revenue and expenditures has proven above the TEL limit in a budget stabilization fund
more effective than the use of projected measures. is the return of that surplus revenue to taxpayers
Historical data from the most recent budget cycle is through tax rebates and tax cuts. The more of the
easily obtained and does not rely upon projections surplus revenue returned to taxpayers the lower the
of revenue or expenditures that are subject to error rate of growth of government relative to the private
and bias. sector in the long run. Allocating some of that reve-
nue to a budget stabilization fund provides the funds
to stabilize the budget, but also reduces the
constraint imposed by the TEL on the growth of
government.

Rules must establish how much of the surplus rev-


enue to allocate to the budget stabilization fund at a
given point in time; and what, if any, cap should be
placed on the size of the budget stabilization fund.
Wall street and bond rating agencies often suggest
an appropriate size for a budget stabilization fund in
the range of 6 to 7 percent of the state budget. But,
each state is unique in its preferences and require-
ments for a budget stabilization fund, and it is fair to
say that there are no hard and fast rules..

E. Rules for Allocating Money from the Budget


Stabilization Fund to the General Fund

A rules-based budget stabilization fund would


require the allocation of money from the budget sta-
bilization fund to the general fund whenever there is
a revenue shortfall. These rules are also important
because they determine the tradeoff between con-
straining the budget over the long run, and stabiliz-
ing the budget over the business cycle.

If the primary emphasis is on budget stabilization


then money would be transferred equal to the rev-
enue shortfall until all of the funds in the budget
stabilization fund are exhausted. If the emphasis is
on constraining the growth of government in the
long run, then only a portion of the budget stabiliza-
tion fund would be transferred into the general fund
at a given point in time. In the latter case a revenue
shortfall would also require reductions in govern-
ment spending.

Voter surveys suggest that money should be trans-


ferred from the budget stabilization fund to offset
some, but not all, of the revenue shortfall. For
example, the rule might require that only half of
the revenue shortfall be offset by money transferred
from the budget stabilization fund in any given fiscal
year, with the other half offset by budget cuts. Such
a decision rule might mean that all of the budget
stabilization fund would not be exhausted in any
given recession to offset revenue shortfalls.
APPENDIX: THE NEXT GENERATION OF TELS - A MODEL TEL

The author has been consulting with a number of states on legislation to introduce, or modify, TELs along

the lines of the previous discussion of the next generation of TELs.14 The legislation proposing a new TEL

for Kansas is included here as an appendix, because it is the most carefully crafted TEL embodying these

principles.15

WORKING DRAFT NO. 5

December 22, 2003

3rs1247

DRAFT CONCURRENT RESOLUTION NO. ____

By

A PROPOSITION to amend the constitution of the state of Kansas by adding a new article thereto, prescrib-

ing certain limits upon taxes, revenues and expenditures by the state and local governments.

Be it resolved by the Legislature of the State of Kansas, two-thirds of the members elected (or appointed) and

qualified to the House of Representatives and two-thirds of the members elected (or appointed) and qualified to

the Senate concurring therein:

Section

1 . The following proposition to amend the constitution of the state of Kansas shall be submitted to

the qualified electors of the state for their approval or rejection: The constitution of the state of Kansas is

amended by adding a new article thereto to read as follows:

”Article16.

TAX, REVENUE AND EXPENDITURE LIMITATIONS ON STATE AND LOCAL GOVERNMENTS.


1. Definitions. As used within this article:

(a) ”State” means the state government including all branches, state offices, authorities,

agencies, boards, commissions, institutions, instrumentalities and any division or unit of state government

which are directly supported with tax funds, except that ”state” does not include any enterprise;

(b) ”local government” means any county, township, city, education district, other special

district and any other taxing district or political subdivision of Kansas which is directly supported by tax funds,

except that ”local government” does not include any enterprise;

(c) ”enterprise” means a state-owned or local government-owned business authorized to

issue its own revenue bonds and receiving less than 10% of annual revenue in grants or other direct cash ben-

efit from the state and local governments combined;

(d) ”bond” means any bond, note, debenture, interim certificate, grant and revenue antici-

pation note, lease-purchase agreement, lease certificate of participation or other evidence of indebtedness

which, in any such case, is entered into or establishes a debt obligation for longer than one fiscal year, wheth-

er or not the interest on which is subject to federal income taxation;

