Sie sind auf Seite 1von 99

On Bread and Circuses:

Food Subsidy Reform and


Popular Opposition in Egypt

Ram Sachs

Advisor: Professor Lisa Blaydes


Center for International Security and Cooperation
Stanford University
May 21, 2012

ii

Abstract
In January 1977, Egyptian President Anwar al-Sadat faced tremendous public protest
after implementing relatively small changes to the countrys food subsidy regime.

In

contrast, during the 1980s, and more aggressively in the 1990s, the government of Hosni
Mubarak implemented more consequential reductions to subsidies on core food items while
avoiding popular protest on a similar scale. I argue that the Mubarak regime engaged in
covert price increases, distribution controls, temporary policy reversals, and repression,
which allowed it to successfully reduce food subsidies without igniting regime-threatening
public opposition during this period. Following the January 2011 revolution, further reform
efforts are unlikely as the transitional democratic politics and the increased number of
political participants will block change in the short term.

iii

iv

Acknowledgements
This thesis has served to unite my academic experience at Stanford. Four years of
preparation, and the past year of writing, have produced this exploration of food, politics, and
the Middle East. The CISAC Honors Program has provided a fantastic interdisciplinary
home for this pursuit.
I am thankful to Professors Blacker and Crenshaw for their guidance in this yearlong
process. I will fondly remember the quarterly presentations, Professor Blackers insistence
on concise language, and Professor Crenshaws direction on crystallizing the puzzle. My
fellow CISAC students were a cornerstone of the thesis experience, both in Washington and
on campus. We gained a community that understood the travails of literature reviews and
last-minute chapters, and the thrills of inside-the-beltway meetings.
At Stanford, Professor Blaydes provided the essential expertise on Egypt to guide my
research. After discussing Egypt in her office for the past year, I hope to one day eat my own
loaf of subsidized baladi bread from a Cairo bakery.
Finally, I would like to thank my parents, Anat and Avi, for their support throughout
the Stanford experience, and enduring the saga of aborted travel plans to the Middle East.

vi

Table of Contents
I. Introduction ................................................................................................................. 1
II. Literature Review ....................................................................................................... 3
III. Two Days in January 1977: The First Crisis in Subsidy Reform .............................. 25
IV. Subsidy Reduction in the 1980s............................................................................... 45
V. The 1990s: Repression, Extremism, and Economic Change...................................... 63
VI. The Food Crisis of the 2000s................................................................................... 69
VII. Conclusion: Assessing Reform in Contemporary Egypt ......................................... 75
VIII. Bibliography......................................................................................................... 79

Table of Figures
Figure 1: Incidence of Protests, 2004 - 2011.................................................................... 6
Figure 2: Cereal Prices and Riots in 2007 - 2008............................................................. 7

vii

viii

Key Terms
Baladi:

The simplest type of subsidized Egyptian bread, consisting of 82 percent


extraction. This bread serves as a staple of the Egyptian street.

Shami:

Higher quality bread of 76 percent extraction flour. The type is often


included within government subsidy lists.

Fino:

Highest quality bread, often baked in a Western style, consisting of 72


percent extraction flour.

Extraction Rate: The amount of flour produced from one pound of grain. Higher extraction
rate refers to the more inclusion of bran, endosperm, and germ,
contributing to a rougher texture.

A Note on the Thesis Title


The Ancient Romans served popular opinion by distributing free bread and public
entertainment during holidays. Modern Egypt has witnessed a similar dynamic, where food
subsidies have fulfilled populist desires.

Management of expectations regarding food

subsidies often resembles a circus, where clowns and magicians divert the audiences
attention.

ix

I. Introduction
We need a radical shift in the way we deal with our bread subsidy system
-Social Solidarity Minister Gouda Abdel Khaleq, September 20111

Since the economic crises of the 1970s, Egyptian officials have attempted to reform
the bloated food subsidies regime.

The new call from the post-Mubarak government

emerges from the same basic prognosis: an untargeted subsidy is draining public coffers.
The government spends $5.5 billion annually on food subsidies that support both rich and
poor. In Cairo, bread often costs no more than 1 American cent. Humans are not the only
consumers of this heavily subsidized imported wheat: loaves are used in place of animal
feed. In an era of higher global food prices and low Egyptian production, the government
faces the choice of reform, resulting in higher consumer prices and popular discontent, or
continued expenditures on increasingly expensive imports. This thesis asserts that while the
1

El Dahan, Maha. "Egypt Inches towards Far-reaching Food Subsidy Reform." Reuters, 28 Sept. 2011. Web. 05
Dec. 2011. <http://www.reuters.com/article/2011/09/28/us-egypt-food-idUSTRE78R2SD20110928>.

Egyptian subsidy system remains inefficient at alleviating poverty, reform and subsidy
pullback has still occurred, and often in a very aggressive fashion.
In 1977, Egyptian President Anwar al-Sadat faced tremendous public protest after
implementing relatively small changes to the countrys food subsidy regime. In contrast,
during the 1980s, and more drastically in the 1990s, the government of Hosni Mubarak was
able to avoid popular protest after putting into place considerably more consequential
reductions to subsidies on core food items. This paper argues that the Mubarak regime
engaged in covert price increases, distribution controls, and repression, which allowed it to
successfully reduce food subsidies without igniting regime-threatening public opposition. In
the 2000s, these coping strategies were used to dampen protests during global food price
spikes, but increased tensions forced Mubarak to rely on military forces to resuscitate the
subsidized bakery system. Following the January 2011 revolution, further reform efforts are
unlikely as transitional democratic politics and the increased number of participants in the
political system will block further change.
The following chapters will provide a chronological view of Egyptian food reform,
beginning with a review of relevant literature in Chapter 2. Chapter 3 will discuss the food
riots of January 1977, which dominate the history of Egyptian subsidy reform. Each of the
three subsequent decades will be discussed in Chapters 4, 5, and 6. The final chapter will
analyze the prospects for subsidy reform in post-revolution Egypt.

II. Literature Review


The linkage between food and popular support is hardly a new phenomenon. In
Imperial Rome, emperors would provide grain to citizens, and an angry public would riot
against shortages.2

During the food crisis of 22 BC, Augustus cemented his political

influence by buying wheat for the public at his personal expense.3 Modern Egyptian regimes
have similarly viewed food as a tool for political loyalty.
This literature review will explore the linkages between protests, food prices, and
subsidy reform. The concepts outlined below will enable an analysis of Egyptian attempts at
reform from the 1970s onwards, drawing the connection between government policy, local
discontent, and the international context.

The Dynamics of Protest


This thesis will analyze the use of popular action in response to food prices and
subsidy changes. These actions emerge within the context of austerity protests.4 This phrase
typically refers to popular response to cutbacks in government outlays, especially for social
services.

The term came to use during the 1970s, when international creditors forced

indebted governments to restructure expenditures. Walton and Seddon propose that these
events, whose more violent permutations have acquired the name IMF riots, include political
demonstrations, general strikes, and riots, driven by opposition to market regulation and debt
reduction policies. The first of these contemporary protests occurred in July 1976 in Peru,

Africa, Thomas W. "Urban Violence in Imperial Rome." The Journal of Interdisciplinary History 2.1 (1971):
3-21.
3
Harlan, J. R. "The Early History of Wheat: Earliest Traces to the Sack of Rome." Wheat Science, Today and
Tomorrow. Ed. L. T. Evans, W. J. Peacock, and O. H. Frankel. Cambridge: Cambridge UP, 1981. 10-14.
4
Walton, John, and David Seddon. "Global Adjustment." Free Markets & Food Riots: the Politics of Global
Adjustment. Oxford, UK: Blackwell, 1994. 1-22.

followed by Egypt in January 1977.

These events serve in large part as signaling

mechanisms, and as such, ought to be distinguished from revolutions.5 Revolutions aim to


change the status quo government, while riots and protests generally arise from specific
grievances.
Public demonstrations in authoritarian countries provide a useful reference for food
protests in Egypt.

Authoritarian rulers fear the escalation of protests from signaling

mechanisms to regime threats. In hybrid autocracies, informational cascades allow the


message of a minority to resonate throughout the public sphere.6 Protests focusing on food,
rather the overthrow of the regime, serve as useful signals in political systems where
bureaucracies and state-controlled media often hide the impacts of public policy.
According to Bienen, authoritarian protests undergo the following stages:
1)

Signaling Function: Protests enable dissatisfied citizens to publicize their


policy preferences. Participants must face political costs, such as detention.

2)

Informational cues: from the size of the first protests can engage a critical
mass.

If a critical mass appears, protesters gain further confidence in

challenging the existing political regime.

Without a critical mass, the

protest movement recedes. At this stage, popular opinion judges the utility
of a regime.
3)

Order is reestablished: or conversely, protests destabilize a regime.7

Hendrix, Cullen, Stephen Haggard, and Beatriz Magaloni. "Grievance and Opportunity: Food Prices, Political
Regime, and Protest." International Studies Association Convention, 15 Feb. 2009. Web. 5 Dec. 2011.
<http://www.kent.ac.uk/brussels/conference/documents/Food_prices-protests.magahaggahendrix_isa.pdf>.
6
Ibid., Kuran, Timur. "Sparks and Prairie Fires: A Theory of Unanticipated Political Revolution." Public
Choice 61.1 (1989): 41-74.
7
Lohmann, Susanne. "The Dynamics of Informational Cascades: The Monday Demonstrations in Leipzig, East
Germany, 1989-91." World Politics 47.1 (1994): 42-101.

Most protests, particularly food protests, remain in the signaling phase.

Their

relatively short existence means that most engage on focused policy issues, forcing
governments to consider policy changes. Bienen and Gersovitz outline an explanation for
food protests relative short life-span. First, subsidy protests are spontaneous and hard to
sustain.

Next, protests lack an articulated agenda beyond annulling price increases.

Furthermore, there is usually little leadership, and if leadership exists, governments use these
occasions to shut down trade unionists or the opposition.8
These arguments ignore the role of common concerns, such as food, in uniting an
opposition. Organization to develop these protests, and a growing habit of taking to the
street, can enable more forceful future protests that threaten regime legitimacy.
A more compelling reason for the relatively short life span of food riots is that
subsidy cuts are often reversed with relative ease, by bureaucratic fiat.9

Subsidies are

budgetary priorities that can be shaped by determined interest groups. Protests by urban
residents near government centers can demonstrate popular will and change policy
calculations for regime survival. The government can easily placate protesters by renouncing
cuts.
The importance of protests as signaling mechanisms emerges from an analysis of
Egyptian policy choices prior to the 1977 riots. Hopkins outlines the four target groups
assessed before the 1977 food riots in Egypt: The government decided between cuts affecting

Bienen, Henry S., and Mark Gersovitz. "Consumer Subsidy Cuts, Violence, and Political
Stability." Comparative Politics 19.1 (1986): 25-44.
Kricheli, Ruth, Yair Livne, and Beatriz Magaloni. "Taking to the Streets: Theory and Evidence on Protests
under Authoritarianism." (2011).
<http://cddrl.stanford.edu/publications/taking_to_the_streets_theory_and_evidence_on_protests_under_authorit
arianism/>.
9
Gutner, Tammi. The Political Economy of Food Subsidy Reform in Egypt. Rep. no. 77. International Food
Policy Research Institute, Nov. 1999. Web.
<http://www.ifpri.org/sites/default/files/pubs/divs/fcnd/dp/papers/dp77.pdf>.

the military, industrialists, financial leaders, and the poor.10 The first three groups had
sufficient access to political leaders to shift the burden of reform to the Egyptian masses.
Protests in 1977 and 1984 provided an important channel of communication in the political
system. The elites seclusion from the masses, and a largely dysfunctional political system,
resulted in hidden or misleading signals from the poor.

The Relationship between Protests and Price


The literature is in agreement that protests coincide with higher price on the global
level. Statistical analyses of the food prices during the most recent peaks of high food prices
demonstrate an increased number of food protests. Lagi records food prices from 2004 to
2011, identifying price peaks coinciding with protests in 2008 and 2011. The study focuses
on protests incidents in Africa and Asia during the 2004 2012 time frame.

Figure 1. Incidence of protests, 2004 - 2011. Protests increase in frequency past a threshold level at 210
points on the FAO price index.11
10

Hopkins, Raymond F. "Political Calculations in Subsidizing Food." Political Calculations in Subsidizing


Food. International Food Policy Research Institute. Web.
<http://www.ifpri.org/sites/default/files/pubs/pubs/books/ppa88/ppa88ch07.pdf>.
11
Lagi, Marco, Karla Z. Bertrand, and Yaneer Bar-Yam. "The Food Crises and Political Instability in North
Africa and the Middle East." New England Complex Systems Institute, 28 Sept. 2011. Web.
<http://necsi.edu/research/social/food_crises.pdf>.

Similar analysis by Brinkman and Hendrix focused on cereal prices during 2007 and
2008, analyzed on a monthly scale, reveals a similar trend.

Figure 2. Cereal Prices and Riots in 2007-2008. An increase in the FAO cereal price index from 150 to
250 resulted in a sharp and limited increase in riots during May and August 2008.12

Underlying these analyses is the increasing globalized nature of modern food


systems, which exposes consumers and producers to price pressures beyond the local
market.13 Food riot literature discusses previous changes on the scale of food systems in the
case of the European states in the 1700s. During that time, locals were increasingly angered
at the loss of food to a national market, often under growing central control and taxation.14
In these cases, a smaller harvest in other regions had adverse affects on the price and
availability of food in producer markets.

12

Brinkman, Henk-Jan S., and Cullen S. Hendrix. "Food Insecurity and Conflict: Applying the WDR
Framework." World Bank Development Repot 2011. World Bank, 2 Aug. 2010.
13
Bonanno, Alessandro. From Columbus to ConAgra: the Globalization of Agriculture and Food. Lawrence,
KS: University of Kansas, 1994.
14
Tilly, Charles, and Gabriel Ardant. "Food Supply and Public Order in Modern Europe."The Formation of
National States in Western Europe. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Publishing, 1975. 380-455.

The research on modern foot protests, noted above, largely ignores local
differentiation. While the literature generally agrees about the positive relationship between
global food prices and protests, policy disparities within each country cause producer and
consumer prices to vary substantially from global indices.15

National Government Policies


The agricultural industry is significantly impacted by government policies through
both budgetary actions and trade policies. Budgetary support directly impacts consumers
through subsidies on basic commodities. Under this lower price structure, consumers will
consume more of these subsidized products.16 Agricultural producers also benefit from a
wide variety of budgetary support, including infrastructure investment, research and
development, and direct reimbursement for production.
Trade policies emerge as an important determinant of local food costs. Countries
may choose to pursue export taxes and bans to reduce local prices. This was the case in
2008, when Ukraine, seeking to blunt local consumers from higher world prices, instituted
wheat export bans. For importing nations, like Egypt, tariff structures remain important. The
Egyptian government has responded to past food crises by lowering tariffs, which may
reduce government revenues but lowers domestic food prices.
In sum, general studies focusing purely on the relationship between global price and
rioting provide a reassuring affirmation of an intuitively understandable phenomenon.
However, these studies fail to fully explain the dynamics within the local environment.

15

Alston, J. M., J. M. Beddow, and P. G. Pardey. "Agricultural Research, Productivity, and Food Prices in the
Long Run." Science 325.5945 (2009): 1209-210.
16
Besley, Timothy, and Ravi Kanbur. "Food Subsidies and Poverty Alleviation." The Economic Journal 98.392
(1988): 701-19.

While the basic commodity price appearing to consumers in Egypt is decoupled from
international rates, Egypts low food self-sufficiency does expose government budgets to
swings in international food prices.

Mechanisms for Food-Related Protests


In Political Order in Changing Societies, Huntington argues that political instability
arises from tensions within the political systems, particularly unfulfilled popular
expectations, social change, and political mobilization of dissatisfied groups.17 Drawing on
this explanation, the academic literature debates the drivers of riots through both the rational
response theory and moral economy arguments.

These mechanisms are important for

understanding the groups mobilized against subsidy reform in Egypt.


The rational response theory favors an approach to riots as rebellions of the belly
based on direct linkage to economic grievances. Bohstetd describes these riots as dependent
on events like harvest failures, unemployment, depressions as the principal causes of riots.18
Affected groups riot in order to bolster their material well being by redistributing food,
changing existing political structures, and forcing government action.19 Grievance literature
ties protest to the relative deprivation theory, where the poor take to the streets in opposition
to prosperity among specific groups.20
Walton and Seddon dismiss this argument as insufficient as it fails to explain the
process in which people decide how and when to act.21 Tilly asserts that food riots in
17

Huntington, Samuel P. Political Order in Changing Societies. New Haven: Yale University Press, 1968.
Bohstedt, John. Riots and Community Politics in England and Wales: 1790-1810. Cambridge, MA: Harvard
University Press, 1983.
19
Walton and Seddon 24.
20
Gurr, Ted Robert. Why Men Rebel. Princeton, NJ: Published for the Center of International Studies, Princeton
University Press, 1970.
21
Walton and Seddon 31.
18

France often occurred as harvests improved, rather than during the depth of famine.22 While
one might excuse the grievance model for its limited explanations, Lichbach further
undercuts this approach with analysis countering that unequal income distribution is a strong
determinant of political unrest.23
Clark asserts that price discrepancies, rather than absolute prices, drove European
protests.24 These discrepancies could be described on the geographic scale, between town
and countryside, on the moral scale, between the fair conception of price and the market
status, or the temporal scale, referencing past price trends. Before discussing theories of
moral economy, it is important to note that Clarks analysis elucidates the most recent food
research along the price-riot nexus. The previously noted research demonstrates that a slow,
gradual increase would remain unproblematic, but a sudden inflation in food prices, as
witnessed in the past decade, drives popular anger. The spike in prices during the last
decades may have stronger roots in the popular memory of affordable bread, rather than the
actual economic impact of higher prices.

