Sie sind auf Seite 1von 14

Carbon Market Analyst

North America

The Power of Carbon


RESEARCH July 18, 2008

TO THE POINT CONTENT


The US will most likely be operating in a carbon-constrained 2 Executive summary
economy in the near future as both presidential candidates 3 What future carbon constrained
favor a greenhouse gas cap-and-trade system to reduce
domestic emissions. economy?
4 Carbon and Power
Implications of such a system includude increases in the price
of electricity and transportation fuels, as the emitters and fuel 10 Carbon and Transportation Fuels
providers must account for the cost of carbon associated with 13 Conclusions
their product.
14 Contacts
Increases in electricity prices will be more drastic in coal-
heavy regions. This is especially true for deregulated power
markets where the fuel on the margin determines the
electricity price.
In regulated power markets, public officials will have a
certain degree of control over the carbon-induced power
price increase, as they may limit the degree to which fossil fuel
fired generators can pass the cost of carbon on to consumers
in the form of higher rates.
In the transportation sector, carbon caps will make biofuels UPCOMING REPORTS
more price-competitive with their fossil-derived counterparts.
Our analysis looks at an expanded scope of regulation in the
transportation sector that may exist in future cap-and-trade • Pre-emptive strike: The Future of
proposals. Regional Carbon Trading Programs
in the US
If fuels are regulated according to their lifecycle carbon • RECs and the Carbon Market
emissions, certain types of biofuels will become more • North American Offset Supply
competitive and the profit margins of the most energy-
intensive fossil fuel producers would narrow.

POINT CARBON RESEARCH All rights reserved © 2008 Point Carbon


Carbon Market Analyst North America CMA July 18, 2008

Executive summary
In this issue of Carbon Market Analyst North America, we take a look at the implications of impending carbon constraints
on energy commodities: electricity and transportation fuels.
Current legislative proposals for combating climate change in the US include a greenhouse gas cap-and-trade system
that would include emissions from the power and transportation sectors. We use the most recent such proposal, the
Lieberman-Warner bill, to exemplify a future carbon trading regime in the US and explore its implications for the power
and transportation sectors.
Cap-and-trade’s most immediate effect in the power sector is to alter the price differential among fuels used to produce
electricity. The price of natural gas and oil will go up because refiners will have to submit allowances for those fuels’
carbon emissions. Coal-fired power generators will have to submit allowances for the emissions associated with their
coal combustion. The cost differential between coal and natural gas in power generation will narrow following this
inclusion of a carbon price, which will incentivize “fuel-switching” from coal to natural gas on the margin.
Increases in electricity prices will be more drastic in coal-heavy regions. This is especially true for deregulated power
markets where the fuel on the margin determines the electricity price. In regulated power markets, public officials
could have some control over the retail power price increase, as they may limit the degree to which fossil fuel-fired
generators can pass the cost of carbon on to consumers in the form of higher rates.
In the transportation sector, refiners and processors of fossil fuels would have to pay for the emissions that will occur
when the fuel is burned. In a carbon-constrained economy modeled after the Lieberman-Warner bill, fossil fuel prices
would rise while all biofuels would become more competitive.
Policymakers are increasingly aware of the differentiated environmental effects of energy crops, meaning that the
way biofuels are regulated may change in future cap-and-trade proposals. Such a change could involve expanding
the compliance burden in a cap-and-trade system to refiners and importers of all fuels, requiring them to surrender
allowances for the lifecycle emissions of their products.
Under that regulatory scenario, the relative prices of fuels would be differentiated beyond the fossil fuel - biofuel
divide. Some types of biofuels would become more competitive relative to others, facilitating an overall reduction in
average fuel carbon intensity.

Setting the scene there will be a complex market once


the rules of trading are set.
and transportation causes nearly
three-fourths of the country’s total
With both US presidential candidates emissions. Putting a price on these
in favor of addressing the problem of emissions will raise the price of fuels
Setting a cap on
climate change by implementing a with which we tank our cars and
cap-and-trade system to reduce US greenhouse gas influence the economics of energy
greenhouse gas emissions, a carbon- emissions makes markets, favoring less carbon-
constrained US economy is likely in carbon a commodity intensive electricity generation.
the near future.
In this Carbon Market Analyst North
Businesses in all sectors are The price of carbon will have direct America, we explore the impact
bracing themselves for what this and significant effects on the price of of potential US carbon emissions
means to their bottom line, and other commodities, particularly those regulation on electricity prices and
consumers wonder how it will affect in sectors that are the largest sources the relative costs of transportation
their pocketbook. Setting a cap on of emissions: power generation and fuels, showing what the market for
greenhouse gases and monetizing transportation fuels. these commodities could look like
each ton emitted makes carbon a in a future carbon-constrained US
commodity – a commodity for which Overall in the US, burning the fuels economy.
needed for electricity generation

