Sie sind auf Seite 1von 11

JOURNAL OF THE AMERICAN WATER RESOURCES ASSOCIATION

OCTOBER AMERICAN WATER RESOURCES ASSOCIATION 2003

WATER TRANSFERS AND THEIR IMPACTS: LESSONS


FROM THREE COLORADO WATER MARKETS1

Charles W. Howe and Christopher Goemans2

ABSTRACT: This paper presents an analysis of the effects of differ- already so highly regulated that added storage would
ent institutional arrangements and economic environments on decrease yields. Thus it is important that water be
water markets. Characteristics of water rights transfers in the
South Platte Basin of Colorado and transfers of shares of the
transferable from older, lower valued uses to newer,
Northern Colorado Water Conservancy District (NCWCD) are com- higher valued uses, especially because roughly 85 per-
pared to show how different institutional arrangements can affect cent of the consumptive use of water takes place in
the types and size distributions of transfers. The characteristics of irrigated agriculture, much of it in the production of
water rights transfers in the prosperous South Platte are then com- low valued crops (USGS, 1995). In numerous studies,
pared with water rights transfer characteristics in the economically
marginal Arkansas River basin of Colorado to identify the effects of
researchers have argued that water markets are
different economic environments. Finally, the economic losses from important in increasing this flexibility (Howe et al.,
reductions in irrigated acreage resulting from water transfers are 1986a, 1986b; Wahl, 1989; Anderson and Hill, 1997;
estimated for the South Platte and Arkansas and compared with Easter et al., 1998).
purchase prices by municipalities. Transfers in the South Platte Changes in water ownership in the western United
were to new uses in the same basin, while more recent transfers in
the Arkansas were to out of basin users. Transfers of South Platte
States occur largely through informal water markets
rights and especially NCWCD shares were small and continuous in which buyers and sellers search for one another in
over time, while transfers in the Arkansas were dominated by a few ways varying from phone calls and local bulletin
very large transfers. The negative impacts are judged to be more boards to water brokers and regional computer net-
severe in the Arkansas basin than in the South Platte. Purchase works such as that found in the Westlands Irrigation
prices paid by municipalities substantially exceeded capitalized
transitional losses in the selling areas. In the South Platte, gains
District of California (Howitt, 1998). These ownership
and losses were in the same basin, while the Arkansas absorbed transfers involve either state water rights or shares
the losses, with the benefits going to the purchasing basin. in water distribution organizations such as ditch
(KEY TERMS: water markets; transaction costs; economic efficien- companies and conservancy districts whose supplies
cy; economic impacts; compensation.) are underlain by water rights. An obvious condition of
Howe, Charles W. and Christopher Goemans, 2003. Water Transfers and Their
a transfer is that infrastructure must exist through
Impacts: Lessons From three Colorado Water Markets. Journal of the American which the water can be transferred to the new use,
Water Resources Association (JAWRA) 39(5):1055-1065. although “exchange” arrangements can be agreed
upon to effect transfers indirectly.
The objectives of this study are (1) to observe how
different institutional arrangements for water mar-
OBJECTIVES AND STRATEGY. kets, regional economic conditions, and property right
definitions in water affect the functioning of water
In the western United States, the development of markets in terms of the types, size, and frequency of
new water supplies has become costly in economic transfers that occur; and (2) to determine how
and environmental terms. New dams and reservoirs the economic and social conditions of a river basin
generate strong opposition, while some rivers are affect the economic impacts of agricultural to urban

1Paper No. 02065 of the Journal of the American Water Resources Association. Discussions are open until April 1, 2004.
2Respectively,Professor Emeritus of Economics and Ph.D. Candidate in Economics, University of Colorado-Boulder, Campus Box 468,
Boulder, Colorado 80309 (E-Mail/Howe: Charles.Howe@Colorado.edu).

