Sie sind auf Seite 1von 23

1

Political instability, political regimes and economic performance in


African countries
Jean-Claude Berthlemy*, Cline Kauffmann
+
, Laurence Renard and Lucia Wegner
+
First draft, 11 March 2002
Abstract
This paper is based on the work carried out for the African Economic Outlook (2002),
joint report recently published by the African Development Bank (ADB) and the OECD
Development Centre. The original data are computed from the weekly newspaper
Marchs Tropicaux et Mditerranens. The paper uses the methodology first proposed by
Dessus, Lafay and Morrisson in A Politico-economic Model for Stabilisation in Africa
(Journal of African Economies, 1994). The qualitative information obtained from
Marchs Tropicaux et Mditerranens is used to construct three indicators referring to:
1. Political instability: based on occurrence of strikes, demonstrations, violence and
coup dtat.
2. An index of the softening of the political regime derived from information on releases
of political prisoners, measures in favour of human rights, decisions promoting
democracy, lifting of bans on demonstrations and public debates.
3. A measure of hardening of the political regime based on incarcerations of opponents,
measures threatening democracy such as dissolution of political parties, violence
perpetrated by the police and the banning of demonstrations or public debates.
The resulting database covers 22 African countries over the ADB 5 sub-regions of Africa
in order to reach a sample representative of the continent, on a weekly basis from January
1996 to December 2001. Quarterly data is then computed to study the relationship
between political unrest and the nature of the political regime while annual data is used to
investigate the political and economic dynamics.
The paper suggests a strong correlation between conflict and political regime. It also
conveys the idea that economic performance in Africa interacts deeply with political
factors.
* Universit Paris I Panthon Sorbonne, France and OECD Development Centre
+
OECD Development Centre
Universit Paris I Panthon Sorbonne, France
The OECD, the OECD Development Center and their member governments are not
responsible for the 4opinions expressed in this paper.
2
1. Introduction
Preventing conflicts is becoming a widespread objective in Africa as recent international
evidence show an increase of crime and violence in developing countries and negative
spillovers for neighboring economies are highlighted. Both at the international level
(through the recent focus of World Bank on conflict and the work on helping prevent
violent conflict at OECD Development Assistance Committee, DAC) and regionally
(through the NEPAD, New Partnership for African Development), awareness of the
dreadful effects of conflict is rising and the need for prevention tools is underlined.
Preventing conflict requires a good knowledge of the interaction between the economic
sphere and the political one, as well as the dynamic of political decisions. It implies
access to indicators that are informative about the risks of running into conflicts and that
allow a close monitoring of fragile/unstable countries. DAC relates those risk indicators
to the following aspects:
- loss of political space for opposition, civil society and media
- social, economic and political exclusion
- unemployment, especially among youth
- impoverishment
- increasing inequalities
- human rights violations
- increasing insecurities
- migratory flows
In this paper, we present a set of three political indicators based on the series of events
displayed below. Those indicators allow us to investigate on a quarterly basis the
dynamic of political institutions, their adaptation to social and political unrest and the
resulting impact on economic performance for 22 African countries over a 6-year period,
from 1996 to 2001. The objective is not to address the issue of conflicts in countries that
are already affected, but to offer early warning and risk indicators for countries that are
3
still relatively stable. As such, none of the countries covered by the paper are in a
situation of open war, although one or two might drift towards such a situation.
1. Political instability: based on occurrence of strikes, demonstrations, violence and
coup dEtat.
2. An index of the softening of the political regime derived from information on releases
of political prisoners, measures in favour of human rights, decisions promoting
democracy, lifting of bans on demonstrations and public debates.
3. A measure of hardening of the political regime based on incarcerations of opponents,
measures threatening democracy such as dissolution of political parties, violence
perpetuated by police and banning of demonstrations or public debates.
As opposed to the traditional literature on this issue, our approach is not static.
Traditionally, the empirical papers consider the impact of political characteristics on the
economic performance or the politico-economic characteristics of countries at war. Here,
we investigate the responses of the institutions to political and social unrest, namely
whether the government chooses to respond by a softening or a hardening of the regime,
and their implications at the institutional level and for economic performance.
The traditional approach is also partial as it mainly considers causality of political factors
on economic performance, more rarely the reverse and even more rarely the correlation
between institutional variables. The study of political factors is usually left to political
sciences. This paper deals with the dynamic of political responses to political instability
as well as their consequences for economic growth. We use causality tests to investigate
the relationship between instability and the softening/hardening of the regime.