2 All rights reserved © 2008 Point Carbon


Carbon Market Analyst North America CMA July 18, 2008

What future carbon- The compliance obligation on the part Assuming a possible near-term cost
of emitters and fuel providers changes of carbon derived from analyses of
constrained economy? the current cost ratios in markets the Lieberman-Warner bill, we show
Several proposals to implement a for power and fuels, as generating some of the effects of this cost on
cap-and-trade system have been electricity by burning coal becomes regional electricity prices as well as
introduced in the US Congress, relatively more expensive compared fuel price spreads.
each with differing reduction to lower-carbon sources - just as
gasoline or diesel becomes more The timeframe we look at represents
timelines, points of regulation, and
expensive relative to lower-carbon the initial years of the proposed US
allocation structures. We base our
fuels like ethanol or biodiesel. carbon market, during which the
calculations on the proposal that
made it the farthest toward actual
implementation, the Lieberman- Textbox 1: The price of carbon in 2012
Warner Climate Security Act that was The US Environmental Protection Agency (EPA) published a detailed
briefly debated on the Senate floor in analysis of the Lieberman-Warner bill in March 2008, including projected
June 2008. per-ton prices of carbon given various policy and fuel cost scenarios. The
agency came up with a range of carbon price estimates over the 2012-2050
Although this bill failed to pass a cloture
period covered by the bill, based on Computable Generalized Equilibrium
vote, it is the best available indication
models.
of what policy might be adopted
under the next administration: several These models, with acronyms IGEM and ADAGE, forecast expected
of its components will be included allowance prices based on economic activity, fuel prices, technology
in a successor bill on cap-and-trade, development, carbon offset availability, and several other factors. Using
which both presidential candidates
different scenarios containing a mix of these parameters, the EPA models
would be likely to sign into law.
revealed possible carbon price curves throughout the 2012-2050 period.
Both presidential
100
candidates would be
90
likely to sign a successor
80
bill into law EPA - LW IGEM
70
EPA - LW ADAGE
Price ('05 $/ton)

The Climate Security Act would 60


impose a limit on over 80 50
percent of US carbon emissions,
40
including electricity generation
and transportation. While the bill 30
regulates these emissions from coal- 20
fired power plants directly, it covers
10
the emissions associated with other
fuels (natural gas and transport fuels 0
such as gasoline) further upstream, 2010 2012 2014 2016 2018 202 0 202 2 2024 2026 2 028 2 030
Year
at the refinery or fuel import level Source: EPA 2008
(see Textbox 2).
The initial price estimates for the start of the bill’s cap-and-trade program
This means that while coal-burning in 2012 were $24.20 per ton CO2e in the low estimate and $33.40 on the
power plants must surrender high end – we take the average, $28.80, as a central carbon price estimate
allowances (or carbon emission in 2012.
permits) for each ton of carbon
dioxide equivalent (CO2e) they emit, This price fits within the range of another component of the Lieberman-
emissions from cars and natural Warner bill, a so-called cost-containment auction through which the EPA
gas-fired generation are accounted administrator would sell allowances ‘borrowed’ from the period after 2030
for by the provider of that fuel – the to emitters during the early years of the program. According to the bill,
refiners and processors must submit regulators should sell the allowances in this auction at a price between $22
an allowance for every ton of CO2e
and $30 initially.
that will be emitted when that fuel is
burned.

3 All rights reserved © 2008 Point Carbon


Carbon Market Analyst North America CMA July 18, 2008

obligation to surrender emissions The prices shown in the table are In states where power comes
allowances for emissions will have actual exchange-traded fuel futures mainly from fossil fuels, wholesale
just entered into force (2012-2015). from late June 2008 for typical plant electricity costs will increase under
efficiencies, representing the “carbon- a carbon-capped economy. But
The price we use as representative added” scenario under one set of that power price increase will not
for the cost of a ton of CO2e at conditions. The adjusted fuel cost for be uniform: the “spread” between
that time ($28.8) is derived from each plant will change depending on current power prices and those
US government analyses of the actual fuel prices in 2012. adjusted to include the additional
Lieberman-Warner bill (see Textbox cost from carbon is largest where
1).
Generating electricity the generation mix is most coal-
by burning coal be- heavy.
Carbon and Power
comes more expensive Spread varies by season
The effect of a $28.80 per ton
carbon price on 2012 electricity Figure 1 illustrates this difference
costs will vary by region, depending The US gets roughly half its electricity in power price spread for two
on the respective states’ generation from coal, but coal makes up a existing power markets – the
mix, transmission grid, and whether different percentage of the generation more coal-heavy PJM region
its power market is regulated or mix in each state.Pacific Northwest, in the eastern mid-Atlantic and
deregulated. for instance, is supplied largely by New England’s more natural gas-
hydroelectric power, dampening dependent power market.
Fuel mix the carbon-induced power price
increase in that region. West Virginia The bottom curves represent real
A region’s fuel mix is the primary traded forward prices for peak
and Kentucky, however, get over 90
factor determining the extent to which power in these regions, while
percent of their power from coal,
carbon costs add to power prices. the top lines represent that same
amplifying the effect of carbon costs
Conventional power generation generation with the carbon price’s
on energy prices.
from coal is more greenhouse gas increased cost of fuel included in
intensive than any other type of California’s in-state power generation the price.
fossil-fueled generation, so the cost is nearly 50 percent natural gas, which
of producing power under carbon
constraints increases more for coal-
emits roughly half the carbon per unit The increase in
of energy as coal. However, the state
heavy producers than for those imports 20 percent of its electricity
power prices will
burning other fossil fuels. from coal-heavy neighbors like Utah not be uniform
and Nevada, whose generation mix is
As shown in Table 1, the cost of The width of the bands,
among the most carbon-intensive in
electricity from coal would increase representing the spread between
the nation.
by over 30 percent if emissions are electricity prices and their carbon-
accounted for and passed through Coal makes up a adjusted equivalent, is narrower
to the consumer, while the cost of different percentage in New England than in the PJM
generating power from oil and natural of the generation mix in region. This is because coal is on
gas would increase only 11 and 9 the margin more often in PJM
percent, respectively. each state (Figure 1a), while lower-carbon

