Sie sind auf Seite 1von 29

Does Economic Integration Across the Taiwan Strait Make Military Conflict Less Likely?

Author(s): Scott L. Kastner


Source: Journal of East Asian Studies, Vol. 6, No. 3 (SEPTEMBERDECEMBER 2006), pp. 319-346
Published by: Lynne Rienner Publishers
Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/23417931
Accessed: 11-11-2015 13:00 UTC
REFERENCES
Linked references are available on JSTOR for this article:
http://www.jstor.org/stable/23417931?seq=1&cid=pdf-reference#references_tab_contents
You may need to log in to JSTOR to access the linked references.

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at http://www.jstor.org/page/
info/about/policies/terms.jsp
JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content
in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship.
For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.

Lynne Rienner Publishers is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to Journal of East Asian Studies
.

http://www.jstor.org

This content downloaded from 203.78.9.149 on Wed, 11 Nov 2015 13:00:02 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Journalof East Asian Studies 6 (2006), 319-346

Does Economic Integration


Across the Taiwan Strait Make

MilitaryConflictLess Likely?
Scott L. Kastner

economic
ties across the Taiwan
Strait are widely believed
by ana
Deepening
relations.
Yet
to be a stabilizing
force in cross-Strait
lysts and scholars
political
within the broader
international
the relationship
between
relations
literature,
economic
This

interdependence

article

likelihood

examines

of cross-Strait
A description

erature.

and

of growing

military
of three

conflict

military

the impact

conflict

separate

continues

cross-Strait

within
causal

to be controversial.
economic

the context

links

on the

of this broader

lit

in the

mechanismsidentified

ties could promote


is fol
peace
are operating
in the Tai
processes
not rule out the possibility
that eco

which economic
existing
literaturethrough
lowed by a discussion
of how broadly
these
wan

Strait

nomic

case.

Although

integration

it shows
Keywords:

across

that the evidence


China,

Taiwan,

the article
the Strait
in support
economic

does
makes

a military

of such

confrontation

a proposition

interdependence,

less

likely,

is ambiguous.

trade,

conflict

eepening economic ties across the Taiwan Strait are widely be


lieved by analysts and scholars to be a stabilizing force in cross
Strait political relations, at least on the margins.1 The logic behind this
view is straightforward. By raising the costs of military conflict, eco
L-/

nomic exchange potentially encourages restraint in Beijing and Taipei.2


Over the longer term, increased contacts generated by growing eco
nomic linkages may also lay an "important foundation for political

community" across the Taiwan Strait.3 Official US policy is to encour


age cross-Strait economic integration for these reasons.4
Within the broader international relations literature, however, the
relationship between economic integration and military conflict contin
ues to be a hotly debated topic, and liberal arguments that trade pro
motes peace remain controversial. A growing body of recent scholarship
319

This content downloaded from 203.78.9.149 on Wed, 11 Nov 2015 13:00:02 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

320

Does

Economic

Integration

Make

Conflict Less Likely?

the debate by considering more closely the precise causal


processes through which commerce could influence the propensity for
military conflict between states. This focus on microfoundations has im
advances

portant implications for studies that are trying to ascertain whether eco
nomic integration will facilitate peace across the Taiwan Strait. Know

ing that economic ties tend, on balance, to have a pacific effect is of only
limited use when considering a particular case, since it is certain that
sometimes economic ties fail to have such an effect: the outbreak of
World War I, despite extensive trade ties among the major European
powers at the time, is an obvious example. Without a clear specification
of the causal mechanisms linking economic interdependence to a re

of military violence, it is simply difficult to know


whether or not the relationship across the Taiwan Strait resembles fail
ures, like pre-World War I Europe, in that regard.
duced likelihood

Existing studies in the international relations literature have de


rived at least three broad causal mechanisms through which growing
bilateral economic ties can generate a reduced probability of military
conflict between states. First, economic ties can act as a constraint on
state behavior; the increased costs of military conflict in the presence
integration deter states from settling disputes using mili
tary force or engaging in provocative behavior that might invite mili
of economic
tary

retaliation.

