Sie sind auf Seite 1von 18

This document is copyrighted by the American Psychological Association or one of its allied publishers.

This article is intended solely for the personal use of the individual user and is not to be disseminated broadly.

Copyright 1990 by the American Psychological Association, Inc.


0033-2909/90/$00.75

Psychological Bulletin
1990, Vol. 108, No. 3,515-532

Negotiation Behavior and Outcomes:


Empirical Evidence and Theoretical Issues
Leigh Thompson
University of Washington
This article examines the ability of the individual differences, motivational, and cognitive approaches of negotiation to account for empirical research on dyadic negotiation. Investigators have
typically focused on objective, economic measures of performance. However, social-psychological
measures are important because negotiators often do not have the information necessary to make
accurate judgments of the bargaining situation. Negotiators' judgments are biased, and biases are
associated with inefficient performance. Personality and individual differences appear to play a
minimal role in determining bargaining behavior; their impact may be dampened by several
factors, such as homogeneity of subject samples, situational constraints, and self-selection processes. Motivational and cognitive models provide compelling accounts of negotiation behavior. A
psychological theory of negotiation should begin at the level of the individual negotiator and
should integrate features of motivational and cognitive models.

Morgenstern, 1947) and prescribe how people should behave in


competitive situations (Cross, 1965; Harsanyi, 1956; Nash,
1950,1953). Normative models have largely been the province
of economists and game theorists (cf. Cross, 1965; Harsanyi,
1956; Nash, 1950). As Raiffa (1982) stated, "Game theorists. . .
examine what ultrasmart, impeccably rational, superpeople
should do in competitive, interactive situations. They are not
interested in the way erring folks like you and me actually behave, but in how we should behave if we were smarter, thought
harder, were more consistent, were all knowing" (p. 21). Normative models have advanced the understanding of conflict
behavior by providing compelling analyses of optimal or rational behavior in competitive situations.
In addition to prescribing how negotiators should behave,
some economic models were also intended to describe the actual behavior of negotiators (Nash, 1950). However, empirical
observation indicates that normative models do not adequately
describe the behavior of most people in bargaining situations
(Neale & Bazerman, 1985a; Northcraft & Neale, in press;
Thompson & Hastie, in press). Specifically, bargainers do not
behave according to principles of normative bargaining models
and, in fact, systematically violate key principles (Bazerman &
Neale, 1983). Primarily as a response to the inadequacy of normative models to account for empirical observation, purely descriptive theories of negotiation behavior have developed. Descriptive theories have been largely the province of psychologists and organization theorists (cf. Bazerman & Carroll, 1987;
Kelley, 1966; Pruitt & Rubin, 1986). Descriptive theories examine the influence of individual characteristics, motivations,
and cognitive processes on judgment, behavior, and outcomes
in negotiation. The focus of this article is on descriptive accounts of negotiation behavior.
Because of the large volume of research on negotiation behavior in many disciplines, it was necessary to restrict the scope of
this review in four ways. First, I examined negotiation or explicit bargaining (Chertkoff & Esser, 1976; Cross, 1965; Siegel &

Negotiation is a pervasive and important form of social interaction. Negotiation is necessary whenever conflict erupts and
there are no fixed or established rules or procedures to resolve
conflict and whenever people want to search for agreement
without resorting to aggression or open fighting (Lewicki &
Litterer, 1985). Negotiation occurs in business and academic
environments and in informal social interactions such as deciding with a friend or spouse where to dine or vacation. Clearly,
negotiation is essential for anyone who must interact with other
people to accomplish their objectives.
There is broad interest in the study of negotiation behavior.
This interest is evident in the interdisciplinary history of the
study of negotiation in the fields of psychology, economics,
industrial relations, organization behavior, sociology, and law.
The theoretical goal is to predict the processes and outcomes of
negotiation. The practical or applied goal is to help people negotiate more effectively (Bazerman, 1986; Raiffa, 1982). The fundamental and enduring questions raised by the growing body of
research on negotiation behavior include the following: What
factors lead to negotiation success or failure? Which theoretical
perspective provides the best account of negotiation behavior?
What empirical findings must a theoretical approach to negotiation explain? The purpose of this article is to address these
theoretical and empirical issues.
A variety of theoretical analyses of negotiation behavior have
been developed. An important theoretical distinction is that
between normative and descriptive approaches (Neale &
Northcraft, in press; Raiffa, 1982). Normative models are
based on axioms of individual rationality (cf. von Neumann &

I thank Max Bazerman and Reid Hastie for helpful comments on


drafts of this article.
Correspondence concerning this article should be addressed to
Leigh Thompson, Department of Psychology, University of Washington, Seattle, Washington 98195, or by bitnet to Ithompson@max .acs.washington.edu.

515

This document is copyrighted by the American Psychological Association or one of its allied publishers.
This article is intended solely for the personal use of the individual user and is not to be disseminated broadly.

516

LEIGH THOMPSON

Fouraker, 1960). This definition excluded research on matrix


games such as the Prisoner's Dilemma (for reviews, see Northcraft & Neale, in press; Pruitt & Kimmel, 1977; Smith, 1987).
Pure negotiation situations differ from social dilemmas in
terms of the communication between parties, the parties' ability to make provisional offers, the veto power that each party
has on any outcome other than the disagreement outcome, and
each party's knowledge of the other's payoffs, interests, and
structure of the task (Bartos, 1972; Chertkoff & Esser, 1976;
Rapoport, 1968; Siegel & Fouraker, 1960). Second, the focus
was on two parties, or dyadic negotiation, as opposed to multiparty negotiation involving coalitional activity (for reviews of
coalitional bargaining, see Miller & Komorita, 1986; Murnighan, 1986). The review was restricted to bargains in which
negotiators were monolithic (i.e., negotiators bargain for their
own interests or, if representing a constituency, the constituency members have uniform interests; Raiffa, 1982). Third, I
examined three theoretical approaches: individual differences,
motivational, and cognitive models. These approaches represent the most common theoretical orientations in the study of
negotiation (Bazerman & Carroll, 1987; Neale & Northcraft, in
press). However, they do not exhaust the set of theoretical perspectives in negotiation.1 Finally, third-party interventions (e.g.,
mediation, arbitration) are not discussed (for reviews, see Rubin, 1980; 1986; Sheppard, 1984). This review focused on the
interchange that occurs between two people attempting to resolve a conflict of interest.
In the sections that follow, I discuss the characteristics and
basic features of negotiation, identify economic and social-psychological measures of negotiation performance, review the
major theoretical approaches to negotiation, and examine
current empirical research. I conclude by proposing a theoretical and empirical research agenda.

DEFINITION OF NEGOTIATION
Negotiation is the process whereby people attempt to settle
what each shall give and take or perform and receive in a transaction between them (Rubin & Brown, 1975). A negotiation
situation has five characteristics: (a) People believe that they
have conflicting interests; (b) communication is possible; (c)
intermediate solutions or compromises are possible; (d) parties
may make provisional offers and counteroffers; and (e) offers
and proposals do not determine outcomes until they are accepted by both parties (Chertkoff & Esser, 1976; Cross, 1965;
Schelling, 1960).
The basic features of negotiation include the negotiating parties, their interests, the negotiation process, and the negotiation
outcome (Thompson & Hastie, 1990). A party to a negotiation
is a person (or a group of persons with common interests) who
acts in accord with his or her preferences. The interests of negotiators are the preferences or utilities that each person has for the
resources to be divided (Walton & McKersie, 1965). The structure of the bargaining situation is determined by the degree of
conflict between parties' interests. Pure conflict exists when
parties' interests are perfectly negatively correlated; that is, any
outcome that increases one party's utility decreases the other
party's utility in a fixed-sum fashion. Pure conflict situations
are known as fixed-sum or purely distributive negotiations

(Walton & McKersie, 1965). Two people bargaining over the


price of a used car for which the seller wants more money and
the buyer wants to pay as little as possible is an example of a
distributive negotiation. Pure coordination situations exist
when parties' interests are perfectly compatible; increasing one
party's utility also increases the other party's utility. A negotiation over an orange in which one person desires only the peel
and the other desires only the juice is an example (Follett,
1940). In empirical investigations, researchers typically do not
examine bargaining in pure coordination situations, although
interesting questions concern whether negotiators are able to
realize when their interests are compatible with those of another (Hammond, Stewart, Brehmer, & Steinmann, 1975;
Thompson & Hastie, in press). Sometimes parties' interests are
neither completely opposed nor purely compatible. Such situations are known as variable-sum or integrative negotiations
(Walton & McKersie, 1965).2 In integrative bargaining situations, the gains of one party do not represent equal sacrifices by
the other. Pruitt (1986) gave the example of a couple in conflict
over where to spend a vacation. The husband prefers a cabin in
the mountains; the wife prefers a luxury hotel on the seashore.
The husband is primarily concerned with location; the wife is
primarily concerned with accommodations. An integrative
agreement is reached when the couple agree to vacation in a
luxury hotel in the mountains. Many researchers contend that
most negotiation situations are integrative (Pruitt & Rubin,
1986; Raiffa, 1982; Walton & McKersie, 1965). Although there
is no empirical evidence to support this contention, two logical
arguments support it. The deductive argument is that two people are more likely to have different priorities, risk preferences,
and valuations of resources than they are likely to have identical preferences across such dimensions. Differences on any dimension define opportunities for integrative trade-offs (Raiffa,
1982). The inductive argument is based on the large volume of
case studies of negotiation situations in which opportunities for
integrative agreements have been identified (Lax & Sebenius,
1985).
The negotiation process is the interaction that occurs between parties before the outcome. Negotiation processes include communication between bargainers and behavioral enactments of bargaining strategies. The negotiation outcome is
the product of the bargaining situation. Negotiations may end
in impasse (i.e., the parties fail to reach a mutually acceptable
agreement) or in mutual agreement. In integrative and pure
coordination situations, outcomes that result in mutual agreement may be examined in terms of the efficiency of the outcome. A negotiation outcome is said to be efficient or pareto
optimal if there does not exist some other feasible solution or set
of solutions that would improve the utility of one or both parties while not hurting either party (Nash, 1950). Finally, negotia1
At least two other approaches have been acknowledged: a communications approach and a structural approach (for reviews, see Chatman & Sondak, in press; Neale & Northcraft, in press). In general,
these approaches are more piecemeal and less well developed than
those reviewed in this article.
2
Technically, the label integrative also includes purely compatible
situations. In this discussion, integrative refers to situations characterized by a partial conflict of interest.

This document is copyrighted by the American Psychological Association or one of its allied publishers.
This article is intended solely for the personal use of the individual user and is not to be disseminated broadly.

NEGOTIATION BEHAVIOR AND OUTCOMES

tion outcomes are also examined in terms of the distribution of


resources among bargainers.
MEASURES OF NEGOTIATION BEHAVIOR
Measures of behavior and performance in negotiation may
be grouped into two general categories: economic and socialpsychological measures. Economic measures focus on the outcomes or products of the negotiation and are derived from axioms of individual rationality and normative analyses of negotiation behavior (Nash, 1953). Social-psychological measures
focus on both the processes and the outcomes of negotiation
and are based on elements and processes of social perception
(Thompson & Hastie, 1990). Of course, social-psychological
measures may influence economic measures of performance,
and vice versa. The measures are distinguished here because
many research programs have not included both in their analyses, and comparative analyses of behavior are difficult when
investigators use different measures of performance. Apparently inconclusive results and even contradictory findings may
often be traced to different measures of performance. The key
distinction is one of perspective: Negotiators typically do not
perform a full, rational analysis of the negotiation situation
either because the relevant information is not available or because they ignore or distort information (Thompson & Hastie,
1990). Negotiators' perceptions may differ substantially from
objective economic analyses (Thompson & Hastie, in press).

Economic Measures
Economic measures are based on axioms of individual utility
usually attributed to von Neumann and Morgenstern (1947)
and on Bayesian Decision Theory (deGroot, 1970) and represent the most well-formulated specifications of optimal negotiation performance. Economic measures are primarily axiomatic; that is, they focus on the outcomes or products of negotiation and do not specify the processes or methods necessary or
sufficient to yield such outcomes. Three measures of performance are specified by normative bargaining models (Nash,
1953).

517

tors' reservation prices overlap; a negative bargaining zone exists if negotiators' reservation prices do not overlap. When a
positive bargaining zone exists, both negotiators gain from mutual agreement; when a negative bargaining zone exists, negotiators do not profit from mutual agreement. For example, if a
buyer's reservation price, or maximum amount that he or she is
willing to pay for a used car is $700 and the seller's reservation
price, or the minimum amount that he or she is willing to
accept is $600, a positive bargaining zone exists. A negative
bargaining zone would exist if the buyer's reservation price was
$600 and the seller's reservation price was $700.