Most empirical papers on political environment and economic performance rely on yearly
and aggregated data as a result of the constraint on macro-economic data. However, our
dataset allows us to follow the countries on a quarterly basis. It also provides us with
4
more detailed information on political institutions as the data are computed from events
and do not derive from the perception of the democratic profile of the power.
In section 2, we survey the previous literature. Section 3 provides details on the quarterly
data set on political events that we have built. Section 4 is devoted to tests of causality
between political instability and political decisions made by the governments; it shows a
bi-directional causality between political troubles and political hardening by the
government. Based on annualized data, section 5 studies complementary economic
determinants of political instability while section 6 studies the reverse impact of political
instability on investment and economic growth. Section 7 concludes.
2. The literature on political environment and economic performance
The literature on the subject is relatively abundant on 2 aspects: civil wars and the impact
of political background on economic performance. Whereas the first kind of papers
tackles the issue of the incidence of conflicts, the causes and consequences of wars in
countries that are affected, the second type of paper investigates the interaction between
economic performance and political developments. Since this paper does not focus on
countries at war, it then belongs to the second strand.
Political context and economic performance
Since North (1991), several economic papers have underlined the importance of the
political environment for promoting economic development. Sound political institutions
are believed to foster economic transactions mainly by reducing risks. However,
controversies arise on what sound political institutions means and on the channels
through which they impact economic performance.
The uncertainty concerning the concept and the impact of democracy
5
Of the two questions that arise from the debate on sound political institutions, one
focuses on the generic notion of democracy as a synonymous for sound institutions. But,
although democracy has been largely studied in the economic literature there is little
agreement on its impact on economic performance. Barro (1991) and zler and Rodrik
(1992) disclose a significant and positive correlation between political freedom and
economic performance. By contrast, Alesina and Perotti (1994) can not highlight any
impact of democracy on growth, while Barro (1996) suggests a non-linear relationship,
too much and not enough democracy being harmful to growth.
Such uncertainty is largely due to the fact that the concept of democracy covers many
different realities and that apart from sharing a common poll system, democracies differ
widely in their characteristics. As democracy, as well as dictatorship, reveals itself too
broad a concept, one has to go down to the desaggregated features of the political regimes
to be able to pin down properly the impact of political environment on economic
development. In this paper, we consider three features of political institutions: hardening
of the regime, softening of the regime and political instability, of which only the last one
has been studied so far in the literature.
The role of political instability
There is almost a consensus concerning the impact of political instability on growth,
although the concept of instability itself is rather ambiguous. It covers both legal changes
of heads of state and governments and violent take-overs. Whereas the first one refers to
political changeover, the second one is more appropriately related to instability and has a
broadly acknowledged negative impact on economic growth. That second concept
includes elite instability, as defined by Fosu (1992)
1
, as well as less dramatic events
linked to social unrest (demonstrations, political violence). Considering data availability,
this paper mainly tackles the second sense of the concept of political instability.

1
It comprises for instance coup dEtat as well as political plots.
6
The negative correlation between political instability and growth can be explained
through impaired production factors accumulation and efficiency, as underlined by Fosu
(1992) and Dixit and Pindick (1994). Instability prevents political institutions from
ensuring property rights, which in turn increases the probability that returns on
investment are expropriated. As a result of higher risk, less investment is undertaken.
Fosu (1992) shows that the same applies to human capital accumulation, as political
instability might cause brain drain. In extreme cases of instability like revolutions or
coups dtat, Fosu (1992) argues that breaks in the production process might occur,
reducing directly the level of GDP. Moreover, the impact on production-factor
accumulation can also be accompanied by a negative influence on their productivity.
Indeed, the effect of investment and human capital accumulation on growth performance
is likely to depend on the institutional context as efficiency of production factors is
certainly improved in a stable environment.
