Sie sind auf Seite 1von 6

14.

32 Problem Set 6 Solutions


Paul Schrimpf
May 19, 2009
A. Wooldridge
Solutions from Instructors Manual for 2nd Edition
8 points each
15.2 (i) It seems reasonable to assume that dist and u are uncorrelated because classrooms are not usually
assigned with convenience for particular students in mind.
(ii) The variable dist must be partially correlated with atndrte. More precisely, in the reduced form
atndrte =
0
+
1
priGPA +
2
ACT +
3
dist + v
we must have
3
= 0. Given a sample of data we can test H
0
:
3
= 0 against H
1
:
3
= 0 using
a t test.
(iii) We now need instrumental variables for atndrte and the interaction term, priGPAatndrte. (Even
though priGPA is exogenous, atndrte is not, and so priGPA atndrte is generally correlated with
u.) Under the exogeneity assumption that E(u|priGPA, ACT, dist) = 0, any function of priGPA,
ACT, and dist is uncorrelated with u. In particular, the interaction priGPA dist is uncorrelated
with u. If dist is partially correlated with atndrte then priGPA dist is partially correlated with
priGPA atndrte. So, we can estimate the equation
stndfnl =
0
+
1
atndrte +
2
priGPA +
3
ACT +
4
priGPA atndrte + u
by 2SLS using IVs dist, priGPA, ACT, and priGPA dist. It turns out this is not generally
optimal. It may be better to add priGPA
2
and priGPA ACT to the instrument list. This would
give us overidentifying restrictions to test. See Wooldridge (2002, Chapters 5 and 9) for further
discussion.
15.3 It is easiest to use (15.10) but where we drop z . Remember, this is allowed because

n
i=1
(z
i
z)(x
i

x) =

n
i=1
z
i
(x
i
x). and similarly when we replace x with y. So the numerator in the formula for

1
is

z
i
(y
i
y) =

z
i
y
i

z
i

y = n
1
y
1
n
1
y (1)
where n
1
=

z
i
is the number of observations with z
i
= 1 and we have used the fact that

z
i
y
i
/n
1
=
y
1
, the average of the y
i
with z
i
= 1. So far, we have shown that the numerator in
1
is n
1
( y
1
y).
Next, write y as a weighted average of the averages over the two subgroups:
y = (n
0
/n) y
0
+ (n
1
/n) y
1
where n
0
= n n
1
. Therefore,
y
1
y =[(n n
1
)/n] y
1
(n
0
/n) y
0
=(n
0
/n)( y
1
y
0
)
1
Therefore, the numerator of

beta
1
can be written as
(n
0
n
1
/n)( y
1
y
0
)
By simply replacing y with x, the denominator in

1
can be expressed as (n
0
n
1
/n)( x
1
x
0
). When
we take the ratio of these, the terms involving n
0
, n
1
, and n, cancel, leaving

1
=
y
1
y
0
x
1
x
0
15.6 (i) Plugging (15.26) into (15.22) and rearranging gives
y
1
=
0
+
1
(
0
+
1
z
1
+
2
z
2
+ v
2
) +
2
z
1
+ u
1
=(
0
+
1