(e) ”fiscal year” means the twelve-month fiscal period prescribed by law for the state or the

local government;

(f) ”fiscal year spending” means all expenditures and reserve increases except, as to both,

expenditures for refunds of any kind or expenditures of moneys received from the federal government, mon-

eys received as grants, gifts or donations which are to be expended for purposes specified by the donor, mon-

eys that are collections for another government, moneys received for pension contributions by employees and

pension fund earnings, reserve transfers or expenditures;

(g) ”inflation” means the change expressed as a percentage in the consumer price index

for the Kansas City metropolitan area, all goods, all urban consumers, as officially reported by the bureau of
labor statistics of the United States department of labor, or its successor index; and

(h) ”population” means the more recent of either the periodic census conducted by the

United States department of commerce or its successor agency or the annual update of such census as pre-

scribed by the legislature by law, which shall be adjusted every decade to match the federal decennial census.

(i) ”education district” means each school district, vocational or technical school, commu-

nity college, technical college, municipal university, and any other public educational entity established as

provided by law, except that ”education district” does not include any state educational institution under the

control and supervision of the state board of regents.

(j) ”total state revenue” means all moneys received by the state from any source except any

of the following:

(1) Moneys received as grants, gifts or donations which are to be expended for purposes

specified by the donor;

(2) moneys received from the federal government; and

(3) moneys which are income earned on moneys in permanent endowment funds, trust

funds, deferred compensation funds or pension funds and which are credited to such funds;

(k) ”total local government revenue” means all moneys received by the local government

from any source except any of the following:

(1) Moneys received as grants, gifts or donations which are to be expended for purposes

specified by the donor;

(2) moneys received from the federal government; and

(3) moneys which are income earned on moneys in permanent endowment funds, trust

funds, deferred compensation funds or pension funds and which are credited to such funds.
§ 2. Prior Elector Approval for Tax Increases or Issuance of Certain Bonds. (a) For any fiscal

year that commences on or after July 1, 2005, the state must have approval of the electors in advance (1) for

any new state income, sales or other excise tax rate increase before the state tax rate increase can take effect,

(2) for any state mill levy ad valorem property tax rate increase above the state mill levy ad valorem property

tax rate for the prior year before the state mill levy ad valorem property tax rate increase can take effect, (3)

for any extension of any expiring state income, sales or other excise tax or expiring state ad valorem property

tax before the extension can take effect, or (4) for any state tax policy change enacted into law by the state

which would directly cause a net tax revenue gain to the state or local government, before such tax policy

change can take effect.

(b) For any fiscal year that commences on or after July 1, 2005, each local government must

have approval of the electors in advance (1) for any new local government income, sales or other excise tax

rate increase, which is authorized by law, before the local government tax rate increase can take effect, (2)

for any local government mill levy ad valorem property tax rate increase, which is authorized by law, before

the local government mill levy ad valorem property tax rate increase can take effect, (3) for any extension of

any expiring local government income, sales or other excise tax or local government ad valorem property tax,

which is authorized by law, before the extension can take effect, or (4) for any local government tax policy

change authorized by law and adopted in a resolution or ordinance by a local government which would direct-

ly cause a net tax revenue gain to the local government, before such tax policy change can take effect.

(c) For any fiscal year that commences on or after July 1, 2005, the state and each local

government must have approval of the electors before authorizing any bonds, except for refinancing existing

bonded debt at a lower interest rate.

(d) The legislature shall provide by law for the manner of submitting matters subject to

approval under this section to the electors.

§ 3. Spending and Revenue Limits. (a) For any state fiscal year that commences on or after

July 1, 2005, fiscal year spending by the state shall not increase above the fiscal year spending for the preced-

ing state fiscal year by more than the maximum percentage increase determined pursuant to this section.

The maximum percentage increase in fiscal year spending for a state fiscal year shall be equal to the result
obtained by adding the rate of inflation for the calendar year ending during the preceding state fiscal year,

plus the percentage change in state population during the calendar year ending during the preceding state

fiscal year if a positive number, adjusted for revenue changes approved by electors under section 2 of this

article.