Another channel through which political instability affects economic performance relates
to political economy and consists in the reduction of time horizon that politicians might
suffer when instability is high. In a context of high instability, politicians tend to avoid
structural reforms and lead wait-and-see policies instead in order to limit disagreement
with the population and the other political parties. A government can also choose to
pursue the same economic policy in spite of all the evidence, in order to defeat its
opponents. Such schemes have been developed in the political economic literature by
Alesina and Tabellini (1989), Cukierman, Edwards and Tabellini (1992) and Ozler and
Tabellini (1991). Following the same perspective, Clague, Keefer, Knack and Olson
(1996) consider that short-term perspectives are not likely to help policy makers keep
their commitments, while Murphy, Shleifer and Vishny (1991) and Terrones (1990)
underline that a government threatened by instability may be tempted to use corruption to
insure the loyalty of the bodies that might help it to remain in power like the police, the
army, the administration...
Despite the diversity of the datasets as well as the methodologies used, the empirical
studies suggest a significant negative correlation between political instability and
7
economic growth (Barro, 1991, Alesina, zler, Roubini and Swagel, 1996, Azam,
Berthlemy and Calipel, 1996). Guillaumont, Guillaumont and Brun (1999) goes even
further, showing that political instability combined with trade instability are the main
factors behind the poor economic performance of African countries on 1970-1990.
The channels
Concerning the channels, there is debate whether institutions affect economic
performance directly or more indirectly, through production-factor efficiency and the
establishment of an environment conducive for business. The inconclusive impact of
democracy on growth points towards an indirect influence, as underlined by Tavares and
Wacziarg (1997). The authors then turn towards more complex models than the
traditional Barro one equation specification to justify the interlink between the
economic and the political spheres. To that purpose, they systematically investigate nine
channels through which they assume democracy might affect growth, using a
simultaneous equations model. Two channels emerge as highly influential: through
human capital accumulation and through political stability.
Fosu (1992) insists on the role of human capital accumulation as the channel through
which political instability affects growth. He proves his point using multiplied
(interactive) variables in the specification. De Haan and Siemann (1996) show that the
impact through investment prevails since adding up and withdrawing this variable from
the equation heavily influence the results. However, Guillaumont, Guillaumont and Brun
(1999) question these results in the case of African countries and show that political
instability, defined as a combination of coups dtat and foreign/civil wars, directly
affects the residuals of the growth equation.
The determinants of political context
The channels are not the only issues at stake in the debate about political institutions and
economic performance. Causality is also a major concern. Limongi and Przeworki (1993)
8
justify the unclear impact of democracy on economic performance through
methodological problems. They argue that it is impossible to compare the incidence of
democracy and dictatorship holding everything else constant providing that dictatorships
develop more easily when the economic situation is difficult. But because most studies
limit the analysis to the impact of political factors on economic performance, completely
overlooking one side of the relationship, they face simultaneity and endogeneity
problems. By contrast, Limongi and Przeworki (1993) suggest that the economic context
has a significant influence on the development of the institutions and might help
justifying the settling of democracy.
The economic determinants of institutions
The economic determinants of the political context have been little investigated in the
economic literature. After Lipset (1959), economic development has been seen as an
important factor in promoting political stability and democracy according to the argument
that in wealthy societies, redistribution conflicts are defused. By contrast, the correlation
between economic growth and political context remains unclear. While weak economic
performance is likely to spark redistribution conflicts, a strong growth might destabilise
the economy. At the empirical level, Barro (1996) and Tavares and Wacziarg (1997)
confirmed the Lipset hypothesis on a cross section of countries and on panel data
respectively while Alesina, zler, Roubini and Swager (1996) did not find any evidence
of a negative impact of a weak growth rate on political stability, underlining the
contradictory effects of growth.
The political factors
Among the political determinants of the institutional environment, democracy is
considered to help strengthen political stability. Democracy involves rules and opposition
force that reduce the risk of arbitrary decisions. Clague, Keefer, Knack and Olson (1996)
underline that a democratic system is more likely to ensure the respect of property rights
and the enforcement of contracts. Going back to Weber (1922), one can also argue that
9
turnovers under democracies are less likely to bring political unrest since they are
regulated by a legal framework. However, if democracy strengthens political stability,
political stability is symmetrically more likely to help democracy settle. Few empirical
studies tackle the interaction between the economic and the political spheres at a global
level, taking into account the correlation between political factors. Among those
frameworks, Tavars and Wacziarg (1997) and Poirson (1998) confirm the negative
correlation between democracy and political instability.