0
) + (
1

1
+
2
)z
1
+
1

2
z
2
+ u
1
+
1
v
2
and so
0
=
0
+
1

0
,
1
=
1

1
+
2
, and
2
=
1

2
.
(ii) From the equation in part (i), v
1
= u
1
+
1
v
2
.
(iii) By assumption, u
1
has zero mean and is uncorrelated with z
1
and z
2
, and v
2
has these properties
by denition. So v
1
has zero mean and is uncorrelated with z
1
and z
2
, which means that OLS
consistently estimates the
j
. [OLS would only be unbiased if we add the stronger assumptions
E(u
1
|z
1
, z
2
) = E(v
2
|z
1
, z
2
) = 0.]
15.7 I made some minor changes to the solution from the instructors manual
(i) Even at a given income level, some students are more motivated and more able than others, and
their families are more supportive (say, in terms of providing transportation) and enthusiastic
about education. Therefore, there is likely to be a self-selection problem: students that would do
better anyway were also more likely to attend a choice school.
(ii) Yes, since u
1
does not contain income, random assignment of grants within income class means
that grant designation is not correlated with unobservables such as student ability, motivation,
and family support.
(iii) The reduced form is
choice =
0
+
1
faminc +
2
grant + v
2
and we need
2
= 0. In other words, after accounting for income, the grant amount must have
some aect on choice. This seems reasonable, provided the grant amounts dier within each
income class.
(iv) To obtain the reduced form for score we simply substitute the reduced form for choice into the
equation of interest. This leads to an equation for score that is a linear function of the exogenous
variables. For suitably dened , we have:
score = 0 + 1faminc + 2grant + v1.
This equation allows us to directly estimate the eect of increasing the grant amount on the test
score, holding family income xed. From a policy perspective this is itself of some interest.
15.10 (i) Better and more serious students tend to go to college, and these same kinds of students may be
attracted to private and, in particular, Catholic high schools. The resulting correlation between
u and CathHS is another example of a self-selection problem: students self select toward Catholic
high schools, rather than being randomly assigned to them.
(ii) A standardized score is a measure of student ability, so this can be used as a proxy variable in
an OLS regression. Having this measure in an OLS regression should be an improvement over
having no proxies for student ability.
2
(iii) The rst requirement is that CathRe1 must be uncorrelated with unobserved student motivation
and ability (whatever is not captured by any proxies) and other factors in the error term. This
holds if growing up Catholic (as opposed to attending a Catholic high school) does not make you
a better student. It seems reasonable to assume that Catholics do not have more innate ability
than non-Catholics. Whether being Catholic is unrelated to student motivation, or preparation
for high school, is a thornier issue.
The second requirement is that being Catholic has an eect on attending a Catholic high school,
controlling for the other exogenous factors that appear in the structural model. This can be
tested by estimating the reduced form equation of the form CathHS =
0
+
1
CathRel +
(other exogenous factors) + (reduced form error)
(iv) Evans and Schwab (1995) nd that being Catholic substantially increases the probability of at-
tending a Catholic high school. Further, it seems that assuming CathRe1 is exogenous in the
structural equation is reasonable. See Evans and Schwab (1995) for an in-depth analysis.
B. Angrist and Krueger
12 points
Use the data set on the course web site to replicate the OLS and IV estimates of the returns to schooling
for the 1980 Census reported in Table V, Columns 1 through 4, of the paper by Angrist and Krueger (1991).
Organize your results into a table that has the same layout as Table V. Show both your results and the Angrist
and Krueger results side by side.
See do and log le. The results are identical to those in Angrist and Krueger. A good solution would
include a nice looking table of the results.
C. More Wooldridge
8 points each
16.1 (i) If
1
= 0 then y
1
=
1
z
1
+u
1
, and so the right-hand-side depends only on the exogenous variable
z
1
and the error term u
1
. This then is the reduced form for y
1
. If
1
= 0, the reduced form for
y
1
is y
1
=
2
z
2
+u
2
. (Note that having both
1
and
2
equal zero is not interesting as it implies
the bizarre condition u
2
u
1
=
1
z
1

2
z
2
.)
If
1
= 0 and
2
= 0, we can plug y
1
=
2
z
2
+ u
2
into the rst equation and solve for y
2
:

2
z
2
+ u
2
=
1
y
2
+
1
z
1
+ u
1
or

1
y
2
=
1
z
1

2
z
2
+ u
1
u
2
.
Dividing by
1
(because
1
= 0) gives
y
2
=(
1
/
1
)z
1
(
2
/
1
)z
2
+ (u
1
u
2
)/
1
=
21
z
1
+
22
z
2
+ v
2
where
21
=
1
/
1
,
22
=
2
/
1
, and v
2
= (u
1
u
2
)/
1
. Note that the reduced form for y
2
generally depends on z
1
and z
2
(as well as on u
1
and u
2
).
(ii) If we multiply the second structural equation by (
1
/2) and subtract it from the rst structural
equation, we obtain
y
1
(
1
/
2
)y
1
=
1
y
2