JOURNAL OF THE AMERICAN WATER RESOURCES ASSOCIATION 1055 JAWRA


HOWE AND GOEMANS

transfers on the areas of origin. The study initially In addition to permanent transfers of water owner-
contrasts the transfers of state water rights (native ship, it is possible under some conditions for water
water) that pass through the Colorado water court owners to “rent” or “lease” water temporarily to other
system with transfers of shares in the NCWCD that users for periods of a year or more, greatly facilitating
are able to bypass review by the water courts. Trans- adjustments to short term climate events, especially
fers of state water rights in the South Platte are then droughts. In nondrought years, towns frequently rent
compared with such transfers in the Arkansas. The some of the excess water held for drought protection
direct and indirect economic impacts are then esti- or future growth to nearby agriculture, subject to
mated of agricultural to urban water rights transfers recall in drought years (regarding rental markets in
in those two basins. Only a few studies have quanti- the Northern Colorado Water Conservancy District
fied the impacts that water transfers have had on see Howe et al., 1986a, pp. 189-192). Cities are
areas of origin (e.g., Vaux and Howitt, 1984; Howe et increasingly contracting with agricultural interests
al., 1990; Taylor and Young, 1995). The study is based for agricultural to urban leases on a climate contin-
on all traditional water rights transfers and all trans- gency basis to firm up their supplies during drought.
fers of shares in the NCWCD from 1979 through
1995, and these transfers were characterized by type
(for example, agricultural to urban), size in acre feet,
and date of the transfer. COMPARISON OF THE TWO STUDY BASINS:
THE SOUTH PLATTE AND ARKANSAS
BASINS IN COLORADO

WATER OWNERSHIP IN THE Table 1 provides comparative economic, land use,


WESTERN UNITED STATES and demographic data for the two regions. It is imme-
diately seen that the Arkansas is much more special-
The predominant legal system relating to water in ized in agriculture and that population density is
the western United States is the “appropriations” or much lower. The South Platte Valley is a prosperous,
“priority” system that, in contrast to the older “ripari- diversified, and highly integrated region. Land use
an” system of water law of the eastern states, treats changes are occurring in part for reasons unrelated to
the use of water as personal property separate from water availability, especially rapidly expanding
the land and subject to transfer or sale (Radosevich urbanization and commercial development.
et al., 1976; Getches, 1997). Under this system, all Agriculture is increasingly specializing in horticulture
water withdrawn from the natural setting is repre- and livestock with resultant net income per farm acre
sented by a “water right” or by a ground water pump- ($73) much higher than in the Arkansas Valley ($26).
ing permit. These rights and permits may be owned The Front Range cities in the South Platte like Fort
by individuals or water distribution organizations Collins, Greeley, Boulder, and Denver have experi-
such as irrigation ditch companies, conservancy dis- enced rapid growth in the food processing, telecom-
tricts, municipalities, or firms. The shares of these munications, biotechnology, and energy sectors.
organizations, in turn, can be bought or sold. In Col- A unique form of water market is found in the
orado, the transfers of state water rights and out of NCWCD that provides about 30 percent of the water
ditch share sales are overseen by a system of water available in the South Platte by importing supple-
courts, while in other western states similar transfers mental water from the western side of the Rockies
are overseen by the office of the state engineer or through the federal Colorado-Big Thompson Project.
other competent water agencies. This oversight is NCWCD shares have unique characteristics that
intended to protect property rights in water and to make them particularly attractive to water users and
protect third parties from externalities that might be particularly conducive to market activity: (1) they are
generated by transfers. In Colorado, this protection is homogeneous units (each share gets the same amount
extended only to other water users, not to public val- of water and there are no priorities); (2) there is no
ues such as water quality, ecosystems, and communi- responsibility for the protection of return flows, a
ty values. Other western states use broader sets of quirk of Colorado water law concerning water import-
criteria in the water transfer approval process (for ed from another major basin; and (3) transfers do not
Idaho see IDWR, 1985, 1986; for Wyoming see Dobbs have to pass through the water court but require only
et al., 1971; MacDonnell and Rice, 1994). More will be the approval of the NCWCD board. These features
said about these criteria in the section on economic suggest that transaction costs of transfers should be
impacts. Water rights and water shares can be modi- much lower than for transfers of traditional water
fied by the oversight agency as a condition of transfer rights. NCWCD water cannot, however, be trans-
approval. ferred outside the Northern District boundaries

JAWRA 1056 JOURNAL OF THE AMERICAN WATER RESOURCES ASSOCIATION


WATER TRANSFERS AND THEIR IMPACTS: LESSONS FROM THREE COLORADO WATER MARKETS

TABLE 1. Characteristics of the South Platte and Arkansas Basins.