Bienen and Gersovitzs analysis of previous

decades food riots underlines the connection linking protests to immediate and large
increases (at least 25%) in food prices.25
The shouts of dignity and fairness resonated from the town squares of 18th century
England to Tahrir Square. In The Moral Economy of the English Crowd in the Eighteenth
Century (1971), Thompson opposed the tendency of rational response theory to connect data

22

Tilly, Louise A. "The Food Riot as a Form of Political Conflict in France." The Journal of Interdisciplinary
History 2.1 (1971): 23-57.
23
Lichbach, Mark I. "An Evaluation of "Does Economic Inequality Breed Political Conflict?" World
Politics 41.4 (1989): 431-70.
24
Clark, Peter. "Popular Protest and Disturbance in Kent, 15581640." The Economic History Review 29.3
(1976): 365-82.
25
Bienen and Gersovitz 1986.

10

in economic history, such as unemployment rates, with popular protest.26 Instead, Thompson
argues for a greater understanding of the social norms. He explains food riots in the 18th and
19th century as a result of changing market practices that disrupted accepted social patterns.
During this time, Adam Smith argued for free corn trade, among other liberal ideas.27
Market practices, liberated from protectionist local regulations, helped develop a national
market for agricultural products. While benefits accrued from more efficient distribution of
bountiful harvests, an insufficient harvest would ripple across a nation. The local tradition of
social norms and obligations was exchanged for a more unified domestic market in food.28
Tilly (1971) demonstrates in a similar analysis of seventeenth century French food riots.
Reduced government regulation broke up the extremely local paternalism and noblesse
oblige that had previously provided for the poor. The formation of a national market in grain
eroded local control and stability.
In the modern context, the moral economy argument relates to a perceived decline in
living standards and attachment to a particular foodstuff. In 1905, rioters in Santiago, Chile
protested food prices for cultural reasons: Increasing meat prices reduced access to only the
richest residents.29 An emotional attachment to a certain foodstuff is also apparent in the
most recent food riots. Italians launched pasta protests in response to the 2007 price peaks,
which had raised prices of the basic staple by 30%. The perceived overpricing of cottage
cheese, a staple of the Israeli breakfast, sparked demonstrations in the summer of 2011 that

26

Thompson, E. P. "The Moral Economy Of The English Crowd In The Eighteenth Century." Past and
Present 50.1 (1971): 76-136.
27
Smith, Adam. "Digression concerning the Corn Trade and Corn Laws." Wealth of Nations.
28
Walton and Seddon 72.
29
Orlove, Benjamin S. "Meat and Strength: The Moral Economy of a Chilean Food Riot."Cultural
Anthropology 12.2 (1997): 234-68.

11

quickly evolved into countrywide protests against the high cost of living.30 In developed
economies, food prices hardly affect the household budget.

Instead, consumers view

cherished food items as proxies for social well-being. Egyptians may also view the heavilysubsidized baladi bread as a marker for social welfare.
Sharp counters the moral economy argument by accusing Thompson of understating
the pain, desperation, and anger [the poor] felt in times of depression and scarcity.31
However, in cases of true hunger, it is unlikely that political action would result, as popular
protest would not fulfill immediate individual needs.
Other authors note the role of community dynamics and the state in these
mechanisms. Snyder and Tilly reject the grievance-based approach, pointing to changing
relations between individuals and coercive power of the government as a determinant force
in protest.32 Borrowing from literature on civil war, Fearon and Latin demonstrate that it is
political opportunity that determines the rise of opposition.33
Hendrix similarly focuses on political structure as an important element of food
protests.34 In a study of different regime types, hybrid autocratic regimes face more political
protest during food price fluctuation than do democracies or full autocracies. The authors
define a hybrid regime as one with formal democratic institutions like elections, but run by a
single party. Examples include Mexico under the PRI and the subject of this thesis, Egypt.

30

Golan, Galia. "The Domestic Impact on Israel of the Spring, Summer, and September." Middle East
Program: Occasional Paper Series. Woodrow Wilson International Center for Scholars, 2011. Web.
<http://wilsoncenter.net/sites/default/files/Domestic%20Impact%20on%20Israel.pdf>.
31
Sharp, Buchanan. In Contempt of All Authority: Rural Artisans and Riot in the West of England, 1586-1660.
Berkeley: University of California, 1980.
32
Snyder, David, and Charles Tilly. "Hardship and Collective Violence in France, 1830-1960." American
Sociological Review 37.5: 520-32.
33
Fearon, James D., and David D. Laitin. "Ethnicity, Insurgency, and Civil War."American Political Science
Review 97.01 (2003): 75.
34
Hendrix et al. 2009.

12

Food Subsidies and Egyptian Society


While tariffs and trade policy do play some role in determining the price of food in
Egypt, consumer subsidies have historically had the largest impact. Consumers, rather than
producers, are the key constituencies for Egyptian political leaders. As a result, consumer
subsidies and their withdrawal determine the relationship between protests and food prices in
Egypt.
Thomson posits that the Egyptian subsidy system emerges out of the aims of
government development policies and the characteristics of the Egyptian population.35
Subsidies provide food supply at a stable price level, alleviating hunger and maintaining
human capital. Egypts high degrees of urbanization and population concentration provided
the opportunity for an interventionist state to develop a subsidized commodities distribution
and bakery network.
Egyptian government policy has viewed industrialization as the key development
strategy. The government attempted to support new industry by ensuring low wages by
maintaining a low cost of living. Food, the most basic commodity, emerges as a primary
means of managing these costs.
While agreeing that economic forces play a role in setting subsidies, Hopkins
discounts the development-driven argument by highlighting that political leaders value
tenure in office. Instead, he argues that political calculations are usually decisive and that
they fully explain the expansion and contraction of state intervention in the food system.36
These political calculations are focused on regime survival. A careful balancing of political

35
36

Thomson, Anne. "Egypt: Food Security and Food Aid." Food Policy 8.3 (1983).
Hopkins 1988.

13

support and opposition to food subsidies determines a regimes propensity towards reform or
further entrenchment.
Hopkins outlines the origins of subsidies as one of three factors: social welfare goals,
external international factors, and the political impacts of subsidy policies. It is important to
note that social welfare, in his critical view, arises primarily from ideological calculations by
socialist and populist leaders.
This model fits well for the Egyptian case. As in other former British colonies, the
external pressure of World War II brought about a system of food rationing to control the
supply and price of basic goods. Following the end of hostilities, Egypt maintained these
controls. Nassers socialist ideology and cheap American wheat enabled the expansion of the
food subsidy system.
Hopkins argument emerges as particularly salient in Egypts experience of dictators
concerned about public opinion of certain groups, rather than extensive economic reforms.
While emerging for war exigencies, food rationing became embedded as a citizens right and
While emerging for war exigencies, food rationing became embedded as a citizens right and
blame fell on the government for price increases.
Vocal constituencies become a central element in a political analysis of food
subsidies. Subsidies can instill support for the regime by providing material side payments
to these constituencies and providing a diffuse symbolic fulfillment of a social contract.37
These arguments combine the rational response and moral economy theories of food protests.
Singerman, writing in 1995, explains that:
The Egyptian Government's policies of political exclusion have gone hand in hand
with their public commitment to provide for the basic needs of the population... the
37

Hopkins 1988.

14

government maintains its legitimacy by providing goods and services to the


population."38
Sadiki has defined this arrangement, prevalent in the Arab World, as demuqratiyat alkhubz39, in which bread or other basic commodities are the currency for regimes to buy
popular support.40
Food subsidies are particularly attractive to rulers worried about large urban
populations, who have a propensity to politically organize and instigate policy change.
Urban areas contain civil servants and urban labor, which often form the strongest nonmilitary interest groups. In many decolonized nations, the large low-income urban class
worked for the government. Subsidies targeted towards these groups strengthen the link
between government and population.

The selectorate, made up of the subset of the

population that threatens regime rule, is thus coopted.41


It is important to note that price controls also negatively impact agricultural
producers. The Egyptian food system, particularly wheat controls, has substantially reduced
producer incentives. Between 1950 and 1980, domestic wheat production grew by only 76%
while overall consumption grew nearly 450%.42

Imports financed through government

purchase and food aid provided the bulk of this difference. As demonstrated later in this
chapter, PL-480 food aid and its provision of cheap American wheat encouraged the shift in
consumer demand.

38

Singerman, Diane. Avenues of Participation: Family, Politics, and Networks in Urban Quarters of Cairo.
Princeton, NJ: Princeton UP, 1995.
39
The phrase can be literally translated as democracy of bread. Thought often used to refer to other social
service provisions, the phrases focus on the food-governance link highlights its importance.
40
Sadiki, Larbi. "Towards Arab Liberal Governance: From the Democracy of Bread to the Democracy of the
Vote." Third World Quarterly 18.1 (1997): 127-48.
41
Bueno de Mesquita, Bruce, Alastair Smith, Randolph M. Siverson, and James D. Morrow. 2003. The Logic
of Political Survival. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
42
Thompson 1983.

15

The Role of Food Aid


Egypt received extensive food aid from the United States through the Public Law 480
program, which in turn solidified the Egyptian demand for bread and built government
capacity for distribution.

Food thus became deeply political, involving both domestic

political consideration and Egypts foreign policy orientation.


The Egyptian government has maintained these stable prices through extensive
imports and the Public Law 480 food aid program.

During earlier decades, food aid

comprised more than 50% of food imports, reducing pressure for budgetary reform.43
Egypts government was able to fully develop the subsidy system, and later extend its
survival, using food subsidies.44
The role of Public 480 aid in Bangladesh demonstrates the impact of food aid on
recipient nations. Public Law 480 helped bolster the rationing system of the then-East
Pakistan, dramatically changing local diets. Bengalis moved from a traditional rice diet,
produced locally, towards higher wheat consumption, enabled by American farms. This
evolution exposed Bangladesh towards greater dependence on foreign food sources.45
A similar trend can be witnessed in Egypt. Income growth and population do not
fully explain the 450% rise in consumption for wheat during the thirty years preceding 1977.
During the post-war era through the 1970s, Egypt maintained stable nominal bread prices. In
real terms, prices declined, driving an increase in consumption.46

43

Thompson 1983.
Hopkins 1988.
45
Ahmed, Raisuddin, Steve Haggblade, and Tawfiq-e-Elahi Chowdhury. Out of the Shadow of Famine:
Evolving Food Markets and Food Policy in Bangladesh. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins UP, 2000.
46
Alderman, Harold, Joachim Von Braun, and Ahmed Sakr. Egypt's Food Subsidy and Rationing System: a
Description. Washington, D.C.: International Food Policy Research Institute, 1982.
44

16

The Political Economy of Economic Reform in Egypt and Developing Economies


The era of economic reform in Egypt began in October 1974, when President Anwar
Sadat announced the new policy of Infitah.

The opening of the Egyptian economy

included allowing direct private investment, reducing state intervention in the economy, and
partnering with international finance organizations.47 Sadats new orientation marked a
dramatic policy shift from the import-substitution and self-sufficiency promoted under
Nasser.
Conditions placed on the government of Egypt by creditors, mainly Western nations
and international organizations, slowly pushed forward this economic liberalization. These
programs included privatization of state enterprises, foreign exchange adjustments, and
subsidy reform.
The literature on economic reforms, and the requirement for their success, will guide
the subsequent analysis of Egyptian food subsidies from the 1970s to the present. Haggard
and Webb outline the successful elements of an economic reform policy.48 The literature on
policy design largely aligns with the same general framework, but provides differing
diagnoses on the challenges of implementation.
Successful reform programs generally share the following characteristics:
1. Acting without delay builds public credibility. Rapid implementation following the
formulation and announcement of reforms strengthens the potential for success. In
cases where macroeconomic balances are not as severe, slower reforms may also be
successful.

47

Abdel-Khalek, Gouda. "Looking Outside, or Turning Northwest? On the Meaning and External Dimension of
Egypt's Infitah 1971-1980." Social Problems 28.4 (1981): 394-409.
48
Haggard, Stephan, and Steven B. Webb. "What Do We Know About The Political Economy Of Economic
Policy Reform?" The World Bank Research Observer 8.2 (1993): 143-68.

17

2. Instituting reforms at the onset of a new administration allows shifting political blame
to previous leaders and ensuring sufficient time for the full implementation of the
reform package.
3. Reforms result in both gains and losses to social groups. Bundling reform measures
can better distribute the impacts of reform. In addition, compensation is an important
means of winning the support of a negatively impacted group.

Given Egypts closed political structure until January 2011, it is also important to
discuss economic reform within the context of authoritarian states. Many economists view
states with strong executives or limited checks-and-balances as successful implementers of
reform. Pinochets liberalization of the Chilean economy, later reaffirmed by democratic
elections in 1989, takes a prominent place among supporters of the authoritarian
advantage.49 However, neither autocracies nor democracies are immune to the challenges
faced by reformist governments.
Reform efforts require commitment and perseverance, as the benefits of liberalization
may only bear fruit after several years. The delayed rewards of policy adjustment raises the
barrier for leaders beholden to public opinion. The election cycle of democracies may
impede strategic longer-term thinking. In contrast, long-lasting authoritarian regimes may
include the distant benefits to immediate policy calculations.50
In less-developed countries, income disparities and social stratification emerge as a
primary area for conflict. Alesina and Tabellini demonstrate that greater inequality leads to

49
50

Rodrik, Dani. "Understanding Economic Policy Reform." Journal of Economic Literature 34.1 (1996).
Haggard and Webb 1993.

18

polarization of society, particularly during points of policy change.51 These groups, with
hardened opinions, may begin a war of attrition, with little desire for compromise.
Subsequent studies by Alesina and Drazen demonstrate that in more unequal societies, a
longer delay occurs before stabilization and reforms are implemented.52 An argument may
emerge that authoritarian regimes are more free from these rent-seeking groups prevalent in
democratic processes. However, Olson demonstrates that decreased turnover and political
competition result in more entrenched interest groups.53 Authoritarian regimes have greater
coercive force to suppress dissent, but policy implementation may be less informed as public
debate is stifled. Only select interest groups may have the sufficient resources and access to
opine on policy, thus excluding significant portions of the public interest. On the topic of
these entrenched interest groups, Ranis and Mahmoud assert, resistance to vested interests
can be overcome only when the system has no other ways of avoiding the required
adjustment.54 This element comes into play during Egypts reforms in the 1980s and 1990s.
Richards highlights extensive economic rents as the key differentiator between Egypt
and other countries attempting reform.55 Egypts use of oil revenues, remittances, and most
critically, strategic rent, serves as an escape hatch for the regime. Strategic rent refers to the
extensive aid agreements between the United States and Egypt, which grew dramatically
following Egypts peace treaty with Israel. While Egypt shares the characteristics of other
less developed countries in its large and ineffective government and powerful interest groups,
51

Alesina, Alberto, and Guido Tabellini. "External Debt, Capital Flight and Political Risk."Journal of
International Economics 27.3 (1989): 199-220.
52
Alesina, Alberto, and Allan Drazen. "Why Are Stabilizations Delayed?" American Economic Review 85.5
(1991): 1170-88.
53
Olson, Mancur. "Autocracy, Democracy, and Prosperity." Ed. Richard Zeckhauser. Strategy and Choice.
Cambridge, MA: MIT, 1991.
54
Ranis, Gustav, and Syed Akhtar. Mahmood. The Political Economy of Development Policy Change.
Cambridge, MA: B. Blackwell, 1992.
55
Richards, Alan. The political economy of dilatory reform: Egypt in the 1980s. World Development. 19.12
(1991): 1721-30.

19

it is these three rents that decouple government budgets from the domestic economic
situation. Given Egypts declining oil revenues and unstable remittance flows, strategic rent
has become the most dependable external support for the government. The countrys foreign
policy orientation has enabled a closer relationship with the United States, increased access
to aid, by extension, increased bargaining power with international lending organizations.
Multiple and competing goals, including strategic interests and economic agreements,
complicate the relationship between loan providers, aiming for better government
accountability, and the recipient state.

The United States - Egypt relationship, which

intertwines foreign aid and American regional goals, has undercut efforts towards aid
effectiveness through conditionality. Rodrik notes, promises of aid, even when tied to
economic improvements, can result in groups delaying stabilization until aid reduces
costs for the groups in question.56 The use of strategic rent may exacerbate the social
gridlock caused by inequality. In the following case studies of failure, one is likely to
witness the effect of aid in dissuading the follow-through of reform. As noted economic
Jeffrey Sachs explains, Aid is only helpful once a government is committed to reform.57
Providing conditional-based aid to a government that lacks sufficient will or intent to reform
may only result in disappointment for the donor.
As a final note to this section, price fluctuations of subsidized food commodities will
likely to provide added incentive for reform. Ranis and Mahmoud demonstrate that reform
efforts in less developed countries can be tied to world price shifts for primary products and

56

Rodrik 1996.
Sachs, Jeffrey. Life in the Economic Emergency Room. The Political Economy of Policy Reform. Ed. John
Williamson, 1994.
57

20

business cycles in developed economies.58 Given Egypts exposure, via import dependency,
to world food prices, reform will likely be intertwined with these commodities fluctuations.

Applying Economic Liberalization Lessons to Food Subsidy Reforms


The integration of concepts in economic liberalization and food subsidies reform
serves as a final step towards developing an analytical baseline for the following case studies.
Hopkins compares food subsidies reform in developing countries using Egypt and Sri
Lanka as opposing examples. Hopkins criticizes the ineffectiveness of Egyptian reform,
particularly in 1977, over the following issues: First, government actions were neither well
prepared nor undertaken in a way that promoted acquiescence.

Second, the Egyptian

government was divided over the issue. And third, the government was less legitimate than
was the Sri Lankan government.59
This framework provides three criteria for explaining relative success and failure:
First, public outreach and preparation ensure public consent.

Second, bureaucratic and

political unity ensures implementation. Third, regime legitimacy, distinct from this policy
action, is an important element towards strengthening implementation.
Beyond these three reasons, we must also include some measure of public confidence
in government functions. For public consent, the withdrawal of subsidies must rebalance the
social contract with some other form of positive government involvement. The public must
believe that in some form, its economic status will improve. An ineffective government

58
59

Ranis and Mahmoud 1992.


Hopkins 1998.