1
y
2
+
1
z
1
(
1
/
2
)
2
z
2
+ u
1
(
1
/
2
)u
2
=
1
z
1
(
1
/
2
)
2
z
2
+ u
1
(
1
/
2
)u
2
3
or
[
1
(
1
/
2
)]y
1
=
1
z
1
(
1
/
2
)
2
z
2
+ u
1
(
1
/
2
)u
2
.
Because
1
=
2
,
1
(
1
/
2
) = 0, and so we can divide the equation by
1
(
1
/
2
) to obtain the
reduced form for y
1
: y
1
=
11
z
1
+
12
z
2
+v
1
, where
11
=
1
/[1(
1
/
2
)],
12
= (
1
/
2
)
2
/[1
(
1
/
2
)], and v
1
= [u
1
(
1
/
2
)u
2
]/[1 (
1
/
2
)]. A reduced form does exist for y
2
, as can be
seen by subtracting the second equation from the rst:
0 = (
1

2
)y
2
+
1
z
1

2
z
2
+ u
1
u
2
;
because
1
=
2
, we can rearrange and divide by
1

2
to obtain the reduced form.
(iii) In supply and demand examples,
1
=
2
is very reasonable. If the rst equation is the supply
function, we generally expect
1
> 0, and if the second equation is the demand function,
2
< 0.
The reduced forms can exist even in cases where the supply function is not upward sloping and the
demand function is not downward sloping, but we might question the usefulness of such models.
16.2 Using simple economics, the rst equation must be the demand function, as it depends on income,
which is a common determinant of demand. The second equation contains a variable, rainfall, that
aects crop production and therefore corn supply.
16.5 (i) Other things equal, a higher rate of condom usage should reduce the rate of sexually transmitted
diseases (STDs). So
1
< 0.
(ii) If students having sex behave rationally, and condom usage does prevent STDs, then condom
usage should increase as the rate of infection increases.
(iii) If we plug the structural equation for infrate into conuse =
0
+
1
infrate+..., we see that conuse
depends on
1
u
1
. Because
1
> 0, conuse is positively related to u
1
. In fact, if the structural
error (u
2
) in the conuse equation is uncorrelated with u
1
, Cov(conuse, u
1
) =
1
V ar(u
1
) > 0. If
we ignore the other explanatory variables in the infrate equation, we can use equation (5.4) to
obtain the direction of bias: plim(