3. Construction of political indicators
In order to both follow through the political developments in the countries under study in
the African Economic Outlook (2002), recently published by the African Development
Bank and the OECD, and to assess the interaction between the institutional context and
economic performance, three political indicators were computed. They were built on
information taken from the weekly newspaper Marchs Tropicaux et Mditerranens
according to a methodology first proposed by Dessus, Lafay and Morisson (1994). The
qualitative information derived from the newspaper was either computed as 0-1 variables
with 0 being the non-occurrence of the event and 1 its occurrence or as 4-value indicators
(with 0: non-occurrence, 1: occurrence but weak intensity, 2: medium intensity and 3:
strong intensity). From these indicators, the three following main political indexes were
constructed: an index of political instability and social unrest, a measure of the softening
of the political regime and one of its hardening.
Political instability
Strikes
0 = non-occurrence,
1 = 1 strike or number of strikers lower than 1 000 (included),
2 = 2 strikes or number of strikers between 1 000 and 5 000 (included),
3 = 3 strikes or number of strikers strictly higher than 5 000.
Unrest and violence (number of dead and injured)
Dead 0 = none,
10
1 = between 1 and 10 (not included),
2 = between 10 and 100 (not included),
3 = higher than 100.
Injured 0 = none,
1 = between 1 and 50 (not included) or if the number of dead is between 1
and 10,
2 = between 50 and 500 (not included) or if the number of dead is between
10 and 100,
3 = higher than 500 or if the number of dead exceeds 100.
Demonstrations
0 = non-occurrence,
1 = 1 demonstration or number of strikers lower than 5 000 (not included),
2 = 2 demonstrations or number of strikers between 5 000 and 10 000 (not included),
3 = 3 demonstrations or number of strikers higher than 10 000.
Coup dtat and attempted coup dtat
Softening of the political regime
Lifting of state of emergency
Releases of political prisoners
Measures in favour of human rights
Improvement of political governance (fight against corruption)
Relinquishment of political persecution, rehabilitation, return from exile
Political opening (measures in favour of democracy)
1 = Discussion with the opposition,
2 = Entry of the opposition to power,
3 = Opening of a regime to elections.
Lifting of bans on strikes or demonstration
Lifting of bans on press or public debates
11
Hardening of the political regime
State of emergency
Arrests, incarcerations
0 = non-occurrence,
1 = between 1 and 10 (not included),
2 = between 10 and 100 (not included),
3 = higher than 100.
Additional resources for the police, propaganda or censorship
Toughening of the political environment (expulsions, dismissals, curfew, dissolution
of political parties)
Violence perpetuated by the police (number of dead and injured)
Dead 0 = none,
1 = between 1 and 10 (not included),
2 = between 10 and 100 (not included),
3 = higher or equal to 100.
Injured 0 = none,
1 = between 1 and 50 (not included),
2 = between 50 and 500 (not included),
3 = higher or equal to 500.
Prosecutions, executions
Bans on strikes and demonstrations
Bans on press or public debates
Closing of schools
Forced demonstrations
The data were collected for the countries covered by the African Economic Outlook
report (2002) as tools to precisely follow through the political developments in those
countries. The sample is then highly driven by the reasons that prevailed in the choice of
the report coverage. That coverage includes Botswana, Burkina Faso, Cameroon, Chad,
Cte dIvoire, Egypt, Equatorial Guinea, Ethiopia, Gabon, Ghana, Kenya, Mali,
12
Mauritius, Morocco, Mozambique, Namibia, Nigeria, Senegal, South Africa, Tanzania,
Uganda and Zimbabwe. The most important countries in each of the continents five
regions as defined by the African Development Bank
2
are among them as well as smaller
countries to make the sample more representative. Nations involved in civil war have
been left out mainly because of logistical problems. Consequently Central African
countries are the least represented countries among Sub-Saharan countries. Similarly, the
reports look at North Africa, economically rather different from the rest of Africa, is
limited to the two strongest economies: Egypt and Morocco. Overall, the sample accounts
for 2/3 of the continents GDP and ! of its population.
The resulting database, firstly computed on a weekly basis corresponding to the
periodicity of Marchs Tropicaux et Mditerranens , was then aggregated on a
quarterly basis in order to proceed with the statistical analysis. The weekly format would
not be appropriate because of a lack of variance as the information collected on such a
desagregated basis is very scarce.
A principal component analysis was undertaken in order to determine the set of relevant
weights for the qualitative variables within the synthetic indexes. To that purpose, the
dimensions of the different indicators were made homogenous. All 4-value indicators
were split into 3 binary variables with one representing the occurrence of the event with
weak intensity, the second binary indicator including weak and medium intensity and the
third one the strong intensity.