Table 1

Generation type Carbon intensity Typical heat Fuel cost $/MWh increase Carbon adjusted fuel
(lbs CO2e /MMBtu) rate (Btu/kWh) ($/MWh) due to CO2 cap cost ($/MWh)
gas 115 8000 104 10 114

oil 174 12300 208 27 235

coal 210 10800 65 28 93

Source: EIA, Nymex

4 All rights reserved © 2008 Point Carbon


Carbon Market Analyst North America CMA July 18, 2008

Figure 1: Different spreads for different generation mixes - The cost differential between electricity with carbon constraints and
without is larger where coal is more often on the margin

180 180

160 160

140 140
$/mwh

$/mwh
120 120

100 100

80 80
Jul-08 Oct-08 Jan-09 Apr-09 Jul-09 Oct-09 Jul-08 Oct-08 Jan-09 Apr-09 Jul-09 Oct-09
PJM On Peak with CO2e PJM OnPeak ISO-NE OnPeak with CO2e ISO-NE OnPeak

Source: NyMex, PJM, ISO-NE

natural gas is almost always the fuel gas-heavier portion of PJM and the distribute a certain percentage of
on the margin in New England. western, coal-heavier parts. the country’s emissions permits to
fossil-fired facilities for free, rather
Though it is less visible on the graph, Provisions limit impact on than requiring companies to buy
both bands representing the cost electricity prices them from the government. The
spread are slightly narrower during number of allowances generators
peak demand seasons, especially in But the effect of fuel carbon intensity would receive is proportional to their
summer when gas is more frequently on the cost of producing electricity is carbon intensity.
on the margin. The cost differential not the only thing that affects what
between PJM’s power prices and consumers see on their utility bills. The Lieberman-Warner cap-and-trade
carbon-adjusted power prices is only The Lieberman-Warner bill aims to design decreases the total amount
$20-$21 per MWh in the hot months lessen the need for power firms to of transition assistance distributed
of July and August, when natural gas pass on their higher generation costs over the years, such that by 2030,
fired plants are running to power air to consumers. It provides so-called generators do not receive any free
conditioning units across the region. transition assistance to fossil fuel- allowances at all. At the bill’s required
fired power generators, in the form start of carbon trading in 2012,
The so-called shoulder months of free emission allowances. however, fossil fuel-fired generators
of March and April, on the other would get a full 18 percent of the
hand, would see a price differential total US allowance budget from
between $22 and $23 per MWh. The power price
the government. This accounts for
Average demand for electricity is spread is lower 40 percent of the emissions from
lower during these months, as homes in hotter months, fossil fueled generators expected
and industries require less power for
heating or cooling overall. Therefore
when gas is more fre- emissions in that year, leaving 60
percent to be purchased.
fewer natural gas-fired peaking quently on the margin
plants are run and the fuel mix in both How regional regulators allow
regions is more coal-heavy. The administrator of the US generators to pass on the cost of
Environmental Protection Agency these allowances in their electricity
The same differential would develop (who would run much of the US rates will determine the cap-and-
regionally, between the eastern, carbon trading program) would trade program’s effect on retail

5 All rights reserved © 2008 Point Carbon


Carbon Market Analyst North America CMA July 18, 2008

power prices. Therefore, state public


utility commissions and other energy Figure 2: How much do emitters get for free? “Transition assistance” to electric
regulators have some degree of power generators would cover about 40 percent of their emissions
control over the power price effects
of federal carbon legislation. US allowance budget in 2012: 5.8 billion tons
Regulated power markets
In states where energy markets are
regulated, public utility commissions
(PUCs) determine the rates
companies are allowed to charge
for their power. They could allow
generators to recover the cost of
their allowances entirely, or limit the 60% Expected US emissions from fossil fuels
carbon cost “pass-through” to the in 2012: 2.6 billion tons
amount of allowances that actually
had to be purchased.
18% 40% Allowances covered by transition
To illustrate the effect of PUC
decisions on this point, figures 3 and
assistance: 1.04 billion
4 show two potential impacts on
electricity prices in regulated states.
their emissions. The incremental emissions permits they had to buy
Fossil fuel-fired gen- cost of electricity is calculated from (60 percent).
erators would get 18 the states’ average emissions rate,
under the assumption that assets in We determined each state’s individual
percent of the US “allocation rebate” from transition
regulated markets are able to recover
allowance budget for free their costs. assistance – again based on its
percentage of fossil fuels and their
In the scenario illustrated by figure 3, In the figure 4 scenario, PUCs respective carbon intensity – and
PUCs would allow full cost recovery recognize that nearly half of the subtracted its monetary equivalent
(total carbon cost pass-through) for allowances needed to cover those in terms of incremental electricity
power generators having to comply costs were given out to generators cost to get the net retail price of
with Lieberman-Warner’s carbon for free, so they only allow power power accounting for a limited pass-
caps by purchasing allowances for companies to pass on the cost of through.