21

promising to cut a seemingly effective program draws the ire of a public dissatisfied with
previous reforms and changes.60
A leading scholar of the Egyptian subsidy system, Tammi Gutner, highlights
government commitment to reform, public perception towards reform, and strategic
implementation of reform as key determinants of success.61 Her analysis dovetails with
existing economic reform literature, but tailors recommendations to the Egyptian political
context and food subsidy reform.
Gutner agrees that government commitment to reform is strongest after elections,
when legitimacy is strongest.

New regimes can demonstrate popular support among

entrenched constituencies or against groups angered by the cuts.62 Long-lasting regimes that
attempt cuts, but lack popular legitimacy, face greater challenges.

Regime change

engineered by a small military cohort (Sadat-Mubarak, for example), may not maintain
legitimacy to implement reform.
In contrast to previously cited authors, Gutner explains that an incremental approach
towards subsidies prevents individuals groups from linking up in opposition and instead
spreads the burden of adjustment. This represents an important distinction from the
literature on economic liberalization, which usually cautions against gradualism in favor of
bundling. Gutner thus targets her advice to the authoritarian context of the Egyptian political
system, where the regime can determine policy without extensive public consultations.
In addition to defusing tension through gradual reforms, public outreach is another
successful tactic. Public perception towards reform often revolves around issues of equity.

60

Graham, Carol. Safety Nets, Politics, and the Poor: Transitions to Market Economies. Washington, D.C.:
Brookings Institution, 1994.
61
Gutner 1999.
62
Alderman 1991.

22

Dialogue with middle class groups can engage actors in ensuring that the withdrawal of
subsidies to the better off does not result in protests. Governments can provide an economic
vision in return.63
Compensation, originally broached during the economic reform discussion, is
particularly important for food subsidies reform. Compensation helps offset the increased
cost of food. Gutner cites Pakistans approach, where government salaries increased or taxes
were lowered when subsidy withdrawal occurred. However, this approach has major failings
for individuals in the informal economy: Minimum wage or government salary increases do
not apply to many poor urban constituents.

The preceding literature review has discussed the theoretical context of food riots and
reform efforts. When discussing Egypt, the literature primarily focuses on the 1977 food
riots with only passing mention to other incidents.

This following chapters will apply

theories and understandings about food riots and reforms to the range of incidents since
1977.

Drawing together these incidents will reveal a progression of Egyptian policy

responses, demonstrating how reform of the food subsidy system takes place within the
larger political context.

63

Nelson, Joan M. Fragile Coalitions: The Politics of Economic Adjustment. New Brunswick, USA:
Transaction, 1989.

23

24

III. Two Days in January: The First Crisis in Subsidy Reform


The Riots and Aftermath of January 18 19, 1977

The origin of Egypts challenge with food subsidy reform emerges from the aborted
reforms of January 1977.

The governments abrupt announcement of policy changes

interlocked with existing social complaints to create the riots and demonstrations that
engulfed Egypt for two days. As a result of these events, the Egyptian government retreated
in its reform efforts. In later years, reform was dominated by a more cautious and gradual
approach to prevent a reoccurrence of mass popular unrest. The riots of 1977 provide the
essential starting position for understanding how the Egyptian government accomplished
later subsidy reform.
The following chapter first introduces the economic and political background to
contextualize the aborted reforms and popular opposition. Subsequent sections describe the
events of the January 1977 and their implications both for reform and Egypts domestic and
regional standing. The final section covers subsidy changes and reform efforts later in the
decade.

The Beginnings of Infitah: The Open Door Policy


Anwar Sadat came to power in 1970 with the heavy burden of economic challenges
and the need for modernization.

Nassers Egypt had created a government-dominated

economy with excessive and growing external imbalances and debts. Sadats decisions to
turn rightward, towards Western capitalism, riled Nasserites and left-wing Egyptians.

25

The shift of power between establishment Nasserists to the new capitalists supportive
of liberalization naturally upset the existing social balance. Egyptian left-wing critic Nadime
Lachine characterizes the Nasser regime as a new bourgeoisie to replace the pre-1952 rural
and urban capitalist alliance.

Army officers, professionals, and mid-level bureaucrats

dominated this class.64 The state expropriated the means of production, leading to a socialist
outlook and central planning. In contrast, Sadat embraced private capital, particularly from
abroad, as a key towards reforming the economy. Waterbury highlights Law 65 of 1971 as
the first step towards securing foreign investment with a loosened corporate tax regime and
the autonomy of joint ventures.65 A marked shift from the nationalization campaigns of
Nasser can be seen by the 1974 decision by the Highest Court of Appeals declaring all
confiscation and sequestration of private property illegal.66 Thus, Sadat realigned economic
policy towards the West, creating a more robust framework of property rights protection and
private capital investment.
Separate from ideological considerations, subsidies ballooned prior to the January
1977 riots due to global macroeconomic changes. In particular, the increase in world oil
prices impacted the cost of petroleum and all goods transported in the economy. In 1972, by
consequence, food security became a major policy issue, as world grain prices increased
from $60 to $250/ton. The infitah era, Waterbury states, marks a sharp break with the
socialism of the 1960s, at which time consumer subsidies first gained some importance.67
Until 1977, the Egyptian government had largely resolved to insulate the Egyptian people
from this inflation.
64

Lachine, Nadime. "Class Roots of the Egyptian Regime." MERIP Reports 56 (1977): 3-7. Print.
Waterbury, John. The Egypt of Nasser and Sadat: The Political Economy of Two Regimes. Princeton, NJ:
Princeton UP, 1983. 129. Print.
66
Lachine 1977.
67
Waterbury 218.
65

26

Semblances of Political Liberalization


While the Open Door policy markedly reshaped the economy and threatened existing
institutional and social interests, Sadat also began pursuing political liberalization.
During the early transition years of the regime, Sadat demonstrated a desire to realign
Egypt away from the one-party system of Nasser, dominated by the Arab Socialist Union
(ASU). In May 1977, Sadat told a crowd of Nasserite students, What does Nasserism
mean? It turned out that we must reintroduce the detention camps, custodianship, and
sequestration. We must revert to a one-opinion, one-party system, abandon democracy, and
adopt Marxism.68 The ASU and its leadership represented a competing power base to
Nassers successor.
The Corrective Revolution of 1971 enabled Sadat to take control of ASU functions
and distance his rivals. After increasing opposition and an attempted coup attempt by Ali
Sabri and other figures of the ancien regime, Sadat dismissed Sabri from his position as Vice
President and demoted his co-conspirators. Rivlin characterizes this period as the ousting of
the leftists, given Sadats increasing focus on private capital.69 Waterbury characterizes
Sadats perception of the left as his primary source of opposition. In retrospect it appears
that Sadat must have anticipated most of his political opposition from the left in the form of
Nasserists, Marxists, and assorted radical student.

He may have overestimated their

potential, but given the disturbances of 1972 and 1973 that is understandable.70 These

68

2 May 1977 Press Review, Foreign Broadcast Information Service Database, Cairo Domestic Service in
Arabic
69
Rivlin, Paul. The Liberalization of the Egyptian Economy: An Examination of the Decision-making Process.
Tel Aviv: Shiloah Center for Middle Eastern and African Studies, Tel Aviv University, 1981. 7.
70
Waterbury 359.

27

disturbances, led by students immersed in Nasserist ideology, opposed the increasingly


obvious change of official ideology.
Sadats standing among the Egyptian public rose following the 1973 October War,
which helped disperse the anti-Sadat student sentiment of the previous two years. In April
1974, Sadat issued the October Paper, which rejected the single party governance of the
previous decades.71
The new political outlook incorporated platforms (manabir) into the ASU. By 1976,
Sadat organized politics through three groups, representing the Right (Liberal Socialist
Organization,

Al-Ahrar

Al-Eshtarakyeen),

Left

(National

Progressive

Unionist

Organization, al-Tagammu ), and Center (Egyptian Arab Socialist Organization, Tanzim


Masri Al-Araby Al-Eshtraky). The subsequent parliamentary election that year tilted heavily
rightwards. The centrist party, openly supported by Sadat, won 280 of 352 seats. A strong
contingent of 48 Independents successfully won office, but the designated parties of the
Right and Left won merely twelve and two seats, respectively. Waterbury characterizes
this period, including the fall of 1976 and the first two weeks of January 1977, as the
heydey of Sadats liberal experiment.72
While Egypt desperately required an infusion of foreign aid to cover its balance-ofpayments deficit, timing for reform was key. Subsidy announcements were only made
following the 1976 elections.
In Waterburys judgement, Sadat was more open to political diversity than Nasser,
but ultimately, Sadat reverted to the Nasserist style he nominally abhorred.73 In large part,
this was undoubtedly due to the events of 1977, which pushed against the political
71

Beattie, Kirk J. Egypt during the Sadat Years. New York: Palgrave, 2000. 167.
Waterbury 366-367.
73
Waterbury 354.
72

28

liberalization of the earlier decade. Sadats liberalization likely intended to undermine the
Arab Socialist Union, the vanguard of Nassers rule, but also raised expectations regarding
political openness and change.
Following the election, Sadat strengthened the reformist elements within the
government. In November 1976, a cabinet reshuffle focused on bringing more reformminded players into the cabinet.74 Ironically, these changes actually highlight the ongoing
disagreements among the elite on ongoing liberalization and proposed changes to the subsidy
system.

Financial Decisions, International Creditors, and the Road to January


During the entirety of the Sadat era, Egypt suffered an increasing budget deficit and a
significant balance-of-payments challenge from excessive imports.

Hirst and Beeson

calculated that in 1973, national debt stood at 1.25 billion Egyptian pounds (EP), with an
additional 2 billion Egyptian pound military debt to the USSR. Each subsequent year saw a
significant rise in the annual deficit, from 249.8 million EP in 1973, 670 million in 1974, to
1,386 million in 1975. In the second half of 1976, Egypt witnessed 1.25 billion EP deficit.75
The increasingly deteriorating situation forced Prime Minister Mamdouh Salem to confront
the budget imbalance.
In order to close the deficit, the GOE had three options: tax the rich, cut military
expenditures, or rely on external borrowing.76 Egypts tax collection rates are notoriously
low, and given the Infitah reliance on bourgeois support, taxes would not fit within the GOE
policy orientation or capacity. Despite ongoing American shuttle diplomacy on Arab-Israeli
74

Feiler 193.
Hirst, David, and Irene Beeson. Sadat. London: Faber and Faber, 1981. 123.
76
Ansari, Hamied. Egypt, the Stalled Society. Albany: State University of New York Press, 1986. 185.
75

29

peace, the continued threat of war with Israel discarded any possibility of cutting military
expenditures. As a result, external borrowing became the most viable option. Egypts two
most appealing sources of funding were the oil-rich Arab states and Western finance
agencies under the guise of the United States.
Egypt had an extensive aid relationship with the wealthier Gulf states. Pan-Arab
support for Egypt, a front-line country in the fight against Israel, intended to bolster its
strategic position. Feiler highlights the year 1976 as a major turning point in policy, when
the individual Arab states began funneling funding through the Gulf Organization for the
Development of Egypt (GDFE). Managers of this fund evaluated Egyptian requests for aid,
and added the primary condition that Egypt accept IMF reforms. Upon its founding its July
1976, the GDFE received only $2 billion in funding, much less than the $12 billion requested
by Sadat.77 In October 1976, the GDFE, a consortium of Arab countries, refused to provide a
$1-1.2 billion loan to fund Egypts balance of payments deficit.78 In this context, Egypts
situation was clearly dire, as its balance of payment gap stood at around $4 billion in 1975.79
The Western finance agencies remained the next appealing options. However, the IMF took
a strong approach against Egypts widely-applied subsidies on basic goods.
Throughout this period, posturing on Egyptian national sovereignty became common.
Minister of the Treasury Muhammad Zaki Shafi stated: We will not bow to any pressure,
even while Egyptian officials repeatedly traveled abroad with requests for aid.

77

Feiler, Gil. Economic Relations between Egypt and the Gulf Oil States, 1967-2000: Petro Wealth and
Patterns of Influence. Brighton, England: Sussex Academic, 2003. Print.166.
78
Adams, Richard H. Self-targeted Subsidies: The Distributional Impact of the Egyptian Food Subsidy System.
Washington, DC: World Bank, Poverty Reduction and Economic Management Network, Poverty Division,
2000. Print; Feiler 139.
79
Waterbury, John. Egypt : Burdens of the Past, Options for the Future. Bloomington: Indiana University
Press, 1978. 307.

30

Riots in the Street: A Popular Uprising and the Official Response


In January 1977, Egypt complied with IMF negotiators and undertook a first step
towards reducing subsidies. The Egyptian food subsidy system has three types of bread and
flour 82 percent extraction, know as baladi, 76 percent extraction, know as shami, and 72
percent extraction, know as fino. In 1977, the price of lower-grade baladi and shami bread
remained untouched. Meanwhile, price increases were announced for high-grade fino bread
(50 percent increase), 72 percent grade flour (67 percent), sugar (4 percent), rice (20 percent),
tea (canceled subsidy), butane cooking gas (46 percent), gasoline (26-31 percent), and
cigarettes.80

While the most essential commodities remained unchanged, the public

responded with extreme opposition.


Following the announcement of the subsidy cuts on January 17, thousands took to the
streets in major Egyptian cities, representing a major affront in Egypts repressive political
system. In Cairo, 2,000 4,000 protestors riots.81 In Alexandria, 20,000 people marched.
Authorities placed a nighttime curfew over major cities and set up barricades.82 Local
newspapers highlighted the damage done to private property and institutions through fires
bombs and crowd violence.83 The government suspended studies at universities and schools
for two days.84 In sum, 79 were reported killed and 566 injured during the rioting, with
around 1,250 arrested.85

80

Alderman, Harold, and Joachim Von Braun. Egypt's Food Subsidy Policy: Lessons and Options. Washington,
D.C.: International Food Policy Research Institute, 1986.
81

Daines, Victoria, John Walton, and David Seddon. Free Markets and Food Riots: The Politics of Global
Adjustment. Oxford: Blackwell, 1994. Print. 184.
82
19 January 1977 Press Review, Foreign Broadcast Information Service Database, Paris AFP in English
83
19 January 1977 Press Review, Foreign Broadcast Information Service Database, Cairo MENA in Arabic
84
19 January 1977 Press Review, Foreign Broadcast Information Service Database, Cairo Domestic Service in
Arabic
85
24 January 1977 Press Review, Foreign Broadcast Information Service Database, Cairo Domestic Service in
Arabic. Tanner, Henry. "A Stringent Decree Put to Vote in Egypt." New York Times 11 Feb. 1977. Print.

31

Official Response to Riots: Rhetorical Explanations and Attacks


The government engaged in a multi-pronged approach towards confronting popular
protest. On media outlets, officials reiterated the need to reform the subsidy system to
protect the poor and resuscitate state finances. Simultaneously, blame for violence was
firmly placed on left wing elements and the Soviet Union, rather than legitimate popular
sentiment.
On January 18, Deputy Prime Minister Kaysuni, Minister of the Economy Hamid AlSayih, Minister of Finance Salah Hamid, and chief editors of the countrys leading
newspapers participated in a televised debate on the proposed reforms. Kaysuni argued that
in order to overcome the severe and profound economic situation, Egypt must directly
confront in deficit. Interestingly, in a relatively closed authoritarian government, Kaysuni
argues that GOE must submit an honest budget that refrains from making promises that
we cannot keep we cannot deceive the people. In essence, openness appears to be the
underlying strategy for this first preliminary round of subsidy cuts. The GOE leadership
publicly disclosed and discussed these subsidy changes, and engaged in a well-publicized
campaign to explain its eventual decision.86
As the leader of these reforms, Kaysuni argues that in Egypts hierarchy of interests,
subsidy cuts were the best option. The Egyptian budget, in his conception, was divided along
three main objectives. The budget protects military and investments targeted towards social
and economic development, while targeting the allocations for expenditure items. Kaysuni
appealed to nationalist sentiment, asking rhetorically how the military, on which we pin our

86

19 January 1977 Press Review, Foreign Broadcast Information Service Database, Cairo MENA news service
in Arabic

32

hopes for the liberation of our lands, could face cuts in its one-fourth stake of the national
budget. In hindsight, this ironic appeal highlights not nationalist sentiment, but the integral
role of the military in Egyptian public life. Within a year, Sadat will have traveled to
Jerusalem, and in 1979, signed a peace treaty with Israel.87
Kaysuni attempts to differentiate the elements of subsidy reform from the anger of the
masses. In his view, the toiling masses will be unaffected by the reforms, which will
instead cut into the huge profits of commodity dealers. Salah Hamid attempts to reiterate
that basic commodities, such as bread, meat, and lentils, will be unaffected. The toiling
classes remain an important element throughout this discussion, in attempt to paint these
reforms as populist attempts.88
Finally, in an important note given the aforementioned discussion regarding foreign
creditors role in these reforms, Kaysuni denies this decision was made under pressure
from any foreign source such as the IMF.89 This statement underlines the desire from the
GOE to maintain the semblance of independence, although continuing to rely heavily of
foreign infusion of aid and loans.
On January 18, Dr. Fuad Muhyi ad-Din, Minister of State for Peoples Assembly
affairs, during the plan and budget committee meeting, stated, The government is ready to
join in making an objective review of the price list announced yesterday in such a way as not
to affect the toiling classes. In the same report, Vice Premier Kaysuni mentioned the further
discussions of prices among assembly members would be taken into consideration.90 This
87

19 January 1977 Press Review, Foreign Broadcast Information Service Database, Cairo MENA news service
in Arabic
88
19 January 1977 Press Review, Foreign Broadcast Information Service Database, Cairo MENA news service
in Arabic
89
19 January 1977 Press Review, Foreign Broadcast Information Service Database, Cairo MENA news service
in Arabic
90
19 January 1977 Press Review, Foreign Broadcast Information Service Database, Cairo MENA news service

33

quick questioning of the policy, emerging from the highest reaches of the elite, only served to
further embolden protests in the following day.
The Arab Socialist Party statement, released on January 19, appeared to further
highlight splits within the elite.