Creating Resources: Integrative Bargaining


When negotiators' interests are not purely competitive, negotiation involves not just dividing resources (distributive bargaining) but identifying additional value, benefits, and resources (integrative bargaining). The economic definition of
integrative bargaining is precise and refers to whether negotiated outcomes are efficient, or pareto optimal. In empirical
examinations of negotiation behavior, researchers have used
different operationalizations of this economic definition. Typically, negotiators' outcomes are summed to form a measure of
joint profit, which is used as a measure of integration.5 Integrative agreements allow negotiators to achieve greater utility, allow negotiators to avoid potential stalemates, are more stable
over time, foster harmonious relations between parties, and
contribute to the welfare of the broader community (Pruitt &
Rubin, 1986). Pruitt (1983; Pruitt & Rubin, 1986) identified
several strategies for reaching integrative agreements, including
logrolling, in which negotiators make trade-offs between issues
so that each party gets all or most of his or her preferred outcome on important issues but concedes on issues of little importance (Froman & Cohen, 1970). Thompson and Hastie (in
press) noted that negotiators may reach integrative agreements
by identifying compatible issues. Compatible issues are issues
for which negotiators have similar preferences.

Claiming Resources: Distributive Bargaining


All negotiation situations, except those in which parties have
completely compatible interests, involve a distributive compo-

Mutual Agreement
According to most economic bargaining models, negotiators
should reach a mutual agreement if the alternative (known as
the disagreement outcome) is worse than what they could
achieve through agreement with the other party.3 Simply stated,
negotiators should reach an agreement with the other party if it
is in both their interests to do so. The utility of a mutual agreement is determined by the zone of agreement defined by negotiators' reservation prices (Raiffa, 1982). A negotiator's reservation price represents the minimum that he or she will settle for;
anything less represents an outcome that is worse than the disagreement outcome. Simply put, an individual's reservation
price is the point at which he or she can achieve equal or greater
utility by engaging in another course of action (e.g., dealing with
another party or simply maintaining the status quo).4 Bargaining zones may be positive or negative (Raiffa, 1982; Walton &
McKersie, 1965). A positive bargaining zone exists if negotia-

3
This is generally true, but subtleties arise depending upon the particular task. For example, Myerson (1987) proved that impasses occur
even when there are gains to trade when bargainers do not have complete information.
4
Whereas it is generally assumed that reservation prices are stable
and exogenously determined (e.g., they do not change as a result of the
bargaining process), other closely related concepts, such as comparison level for alternatives (Thibaut & Kelley, 1959), minimum necessary
share (Kelley, Beckman, & Fischer, 1967), reservation points (Walton
& McKersie, 1965), and minimum disposition (Ikle & Leites, 1962) are
more labile.
5
Lax and Sebenius (1987) argued that joint profit is not an especially
sensitive measure of integration and developed a measure, called the
integrative quotient, that measures the distance of the outcome from
the pareto optimal frontier. The few researchers who have used this
measure have reported high correlations between this measure and the
typical measure of joint profit (Weingart, Thompson, Bazerman, &
Carroll, 1990).

This document is copyrighted by the American Psychological Association or one of its allied publishers.
This article is intended solely for the personal use of the individual user and is not to be disseminated broadly.

518

LEIGH THOMPSON

nent (Lax & Sebenius, 1985). The distributive component reflects the primary motivation of negotiators: to maximize their
utility.6 A fundamental task for the negotiator is to divide resources in such a manner that he or she keeps most of the
bargaining surplus. The bargaining surplus is the difference
between one's reservation price and the final settlement
(Raiffa, 1982; Walton & McKersie, 1965).
Social-Psychological Measures
Social-psychological measures of negotiation performance
are based on concepts of social perception (Allport, 1955). The
elements of social perception include most aspects of perceivers' social worlds: people, their behaviors, and contexts or
situations (Schneider, Hastorf, & Ellsworth, 1979). The most
important elements of social perception in negotiation are negotiators' perceptions of the bargaining situation, the other party
or bargaining opponent, and themselves (Thompson & Hastie,
1990).
The key principles of social perception can be summarized
as list of principles or features (Schneider et al, 1979; Shaver,
1987). People actively perceive their social world by selecting,
categorizing, interpreting, and inferring information. For example, negotiators do not know what the interests of the other
party are but instead make inferences about their opponent
(Hammond et al, 1975; Harsanyi, 1962). In some sense, negotiators may not be aware of their own interests and values (Fischhoff, Slovic, & Lichtenstein, 1980; March, 1978) but rely on
cues to guide their behavior and choice (Bern, 1967). The perception process is constructive and selective; that is, perception
is influenced by the salience of information and the order in
which information is presented, as well as by perceivers' expectations, knowledge, and experience. Finally, people's perceptions influence their behavior.
The principles of social perception have special implications
for negotiation situations. In most bargaining situations, negotiators do not have the information necessary to perform an objective analysis of the bargaining situation. Consequently, negotiators' perceptions of the bargaining situation may be quite
different from that provided by an objective economic analysis
(Bazerman & Carroll, 1987; Thompson & Hastie, 1990, in
press). Negotiators' perceptions may not only differ from objective analyses but may also differ from those of the other party.
Thus two people involved in the same conflict may have different perceptions about the basis of conflict (Hammond et al.,
1975; Pinkley, 1990). People may perceive a conflict of interest
when in fact none exists, or they may fail to perceive conflict
when it does exist (Hammond, et al., 1975; Thompson & Hastie, in press). A number of cognitive and motivational heuristics
have been found to disturb the accuracy of social information
processing in a variety of domains (Fiske & Taylor, 1984; Markus & Zajonc, 1985), and similar heuristics have been found to
bias judgment and affect behavior in negotiation (Bazerman &
Neale, 1983; Thompson & Hastie, 1990, in press).
Perceptions of the Negotiation Situation
Perceptions of negotiation situations involve the judgments
that people make about the bargaining process and outcome.

Negotiators' judgments of the fairness of the procedures and


outcomes of negotiation and their expectations and perceived
norms concerning appropriate behavior are examples of social
perception in negotiation (Schelling, 1960; Thibaut & Walker,
1975; Tyler, 1986). Negotiators' perceptions of bargaining situations are influenced by their implicit theories of bargaining,
conflict, and negotiation (Carroll & Payne, in press). These
mental structures are typically represented as lists of features or
as temporal sequences of events, or scripts, with specific features, variables, and default values (Abelson, 1976). Bazerman
and Carroll (1987) described several examples of bargaining
scripts, such as "the car-buying script," "the bidding war script,"
and so forth. Negotiators' perceptions of bargaining situation
also include their views of the structure of the bargaining task:
purely competitive, cooperative, or integrative (Thompson &
Hastie, 1990). Pinkley (1990) noted that negotiators' perceptions of conflict are multidimensional and may be characterized by three bipolar dimensions, or "conflict frames": relationship-task, emotional-intellectual, and compromise-win.
Perceptions of the Other Party
Perceptions of one's negotiation opponent include many of
the processes and elements associated with the more general
process of person perception and impression formation. An
important and powerful aspect of person perception is evaluation or liking (Osgood, Suci, & Tannenbaum, 1957). Relevant
dimensions in negotiation include negotiators' liking and attraction to the other party and their perceptions of the other
party's trustworthiness and fairness. Perceptions of the other
party include the trait inferences that negotiators make about
the other party's intelligence, sociability, expertise, skill, ability,
cooperativeness, and competitiveness. Perceptions of the other
party also include the attributions that negotiators make to explain the behavior of their bargaining opponent and the predictions they make about the opponent's future behavior. Perceptions of the other party include negotiators' behavioral intentions, such as their willingness to interact with the other party
in the future. Perceptions of the other party are hypothesized to
be mentally represented in memory as a person or role schema
(Taylor & Crocker, 1981), in which a person node with the label
associated with the opponent is connected to a list of features or
characteristics describing the person (Bazerman & Carroll,
1987; Hastie & Kumar, 1979).
Perceptions of the Self
Perceptions of the self include many of the dimensions relevant to perceptions of the bargaining opponent, such as skill,
cooperativeness, fairness, and so forth. Self-perceptions also
include negotiators' judgments of their own interests, values,
goals, and risk preferences (Fischhoff et al., 1980); social comparisons between the self and the other party (Zechmeister &
6
In most cases, the maximization of utility is assumed to be equivalent to maximizing one's own gains. Most economic models assume
that people seek to maximize their own gain. However, some descriptive approaches do not assume that negotiators' goals are to maximize
self-gain.

This document is copyrighted by the American Psychological Association or one of its allied publishers.
This article is intended solely for the personal use of the individual user and is not to be disseminated broadly.

NEGOTIATION BEHAVIOR AND OUTCOMES


Druckman, 1973); self-evaluations; and self-presentational
concerns (Brown, 1968; Hiltrop & Rubin, 1981; Pruitt & Johnson, 1970). The hypothesized mental structures used to represent self-perceptions are self-schemata (Markus, 1977).
THEORETICAL APPROACHES AND MODELS
Most descriptive theories and approaches of negotiation behavior may be classified into one of three broad domains: individual differences, motivational, and cognitive models (Bazerman & Carroll, 1987; Carroll & Payne, in press; Neale & Northcraft, in press). I now describe each approach and examine
empirical research on economic and social-psychological measures of performance.

Individual Differences Approach


The individual differences approach is an attempt to identify
stable characteristics of people that reliably affect their bargaining behavior and performance. The individual differences
approach does not represent a single, well-established theory.
Rather, it is a collection of disparate hypotheses, predictions,
and low-level theoretical statements. Two general classes of theoretical models characterize the individual difference approach: direct-effect models and contingency models. According to direct-effect models, individual differences directly influence social behavior. The hypothesis that women perceive
conflict differently than do men is an example of a direct-effect
model (Pinkley & Northcraft, 1989). In empirical research, investigators commonly use standardized personality assessment
techniques to measure characteristics of negotiators. Individual
differences that have received the most attention in the negotiation literature include relationship orientation (Machiavellianism; cooperative-competitive orientation); cognitive ability
(cognitive complexity; perspective-taking ability), and gender/
sex role orientation (Rubin & Brown, 1975).7 These characteristics are the primary focus of my analysis.
According to contingency models, negotiation behavior is
determined by specific characteristics of persons and particular features of the situation. Situational factors in contingency
models have included communication modality and the presence or absence of bargaining constituents (Zechmeister &
Druckman, 1973). The hypothesis that a Machiavellian bargainer will take advantage of a non-Machiavellian bargaining
opponent when the interaction occurs face to face, but not
when a barrier obstructs their visual contact, is an example of a
contingency model (Fry, 1985). In the next section, research
studies on the impact of individual differences on economic
and social-psychological measures of performance are discussed.

Economic Criteria
Mutual Agreement
Fry (1985) proposed a contingency model relationship between negotiator Machiavellianism and visual accessibility. Fry
reasoned that "low-Machiavellian" bargainers would be
aroused by and distracted in the presence of "high-" but not
low-Machiavellian bargaining opponents. Fry paired low-low,

519

high-high, and low-high Machiavellian people and allowed


some to bargain face to face; others bargained through a barrier
that obstructed visual contact. Fry hypothesized that the lowhigh pairs negotiating face to face would be most likely to fail to
reach agreement because the low-Machiavellian bargainer
would be susceptible to the strong emotional appeals advanced
by the high-Machiavellian bargainer. The hypothesis was supported. Failure to reach mutual agreement was attributed to the
low-Machiavellian bargainer, who suggested significantly fewer
potential solutions when negotiating face to face with a highMachiavellian bargainer.

Joint Outcomes
Cognitive ability. Integrative bargaining situations often require problem-solving behaviors to maximize joint gain
(Pruitt, 1983; Pruitt & Rubin, 1986). This analysis has led some
researchers to speculate that cognitive reasoning ability may
facilitate the problem-solving behavior necessary to reach integrative outcomes. Pruitt and Lewis (1975) hypothesized that
cognitively complex negotiators entertain more alternative conceptions of bargaining situations and gather and integrate more
information during bargaining. Therefore, cognitively complex
negotiators should be more likely to find mutually beneficial
solutions than would less cognitively complex negotiators. However, this hypothesis was not supported. Neale and Bazerman
(1983) examined another measure of cognitive functioning:
perspective-taking ability (Davis, 1981). They hypothesized
that failure to understand one's bargaining opponent is a primary cause of suboptimal negotiation performance. However,
perspective-taking ability did not affect joint performance, as
measured by the number of issues resolved.
Gender. Other researchers have hypothesized that the sex
composition of the dyad may affect integrative bargaining outcomes (Kimmel, Pruitt, Magenau, Konar-Goldband, & Carnevale, 1980; Rubin & Brown, 1975; Turnbull, Strickland, &
Shaver, 1976). For example, Kimmel et al. (1980) hypothesized
that men seek to maximize their own gains, whereas women
respond to the interpersonal aspect of the situation. However,
there was no support for this prediction.