(b) If the amount of the total state revenue for the preceding state fiscal year exceeds the

amount of total state revenue for the second preceding state fiscal year, the total state revenue limitation for

a state fiscal year shall be the result obtained by adding (1) the lesser of (A) the amount of total state revenue

for the preceding state fiscal year or (B) the amount of the total state revenue limitation for the preceding

state fiscal year, and (2) the product of (A) the amount determined under clause (1) of this subsection, and

(B) the sum of (i) the rate of inflation for the calendar year ending during the preceding state fiscal year, plus

(ii) the percentage change in state population during the calendar year ending during the preceding state fis-

cal year if a positive number.

(c) If the amount of the total state revenue for the preceding state fiscal year is less than the

amount of total state revenue for the second preceding state fiscal year, the amount of the total state revenue

limitation for a state fiscal year shall be the lesser of (1) the amount of total state revenue for such state fiscal

year, or (2) the amount of the total state revenue limitation for the most recent state fiscal year for which the

amount of total state revenue exceeded the amount of total state revenue for the preceding state fiscal year.

(d) For any local government, other than an education district, for any local government fis-

cal year that commences on or after July 1, 2005, fiscal year spending by the local government, other than an

education district, shall not increase above the fiscal year spending for the preceding local government fiscal

year by more than the maximum percentage increase determined pursuant to this section. For any fiscal year

that commences on or after July 1, 2005, the maximum percentage increase in fiscal year spending by a local

government, other than an education district, equals the sum of inflation during the preceding calendar year

plus the percentage change in the local government population during the preceding calendar year if a posi-

tive number, adjusted for revenue changes approved by the electors under section 2 of this article.

(e) For any education district fiscal year that commences on or after July 1, 2005, fiscal year

spending by the education district shall not increase above the fiscal year spending for the preceding educa-

tion district fiscal year by more than the maximum percentage increase determined pursuant to this section.
For any fiscal year that commences on or after July 1, 2005, the maximum percentage increase in fiscal year

spending by an education district equals inflation during the preceding calendar year, plus the percentage

change in its pupil or student enrollment for the school year commencing during the preceding calendar year

as compared to the school year preceding that school year if a positive number, adjusted for revenue changes

approved by the electors under section 2 of this article.

(f) If the amount of the total local government revenue for the preceding local government

fiscal year exceeds the amount of total local government revenue for the second preceding local government

fiscal year, the total local government revenue limitation for a local government fiscal year shall be the result

obtained by adding (1) the lesser of (A) the amount of total local government revenue for the preceding local

government fiscal year or (B) the amount of the total local government revenue limitation for the preced-

ing local government fiscal year, and (2) the product of (A) the amount determined under clause (1) of this

subsection, and (B) the sum of (i) the rate of inflation for the calendar year ending during the preceding local

government fiscal year, plus (ii) in the case of a local government other than an education district, the per-

centage change in local government population during the calendar year ending during the preceding local

government fiscal year if a positive number, or (iii) in the case of an education district, the percentage change

in its pupil or student enrollment for the school year commencing during the preceding calendar year as com-

pared to the school year preceding that school year if a positive number.

(g) If the amount of the total local government revenue for the preceding local government

fiscal year is less than the amount of total local government revenue for the second preceding local govern-

ment fiscal year, the amount of the total local government revenue limitation for a local government fiscal

year shall be the lesser of (1) the amount of total local government revenue for such local government fiscal

year, or (2) the amount of the total local government revenue limitation for the most recent local government

fiscal year for which the amount of total local government revenue exceeded the amount of total local gov-

ernment revenue for the preceding local government fiscal year.

(h) The legislature, by law, shall provide a mechanism to adjust the amount of a limitation

under this section to reflect any subsequent transfer of all or any part of the cost of providing a governmen-

tal function. The mechanism shall adjust the amount of a limitation so that total costs are not increased as a

result of the transfer. The adjustment mechanism provided for in this subsection shall be used in determining

a limitation under this section beginning with the fiscal year immediately following the transfer.
(i) The legislature, by law, shall provide a mechanism to adjust the amount of a limitation

under this section to reflect the cost of providing a governmental function on account of any subsequent

annexation, creation of a new governmental unit, or any consolidation or change in the boundaries of a gov-

ernmental unit. The mechanism shall adjust the amount of limitation so that total costs are not increased as

a result of the annexation, creation, consolidation or change in boundaries. The adjustment mechanism pro-

vided in accordance with this subsection shall be used in determining a limitation under this section beginning

with the fiscal year immediately following the annexation, creation of a new governmental unit, or consolida-

tion or change in the boundaries of a governmental unit.