The partys parliament announced its disapproval of

commodity price increases that would harm broad masses of the people. In contrast to
Kasyunis attempts to differentiate these commodity cuts from the toiling masses, the party
statement instead takes on the populist narrative. The General Federation of Students issued
a similar call to revise the recent decisions on raising prices, appealing to the Peoples
Assembly to stop the reforms.91
A statement from the Interior Ministry on the evening of January 18 sets up the
governments assault on violent protests as the work of leftist agents. The statement places
blame on Communist and Marxist elements for attacks and violence in Cairo, Helwan, and
Alexandria. In particular, the statement singles out groups calling themselves Nasserites.
Given Sadats uneasy relationship with the legacy of his predecessor, such as a statement
identifies these groups as highly subversive. A related statement issued by the Ministry of
the Interior on the morning of January 19 warned that communist-led demonstrations
would be fired upon.92
On January 22, newspapers ran papers highlighting a plan to burn Cairo, discovered
in the hands of the banned Communist Labor Party. These reports portrayed a far-reaching
conspiracy with command committees present in several Egyptian provinces.93

91

24 January 1977 Press Review, Foreign Broadcast Information Service Database, Paris AFP
19 January 1977 Press Review, Foreign Broadcast Information Service Database, Cairo Domestic Service in
Arabic
93
24 January 1977 Press Review, Foreign Broadcast Information Service Database, Cairo Domestic Service in
Arabic
92

34

The government not only used the riots to harass leftist elements, but also publicly
assailed wealthier Arab nations from skirting their obligations to Egypt, which had so
fiercely championed Arab nationalism. The Arab Socialist Party statements calls on other
Arab nations to remember their commitments to Egypts continued war effort. Egyptian
author Naguib Mahfouz highlights officialdoms anti-Arab feelings: Why should our
nationalism create hunger and suffering only? I implore with all my strength that we
abandon the Arabs if they have decided to abandon us. Trade unions all moved to support
the government, calling for calm and a halt to disturbances.94
By the afternoon of January 19, Prime Minister Salim suspended the decision on
commodity prices. On January 20, the Peoples Assembly Plan and Budget committee,
composed of Kaysuni and other relevant figures, decided on the cancellation of all increases
in the commodities to their status prior to January 17.95
The regime quickly attempted to consolidate the official line away from the
conflicting statements emerging from Parliament, political parties, and individual officials.
Reports in the subsequent days aimed to portray the regime as united, highlighting President
Sadat and Vice President Mubarak meeting with leaders of state institutions. Letters of
support are noted from King Khalid of Saudi Arabia and Sudanese President Numayri. On
June 23, a new $20 million US-Egyptian loan agreement is announced, forming part of the
$1 billion aid for the US to Egypt.96 These attempts appear calculated to reaffirm regime
stability.

94

24 January 1977 Press Review, Foreign Broadcast Information Service Database, Cairo Domestic Service in
Arabic
95
24 January 1977 Press Review, Foreign Broadcast Information Service Database, Cairo Domestic Service in
Arabic
96
24 January 1977 Press Review, Foreign Broadcast Information Service Database, Cairo Domestic Service in
Arabic

35

Sadat only publicly addressed the nation via radio on February 3, two weeks
following the outburst of riots. He repeatedly highlights the role of institutions in quelling
the recent riots, and reiterates government accusations against the left. Specifically, he
accuses new members of the Leftist party, Tagammu, recently formed in the semi-pluralist
electoral system, of supporting civil disturbances as agents of the Soviet Union.

The

President reminisces about previous conflicts with political rivals, and strongly regrets not
full purging communist elements. He highlights the riots as a fully-designed attempt to
weaken Egypts negotiating position with Israel, by demonstrating the disconnection between
Sadat and his people. In a nod to the countrys populist sentiment, Sadat rescinds taxes on
the very poor and requires a declaration of all wealth for the rest of society. Simultaneously,
the government prohibits strikes, congregations, or sit-ins which threaten the national
economy a broad definition fitting for post-crisis repression.97
A scheduled referendum of the Presidential Decrees occurred on February 10, with
99.4% of voters in support.98 These efforts aimed to reassert government control over Egypt,
and reaffirm the peoples backing of Anwar Sadat. The New York Times viewed the regime
as striking in two directions, attempting to salvage Sadats policy of political
liberalization while at the same time readying the tools by which any political challenge to
the President could be repressed.99
In the aftermath of the riots, the left-leaning plank in Egyptian politics found itself
attacked by the Sadat loyalists. The partys head, Khaled Mohiedin, attempted to defend his
organization in a press conference.

The New York Times reported that major local

97

4 February 1977 Press Review, Foreign Broadcast Information Service Database, Cairo Domestic Service in
Arabic
98
Nohlen, Dieter, Michael Krennerich, and Bernhard Thibaut. Elections in Africa: A Data Handbook. Oxford:
Oxford UP, 1999. 336.
99
Tanner, Henry. "A Stringent Decree Put to Vote in Egypt." New York Times 11 Feb. 1977. Print.

36

newspapers had rejected printing his statements. The party had opposed the referendum on
Sadats proposed clampdowns following the riots, making itself the most prominent
organization to oppose the President during the period of national reconsolidation.100

Contemporary Analysis and Historical Revision


Contemporary analysts highlighted the most immediate and apparent reasons for the
riots, while later scholars placed the events of 1977 within the context of transitions in social
classes.
The Al-Ahram daily argued in January 1977 that the perpetrators of these incidents
exploited the prevailing climate of democracy in which the authorities restrained themselves
up to the last moment, permitting peaceful demonstration until the nature of the plot became
clear.

Hence, strict firmness was inevitable.101

The climate of democracy may have

increased these protests. In the spirit of openness and press liberalization, the straightforward
policy presentation by Kaysuni and the public opposition may have expanded further than it
would have been under a more repressive system.
Tawfiq al-Hakim, appearing in a January edition of Al-Ahram, explains that protests
erupted for both mismatched expectations and a procedural reason: First, the high cost of
living led to popular expectations of price reductions, rather than increases. Second, the
announcement had occurred before the proposal was submitted to the Peoples Assembly.

100

Ibid.
24 January 1977 Press Review, Foreign Broadcast Information Service Database, Cairo Domestic Service in
Arabic
101

37

Proper discussion, according to Hakim, would have lessened the shock of subsidy
withdrawal.102
Journalist Henry Tanner, writing on January 24, observed that the riots demonstrated
the newly-robust influence of the Egyptian masses. He asserts that, Egypts poor are no
longer prepared to take foreign policy success and internal political reform as a substitute for
the improvement of their personal living conditions. Furthermore, Tanner raises the
dilemma of continued political liberalization in the midst of opposition, reporting that several
members of the official Leftist party were arrested.103 This analysis foreshadows later efforts
by the Government of Egypt to push through reforms during a time of repression. The Sadat
regime chooses to halt political liberalization, and instead bolsters consumption with further
funding for subsidies.
The regime had placed blame for the riots on Communist agitators, but Soliman
argues civil servants and those who expected to join the civil service (e.g. university
students) mustered the 1977 riots.104 The urban poor who joined the fray were not the
primary drivers, but may have contributed to its violent nature.
As has been demonstrated previously, the regime failed to adequately argue for the
distinction between these cuts, aimed at non-essential products, and the basic commodities
needed by the poor.

Soliman overlooks the messaging component of the forms

implementation, instead arguing that the subsidy reform was important for its symbolic
nature. In his analysis of budget data, the subsidy cuts amounted to only $28 million. The

102

19 January 1977 Press Review, Foreign Broadcast Information Service Database, Cairo Domestic Service in
Arabic
103
Tanner, Henry. "Egyptian Riots Have Seriously Sadats Freedom of Action at Home and Abroad." New York
Times 25 Jan. 1977: 3.
104
Soliman, Samir, and Peter Daniel. The Autumn of Dictatorship : Fiscal Crisis and Political Change In Egypt
Under Mubarak. Stanford, California: Stanford University Press, 2011. 59.

38

cutbacks represented the decline of the civil servant, the Nasser eras elite class, into their
lower-middle class status.
Waterbury largely agrees with the class-based transition. The truly depressed
stratum, he asserts, are the 2 million or so civil servants on fixed salaries who are kept
afloat only by large annual cost-of-living bonuses and holding two jobs.105 These, rather
than the leftists of Sadats accusations, were likely the driving factor for the riots. The
subsidies threatened the livelihoods of a highly urban class reliant on the states provision of
affordable food.
Beyond the discussion of the relatively educated urban classes, the subsidy cutbacks
also threatened the poorest Egyptians with a revision of the social contract. Subsidy cuts
included some discussion of wage increases, ignoring Egyptians with informal jobs or those
unemployed. An estimated 25% of Egypts work force was unemployed or underemployed,
and thus particularly vulnerable to commodity price rises even with official salary
adjustments.106
Because of this incident, the Egyptian government clearly came to believe that frank
and public discussions on the subsidy issue could not pass in Egyptian public life. Following
the events of January 1977, the Egyptian government adopted a more restrained and gradual
approach towards reform.

105

Waterbury, John. The Egypt of Nasser and Sadat : the Political Economy of Two Regimes. Princeton, N.J.:
Princeton University Press, 1983. 42.
106
Howe, Marvine. "Egypt Weighs Food-Aid Cuts Again." New York Times 19 Aug. 1977: A4.

39

Implications of the January Riots


The Egyptian government had effectively demonstrated the domestic constraints for
reform. International creditors, sufficiently concerned for Egyptian instability, became more
forthcoming in funding.
The reticent leaders of the Gulf states agreed to provide more lenient financial terms
for Egypt. Arab financial ministers arrived in Egypt two weeks following the start of the
riots, assessing the situation with their Egyptian counterparts.

In April, the countries

announced a $1.474 billion grant to Egypts central bank, as well as delayed repayment of
existing loans and delayed withdrawal of funds from the Egyptian Central Bank, totaling
close to $4 billion.107

Further funding from the IMF and the United States continued

following the riots, particularly following Sadats visit to Jerusalem in late 1977. In the week
following the riots, the IMF announced a $140 million loan.108 On February 1, the Carter
Administration informed Congress that it would reallocate $190 million in aid funds for
immediate disbursal to Egypt, which was seen as a major gesture of support.109 In
negotiation with the IMF and international creditors, Egypt could now leverage this historical
incident to loosen terms for loans and financial support.
In the years following the riots, the government expanded financial support for the
subsidy system to avoid passing increased global costs to the Egyptian consumer. In 1977,
subsidies accounted for 15.5% of government expenditures. By 1980/81, that figure rose to

107

Feiler 144.
Adams, Richard H. Self-targeted Subsidies: The Distributional Impact of the Egyptian Food Subsidy System.
Washington, DC: World Bank, Poverty Reduction and Economic Management Network, Poverty Division,
2000.
109
"US Plans to Bolster Aid to Egypt by $190 Million to Ease Unrest." New York Times 2 Feb. 1977.
108

40

20.5%.110 The government could not confront this major outflow from the treasury, hobbled
by fears of instability.
The cost of subsidies increased not only due to increasing prices, but also because of
an expanded subsidies regime. Sadat began to finance imports of chicken and beef while
further increasing subsidies. Public sector workers, a major urban interest group, received a
new system of bonuses given on national holidays. Finally, Sadat brought rural consumers
into the government-run food subsidy system by ordering the Ministry of Supply to expand
subsidized flour coverage to rural areas.111
The riots also fundamentally undercut the more glorious perception of Egyptian
success. The 1977 riots highlighted the regimes weakness, as Sadat consistently battled the
pan-Arab popularity of the Nasser regime.112 Domestically, Egypt could no longer view
itself on an upward trajectory. Hamied Ansari notes that, the euphoria in the wake of the
October War and the economic promise of the Open Door policy died suddenly amid the
Food riots of 18 and 19 January 1977.113 Sadat clearly aimed to regain public trust in the
regime through increasing hand-outs targeted towards specific groups.
Beyond domestic perceptions, Egypts looming bankruptcy and the regimes limited
flexibility in the domestic arena for cutting spending likely caused additional pressure to find
alternative revenue sources. By negotiating a peace agreement with Israel, Sadat was able to
sidestep domestic reform pressures and access growing funds from the West, and the United
states in particular. Several scholars, including Arie Kacowicz, notes that, paradoxically,
looming economic bankruptcy had been a critical factor in driving Sadat to choose war in
110

Soliman and Daniel 58.


Sadowski, Yahya M. Political Vegetables? Businessman and Bureaucrat In the Development of Egyptian
Agriculture. Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution, 1991. 160.
112
Feiler 193.
113
Ansari 185.
111

41

1973 and peace in 1977-79. By 1977 Egypt was in a critical economic situation, exacerbated
by the rising expectations from the open door economic policy introduced after 1973.
Hence, the link between the foot riots of January 1977 and Sadats visit to Jerusalem in
November of the same year, though not linear, should not be underestimated.114
Within the context of domestic contestation and weakness, Sadats visit to Jerusalem
may be seen as a means of realigning the domestic conversation away from economic
challenges towards a foreign policy achievement. By visiting Jerusalem, Sadat attempted to
achieve not only the international fame that his foreign minister, Ismail Fahimi, stated he
craved, but also to reassert Egypts distinct geopolitical identity.115 Sadat embarked on a
policy of Egypt First, where Egyptian benefits from peace outweighed any damage the
agreement dealt to the pan-Arab cause.116 Fouad Ajami notes that, Sadat could hope to
compete with his predecessor in Egypt proper, but in the Arab world his predecessor was
larger than life.117 In fact, these domestic travails, coming on the heels of the Arabs 1976
rejection of loan pleas, may have further accentuated Sadats sense of Egyptian nationalism.
Karawan advances an alternate argument connecting Sadats perception of Soviet
involvement in the January riots to the Jerusalem visit. Sadats anti-Sovietism arose from his
perception of Soviet support for his domestic rivals. For example, Ali Sabri, Sadats rival in
succession to Nasser, was widely perceived to hold implicit Soviet support, or at the very
least, preference.118 In 1972, Sadat expelled Soviet advisors and began seriously embarking

114

Kacowicz, Arie Marcelo. Peaceful Territorial Change. Columbia, S.C.: University of South Carolina Press,
1994.134.
115
Fahmy, Ismail. Negotiating for Peace In the Middle East. Baltimore, Md.: Johns Hopkins University Press,
1983. 283-90.
116
Karawan, Ibrahim A. "Sadat and the EgyptianIsraeli Peace Revisited." International Journal of Middle East
Studies 26.02 (1994): 249-266.
117
Ajami, Fouad. The Arab Predicament: Arab Political Thought and Practice since 1967. Cambridge:
Cambridge UP, 1981. 94.
118
Karawan 249-266.

42

on the Open Door policies.

Sadats blame on leftist and communist elements fits the

atmosphere of heightened Egyptian-Soviet tensions and decisions to strengthen the alliance


with the United States. Karawan conducted a personal interview with Deputy Prime Minister
Hassan al-Tuhami, who summarized the connection:
The January riots had shown us the deliberate intentions of the
Soviet Union to bring the regime down. The local communists moved
all over the country, repeating the same slogans and using the same
tactics. But we know that local communists cannot do anything by
themselves, and without the orders, or at least approval, of the Soviet
Union. The response of the president was a decision to kick the Soviet
Union and its agents out of the area. 119
Furthermore, the visit can be seen as a subversion of the Carters administrations
attempts to include the Soviet Union as a cosponsor of the Geneva conference.

The

surprising initiative realigned Egypt from a participant to a driver of the peace process. In
this position, Sadat could better exclude the Soviet Union from regional peace discussions.

Subsequent Subsidy Reform in the 1970s


Attempts to cut back on subsidies following the January 1977 riots occurred slowly
and meticulously, with trial balloons floated and little substantial action taken.
In August 1977, the Egyptian government announced that Prime Minister Mamdouh
Salem would convene a government committee to study a proposal for food subsidy cuts.120
The proposal appears not to have progressed any further, but instead served as reintroduction
of a controversial topic into the public sphere.
In December 1978, the government engaged in a new program to increase the prices
of nonessentials and luxuries. On December 29, cigarettes increased by 5 cents, to 42 cents

119
120

Karawan 249-266.
Howe, Marvine. "Egypt Weighs Food-Aid Cuts Again." New York Times 19 Aug. 1977: A4.

43

per pack, lower grade gasoline increased by 4 cents, to 37 cents a gallon, and premium
gasoline increased by 3 cents to 65 cents per gallon. Other measures, including raising the
prices of beer, soft drinks, and color television sets, were expected to increase in the near
future as well. In addition, Western economists began hinting at other means of reducing the
burden of subsidies, including limiting the number of ration card holders.121 The timing of
this announcement occurred during the midst of peace talks with the Israelis. In much of the
Cairo press, the conversation was dominated by foreign policy. The 1977 subsidy reform
announcement occurred during a momentary lull for Egyptian foreign affairs, and followed
an election where domestic issues became prominent. In contrast, the minor December 1978
announcement occurred while Egyptian eyes were focused on the prospect of peace and selfrule in the Sinai.
By December 1979, the Egyptian governments strategy for the following decade was
becoming clear: The government would focus on withdrawing the easier subsidies and price
controls first, and restrict access to ration cards. Under this new policy, the government
determined that:

The prices of goods sold on ration cards, including cooking gas and staple foods,
would remain constant. The government faced particular budgetary pressure for
cooking gas, as Gulf producers have cut off supplies following the peace treaty with
Israel. Previously, the government paid concessionary rates of $50 to $192 per ton.
Under new contracts from Mediterranean suppliers, the government began to buy gas
for $490 per ton.

121

Sugar in private stores would increase by 16 cents per pound (3 cent increase).

"Egypt Raises Some Prices but Holds the Line on Food." New York Times 30 Dec. 1978.

44

Regular Gasoline prices would increase 60 cents per gallon (11 cent increase);
Premium Gasoline would increase 71 cents per gallon (11 cent increase).

Local Cigarettes would increase 47 cents (4 cent increase); Foreign Brands would
increase 87 92 cents, (8 cent increase). 122
During this period of policy change, wage adjustments in the public sector played a

calming role. The government proposed for monthly wage increases in the public sector and
public companies from $4.30 for unmarried workers to $14.30 for married workers.