Totals
Without
South Platte Arkansas Valley City of Pueblo

Land In Farms (1,000 Acres1992)* 2,887 3,629 2,732


Total Land (1,000 Acres 1992)* 5,151 4,934 3,414
Farm Land as a Percent of Total Land (1992)* 56 74 80

Farm Net Income (1,000 $,1990)** 209,550 94,046 72,702


Total Personal Income (1,000 $,1990)** 13,768,637 1,345,787 278,587
Farm Income as a Percentage of Total (1990)** 1.5 7 26

Population (1990)* 984,846 153,809 30,751


Total Land Square Miles (1990)* 8,108.9 7,725.8 5,337
Population Per Square Mile (1990)* 121.5 19.9 5.8

**U.S. Bureau of the Census (1996).


**U.S. Bureau of the Census (1994).

because of financial obligations of the District to the Frying Pan-Arkansas Project. The Frying Pan-
U.S. Bureau of Reclamation. Arkansas Project was initiated in the 1960s to supple-
Unlike northeastern Colorado, the agricultural ment the highly variable native supplies in the
economy of the Arkansas Valley in Colorado has been Arkansas. This supplemental water is administered
depressed for decades. Climatic extremes and highly by the Southeastern Colorado Water Conservancy
variable water supplies have made much of agricul- District, in many ways the counterpart of the
ture economically marginal. The beet sugar industry, NCWCD. The major difference between the two dis-
on which the early hopes for settlement in the valley tricts, however, is that the “Fry-Ark” water is allocat-
were pinned in the late 1800s, has closed down com- ed annually by an elected committee and is not
pletely. The city of Pueblo has experienced cycles of subject to trade or sale. As with NCWCD water, this
growth and contraction. Assessed values and property water cannot be transferred outside the Southeastern
taxes have failed to grow. Demographic data show District.
young people leaving the region (Weber, 1989),
although there has been a small population increase
since 1996. The valley has long had small acreages of
high-valued horticultural crops like flower seeds, mel- THE TWO WATER MARKETS OF
ons, and tomatoes, but these crops are severely mar- THE SOUTH PLATTE BASIN
ket-limited so cannot significantly be expanded.
In the early post-World War II period, water sales The first market to be characterized is that for
in the valley were from agricultural interests to the water rights representing water native to the basin.
local cities of Pueblo and Pueblo West and to thermal All such transfers in the South Platte Basin were
electric generating plants. By the 1980s, transfers identified in the records of the Division 1 (South Plat-
increased in size and were to the larger cities in the te) Water Court for 1979 through 1995. These trans-
Denver metropolitan area. This change occurred part- fers frequently take the form of shares in ditch
ly because of the rapid growth of those cities and their companies that own the underlying water rights.
need for water and partly because of the persistence Amounts transferred annually were compiled, and the
of depressed economic conditions in the Arkansas. transfers were classified by size in acre feet (1 acre
The out of basin transfers were facilitated by existing foot = 1,230 cubic meters) and nature of buyer and
diversion facilities in the upper Arkansas that permit- seller (agricultural to agricultural, agricultural to
ted diversions into the South Platte River, which urban, nonagricultural to nonagricultural).
serves the metro area. The tables and graphs below characterize the
Like the South Platte, the Arkansas has two types transfers of state water rights in the South Platte
of water: the native water represented by traditional Basin from 1979 through 1995. Figure 1 shows the
water rights and supplemental water imported from acre feet of native water transferred by year. The
the western side of the Rockies through the federal 1987 peak followed several years of high population

JOURNAL OF THE AMERICAN WATER RESOURCES ASSOCIATION 1057 JAWRA


HOWE AND GOEMANS

Figure 1. Quantity of Native South Platte Water Transferred by Year.

growth and the resultant municipal purchases of and vary from sale to sale as affected by the seniority
water from agriculture. The 1992 peak represents of the right, proximity to buyer, water quality, costs of
large purchases by the City of Fort Collins for much physical transfer, and level of legal opposition by
the same reason. Of all the transfers, 87 percent were other water users. However, data on city purchases
from agricultural to urban use. Figure 2 shows the indicate recent prices in the $2,000 to $2,500 per acre
frequency distribution of these water transfers by foot range for permanent transfers (CSUWC, 2001,
size. 2002).
The median transfer size of 367 acre feet is small The second market in the South Platte is that for
compared with some large transfers that have recent- shares in the NCWCD, which was established in 1937
ly attracted the public’s attention (e.g., the City of to contract with the Bureau of Reclamation for water
Thornton’s transfer of 20,000 acre feet in the South from the federally sponsored Colorado-Big Thompson
Platte in 1987). The mean value of 3,425 acre feet Project. This project was initiated in 1937 in response
results from unusually large purchases by Thornton to the drought conditions of the 1930s (see Tyler,
and Fort Collins. The small median size suggests a 1992). The project brings an average of 270,000 acre
relatively smooth working water market in which feet of water into the Platte Basin from the headwa-
transaction costs are not high enough to preclude fre- ters of the Colorado River on the western slope of the
quent smaller purchases when added supplies are Rocky Mountains and represents about 30 percent of
needed. Price data are not recorded by the water the total supply in the South Platte. The establish-
court or the division engineer ’s office nor by the ment of a market for this water in the form of shares
NCWCD, so prices are somewhat difficult to uncover in NCWCD is greatly facilitated by the characteristics

Figure 2. Distribution of Native South Platte Transfers by Size.