Individual Outcomes
Machiavellianism. In general, Machiavellian bargainers
claim more resources than do non-Machiavellian bargainers
(Fry, 1985; Huber & Neale, 1986). According to Fry's (1985)
analysis, low-Machiavellian negotiators lose to high-Machiavellian negotiators because they are susceptible to the arousing,
emotional appeals put forth by high-Machiavellian bargainers.
However, Greenhalgh and Neslin (1983) found that Machiavellian bargainers performed worse than non-Machiavellians. The
negotiation task and measures of individual performance used
by Greenhalgh and Neslin differed in many respects from the
ones used by Fry and by Huber and Neale, and so this apparent
7

In many analyses of individual differences, such as Kelley and Stahelski's (1970) study of cooperators and competitors, researchers have
used the Prisoner's Dilemma paradigm, and those studies are not covered in this review.

This document is copyrighted by the American Psychological Association or one of its allied publishers.
This article is intended solely for the personal use of the individual user and is not to be disseminated broadly.

520

LEIGH THOMPSON

inconsistency may be attributable partly to the task. These results also suggest that trait Machiavellianism may not directly
influence negotiation behavior but may instead interact with
situational and task constraints to influence performance.
Cognitive ability. Cognitive reasoning skills have been predicted to increase negotiators' ability to claim resources. For
example, Neale and Bazerman (1983) reasoned that negotiators
with high perspective-taking ability would be able to persuade
their opponents to settle close to their reservation price and
therefore claim most of the bargaining surplus for themselves.
Results supported the hypothesis: Negotiators with high perspective-taking ability earned higher outcomes than did those
with low perspective-taking ability. Neale and Bazerman concluded that bargainers with high perspective-taking ability are
able to learn more information about their opponent, which
allows them to accurately assess their opponent's goals, expectations, and reservation price. However, Greenhalgh and Neslin (1983) found that perspective-taking ability was not predictive of individual utility. Again, the task and the dependent
measure of performance were different from those used by
Neale and Bazerman. The impact of perspective-taking ability
on performance may depend in part on the particular bargaining situation.

Social-Psychological Measures
Investigators of individual differences on social-psychological measures have primarily explored the direct effects of
gender and sex role orientation on perceptions.

Perceptions of the Bargaining Situation


Although there is no clear evidence suggesting that men are
more or less effective negotiators than are women, men may
perceive conflict differently than do women (Gilkey & Greenhalgh, 1984; Pinkley, 1990; Zechmeister & Druckman, 1973).
In general, men are more concerned with winning and maximizing their outcomes, whereas women are more concerned
with maintaining the relationship. For example, Pinkley found
that women were more likely than men to interpret a conflict
situation in relationship terms, whereas men were more concerned with the exchange of resources. Zechmeister and
Druckman (1973) reported that men rated "coming out favorably" as more important than did women.

Perceptions of the Opponent


Women tend to perceive their opponents as similar to themselves, whereas men perceive themselves as fundamentally different from their opponents (Gilkey & Greenhalgh, 1984; Zechmeister & Druckman, 1973). Zechmeister and Druckman
(1973) found that women rated themselves as more similar to
their opponents in terms of attitudes toward racial problems
(the subject of the negotiations) after negotiation than did men;
Gilkey and Greenhalgh (1984) measured negotiators' sex role
orientations and found that "feminine" negotiators were more
empathic than were "masculine" negotiators.

Perceptions of the Self


There is some evidence for sex differences in terms of negotiators' evaluations of their own performance (Kimmel et al.,
1980; Turnbull et al., 1976). Women engage in more self-derogation during negotiation than do men (Kimmel et al, 1980).
Men perceive themselves as more powerful than do women
(Turnbull et al, 1976). Again, although men evaluate themselves more favorably than women evaluate themselves, there is
no clear evidence suggesting that men actually perform better
than women.

Discussion
On the basis of the studies examined in this review, there is
some suggestion that certain individual differences may be related to bargaining behavior. The clearest relationships appear
among cognitive reasoning ability and individual performance
and among gender and perceptions of negotiation. However,
these conclusions are based on a small number of studies and
should therefore be viewed as tentative. A further caveat is that
researchers have not been consistent in their reporting of sex
differences; many report sex difference effects as a secondary
analysis. The implication is that in a large number of studies,
the researchers also performed secondary analysis and did not
find or did not report null results for gender.
The scant number of clear relationships observed in this review is consistent with Hamner's (1980) conclusion that there
are few significant relationships between personality and negotiation outcomes. Some researchers have even stated this more
forcefully: "From what is known now, it does not appear that
there is any single personality type or characteristic that is directly and clearly linked to success in negotiation" (Lewicki &
Litterer, 1985, p. 276). However, this conclusion is incomplete
and overly simplistic. It is only reasonable to assume that individual characteristics influence bargaining behavior. People exhibit a great deal of consistency across situations, and this suggests that personality is an important influence on social behavior (Staw & Ross, 1985).
So, why do individual differences not appear to play a central
role in experimental investigations of negotiation? There are
several possible explanations (Lewicki & Litterer, 1985). First,
individual differences are often measured with a homogeneous
sample of subjects, usually college students. The failure to observe relationships between individual differences and bargaining behavior may be attributed partially to the narrow range of
individual differences within subject populations (Hamner,
1980). A second possibility concerns the assessment of individual differences. Most individual differences are assessed by
means of paper-and-pencil measures. However, the key dependent variables of interest in negotiation are typically behavioral
measures of performance. Given the inconsistency between attitudes and behavior and the unreliability of self-report measures, behavioral assessment of individual differences may
yield more reliable and consistent relationships with social behavior (Staw & Ross, 1985). A third explanation is that other
factors may outweigh the more subtle effects of personality in
bargaining (Davis-Blake & Pfeffer, 1989). Monson, Hesley, and
Chernick (1982) suggested that personality is more predictive

This document is copyrighted by the American Psychological Association or one of its allied publishers.
This article is intended solely for the personal use of the individual user and is not to be disseminated broadly.

NEGOTIATION BEHAVIOR AND OUTCOMES

of behavior in ambiguous situations than in settings in which


there are strong prescriptions for behavior. Fourth, personality
may not exert main effects on negotiation performance but
rather may interact in complex ways with situational factors
and characteristics of the particular task (Fry, 1985; Harnett,
Cummings, & Hughes, 1968). This alternative suggests that a
contingency approach may have more predictive validity than a
direct-effect model. Fifth, the absence of a comprehensive
theory relating individual differences to negotiation behavior
makes it difficult to identify clear relationships. Finally, it may
be that individual characteristics of bargainers exert their impact on prenegotiation behaviorsthat is, factors that predispose people to avoid or engage in negotiation, rather than on
bargaining behavior per se (Emmons & Diener, 1986). In this
sense, individual differences act as an important self-selection
process in negotiation that is not captured by extant measures
of negotiation behavior and performance.

Motivational Approaches
Motivational models of bargaining behavior examine the influence of aspirations and goals on bargaining behavior and
outcomes. Two general theoretical approaches have developed
within this broad area. According to one approach, aspiration
is a continuous, unidimensional concept ranging from low to
high (Hamner & Harnett, 1975; Siegel & Fouraker, 1960). Aspiration is denned in terms of utility theory, and a negotiator's
aspiration level is represented as a position on his or her bargaining utility function (Siegel, 1957). In general, the member
of the bargaining pair who has a higher level of aspiration obtains a larger share of the joint profit (Siegel & Fouraker, 1960).
Negotiators with high aspirations make smaller concessions,
make larger demands, take longer to reach agreement, and earn
higher profits than do negotiators with low aspirations (Siegel &
Fouraker, 1960).
The second approach differs from aspiration-level theories
by positing that bargaining goals are not unidimensional and
that the maximization of gain is not the primary goal of bargaining (Blake & Mouton, 1962; Pruitt & Rubin, 1986). According to the Dual Concern Model (Pruitt & Rubin, 1986), negotiators' goals are determined by two independent factors: negotiators' concern for themselves and their concern for the other
party. This approach also differs from aspiration-level theories
in that utility functions are not continuous but are modeled as
discrete functions. In the model, concern is either high or low
for each factor (self; other party), and the resulting product is a
four-cell matrix specifying the strategies associated with each
goal orientation. A key prediction of the Dual Concern Model
is that negotiators who have a high degree of concern for themselves coupled with a high degree of concern for the other party
will reach more integrative outcomes than will negotiators who
are concerned only with maximizing their own outcomes, negotiators who are concerned only with the other party, and negotiators who are not concerned with themselves or the other party.

Economic Criteria
Mutual Agreement
A key prediction of aspiration-level models is that high aspirations block opportunities for mutual agreement and increase

521

the likelihood of an impasse. Two separate lines of evidence


support this prediction: studies of constituency pressure and
explicit goal setting.
Constituency pressure. The first line of support is based on
studies in which researchers examined aspirations indirectly,
typically by manipulating the amount of constituency pressure
on bargainers (Carnevale, Pruitt, & Britton, 1979). The hypothesis is that negotiators who represent a larger group or constituency feel accountable to their constituency and pressured to
meet their goals and, consequently, adopt higher aspiration levels and remain firmer in their aspirations than do negotiators
who are not under constituency pressure (Neale, 1984; Pruitt &
Lewis, 1975; Tjosvold, 1977). Tjosvold (1977) found that negotiators under constituency pressure to maximize gains were
more likely to reach impasses than were those whose constituencies encouraged them to reach a fair outcome. In a similar
study, Neale (1984) told some negotiators that their outcomes
would be determined by evaluations of their performance that
were made by constituency members (high constituency-pressure group); others were not told that their outcomes were contingent on constituency evaluations (low constituency-pressure
group). Impasses occurred more often when constituency pressure was high.
Explicit goal setting. The second line of support is based on
studies in which researchers attempted to manipulate negotiators' aspirations by providing them with a specific goal or target value to achieve. Most of this research has been conducted
using the experimental bargaining market paradigm (cf. Bazerman, Magliozzi, & Neale, 1985). In experimental bargaining
markets, several buyers and sellers interact under the instruction that they should complete as many profitable negotiations
as possible in a fixed amount of time. Negotiators are given a
specific goal to achieve in the negotiation. This is typically
operationalized by instructing negotiators to meet or exceed a
given payoff level. In general, negotiators who are given specific, challenging, or demanding goals complete fewer successful transactions than do those not given challenging goals (Bazerman et al, 1985; Huber & Neale, 1987; Neale & Bazerman,
1985a, 1985b; Neale, Northcraft, & Barley, 1988). One explanation of this finding is that negotiators with high aspirations
have more unsuccessful transactions (i.e, reach more impasses)
than do negotiators with lower aspirations. However, an equally
plausible interpretation is that negotiators with high aspirations
do not make as many attempts to negotiate as do those with low
aspirations, perhaps because negotiators with high aspirations
spend a longer time negotiating (Neale & Bazerman, 1985b).
Unfortunately, the number of transactions attempted, the number actually completed, and the time to complete them were
not reported; so it is not possible to determine whether high
aspirations are related to higher impasse rates or simply fewer
attempts to negotiate. If high aspirations lead to more frequent
impasses, a central question concerns the mechanism involved:
Specifically, do high aspirations prevent negotiators from discovering viable agreements, or are negotiators with high aspirations more reluctant to agree to proposals that barely exceed
their reservation price (cf. Kelley et al, 1967)? Stated another
way, do bargainers become committed to positions and refuse
to move away from their demands, or are bargainers reluctant
to adopt feasible solutions?

This document is copyrighted by the American Psychological Association or one of its allied publishers.
This article is intended solely for the personal use of the individual user and is not to be disseminated broadly.