The dynamic between subsidy policy change and popular response, already
perceptible in the late 1970s, would continue to dominate Egyptian food subsidy reform in
the following decades. Stealth reform and other calming mechanisms would emerge as key
elements of any subsidy withdrawal process. These strategies aimed to avoid a repetition of
the January 1977 riots, which continued to loom over the any prospective reforms.

122

Tatro, Earleen. "Egypt's Proposed Budget For 1980 Sets Off Price Increases for Most Items." New York
Times 26 Dec. 1979.

45

46

IV. A Slow Period of Change: Subsidy Reduction in the 1980s

Hosni Mubarak ascended to power in 1981 following the assassination of his


predecessor, President Anwar Sadat.

The Mubarak regime successfully reduced food

subsidies during the 1980s through largely covert policy changes and distribution controls.
As in 1977, the government responded to protests with both repression and retreat from
policy changes.

While the subsidy reductions were largely minimal, these policies

demonstrate the tenuous steps undertaken by the regime to reduce the food subsidy bill. This
chapter will also include Egypts relationship with the International Monetary Fund (IMF),
and the means by which it received loan guarantees and approvals without fully complying
with requirements for subsidy reform. The successful management of the IMF relationship,
using American leverage, enabled Egyptian leaders to determine the pace of domestic
reform, enabling less abrupt and more covert implementation.

Conceptualizing Reform in the 1980s


In contrast to outside analyses faulting the regime for continuing an efficient subsidy
system, the record from the 1980s demonstrates high sophistication in balancing fears of
social unrest, outside pressure (mainly from the IMF), and an internal recognition of the need
for reform. The legacy of the 1977 riots, in addition to continued media scandals over food
prices, reinforced the governments fear of open reform.
Sadowski describes three primary strategies by which the Mubarak regime changed
the subsidy regime without inflaming public opinion: Distribution controls, cash
compensation, and reform by stealth. Distribution controls, aimed at limiting access to

47

goods, enabled the government to attempt more sophisticated targeting strategies. Cash
compensation, in the form of higher wages, remained a promising means of placating urban
workers with formal employment. A final subset of reforms, reform by stealth, covers the
remaining reforms.

By changing policies, adding options, and recalibrating prices and

quality, the government encouraged shifts in consumption patterns more beneficial to the
budgetary bottom line.
The snails pace of reform was not sufficient to stem the rising tide of import
expenditures. Towards the end of the 1980s, food prices rose substantially, while Egypts
main commodity export, oil, suffered from the low prices caused by OPEC overproduction.
In the mid-1980s, wheat sold for $70/$80 per ton. By July 1988, Egypt paid $149 per ton for
wheat, with prices increasing to nearly $300 by the next year. Simultaneously, outside
support for wheat declined.

The United States had previously provided Egypt with

concessional loans totaling $2.7 billion in the previous decade. During times of low prices,
the United States government supported agricultural exporters through such foreign deals.
However, during times of high prices, few government policies are needed to support
agricultural interests, and instead, recipient governments like Egypt needed to buy wheat on
the open market.123 The increasing prices also affected other staples. Corn rose $84 to $132
per ton, cooking oil rose from $458 to $790 per ton, and sugar from $171 to $270 per ton.124
These prices drove Egypt back into the hands of international creditors, and by extension, the
International Monetary Fund (IMF). The dynamics of these interactions will be discussed in
depth later in this chapter.

123

Singerman and Hoodfar 1996.


Mubarak 23 July Revolution Anniversary Speech 21 July 1988 Press Review, Foreign Broadcast
Information Service Database.
124

48

The countrys food subsidy system, while seeming irrational to both international ad
domestic observers, actually contained measures directly targeting products towards the poor.
Subsidized foods, at the onset of the decade, included a whole range of goods for both daily
sustenance and more special occasions. In 1980, subsidized foods included bread (baladi,
shami, and fino), flour, sugar, rice, tea, edible oil, beans, lentils, macaroni, coffee, sesame,
shortening, imported cheese, frozen meat, fish, egg, and chicken.125 This extensive list
included sources of animal protein, a highly expensive expenditure. By 1995, the subsidy
regime only covered baladi bread, wheat flour (82% extraction), edible oil, and sugar.126 The
poor consumed these inferior goods, particularly the coarse bread, whose subsidy was
maintained through the reform process until the present day.
Khouri describes the perception of food prices in Egypt as a scale, with bread and
meat on opposite ends.127 Bread represents the cheapest product, while meat the most
expensive.

Thus, the prices of goods are judged within the hierarchy of household

expenditures, rather than on an independent basis.

Playing Around with Bread Size: Changes at the Margins


The Egyptian governments reform by stealth took advantage of small, gradual
changes to increase public acceptance of changes to the bread subsidy. The loaves available
at bakeries served as a dietary staple infused with expectations.

125

Provision of bread

Adams, Richard H. Self-targeted Subsidies: The Distributional Impact of the Egyptian Food Subsidy System.
Washington, DC: World Bank, Poverty Reduction and Economic Management Network, Poverty Division,
2000.
126
Abd al-Khaliq, Judah, and Karima Korayem. Fiscal Policy Measures In Egypt: Public Debt and Food
Subsidy. Cairo: American University in Cairo Press, 2001.
127
Singerman, Diane, and Homa Hoodfar. Development, Change, and Gender In Cairo: a View From the
Household. Bloomington: Indiana University Press, 1996.

49

represented a primary connection between the citizenry and regime. Thus, tweaking this
system required finesse.
In May 1983, a parliamentary discussion on raising the price of bread from 1 to 2
piastes provoked a national outcry.

Instead of pushing through complete reform, the

government circumvented the public process by theoretically maintaining consumer choice,


while in actuality, pushing the populace toward the decided policy. In 1981, the government
began providing a two piastre bread made of higher quality wheat, while simultaneously
reducing the quality and availability of the one piastre staple.128 Other sources note this
change happening in earnest in 1983 and 1984 when prices rose and the governmentmandated size of baladi bread decreased from 168 to 160 grams.129
Small changes continued to occur. In 1986, the government reduced the size of the
two piaster loaves, reducing the standard weight from 160 grams or above to only 135 grams.
In 1988, the quality of loaves further declined, as the government reduced wheat content in
loaves by 20 percent. These measures resulted in savings of 1 million tons of wheat,
translating to 350 million Egyptian pounds.130 The process of reduction appears to have
continued over several years. In 1988 and 1989, the price of bread increased to five piasters,
while bread size was reduced to 130 grams.131
Corruption remained a challenge for all subsidized products. The open market prices
for subsidized goods were much higher than the government price. Naturally, a secondary
informal market developed for goods bought cheaply at government cooperatives and
subsidized bakeries.

The government subverted these black markets by creating new

128

Singerman and Hoodfar 1996.


Adams 2000.
130
Singerman and Hoodfar 1996.
131
Adams 2000.
129

50

products to capture the unauthorized market and increasing surveillance. Thus, government
tinkering with the bread system attempted to confront corruption.
In 1989, Egypt faced a bread crisis, with long lines and increasing prices. Bakers had
diverted flour for use in higher-priced types of bread, primarily tabaqi loaves, which were
sold on the open market. In response to this trend, Minister of Agriculture Yusuf Wali
created two official tabaqi loaves, costing less than the bread at open market. As a result of
the increased product offering, the government recaptured part of the subsidized flour
leakage and encouraged consumer demand to migrate toward more expensive subsidized
bread.132

The Distribution System: Withdrawing the Availability of Subsidies


The government attempted to cut back on subsidies without explicit policy changes
by limiting the reach of subsidized goods. In 1981, the Ministry of Trade and Supply began
limiting the number of ration cardholders. These initial reforms took on common sense
approaches the names of people abroad or the deceased were removed from public rolls.
The government also began to attempt to discriminate provisions based on income.
Householders of higher net worth, including investors, owners of buildings, shops, or cars,
and proprietors of more than 10 feddans of land were divided into a separate category than
the poor, who maintained fully subsidized green ration books. Partially subsidized red ration
books failed to take root, as by 1994, only 3 percent of the Egyptian population had
transferred to the limited subsidy group.133

132
133

Singerman and Hoodfar 1996.


Adams 2000.

51

During the 1980s, the Egyptian government continued to maintain some subsidies on
non-essential consumer goods, such as cigarettes. In July 1986, the government attempted to
confront the black market by establishing a two-tiered distribution system.

Poorer

neighborhoods received cheaper but lower quality goods, while better-off neighborhoods
benefited from more availability of goods at higher prices. The discrepancy led to informal
means of distribution in poorer areas, where supplies were diverted and often sold at higher
prices. Managers allocated limited supplies of goods by selling under the counter, charging
more for skipping queues, and selling goods in advance to legions of women peddlers who
would resell at higher prices.
Attempts to limit the number of Egyptians on the subsidy rolls had largely failed by
the end of 1994. 78 percent of the population remained on ration books. Far more effective
in reducing actual subsidy expenditure was the pullback in the goods covered by public
subsidies.134

Civil Disorder: Recurrences of 1977


Sporadic protests linked to increases in food prices and shortages reaffirmed
government suspicions of overly ambitious liberalization. The government response aimed
to reduce the motivation for protest, by reverting temporarily to previous policies, and
controlling opposition figures through arrests and political repression.
In September 1984, workers in Kafr el-Dawwar rioted over price increases. This
industrial city in the Nile Delta holds significance as a historical hotbed of the Egyptian labor

134

Ibid.

52

movement.135 A 30 percent unannounced hike in the price of cooking oil and pasta, the
disappearance of the one-piaster loaf, and an increase in wage deductions of social security
led workers to refuse wage packets in protest.136 Violent demonstrations eventually resulted
in three killed and 26 wounded.
This government response followed the established to relieving social pressure:
retreat followed by repression. President Mubarak calmed protesters by intervening directly
to rescind the price increases and promising to halt any further increases.137 Mubarak
promised to limit the new and improved two-piaster loaves to higher income areas, while
poor areas would maintain availability of the one-piastre standard baladi bread. Reporters on
the ground noted the difficulty of finding the cheaper loaves in poorer urban districts
throughout the country.138
Simultaneously, the regime arrested leftist leaders. In Minya, seven local leaders of
the National Progressive Unionist Party (NPUP) were arrested.139 On September 29, as the
government publicized the role of extremists in fomenting these revolts, Interior Minister
Kamal Hasan Ali announced an extension of the Emergency Law by almost two years.140 In
October, security forces arrested leftists, student activists, workers, and other affiliates of the
NPUP throughout Egypt on charges of coup plotting.141

135

El-Hamalawy, Hossam. "Egypt: Revolt of the Hungry." Egypt: Revolt of Hungry. Socialist Worker, 17 Feb.
2005. Web. 12 Mar. 2012. <http://www.socialistworker.co.uk/article.php?article_id=10705>.
136
Miller, Judith. "Egyptians Worry Despite Riot's End." New York Times 7 Oct. 1984: 17.
137
Mubarak Prohibits Further Price Increases.1 October 1984 Press Review, Foreign Broadcast Information
Service Database, Cairo MENA news service in Arabic.
138
Miller 1984.
139
"Egypt August 1986." Keesing's Record of World Events 31: 33817.
140
Ali on Extending Emergency Law by 19 Months. 29 September 1984 Press Review, Foreign Broadcast
Information Service Database, Cairo MENA news service in Arabic.
141
Authorities Reportedly Arrest Communist Group 16 October 1984 Press Review, Foreign Broadcast
Information Service Database, Al-Sharq Al-Awsat.

53

These events occurred in the background of a parliamentary election in May 1984.


The results of those elections favored the National Democratic Party, which won 72 percent
of the vote. The NPUP came in fourth, with only 4 percent of valid votes.142
The regime responded to the popular opposition by first placating the public. Once
the situation calmed, a larger purge against organizers took place. Increases in social security
contributions and the price of cigarettes were maintained, while the price of commodities
loaded with significance, such as bread, pasta, and cooking oil, were reduced. In the midst of
these events, diplomats noted the Mubarak regimes success in using subtle tactics to raise
subsidies.143
Less violent popular responses over price reforms created further challenges for the
government. In May 1985, the government relaxed price controls on fruits and vegetables in
an attempt to stimulate production.

However, prices skyrocketed and newspapers and

parliamentarians fanned the flame of scandal. Media reports point to an increase in prices of
200 to 300 percent over wholesale costs. Sadowski notes the concentration of the vegetable
and fruit market in Cairo as a key reason for this price inflation, as businessmen from three
villages in Upper Egypt monopolized 70 percent of the citys produce market.

By

September, the government reasserted control over vegetable prices. The failure at reform
stemmed from the concentration present in the distribution system.144
In 1986, a police mutiny in Cairo and its suburbs rocked the foundation of the
Mubarak regime. Up to 17,000 conscripts committed arson and destruction against luxury
hotels, nightclubs, and restaurants, with over 100 killed. Circulating rumors about extension
of conscription from two to three years, and continued mistreatment and abuse, had riled the
142

"Egypt September 1984." Keesing's Record of World Events 30: 33124.


Miller 1984.
144
Singerman and Hoodfar 170.
143

54

conscripts. Most worryingly for the Mubarak regime, the riots came from the ranks of the
Central Security Force, established in 1968 and expanded after 1977 to deal with
demonstrations. The Armys deployment in the streets of Cairo reasserted order, but the riots
underlined the fragility of Egypts social stability.145
In May 1988, riots in the working class Cairo district of Ain Shams revealed popular
dissatisfaction with a deteriorating standard of living. Conflict between security forces and
radical Islamists, many from the extremist group Jamaat Islamiya, erupted in clashes
following Friday prayers. One diplomat noted that for the first time since 1977, ordinary
people have taken to the streets in large numbers to protest and to confront authority.146
These protests occurred within the larger context of a perceived decline in living standards
for poor Cairenes. In contrast to previous occasions, where leftist elements were blamed in
the media, in this case, fundamentalist Islamists became the main focus of investigations.
In 1989, bread shortages led to protests in Minya and Bani Suwayf. In January 1988,
prices per bushel of wheat had stood at $2.90 and by July, prices rose to nearly $4.00 per
bushel.147 Demonstrators in Minya especially protested the rise of the fino loaf prices.148
Minya had witnessed clashes between Islamic fundamentalists and the government during
the previous months, and the Interior Minister had closed down al-Rahman Mosque, a
headquarters of Islamic groups.

Papers reported arrests in Port Said, Cairo, and other

provincial cities over protest against rising bread prices.149 Supply Minister Jalal Abu alDhahab noted that the seven prices for flour led to the bread crisis, encouraging pilfering in
145

Rogg, Margaret L. "Egypt Says Police Rebellion Is Quelled." New York Times 28 Feb. 1986: A3.
"Islamic Radicals' Appeal Seems to Be Gaining in Egypt." Los Angeles Times, 18 Nov. 1988. Web. 12 Mar.
2012. <http://articles.latimes.com/1988-11-18/news/mn-756_1_islamic-radicals>.
147
Singerman and Hoodfar 1996.
148
Demonstrations Over Bread Prices in Al-Minya 6 February 1984 Press Review, Foreign Broadcast
Information Service Database, Al-Wafd.
149
Arrests Reported for Protests Over Bread Price 10 April 1989 Press Review, Foreign Broadcast
Information Service Database, Al-Wafd.
146

55

the black market. He asserted that the largest portion of leaked flour from the subsidized
bread system goes to fodder, whose price is higher than that of flour.150
Newspapers covered the issue as a human-interest story. The Ministry of Supply
publicized arrests of bakers, and prison areas were set aside for bread offenses.151 Other
media outlets noted the spread of shortages to villages.152 In response, the government made
a well-publicized push to exert control over distribution networks.153 The government
attempted to assert its success by publicizing that the phenomenon of crowds outside the
bakeries have disappeared.154
Beyond these specific incidents, newspapers during the mid-1980s took a very
publicized stance against the price increases. Staples like kushari had increased in prices,
likely in connection to the liberalization of vegetable and fruit prices during the previous
year.155 Al Shab newspaper asked, will a plate of kushari turn into a tourist dish?
reflecting the increasing prosperity and social cleavages from Egypts opening to the West
while the popular classes bore the brunt of increasing prices.156 Official newspapers often
used their pages to respond to critiques from more critical press outlets. Al Shab ran
everyman perspectives in 1986 on a treasonous increase in tea prices. In response, the
official Al Ahram published an explanation from the Minister of Supply citing distributional

150

Supply Minister on Flour Prices, Bread Crisis 18 April 1989 Press Review, Foreign Broadcast Information
Service Database, Al-Akhbar.
151
Paper Reviews Bread Crisis 4 April 1989 Press Review, Foreign Broadcast Information Service Database,
Al-Shab.
152
Shortages Spread to Villages 10 April 1989 Press Review, Foreign Broadcast Information Service
Database, Al-Ahrar.
153
Governorate Moves To Control Bread Distribution 5 April 1989 Press Review, Foreign Broadcast
Information Service Database, Al-Akhbar.
154
Government Bread Control Decreases Bakery Crowds 17 April 1989 Press Review, Foreign Broadcast
Information Service Database, Al-Wafd.
155
Singerman and Hoodfar 1996. 177.
156
Abu Liwaayah, Muhammad. "Will a Plate of Kushari Turn into a Tourist Dish?" Al-Shab 12 Aug. 1986: 3.

56

problems and a strike in India as the source of the shortage, which had resulted in higher
prices.157

Managing External Relations: Egypt and the International Monetary Fund


During the late 1980s and early 1990s, the International Monetary Fund (IMF)
engaged in economic liberalization throughout the developing world. For countries facing
economic crisis and government deficits, the IMF can provide loans. In addition, agreements
signal good financial standing to creditors and donor countries, enabling access to
international financial markets.

IMF agreements included structural conditionality

agreements, requiring reform of pricing policies, trade liberalization, taxation, and


government expenditure.158

These policies create domestic challenges between groups

favoring the status quo and government officials cognizant of the need for economic
solutions.
Egypts relations with the IMF were dramatically marked by the 1977 riots.
Immediate adjustment measures, with the scaling back of food subsidies, were seen to lead
directly to major protests. From that point onwards, Egyptian leaders reticently received
economic advice focusing on liberalization. The government leveraged Egypts strategic
position and relationship with the United States to pressure the IMF for lenient terms.