Textbox 2: Point of regulation - Who gets hit with the cost of carbon?
Carbon constraints play out differently of CO2 emitted. But when the trading For the power sector, this means that
depending on where they are applied. system covers the transportation coal-burning power generators must
Policy makers generally distinguish sector as the Lieberman-Warner bill pay for their emissions, while plants
between downstream regulation, does, some upstream regulation is that burn oil or natural gas are covered
which affects the entity that actually required because the government indirectly through higher fuel prices:
emits the carbon into the atmosphere, cannot track emissions from (and the refiners and processors who had
and upstream regulation, which holds require allowances for) every single to surrender allowances for the fuels’
entities closer to the source of fossil car or truck. emissions will presumably recover
fuel responsible for the emissions it those costs by charging more.
Proposals to include transportation
will cause when burned.
under a cap therefore regulate the Regardless of fuel type, the carbon
Europe’s emissions trading program fuel production chain by requiring that cost eventually reaches ratepayers,
covers only electricity and industry, producers, refiners, or distributors as generators pass down the added
so it caps actual emissions from of a fuel surrender allowances for cost of allowances or the increased
those sectors. Installations (power its carbon content. The Lieberman- cost of fuel to their customers in the
plants and industrial facilities) must Warner bill regulates processors or form of higher electricity rates.
surrender an allowance for each ton refiners for all fuels except coal.

6 All rights reserved © 2008 Point Carbon


Carbon Market Analyst North America CMA July 18, 2008

The figures show that if regulators


restrict the ability of utilities to pass Figure 3: A full carbon cost pass-through Carbon price increases in regulated
on the cost of the carbon for which electricity markets, assuming full cost recovery from generators at $28.80/ton carbon price
they were compensated through
transition assistance, there is a much
< 5 $/MWh
lower price impact on ratepayers.
5 – 10 $/MWh

10 – 15 $/MWh
The two figures represent bookends in 15 – 20 $/MWh
a range of possible scenarios, as it is 20 – 25 $/MWh
uncertain what degree of “carbon cost > 25 $/MWh
pass-through” officials will consider
fair. Regulators’ decisions will be most
influential in regions highly dependent
on fossil fuels. Non-emitting power
sources like hydroelectric dams and
nuclear power plants will receive no
transition assistance allowances,
but will also not be required to buy
emission permits for which they could
pass costs through to ratepayers.
Figure 4: Limited carbon cost pass-through Price increase in regulated electricity
No great price in- markets assuming cost pass-through is limited to 60 percent of allowances at $28.80/ton
crease for regions carbon price
with hydro and other < 5 $/MWh

renewables 5 – 10 $/MWh

5 – 10 $/MWh

15 – 20 $/MWh

Hydro-heavy pacific northwest states 20 – 25 $/MWh

of Idaho, Oregon and Washington > 25 $/MWh

would experience no great increase


in power prices in either scenario, as
most of their power generators will
not have to purchase allowances or
face higher fuel costs under carbon
caps. The wholesale power price
increases in those states would be $2,
$6, and $4.70 per MWh, respectively,
whereas limiting carbon cost pass-
through would change those increases
those states. public officials in the US could lean
to $1.80, $5.20, and $4.40.
toward a rate-setting scenario that
Regulators may be influenced by
In contrast, the increase in power resembles figure 4.
evidence from Europe’s carbon
prices in Kentucky and West Virginia in
market, which indicates that utilities
the east, as well as Utah and Colorado
made so-called windfall profits by
Regulators’ deci-
in the west, will depend strongly on sions will be most
passing the cost of carbon on to
the degree to which coal-fired power
plants are allowed to recover costs of
their customers through increased influential in regions
rates even though all their emission highly dependent on fos-
emission allowance from ratepayers.
allowances were given out for free.
sil fuels
The wholesale power price increase
European power firms justify the cost
under our scenario would amount Note that our depiction of power
pass-through, arguing that keeping
to $26.90 per MWh in Kentucky and price increases by state is an
allowances rather than selling them
$27.80 in Utah, whereas limiting the oversimplification, as all regional
represents foregone revenue. To
degree of carbon cost pass-through power grids are connected through
avoid this situation of power firms
would confine retail power price transmission lines. In actual power
passing on costs they did not incur,
increases to $16.60 and $16.80 in markets, the colors would be

7 All rights reserved © 2008 Point Carbon


Carbon Market Analyst North America CMA July 18, 2008

blurred according to which system


operator, transmission grid, and Figure 5a: Typical dispatch order without carbon caps
power market the respective area
falls under – power prices do not
change at state borders, but at utility

Short Run Marginal Cost $/MWh


service areas. Load curve

Other influences on retail power prices Peakers


not shown here include potential
additional transition assistance to rural
electric cooperatives (such a provision
is included in the Lieberman-Warner
bill) as well as some form of overall Gas
financial assistance to low-income Nuclear
electricity ratepayers, to compensate Coal
Hydro/Wind/Renewables
them for a general power price
increase. Capacity in MW

Deregulated power markets


Figure 5b: Adding the cost of carbon The boxes on fossil-fired plants represent power
Prices in deregulated electricity price increase incurred by accounting for CO2 emissions.
markets are set by the fuel on the
SRMC
margin, meaning the last (most
$/MWh
expensive to run) unit of power used
to meet demand. The price bid by
the generator supplying this last unit Peakers
of power sets the price paid to all
generators in the market.
Price
Figure 5 illustrates the dynamics increase
of carbon costs with marginal Gas
Emissions
pricing. Gas is on the margin in a
typical electricity “stack” (figure Coal
Nuclear
5a) where the location of the load
curve determines the price of power. Hydro/Wind/Renewables
The boxes on top of the original
Capacity in MW
coal and gas prices in figures 5b
and 5c represent the added cost of
producing power from these fuels Figure 5c: Carbon-induced fuel-switch The least-efficient coal plant becomes more
under carbon caps. expensive to run than the most efficient gas plant, changing their respective dispatch order.