522

LEIGH THOMPSON

Dual Concern Model. The Dual Concern Model (Pruitt &


Rubin, 1986) suggests that the relationship between aspiration
and bargaining outcomes is more complex and requires consideration of negotiators' concern for the other party in addition to
their own level of aspiration. According to the Dual Concern
Model, high concern for oneself coupled with low concern for
the other party increases the likelihood of an impasse because
both parties will engage in contentious behavior rather than the
problem-solving behavior hypothesized to be necessary for integrative agreement. In contrast, negotiators who have high aspirations coupled with concern for the other party should be
more likely to engage in problem solving that results in mutual
agreement (Pruitt & Rubin, 1986). The empirical evidence
bearing on this hypothesis is mixed. Two studies have found
clear support for the model's predictions (Carnevale & Lawler,
1986; Pruitt & Lewis, 1975). For example, Pruitt and Lewis
(1975) manipulated negotiators' aspirations by instructing
them to meet or exceed either a high or a low payoff; they
manipulated concern for the other party by instructing negotiators to adopt either an individualistic or a cooperative orientation. Negotiators with high aspirations and individualistic orientations were most likely to reach an impasse. Two direct tests
of the model were equivocal: The effects were in the predicted
direction, but not significant (Ben Yoav & Pruitt, 1984a, 1984b).
One study did not support the predictions of the model (Pruitt,
Carnevale, BenYoay, Nochajski, & Van Slyck, 1982).
Whereas "concern" for the other party per se does not consistently influence the likelihood of impasse, negotiators do
appear to be sensitive to overt attempts by the other party
to exploit or manipulate them. For example, Cruder (1971)
found that negotiators who bargained with "exploitative" opponentspeople who misrepresented their reservation price
were more likely to reach an impasse than were negotiators who
bargained with "fair" opponents. Tjosvold (1978) similarly
found that negotiators who interacted with a partner who indicated an intention to control rather than collaborate were more
likely to reach an impasse.
Joint Outcomes
Explicit goal setting. The research on explicit goal setting is
derived from aspiration-level theories (Siegel & Fouraker,
1960). In general, higher aspirations are predicted to lead to
greater joint profit. The reasoning is that negotiators with high
aspirations are more likely to explore ways of maximizing their
outcomes because simple compromises do not satisfy their
goals, whereas negotiators with low aspirations are more likely
to settle for obvious solutions yielding low joint payoffs (Kelley
& Schenitzki, 1972). In some experiments, negotiators are given
a specific payofflevel or target value to achieve, others are given
lower targets, and a control group that is not given a target value
or goal instruction is often included. In general, negotiators
with high target levels are more likely to reach integrative agreements (Bazerman et al., 1985; Huber & Neale, 1986,1987; McAlister, Bazerman & Fader, 1986; Neale & Bazerman, 1985b;
Neale & Northcraft, 1986; Neale, Northcraft, & Early, 1988;
Scholz, Fleischer, & Bentpup, 1982). However, there is an important qualification. Explicit goals increase the profitability
of negotiation outcomes as well as the time required to com-

plete negotiation transactions, which results in fewer transactions completed within a fixed amount of time (Neale & Bazerman, 1985b). Thus a curvilinear relationship between goal difficulty and total profitability exists when total profitability is
the product of the number and the value of completed transactions. Again, this is an instance in which apparently contradictory findings may be traced to different measures of performance.
Dual Concern Model. According to the Dual Concern
Model, the relationship between goals and outcomes is more
complex and requires consideration of negotiators' attitudes toward the other party (Pruitt & Rubin, 1986). The prediction is
that high aspirations will increase joint outcomes only when
the negotiator is concerned with the interests of the other party.
The first empirical examination bearing on this hypothesis (although not intended as a test of the model) was a study in which
negotiators were instructed either to maximize their own gains
(individualistic orientation) or to maximize joint gains (team
orientation; Kelley & Schenitzki, 1972). Furthermore, negotiators were told that their monetary payoffs would depend either
on their own outcomes or on the joint amount of resources
achieved. The paradoxical result was that negotiators with an
individualistic orientation achieved higher joint outcomes than
did those with a team orientation. However, this effect was
obtained only when negotiators communicated through written messages; the effect disappeared when negotiators communicated face to face. Schulz and Pruitt (1978) hypothesized that
negotiators with a team orientation would reach higher joint
outcomes if given an opportunity to divulge information about
their interestssomething they were not allowed to do in Kelley and Schenitzki's study. Negotiators were instructed to adopt
either an individualistic or a team orientation; some pairs communicated freely, and others were restricted to truthful information exchange. In contrast to Kelley and Schenitzki's finding, and in support of the Dual Concern Model, negotiators
with a team orientation achieved higher joint profits than did
pairs with individualistic orientations; the communication
conditions did not affect joint profitability.
In subsequent studies, Pruitt and his colleagues have tested
predictions of the Dual Concern Model by independently manipulating negotiators' concern for themselves and concern for
the other party. They manipulated concern for the self by informing negotiators that they were accountable to a larger constituency (Ben-Yoav & Pruitt, 1984b) or by providing negotiators
with an explicit goal to reach (Ben-%av & Pruitt, 1984a). They
operationalized concern for the other party by providing negotiators with a small gift (Carnevale & Isen, 1986; Pruitt et al.,
1982), leading some negotiators to expect cooperative future
interaction with their opponent (Ben-Yoav & Pruitt, 1984a,
1984b), or by encouraging negotiators to adopt a cooperative
orientation (Carnevale & Lawler, 1986). The prediction that
high concern for oneself coupled with high concern for the
other party leads to higher joint outcomes has generally been
supported (Ben-Yoav & Pruitt, 1984a, 1984b).
Individual Outcomes

Aspirations also improve distributive bargaining behavior.


Bargainers who have specific, explicit goals achieve higher indi-

This document is copyrighted by the American Psychological Association or one of its allied publishers.
This article is intended solely for the personal use of the individual user and is not to be disseminated broadly.

NEGOTIATION BEHAVIOR AND OUTCOMES

vidual outcomes than do bargainers not given explicit goals to


achieve (Huber & Neale, 1986,1987; McAlister et al, 1986)."
One complication with providing negotiators with an explicit
goal is that the goal may not be adopted by the subject or the
goal may provide clues to subjects about the structure of the
negotiation task. Simply put, a negotiator who is told to maximize joint gain rather than individual gain may realize that the
experimenter's game does not contain a fixed amount of resources. Similarly, the bargainer who is instructed to try to earn
a large amount of profits may similarly (and accurately) reason
that there may be more resources available than a fixed-sum
situation would dictate. One solution to these cuing problems is
to measure goals, rather than to manipulate goals. For example,
Hamner and Harnett (1975) measured negotiators' aspirations
and found that bargainers with higher aspirations were more
successful than were those with lower aspirations.

Social Psychological Measures


A small number of researchers have examined the implications of constituency pressure on negotiators' perceptions of
bargaining. In general, constituency pressure is hypothesized
to increase negotiators' aspirations (Carnevale et al, 1979).

Perceptions of the Bargaining Situation


Negotiators under constituency pressure view bargaining situations as more competitive and less productive than do bargainers who do not represent a constituency or at least do not
feel pressured to maximize profits for a constituency (Druckman & Zechmeister, 1973; Tjosvold, 1977; Zechmeister &
Druckman, 1973). Negotiators whose constituencies pressure
them to maximize individual profits report less willingness to
compromise, fewer efforts to be just, and fewer feelings of generosity than do negotiators whose constituencies are committed
to "justice" (Tjosvold, 1977). Negotiators who confer with their
constituency to formulate arguments before negotiation are
more likely to view negotiation as a win-lose, competitive enterprise than are negotiators who spend time with members of
the other party before negotiation (Druckman & Zechmeister,
1973). Thus constituency pressure in the form of sanctions and
evaluations reduces the bargainer's perception of personal control and satisfaction with the bargaining process, but it does not
necessarily hinder the quality of the economic outcomes and
may even improve performance when constituents provide negotiators with specific goals to achieve.

Perceptions of the Other Party


Tjosvold (1977) found that negotiators under pressure from
their constituencies to maximize gains perceived themselves as
more dissimilar to their opponents than did negotiators who
were not under pressure to maximize gains.

523

points. Thus high aspirations may improve individual and joint


outcomes in some situations but lead to an unnecessary impasse in other situations. Economic bargaining theory cannot
account for these empirical findings because aspirations or target values are theoretically independent of reservation prices,
and it is reservation price that determines the size of the bargaining zone and hence the likelihood of impasse. The empirical evidence suggests, however, that aspiration values and reservation price are not independent and that increasing the negotiators' target value also affects their reservation price. This of
course suggests that reservation price is not exogenously determined but a psychological value. The most likely psychological
explanation of this relationship is the anchoring and adjustment heuristic in which one estimates a value or a position on a
dimension by starting with some initial value (anchor) and then
adjusting it (Tversky & Kahneman, 1974). Typically, adjustment is insufficient (e.g, the judgment of the new position is too
close to the initial value).
The primary theoretical concerns with motivational approaches are the operationalization and measurement of aspirations. The common method used to examine aspiration is to
instruct negotiators to meet or exceed an explicit, fixed payoff
level. However, experimenter-provided goals may not act as an
aspiration as intended but may instead provide subjects with
unintentional information about the structure of the bargaining task (e.g, a variable-sum structure). Furthermore, there is
typically no assessment to indicate whether bargainers accept
the experimenter-provided goals. Another problem is that negotiators' goals may change during the course of bargaining
(Werner & Tietz, 1982), yet in empirical analyses researchers
have assumed goals are stable throughout bargaining.
The Dual Concern Model represents a dramatic shift from
traditional bargaining theories that view aspiration as a continuous, unidimensional concept in which the primary objective
attributed to negotiators is that of maximizing individual gain.
A key concern with the Dual Concern Model is the experimental incentives and the theoretical concepts. Subjects are typically instructed to earn as many points as they can in a negotiation task in which they know only their own preferences. This
aspect of the experiment is designed to induce a high concern
for oneself. Then subjects are told that they should expect to
interact with the other party in the future (Ben%av & Pruitt,
1984a, 1984b) or are given a small gift from the experimenter
(Pruitt et al, 1982). This aspect of the experiment is designed to
heighten negotiators' concern for the other party. However, it is
unclear whether this manipulation actually produces greater
concern for the other party; no manipulation checks are reported. Furthermore, even if subjects are motivated to care
about the other party, it is not clear how they transform their
motivation into behaviors and strategies, given that they do not
know the interests of the other party.
A more serious concern with the model is that the experimental manipulations used to induce concern for the other party

Discussion
Aspirations play an important role in determining bargaining behavior and performance. The research findings are clear
but complex: Higher aspirations increase profitability but decrease negotiators' willingness to concede from their target

A methodological complexity is the fact that the higher joint outcomes obtained in the high-aspiration conditions are confounded with
the measure of individual profit. A pure measure of individual profit
would require a comparison of outcomes within each bargaining pair.

This document is copyrighted by the American Psychological Association or one of its allied publishers.
This article is intended solely for the personal use of the individual user and is not to be disseminated broadly.

524

LEIGH THOMPSON

also contain unintentional clues about the variable-sum structure of the task. Simply put, if negotiators are told to maximize
joint outcomes, they may logically conclude that the task is not
a fixed-sum game. Thus the goal orientation is confounded
with information about the structure of the task.
The model also has difficulty accounting for how negotiators
who have individualistic orientations (e.g., no or little concern
for the other party) reach integrative outcomes (Bazerman et al,
1985; Kelley, 1966; Kimmel et al, 1980; Thompson & Hastie, in
press). According to the Dual Concern Model, integrative outcomes are reached through joint problem-solving in which both
parties are concerned with each other's welfare. However, high
joint outcomes may be reached without problem-solving efforts, through the efforts of each party to pursue his or her own
interests (Kelley & Schenitzki, 1972). The model has similar
difficulty explaining how negotiators who are presumably
highly concerned with their opponents' welfare (e.g., partners in
romantic relationships) fail to reach mutually beneficial outcomes (Fry, Firestone, & Williams, 1983).
Finally, the model is restrictive and difficult to generalize.
Concern for oneself and another is modeled in an overly simplistic fashion: either high or low. It is possible that negotiators
have more complex goals, such as a desire to reach a fair outcome (Loewenstein, Thompson, & Bazerman, 1989; Schelling,
1960). These alternative goals are not captured by the model.
Furthermore, the model's predictions are limited to situations
in which negotiators have the same bargaining orientation. It is
not clear what predictions would be made for situations in
which negotiators have different motivational orientations.

locations, and it diminishes sharply with the distance from the


source of activation (Anderson, 1985). An executive monitor
controls the information-processing system by operating on
goals and plans organized into a control structure hierarchy.
The larger information-processing system comprises a series of
component locations that are referred to as independent memories. The information-processing system tends to behave economically to accomplish it goals by expending a minimum
amount of time and processing resources. This tendency gives
rise to heuristics or cognitive shortcuts that facilitate information processing but often produce inaccurate judgments and
biases (Tversky & Kahneman, 1974).
Researchers have enhanced theoretical development of the
cognitive approach by identifying the judgment tasks that negotiators face (Carroll & Payne, in press; Thompson & Hastie,
1990), examining negotiators' mental representations of the
task and their opponent (Carroll, Bazerman, & Maury, 1988;
Pinkley, 1990; Thompson & Hastie, in press), examining the
accuracy of negotiators' judgments (Bazerman & Carroll, 1987;
Thompson & Hastie, in press), and exploring the relationship
between judgment and behavior (Thompson & Hastie, in
press). Methodologies, such as recall and think-aloud measures
are used to examine information processing and judgment in
negotiation (Carroll et al, 1988; Thompson & Hastie, 1990, in
press). A number of judgment errors have been identified in
negotiation (Bazerman & Neale, 1983; Thompson & Hastie,
1990, in press), and heuristic information processes similar to
those identified in individual decision-making tasks are hypothesized to guide social judgment and behavior in negotiation.