Table 1 - Weights in Conflicts
low medium high
Strike 0.53 0.55 0.59
Dead 0.76 0.79 0.79
Injured 0.77 0.80 0.80
Demonstration 0.61 0.63 0.64
Coup d'tat and attempt 0.19

2
The five regions under consideration are North Africa, Western Africa, Central Africa, Eastern Africa and
Southern Africa.
13
Table 2 - Weights in Softening of the political regime
low medium high
Lifting of state of emergency 0.05
Releases of political prisoners 0.19
Measures in favor of human rights 0.14
Improvement of political governance 0.32
Relinquishment of political persecution 0.11
Political opening 0.95 0.96 0.96
Lifting of bans on strikes or public debates 0.14
Table 3 - Weights in Hardening of the political regime
low medium high
State of emergency non-significant
Violence perpetuated by the police: Dead 0.23 0.26 0.26
Injured 0.91 0.92 0.93
Arrests 0.43 0.47 0.47
Additional resources for the police non-significant
Toughening of the political environment 0.20
Prosecutions, executions 0.09
Bans on strikes and demonstrations 0.47
Closing of schools 0.20
Forced demonstration non-significant
4. The interaction between political instability and political hardening
Political instability is in practice the result of a combination of events that leads to social
and political discontent. Among those factors, the political behaviour of the government
plays a leading role. Very often, discontent is spurred by government decisions against
political freedom. As a matter of fact, between 1996 and 2001, political tensions were
highly correlated with more repressive political decisions in the countries under study.
However, a reverse causation is also plausible if governments themselves decide to
harden their policies in response to political dispute. In order to test these hypotheses, we
have performed Granger tests, which show that the correlation between political
instability and hardening of the regime is in fact bi-directional. As a consequence,
political hardening and political instability reinforce each other. However, no correlation
and no causality are found between instability and softening of the political regime
(results not shown).
14
These tests should be preferably performed at the national level, considering that each
political system has its own dynamic behaviour. However, the number of observations
constrains our causality tests. Therefore, we combine a global test, assembling all 22
countries, and tests performed at the regional level. Most of these tests provide significant
results. The smallness of our North African and Central African samples helps explain
the lack of significance of the tests for these regions.
Table 4 Results of the Granger causality tests
Instability => Hardening Hardening => Instability Sample
Number of
observations
Opt. lag F-stat Opt. lag F-stat
Overall 462 3 16.2 (.00) 3 15.1 (.00)
Western Africa 138 1 7.3 (.01) Non significant
Eastern Africa 115 1 13.4 (.00) 2 6.8 (.01)
Central Africa 92 Non significant Non significant
South Africa 115 3 15.4 (.00) 3 22.4 (.00)
North Africa 46 Non significant Non significant
Table 5 reports the corresponding estimated parameters for both causal regressions run on
the overall sample. These results suggest a bigger impact of political hardening on
instability than of instability on hardening: computed long term parameters are equal to
1.33 for the impact of hardening on instability and only 0.09 for the reverse impact. The
smallness of the latter parameter suggests that the interaction between both variables will
usually end up in a stable equilibrium, rather than in an unstable one, which would drive
the economy in a vicious circle. This means that the mechanism uncovered by our data
does not, in itself, lead to open conflicts. It may, however, exacerbate conflicts arising
from political and economic shocks or mismanagement.
15
Table 5 Estimated parameter for the overall regressions
Political instability Hardening of the regime
Intercept 1.37 0.51
(4.1) (4.6)
Lagged dependent variable 0.3 0.22
-7.6 (4.9)
Lags of Hardening/Instability
-1 -0.17 -0.007
(1.1) (-0.5)
-2 0.63 0.02
(4.6) (1.6)
-3 0.47 0.06
(3.4) (5.1)
T-stat in parenthesis.
Some examples of the interactions between political instability and government policy
may illustrate our results. As displayed in the following graphs, political instability has
resulted in a reaction from the authorities in the case of Cte dIvoire during 1996, for
Zimbabwe in 1998 and for Egypt and Chad throughout the period. Reciprocally, Nigeria
displays a situation in which the hardening of the regime clearly explains the occurrence
of political troubles, a pattern that also seems to be followed by Zimbabwe at the end of
the period. South Africa exhibits contemporaneous correlation due to the immediate
repression exerted by the authorities at the time of the troubles (mainly demonstrations
and strikes).