(j) In the case of the state or any local government having a fiscal year ending on June 30,

2005, for the purposes of determining total revenue limitations under this section for the state or any such

local government, the total authorized fiscal year expenditures for the fiscal year ending on June 30, 2004,

shall be construed to be the total revenue limitation for that preceding fiscal year and the total authorized

fiscal year expenditures for the fiscal year ending on June 30, 2005, shall be construed to be the total revenue

limitation for that preceding fiscal year. In the case of any local government having a fiscal year ending on

December 31, 2005, for the purposes of determining total local government revenue limitations under this

section for any such local government, the total authorized fiscal year expenditures for the fiscal year ending

on December 31, 2004, shall be construed to be the total revenue limitation for that preceding fiscal year and

the total authorized fiscal year expenditures for the fiscal year ending December 31, 2005, shall be construed

to be the total revenue limitation for that preceding fiscal year.

§ 4. Emergency Reserve Funds. (a) For any state fiscal year that commences on or after July

1, 2005, if revenue from sources not excluded from total state revenue exceeds the total state revenue limita-

tion for that state fiscal year and subject to the other provisions of this section, a portion of total state rev-

enue in excess of the total state revenue limitation, determined in accordance with section 3 of this article,

shall be transferred in the amount and in the manner prescribed by the legislature by law to the emergency

reserve fund, which fund is hereby created in the state treasury, to the extent necessary to ensure that a bal-

ance of the emergency reserve fund at the end of the state fiscal year is an amount equal to not more than

3% of the total state revenue limitation for the ensuing state fiscal year. Any amount required to be main-

tained in the ending balance of the state general fund as provided by law shall be excluded from the amount

available for transfer to the emergency reserve fund of the state by this section. Each transfer to the emergen-
cy reserve fund of the state prescribed by this section shall be made before making any transfer to the budget

stabilization reserve fund as provided in section 5 of this article or any refunds as required by section 6 of this

article. The state shall not be required to transfer any moneys other than any amount of total state revenue

in excess of the total state revenue limitation to the emergency reserve fund. The moneys in the emergency

reserve fund shall be in addition to, and shall not be used to meet, any other reserve requirement under this

constitution or any law. In no case shall additional moneys be transferred to the emergency reserve fund if

the balance in the emergency reserve fund is more than 3% of the total state revenue limitation for the ensu-

ing state fiscal year.

(b) Moneys in the emergency reserve fund of the state may be expended only for emer-

gencies declared by law. Two-thirds (2/3) of the members then elected (or appointed) and qualified in each

house, voting in the affirmative, shall be necessary to declare an emergency within the state of Kansas as

a whole and to pass any bill making an appropriation of money from the emergency reserve fund. Income

earned on the emergency reserve fund of the state shall accrue to the fund.

(c) For each local government fiscal year that commences on or after July 1, 2005, each

local government shall reserve and maintain in an emergency reserve fund an amount equal to not more than

3% of its total local government revenue limitation for the ensuing local government fiscal year in accor-

dance with this section. For any local government fiscal year that commences on or after July 1, 2005, if total

local government revenue from sources not excluded from total local government revenue exceeds the total

local government revenue limitation for that local government fiscal year and subject to the other provisions

of this section, a portion of total local government revenue in excess of the total local government revenue

limitation, determined in accordance with section 3 of this article, shall be transferred in the amount and in

the manner prescribed by the legislature by law to the emergency reserve fund of the local government. Any

amount required to be maintained in the ending balance of the general fund of the local government as pro-

vided by law shall be excluded from the amount available for transfer to the emergency reserve fund of the

local government by this section.

(d) Moneys in the emergency reserve fund of a local government may be expended only for

emergencies within a local government declared by the local government in the manner prescribed by law.

Income earned on the emergency reserve fund of the local government shall accrue to the fund.
(e) As used in this section ”emergency” means an extraordinary event or occurrence that

could not have been reasonably foreseen or prevented and that requires immediate expenditures to preserve

the health, safety and general welfare of the people within a local government or the state and ”emergency”

does not mean a revenue shortfall or budget shortfall.