(Median: 367.17; Mean: 3,425.31)

JAWRA 1058 JOURNAL OF THE AMERICAN WATER RESOURCES ASSOCIATION


WATER TRANSFERS AND THEIR IMPACTS: LESSONS FROM THREE COLORADO WATER MARKETS

cited earlier: the shares are homogeneous, deliverable business and demographic conditions and in part to
almost anyplace in the district because of well devel- varying climatic conditions. Statistical analyses of
oped infrastructure, and not subject to the water these relationships are continuing.
court review process (Radosevich et al., 1976, Chapter Figure 6 shows the distribution of NCWCD trans-
6). A very active water market has developed within fers by size. Transfers were predominantly agricultur-
the district (Howe et al., 1986a, 1986b; Michelsen, al to urban (64 percent), but 26 percent were
1994). Figure 3 shows both the changing pattern of agricultural to agricultural. The persistence of agri-
ownership and actual use of Northern District water. cultural to agricultural transfers in the Northern Dis-
Cities and industry are increasing their share of own- trict suggests that there is a large potential for
ership, but the share in actual use is not increasing as beneficial agricultural to agricultural transfers when
rapidly because towns typically “rent” some of their transaction costs are low. The median size of transfer
water back to agriculture on an annual basis, subject of 16.8 acre feet is much smaller than that of state
to recall in drought years. In this respect, the water water rights transfers, suggesting an efficient and
courts have allowed towns wide latitude in defining continuous market with low transaction costs that
what constitutes “beneficial use.” allow buyers and sellers to undertake small transac-
Figure 4 shows the volume of NCWCD water trans- tions as the need arises rather than occasional larger
ferred by year. These transfers have accelerated in transfers.
recent years because of the highly desirable charac- Comparison of the results of these two markets
teristics of the shares (as described earlier) and rapid suggests the following conclusions: (1) the homoge-
population growth in northeastern Colorado. Share neous nature of the NCWCD shares greatly facilitates
prices have followed the growth pattern, too, as trading; (2) the avoidance of water court review great-
shown in Figure 5. The patterns of prices and volume ly reduces transaction costs and decreases the uncer-
of transfers show cycles that relate in part to varying tainty of outcome introduced by that process; and (3)

Figure 3. (a) Colorado-Big Thompson Water Deliveries (1957 to 1999) and


(b) Colorado-Big Thompson Shares Owned (1957 to 1999).

Figure 4. Quantity of NCWCD Water Transferred by Year.

JOURNAL OF THE AMERICAN WATER RESOURCES ASSOCIATION 1059 JAWRA


HOWE AND GOEMANS

Figure 5. Colorado-Big Thompson Price data. Data from “The Water Strategist” indicated by WS data.

Figure 6. Distribution of NCWCD Transfers by Size (1979 to 1999).


(Median: 16.8; Mean: 34.00)

the ease of trading and the small size of the shares Court. Nearly all water rights transfers were from
result in continuous trading over time so that water agricultural to urban uses. As a result, the region lost
users do not have to “buy ahead” as is the case with approximately 68,000 irrigated acres during the data
buying traditional water rights. period. Transfers over time were again quantified in
acre-feet and are shown in Figure 7. This shows a dis-
continuous pattern of transactions with a bulge in the
1983 through 1984 period when most of the water of
COMPARISON OF TRANSFERS OF TRADITIONAL the Colorado Canal was sold to the City of Aurora.
WATER RIGHTS IN THE ARKANSAS VALLEY The distribution by size of transfer (Figure 8) is also
AND THE SOUTH PLATTE discontinuous, consisting of some small transfers but
dominated by two very large transfers: the Colorado
The strategy of this section is to compare the char- Canal sale of 100,000 acre feet in 1985 and the Rocky
acteristics of water transfers in the Arkansas Valley Ford majority of 11,890 acre feet, also in 1985.
with those of the South Platte. Thus, water rights It seems clear that limited demand for new water
transfer data were collected for the period 1979 supplies within the basin and high transaction costs
through 1995 from the Division 2 (Arkansas) Water associated with transbasin transfers caused water

JAWRA 1060 JOURNAL OF THE AMERICAN WATER RESOURCES ASSOCIATION


WATER TRANSFERS AND THEIR IMPACTS: LESSONS FROM THREE COLORADO WATER MARKETS

Figure 7. Quantity of Arkansas Valley Water Transferred by Year.