16
Chart 1. Political instability and hardening of the regime in 6 African countries
Cte d Ivoire Zimbabwe
South Africa Chad
Egypt Nigeria
Legend: --- Political instability ! Hardening of the political regime
0
5
10
15
20
25
30
35
9
6
-1
9
6
-2
9
6
-3
9
6
-4
9
7
-1
9
7
-2
9
7
-3
9
7
-4
9
8
-1
9
8
-2
9
8
-3
9
8
-4
9
9
-1
9
9
-2
9
9
-3
9
9
-4
0
0
-1
0
0
-2
0
0
-3
0
0
-4
0
1
-0
1
0
1
-0
2
0
1
-0
3
0
1
-0
4
0
5
10
15
20
25
30
9
6
-1
9
6
-2
9
6
-3
9
6
-4
9
7
-1
9
7
-2
9
7
-3
9
7
-4
9
8
-1
9
8
-2
9
8
-3
9
8
-4
9
9
-1
9
9
-2
9
9
-3
9
9
-4
0
0
-1
0
0
-2
0
0
-3
0
0
-4
0
1
-0
1
0
1
-0
2
0
1
-0
3
0
1
-0
4
0
10
20
30
40
50
60
70
9
6
-1
96-2
9
6
-3
9
6
-4
97-1
9
7
-2
9
7
-3
97-4
9
8
-1
9
8
-2
98-3
98-4
9
9
-1
9
9
-2
99-3
9
9
-4
0
0
-1
00-2
0
0
-3
0
0
-4
01-01
0
1
-0
2
0
1
-0
3
01-04
0
2
4
6
8
10
12
9
6
-1
9
6
-2
96-3
96-4
97-1
9
7
-2
9
7
-3
9
7
-4
98-1
98-2
98-3
9
8
-4
9
9
-1
9
9
-2
9
9
-3
99-4
00-1
0
0
-2
0
0
-3
0
0
-4
01-01
01-02
01-03
0
1
-0
4
0
5
10
15
20
25
30
35
40
45
9
6
-1
9
6
-2
9
6
-3
96-4
9
7
-1
9
7
-2
97-3
9
7
-4
9
8
-1
98-2
9
8
-3
9
8
-4
99-1
9
9
-2
9
9
-3
99-4
0
0
-1
0
0
-2
00-3
0
0
-4
0
1
-0
1
0
1
-0
2
01-03
0
1
-0
4
0
5
10
15
20
25
30
35
40
9
6
-1
9
6
-2
9
6
-3
9
6
-4
9
7
-1
9
7
-2
9
7
-3
9
7
-4
9
8
-1
9
8
-2
9
8
-3
9
8
-4
9
9
-1
9
9
-2
9
9
-3
9
9
-4
0
0
-1
0
0
-2
0
0
-3
0
0
-4
0
1
-0
1
0
1
-0
2
0
1
-0
3
0
1
-0
4
0
0.5
1
1.5
2
2.5
3
3.5
17
5. Economic factors explaining political instability
Our results in previous section are only partial, as other variables may explain political
instability. It is in particular tempting to test whether economic variables affect political
instability. This is what is attempted in this section, again based on the data collected by
the African Development Bank and the OECD for producing the African Economic
Outlook. In doing so, we face an inevitable limitation, which is the lack of quarterly
economic data. Therefore, we use a panel data estimation, based on yearly data (1996-
2001) for our 22 countries. Results are reported in Table 6.
Table 6 - Political instability
Political instability
Hardening(-1) 1.49 (6.02)
Growth (value) -15.56 (-1.81)
Western Africa 7.27 (2.03)
Southern Africa 5.73 (1.53)
C .84 (.2)
Nb of observations 110
Adjusted R" .40
T-stat in parenthesis.
As seen earlier, political instability is partly driven by the hardening of the regime. It is
worth noting that the lagged value of political instability does not have a significant
impact on its current level when included in the regression, while it was significant on a
quarterly basis. This suggests that there is only a short period of persistence of political
instability. Moreover, the parameter of Hardening, 1.49, is close to the long run value of
the impact of Hardening on Instability computed from Table 5 (1.33). Although they are
based on data with different frequencies, our analysis in this section and in previous
section are therefore consistent.