§ 5. Budget Stabilization Reserve Funds. (a) For any state fiscal year that commences on or

after July 1, 2005, if total state revenue exceeds the total state revenue limitation for that state fiscal year,

then the remaining excess amount, after making any transfer to the emergency reserve fund as required by

section 4 of this article, shall be reserved as prescribed by this section or refunded as prescribed by section

6 of this article, subject to the other provisions of this section. Any amount required to be maintained in the

ending balance of the state general fund as provided by law shall be excluded from the amount available for

transfer to the budget stabilization reserve fund of the state by this section.

(b) After any amount required to be transferred to the emergency reserve fund of the state

pursuant to section 4 of this article has been transferred, an amount of any remaining excess amount of total

state revenue shall be transferred in the amount and in the manner prescribed by the legislature by law to the

budget stabilization reserve fund, which fund is hereby created in the state treasury. The amount transferred

to the budget stabilization reserve fund in accordance with this subsection shall be equal to the lesser of (1)

the amount necessary to ensure that the balance in the budget stabilization reserve fund at the end of the

state fiscal year is an amount equal to 10% of the total state revenue limitation for the ensuing state fiscal

year, or (2) the amount equal to 50% of any such remaining excess amount of total state revenue. Income

earned on the budget stabilization reserve fund shall accrue to the fund. In no case shall additional moneys

be transferred into the budget stabilization reserve fund if the balance in the fund is equal to or more than

10% of the total state revenue limitation for the ensuing state fiscal year.

(c) For any state fiscal year that commences on or after July 1, 2005, if the amount of the

total state revenue is less than the amount of total state revenue for the prior state fiscal year, the legislature

shall provide by law for the transfer of moneys from the budget stabilization fund to the state general fund

in an amount equal to not more than the difference between the amount of total state revenue for the prior

state fiscal year and the amount of total state revenue for the state fiscal year. Under no other circumstances

shall moneys be transferred or expended from the budget stabilization fund of the state.
(d) For each local government fiscal year that commences on or after July 1, 2005, each

local government shall reserve and maintain in a budget stabilization reserve fund an amount equal to not

more than 10% of its fiscal year estimated spending in accordance with this section. For any local govern-

ment fiscal year that commences on or after July 1, 2005, if total local government revenue from sources not

excluded from total local government revenue exceeds the total local government revenue limitation for that

local government fiscal year and subject to the other provisions of this section, a portion of total local govern-

ment revenue in excess of the total local government revenue limitation, determined in accordance with sec-

tion 3 of this article, shall be transferred in the amount and in the manner prescribed by the legislature by law

to the budget stabilization reserve fund of the local government. Any amount required to be maintained in

the ending balance of the general fund of the local government as provided by law shall be excluded from the

amount available for transfer to the budget stabilization reserve fund of the local government by this section.

No amount shall be transferred to the budget stabilization reserve fund of a local government until after any

amount required to be transferred to the emergency reserve fund of the local government pursuant to section

4 of this article has been transferred.

(e) For any current local government fiscal year that commences on or after July 1, 2005, if

the amount of the total local government revenue is less than the amount of total revenue for the prior fiscal

year, the local government shall provide for the transfer of moneys from the budget stabilization fund to the

general revenue fund of the local government in an amount equal to not more than the difference between

the amount of total local government revenue for the prior local government fiscal year and the amount of

total revenue for the current local government fiscal year. Under no other circumstances shall moneys be

transferred or expended from the budget stabilization fund of the local government.

§ 6. Disposition of Excess Revenues. (a) Any excess amount of total state revenues for a state

fiscal year that remains after the transfers to the emergency reserve fund and budget stabilization reserve

fund pursuant to section 4 or section 5 of this article, if any, shall be reserved in the current state fiscal year

and shall be refunded as provided by law during the next ensuing state fiscal year to the taxpayers who paid

the state ad valorem property taxes or state income, sales or other excise taxes for or during the preceding

state fiscal year, in a manner that is proportional, on a pro rata basis, to the manner in which such taxes were

collected from such taxpayers. Any amount required to be maintained in the ending balance of the state gen-

eral fund as provided by law shall be excluded from the amount available to be reserved and refunded by the

state as prescribed by this section.


(b) Any excess amount of local government revenues for a local government fiscal year that

remains after transfers to the emergency reserve fund and budget stabilization reserve fund of the local gov-

ernment pursuant to section 4 or section 5 of this article, if any, shall be reserved in the current local govern-

ment fiscal year and shall be refunded during the next ensuing local government fiscal year to the taxpayers

who paid the ad valorem property taxes or income, sales or other excise taxes of the local government for or

during the preceding local government fiscal year, in a manner that is proportional, on a pro rata basis, to the

manner in which such taxes were collected from such taxpayers. Any amount required to be maintained in

the ending balance of the general fund of the local government as provided by law shall be excluded from the

amount available to be reserved and refunded to taxpayers by the local government as prescribed by this sec-

tion.