Figure 8. Distribution of Native Arkansas Valley Transfers by Size.


(Median: 366.82; Mean: 6,199.09)

market activity to be dominated by a small number of The pattern of Arkansas transfers over time and the
large transfers. Transbasin transfers always attract distribution of transactions by size are both discontin-
protests that increase the time and cost of the court uous.
review process. Transaction costs do not increase in
proportion to the size of transfer, so metropolitan buy-
ers prefer to buy in large amounts when negotiating
transbasin transfers, i.e., there are economies of scale THE COMPARATIVE REGIONAL ECONOMIC
for the buyer. IMPACTS OF WATER RIGHTS TRANSFERS
In comparing water rights transfers in the two IN THE SOUTH PLATTE AND
basins, the greatest difference is that all the transfers ARKANSAS BASINS OF COLORADO
in the South Platte were to other uses in the same
basin (and hence generally in the same economic The economic and social impacts of a sale of agri-
area) while out of basin transfers in the Arkansas cultural water on the area of origin are hypothesized
totaled 114,320 acre feet (88 percent) compared to to depend on (1) the size and seniority of the transfer,
15,568 of in basin transfers. The median size of trans- (2) the vitality of the regional economy, and (3)
fer of 367 acre feet is identical to that of the South whether the transfer is to a new use in the same or a
Platte, while the mean sizes are quite different: 6,199 different economic region. When agricultural water
in the Arkansas versus 3,425 in the South Platte rights (typically senior) are sold in Colorado, the land
because of the very large Colorado Canal transfer. that had been irrigated by that water is usually

JOURNAL OF THE AMERICAN WATER RESOURCES ASSOCIATION 1061 JAWRA


HOWE AND GOEMANS

required by the water court to be dried up in perpetu- To estimate the direct and indirect personal
ity (a requirement that makes little economic sense if income, employment, and tax losses occasioned by
junior rights might be substituted for those sold to water sales in the two regions, input/output models of
support production of alternative lower valued crops). the Minnesota IMPLAN Group, Inc. (IMPLAN, 1999)
When agricultural production falls, activities linked have been used. Input/output models show the pat-
to agriculture are negatively affected: suppliers of terns of provision of inputs and the uses of outputs
agricultural inputs lose business; processors of agri- by the different regional sectors (SIC groups) in the
cultural outputs lose supply sources; financial institu- production of goods and services to satisfy “final
tions lose the demand for loans, etc. While the selling demands” – demands that do not depend on local pro-
farmer is presumably better off, the surrounding com- duction levels (Pleeter, 1980). The IMPLAN system
munity suffers losses of income and social displace- was designed by the U.S. Forest Service to permit
ments as people must move and change jobs while the estimates of the input-output structure of regional
community loses some of its ability to support commu- economies down to the county level for policy analysis
nity services. Naturally, similar consequences occur purposes. Datasets are now commercially available
whenever any activity shuts down, so the question is that permit the construction of the input/output struc-
whether unique consequences result from irrigated ture of multicounty groups such as the five-county
agricultural acreage. area used for the South Platte (Boulder, Adams, Jef-
If the economic region is economically diversified ferson, Larimer, and Weld) and the six counties of the
and buoyant, alternative employment opportunities Arkansas Valley (Pueblo, Otero, Crowley, Bent,
are close at hand and the selling farmer can find local Kiowa, and Las Animas). These sets of counties
investment opportunities for his or her money. The account for most of the agricultural activity of the two
“secondary impacts” in such a setting are likely to be regions.
short lived. If the new use of the water supports more The procedure for utilizing the models involves the
profitable activities in the same economic region, the following steps: (1) to determine the cropping pattern,
region as a whole will be better off economically from crop yields, and crop prices for the lands dried up by
the water sale. The South Platte basin is such a the transfer; (2) to determine (from trade flow data
region. We have seen above that the majority of trans- from IMPLAN) how much of the lost output had been
fers in the South Platte basin are from agricultural to sold outside the subject areas; and (3) treating these
urban and industrial uses and all were to uses in the lost out of area sales as reductions in “final demands,”
same basin. Thus while agricultural and linked activi- to run the input/output model to determine the
ties are diminished over time, other activities are changes in payments to households, taxes, and
stimulated by the efficient acquisition of water and employment that result directly and indirectly. Table
unemployed resources are likely to quickly find alter- 2 provides estimates of the annual direct plus indirect
native opportunities. impacts per acre foot of water transferred on the
In the Arkansas Valley, the economy has historical- regional economies of the South Platte and Arkansas
ly been depressed and new local demands for water basins. These estimates were based on samples of
supply have been limited. Eighty-eight percent of the large agricultural to urban transfers for which
water transferred in the 1979 through 1995 study detailed cropping data were available and that
period was to out of basin buyers. The water use ben- occurred in the two basins during the study period.
efits were, therefore, outside of the region, while lim- For the South Platte, direct and indirect personal
ited opportunity existed for the proceeds from the sale income losses (including wages, salaries, income from
of the water to be invested in the local economy. Most business and investments) amount to $22 per acre
of the water sale proceeds have been used to reduce foot sold. Direct plus indirect employment losses per
farm debt (Weber, 1988, unpublished paper, 1989, thousand acre feet of water sold amount to approxi-
unpublished paper). In such cases, the regional mately 1.8 jobs. Tax losses represent a reduction in
impacts of a permanent transfer of water rights can ability to provide public services and come to about $9
be quite severe. per acre foot transferred. The regional losses on a per
It can be argued that the farms would eventually capita basis are nearly negligible.
have failed anyway, so the water market simply These losses represent what occurs in the short run
allowed the farmers to choose the optimal time to when there is limited ability to react to the reduction
leave the business. What the public sees, however, is in agricultural output. Over time, human resources
the sale of water followed by sharp declines in the and fungible capital will migrate to other employ-
agriculture related sectors. What economic analysis ment, although this migration will be lower out of
usually omits are the real human and resource costs agriculture than would be the case with other sectors
that occur during this transition. because of the culture of an agricultural way of life,

