Sie sind auf Seite 1von 4

1.3.6.

Value Chain Governance--Overview

1 of 4

http://www.microlinks.org/print/452

Published on USAID Microlinks (http://www.microlinks.org)


Home > 1.3.6. Value Chain Governance--Overview

1.3.6. Value Chain Governance--Overview


What is Value Chain Governance?
Value chain governance refers to the relationships among the buyers, sellers, service providers and regulatory institutions that operate within or influence the range
of activities required to bring a product or service from inception to its end use. Governance is about power and the ability to exert control along the chain at any
point in the chain, some firm (or organization or institution) sets and/or enforces parameters under which others in the chain operate. The key parameters are:
1. What is to be produced. This includes product design and specifications.
2. How it is to be produced. This involves the definition of the production processes, which can include elements such as the technology to be used, quality
systems, labor standards and environmental standards.
3. How much is to be produced, and when. This refers to production scheduling and logistics. [1] [2]
Actors within the value chain set, monitor and facilitate compliance with rules that pertain to each of these parameters. The actors can be firms (buyers or
producers) within the value chain or public or private institutions from the enabling environment. The same actor does not have to be responsible for setting,
monitoring and facilitating compliance with the rules combinations of actors frequently fulfill these responsibilities. Furthermore, different actors may exert more or
less influence as one moves from local to global markets, and the scope of an actor/action's impact can be industry-specific or broadly focused.
Chain governance exists when some firms work to the parameters set by other powerful firms in the chain. [3] The firm that sets the parameters with which other
firms in the chain must comply is referred to as the lead firm in the chain. The relationships lead firms have with their suppliers can either be helpful with respect to
improving the competitiveness of the industry, based on a commitment to long-term, mutually beneficial relationships with suppliers, or they can be predatory and
focused on realizing a quick profit in the short-term.
The need for lead firms to coordinate value chain activities has primarily come from two main trends. First, the trend towards outsourcing non-strategic activities
that were previously performed in-house by large, vertically integrated companies has led managerial control to be replaced by the need for value chain governance.
Second, product differentiation strategies and concern for meeting the growing number of environmental and social rules and standards set by external agents have
led to the increased need for lead firms to control activities carried out by other firms in the chain. [1]

Why Governance Matters


Recent instances of toxic substances found in the U.S. food supply and other everyday products and stories of children laboring in sweatshops point to the
importance of governance and of the control lead firms can and need to exercise over outsourced providers of both raw materials and finished products. Many firms
do not own the farms and manufacturing facilities that make the products they sell; they take ownership of these products only when they arrive at their warehouses
or distribution centers. However, these firms can and often do influence what happens at earlier points in the chain.
Understanding how and when lead firms set, monitor and enforce rules and standards can help micro and small enterprises (MSEs) and other firms in the chain
better integrate and coordinate their activities. Governance is particularly important for the generation, transfer, and diffusion of knowledge leading to innovation,
which enables firms to improve their performance and sustain competitive advantage. Awareness of the governance structure of a value chain can provide
governments, donors and development practitioners with information about how best to provide MSEs with the training and technical assistance needed to upgrade
their position in the chain.
Governance helps to determine the following:[4]
Acquisition of production capability. Lead firms can be very demanding about reducing costs, raising quality and increasing on-time performance. Yet,
along with high standards, lead firms also provide knowledge and support. MSEs learn by observing what their buyers are doing or in other cases, the lead
firm will transmit best practices through embedded services or provide hands-on advice on how to improve production processes and producers' skills.
Market access. Even as developed countries dismantle trade barriers, developing country producers do not necessarily gain access because chains are often
governed by a limited number of powerful buyers. In order to participate in export manufacturing to developed countries, MSEs need to be on the radar of the
lead firms of their chains because the lead firm frequently makes the decisions on where products will be produced and who will produce them. Producers
need access to lead firms and can gain it only by learning how to communicate with the firms and produce to specification.
Distribution of gains. The activities that reap the highest returns are usually found in intangible competences (R&D, design, branding) characterized by
high barriers to entry that are frequently synonymous with holding the lead firm status in the chain. In contrast, developing country firms tend to engage in
the tangible, production-related activities under terms set by the lead firm that have low entry barriers and thus low returns. It is important to know which
activities in the chain bring in the most profitable returns and who engages in these value-adding segments. Understanding how a chain is governed provides
MSEs and practitioners with valuable information on how to develop skills and with whom to develop relationships that would give them the flexibility and
freedom to undertake additional functions in the chain, thus altering the current distribution of gains.
Leverage for policy initiatives. Given the power lead firms have to impose product and process parameters on their suppliers, they are also excellent
leverage points for the business environment to use to exert influence on what happens in their supplier firms. Understanding chain governance and the
power of lead firms can assist local and global, public and private, government and nongovernmental agencies and practitioners to advocate for better labor
and environmental standards or a more equitable distribution of gains.