(c) In a case of any amount that is received pursuant to any tax and required to be reserved

and refunded to taxpayers by the state or a local government pursuant to this section and that is determined

by the state or local government in the manner prescribed by law to be insufficient for refunds to be made

during the ensuing state or local government fiscal year, as the case may be, such amount shall be reserved

for refunds to be made thereafter when the amount reserved is sufficient therefor.

§ 7. State Temporary Borrowing. On or after July 1, 2005, during any state fiscal year, trans-

fers which are temporary and are to be repaid, or any other temporary borrowing, through certificates of

indebtedness or any other device or manner, of any moneys in the state treasury to be credited to the state

general fund, are prohibited unless the moneys so transferred or otherwise borrowed are restored or repaid

to the original funds or accounts of the state treasury from the state general fund within the same state fiscal

year. The provisions of this section do not apply to transfers from the emergency reserve fund or the budget

stabilization reserve fund to the state general fund in accordance with this article.

§ 8. General Revenue Supplanting. (a) On or after July 1, 2005, any appropriation of moneys

in the state treasury that either supplants any appropriation from the state general fund, or that, if not made,

would require an appropriation from the state general fund is prohibited. For purposes of this subsection,

any appropriation of moneys in the state treasury that is funded by user charges or fees imposed on goods or

services that do not exceed the cost of the goods or services provided shall not be deemed to be an appropria-

tion that supplants any appropriation from the state general fund.
(b) For any local government fiscal year that commences on or after July 1, 2005, no local

government shall impose or shall increase user charges or fees imposed for goods or services provided by the

local government to supplant general revenues of the local government. For the purposes of this subsection,

any imposition or increase of user charges or fees imposed on goods or services that do not exceed the cost

of the goods or services provided shall not be deemed to be supplanting general revenues of the local govern-

ment.

§ 9. State Mandates on Local Governments. A local government may not be required to fulfill

any mandate imposed by the state unless and until, and may be required to fulfill that mandate only to the

extent that, funds are provided to the local government by the state for that purpose. The legislature is not

required to appropriate funds for mandates if more than two years have passed since the effective date of the

mandate and no claim for funding has been made by local government during that period.

§ 10. Construction and Enforcement. (a) The provisions of this article shall be liberally con-

strued for the purpose of effectuating the purposes thereof, except that nothing in this article shall be con-

strued to authorize any new or increased tax of any kind other than as provided or authorized by law enacted

by the legislature in accordance with and subject to the other provisions of this constitution.

(b) In any case of a conflict between any provision of this article and any other provision

contained in the constitution, the provisions of this article shall control.

(c) All laws in force at the time of the adoption of this amendment and consistent therewith

shall remain in full force and effect until amended or repealed by the legislature. The legislature shall repeal

or amend all laws inconsistent with the provisions of this article to conform with the provisions of this article.

(d) Any individual or class of individuals shall have standing to bring a suit to enforce this

article. A court of record shall award a successful plaintiff costs and reasonable attorney fees in the suit, but

may not allow the state or a local government to recover costs and reasonable attorney fees unless a suit

against it is ruled frivolous.”

Sec. . The following statement shall be printed on the ballot with the amendment as a whole:
”Explanatory statement. This amendment would establish requirements for prior voter

approval of tax increases and certain bond issuances by the state and local governments, would place limita-

tions on increases in state and local government spending and provide for the disposition of excess state rev-

enues by establishing certain reserve funds and prescribing certain tax refunds by the state.

”A vote for this proposition would . . .

I.