157

Singerman and Hoodfar 1996. 177.


Bird, Graham. "The International Monetary Fund and Developing Countries: A Review of the Evidence and
Policy Options." International Organization 50.03 (1996): 477.
158

57

In September 1988, Mubarak reiterated the Egyptian position: We need economic


reform, but Ive told the IMF that this reform must be in line with our social and economic
situation and standard of living.159
Momani provides a useful characterization of the major IMF agreements during this
period: 1987 and 1991 are both relatively lenient, while the 1993 and 1996 agreements were
relatively strict.160 In 1987, the Egyptian government managed to exclude price increases on
bread as a loan condition, and furthermore, failed to fully implement the agreed reforms. As
a result, the second tranche of loans were denied. In 1991, Egypt again failed to implement
reforms, but all tranches of loans were disbursed, likely as a reward for Egypts support of
the United States during the First Gulf War.161
Momani proposes three frames to understand IMF dynamics. The functionalist model
argues that staff members conduct IMF negotiations with purely economic considerations in
mind. The bargaining model portrays negotiations between debtor state and the IMF fund as
a negotiation on an individual level. In this frame, the links between Egyptian government
officials and Egyptian-born IMF officials play an important role in the final result. The
political model determines that the outcome of IMF-debtor negotiations are shaped by
member countries.162 These models emerge through the study of the IMF-Egypt relationship.

159

Daines, Victoria, John Walton, and David Seddon. Free Markets and Food Riots: The Politics of Global
Adjustment. Oxford: Blackwell, 1994.
160
Momani, Bessma. "American Politicization of the International Monetary Fund." Review of International
Political Economy 11.5 (2004): 880-904.
161
The American and Egyptian responses to the Gulf War are discussed below in the section covering the 1991
agreement.
162
Momani, Bessma. IMF - Egyptian Debt Negotiations. Cairo: American University in Cairo Press, 2005. 4.

58

Negotiating the 1987 Agreement


In 1985, Egypts economic situation had severely declined. The boost from Sadats
Infitah and the inflow of foreign capital had largely subsided, while the large trade deficit
ballooned. Talks between Egypt and the IMF began in earnest in April 1985. Later that
year, the Egyptian government pledged changes in price control, promising to raise energy
and water prices.163 However, the changes proved to be more symbolic than effectual.
Energy prices increases were restricted to gasoline, while there were no increases in cooking
oil, kerosene, or diesel fuel. These goods, with a large budgetary impact, would have
impacted poorer Egyptian households.
Other IMF staff recommendations proved difficult to implement, as Egyptian officials
such as Finish Minister Salah Hamed called on policymakers to recognize Egypts great
social and political constraints.164

In 1986, the macroeconomic situation became

increasingly pressing, as reduced revenue from oil exports, tourism, and remittances further
impacted Egypts financial health.

Donors from the Arab World refused to provide

additional funding, and the Paris Club, composed of financial officials from the largest
economies, declined to provide aid. As a result, the Egyptian had to return to the IMF.
During this period, the IMF continued to press for further liberalization. Discussions
revolved around the pace and content of reforms.

Choosing the price rises for goods

remained an essential issue, as the Government of Egypt aimed to avoid a repetition of the
1977 riots.
While the government tentatively increased interest rates, lowered energy subsidies,
and unified the systems of exchange rates, all in response to IMF pressure, the government

163
164

Momani 2005. 11.


Momani 2005. 12.

59

simultaneously reaffirmed national sovereignty. In December 1986, Mubarak reiterated to


the public, the government made no concession to the IMF. Simultaneously, government
officials and Mubarak himself had visited European capitals, urging for further financial
support and promising reform in the longer term. The Egyptian government adopted an
attitude of public opposition to the IMF while simultaneously engaging with donors states to
weaken IMF requirements.
The Egyptian government attempted to lengthen the implementation of any reform
plan, most likely in order to avoid rapid reforms. The well-publicized changes of 1977 had
led to instability, and a fast-paced IMF reform plan would require a similarly abrupt
implementation approach.

For example, while IMF representative Shaalan wanted an

increase in energy prices to 60 percent of international levels immediately in 1987, the


Egyptian government preferred to focus on the longer term, aiming to bring prices to
international levels by 1991/1992. This strategy of delay was blasted by IMF staffers, who
asserted that, delay in the adoption of key reforms will neither reduce the magnitude of the
problem nor ease the political difficulties.165 The IMF staff, while cognizant of the social
and political implications of reforms, rejected Egyptian proposals to delay.
The Egyptian government clearly adopted a strategy of longer-term gradual change.
The extended time frame for reforms would empower the Egyptian government to control the
pace of reform. Maintaining local control of reform, in spite of outside pressure, became a
key component of Egyptian policy towards IMF agreements.
In the 1987 Egypt-IMF agreement, Egypt achieved its goals of establishing a fiveyear timeline, through 1991/1992, for reforms in energy prices, the financial system, and

165

Article IV Consultation Document, IMF Egypt, 1986.

60

currency rates. Egypt also designated several basic goods, such as wheat, rice, sugar, and
cotton, as exempt from subsidy reform.166
Egypt was a special case for the IMF and global creditors, given its geopolitical
situation. In an unpublished speech given on May 15, 1987, Executive Director Shaalan
noted the need for a broader perspective for evaluating the adequacy of adjustment
policies.167 This language brought non-economic factors into consideration when the
executive voted to accept the more lenient Egyptian Letter of Intent in May 1987. In an
internal 1987 IMF memo, the External Trade and Relations department decried the program
as resulting in ineffectual reform and a non-viable balance of payments.168 As noted by the
Executive Director, it would not be prudent, for Egypt but also for the Fund, to test the
limits of social tolerance.169 The ramifications of social unrest in Egypt on the Mubarak
regime took precedence over a firm IMF stance.
The 1987 agreement presented a victory to the Egyptian government. The IMF
provided a $327 million Stand-By Credit arrangement, allowing the government to access
IMF reserves, and strengthened lender confidence. As expected, the Paris Club subsequently
agreed to reschedule $7 billion in Egyptian debt.

Thus, while IMF support remained

minimal, the Egyptian government could garner the support of its creditor states.
During the following year, Egypt made tentative progress to liberalize the economy,
but measures continued to fall short of the agreed amounts. A 20 percent increase in public
wages occurred while the government implemented some proposed increases in energy and
other consumer prices. In response, the IMF terminated the agreement in 1988, blocking the

166

Momani 2005. 18.


Momani 2005. 19.
168
Ibid.
169
Ibid.
167

61

release of a second tranche of the Stand-By Credit Agreement. The IMF Executive Board
cited Egyptian procrastination as the source of tension.170

Negotiating the 1991 Agreement


The lack of agreement between the IMF and the Egyptian government continued to
plague negotiations for a new Stand-By Agreement following 1988. Egypt faced marginally
successful attempts at realigning prices, but in large respects, gaps remained in IMF
expectations and commitments from the Egyptian government. In March 1989, the US
government blocked aid totaling $230 million contingent on the full implementation of
economic reform.171 This disagreement changed rapidly following the onset of the 1990 Gulf
War, when the United States took stronger action to support its ally.
Egypt sided with the United States in the fight against the Hussein regime. Egypt
faced ramifications from the war, including a decline in remittances from the Gulf States,
reduced Suez Canal tolls, the cost of armed deployment to the battle theater, and loss of trade
with the Gulf. Egypt contributed 35,000 troops to the war effort, representing the largest
Arab force and the third-largest force overall.172
The US Embassy in Cairo directly linked IMF negotiations to Egypts standing in
relation to the Gulf conflict.

In a communiqu, the embassy noted that an Egyptian

government representative urged the US government to issue a joint proclamation by creditor


nations to reschedule debt and meet the finance gap. As a result, the IMF would not lose
face from lessening the requirements for a Stand-By Agreement. In response, the State

170

Momani 2005. 24.


Momani 2005. 28.
172
"Background Note: Egypt." U.S. Department of State. Web. 13 Mar. 2012.
<http://www.state.gov/r/pa/ei/bgn/5309.htm>.
171

62

Department asked the Embassy to convey to President Mubarak that, we remain committed
to helping you reach an agreement with the IMF and are in touch with them. The United
States brokered multiple meetings between the IMF and Egyptian representatives.

As

Europeans blocked aid, due to failure to repay loans, the Egyptians sounded the alarms, and
American representatives sensed the pressure.173 Secretary of State James Baker and Foreign
Minister Abdel Meguid held meetings with the IMF negotiations as a primary agenda item.174
Although in 1989 the Egyptian government increased consumer prices, IMF negotiators
remained unsatisfied at the pace of reform.
The Gulf War led President Bush to forgive Egypts extensive military debt, totaling
nearly $7 billion.175 The debt forgiveness occurred before the finalization of any IMF
agreement, underlining the divergence of American policy towards Egyptian economic
reform from the fundamental economic analysis espoused by the IMF.
The Egyptian government submitted a Letter of Intent in March 1991 that outlined
reforms in the currency and taxation regimes. However, the regime left ongoing issues of
implementation untouched, particularly the reduction of subsidies. In spite of these issues,
the United States continued to support the Egyptian positions. Secretary of State James
Baker pledged support during his tour of the Middle East.176 Meanwhile, congressional
leaders inquired about State Department efforts to push forward negotiations. By May 1991,
the IMF executive board had signed on to a new agreement, one which largely followed the
contours of Egyptian expectations. Egypt had yet again taken control of the IMF negotiation
process, and while it would later fail to fully follow through in the agreement, small progress

173

Momani 2005. 35.


Momani 2005. 33.
175
Momani 2005. 37.
176
Momani 2005. 41.
174

63

was made towards liberalizing its economic system.

The government had agreed to

reductions in the budget deficit, introduction of a 10 percent sales tax, increasing energy
prices, liberalized interest rates, and more privatization. A vague promise also referenced a
decrease in consumer subsidies.
After signing the agreement, the Egyptian government had challenges in following
through with both cutting government spending while increasing living costs. Mubarak had
already communicated a 29 percent pay rise to public service workers, directly contradicting
the goals of the agreement for reducing the fiscal deficit. From the Egyptian perspective, this
wage increase served as cash compensation for the upcoming increases in cost of living.

Subsidy reform in the early years of the Mubarak era was marked by a gradual
implementation of covert changes and distribution controls.

The regimes successful

management of the IMF relationship forestalled any abrupt changes to the subsidy system
forced by international lenders. Domestically, the government engaged in selective policy
retreat and repression to calm popular anger. As a whole, the Egyptian government set the
gradual pace of reform. In the 1990s, an aggressive repression campaign would embolden
the government to make further cutbacks.

64

V. The 1990s: Repression, Extremism, and Economic Change

Egypt in the 1990s witnessed increasing economic liberalization concurrent with


resurgent political repression. These changes took place under the guise of fighting Islamic
extremism, with expectations that economic freedom would lead to greater political openness
in the longer term. The climate of repression not only targeted violent extremists, but also
more moderate Islamists and other opponents to the regime. Under expanded government
powers and reduced openness, the regime concurrently suppressed opposition to further
economic liberalization and subsidy rollback.

In contrast to previous decades, protests

against the more dramatic subsidy reductions were relatively muted.

Aggressive Subsidy Withdrawal


Following the economic crises of the 1980s, Egypt embarked on a more aggressive
restructuring of the subsidy regime. While the number of goods removed may have been less
than in past years, the removed goods were more central to daily consumption. In 1990/91,
frozen meat was excised. Egypt underwent an even larger subsidy reform in the following
year, as the government withdrew coverage for fish, tea, and fino bread. In 1992/93, the rice
subsidy was removed, with shami bread removed in the following years. By 1995, the
subsidy regime covered only baladi bread, wheat flour (82% extraction), edible oil, and
sugar.177

177

Adams, Richard H. Self-targeted Subsidies: The Distributional Impact of the Egyptian Food Subsidy System.
Washington, DC: World Bank, Poverty Reduction and Economic Management Network, Poverty Division,
2000.

65

The government also continued its program of alternatives, in addition to full-scale


withdrawal. In 1994, the Ministry of Trade and Supply again reduced the number of ration
cardholders by canceling the names of people who were abroad or deceased.

The

government also attempted to change the bread recipe with little public awareness. In 1996,
the government announced plans to reduce wheat imports by adding Egyptian-grown corn
into subsidized flour.178 The government implemented these changes gradually, without
informing bakers the exact contents of the government-supplied sacks. In Egypt, private
operators generally baked bread, while the government mandated and provided the necessary
flour mix.
In contrast to the previous decade, the popular response to these changes failed to
garner sufficient domestic or international attention. The larger environment of political
repression, discussed later in this chapter, overshadowed food subsidy issues.

An Increasing Commitment to IMF Reforms


The reduction in political liberties enabled the government to pursue a more
aggressive economic liberalization strategy supported by the IMF. The greater success and
follow-through in implementing these reforms highlight the effectiveness of political
deliberalization. The 1993 and 1996 Egypt-IMF agreements underline the new cooperative
relationship between the regime and international creditors as Egypt gained confidence in
implementing reforms.
In contrast to the 1987 and 1991 agreements, the 1993 and 1996 agreements were
relatively strict. In a Letter of Intent from the Egyptian government to the IMF released in
January 1993, the government reviewed the difficult commitments made and implemented,
178

Jehl, Douglas. "Egypt Adding Corn to Bread: An Explosive Mix?" New York Times 27 Nov. 1996: A4.

66

including increasing domestic energy prices, reducing food subsidies (including sugar), and
other liberalization efforts. In contrast to the previous haggling and political maneuvering,
Momani notes, The Egyptian government complied with every prior action before the
commencement of the [1993] agreement. Decreased spending on subsidies, primarily tea,
fish, pesticides, and fertilizers, were an important component of these reforms.179 Within the
context of increased repression and reduced political openness, the government had greater
leeway to implement these reforms. As a result, Egypt was able to access IMF resources and
gain the confidence of international lenders.
By the time of the 1996 IMF agreement, food subsidies had already been decreased
substantially, leaving little room for further cutting. The agreement focused on privatization
and macroeconomic policy. Momani identifies this period as encompassing actions and
strategies signaling commitment to economic reform.180

Repression Against Islamic Fundamentalism and Opposition to the Regime


Egypt witnessed a dramatic increase in Islamist violence in the early 1990s. In
previous decades, al-Gamaa al-Islamiya and related groups had previously targeted Copts,
leftists, and most prominently, President Anwar Sadat. The levels of confrontation reached
new heights in the middle part of the decade. Between 1992 and 1997, 741 attacks occurred,
resulting in 1,442 deaths and 1,779 injuries. In contrast, the previous two decades had
witnessed 143 incidents resulting in around 120 deaths.181

179

Momani, Bessma. IMF - Egyptian Debt Negotiations. Cairo: American University in Cairo Press, 2005. 51.
Ibid. 60.
181
Wiktorowicz, Quintan. Islamic Activism: a Social Movement Theory Approach. Bloomington, Ind.: Indiana
University Press, 2004. 84.
180

67

One school of scholars links these violent events to the deliberalization of the
political process. Hafez and Wiktorowicz outline the shift in government policy towards
fundamentalists: the 1980s saw attempted cooptation and permissiveness, while policies in
the 1990s reflected the perception of a failure in marginalizing fundamentalists, and
increasing use of violent repression. The political inclusion of the more moderate Muslim
Brotherhood and the expansion of Islamist social services in the face of government retreat
aimed to constrain the most radical elements.
Hisham Mubarak termed this strategy permissive repression, where only the most
confrontational actions resulted in state responses.182 For example, small-scale sectarian
conflict in Upper Egypt resulted in relatively little state repression. Meanwhile, the militant
group al-Gamaa al-Islamiya continued to develop further legitimacy within poor urban
districts through social welfare networks, providing food and basic supplies during holidays.
In 1992, sectarian clashes, attacks on tourists and a prominent intellectual provoked
the deployment of soldiers in Upper Egypt to contain demonstrations between the police and
the Islamists. By December, the government sent 16,000 soldiers into the Imbaba slum in
Cairo, with additional deployments in outlying provinces during the following months.183
This escalation was matched by a withdrawal in political liberties.
The reduction in positive and negative political liberties began in 1992, conceivably
as a response to the increasing violence. Negative political liberties, protecting society from
the interference of rulers, declined as the regime attempted to combat the organization
network of Islamist groups. The legal process became dramatically harsher, as the regime
tried civilians in military courts, imposed more death penalties, and detained political

182
183

Ibid. 74.
Ibid. 78.

68

opponents. A press law, passed in 1995, placed a five-year sentence and high fines on the
printing of rumors and mendacious information against the state.184
Positive political liberties, understood as public participation and representation,
declined in each successive election between 1987 and 1995. The ruling NDP first increased
its share of parliament from 68% to 79%, reaching 94% after 1995. Repression, widespread
arrests, and opposition boycotts contributed to these results.

More prominently, even

alternative representative bodies, such as the syndicates, were placed under greater regime
control.

Union elections, with relatively low participation rates, were vulnerable to an

opposition takeover with a relatively small but motivated contingent. In response, the NDP
parliament established minimum turnout rules. If turnouts requirements were not achieved
after three attempts, regime administrators would lead the union board.185
These developments, particularly control over union apparatuses, highlight a more
broad-based repression beyond simply rooting out violent extremism. The closing-off of the
political process aimed to reduce other means of expressing anti-regime grievance, often
driven by economics. In 1977, trade unions and other civil society groups had taken a strong
public stance against the price increases and supporter the riots. A similar role could have
emerged for trade unions during the continued IMF reforms and price liberalizations. The
changed press laws and union elections had little direct link to the violence extremism in the
rest of Egypt. In contrast, these laws attacked the very source of negative publicity to
economic reforms that the Egyptian regime had feared since 1977.