Second,

economic

ties

can,

over

time,

change

the goals

that states pursue, so that they are less in conflict with the goals of other
states; as such, the underlying hostilities that are at the root of military
conflict can be reduced as economic integration deepens. Finally, eco
nomic integration can make it easier for states to signal their true level
of resolve, thereby reducing the dangerous uncertainties that can lead
to war in crisis situations. These three causal mechanisms are not mu

tually exclusive; rather, it may be that economic interdependence pro


motes peace through multiple channels.
The purpose of this essay is to reconsider, within the context of
this broader international relations literature, whether growing Main
land China-Taiwan

economic integration affects the likelihood of a


cross-Strait military confrontation. Each of the causal mechanisms out
lined above specifies a process, with observable implications, through
which growing economic ties yield a reduced likelihood of military vi
olence. I assess the extent to which these different causal processes are
operating across the Taiwan Strait. My conclusions suggest that caution
is warranted when considering the impact of economic integration on
the prospects for cross-Strait peace. While it may be that economic in

This content downloaded from 203.78.9.149 on Wed, 11 Nov 2015 13:00:02 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Scott L. Kastner

321

tegration across the Strait makes a military confrontation less likely, I


show that the evidence in support of such a proposition remains quite
ambiguous.

How
Lead

Might Economic
to Peace?
Three

Interdependence
Causal Arguments

The liberal argument that trade promotes peace has a long history, and a
series of recent works by John R. Oneal and Bruce Russett have con
firmed statistically that trade, along with democracy and international or
ganizations (the "Kantian tripod"), is correlated with a reduced likeli
hood of military violence between countries.5 But the idea that economic
ties facilitate peace remains controversial. Realist scholars sometimes
note, for example, that bilateral economic ties typically represent only a
small fraction of any two countries' economies; this is especially the case
with great powers, which typically have large internal markets and a
wide array of trading partners. Economic ties are thus unlikely to have
much of an impact on state behavior, particularly when great powers
compete over important issues.6 Others argue that economic interde
pendence can actually provoke conflict because economic ties cause new
frictions to develop between countries,7 and still others suggest that eco
nomic patterns are more likely a reflection of existing political relations

than an important determinant of those relations.8 Meanwhile, a number


of recent quantitative9 and carefully designed qualitative studies10 call
into question on empirical grounds the commercial liberal argument.11
As Edward Mansfield and Brian Pollins write, a growing number of

studies are advancing the debate by focusing more squarely on the con
ditions under which economic ties have an effect. That is, they ask not if
interdependence leads to peace but rather when it does, and
thus focus on the variables that might intervene in the relationship be
tween economic ties and conflict.12 This focus on boundary conditions
economic

serves to highlight the probability that economic integration does not al


ways lead to pacific political relations. And given that the effect is not
universal, if we are to have any ability to predict whether economic ties
will have a pacific effect in a particular caselike the relationship across
the Taiwan Straitit becomes imperative to have a clear understanding
of the microfoundations underlying any relationship that might exist be
and conflict. In other words, simply knowing that
ties
are present in a particular case should not convince
economic
strong

tween commerce

This content downloaded from 203.78.9.149 on Wed, 11 Nov 2015 13:00:02 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

322

Does

Economic

Integration

Make

Conflict Less Likely?

us that the likelihood of a military confrontation is therefore reduced in


that case. Rather, it would be better to be able to observe whether or not
the causal processes that link economic interdependence to a reduction
in military violence are operating in that case. Existing studies have
identified at least three non-mutually exclusive causal mechanisms
through which economic interdependence can yield a reduced probabil

ity of military conflict.


First, economic ties can act as a constraint on state leaders. Be
cause war is likely to be disruptive to trade and investment flows, the
expected costs of war rise as international economic flows increase.
Commercial

disruptions can impart substantial adjustment costs on na


tional economies; such disruptions could also be especially damaging
to business interests with strong political clout. Leaders should there

fore be less likely to risk military violence with countries with which
their home state is integrated economically.13 These sorts of constrain
ing effects may be more likely to take place in democracies, which pro

vide actors who benefit from trade with clear paths through which to
influence the political process;14 leaders in authoritarian states who
draw support from internationalist economic interests may also be
more susceptible to these effects.15
A second, less prominent, causal argument suggests that commer
cial integration can transform state preferences. Here, international eco
nomic ties push issues that previously had threatened to spark war down