Cognitive Approach
According to the cognitive approach, negotiation is a complex decision-making task in which negotiators are faced with
alternative courses of action, and choices among behavioral alternatives are determined by negotiators' judgments of the task
(Bazerman & Carroll, 1987). Negotiators construct mental representations of the negotiation situation and their opponent,
and their behavior is influenced by their judgments of the other
party, their own bargaining role, and the bargaining situation.
The basis of the cognitive approach is information-processing theory (Bazerman & Carroll, 1987; Carroll & Payne, in
press). Cognitive information-processing theory is a theory of
the mind of the individual actor. The essential elements of the
information-processing approach are presented as a list of general principles briefly described here (see Anderson, 1985, and
Hastie, 1986, for more extensive treatments). The fundamental
material of the information-processing approach is information. Information is typically represented as a list of features;
concepts are represented as nodes labeled with a word or a
phrase, and relations between idea nodes are symbolized theoretically as links in a network. Information is stored in memory
in one of several alternative structures. The most common is a
list of concepts, wherein each concept is linked to one or two
adjacent nodes. Information is available according to simple
spreading-activation principles. Activation spreads from a
currently active location in a knowledge structure to other
nearby locations; the spread is rapid, and the amount of activation of proximate locations is inversely related to the number of

Economic Criteria
Mutual Agreement
Neale and Bazerman (1985a) derived a prediction from prospect theory to examine whether a negotiator's mental representation of the task, or cognitive frame, influences bargaining
behavior. According to prospect theory (Kahneman & Tversky,
1979), people have different utility functions for gain and loss,
and objectively identical decision tasks produce different
choices among identical options when the reference point defining gain and loss is altered. The hypothesis was that negotiators who were risk averse would be more likely to make concessions to avoid an impasse; in contrast, risk-seeking negotiators
would be less likely to make concessions and more likely to risk
an impasse. Neale and Bazerman examined two factors that
they thought would affect risk aversion: the framing of negotiation payoffs and negotiators' judgments of the probability that
their offer would be selected by a neutral third party under
final offer arbitration. They manipulated reference points by
instructing some negotiators to "maximize gain" and providing
negotiators with payoff schedules containing positive numbers;
negotiators with a negative frame were instructed to "minimize
loss" and were provided with a payoff schedule containing negative numbers. Of course, the negotiation tasks were objectively
identical. Neale and Bazerman further hypothesized that negotiators who believed that an arbitrator would choose their offer
under final offer arbitration would be less likely to compromise

This document is copyrighted by the American Psychological Association or one of its allied publishers.
This article is intended solely for the personal use of the individual user and is not to be disseminated broadly.

NEGOTIATION BEHAVIOR AND OUTCOMES


and more likely to risk reaching an impasse than would negotiators who were less confident that their offer would be selected.
They therefore instructed half of the negotiators in their sample
about the overconfidence judgment error; the remaining half
were not given training. As predicted, negotiators who viewed
negotiation in terms of minimizing loss and who believed that
their offer would be chosen in the case of final offer arbitration
were more likely to reach an impasse. Neale and Bazerman
concluded that framing affects negotiation behavior in a manner similar to that observed in individual decision-making
tasks.

525

party places the same importance on, or has the same priorities
for, the negotiation issues as they do when in fact negotiators
have different priorities is referred to as the fixed-pie error (Bazerman & Neale, 1983; Thompson & Hastie, in press). Thompson and Hastie (1990, in press) measured negotiators' perceptions several times during negotiation and found that judgment
accuracy was strongly related to negotiation outcomes: negotiators who made accurate priority and compatibility judgments
attained higher joint outcomes than did those who made fixedpie and incompatibility errors. The conclusion was that negotiators' perceptions influence their behavior and the quality of
their outcomes.

Joint Outcomes
Framing of negotiation payoffs.
Predictions derived from
prospect theory have also been tested to examine joint profitability in negotiation (Bazerman et al, 1985; Neale & Bazerman, 1985a; Neale, Huber & Northcraft, 1987; Neale & Northcraft, 1986). The prediction is that negotiators with a positive
frame (who view negotiation in terms of maximizing gain)
should be risk averse, whereas those with a negative frame (who
view negotiation in terms of minimizing loss) should be risk
seeking. Risk aversion should lead to more concessionary behavior and higher joint outcomes; risk seeking should lead to
more contentious behavior and more impasses, resulting in
lower joint outcomes. This prediction has received support in a
number of studies (Bazerman et al, 1985; Neale & Bazerman,
1985a; Neale et al, 1987; Neale & Northcraft, 1986). However,
there is an important qualification. Most of this research is
based on market simulations in which negotiators make a number of transactions. Positively framed negotiators complete
more transactions than do negatively framed negotiators, which
results in greater total profit; however, negatively framed negotiators earn more per transaction (Bazerman et al, 1985; Neale &
Bazerman, 1985b; Neale et al, 1987; Neale & Northcraft, 1986).
Again, this is an example of how different measures of performance appear to yield inconsistent results.
Judgment accuracy. Thompson and Hastie (1990, in press)
hypothesized that misperceptions of the other party are a primary cause of suboptimal outcomes in negotiation. They reasoned that a key judgment that negotiators make concerns their
perception of the other party's interests and the structure of the
bargaining task (e.g., purely competitive or integrative; Thompson & Hastie, 1990, in press). Thompson and Hastie identified
two critical judgments that negotiators make about the other
party's interests: compatibility judgments and priority judgments. When negotiators make compatibility judgments, they
determine whether all or only some of their interests are incompatible with those of the other party. The tendency to perceive
conflict when none exists is referred to as incompatability error
(Thompson & Hastie, in press). Priority judgments concern
negotiators' perceptions of the other party's evaluation of the
relative importance of the to-be-negotiated issues. If the two
parties have different evaluations of the relative importance of
the issues, then an integrative solution is possible (Pruitt &
Rubin, 1986; Raiffa, 1982). Simply put, when negotiators have
different values, each has something to offer that is relatively
less valuable to them than to those with whom they are bargaining. The tendency for negotiators to assume that the other

Claiming Resources
Framing of negotiation payoffs. Buyers tend to outperform
sellers in symmetric bargaining tasks (Bazerman et al, 1985;
Eliashberg, LaTour, Rangaswamy, & Stern, 1986; Huber &
Neale, 1986; McAlister et al, 1986; Neale & Northcraft, 1986).
This effect is perplexing because the roles of "buyer" and
"seller" in these laboratory tasks are objectively identical; neither party has an inherent advantage. Neale et al. (1987) hypothesized that this phenomenon may be interpreted as a framing effect. They reasoned that buyers view negotiation in terms
of losing resources or giving up something, whereas sellers view
negotiation in terms of gaining resources. This interpretation,
in light of prospect theory's prediction that people have different utility functions for gain and loss, suggests that buyers are
risk seeking and sellers are risk averse. Neale et al. hypothesized
that the more risk seeking the negotiator is, the higher the premium he or she would demand for a negotiated settlement and
the greater amount of resources he or she would claim. To test
their hypothesis, Neale et al. had some negotiators complete a
traditional negotiation task involving buyer and seller roles; the
other subjects completed a task that was objectively identical
except that the context was changed: the labels buyer and seller
were changed to mythical names that presumably would not
lead to different gain/loss frames. When role information was
absent (mythical roles), task characteristics influenced mean
profit per transaction: Negatively framed bargainers outperformed positively framed bargainers. However, when role information was present (buyer-seller roles), role information influenced mean profit per transaction: Buyers outperformed
sellers. The conclusion was that there are multiple sources of
framing bias in negotiation: those that are responses to task
demands and those that are contextually elicited by roles.
Judgment accuracy. Thompson and Hastie (1990, in press)
hypothesized that the accuracy of negotiators' perceptions of
the other party's interests should play a large role in determining outcomes. The reasoning was that negotiators who make
inaccurate judgments about the other party assume that the
other party's interests are completely opposed to their own, and
they therefore overlook opportunities for mutual gain and settle
for suboptimal solutions. In a series of studies, the relationship
between the accuracy of priority and compatibility judgments
and bargaining performance was examined. A strong relationship between judgment accuracy and payoffs emerged: Negotiators who made more accurate judgments about the other party's
interests earned higher individual payoffs.

This document is copyrighted by the American Psychological Association or one of its allied publishers.
This article is intended solely for the personal use of the individual user and is not to be disseminated broadly.

526

LEIGH THOMPSON

Social Psychological Criteria


Perceptions of the Bargaining Situation
Bazerman and Neale (1983) speculated that negotiators bring
a fixed-pie, or win-lose, perception to negotiation. They further argued that the fixed-pie perception represents a faulty
judgment when negotiation situations are truly integrative or
provide opportunity for joint gain. Thompson and Hastie
(1990) measured negotiators' perceptions immediately before, 5
min into, and immediately after an integrative negotiation task.
The majority of negotiators entered negotiation with a fixed-pie
perception of the task. As the negotiation progressed, some
negotiators learned that the other party's interests were not completely opposed to their own. However, misperceptions after
negotiation were still substantial. For example, after negotiation, most negotiators (85%) failed to realize that they had interests on one issue that were perfectly compatible with those of
the other party, and a majority (68%) had a fixed-pie perception.
The conclusion is that negotiators bring a win-lose, competitive
expectation to negotiation that is remarkably resistant to
change.
Perceptions of the Opponent
Negotiators tend to perceive the other party as completely
dissimilar to themselves. For example, negotiators expect the
other parties' interests to be completely opposed to their own
(Thompson & Hastie, 1990). This expectation persists even
after bargains in which negotiators have some interests that are
completely compatible with those of the other party (Thompson & Hastie, in press). The existence of the fixed-pie and incompatibility perceptions suggests that negotiators often use
their own interests to make an inference about those of the
other party. The typical inference process is to assume that the
other party's interests are completely opposed to one's own.
A complementary psychological process was suggested by
Oskamp (1965) and Stillinger and Ross (1987). Stillinger and
Ross hypothesized that negotiators reason that proposals offered by their opponent must be less advantageous for themselves and more advantageous to the adversary than they appear to be. Simply put, negotiators reason that whatever is good
for their opponent must be bad for themselves. This suggests
that proposals and offers suggested by opponents may be devalued in negotiation. To examine this hypothesis, Stillinger and
Ross had some negotiators rate the value of an opponent's concession before it was actually made; others rated the value after
the concession was offered. Negotiators engaged in reactive devaluation: They devalued the concessions after they were offered by their opponent.
The Thompson-Hastie analysis differs from the StillingerRoss effect in terms of the locus of the inference process.
Thompson and Hastie (1990, in press) posited that negotiators
make inferences about their opponent's interests on the basis of
their own values; Stillinger and Ross (1987) suggested that negotiators make inferences about their own values on the basis of
those articulated by the other party. Are these inference processes contradictory? I believe that both processes characterize
social inference in negotiation and that the occurrence of each
process depends on the strength, clarity, and commitment of

negotiators' values and the other party's interests. When negotiators are uncertain about their own interests or have conflicting
interests, then reactive devaluation processes most likely characterize bargaining behavior. However, when negotiators' own
interests are available and clear, then fixed-pie and incompatibility inferences characterize bargaining behavior. The important implication is that both inference processes lead to the
perception of conflict between parties.
Perceptions of the Self
Self-serving evaluations. Negotiators make self-serving attributions and evaluations in bargaining (Brandstatter, Kette, &
Sageder, 1982; Turnbull et al, 1976). For example, negotiators
who are unable to reach mutually acceptable agreements blame
their opponent for the failure, whereas they usually attribute
success to themselves (Brandstatter et al, 1982). This pattern of
results is consistent with research in other social domains that
suggests that people make self-serving attributions for success
and failure (McFarland & Ross, 1982) and make self-enhancing
downward social comparisons (Wills, 1981).
Overconfidence. Overconfidence in judgment is closely related to self-serving processes and is pervasive in bargaining.
For example, Neale and Bazerman (1983) examined negotiators' perceptions that an arbitrator would favor their proposal
over the proposal suggested by their adversary. The majority of
negotiators believed that an arbitrator would favor their proposal. Neale and Bazerman reasoned that negotiators were
overconfident when they made probability estimates greater
than 50% because, on average, negotiators should expect that
their offer will be selected by a neutral third party about half of
the time.
Discussion
The cognitive approach is especially appealing because it is
an attempt to predict behavior across a broad range of people
and situations. Another advantage of the approach is that it
provides methodological tools, such as recall and think-aloud
measures that have proved useful in identifying constructs,
measuring variables, and exploring implications of the approach. Finally, the cognitive approach provides conceptual
links to other social-cognitive theories at different levels of scientific analysis. The approach, however, is not complete. It
shares all of the disadvantages associated with more general
cognitive information-processing models (cf. Hastie, 1986) and
also has some unique shortcomings. First, the cognitive approach is still in its infancy. Although this is not a disadvantage
per se, a coherent, internally consistent, falsifiable theory of the
negotiator has not been developed, and the approach does not
readily suggest testable implications. Second, the current application of methodological tools is incomplete. Research methodologies often fall short of a thorough information-processing
analysis (Carroll & Payne, in press). Judgment processes and
products are often inferred on basis of negotiation outcomes
rather through direct examination. Some exceptions are
Carroll et al.'s (1988) think-aloud study of decision-making processes in competitive situations and Thompson and Hastie's
(1990, in press) think-aloud analysis of judgment error in negoti-