Types of Value Chain Governance


The connections between industry activities within a chain can be described along a continuum extending from the market, characterized by "arm's-length"
relationships, to hierarchical value chains illustrated through direct ownership of production processes. Between these two extremes are three network-style modes

5/27/2014 12:36 PM

1.3.6. Value Chain Governance--Overview

2 of 4

http://www.microlinks.org/print/452

of governance: modular, relational, and captive. Network-style governance represents a situation in which the lead firm exercises power through coordination of
production vis--vis suppliers (to varying degrees), without any direct ownership of the firms.[5]
Market. Market governance involves transactions that are relatively simple, information on product specifications is easily transmitted, and producers can
make products with minimal input from buyers.
Modular. Modular governance occurs when a product requires the firms in the chain to undertake complex transactions that are relatively easy to codify.
Relational. In this network-style governance pattern, interactions between buyers and sellers are characterized by the transfer of information and embedded
services based on mutual reliance regulated through reputation, social and spatial proximity, family and ethnic ties, and the like.
Captive. In these chains, small suppliers are dependent on a few buyers that often wield a great deal of power and control. Such networks are frequently
characterized by a high degree of monitoring and control by the lead firm.
Hierarchy. Hierarchical governance describes chains that are characterized by vertical integration and managerial control within a set of lead firms that
develops and manufactures products in-house. This usually occurs when product specifications cannot be codified, products are complex, or highly competent
suppliers cannot be found.

Determinants of Governance Structure


The form of governance can change as an industry evolves and matures, and governance patterns within an industry can vary from one stage of the chain to another.
The dynamic nature of governance can be largely accounted for with three variables: the complexity of information that the manufacture of a product entails (design
and process); the ability to codify or systematize the transfer of knowledge to suppliers; and the capabilities of existing suppliers to efficiently and reliably produce
the product. Additional influences on the governance structure include the quality, stability, and power of the business enabling environment and institutions, as well
as other sources of power in the chain, such as suppliers and consumers.
Information Complexity refers to the intricacy of information and knowledge that must be transferred to ensure a particular transaction can occur.
Information Codification is the extent to which lead firms can convert tacit, implied information and knowledge into explicit, concrete and situation-specific
information and transmit it to producers effectively, efficiently and at minimal cost.
Supplier Capability refers to the ability of suppliers to meet all transaction requirements. These may include quantity and quality specifications; on-time
delivery; and environmental, labor and safety standards.

Dynamism in Governance
If one of these three variables changes, then value chain governance patterns tend to shift in predictable ways. For example, if a new technology renders an
established codification scheme obsolete, modular value chains are likely to become more relational; and if competent suppliers cannot be found, captive networks
and even vertical integration would become more prevalent. Conversely, rising supplier competence might result in captive networks moving towards the relational
type, and better codification schemes set the stage for modular networks.

5/27/2014 12:36 PM

1.3.6. Value Chain Governance--Overview

3 of 4

http://www.microlinks.org/print/452

The most common initial form of governance that lead firms establish with MSEs in developing countries is the captive form. In captive value chains, the lead firm
(typically a global buyer from the United States or Europe) exhibits a great deal of control over the actors in the chain. In contrast, relational structures are the least
likely to initially occur between developing country producers and global buyers due to the knowledge and skill gaps, as well as social and spatial divides. [7] [8]
The following are examples of changes in variables that result in a change in the type of firm governance:
Captive to relational
Captive to modular
Captive to market
Hierarchy to relational
Hierarchy to modular