”A vote against this proposition would . . .” Sec. . This resolution, if approved

by two-thirds of the members elected (or appointed) and qualified to the House of Representatives, and

two-thirds of the members elected (or appointed) and qualified to the Senate shall be entered on the jour-

nals, together with the yeas and nays. The secretary of state shall cause this resolution to be published as

provided by law and shall cause the proposed amendment to be submitted to the electors of the state at the

general election to be held on November 2, 2004, unless a special election is called at a sooner date by con-

current resolution of the legislature, in which case it shall be submitted to the electors of the state at the spe-

cial election.
BIBLIOGRAPHY and Expenditure Limitation Laws.” Public Finance
Quarterly 20:47-63.
Abrams, B.A. and W. R. Dougan (1986). “The
Effects of Constitutional Restraints on Government Flowers, Marilyn R. (1977). “Multiple Tax Sources,
Spending.” Public Choice 49:223-38. Voting Equilibrium, and Budget Size.” Public
Finance 32:210-224.
Bails, Dale G. (1982). “A Critique on the
Effectiveness of Tax-Expenditure Limitations.” Hettich, Walter and Stanley Winer (1984). “A
Public Choice 38:129-138. Positive Model of Tax Structure.” Journal of Public
Economics 24: 67-87.
Bails, Dale G. (1990). “The Effectiveness of
Tax-Expenditure Limitations: A Reevaluation.” Holcombe, Randall G. (2001). “Tax and Expenditure
American Journal of Economics and Sociology 49: Limitations: Issues for Florida.” Backgrounder
223-38. Policy Report #32, The James Madison Institute.

Bails, Dale G. and Margie A. Tieslau (2000). “The Joyce, Phillip G. and Daniel R. Mullins (1991). “The
Impact of Fiscal Constitutions on State and Local Changing Fiscal Structure of the State and Local
Expenditures.” Cato Journal 20:255-277. Public Sector: The Impact of Tax and Expenditure
Limitations.” Public Administration Review 51:240-
Brennan, Geoffrey and James M. Buchanan 253.
(1980). The Power to Tax: Analytical Foundations
of a Fiscal Constitution. Cambridge: Cambridge Kenyon, Daphne and Karen M. Benker (1984).
University Press. “Fiscal Discipline: Lessons From the State
Experienced.” National Tax Journal 37:437-446.
Broder, David S. (2000). Democracy Derailed:
Initiative Campaigns and the Power of Money.
Money New McCary, Ray (2003). 2003 Fiscal Review of Missouri
York: Harcourt. State Government. Missouri Chamber of Commerce
and Industry.
Buchanan, James M. and Richard E. Wagner (1977).
Democracy in Deficit.
Deficit New York: Academic Press. New, Michael J. (2001). “Limiting Government
Through Direct Democracy: the Case of State Tax
Chicoine, David L. and Norman Walzer (1986). and Expenditure Limitations.” Policy Analysis No.
“Factors Affecting Property Tax Reliance: 420, Cato Institute.
Additional Evidence.” Public Choice 49: 17-28.
New, Michael J. (2003). “Proposition 13 and State
Cox, J and D. Lowery (1990). “The Impact of the Budget Limitations: Past Successes and Future
Tax Revolt Era State Fiscal Caps.” Social Science Options.” Briefing Paper No. 83, Cato Institute.
Quarterly 71: 492-509.
Owens, Bill (2003). “Hasta La Vista, Deficit.” Wall
Dougan, W. (1988). “The Effects of Tax or Street Journal, Thursday Oct 16.
Expenditure Limits on State Government.” Working
Paper No. 54, Center for the Study of the Economy Poterba, James M. (1994). “State Responses to
and the State. Fiscal Crises: The Effects of Budgetary Institutions
and Politics.” Journal of Political Economy 102: 799-
Elders, Harold W. (1992). “Exploring the Tax 821.
Revolt: An Analysis of the Effectiveness of State Tax
Poterba, James M. (1996). “Do Budget Rules Reubens, Kim S. (1995). “Tax Limitations
Work?” NBER Working Paper No. 5550, and Government Growth: The Effect of Tax
Cambridge, Mass., National Bureau of Economic and Expenditures Limits on state and Local
research. Government.” Mimeo, MIT Department of
Economics.
Poulson, Barry W. and Jay Kaplan (1994). “A Rent
Seeking Model of TELs.” Public Choice 79:117-134. Riker, William (1980). Implications for the
Disequilibrium of Majority Rule for the Study of
Poulson, Barry W.(1999). “Surplus Expenditures Institutions.” American Political Science Review 74:
in Colorado.” Issue Paper 10-1999, Independence 432-446.
Institute.
Sjonquist, David L. (1981). “A Median Voter
Poulson, Barry W. (2001a). “Learning to Live With Analysis of Variations in the Use of Property Taxes
Colorado’s Tax and Spending Limits.” Issue Paper Among Local Government.” Public Choice 36:273-
9-2001, Independence Institute. 285.