In addition, the econometric test suggests that political factors are not only affected by
political shocks but also by economic performance since growth displays a significant
impact on political instability. Faster growing countries are less likely to experience
political instability. While the literature on the subject does not provide any clear results,
our tests show that for the African countries represented in our sample, growth has
18
softened troubles instead of exacerbating them over the last 6 years. However, the
relevant economic performance estimator is not the GDP growth in volume, but an
indicator of growth in value, underlying the importance of shocks on revenues in
explaining the discontent of the population. The impact of volume growth is much less
significant (regression not shown).
6. Impact of instability on investment and growth
Going back to the ideas developed in the literature, one may want to check whether, in
our dataset, political instability affects growth performance. The econometric tests carried
out on our sample suggest that there is no direct impact of political factors (instability,
hardening or softening) on growth but two indirect channels: through private investment
and through a break in the coefficients in the growth equation.
Table 7 - Private investment
Private Investment
Growth 2.3 (3.7)
Instability -.01 (-1.8)
Western Africa .12 (.84)
Eastern Africa .24 (1.65)
Southern Africa .09 (.64)
Northern Africa .32 (1.45)
c -2.20 (-14.2)
Nb of observations 132
Adjusted R" .19
T-stat in parenthesis.
Political instability has a direct negative impact on the accumulation of private
investment. This effect does not hold for public investment highlighting the fact that the
two types of investment respond to different incentives. Private investment is highly
sensitive to the institutional environment and the performance of the economy, hence
justifying that both growth and instability are highly significant in the regression. On the
contrary, public investment is a tool in the hands of the government to compensate for the
lack of private investment and as such may have counter-cyclical behaviour.
19
Chart 2. Private Investment and Political Tension
Political instability affects growth by hindering physical capital accumulation. It may also
affect growth indirectly through the returns of investment, or directly through total factor
productivity. Although political instability has no linear impact on growth (result not
shown), a simple Chow test shows that the structural parameters of the growth equation
are highly dependent on the level of troubles experienced by the countries. The break in
the coefficients was tested in a systematic way by using all levels of political instability
available in the database as potential thresholds. The Chow test was then performed on
the sub-samples generated by such thresholds. It provided us with a series of Fisher
statistics that helped us decide the relevance of a structural break and its occurrence in
terms of the level of political instability. The cut-off point was inferred for the highest
Fisher statistics. As a result, the strongest difference was found between countries with
and without instability, rather than between countries with different levels of trouble.
Countries experiencing no political troubles display much higher returns to investment
(structural parameter around 0.13) than countries with troubles (0.03). As a consequence,
Mauritius
Senegal
Mozambique
South Africa
Nigeria
Egypt
Cte d'Ivoire
Equatorial Guinea
Gabon
Chad
Tanzania
Uganda
0.00
0.10
0.20
0.30
0.40
0.50
0.60
0.70
0.00 10.00 20.00 30.00 40.00 50.00 60.00 70.00
political tension
p
r
i
v
a
t
e

i
n
v
e
s
t
m
e
n
t
s
20
not only political instability hinders physical capital accumulation, it also alters its
efficiency by reducing the impact of investment on growth.
Table 8 - Growth equation
Growth No troubles Troubles
Private Investment .04 (3.9) .13 (2.2) .03 (5.4)
North Africa .15 (6.6) .17 (2.8) .07 (4.7)
Oil producer .05 (3.0) .04 (0.5) .03 (3.8)
C .13 (4.9) .30 (2.3) .12 (8.7)
Nb of observations 132 36 96
Adjusted R" .45 .48 .53
Chow test F(2,128)=20.53 (.000)
T-stat in parenthesis.
Consistently, the following graph shows clearly that over the period under study the
trouble-free countries have experienced faster growth rates than the countries with
political unrest. The only counter-example is 1996 for which there is no evidence of
significantly different growth rates for both samples.
Chart 3. Economic growth and political instability
0
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001
No troubles troubles
21
7. Concluding remarks
This paper aimed at providing tools to both follow through and assess the dynamic of
political institutions, their adaptation to political unrest and the resulting interaction with
economic performance. Those tools were designed in the context of the African
Economic Outlook project on a sample of 22 African countries over 1996-2001 and
encompass three political indicators: political instability, hardening and softening of the
regime. Simple descriptive analysis and econometrics on these indicators have clarified
the dynamics of institutions and highlighted a high degree of interaction between political
context and economic performance.