This document is copyrighted by the American Psychological Association or one of its allied publishers.
This article is intended solely for the personal use of the individual user and is not to be disseminated broadly.

NEGOTIATION BEHAVIOR AND OUTCOMES


ation. The aim of information-processing approach is to obtain
a "picture" of the negotiator's mindto understand its processes and products. In order to accomplish this, it is necessary
to move away from comparing negotiators' behavior with predictions derived from normative models and, instead, focus on
the cognitive processes of negotiators. This approach, of course,
requires that researchers include social-psychological measures
in their investigations of bargaining behavior to examine negotiators' perceptions.
A unique set of problems arises from the imperfect mapping
of cognitive information processing theory onto the study of
negotiation. One limitation of the cognitive approach is the
impoverished treatment of motivational factors. Although concepts of utility, aspiration, and goals are acknowledged, their
representation and relationship to judgment and decisions are
not well specified. This task becomes even more complicated
when models posit the existence of goals more complex than
simple economic utility maximization.
An implicit assumption of the cognitive approach is that
many of the judgment phenomena that occur in individual
decision-making tasks may be extended to the interpersonal
task of negotiation. Consequently, many of the phenomena
studied have been those explored in individual judgment tasks.
This reasoning however, constrains the scope of theoretical
analysis. In extending individual judgment phenomena to negotiation tasks, researchers often ignore the interactive nature of
negotiation. It is assumed that negotiators' perceptions and
judgments are relatively static and do not change as a function
of the influence of the other party. Furthermore, such assumptions often constrain the focus of analysis: Individual judgment
phenomena that may be easily extended to negotiation situations are most often studied.
Finally, the identification of judgment errors and biases is
problematic. Judgment errors and biases are hypothesized to be
the major cause of ineffective negotiation behavior and suboptimal outcomes. An analysis of judgment error and bias requires
consideration of three elements: a judgment, a standard or a
criterion of truth, and a rule specifying a correspondence relation between the judgment and the criterion (Hastie & Rasinski, 1988). It has been hypothesized that negotiators ignore
relevant information and distort otherwise accurate information (Carroll et al., 1988). However, it is also possible that negotiators may not have the necessary information to make accurate
judgments of the other party because of insufficient or deceptive information exchange (Pruitt & Lewis, 1975; Thompson, in
press-a). Under such circumstances, it is not appropriate to
view inaccuracy as indicative of bias (Funder, 1987).
CONCLUSIONS

Theoretical Issues
It was clear before I wrote this article that normative models
do not adequately account for empirical observations of bargaining. My argument is that psychological theories of negotiation provide the best approach for understanding negotiation
behavior. The descriptive approaches examined in this article
offer important insights for understanding negotiation, but
each also contains shortcomings and limitations. In this review,

527

I made clear distinctions among the individual differences,


motivational, and cognitive approaches. However, I do not
mean to imply that these theoretical approaches are necessarily
contradictory. The approaches focus on different constructs,
and few researchers have attempted to pit one approach against
another. Instead, investigators in recent analyses have attempted to integrate these approaches by developing frameworks that include personality, motivation, and cognitive processes (Bazerman & Carroll, 1987; Neale & Northcraft, in
press). These frameworks are primarily structural and serve
chiefly to organize the large literature on negotiation rather
than to derive implications and testable predictions.
The purpose of this article is not to propose a new theory of
negotiation behavior but to identify the elements and processes
that should be included and the phenomena that must be explained by a psychological theory of negotiation. First, the
theory should be accessible to objective, economic analysis;
that is, the theory should provide a way of measuring concepts
such as the bargaining zone, integrative outcomes, and distributive bargaining outcomes. Second, a theory of negotiation
should explain the perceptual experience of negotiators and
their judgment processes. The most enduring and robust perceptions include the fixed-pie perception, self-serving attributions, and gain and loss frames of reference. Third, a theory
should explain the relationships between judgment and behavior in negotiation, such as those between fixed-pie perceptions
and outcomes and between gain/loss frames of reference and
performance. Fourth, in addition to explaining the correspondences between judgment and behavior, the theory should explain discrepancies. Discrepancies occur on the general level
between social-psychological and economic measures. For example, although most negotiators fail to realize that their interests may be completely compatible with those of their opponent, many are able to reach optimal agreements on these issues
anyway (Thompson, 1990, in press-a). Discrepancies also occur
on a more local level; for example, aspiration levels affect perceptions of reservation price. Finally, motivation and goals are
essential ingredients in a theory of negotiation. The fundamental elements of negotiation imply the existence of motivation
(e.g, interests, utilities), and aspirations are clearly empirically
related to behavior and performance. In economic analyses,
researchers typically assume that negotiators' primary motivation is to maximize their own gain. However, negotiators' goals
are undoubtedly more complex, and they are clearly concerned
with the outcomes of the other party as well as their own (Loewenstein et al, 1989; Messick & Sentis, 1985; Schelling, 1960).
The theory should provide a way of capturing alternate goals.
The list of theoretical imperatives outlined here is not exhaustive. The temptation facing theoreticians is to develop conceptual frameworks that encompass all the features and characteristics of negotiation and apply to several levels of analysis.
However, I think that the most powerful theory of negotiation
behavior will begin at the level of the individual negotiator.
This view, of course, is most consistent with the informationprocessing theory that is the basis of the cognitive approach
outlined in this article. In advocating this model as a basis for
constructing a theory of the negotiator, I do not suggest that the
interpersonal aspect of negotiation be ignored. I believe that
the theoretical task of understanding communication will be

This document is copyrighted by the American Psychological Association or one of its allied publishers.
This article is intended solely for the personal use of the individual user and is not to be disseminated broadly.

528

LEIGH THOMPSON

facilitated once an understanding of the individual negotiator's


mind is developed. Also, I do not suggest that the cognitive
approach is incompatible with motivational and aspiration
models of behavior. Quite the contrary. As noted earlier, a psychological theory of negotiation behavior will need to include
motivational factors as well as social judgment processes.
It may help to clarify the relationship between motivational
and cognitive models if I suggest an illustrative relation. A
current theoretical and empirical hole in negotiation research
concerns how negotiators develop goals in bargaining. In most
of the studies addressing the goal-performance relationship,
investigators experimentally manipulate goals by providing negotiators with a performance level to achieve or exceed. In the
absence of performance constraints imposed by experimenters,
what determines the goals that negotiators adopt? One hypothesis is that negotiators' goals are guided by their judgments of
the amount of available resources and the other party's interests. Thus judgments influence bargaining aspirations, which
guide behavior. The suggestion that goals guide behavior is not
new; in some of the earliest and most important analyses of
negotiation behavior, researchers hypothesized that goals guide
search and behavior (cf. Schelling, 1960; Siegel & Fouraker,
1960). What is new about this view is the role of judgment in
negotiation and the relationship between judgment and aspirations. Researchers have already begun to explore the assumptions that negotiators bring to negotiation and how perceptions
change during negotiation (cf. Thompson & Hastie, 1990, in
press). The next important step is to explore the relationship
between judgments and goals.
Empirical Issues
Examination of the matrix created by the intersection of
theory and research in this review highlights areas that are in
need of development. In general, economic measures of performance have been used more extensively than social-psychological measures. I do not suggest that social-psychological measures replace objective analysis; it is important to include both
measures in research programs. There are at least three reasons
for this. First, negotiators typically do not have the information
necessary to make objective judgments of the bargaining situation; their understanding of the bargaining situation is based
on their perceptions. A "picture" of the negotiator's perceptual
experience seems to be important for a theory of negotiation.
Second, it is useful to compare negotiators' perceptions with
objective measures. Some of the most enduring questions in
psychology have to do with the study of accuracy of judgment
and perception (Funder, 1987; Hastie & Rasinski, 1987; Kruglanski, 1989). Researchers in other domains such as person
perception have been forced to rely on indirect methods that
infer error from subjects' tendencies to rely on "bad cues" and
to ignore "good cues" or their failure to match the output of a
normative model (e.g., Nisbett & Ross, 1980). Negotiation with
its well-defined, objective task structure provides an ideal set of
criteria from which to examine the accuracy of negotiators'
perceptions (Thompson & Hastie, 1990). Finally, negotiators'
perceptions are important to examine because they influence
behavior in negotiation (Thompson & Hastie, in press).
Negotiation performance (in terms of economic criteria) is

frequently less than optimal. Although this empirical reality


suggests that the normative model of negotiation does not fulfill a descriptive function, one can argue that the paradigm on
which descriptive research is based does not provide an appropriate testing ground for the economic approach. Simply put,
many of the studies that indicate that negotiation behavior and
outcomes are inefficient have been based on examinations of
single or one-shot negotiation situations. One argument is that
research findings observed in one-shot interactions are trivial
because inefficiencies are corrected by experience in the market (Grether & Plott, 1979). Although the precise mechanism
by which experience improves performance is not well specified, experience is generally thought to provide individuals
with feedback that they can use to correct their judgments (Hogarth, 1981). However, Einhorn (1980) noted that learning from
experience is difficult because feedback is often incomplete or
delayed.
This challenge is compelling because many negotiations take
place not as isolated interactions but as part of a continuous
process (Carroll & Payne, in press; Hogarth, 1981; Raiffa,
1982). A modest but important set of studies has begun to
address the question of whether people bargain more effectively if they gain experience. This research is characterized by
three paradigms: studies of expert negotiators, experimental
bargaining markets, and laboratory negotiation experiences.
Studies of Experts
A widely held view is that expertspeople who negotiate for
a livingshould be better negotiators than are novices. Neale
and Northcraft (1986) compared experts' performance to amateurs' performance on an integrative bargaining task. The experts were corporate real estate executives with an average of 10
years' experience; the amateurs were students at a state university. The experts were more successful in reaching integrative
outcomes in a novel bargaining task than were the amateurs. In
a similar analysis, Scholz et al. (1982) compared professionals
(head buyers of West German department stores) with nonprofessionals (vocational retraining students) on an integrative bargaining task. Professionals resolved conflicts more quickly
than did nonprofessionals but did not differ from them in
terms of joint outcomes. However, the measures of joint performance in each study were different; the discrepancy may be a
function of the different dependent variables used in each
study. In general, the research on professionals versus novices is
scant. One problem with comparisons of professionals with
nonprofessionals is the inability to infer a causal relationship
between negotiation skill and performance; professionals
differ in a number of other ways from novices. As a result, some
researchers have manipulated (rather than measured) experience.
Experimental Bargaining Markets
In market simulations, buyers and sellers are instructed to
complete as many profitable transactions as they can within a
short amount of time (usually 25 min or less). The only restriction is that parties may not interact with the same person more
than once. In market studies, negotiators are essentially clones

This document is copyrighted by the American Psychological Association or one of its allied publishers.
This article is intended solely for the personal use of the individual user and is not to be disseminated broadly.