Other Contributing Factors


If the governance mechanism in an industry is not adequately explained through one of the chain governance structures, then an alternative factor, such as a strong
institutional environment or other sources of market power, is likely to be at work.
Business Enabling Environment and Institutions: The business enabling environment incorporates the physical entities, including government agencies and
nongovernmental organizations--such as multi-lateral agencies, industry trade groups, labor unions and advocacy groups--that set forth institutions. These
institutions are defined as the rules that govern society, including laws, policies, standards and societal and cultural norms that impact the competitiveness of an
industry and shape the forms and actions of entities in the business enabling environment. Institutions can be legally or voluntarily enforceable. The
rules/institutions set by the enabling environment are derived, to a greater or lesser degree, by the beliefs, values, meanings and priorities embedded in the
societies that create, fund and staff them. As a result, limits are placed on actions, and firms or managers that surpass those limits run the risk of sanction, creating
pressure for firms to operate according to the norms and expectations of the societies in which they operate.[9]
The business enabling environment not only sets rules; it also creates resources to facilitate compliance with rules set by internal and external members of the
chain. The enabling environment also acts as a check and balance systemwhen lead firms become too powerful or engage in predatory practices, institutions can
place limits on these actions. For example, the power attributed to buyers such as Nike or The Gap is associated with their brands' reputations. When these firms'
reputations were threatened by external activists' accounts of unethical labor conditions in their factories, the lead firms were quick to voluntarily improve their
conditions. Later on, this frequently leads to mandated institutions to regulate social and environmental practices, as well as means to ensure, certify and assist
factories with compliance.
Power: Power is the ability of a firm or organization to exert influence and control over other firms in the chain. At the firm level, power is accumulated, held, and
wielded in different ways and in different amounts. Power can come from any part of the value chain structure, in many different forms. Within the chain, power
comes from firms and the workers within the firms. Power within the chain can be divided into power exerted by lead firms or from suppliers. Outside the chain,
power comes from institutions created by the enabling environment and consumers.[10] Those in possession of industry power actively shape the distribution of
profits and risk through their activities.

Recommended Good Practices


Analyze chain governance to determine leverage points: where, how and when can practitioners intervene to effect systemic change and influence industry behavior.
Analysis should seek to understand:
Economic interests: Assess interests and incentives at aggregation points and determine how changes in the system will impact the benefits, profits, and
power that are likely to accrue to lead firms versus suppliers.
Social structure: Work with respected social figures, such as key farmers, chiefs and elders who can influence others to adopt or purchase new techniques,
technologies, services or inputs.
Competition and strategy: Changes in the level of competition or in lead firm strategies can pressure buyers, traders and others to change predatory or
abusive behavior.
Encourage capability-enhancing governance at all levels of the chain. Supportive governance facilitates the social and economic development of all of the
firms within the chain, rather than simply meeting the needs of the lead firm. Practitioners should work with lead firms, traders and input suppliers to set, codify and
monitor rules and standards that will help make the chain effective, efficient and equitable for all parties involved. It is important to make sure that all parts of the
chain understand the terms and meet the standards.
Facilitate the development of supporting markets. Technical assistance, training and business services are critical to helping suppliers improve their ability to
meet customer/lead firm specifications and can be a primary avenue of intervention for practitioners. In addition to helping MSEs upgrade, support services can be
provided to train other MSE service providers in compliance monitoring or to teach producers how to comply with standards. Though some programs are beginning to
use buyers to reach greater numbers of MSEs, programs also may have to work with and mentor lead firms in transferring information and skills.

Footnotes
1. Chain Governance and Upgrading: Taking Stock. Humphrey, J., and Schmitz, H. (2004). In H. Schmitz (Ed.), Local Enterprises in the Global Economy:
Issues of Governance and Upgrading (pp. 349-381). UK: Edward Elgar Publishing Limited.
2. Inter-firm Relationships in Global Value Chains: Trends in Chain Governance and Their Policy Implications. Humphrey, J. & Schmitz, H. (2008). International
Journal of Technological Learning, Innovation, and Development, 1(3), pp. 258-282.
3. Developing Country Firms in the World Economy: Governance and Upgrading in Global Value Chains, Humphrey, J., & Schmitz, H.; INEF Report No. 61
(2002). Duisburg: University of Duisburg.
4. Humphrey (2002)
5. Export-oriented Growth and Industrial Upgrading: Lessons from the Mexican Apparel Case, Gereffi, G.; World Bank case study for Uma Subramanian.
January 31; 2005.
6. The Governance of Global Value Chains. Gereffi, G., Humphrey, J., & Sturgeon, T. (2005). Review of International Political Economy, 12(1), p. 89.
7. Governance and Upgrading: Linking Industrial Cluster Global Value Chain Research.Humphrey, J., & Schmitz, H.; IDS Working Paper (No. 120), Institute of
Development Studies; (2005).
8. Upgrading in Global Value Chains: Lessons from Latin American Clusters. Giuliani, E., Pietrobelli, C., & Rabellotti, R.; World Development, 33(4), 549-573;
(2005).
9. From Commodity Chains to Value Chains: Interdisciplinary Theory Building in an Age of Globalization, Sturgeon, T. In J. Bair (Ed.), Frontiers of Commodity
Chain Research. Stanford University Press; (2009).
10. Sturgeon (2009).

5/27/2014 12:36 PM

1.3.6. Value Chain Governance--Overview

4 of 4

http://www.microlinks.org/print/452

COMMENTS (0)

5/27/2014 12:36 PM

Das könnte Ihnen auch gefallen