As illustrated by Granger causality tests, the 22 African countries covered in our analysis
have experienced a bi-directional causality between political instability and hardening of
the regime, suggesting that not only social unrest might lead to a hardening of the
political stance of the government, but also that the behaviour of the leadership plays a
key role in explaining the discontent of the population. It also appears that political
softening does not create a reverse impact, suggesting the existence of a sort of hysteresis
impact of political hardening.
Moreover, the econometric tests carried out suggest that political developments are not
only driven by political events but are closely related to economic factors. For instance,
growth seems to have softened political instability for the 22 African countries of our
sample over 1996-2001, since countries that have experienced faster growth have been
less exposed to troubles.
Furthermore, the analysis on the reverse impact of political instability on investment and
economic growth reveals that political tensions have a direct negative impact on the
accumulation of private investments, affecting growth indirectly. Troubles also affect
growth indirectly through a significant negative impact on the productivity of investment.
It is shown, using a chow test, that countries experiencing no political instability display
higher returns to investment than countries politically very unstable.
22
8. References
A.Alesina, S.Ozler, N.Roubini and P.Swagel, Political Instability and Economic Growth,
Journal of Economic growth1 (June), pp.189-211, 1996
A.Alesina and R.Perotti, The Political Economy of Growth: A Critical Survey of the
Recent Literature, The World Bank Economic Review 8(3), pp 351-371, 1994
A.Alesina and G.Tabellini, External Debt, Capital Flight and Political Risk, Journal of
International Economics 27(3-4), pp 199-220, 1989
J.P.Azam, J.C.Berthelemy and S.Calipel, Risque Politique et Croissance in Afrique,
Revue Economique, 47, pp 819-29, 1996
R.J.Barro, Economic Growth in a Cross Section of Countries, Quarterly Journal of
Economics 106(2), 1991
R.J.Barro, Democracy and Growth, Journal of Economic Growth; 1(1), pp 1-27, March
1996
C.Clague, P.Keefer, S.Knack and M.Olson, Property and contract rights in autocracies
and democracies, journal of Economic Growth 1(2), pp243-276, 1996
A.Cukierman, S.Edwards and G.Tabellini, Seignorage and Political Instability, American
Economic Review 82, pp 537-555, 1992
J.De-Haan, C-L. Siermann, Central Bank Independence, Inflation and Political
Instability in Developing Countries,Journal-of-Policy-Reform; 1(2), pp 135-
47,1996.
S.Dessus, J-D.Lafay, and C.Morrison, A Politico-economic Model for Stabilisation in
Africa, Journal of African Economies, Vol.7, 1, pp 91-119, 1994
DAC Guidelines, Helping Prevent Violent Conflict, OECD, 2001
A.K.Fosu, Political instability and economic growth: evidence form sub-Saharan Africa.
Economic Development and Cultural change 40 (4), pp 829 841, 1992.
P.Guillaumont, S.Guillaumont and J-F.Brun, How Instability Lowers African Growth,
Journal of African Economies 8(1), pp 87-107, 1999
F.Limongi, A.Przeworski, Political Regimes and Economic Growth, Journal-of-
Economic-Perspectives; 7(3), pp 51-69, Summer 1993.
S.M.Lipset, Some Social Requisites of Democracy: Economic Development and Political
Legitimacy, American Political Science Review (1959).
23
K.Murphy, A.Shleifer and R.Vishny, The Allocation of Talent: Implications for Growth,
Quarterly Journal of Economics 106(2), pp 503-530, 1991
D.North, Institutions, Journal of Economic Perspectives 5(1), pp 97-112, 1991
S.Ozler and D.Rodrik, External Shocks, Politics, and Private Investment: Some Theory
and Empirical Evidence, Journal of Development Economics 39(1), pp 141-162,
1992
S.Ozler and G.Tabellini, External Debt and Political Instability, NBER Working Paper,
1991
H.Poirson, Essais en Economie de la Croissance and du Dveloppement, Thse de
Doctorat, Ecole des Hautes Etudes en Sciences Sociales, 1998
J.Tavars and R.Wacziarg, How Democracy Fosters Growth, Working Paper, Harvard
University, 1996
M.Terrones, Influence Activities and Economic Growth, unpublished, 1990
M.Weber, Economie et Socit, Plon 1971, 1922

Das könnte Ihnen auch gefallen