NEGOTIATION BEHAVIOR AND OUTCOMES


(i.e., all buyers have identical preferences and all sellers have
identical preferences). The robust finding in market studies is
that negotiation contracts become more integrative over time
(cf. Bazerman et al, 1985). However, because all buyers are
identical and all sellers are identical, there exists a given set of
optimal solutions. Thus one explanation for the improvements
in performance over time is that knowledge of the "best solution" simply spreads through the market. Thus it is unclear
whether negotiators are learning negotiation skills that generalize across different situations or whether performance is task
specific.

Negotiation Experience
Thompson (1990) challenged negotiators with several bargaining tasks, each requiring unique solutions in order to reach
integrative agreement. Thus in contrast to bargaining markets
in which bargainers negotiate with opponents who all have the
same preferences, one could not reach integrative solutions in
Thompson's tasks by merely applying the same solution. Negotiators engaged in seven bargaining tasks (the high-experience
group); their opponents had either no experience or just a single
previous bargaining experience (the naive group). Logrolling
skills improved as negotiators gained experience. Furthermore,
negotiators were more successful in logrolling when the naive
member of the bargaining pair had just a single previous experience as opposed to no previous experience, and highly experienced bargainers were able to claim a larger share of the resources at the expense of their naive opponents. There was an
important caveat on the experience-performance relationship:
Experience did not improve negotiators' ability to recognize
compatible issues. At least one negotiator in 71% of all pairs
failed to realize that some interests of the other party were
perfectly compatible with their own; 20% of the pairs reached
suboptimal outcomes on compatible issues.
In another study, Thompson (in press-b) reasoned that experience may not always have a beneficial effect on performance
and could potentially hinder negotiators' ability to reach integrative agreements. Thompson reasoned that negotiators who
engaged in purely distributive negotiations would develop a
fixed-pie perception of the task. When they are confronted
with a subsequent integrative negotiation situation, their performance may be hindered as a consequence of their erroneous
expectation that is based on their experience. The hypothesis
was supported: Negotiators who had experience in tasks with
logrolling potential performed better in a subsequent logrolling
task than did negotiators whose initial experience was in a distributive task.
The purpose of this article has been to address the important
empirical and theoretical issues in negotiation research. Because negotiation behavior is a fundamental form of social interaction, it is a major area of research in several fields. A number of perspectives that attempt to predict behavior and performance have emerged, and a number of performance criteria
have been identified to measure performance. In this article I
have identified some important factors that predict negotiation
behavior and performance and some theoretical issues for future research.

529

References
Abelson, R. (1976). Script processing in attitude formation and decision making. In J. S. Carroll & J. W Payne (Eds.), Cognition and social
behavior (pp. 33-46). Hillsdale, NJ: Erlbaum.
Anderson, J. (1985). Cognitive psychology and its implications. New
York: W H. Freeman.
Allport, F. (1955). Theories of perception and the concept of structure.
New York: Wiley.
Bartos, O. J. (1972). Foundations for a rational-empirical model of
negotiation. In J. Berger, M. Zelditch, & B. Anderson (Eds.), Sociological theories in progress (Vol. 2., pp. 3-20). Boston: Houghton-Mifflin.
Bazerman, M. (1986). Judgment in managerial decision making. New
York: Wiley.
Bazerman, M. H, & Carroll, J. (1987). Negotiator cognition. In B. Staw
& L. L. Cummings (Eds.), Research in organizational behavior (Vol.
9, pp. 247-288). Greenwich, CT: JAI Press.
Bazerman, M. H., Magliozzi, T., & Neale, M. A. (1985). Integrative
bargaining in a competitive market. Organizational Behavior and
Human Performance, 34, 294-313.
Bazerman, M. H, & Neale, M. A. (1983). Heuristics in negotiation:
Limitations to effective dispute resolution. In M. H. Bazerman &
R. J. Lewicki (Eds.), Negotiatingin organizations (pp. 51 -67). Beverly
Hills: Sage.
Bern, D. (1967). Self-perception: An alternative interpretation of cognitive dissonance phenomena. Psychological Review, 74,183-200.
Ben-Yoav, O, & Pruitt, D. G. (1984a). Resistance to yielding and the
expectation of cooperative future interaction in negotiation. Journal
of Experimental Social Psychology, 20, 323-353.
Ben-Yoav, O, & Pruitt, D. G. (1984b). Accountability to constituents: A
two-edged sword. Organizational Behavior and Human Processes,
34, 282-295.
Blake, R. R., & Mouton, J. S. (1962). The managerial grid. Houston:
Gulf.
Brandstatter, H, Kette, G., & Sageder, J. (1982). Expectations, attributions, and behavior in bargaining with liked and disliked partners.
In R. Tietz (Ed.), Aspiration levels in bargaining and economic decision making (pp. 136-152). Berlin: Springer-Verlag.
Brown, B. (1968). The effects of need to maintain face on interpersonal
bargaining. Journal of Experimental Social Psychology, 4,107-122.
Carnevale, P. J. D, & Isen, A. (1986). The influence of positive affect
and visual access on the discovery and integrative solutions in bilateral negotiations. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 37,1-13.
Carnevale, P. J. D., & Lawler, E. J. (1986). Time pressure and the development of integrative agreements in bilateral negotiation. Journal of
Conflict Resolution, 30, 636-659.
Carnevale, P. J. D., Pruitt, D. G, & Britton, S. (1979). Looking tough:
The negotiator under constituent surveillance. Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin, 5,118-121.
Carroll, J. S, Bazerman, M., & Maury, R. (1988). Negotiator cognitions: A descriptive approach to negotiators' understanding of their
opponents. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes,
41, 352-370.
Carroll, J. S., & Payne, J. (in press). An information processing approach to two-party negotiations. In M. H. Bazerman, R. J. Lewicki,
& B. H. Sheppard (Eds.), Research on negotiation in organizations
(Vol. 3.). Greenwich, CT: JAI Press.
Chatman, J., & Sondak, H. (in press). Integrating communication and
negotiation research. In M. H. Bazerman, R. J. Lewicki, & B. H.
Sheppard (Eds.), Research on negotiation in organizations (Vol. 3).
Greenwich, CT: JAI Press.
Chertkoff, J. M, & Esser, J. K. (1976). A review of experiments in

This document is copyrighted by the American Psychological Association or one of its allied publishers.
This article is intended solely for the personal use of the individual user and is not to be disseminated broadly.

530

LEIGH THOMPSON

explicit bargaining. Journal of Experimental Social Psychology 12,


464-486.
Cross, J. (1965). A theory of bargaining process. American Economic
Review, 40, 67-94.
Davis, M. (1981). A multidimensional approach to individual differences in empathy. JSAS Catalogue of Selected Documents in Psychology, 10, 85.
Davis-Blake, A., & Pfeffer, J. (1989). Just a mirage: The search for dispositional effects in organizational research. Academy of Management Review, 14, 385-400.
deGroot, M. H. (1970). Optimal statistical decisions. New York:
McGraw-Hill.
Druckman, D., & Zechmeister, K. (1973). Conflict of interest and
value dissensus: Propositions on the sociology of conflict. Human
Relations, 26, 449-466.
Einhorn, H. (1980). Learning from experience and suboptimal rules in
decision making. In T. Wallsten (Ed.), Cognitive processes in choice
and decision behavior (pp. 1-20). Hillsdale, NJ: Erlbaum.
Eliashberg, J., LaTour, S., Rangaswamy, A., & Stern, L. (1986). Assessing the predictive accuracy of two utility-based theories in a marketing channel negotiation context. Journal of Marketing Research, 23,
101-110.
Emmons, R., & Diener, E. (1986). Situation selection as a moderator of
response consistency and stability. Journal of Personality and Social
Psychology, 51, 1013-1019.
Fischhoff B., Slovic, P., & Lichtenstein, S. (1980). Knowing what you
want: Measuring labile values. In T. Wallsten (Ed.), Cognitive processes in choice and decision behavior (pp. 11-141). Hillsdale, NJ:
Erlbaum.
Fiske, S., & Taylor, S. (1984). Social cognition. New York: Random
House.
Follett, M. P. (1940). Constructive conflict. In H. C. Metcalf & L. Urwick (Eds.), Dynamic administration: The collected papers of Mary
Parker Follett (pp. 30-49). New York: Harper.
Froman, L. A., & Cohen, M. D. (1970). Compromise and logroll: Comparing the efficiency of two bargaining processes. Behavioral
Science, 30, 180-183.
Fry, W R. (1985). The effect of dyad Machiavellianism and visual access on integrative bargaining outcomes. Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin, 11, 51-62.
Fry, W R., Firestone, I, & Williams, D. (1983). Negotiation process and
outcome of stranger dyads and dating couples: Do lovers lose? Basic
and Applied Social Psychology, 4,1-16.
Funder, D. (1987). Errors and mistakes: Evaluating the accuracy of
social judgment. Psychological Bulletin, 101, 75-90.
Gilkey, R. W, & Greenhalgh, L. (1984, August). Developing effective
negotiation approaches among professional women in organizations.
Paper presented at the Conference on Women and Organizations,
Simmons College, Boston.
Greenhalgh, L., & Neslin, S. (1983). Determining outcomes of negotiation: An empirical assessment. In M. H. Bazerman & R. J. Lewicki
(Eds.), Negotiating in organizations (pp. 114-134). Beverly Hills, CA:
Sage.
Grether, D. M., & Plott, C. R. (1979). Economic theory of choice and
the preference reversal phenomenon. American Economic Review,
69, 623-638.
Cruder, C. (1971). Relationships with opponent and partner in mixedmotive bargaining. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 15, 403-416.
Hammond, K., Stewart, T, Brehmer, B., & Steinmann, D. (1975). Social judgment theory. In M. Kaplan & S. Schwartz (Eds.), Human
judgment and decision processes (pp. 271-312). New York: Academic Press.
Hamner, W C. (1980). The influence of structural, individual, and

strategic differences. In D. Harnett & L. L. Cummings (Eds.), Bargaining behavior (pp.). Houston, TX: Dame Publications.
Hamner, W C., & Harnett, D. L. (1975). The effects of information and
aspiration level on bargaining behavior. Journal of Experimental Social Psychology, 11, 329-342.
Harnett, D., Cummings, L., & Hughes, D. (1968). The influence of
risk-taking propensity on bargaining behavior. Behavioral Science,
13,91-101.
Harsanyi, J. (1956). Approaches to the bargaining problem before and
after the theory of games: A critical discussion of Zeuthen's, Hick's,
and Nash's theories. Econometrica, 24,144-157.
Harsanyi, J. (1962). Bargaining in ignorance of the opponent's utility
function. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 6, 29-38.
Hastie, R. (1986). A primer of information processing theory for the
political scientist. In R. Lau& D. Sears(Eds.), Political cognition (pp.
11-39). Hillsdale, NJ: Erlbaum.
Hastie, R., & Kumar, P. (1979). Person memory: Personality traits as
organizing principles in memory for behavior. Journal of Personality
and Social Psychology, 37, 25-38.
Hastie, R., & Rasinski, K. (1988). The concept of accuracy in social
judgment. In D. Bar-Tal & A. Kruglanski (Eds.), The social psychology of knowledge (pp. 193-208). New York: Cambridge University
Press.
Hermann, M. G., & Kogan, N. (1977). Effects of negotiators' personalities on negotiating behavior. In D. Druckman (Ed.), Negotiations:
Social-psychological perspectives (pp. 247-274). Beverly Hills: Sage.
Hiltrop, J., & Rubin, J. (1981). Position loss and image loss in bargaining. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 25, 521-534.
Hogarth, R. (1981). Beyond discrete biases: Functional and dysfunctional aspects of judgmental heuristics. Psychological Bulletin, 90,
197-217.
Huber, V, & Neale, M. (1986). Effects of cognitive heuristics and goals
on negotiator performance and subsequent goal setting. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 38, 342-365.
Huber, V, & Neale, M. (1987). Effects of self- and competitor goals on
performance in an interdependent bargaining task. Journal of Applied Psychology, 72, 197-203.
Ikle, F., & Leites, N. (1962). Political negotiation as a process of modifying utilities. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 6, 19-28.
Kahneman, D, & Tversky, A. (1979). Prospect theory: An analysis of
decision under risk. Econometrica, 47, 263-291.
Kelley, H. H. (1966). A classroom study of the dilemmas in interpersonal negotiation. In K. Archibald (Ed.), Strategic interaction and
conflict. Berkeley: Institute of international studies, University of
California.
Kelley, H. H., Beckman, L. L., & Fischer, C. S. (1967). Negotiating the
division of reward under incomplete information. Journal of Experimental Social Psychology, 3, 361-398.
Kelley, H. H., & Schenitzki, D. P. (1972). Bargaining. In C. G. McClintock (Ed.), Experimental social psychology (pp. 298-337). New York:
Holt.
Kelley, H. H., & Stahelski, A. J. (1970). Social interaction basis of cooperators' and competitors' beliefs about others. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 7, 401 -419.
Kimmel, M. J., Pruitt, D. G., Magenau, J. M., Konar-Goldband, E., &
Carnevale, P. J. (1980). Effects of trust, aspiration, and gender on
negotiation tactics. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 38,
9-22.
Kruglanski, A. (1989). The psychology of being "right": The problem
of accuracy in social perception and cognition. Psychological Bulletin, 106, 395-409.
Lax, D, & Sebenius, J. (1985). The manager as negotiator. New York:
Free Press.