JAWRA 1062 JOURNAL OF THE AMERICAN WATER RESOURCES ASSOCIATION


WATER TRANSFERS AND THEIR IMPACTS: LESSONS FROM THREE COLORADO WATER MARKETS

TABLE 2. Direct and Indirect Negative Impacts of Selected Water Transfers on


Basins of Origin: South Platte and Arkansas Basins, Colorado.

Direct Impacts Direct + Indirect


South Platte Arkansas South Plate Arkansas

Output (per acre-foot) 65.08 88.99 104.06 117.02


Tax Impact (per acre-foot) 8.83 12.24
Personal Income (per acre-foot) 8.52 17.89 21.6 28.48
Employees (per 1,000 acre feet) 1.29 2.02 1.78 2.57
Output (per capita) 1.61 14.11 2.56 18.51
Tax Impact (per capita) 0.22 1.72
Personal Income (per capita) 0.21 2.63 0.53 4.27
Employees (per 100,000 people) 3.92 35.26 5.63 43.49

the older average ages of farmers, and their more iso- exceeds the direct and indirect costs imposed by the
lated locations. The “present value” of the personal reduction of agricultural activities in the South Plat-
income and tax losses over some transition period te. In sum, the basin appears to have gained hand-
during which human resources and fungible capital somely overall in economic terms from the process of
are finding new employment summarizes the region’s transferring water from agricultural to urban uses. At
costs stemming from displaced labor and capital. the same time, most equity issues concerning the inci-
In a prosperous region like the South Platte, dis- dence of benefits and costs have probably been largely
placed labor, capital, and land are likely to be avoided due to the mobility of resources and alterna-
reemployed in other productive activities within a rel- tive employment opportunities.
atively short period. We assume a period of five years. Purchase prices for Arkansas River water rights
If we use the first-year personal income loss per acre have been in the neighborhood of $2,000 per acre foot
foot plus the loss of taxes to public authorities total- (e.g., for the second half of the Rocky Ford Ditch),
ing $31 and assume that the annual loss per acre foot indicating a net gain for the basin of origin by the
drops linearly to zero by the end of year five, the pre- simple comparison of capitalized losses and purchase
sent value of these losses is $83 per acre foot using a payments. However, a significant fraction of the loss-
discount rate of 5 percent. es is imposed on parties other than the seller. We
The losses in the Arkansas are likely to persist know from Weber’s earlier study (1989, unpublished
over a longer period than in the prosperous South paper) that most farmers in the Arkansas who earlier
Platte, perhaps dissipating over ten years rather than sold their water used the money to pay off longstand-
the five we assumed for the South Platte. If it is ing debts. While the reduction in indebtedness is a
assumed that the annual loss per acre foot drops lin- financial gain to the farmer, it creates no new jobs in
early to zero over ten years, then the initial loss of the absence of local investment opportunities.
personal income plus tax losses of $41 per acre foot Comparison of the direct plus indirect loss figures
has a present value of $187 per acre foot (using a 5 for the two basins indicates that the losses per acre-
percent discount rate). This is more than twice the foot incurred from the phase out of agriculture are
capitalized losses in the South Platte. Even if the noticeably more for the Arkansas. Because of the
transition periods were the same, the capitalized loss- much lower population density in the Arkansas Val-
es would be greater for the Arkansas. ley, the per capita losses are about eight times
While marginal benefits of additional water to greater. We argue that the per capita losses are more
municipalities are difficult to estimate because of the relevant measures of the welfare impacts.
delayed and uncertain nature of its uses, the pur-
chase price can be used as a lower bound estimate of
the present value of net benefits perceived by town
officials. Prices being paid for water rights by towns CONCLUSIONS
in the South Platte Valley have been increasing
steadily, as was seen in Figure 5 for NCWCD shares. In comparing the patterns of transfers of tradition-
Fort Collins has paid from $175 per acre foot in 1973 al water rights in the South Platte basin with trans-
to $1,890 per acre foot in 1998 (in nominal terms). fers of shares in the NCWCD, it becomes clear that
Thus this lower bound on benefits substantially the differences in the nature of the property rights