Under these carbon-capped SRMC


conditions, the last, most costly- $/MWh
to-run coal plant that would be
dispatched before resorting to gas
Peakers
(the one farthest to the right on
the stack) actually becomes more
expensive to run than the cheapest Price
gas plant. This incentivizes coal-to- decrease
gas “fuel-switching” (figure 5c). Gas
Emissions
Fuel switching results in overall
emission reductions from the power Nuclear Coal
sector because gas is used to provide Hydro/Wind/Renewables
the same amount of electricity that
would have come from coal. Capacity in MW

8 All rights reserved © 2008 Point Carbon


Carbon Market Analyst North America CMA July 18, 2008

At the fuel prices shown here, the


carbon price required to achieve Figure 6: Carbon’s retail price impact in deregulated markets
such fuel-switching for generic
coal and natural gas plants is $66 < 5 $/MWh

per ton, assuming US coal and 5 – 10 $/MWh

gas plants’ average emissions per 10 – 15 $/MWh

MWh are roughly 0.98 and 0.39 15 – 20 $/MWh

tons, respectively. Thus our per 20 – 25 $/MWh

ton carbon price of $28.80 would > 25 $/MWh


not be enough to induce much
fuel switching on the margin in
these regions.

Fuel switching re-


sults in overall CO2
emission reductions from
the power sector
Source: ISO-NE, ERCOT, MISO, PJM
This is merely a scenario, as
fuel prices change daily and New York and the eastern PJM emissions, and will therefore charge
the switching price is highly region have slightly higher marginal buyers more for these fuels.
dependent on the underlying fuel. emissions rates, making their price
The price of coal as a fuel will remain
Were the price of natural gas to increase under carbon caps more
unaffected by the carbon cap, but
fall $2 below the levels used in our significant.
coal-fired power generators will
Table 1 calculations, all other fuels
have to submit allowances for the
remaining constant, the switching Wholesale and retail emissions associated with their
price would be around $40 per ton
CO2e.
power price impacts coal combustion, while other fossil
are equivalent in deregu- generation will not.
Figure 6 shows how marginal
pricing under carbon caps
lated states The cost differential between coal
and natural gas in power generation
could play out in the major US
will narrow following this inclusion of
deregulated electricity markets. Deregulated markets in the
a carbon price, which will incentivize
Unlike their counterparts in Midwestern US will see the highest
“fuel-switching” from coal to natural
regulated regions, PUCs in power price increases under this
gas on the margin. This incentive is
states with deregulated markets scenario, as coal is more likely to be
highest at peak times, when natural
follow wholesale forward power the fuel type on the margin there:
gas makes up a greater percentage
prices closely when setting retail the average marginal emissions rate
of generation. Power price increases
electricity rates. Wholesale and for the western part of PJM and
under carbon constraints will be
retail impacts are thus equivalent the region served by the Midwest
generally higher for off-peak than for
in deregulated states. Independent System Operator is
peak generation.
over 0.75 tons per mWh, translating
The California, New England
into a price impact of around $22 per Increases in electricity prices will be
and Texas power markets have
MWh. more drastic in coal-heavy regions.
the lowest average marginal
This is especially true for deregulated
emissions rates (0.5 tons CO2 per Conclusions for power power markets where the fuel on
MWh) of the deregulated markets,
Implementing a greenhouse gas the margin determines the electricity
as natural gas is the marginal
cap-and-trade program will alter the price.
fuel of choice in those regions.
Their power prices will therefore price differential among fuels used In regulated power markets, public
increase the least (about $15 per to produce electricity. The price officials will have a certain degree
MWh) under a carbon price of of natural gas and oil will go up of control over the carbon-induced
$28.80. because refiners will have to submit power price increase, as they may
allowances for those fuels’ carbon

9 All rights reserved © 2008 Point Carbon


Carbon Market Analyst North America CMA July 18, 2008

limit the degree to which fossil fuel


fired generators can pass the cost of Figure 7: Fuel prices with carbon constraints.
carbon on to consumers in the form The fuel prices used are August 2008 fuel prices from Nymex in June 2008, adjusted for differing
energy content by volume. The grey boxes represent what refiners would pay for the allowances
of higher rates.
needed
5.00
to cover the amount of CO2 their fuels will emit when burned at a per ton carbon price of
The effect of such limitation is again $28.80
most drastic in states where coal 4.50
makes up a high percentage of the
4.00
resource mix, as those areas will
receive more government-issued 3.50
allowances to cover their emissions.
3.00
$/gallon