This document is copyrighted by the American Psychological Association or one of its allied publishers.
This article is intended solely for the personal use of the individual user and is not to be disseminated broadly.

NEGOTIATION BEHAVIOR AND OUTCOMES


Lax, D., & Sebenius, J. (1987). Measuring the degree of joint gains
achieved by negotiators. Unpublished manuscript, Harvard University.
Lewicki, R, & Litterer, J. (1985). Negotiation. Homewood, IL: Irwin.
Loewenstein, G, Thompson, L., & Bazerman, M. (1989). Social utility
and decision making in interpersonal contexts. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 5 7, 426-441.
March, J. (1978). Bounded rationality, ambiguity, and the engineering
of choice. Bell Journal of Economics, 9, 587-608.
Markus, H. (1977). Self-schemata and processing information about
the self. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 35, 63-78.
Markus, H., & Zajonc, R. (1985). The cognitive perspective in social
psychology. In G. Lindzey & E. Aronson (Eds.), The handbook of
social psychology (Vol. 1, pp. 137-230). New York: Random House.
McAlister, L., Bazerman, M. H, & Fader, P. (1986). Power and goalsetting in channel negotiations. Journal of Marketing Research, 23,
228-236.
McFarland, C, & Ross, M. (1982). Impact of causal attributions on
affective reactions to success and failure. Journal of Personality and
Social Psychology, 43, 937-946.
Messick, D., & Sentis, K. (1985). Estimating social and nonsocial utility functions from ordinal data. European Journal of Social Psychology, 15, 389-399.
Miller, C. E., & Komorita, S. (1986). Coalition formation in organizations: What laboratory studies do and do not tell us. In R. J. Lewicki,
B. H. Sheppard, & M. H. Bazerman (Eds.), Research on negotiation
in organizations (Vol. 1, pp. 117-138). Greenwich, CT: JAI press.
Monson, T, Hesley, J., & Chernick, L. (1982). Specifying when personality traits can and cannot predict behavior: An alternative to abandoning the attempt to predict single act criteria. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 43, 385-399.
Murnighan, K.. (1986). Organizational coalitions: Structural contingencies and the formation process. In R. J. Lewicki, B. H. Sheppard,
& M. H. Bazerman (Eds.), Research on negotiation in organizations
(Vol. 1, pp. 155-174). Greenwich, CT: JAI Press.
Myerson, R. (1987). Analysis of incentives in dispute resolution. Unpublished manuscript, Dispute Resolution Research Center, Northwestern University.
Nash, J. (1950). The bargaining problem. Econometrica, 28,155-162.
Nash, J. (1953). Two-person cooperative games. Econometrica, 21,
129-140.
Neale, M. A. (1984). The effect of negotiation and arbitration cost
salience on bargainer behavior: The role of arbitrator and constituency in negotiator judgment. Organizational Behavior and Human
Performance, 34, 97-111.
Neale, M. A., & Bazerman, M. H. (1983). The role of perspective-taking ability in negotiating under different forms of arbitration. Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 36, 378-388.
Neale, M. A, & Bazerman, M. H. (1985a). The effects of framing and
negotiator overconfidence on bargaining behaviors and outcomes.
Academy of Management Journal, 28, 34-49.
Neale, M. A., & Bazerman, M. H. (1985b). The effect of externally set
goals on reaching integrative agreements in competitive markets.
Journal of Occupational Behavior, 6,19-32.
Neale, M. A., Huber, V, & Northcraft, G. (1987). The framing of negotiations: Contextual versus task frames. Organizational Behavior and
Human Decision Processes, 39, 228-241.
Neale, M. A., & Northcraft, G. B. (1986). Experts, amateurs and refrigerators: Comparing expert and amateur negotiators in a novel task.
Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 38, 305317.
Neale, M. A., & Northcraft, G. (in press). Behavioral negotiation
theory: A framework for conceptualizing dyadic bargaining. In L.

531

Cummings & B. Staw (Eds.), Research on organizational behavior.


Greenwich, CT: JAI Press.
Neale, M. A, Northcraft, G. B, & Earley, C. (1988). The joint effects of
goal-setting and expertise on negotiator performance. Unpublished
manuscript, Northwestern University.
Nisbett, R., & Ross, L. (1980). Human inferences: Strategies and shortcomings of social judgment. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall.
Northcraft, G., & Neale, M. (in press). Dyadic negotiation. In M. H.
Bazerman, R. J. Lewicki, & B. H. Sheppard (Eds.), Research on negotiation in organizations (Vol. 3.). Greenwich, CT: JAI Press.
Osgood, C, Suci, G, & Tannenbaum, P. (1957). The measurement of
meaning. Urbana: University of Illinois Press.
Oskamp, S. (1965). Attitudes toward U.S. and Russian actions: A double standard. Psychological Reports, 16, 43-46.
Pinkley, R. (1990). Dimensions of conflict frame: Disputant interpretations of conflict. Journal of Applied Psychology, 75,117-126.
Pinkley, R., & Northcraft, G. (1989, August). Cognitive interpretations of
conflict: Implications for disputant motives and behavior. Paper presented at the Academy of Management Meetings, Washington, DC.
Pruitt, D. (1983). Achieving integrative agreements. In M. H. Bazerman & R. J. Lewicki (Eds.), Negotiating in organizations (pp. 35-50).
Beverly Hills, CA: Sage.
Pruitt, D. (1986). Achieving integrative agreements in negotiation. In
R. White (Ed.), Psychology and the prevention of nuclear war (pp.
463-478). New York: New York University Press.
Pruitt, D. G., Carnevale, P. J. D, Ben-Yoav, O, Nochajski, T. H., & Van
Slyck, M. R. (1982). Aspiration levels in bargaining and economic
decision making. Berlin: Springer-Verlag.
Pruitt, D. G, & Johnson, D. (1970). Mediation as an aid to face saving
in negotiation. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 14,239246.
Pruitt, D. G, & Kimmel, M. (1977). Twenty years of experimental
gaming: Critique, synthesis, and suggestions for the future. Annual
Review of Psychology, 28, 363-392.
Pruitt, D. G, & Lewis, S. A. (1975). Development of integrative solutions in bilateral negotiation. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 31, 621-630.
Pruitt, D, & Rubin, J. (1986). Social conflict: Escalation, stalemate, and
settlement. New York: Random House.
Raiffa, H. (1982). The art and science of negotiation. Cambridge, MA:
Harvard University Press.
Rapoport, A. (1968). Prospects for experimental games. Journal of
Conflict Resolution, 12, 461-470.
Rubin, J. Z. (1980). Experimental research on third-party intervention
in conflict: Toward some generalizations. Psychological Bulletin, 87,
379-391.
Rubin, J. Z. (1986). Third parties within organizations. In R. Lewicki,
B. Sheppard, & M. Bazerman (Eds.), Research on negotiations in
organizations (Vol. 1, pp. 271-286). Greenwich: CT: JAI Press.
Rubin, J., & Brown, B. (1975). The social psychology of bargaining and
negotiation. New York: Academic Press.
Schelling, T. (1960). The strategy of conflict. Cambridge, MA: Harvard
University Press.
Schneider, D, Hastorf, A., & Ellsworth, P. (1979). Person perception.
Reading, MA: Addison-Wesley.
Scholz, R., Fleischer, A., & Bentpup, A. (1982). Aspiration forming and
predictions based on aspiration levels compared between professional and nonprofessional bargainers. In R. Tietz (Ed.), Aspiration
levels in bargaining and economic decision making (pp. 109-121).
Berlin: Springer-Verlag.
Schulz, J. W, & Pruitt, D. G. (1978). The effects of mutual concern on
joint welfare. Journal of Experimental Social Psychology, 14, 480492.

This document is copyrighted by the American Psychological Association or one of its allied publishers.
This article is intended solely for the personal use of the individual user and is not to be disseminated broadly.

532

LEIGH THOMPSON

Shaver, K. (1987). Principles of social psychology. Hillsdale, NJ: Erlbaum.


Sheppard, B. (1984). Third party conflict intervention: A procedural
framework. Research in Organizational Behavior, 6,141-190.
Siegel, S. (1957). Level of aspiration and decision making. Psychological Review, 64, 253-262.
Siegel, S., & Fouraker, L. E. (1960). Bargaining and group decision-making: Experiments in bilateral monopoly. New York: McGraw-Hill.
Smith, W (1987). Conflict and negotiation: Trends and emerging issues. Journal of Applied Social Psychology, 17, 641-677.
Staw, B., & Ross, J. (1985). Stability in the midst of change: A dispositional approach to job attitudes. Journal of Applied Psychology, 70,
469-480.
Stillinger, C, & Ross, L. (1987, August). Reactive devaluation of concessions: A social-cognitive barrier to conflict resolution. Paper presented
at the annual meeting of the American Psychological Association,
New York.
Taylor, S. E., & Crocker, J. (1981). Schematic bases of social information processing. In E. T. Higgins, C. Herman, & M. Zanna (Eds.),
Social cognition: The Ontario Symposium (pp. 89-133). Hillsdale,
NJ: Erlbaum.
Thibaut, J., & Kelley, H. (1959). The social psychology of groups. New
York: Wiley.
Thibaut, J., & Walker, L. (1975). Procedural justice. Hillsdale, NJ: Erlbaum.
Thompson, L. (1990). An examination of naive and experienced negotiators. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 59, 82-90.
Thompson, L. (in press-a). Information exchange in negotiation. Journal of Experimental Social Psychology.
Thompson, L. (in press-b). The influence of experience on negotiation
performance. Journal of Experimental Social Psychology.
Thompson, L., & Hastie, R. (1990). Judgment tasks and biases in negotiation. In B. H. Sheppard, M. H. Bazerman, & R. J. Lewicki (Eds.),
Research in negotiation in organizations (Vol. 2, pp. 31-54). Greenwich, CT: JAI Press.

Thompson, L., & Hastie, R. (in press). Social perception in negotiation. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes.
Tjosvold, D. (1977). Commitment to justice in conflict between unequal status persons. Journal of Applied Social Psychology, 7, 149162.
Tjosvold, D. (1978). Control strategies and own group evaluation in
intergroup conflict. Journal of Psychology, 100, 305-314.
Turnbull, A., Strickland, L., & Shaver, K. (1976). Medium of communication, differential power, and phasing of concessions: Negotiating
success and attributions to the opponent. Human Communications
Research, 2, 262-270.
Tversky, A., & Kahneman, D. (1974). Judgment under uncertainty:
Heuristics and biases. Science, 185,1124-1131.
Tyler, T. (1986). When does procedural justice matter in organizational
settings? In R. J. Lewicki, B. H. Sheppard, & M. H. Bazerman (Eds.),
Research on negotiation in organizations (Vol 1, pp. 7-24). Greenwich, CT: JAI Press.
von Neumann, J., & Morgenstern, O. (1947). Theory of games and economic behavior. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Walton, R. E., & McKersie, R. B. (1965). A behavioral theory of labor
relations. New York: McGraw-Hill.
Weingart, L., Thompson, L., Bazerman, M., & Carroll, J. (1990). Tactical behavior and negotiation outcomes. International Journal of Conflict Management, 1, 7-32.
Werner, T, & Tietz, R. (1982). The search process in bilateral negotiations. In R. Tietz (Ed.), Aspiration levels in bargaining and economic
decision making (pp. 67-79). Berlin: Springer-Verlag.
Wills, T. A. (1981). Downward comparison principles in social psychology. Psychological Bulletin, 90, 245-27'1.
Zechmeister, K., & Druckman, D. (1973). Determinants of resolving a
conflict of interest. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 17, 63-88.

Received March 14,1989


Revision received February 20,1990
Accepted March 20,1990

Das könnte Ihnen auch gefallen