Poulson, Barry W. (2001b). “Surplus Expenditures: Shadbegian, Ronald J. (1996). “Do Tax and
A Case Study of Colorado.” Public Budgeting and Expenditure Limitations Affect the Size and Growth
Finance Winter 2001: 18-43. of State Government.” Contemporary Economic
Policy 14: 22-35.
Poulson, Barry W. (2003a). “Fiscal Crises in
Colorado.” Issue Paper 2-2003 Independence Spindler, Zane A. (1990). “A rent seeking
Institute. Perspective on Privatization.” North American
Review of Economics and Finance 1: 87-105.
Poulson, Barry W. (2003b). “A Constitutional
Impasse: Gallagher, Bird Arveschaug, TABOR and Stansel, Dean (1994). “Missouri’s Hancock II
Amendment 23.” Article 2003-c, Independence Amendment: the Case for Real Reform.” Briefing
Institute. Paper No. 20, Cato Institute.

Poulson, Barry W. (2003c). “Creating a Rainy Day Treasurer’s Advisory Group on Constitutional
Fund for Colorado.” Mimeo, Treasurer’s Advisory Amendments (2003) Reports and Proposals From
Group on Constitutional Amendments. this Advisory Group can Be found on the State
Treasurer’s web site.
Poulson, Barry W. 2003d) “Putting State fiscal
Policies on Cruise Control.” State Factor American Uhler Lewis K. and Barry W. Poulson (2003). Tax
Legislative Exchange Council Washington, D.C. and Expenditure Limits: From Roots to Current
Realities. The National Tax Limitation Foundation,
Public Interest Institute (2002) The Constitution of Roseville, California.
the State of Michigan Article IX.

Public Interest Institute (2002) The Constitution of


the State of Missouri Article X Taxation.

Rafool, Mandy (1996). “State Tax and Expenditure


Limits,” National Conference of State Legislative
Finance Paper No. 104. ENDNOTES
1
The author has been consulting with these states as a member Copyright ©2004, Independence Institute
of the American Legislative Exchange Council (ALEC) Task Force
on Tax and Fiscal Policy.
2
For a discussion of the political economy of TELs see (Broder INDEPENDENCE INSTITUTE is a non-profit,
2000).
3
For an introduction to this literature see (Buchanan and
non-partisan Colorado think tank. It is governed
Wagner 1977) by a statewide board of trustees and holds a
4
For a discussion of the relevance of rent seeking models to
501(c)(3) tax exemption from the IRS. Its public
TELs see (Poulson and Kaplan 1994).
5
The discussion in this case study is from (Uhler and Poulson policy research focuses on economic growth, educa-
2003) and (New 2001). tion reform, local government effectiveness, and
6
The discussion of this case study draws from (Stansel 1994),
(Public Interest Institute 2002), and (McCarty 2003). Constitutional rights.
7
The discussion of this case study draws on (Holcombe 2001).
8
The discussion of this case study draws on (New 2001) and
(New 2003). JON CALDARA is President of the Institute.
9
The discussion of this case study draws on (Public Interest
Institute 2002) and (Poulson 2002).
10
The discussion of this case study draws on (Poulson 2001), DAVID KOPEL is Research Director of the
(Poulson 2003a), (Poulson 2003b), and (Poulson 2003c). Institute.
11
For insight into this controversy see (Treasurer’s Advisory
Group on Constitutional Amendments 2003).
12
Much of this discussion is drawn from (Poulson 2003d) BARRY POULSON is a Senior Fellow at the
13
The author has been consulting with these states as a mem-
ber of the American Legislative Exchange Council (ALEC) Task
Independence Institute and a professor of economics
Force on Tax and Fiscal Policy. at the University of Colorado.
14
Ibid.
15
This Amendment has been introduced in the Kansas
Legislature by Representative Brenda Landwehr. ADDITIONAL RESOURCES on this subject can
be found at: http://www.IndependenceInstitute.org

NOTHING WRITTEN here is to be construed


as necessarily representing the views of the
Independence Institute or as an attempt to influence
any election or legislative action.

PERMISSION TO REPRINT this paper in whole


or in part is hereby granted provided full credit is
given to the Independence Institute.

Das könnte Ihnen auch gefallen