JOURNAL OF THE AMERICAN WATER RESOURCES ASSOCIATION 1063 JAWRA


HOWE AND GOEMANS

involved and the differences in the types of social ACKNOWLEDGMENTS


oversight used have very different results: the homo-
The authors would like to acknowledge the guidance provided
geneous nature of NCWCD shares make them easier by four persistent referees over several revisions of this paper.
to trade, while the avoidance of water court review Their suggestions greatly improved the paper. The study was spon-
contributes to a continuous market in small transac- sored by the General Service Foundation, Aspen, Colorado, Grant
tions. Traditional water rights have not only different DS-11-99.
priorities but different consumptive fractions and sea-
sonal patterns of use. A prospective buyer must
search for rights that have the right combination of LITERATURE CITED
characteristics. The higher transaction costs of water
court review result in economies of scale in the trans- Anderson, Terry L. and Peter J. Hill (Editors), 1997. Water Market-
fer process, resulting in much larger transfers on the ing: The Next Generation. Rowman and Littlefield Publishers,
Inc., Boulder, Colorado, and New York, New York.
average. CSUWC (Colorado State University Water Center), 2001. “Water
The comparisons of transfer characteristics News Digest” – Colorado Water. Newsletter of the Water Center
between the South Platte and the Arkansas (both of of Colorado State University (October issue).
which involve traditional water rights and are subject CSUWC (Colorado State University Water Center), 2001. “Water
to water court review) suggest that out of basin trans- News Digest” – Colorado Water. Newsletter of the Water Center
of Colorado State University (February issue).
fers (the Arkansas) involve much larger transaction Dobbs, Thomas L., Orman Paananen, and Paul A. Rechard, 1971.
costs and thus, because of scale economies in transfer Criteria and Methods for State Water Resource Planning. Water
costs, result in a distribution of transfer sizes domi- Resources Series No. 22, Water Resources Research Institute,
nated by a few large, occasional transfers. University of Wyoming, Laramie, Wyoming.
The comparative impact analysis indicates that Easter, William K., Mark W. Rosegrant, and Ariel Dinar (Editors),
1998. Markets for Water: Potential and Performance. Kluwer
more severe economic and social impacts are likely in Academic Publishers, Boston, Massachusetts.
specialized, marginal agricultural regions like the Getches, David H., 1997. Water Law in a Nutshell. West Publishing
Arkansas: the direct and indirect losses of income, tax Co., St. Paul, Minnesota.
receipts, and employment per acre foot are likely to be Howe, Charles W., Jeffrey K. Lazo, and Kenneth R. Weber, 1990.
significantly higher than those in a prosperous basin, The Economic Impacts of Agriculture-to-Urban Water Transfers
on the Area of Origin: A Case Study of the Arkansas River Val-
while the losses on a per capita basis are much ley in Colorado. Amer. J. Agr. Econ., pp. 1200-1204.
greater and are likely to persist over a longer time Howe, Charles W., Dennis R. Schurmeier, and William D. Shaw, Jr.,
span. 1986a. Innovations in Water Management: Lessons from the
The results suggest grounds for extra market assis- Colorado-Big Thompson Project and Northern Colorado Water
tance to basins of origin when conditions in the basin Conservancy District. In: Scarce Water and Institutional
Change, Kenneth C. Frederick and Diana C. Gibbons (Editors).
approximate those found in the Arkansas. The set of Resources for the Future, Inc., Washington, D.C., Chap. 6.
criteria to be considered by the transfer agencies in Howe, Charles W., Dennis R. Schurmeier, and W. Douglas Shaw,
approving, modifying, or disapproving water transfers Jr., 1986b, Innovative Approaches to Water Allocation: The
should be expanded to include consideration of the Potential for Water Markets. Water Resources Research
secondary economic and social costs imposed on the 22(4):439-445.
Howitt, Richard E., 1998. Spot Prices, Option Prices, and Water
basin of origin (as is the practice in Utah, Wyoming, Markets: An Analysis of Emerging Markets in California. In:
and Idaho). When it is determined that serious costs Markets for Water: Potential and Performance, K. William East-
will be imposed on the basin of origin, one or both of er, Mark W. Rosegrant, and Ariel Dinar (Editors). Kluwer Aca-
two policies might be followed: (1) a transfer fee per demic Publishers, Boston, Massachusetts, Chap. 8, pp 119-138.
acre foot could be imposed on the buyer and trans- IDWR (Idaho Department of Water Resources), 1985. Currents: A
Publication of Energy and Water Information: Special Water
ferred to a unit of general government (including Allocation Rules Edition. Statehouse Mail, Boise, Idaho.
school districts) in the area of origin to support social IDWR (Idaho Department of Water Resources), 1986. Rules and
services during the period of transition; and (2) a Regulations for Water Appropriation. Statehouse Mail, Boise,
more gradual transfer of the water over several years Idaho.
as is done currently with revegetation requirements Michelsen, Ari M., 1994. Administrative, Institutional and Struc-
tural Characteristics of an Active Water Market. Water
could be specified, allowing more time for adjust- Resources Bulletin 30(6):971-982.
ments to take place. IMPLAN (Minnesota IMPLAN Group, Inc.), 1999. User’s Guide,
IMPLAN Pro, Version 2.0. Stillwater, Minnesota.
MacDonnell, Lawrence J. and Teresa A. Rice, 1994. Moving Agri-
cultural Water to Cities: The Search for Smarter Approaches.
Hastings West-Northwest Journal of Environmental Law and
Policy 2(1):27-55.
Pleeter, Saul (Editor), 1980. Economic Impact Analysis: Methodolo-
gy and Applications. Nijhoff Publishing, Boston, Massachusetts.