184

Kienle, Eberhard. "More than a Response to Islamism: The Political Deliberalization of Egypt in the
1990s." Middle East Journal 52.2 (1998): 219-35.
185
Al-Jarida Al-Rasmiyya. Law 100/1993, 18 February 1993. Law 26/1994, 14 April 1994. 31. Law 142/1994,
31 May 1994.

69

The broad-based definition of terrorism was also used against leftists and their strikes.
Supporters of tenant farmers fighting eviction and increased rents faced the same charges as
those previously applied to Islamist group members.186

The 1990s involved relatively little opposition to the final and most drastic reductions
in basic staple subsidies.

The repressive environment of the Egyptian political system

dampened the more widespread opposition present during the previous decade. A more
closed political environment, driven by fears of violent extremism and opponents of
economic policies, reduced the potential for subsidy changes to dramatically rouse the
Egyptian public.

186

Al-Hayat, 19 June 1997.

70

VI. A Rising Tide Does Not Lift All Boats:


The Food Crisis in the 2000s

Egypts successful liberalization of the food subsidy system, which reduced coverage
to only four goods, exposed citizens to greater fluctuations in world markets. This period
differs from previous decades pattern of reform, as the regime held subsidies relatively
constant. Instead, popular dissatisfaction emerged from high world food prices.
The food subsidy system, which had contained 20 goods in 1980, was reduced to
baladi bread, wheat flour (82% extraction), edible oil, and sugar. The limited coverage,
coupled with shortages of covered goods, forced average Egyptians to resort to private or
black markets. Thus, Egyptians were greatly exposed to global food price trends. Among
the symptoms of these changes were increased industrial unrest and the 2008 bread crisis. In
the latter case, rather than rely solely on repression or compensation, the government
marshaled the armed forces to take over the bakery system, further strengthening the
militarys role in society.

Global Changes, Local Impacts


Egypt faced the same global challenges as other nations during the dramatic rise of
food prices from 2006 to 2008. The three primary commodities relevant to basic sustenance,
wheat, rice, and maize, tripled in real terms in the first six months of 2008, only to fall to 1.5

71

times their 2005 prices during the latter half of the year.187 As highlighted in Chapter 1,
these increases drove protests throughout the developing world.
The underlying causes for price increases included income growth, biofuel
production, and reduced investment in agriculture. In the short term, the volatility witnessed
in 2008 resulted from export bans by producing countries, speculative financial markets, and
higher transport costs.188
Egypt certainly felt the impacts of rising food commodity prices. In September 2007,
the Central Agency for Public Mobilization and Statistics announced that food prices had
increased 12.4 percent over the previous year, including a 37.6 percent increase for
vegetables.189 By March 2008, the Central Agency for Public Mobilization noted increases
in the consumer food basket of 24 percent in urban areas and 27 percent in rural areas.
Vegetable oil increased by 45 percent, and bread prices increased by 48 percent. For a very
poor populace, with over 20 percent living under $2 per day, such price increases proved
disastrous for maintaining social stability.190
Egypt had witnessed little growth in the preceding years. The World Bank reported
that overall poverty in 2004-2005 grew and returned to 1995-1996 levels. In 2008, bread
subsidies cost around $2.74 billion per year, a greater amount than spending on health and
education.191

187

Naylor, Roz, and Walter P. Falcon. "Food Security in an Era of Economic Volatility." Population and
Development Review 36.4 (2010): 693-723.
188
Trostle, Robert. Global Agricultural Supply and Demand: Factors Contributing to the Recent Increase in
Food Commodity Prices. Rep. no. WRS-0801. Economic Research Service of the USDA.
189
Beinin, Joel. "The Militancy of Mahalla Al-Kubra." Middle East Research and Information Project, 29 Sept.
2007. Web. 18 May 2012. <http://www.merip.org/mero/mero092907>.
190
"Arab Republic of Egypt Data." World Bank. Web. 18 May 2012. <http://data.worldbank.org/country/egyptarab-republic>.
191
Slackman, Michael. "Egypts Problem and Its Challenge: Bread Corrupts." The New York Times, 17 Jan.
2008. Web. 18 May 2012. <http://www.nytimes.com/2008/01/17/world/africa/17bread.html>.

72

The 2008 crisis was also preceded by an earlier change in currency value, which
forced the government to increase subsidies once again. In 2003, the government floated the
Egyptian pound, resulting in a depreciation of more than 30 percent. Imported wheat became
more expensive, driving consumers towards the subsidized baladi bread. In response, the
government introduced two types of bread: a 10-piastre bread (to complement the 5-piastre
baladi) and fino bread under a smaller subsidy. In April 2004, the government increased
subsidies to cover seven goods in response to public pressure. While theoretically coverage
increased, supply issues continued to limit availability, particularly when market prices rose.

Bread and Conflict: Increasing Tensions


By January 2008, widespread shortages, long lines, and fistfights in the street made
international headlines.

The Mubarak government, already hobbled by accusations of

widespread corruption and incompetence, was further undermined by its inability to provide
the Egyptian people with daily sustenance.
Corruption within the provisions sector provided the main source of complaints
against the regime. The systems structure naturally encouraged corruption. Bakers bought
government-subsidized 25-pound sack of flour for 8 Egyptian pounds (around $1.50 at 2008
prices). Bakers would then sell bread at the government-mandated price, earning $10 in
profit, or would sell the bag on the black market, earning $15. Bakers who were certified as
faithfully using the flour received an additional refund of $1 after three months, resulting
in a bonus of around 18,000 pounds ($3,300). By colluding with bakers selling flour on the
black market, inspectors could easily augment their low salaries.192

192

Ibid.

73

Rigid supply quotas also hobbled the government bread system. Egyptians can buy
officially unlimited quantities of subsidized bread, but each bakery faces a daily quota for
flour provision. These limits were passed along to the consumer as restrictions on the
number of loaves that can be purchased.193 Salevurakis highlights interviews with average
Egyptians who described the difficulty of finding bread after the early morning hours.194
Mahalla al-Kubra, a major industrial city, was a source of major labor conflict during
the 2000s. Tensions increased particularly from 2006, when strikes in Mahalla spread to
industrial centers in other cities.195 In April 2008, at the height of global food crisis, workers
in Mahalla launched an expanded strike that encompassed larger concerns about inflation and
low salaries.

Protestors burned two schools, and over 150 demonstrators were hurt.

Protestors in Cairo and other cities joined the call for a general strike. In Cairo, stores were
closed and students protested at three universities.196
These events converged with the long lines and shortages throughout Egypt. Fights at
bakeries left at least seven dead during this period.197 Al Jazeera and local news sources
highlighted the sense of injustice for victims of this violence and the widespread inflation.198

Government Response to Food-Driven Labor Unrest

193

Ghonaim, S. "Cabinet Studies Latin American Experience in Rationalizing Subsidies." Al-Ahram [Cairo] 27
Mar. 2005.
194
Salevurakis, J. W., and Sahar Mohamed Abdel-Haleim. "Bread Subsidies in Egypt: Choosing Social
Stability or Fiscal Responsibility." Review of Radical Political Economics 40.1 (2007): 35-49.
195
Beinin, Joel. "The Militancy of Mahalla Al-Kubra."
196
Slackman, Michael. "In Egypt, Technology Helps Spread Discontent of Workers." New York Times 7 Apr.
2008: A6.
197
"Egyptians Riot over Bread Crisis." The Telegraph, 8 Apr. 2008. Web. 18 May 2012.
<http://www.telegraph.co.uk/finance/economics/2787714/Egyptians-riot-over-bread-crisis.html>.
198
Al Jazeera English. "The Casualties of Egypts Food Crisis." YouTube. Web. 11 April 2008.
<http://www.youtube.com/watch?v=Nl_VrbgsjE0>.

74

The direct government response to the Mahalla riots was a recycling of past
strategies. Thousands of riot police confronted protesters and arrested 200. Private media
channels, which had broadcast images of the riots, were raided by government forces.199 In
his annual May Day speech a few weeks later, Mubarak announced wage increases of 30
percent to help Egyptians cope with increased prices.200 To calm public anger, the stateowned Al Ahram announced the arrests of 12,000 people for selling flour on the black
market.201
The strategies of repression, blame, and increased public sector wages were old tricks
of Egyptian regimes. The next step, calling in the military to take over production and
distribution, took the crisis in a new direction. In March 2008, Mubarak promised to end
bakery lines by directing the army to bake bread.202 The military aimed to improve the
production and distribution. The military, which already has extensive commercial interests,
increased its popularity through its perceived competence in providing for the countrys daily
sustenance. These measures, along with additional funding for subsidies, appeared to calm
widespread public anger.
By this point in Egypts liberalization, the government and the average Egyptian were
most connected through the bread subsidy. Failing social services and the reduction in
guaranteed government jobs had broken Nasserite expectations for the states role in society.
The failure to provide bread during a time of crisis underlined the civilian governments
weak capacities. In this light, dissatisfaction over food prices likely undercut Mubaraks
199

Al Jazeera English. "Media Crackdown in Egypt." YouTube. Web. 8 June 2008.


<http://www.youtube.com/watch?v=vUZ1HcHuauY>.
200
Saleh, Heba. "Food Price Crisis Bites in Egypt." BBC News. 05 Mar. 2008. Web. 18 May 2012.
<http://news.bbc.co.uk/2/hi/7381766.stm>.
201
"Egyptians Riot over Bread Crisis." The Telegraph, 8 Apr. 2008.
202
York, Elisabeth. "West Backs Gradual Egyptian Transition: Ally's Stability Hinges on a Secretive
Military." The New York Times. 06 Feb. 2011. Web. 18 May 2012.
<http://www.nytimes.com/2011/02/06/world/middleeast/06military.html>.

75

legitimacy.

Mubaraks subsequent tactical response to the bread crisis may have also

reinforced popular affection for the military. Chants of The Military and the People are One
Hand in Hand abounded during January 2011, highlighting faith in the military as possibly
the sole effective and legitimate government institution. These effects of high food prices
may have driven the 2011 Egyptian Revolution, but a singular cause cannot fully explain the
events in Tahrir Square, or their timing. Widespread anger over food prices fits in to larger
social concerns over corruption, government ineffectiveness, and the future of Egypt.

76

VII. Future Reforms After the 2011 Revolution:


Assessing Contemporary Egypt

The preceding historiography of Egyptian food policy arose out of questions


regarding food and revolution. The thesis has largely focused on analysis of past events,
describing the relative success of the Mubarak regime in confronting food-based protest
through covert price increases, distribution controls, and repression. The reforms of the
1990s, and continued stability through the 2000, demonstrate successful management of
public opposition.
Although the prospects for future reforms exceed the strict limits of this thesis, the
previous history of food reform and public response provide a window into future
possibilities. Further reforms of the food subsidy system towards a cash transfer program are
unlikely under the current political instability. In the competitive democratic process, the
composition of political actors and rise of veto players limit further reform.

Previous

strategies, such as covert changes and repression, will be harder to implement in the more
open political system.
Egyptian leaders have continued to recognize the role of bread in driving popular
opinion and public finances. Noor Ayman Nour, a prominent pro-democracy activist and the
son of an Egyptian presidential candidate, recently asserted that, Bread can be the firestarter or the fire extinguisher of a revolution.203 Food has thus served well in political
rhetoric, but more importantly, it can determine a new governments financial viability.

203

Cunningham, Eric. "Egypt's Bread Revolution." Salon, 10 Apr. 2012. Web. 04 May 2012.
<http://www.salon.com/2012/04/10/egypts_bread_revolution/>.

77

The ongoing weakness of Egypts economy impacts its ability to finance the food
subsidy bill, which topped $5.5 billion last year. Since January 2011, reserves have fallen
from $36 to $15 billion, raising concerns about available funding for imported wheat and
subsidized fuel.204 The continued, although slowing, decline in the Egyptian economy will
require Egypts rulers to seek outside support, as negotiations continue with the IMF and
outside creditors. Current subsidies on energy and food, which account for 28 percent of the
governments $96 billion budget, will likely emerge as a priority area of reduction for
international lenders.205
The internationally-recognized solutions for Egypt involve greater poverty-based
targeting and conditional cash transfer system to encourage system-wide efficiency. Such
programs have emerged as effective tools for social welfare in Latin America.

These

proposals can utilize a variety of proxies for targeting needy Egyptians, whether
geographically, by increasing funding for worse-off governates and increasing distribution in
poor neighborhoods, or by identifying eligible individuals.

Conditional cash transfer

programs require households to meet requirements such as regular health checkups and
childrens school attendance, thus confronting key challenges in the developing country
context.206 The popular fear amidst these reforms is that the government will simply use
these changes as a pretext for a continued retreat from social services. Average Egyptians
may prefer the current imperfect system to the uncertainty of subsidy changes.207

204

"Egypt's Foreign-Currency Reserves Fall To $15.1B." Wall Street Journal, 2 Apr. 2012. Web. 4 May 2012. <
http://online.wsj.com/article/BT-CO-20120402-712594.html>.
205
Bradley, Matt. "Egypt's Brewing Crisis: Subsidies." Wall Street Journal, 22 Mar. 2012. Web. 4 May 2012.
<http://online.wsj.com/article/SB10001424052970204059804577228984285910816.html>.
206
"Conditional Cash Transfers." Safety Nets and Transfers. World Bank. Web. 18 May 2012.
<http://go.worldbank.org/BWUC1CMXM0>.
207
Ahmed, Akhter U., Howarth E. Bouis, Tamar Gutner, and Hans Lofgren. The Egyptian Food Subsidy System
Structure, Performance, and Options for Reform. Rep. no. 119. Washington, D.C.: International Food Policy
Research Institute, 2001.

78

Within the domestic context, a new government is unlikely to take on the food
subsidy challenge. The orientation of the dominant political parties and public opinion
reduces the potential for change. The Muslim Brotherhood will find it difficult to rethink the
food subsidy, as even its leadership, composed of business owners, has adopted the
democratiyyat al-khubz208 mentality to court voters. In recent decades, the organization has
both combined political and social activities, which it has used to its advantage during the
last electoral cycle. During November 2011, the Brotherhood leveraged its charitable muscle
to provide discounted meat and vegetables.209 The appeal of such campaigns is apparent:
Food comprises 40 percent of Egyptian expenditures.210
At this stage of democratic development, voters are driven by tangible benefits
provided by politicians. A voter education activist in Ismailia explained:
The price of sugar, the price of rice thats what voters care about. If Islamists
can deliver on that, theyll succeed.

If not, theyll be voted out in the next

election.211
The structure of the political system will further exacerbate these trends, as the new
government may have an Islamist parliament, independent president, and unpredictable
judiciary. Each of these institutions represents an independent center of power capable of
blocking change.

208

See Chapter 1 for a discussion on democratiyyat al-khubz.


Fadel, Leila. "Muslim Brotherhood Sells Cheap Food Ahead of Holiday and Egypt Parliament
Vote." Washington Post. 5 Nov. 2011. Web. 4 May 2012.
<http://www.washingtonpost.com/world/middle_east/muslim-brotherhood-sells-cheap-food-ahead-of-holidayand-egypt-parliament-vote/2011/11/05/gIQAQD2PqM_story.html>.
210
Natella, Stefano and Giles Keating. Credit Suisse Emerging Consumer Survey 2011. <https://www.creditsuisse.com/news/doc/media_releases/consumer_survey_0701_small.pdf>
211
Kristoff, Nicholas. "Democracy in the Muslim Brotherhood's Birthplace." The New York Times. 10 Dec.
2011. Web. 4 May 2012. <http://www.nytimes.com/2011/12/11/opinion/sunday/kristof-Democracy-in-theMuslim-Brotherhoods-Birthplace.html?_r=1#>.
209

79

Political groups will need to join together to address the budgetary challenge of food
subsidies, as each group will fear its rivals capitalizing on rumors of possible reform. When
voters judge economic performance, the price of bread and basic goods will resonate more
strongly than GDP figures and a balanced budget. In the near future, political power must be
consolidated before a grand reformist bargain can be devised.

80

VIII. Bibliography
Abd al-Khaliq, Judah, and Karima Korayem. Fiscal Policy Measures In Egypt: Public Debt
and Food Subsidy. Cairo: American University in Cairo Press, 2001.
Abdel-Khalek, Gouda. "Looking Outside, or Turning Northwest? On the Meaning and
External Dimension of Egypt's Infitah 1971-1980." Social Problems 28.4 (1981).
Abu Liwaayah, Muhammad. "Will a Plate of Kushari Turn into a Tourist Dish?" Al-Shab.
12 Aug. 1986.
Adams, Richard H. Self-targeted Subsidies: The Distributional Impact of the Egyptian Food
Subsidy System. Washington, DC: World Bank, Poverty Reduction and Economic
Management Network, Poverty Division, 2000.
Africa, Thomas W. "Urban Violence in Imperial Rome." The Journal of Interdisciplinary
History 2.1 (1971).
Ahmed, Akhter U., Howarth E. Bouis, Tamar Gutner, and Hans Lofgren. The Egyptian Food
Subsidy System Structure, Performance, and Options for Reform. Rep. no. 119.
Washington, D.C.: International Food Policy Research Institute, 2001.
Ahmed, Raisuddin, Steve Haggblade, and Tawfiq-e-Elahi Chowdhury. Out of the Shadow of
Famine: Evolving Food Markets and Food Policy in Bangladesh. Baltimore: Johns
Hopkins UP, 2000.
Ajami, Fouad. The Arab Predicament: Arab Political Thought and Practice since 1967.
Cambridge: Cambridge UP, 1981.
Al Jazeera English. "Media Crackdown in Egypt." YouTube. Web. 8 June 2008.
<http://www.youtube.com/watch?v=vUZ1HcHuauY>.
Al Jazeera English. "The Casualties of Egypts Food Crisis." YouTube. Web. 11 April 2008.
<http://www.youtube.com/watch?v=Nl_VrbgsjE0>.
Alderman, Harold, and Joachim Von Braun. Egypt's Food Subsidy Policy: Lessons and
Options. Washington, D.C.: International Food Policy Research Institute, 1986.
Alderman, Harold, Joachim Von Braun, and Ahmed Sakr. Egypt's Food Subsidy and
Rationing System: a Description. Washington, D.C.: International Food Policy
Research Institute, 1982.
Alesina, Alberto, and Allan Drazen. "Why Are Stabilizations Delayed?" American Economic
Review 85.5 (1991).
Alesina, Alberto, and Guido Tabellini. "External Debt, Capital Flight and Political Risk."
Journal of International Economics 27.3 (1989).