2.50
Carbon and transportation
fuels 2.00

1.50
Just as carbon costs change relative
fuel prices in the power sector, they 1.00
alter the relative price of fuels used
in passenger vehicles. This section 0.50

of the report looks at how such


-
alterations would occur under the
Conventional Gasoline Conventional Diesel Brazilian ethanol with Midwest corn ethanol
Lieberman-Warner bill, and discusses import tariff
additional measures that could
Cost ($/gallon) Carbon price impact
influence consumers’ choice at the
Source: Nymex, EIA fuel emissions coefficients available online at http://www.eia.doe.gov/oiaf/1605/coefficients.html
pump. We confine ourselves to fuels
that can be substituted, and therefore
do not include electric power used in to biofuels like ethanol, for which to eat into their profit margin to a
hybrid or plug-in vehicles, although consumers would see no carbon- certain extent, rather than passing
it is commonly considered an induced price increase. Biofuel it on to consumers entirely. The full
“alternative fuel.” prices would therefore become that carbon adder is $0.26 per gallon for
much more competitive relative to gasoline and $0.29 for diesel – and
The direct effect: biofuels over fossil the conventional fuels. zero for ethanol, as biofuel refiners
fuels have no compliance obligation.
The Lieberman-Warner bill names The effect of a cap For the fuel prices used in this
importers and refiners of “petroleum-
based liquid or gaseous fuel” as is similar to a carbon scenario (spot prices from June
2008), the figure illustrates that
the entities which must surrender tax from the consumer’s adding the $28.80-per-ton carbon
allowances for the emissions that perspective cost to petroleum-based fuels can
will be released into the atmosphere alter their relative prices enough
when that fuel is burned. Those Assuming that refiners of petroleum- to tip the scales on ethanol versus
entities will pass on the cost of those based fuel will pass on the entire gasoline. Without the added cost of
permits in the form of higher gasoline cost of allowances, we can assess carbon, Brazilian sugarcane ethanol
or diesel prices, making the effect of the carbon-induced price increase is a few cents per gallon more
the cap similar to a carbon tax from for some conventional fuels. Figure expensive than gasoline for our given
the consumer’s perspective: the 7 illustrates this “carbon adder” for set of prices, when adjusted to its
costs of petroleum-based vehicle fuel conventional gasoline and diesel, gasoline energy-equivalent. Including
would increase relative to its carbon using EPA estimates of the amount the cost of carbon makes gasoline
content. of CO2 these products will emit more expensive.
Refiners and importers of non- when burned.
Of course, the degree to which the
petroleum-based fuel, however, The actual carbon adder may be scales are tipped among fuel types
would not have to submit allowances. smaller, as refiners or importers may depends primarily on the underlying
This gives an automatic advantage allow the cost of emissions permits fuel price – when gas and diesel are

10 All rights reserved © 2008 Point Carbon


Carbon Market Analyst North America CMA July 18, 2008

cheap, an extra $0.25 per gallon


is more significant, while current Textbox 3: Methodology for lifecycle greenhouse gas emissions
skyrocketing gas prices render the
We use in this analysis lifecycle estimates from the University of California
same price increase a less influential
factor. commissioned California regulators to implement their low carbon fuel
standard (LCFS), which aims to limit the average emissions of the state’s
Though biofuels are advantaged by fuel mix.
the Lieberman-Warner plan under
any fuel price scenario, their relative The metric used for the LCFS targets is “average fuel carbon intensity”
competitiveness is heavily altered (AFCI), defined as grams CO2-equivalent per megajoule of fuel, or emissions
through other policy measures. per unit of energy contained in the fuel.
The production of US corn ethanol
is subsidized, while the price of We use this metric in our calculations to show how various biofuels would
Brazilian ethanol is influenced by a fare price-wise, if allowances were required for their lifecycle carbon
$0.54/gallon import tariff. emissions (figure 8). Grams per megajoule are converted to tons per gallon,
and discounted for the lower heating value of biofuels.
Even without carbon caps, Brazilian
ethanol is actually cheaper than Cellulosic ethanol from cover crops such as switchgrass have extremely
conventional gasoline if the tariff is low (sometimes negative) AFCI values, as their growth reduces topsoil
excluded from the price, due partially loss, sequestering more carbon in the soil than is emitted when burned.
to sugarcane’s less energy-intensive
distillation process. However, supply An important limitation to the model is the measure of land use change
constraints and lack of ethanol and its contribution to greenhouse gas emissions. The model accounts for
infrastructure in the US also affect CO2 emissions resulting from converting pastureland to cropland at rates
the penetration of this fuel in the necessary to produce corn-based ethanol in the US.
market.
Most models of lifecycle carbon emissions fail to account for land use
Eliminating the tariff would thus change beyond this, as net emissions impacts of deforestation or other
make Brazilian ethanol even land conversion are not extremely difficult to quantify accurately.
more competitive relative to the
domestically-produced variety.
Presumptive US presidential
candidate John McCain has declared The plants out of which biofuels are issue of land use change comes into
he would remove the current tariff made (corn, sugarcane, or other crops) play. If forests, which are one of the
on sugarcane ethanol as president, instead removed carbon dioxide from earth’s main CO2 ‘sinks,’ are cleared
making this scenario a possibility. the atmosphere as they grew, such to make way for energy crops, there
that burning them as fuel results in is a net carbon increase.
A carbon price could an even net carbon balance.
Massive palm oil plantations in
tips the scales on Not all biofuels are created equal Southest Asia, for instance, are grown
ethanol vs. gasoline The net carbon balance, however,
on land that was originally tropical
rainforest. Lost carbon sink capacity
is not the same for all biofuels. The
from the associated deforestation
amount of greenhouse gas emissions
The rationale behind “promoting” would be part of the fuel’s lifecycle
associated with the respective
biofuels in this way is directly emissions.
biofuel’s lifecycle differs greatly
related to climate change mitigation. depending on what type of crop is The Lieberman-Warner bill’s binary
Refiners and importers are required to used and what happens at the farm distinction between fossil and non-
surrender allowances for emissions and the refinery. fossil fuels does not reflect this
from fossil fuels and not from lifecycle accounting, partially because
biofuels because the latter generally For example, growing corn involves
greenhouse gas emissions of various
emit less carbon. Petroleum is stored fossil fuel use in tractors, harvesters,
fuels are hard to quantify.
plant energy that would remain and refineries. Most crops also use
underground if humans did not dig fertilizer, of which a major component However, policies currently being
it up, so emissions from burning it (nitrous oxide, N2O) is itself a implemented at the state level
are additional to those of the earth’s greenhouse gas. actually measure lifecycle fuel
natural carbon cycle. emissions and can serve as a model
Earlier in a biofuel crop’s lifecycle, the