JAWRA 1064 JOURNAL OF THE AMERICAN WATER RESOURCES ASSOCIATION


WATER TRANSFERS AND THEIR IMPACTS: LESSONS FROM THREE COLORADO WATER MARKETS

Radosevich, G. E., K. C. Nobe, D. Allardice and C. Kirkwood, 1976.


Evolution and Administration of Colorado Water Law: 1876-
1976. Water Resources Publications, Fort Collins, Colorado.
Taylor, R. G. and R. A. Young, 1995. Rural-to-Urban Water Trans-
fers: Measuring Direct Foregone Benefits of Irrigation Water
under Uncertain Supplies. Journal of Agricultural and Resource
Economics 20(2):247-262.
Tyler, Daniel, 1992. The Last Water Hole in the West: The Col-
orado-Big Thompson Project and the Northern Colorado Water
Conservancy District. University Press of Colorado, Niwot, Col-
orado.
U.S. Bureau of the Census, 1994. County and City Data Book:
1994. U.S. Government Printing Office, Washington, D.C.
U.S. Bureau of the Census, 1996. USA Counties: 1996. U.S. Gov-
ernment Printing Office, Washington, D.C.
USGS (U.S. Geological Survey), 1995. Estimated Use of Water in
the United States in 1990. Circular 1081, Books and Open-File
Reports Sales, USGS, Federal Center, Box 25286, Denver, Col-
orado.
Vaux, Jr., H. J. and Richard E. Howitt, 1984. Managing Water
Scarcity: An Evaluation of Interregional Transfers. Water
Resources Research20(7):785-792.
Wahl, Richard W., 1989. Markets for Federal Water: Subsidies,
Property Rights and the Bureau of Reclamation. Resources for
the Future, Inc., Washington, D.C.
Weber, Kenneth R., 1989. Otero County: A Demographic History of
a Colorado High Plains County, 1889-1987. The Social Science
Journal 26(3):265-275.

JOURNAL OF THE AMERICAN WATER RESOURCES ASSOCIATION 1065 JAWRA

Das könnte Ihnen auch gefallen