81

Alston, J. M., J. M. Beddow, and P. G. Pardey. "Agricultural Research, Productivity, and


Food Prices in the Long Run." Science 325.5945 (2009).
Ansari, Hamied. Egypt, the Stalled Society. Albany: State University of New York Press,
1986.
"Arab

Republic of Egypt Data." World Bank. Web.


<http://data.worldbank.org/country/egypt-arab-republic>.

18

May

2012.

Mar.

2012.

Article IV Consultation, IMF Egypt, 1986.


"Background Note: Egypt." U.S. Department of
<http://www.state.gov/r/pa/ei/bgn/5309.htm>.

State.

Web.

13

Beattie, Kirk J. Egypt during the Sadat Years. New York: Palgrave, 2000.
Beinin, Joel. "The Militancy of Mahalla Al-Kubra."
Beinin, Joel. "The Militancy of Mahalla Al-Kubra." Middle East Research and Information
Project,
29
Sept.
2007.
Web.
18
May
2012.
<http://www.merip.org/mero/mero092907>.
Besley, Timothy, and Ravi Kanbur. "Food Subsidies and Poverty Alleviation." The
Economic Journal 98.392 (1988).
Bienen, Henry S., and Mark Gersovitz. "Consumer Subsidy Cuts, Violence, and Political
Stability." Comparative Politics 19.1 (1986).
Bird, Graham. "The International Monetary Fund and Developing Countries: A Review of
the Evidence and Policy Options." International Organization 50.03 (1996).
Bohstedt, John. Riots and Community Politics in England and Wales: 1790-1810.
Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1983.
Bonanno, Alessandro. From Columbus to ConAgra: the Globalization of Agriculture and
Food. Lawrence, KS: University of Kansas, 1994.
Bradley, Matt. "Egypt's Brewing Crisis: Subsidies." Wall Street Journal, 22 Mar. 2012. Web.
4 May 2012.
<http://online.wsj.com/article/SB10001424052970204059804577228984285910816.
html>.
Brinkman, Henk-Jan S., and Cullen S. Hendrix. "Food Insecurity and Conflict: Applying the
WDR Framework." World Bank Development Repot 2011. World Bank, 2 Aug. 2010.
Bueno de Mesquita, Bruce, Alastair Smith, Randolph M. Siverson, and James D. Morrow.
2003. The Logic of Political Survival. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

82

Clark, Peter. "Popular Protest and Disturbance in Kent, 15581640." The Economic History
Review 29.3 (1976): 365-82.
"Conditional Cash Transfers." Safety Nets and Transfers. World Bank. Web. 18 May 2012.
<http://go.worldbank.org/BWUC1CMXM0>.
Cunningham, Eric. "Egypt's Bread Revolution." Salon, 10 Apr. 2012. Web. 04 May 2012.
<http://www.salon.com/2012/04/10/egypts_bread_revolution/>.
Daines, Victoria, John Walton, and David Seddon. Free Markets and Food Riots: The
Politics of Global Adjustment. Oxford: Blackwell, 1994.
Feiler, Gil. Economic Relations between Egypt and the Gulf Oil States, 1967-2000: Petro
Wealth and Patterns of Influence. Brighton, England: Sussex Academic, 2003. Print.
"Egypt August 1986." Keesing's Record of World Events 31: 33817.
"Egypt Raises Some Prices but Holds the Line on Food." New York Times 30 Dec. 1978.
"Egypt September 1984." Keesing's Record of World Events 30: 33124.
"Egyptians Riot over Bread Crisis." The Telegraph, 8 Apr. 2008. Web. 18 May 2012.
<http://www.telegraph.co.uk/finance/economics/2787714/Egyptians-riot-over-breadcrisis.html>.
"Egyptians Riot over Bread Crisis." The Telegraph, 8 Apr. 2008.
"Egypt's Foreign-Currency Reserves Fall To $15.1B." Wall Street Journal, 2 Apr. 2012.
Web. 4 May 2012. < http://online.wsj.com/article/BT-CO-20120402-712594.html>.
El Dahan, Maha. "Egypt Inches towards Far-reaching Food Subsidy Reform." Reuters, 28
Sept. 2011. Web. 05 Dec. 2011. <http://www.reuters.com/article/2011/09/28/usegypt-food-idUSTRE78R2SD20110928>.
El-Hamalawy, Hossam. "Egypt: Revolt of the Hungry." Egypt: Revolt of Hungry. Socialist
Worker,
17
Feb.
2005.
Web.
12
Mar.
2012.
<http://www.socialistworker.co.uk/article.php?article_id=10705>.
Fadel, Leila. "Muslim Brotherhood Sells Cheap Food Ahead of Holiday and Egypt
Parliament Vote." Washington Post. 5 Nov. 2011. Web. 4 May 2012.
<http://www.washingtonpost.com/world/middle_east/muslim-brotherhood-sellscheap-food-ahead-of-holiday-and-egypt-parliamentvote/2011/11/05/gIQAQD2PqM_story.html>.
Fahmy, Ismail. Negotiating for Peace In the Middle East. Baltimore, Md.: Johns Hopkins
University Press, 1983.

83

Fearon, James D., and David D. Laitin. "Ethnicity, Insurgency, and Civil War."American
Political Science Review 97.01 (2003).
Feiler, Gil. Economic Relations Between Egypt and the Gulf Oil States, 1967-2000 : Petrowealth and Patterns of Influence. Brighton [England]: Sussex Academic Press, 2003.
Foreign Broadcast Information Service Database Entries for Egypt:
19 January 1977 Press Review.
24 January 1977 Press Review.
4 February 1977 Press Review.
6 February 1984, Al-Wafd.
29 September 1984 Press Review.
1 October 1984 Press Review.
16 October 1984, Al-Sharq Al-Awsat.
21 July 1988 Press Review.
4 April 1989, Al-Shab.
5 April 1989, Al-Akhbar.
10 April 1989, Al-Ahrar.
10 April 1989, Al-Wafd.
17 April 1989, Al-Wafd.
Ghonaim, S. "Cabinet Studies Latin American Experience in Rationalizing Subsidies." AlAhram [Cairo] 27 Mar. 2005.
Golan, Galia. "The Domestic Impact on Israel of the Spring, Summer, and
September." Middle East Program: Occasional Paper Series. Woodrow Wilson
International
Center
for
Scholars,
2011.
Web.
<http://wilsoncenter.net/sites/default/files/Domestic%20Impact%20on%20Israel.pdf>
.
Graham, Carol. Safety Nets, Politics, and the Poor: Transitions to Market Economies.
Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution, 1994.
Gurr, Ted Robert. Why Men Rebel. Princeton, NJ: Published for the Center of International
Studies, Princeton University Press, 1970.

84

Gutner, Tammi. The Political Economy of Food Subsidy Reform in Egypt. Rep. no. 77.
International
Food
Policy
Research
Institute,
Nov.
1999.
Web.
<http://www.ifpri.org/sites/default/files/pubs/divs/fcnd/dp/papers/dp77.pdf>.
Haggard, Stephan, and Steven B. Webb. "What Do We Know About The Political Economy
Of Economic Policy Reform?" The World Bank Research Observer 8.2 (1993).
Harlan, J. R. "The Early History of Wheat: Earliest Traces to the Sack of Rome." Wheat
Science, Today and Tomorrow. Ed. L. T. Evans, W. J. Peacock, and O. H. Frankel.
Cambridge: Cambridge UP, 1981.
Al-Hayat, Cairo. 19 June 1997.
Hendrix, Cullen, Stephen Haggard, and Beatriz Magaloni. "Grievance and Opportunity: Food
Prices, Political Regime, and Protest." International Studies Association Convention,
15
Feb.
2009.
Web.
5
Dec.
2011.
<http://www.kent.ac.uk/brussels/conference/documents/Food_pricesprotests.magahaggahendrix_isa.pdf>.
Hirst, David, and Irene Beeson. Sadat. London: Faber and Faber, 1981.
Hopkins, Raymond F. "Political Calculations in Subsidizing Food." Political Calculations in
Subsidizing
Food.
International
Food
Policy
Research
Institute.
<http://www.ifpri.org/sites/default/files/pubs/pubs/books/ppa88/ppa88ch07.pdf>.
Howe, Marvine. "Egypt Weighs Food-Aid Cuts Again." New York Times 19 Aug. 1977: A4.
Huntington, Samuel P. Political Order in Changing Societies. New Haven: Yale University
Press, 1968.
"Islamic Radicals' Appeal Seems to Be Gaining in Egypt." Los Angeles Times, 18 Nov.
1988. Web. 12 Mar. 2012. <http://articles.latimes.com/1988-11-18/news/mn756_1_islamic-radicals>.
Al-Jarida Al-Rasmiyya. Law 100/1993, 18 February 1993. Law 26/1994, 14 April 1994. 31.
Law 142/1994, 31 May 1994.
Jehl, Douglas. "Egypt Adding Corn to Bread: An Explosive Mix?" New York Times 27 Nov.
1996: A4.
Kacowicz, Arie Marcelo. Peaceful Territorial Change. Columbia, S.C.: University of South
Carolina Press, 1994.134.
Karawan, Ibrahim A. "Sadat and the EgyptianIsraeli Peace Revisited." International
Journal of Middle East Studies 26.02 (1994).
Kricheli, Ruth, Yair Livne, and Beatriz Magaloni. "Taking to the Streets: Theory and
Evidence
on
Protests
under
Authoritarianism."
(2011).

85

<http://cddrl.stanford.edu/publications/taking_to_the_streets_theory_and_evidence_o
n_protests_under_authoritarianism/>.
Kienle, Eberhard. "More than a Response to Islamism: The Political Deliberalization of
Egypt in the 1990s." Middle East Journal 52.2 (1998): 219-35.
Kristoff, Nicholas. "Democracy in the Muslim Brotherhood's Birthplace." The New York
Times.
10
Dec.
2011.
Web.
4
May
2012.
<http://www.nytimes.com/2011/12/11/opinion/sunday/kristof-Democracy-in-theMuslim-Brotherhoods-Birthplace.html?_r=1#>.
Kuran, Timur. "Sparks and Prairie Fires: A Theory of Unanticipated Political
Revolution." Public Choice 61.1 (1989): 41-74.
Lachine, Nadime. "Class Roots of the Egyptian Regime." MERIP Reports 56 (1977): 3-7.
Lagi, Marco, Karla Z. Bertrand, and Yaneer Bar-Yam. "The Food Crises and Political
Instability in North Africa and the Middle East." New England Complex Systems
Institute, 28 Sept. 2011. Web. <http://necsi.edu/research/social/food_crises.pdf>.
Lichbach, Mark I. "An Evaluation of "Does Economic Inequality Breed Political
Conflict?" World Politics 41.4 (1989): 431-70.
Lohmann, Susanne. "The Dynamics of Informational Cascades: The Monday Demonstrations
in Leipzig, East Germany, 1989-91." World Politics 47.1 (1994): 42-101.
Miller, Judith. "Egyptians Worry Despite Riot's End." New York Times 7 Oct. 1984: 17.
Momani, Bessma. IMF - Egyptian Debt Negotiations. Cairo: American University in Cairo
Press, 2005. 51.
Momani, Bessma. "American Politicization of the International Monetary Fund." Review of
International Political Economy 11.5 (2004): 880-904.
Natella, Stefano and Giles Keating. Credit Suisse Emerging Consumer Survey 2011.
<https://www.creditsuisse.com/news/doc/media_releases/consumer_survey_0701_sm
all.pdf>
Naylor, Roz, and Walter P. Falcon. "Food Security in an Era of Economic Volatility."
Population and Development Review 36.4 (2010): 693-723.
Nelson, Joan M. Fragile Coalitions: The Politics of Economic Adjustment. New Brunswick,
USA: Transaction, 1989.
Nohlen, Dieter, Michael Krennerich, and Bernhard Thibaut. Elections in Africa: A Data
Handbook. Oxford: Oxford UP, 1999. 336.

86

Olson, Mancur. "Autocracy, Democracy, and Prosperity." Ed. Richard Zeckhauser. Strategy
and Choice. Cambridge, MA: MIT, 1991.
Orlove, Benjamin S. "Meat and Strength: The Moral Economy of a Chilean Food
Riot."Cultural Anthropology 12.2 (1997): 234-68.
Ranis, Gustav, and Syed Akhtar, Mahmood. The Political Economy of Development Policy
Change. Cambridge, MA: B. Blackwell, 1992.
Richards, Alan. The political economy of dilatory reform: Egypt in the 1980s. World
Development. 19.12 (1991): 1721-30.
Rivlin, Paul. The Liberalization of the Egyptian Economy: An Examination of the Decisionmaking Process. Tel Aviv: Shiloah Center for Middle Eastern and African Studies,
Tel Aviv University, 1981. 7.
Rodrik, Dani. "Understanding
Literature 34.1 (1996).

Economic

Policy

Reform." Journal

of

Economic

Rogg, Margaret L. "Egypt Says Police Rebellion Is Quelled." New York Times 28 Feb. 1986:
A3.
Sachs, Jeffrey. Life in the Economic Emergency Room. The Political Economy of Policy
Reform. Ed. John Williamson, 1994.
Sadiki, Larbi. "Towards Arab Liberal Governance: From the Democracy of Bread to the
Democracy of the Vote." Third World Quarterly 18.1 (1997): 127-48.
Sadowski, Yahya M. Political Vegetables? Businessman and Bureaucrat In the Development
of Egyptian Agriculture. Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution, 1991. 160.
Saleh, Heba. "Food Price Crisis Bites in Egypt." BBC News. 05 Mar. 2008. Web. 18 May
2012. <http://news.bbc.co.uk/2/hi/7381766.stm>.
Salevurakis, J. W., and Sahar Mohamed Abdel-Haleim. "Bread Subsidies in Egypt: Choosing
Social Stability or Fiscal Responsibility." Review of Radical Political Economics 40.1
(2007): 35-49.
Sharp, Buchanan. In Contempt of All Authority: Rural Artisans and Riot in the West of
England, 1586-1660. Berkeley: University of California, 1980.
Singerman, Diane, and Homa Hoodfar. Development, Change, and Gender In Cairo: a View
From the Household. Bloomington: Indiana University Press, 1996.
Singerman, Diane. Avenues of Participation: Family, Politics, and Networks in Urban
Quarters of Cairo. Princeton, NJ: Princeton UP, 1995.

87

Slackman, Michael. "Egypts Problem and Its Challenge: Bread Corrupts." The New York
Times,
17
Jan.
2008.
Web.
18
May
2012.
<http://www.nytimes.com/2008/01/17/world/africa/17bread.html>.
Slackman, Michael. "In Egypt, Technology Helps Spread Discontent of Workers." New York
Times 7 Apr. 2008: A6.
Smith, Adam. "Digression concerning the Corn Trade and Corn Laws." Wealth of Nations.
Snyder, David, and Charles Tilly. "Hardship and Collective Violence in France, 18301960." American Sociological Review 37.5: 520-32.
Soliman, Samir, and Peter Daniel. The Autumn of Dictatorship: Fiscal Crisis and Political
Change In Egypt Under Mubarak. Stanford, California: Stanford University Press,
2011. 59.
Tanner, Henry. "A Stringent Decree Put to Vote in Egypt." New York Times 11 Feb. 1977.
Tanner, Henry. "Egyptian Riots Have Seriously Sadats Freedom of Action at Home and
Abroad." New York Times 25 Jan. 1977: 3.
Tatro, Earleen. "Egypt's Proposed Budget For 1980 Sets Off Price Increases for Most
Items." New York Times 26 Dec. 1979.
Thompson, E. P. "The Moral Economy Of The English Crowd In The Eighteenth
Century." Past and Present 50.1 (1971): 76-136.
Thomson, Anne. "Egypt: Food Security and Food Aid." Food Policy 8.3 (1983).
Tilly, Charles, and Gabriel Ardant. "Food Supply and Public Order in Modern Europe."The
Formation of National States in Western Europe. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University
Publishing, 1975. 380-455.
Tilly, Louise A. "The Food Riot as a Form of Political Conflict in France." The Journal of
Interdisciplinary History 2.1 (1971): 23-57.
Trostle, Robert. Global Agricultural Supply and Demand: Factors Contributing to the Recent
Increase in Food Commodity Prices. Rep. no. WRS-0801. Economic Research
Service of the USDA.
"US Plans to Bolster Aid to Egypt by $190 Million to Ease Unrest." New York Times 2 Feb.
1977.
Walton, John, and David Seddon. "Global Adjustment." Free Markets & Food Riots: the
Politics of Global Adjustment. Oxford, UK: Blackwell, 1994.
Waterbury, John. Egypt : Burdens of the Past, Options for the Future. Bloomington: Indiana
University Press, 1978.

88

Waterbury, John. The Egypt of Nasser and Sadat : the Political Economy of Two Regimes.
Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1983.
Waterbury, John. The Egypt of Nasser and Sadat: The Political Economy of Two Regimes.
Princeton, NJ: Princeton UP, 1983.
Wiktorowicz, Quintan. Islamic Activism: a Social Movement Theory Approach.
Bloomington, Ind.: Indiana University Press, 2004.
York, Elisabeth. "West Backs Gradual Egyptian Transition: Ally's Stability Hinges on a
Secretive Military." The New York Times. 06 Feb. 2011. Web. 18 May 2012.
<http://www.nytimes.com/2011/02/06/world/middleeast/06military.html>.
Photography
Lubin, Gus. "Non-Political Bread Riots Are Breaking Out In Egypt, Killing Three." Business
Insider. 01 Feb. 2011. Web. 21 May 2012. <http://articles.businessinsider.com/201102-01/news/30057341_1_bread-riots-bread-prices-hosni-mubarak>.

89

Das könnte Ihnen auch gefallen