11 All rights reserved © 2008 Point Carbon


Carbon Market Analyst North America CMA July 18, 2008

for such accounting in cap-and- Fuel price spreads under lifecycle exception is corn ethanol produced
trade. California’s low carbon fuel accounting in coal-fired refineries. Burning the
standard (LCFS) aims to reduce the coal in that refining process is part
Altering the compliance obligation for
state’s average fuel greenhouse of the lifecycle emissions of the fuel
fuel refiners in this way would have
gas intensity (emissions per unit of – as the allowances refiners would
a significant effect on relative price
energy) over a given time period. be required to surrender get more
differences between and among
The Lieberman-Warner bill calls expensive, so does the cost of the
various biofuels. If all fuel refiners had
for a national version of this LCFS ethanol end product. Corn ethanol
to surrender allowances according to
overseen by the EPA, so tools for refined mills fired with the corn’s own
their average fuel carbon intensity
measuring lifecycle emissions stover (husks) has lower lifecycle
(AFCI, see Textbox 3), we would see
could be in place. emissions, as using this byproduct
significant deviation in prices among
cancels out emissions that would
Policymakers are also becoming fuel types. Fuels whose production
have occurred using fossil fuels.
increasingly attuned to the and refining is less greenhouse
significance of lifecycle accounting gas intensive would become more The slope of each line reveals the
for biofuels, as the global competitive the higher the carbon fuel’s relative AFCI. Cellulosic ethanol
controversy over energy crops and price. made from prairie grass, which
their possible role in food price sequesters carbon in the soil and
increases gains media attention. Policymakers are therefore has nearly negative AFCI,
Though this issue is not directly aware of lifecycle is initially more expensive than corn
related to climate change, US accounting ethanol compared to conventional
decision makers are calling for a gasoline. But it catches up with corn
re-think on energy crops and their ethanol when carbon costs around
This is illustrated in figure 8, which
implications. $52 per ton. Its competitiveness
depicts the price spread between
increases more rapidly than that of
In climate terms, such a re-think conventional gasoline and other fuels
corn ethanol under carbon constraints:
may entail a cap-and-trade program if lifecycle emissions are taken into
while cellulosic costs the same as
in which refiners and importers of account.
gasoline when carbon hits $70 per
all fuels are required to surrender
As the figure shows, higher carbon ton, corn ethanol would not become
allowances for the fuels’ lifecycle
prices generally make biofuels more price-competitive with gasoline until
carbon emissions.
competitive compared to gasoline.The carbon costs $90 per ton.

Figure 8: Fuel spreads by lifecycle carbon intensity


The x axis represents carbon prices, while the y axis represents the cost differential between gasoline and the respective biofuel. Where the lines are above
zero, the biofuel is cheaper than conventional gasoline.
2.00

1.50 Brazilian ethanol


Brazilian ethanol with import tariff
Gasoline - biofuel in $/gallon

US corn ethanol coal-fired refinery


1.00 Cellulosic ethanol - prairie grass
Renewable
fuel favored

US corn ethanol stover-fired refinery

0.50

-
- 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 55 60 65 70 75 80 85 90 95 100
Gasoline
favored

(0.50)

(1.00)
$/ton CO2e

Source: www.ethanolmarket.com, Senate testimony by US National Bioenergy Center Director Michael Pacheco on cellulosic ethanol costs, June 2006