1
)
1
>0 because Cov(conuse, u
1
) > 0, where

1
denotes the
OLS estimator. Since we think
1
< 0, OLS is biased towards zero. In other words, if we use
OLS on the infrate equation, we are likely to underestimate the importance of condom use in
reducing STDs. (Remember, the more negative is
1
, the more eective is condom usage.)
(iv) We would have to assume that condis does not appear, in addition to conuse, in the infrate
equation. This seems reasonable, as it is usage that should directly aect STDs, and not just
having a distribution program. But we must also assume condis is exogenous in the infrate:
it cannot be correlated with unobserved factors (in u
1
) that also aect infrate. We must also
assume that condis has some partial eect on conuse, something that can be tested by estimating
the reduced form for conuse. It seems likely that this requirement for an IV see equations (15.30)
and (15.31) is satised.
D. Graddy and the Fulton Fish Market
24 points total, 6 for each part
This problem uses data from Graddys paper on the Fulton Fish Market. These are posted on the web
page.
(1)
.Combine the data for Asians and Whites in a single time series and construct 2SLS estimates of the elasticity
of overall demand for whiting. Your model should include day-of-the-week dummies as exogenous covariates.
Do this two ways:
4
(i) Manual 2SLS (i.e., run a second stage on rst-stage tted values with reg)
(ii) Using ivreg
See do and log les.
(2)
Compare the standard errors you got in (i) and (ii). What explains the dierence? Compare the 2SLS
estimates to OLS estimates. The two sets of point estimates are exactly the same, but the standard errors
dier. Manual 2SLS gives to the usual OLS standard errors, which fail to take into account the fact that p
is estimated. The standard errors of ivregress account for the uncertainty in p.
(3)
The quantity of sh sold seems to dier from day to day. What must be true for you to be able to use these
daily shifts to identify the supply equation? Using the day-of-the-week dummies as instruments, estimate the
supply elasticity by two-stage least squares (using ivreg). Do the results appear to make sense? Is there any
way you can test whether day of the week dummies are valid instruments for the supply equation? (Hint:
Wooldridge Section 15.5).
For the day of the week to be a valid instrument for supply, there must be no direct eect of day of the
week on quantity supplied. The estimated supply elasticity is about 3. It is very imprecisely estimated with
a standard error of 4. This elasticity is high, but that seems reasonable to me. In interpreting the estimate
it is important to think about what type of elasticity it estimates. In the very short run, the elasticity of
sh supply should be zero. If after shing, a sherman suddenly sees that demand is higher than expected,
then he can sell his sh for a higher price, but has no time to go out and catch more sh. However, if a
sherman knows that demand is going to be higher tomorrow, then he can sh longer today to increase
supply tomorrow. Hence, supply elasticity should be high for predictable changes in demand. Since the day
of the week is predictable, the supply elasticity in response to demand changes with the day of the week
should be high.
Since we have one endogenous variable, price, and four day of the week dummies as instruments, the
equation is over-identied, and we can test whether the instruments all give the same estimate. We do this
and fail to reject the null hypothesis that the instruments are valid with a p-value of 0.46.
(4)
Jointly estimate separate demand equations for Asians and Whites using 3SLS. Test whether the elasticities
are in fact equal across the two groups (use the test command). Discuss your results in light of the fact
that Asians appear to pay less for sh than whites.
The estimated elasticity for whites is -1 and for Asians is -1.5. A price discriminating rm would charge a
higher price to less-elastic customers, so these elasticities are consistent with the the fact that Asians appear
to pay less. However, the estimated dierence in elasticities is not statistically signicant.
E. Extra Credit
20 points total, 4 from each part
More on class size.
1
(This problem uses the same class size data you used to do question B in problem
set III; these data are posted in the Angrist Data Archive).
1
This problems illustrates the regression discontinuity method of causal inference
5
(1) Recap
Regress math and verbal scores on class size. Add controls for Percent Disadvantaged and enrollment in
grade. How and why do the class size eects change when you add controls?
Without controls, larger class sizes are associated with higher test scores. This is the opposite of what
most people believe. We think that smaller classes should lead to better results. With controls, the coecient
on class size is nearly zero. This suggests that larger class sizes are associated with other things that raise
test scores.
(2)
In Israel, class size is capped at integer multiples of 40. In other words, if there are 40 kids in your grade,
youre in a class of 40 (usually), but if there are 41, the class is (usually) split. Assuming a new class is
added every time enrollment exceeds an integer multiple of 40 generates the following predicted class size
variable for class size in a school with enrollment e
s
z
s
= e
s
/[INT(e
s
/40) +1] Angrist and Lavy (1999) use
z
s
as an instrumental variable for class size in regressions of test scores on enrollment and class size. They
call z
s
Maimonides Rule, because the medieval Talmudic scholar Moses Maimonides proposed that class size
be capped at 40..
(i) Explain the rationale for this IV strategy
A valid instrument must be correlated with class size and uncorrelated with unobservables that aect
tests scores. Clearly, predicted class size, z
s
, should be correlated with actual class size. Also, since z
s
is a function enrollment, and we can control for enrollment, it is reasonable to think that z
s
would be
uncorrelated with unobservables aecting test scores.
(ii) Why is it a good idea to control for enrollment when using z
s
as an instrumental variable?
It is a good idea to control for enrollment because otherwise z
s
would be unlikely to exogenous. z
s
is clearly correlated with enrollment. From the above, enrollment appears to be correlated with test
scores. If we do not control for enrollment, then it becomes part of the error term, and z
s
would be
correlated with the error, making IV inconsistent.
(3)
Replicate the reduced form estimates in Angrist and Lavy (1999) Table III, Columes 1-6 of Panel A.
See do and log les.
(4)
Replicate the 2SLS estimates corresponding to these reduced form estimates
See do and log les.
(5)
Why do you think the 2SLS estimates show benets from reducing class size while the OLS estimates do not,
even with controls? Because there are unobserved variables that are correlated with class size that aect
test scores.
6

Das könnte Ihnen auch gefallen