12 All rights reserved © 2008 Point Carbon


Carbon Market Analyst North America CMA July 18, 2008

The current US administration’s Policymakers are increasingly aware gallon cost of conventional fuels by
priority of making cellulosic ethanol of the complexity of environmental fractions of a dollar -- given the lack
more cost-competitive, as stated effects of energy crops, so that of alternative transportation fuels,
in President Bush’s 2007 State of the way biofuels are regulated may consumers are relatively insensitive
the Union speech, would therefore change in future cap-and-trade to such a minor price change.
become realized faster in a carbon- proposals. Such a change could
This difference in cap-and-trade’s
constrained economy that accounts involve expanding the compliance
effect on the two sectors suggests
for fuels’ lifecycle greenhouse gas burden to refiners and importers of
that other policies may be needed to
emissions. all fuels, requiring them to surrender
cut greenhouse gases from vehicle
allowances for the lifecycle emissions
Cellulosic ethanol of their products.
use. Some of the most effective
measures to that end include a low
could become Under that regulatory scenario, carbon fuel standard to incentivize
competitive fuel prices would be differentiated cuts in average fuel greenhouse gas
beyond the fossil fuel - biofuel intensity.
Though it is not shown in the graph, divide. Some types of biofuels would
More far-reaching measures involve
assessing lifecycle fuel greenhouse become more competitive relative
cutting vehicle use itself, through
gas intensity allows differentiation to others, and the profit margins of
long-term infrastructural shifts as
among fossil fuels as well. Some the most energy-intensive fossil fuel
well as new settlement patterns
fossil fuels require a lot of energy producers would narrow.
that reduce “vehicle miles traveled.”
to produce and therefore take a
These include an expansion of
double hit under carbon constraints,
public transportation and urban
if the emissions caused by their General conclusions zoning policies geared toward
production are accounted for:
Comparing the cap-and-trade cutting the length of commutes.
bitumen-rich tar sands in western
program’s effect on the power and But in the decades it takes for such
Canada, for example, are refined
transportation sectors, it becomes comprehensive changes to occur,
into oil using filtration and heating
clear that carbon constraints will have the most immediate effect of carbon
processes that require vast amounts
a more immediate effect on emission caps will be to alter the current price
of energy, which in turn is supplied
reductions in the power sector than ratio of those liquid transportation
by burning fossil-fuels.
in transportation. fuels already on the market.
The higher lifecycle emissions
This is largely due to the nature of
inherent to gasoline or diesel
fuel use in each sector. Even relatively
made from tar sands-derived oil
minor increases in the cost of fuel –
may render those products more
brought on by carbon constraints –
expensive relative to gasoline or
can affect the electric power sector
diesel whose oil inputs came from
in a significant way by providing the
less energy-intensive sources. This
incentive to use a lower-emitting
would reduce the profit margin from
power plant.
producing those fuels.
Drivers, on the other hand, have
few low-carbon fuel options readily
Conclusions for transportation available. Petroleum-based fuels
fuels power nearly all motor vehicles in
the US -- and as lifecycle emission
When refiners and processors
analyses have shown, the biofuel
must pay for the emissions that will
alternatives are not always much
occur when their fuel is burned, fuel
better in terms of their climate
prices rise. In a carbon-constrained
change impact.
economy modeled after the
Lieberman-Warner bill, fossil fuel Furthermore, supply and technological
prices would rise while all biofuels constraints limit the ability to switch
would become more competitive easily from one fuel to another. As
because they are assumed to be we have shown, a $28.80 per ton
less greenhouse gas intensive. carbon price would only raise the per-

13 All rights reserved © 2008 Point Carbon


Contacts CMA July 18, 2008

Editorial enquiries Offices Representatives


UK Japan
Véronique Bugnion Point Carbon, UK JPower
vb@pointcarbon.com Second Floor Ms. Sumie Nakayama
Tel +1 202 289 3930 102-108 Clerkenwell Road Sumie_Nakayama@jpower.co.jp
Fax +1 202 289 3967 London, EC1M 5SA Tel +81 3 3546 9375
United Kingdom Mizuho Information and
Kjetil Røine
Phone: +44 (0)20 7253 7878 Research Institute, Inc.
kr@pointcarbon.com
Fax: +44 (0)20 7253 7856 2-3 Kandanishiki-cho
Tel +47 952 01 355
london@pointcarbon.com Chiyoda-ku Tokyo
Fax +47 22 40 53 41
101-8443 Japan
Ukraine Tel +81 3 5281 5410
Fax +81 3 5281 5466
Point Carbon, Ukraine
3 Sportyvna Ploscha yasushi.setoguchi@
Sales enquiries
Entrance IV, 4th floor gene.mizuho-ir.co.jp (Office)
Point Carbon Sales Team
Olymp Business Center setoro@attglobal.net (Res.)
cmanorthamerica@pointcarbon.com
Phone: +1 202 289 3930 01601 Kiev Ukraine
Fax: +1 202 289 3967 Phone + 38 044 499 0308
Fax: +38 044 499 0309
kyiv@pointcarbon.com

Other enquiries United States


Point Carbon, Norway Point Carbon North America
(Main Office) 900 Second St, NE
contact@pointcarbon.com Suite 309
P.O. Box 7120 St.Olav Washington, DC 20002
N-0130 Oslo Phone: +1 202 289 3930
Norway Fax: +1 202 289 3967
Tel +47 22 40 53 40 washington@pointcarbon.com
Fax +47 22 40 53 41

Website

www.pointcarbon.com

A Point Carbon publication


Copyright © 2008, by Point Carbon.
All rights reserved. No portion of
this publication may be photocopied,
reproduced, scanned into an electronic
retrieval system, copied to a database,
retransmitted, forwarded or otherwise
redistributed without prior written
authorization from Point Carbon. See Point
Carbon’s ”Terms & Conditions” at www.
pointcarbon.com

14 All rights reserved © 2008 Point Carbon

Das könnte Ihnen auch gefallen