the hierarchy of state goals. On the one hand, when two states have a
high level of economic integration, actors within their respective soci

eties will come into greater contact with each other and will interact on
a much larger scale. In this environment, they may come to view their
interests as shared and to see prior goals as less important than before.
Leaders, in turn, will over time respond to these transformed societal

preferences.16 On the other hand, international economic ties can spark


coalitional change at the domestic level, because groups with a vested
interest in foreign economic ties grow larger and more powerful than be
fore. These groups, in turn, are less likely to value foreign policy goals,
like territorial expansion, that can propel countries into military conflict.
If economic

integration is extensive, these prointernational coalitions


will grow large and will have the ability to influence state goals and per
haps effect a change in the makeup of the governing coalition itself.17

Military conflict then becomes less likely not simply because it is more
costly (as seen in constraint arguments), but because coalitional change
yields new leaders that place less emphasis on the clashing goals that

had threatened to lead to war to begin with.18

This content downloaded from 203.78.9.149 on Wed, 11 Nov 2015 13:00:02 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Scott L. Kastner

323

A third causal argument, relatively new, focuses on the added in


formation that can be communicated in the presence of economic inte
gration. The argument is an effortto deduce a causal link between com
merce and military conflict in a way that is consistent with bargaining
models of war.19 In these models, disputes sometimes escalate to mili

tary confrontations because it is difficult for the states involved to know


how committed the other side is to the issues at hand. As such, each
side has an incentive to overstate its commitmentor resolvein the
hope that the other side will concede more than it otherwise might; in
other words, both sides have incentives to bluff. Wars can occur when
one state believes the other to be bluffing, when in fact the other state
is highly resolved.
Consider

a hypothetical example concerning the Taiwan Strait.


Clearly, no Chinese leader wishes Taiwan to become independent. Un
fortunately, it is difficult for leaders in Taiwan to determine just how res

olute Beijing is on the issue; whether they mean it or not, all Chinese lead
ers have a strong incentive to say that they will fight a war to block
Taiwanese independence so as to deter the island from choosing that path.
Suppose, now, that a leader in Taiwan believes Beijing to be bluffing
knowing it has an incentive to do soand goes ahead and declares inde

pendence. If China was actually sincere in making the threatmeaning


that Beijing is in fact highly resolved to check Taiwan independence
then the declaration of independence provokes a war. War arises in this

scenario because it is difficult for Beijing to credibly communicate its true


level of resolve on the independence issue. The outcome is clearly sub
optimal: both sides would have been better off had Beijing found a way

to communicate its true level of resolve credibly, since war is costly.


To overcome this problem, states that are truly resolute try to sig
nal that resolve by demonstrating a willingness to pay costs in order to
achieve a favorable outcome. By sending costly signals, states convey
information; since states that lack resolve are by definition unwilling to
pay costs to achieve a favorable bargaining outcome, a willingness to
send costly signals increases the likelihood that a country will be per
ceived as resolute, rather than as bluffing. Economic signaling argu
ments that link economic interdependence to peace suggest that high
levels of economic

integration make it easier for countries to send


allow
them to communicate resolve credibly. Absent
costly signals that
economic integration, nonmilitary signals are relatively uninformative
because

verbal threats or economic sanctions are cheap, meaning a


state that is bluffing could issue such signals at relatively little cost. As
economic integration deepens on a bilateral level, however, it becomes

This content downloaded from 203.78.9.149 on Wed, 11 Nov 2015 13:00:02 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

324

Does

possible

Economic

for a country

Integration

to impose

Make

economic

Conflict Less Likely?

sanctions

that

are

costly.

In

tegration into global markets more generally means that a country's


tough talk is no longer cheap, because it scares international investors
away. Economic integration, then, gives states more ways to demon
strate their true level of resolve in a credible fashion without having to

resort to military action, thus reducing the likelihood that a war would
arise because one state miscalculates the resolve of another.20
Each

of these three causal pathways linking economic interde


to
pendence
peace suggests a mechanism through which growing eco
nomic interaction across the Taiwan Strait could reduce the likelihood
of a cross-Strait military confrontation. But is there any evidence that
one or more of these causal processes are actually at work in Mainland
China-Taiwan

relations? If so, then we might feel more confident that


growing economic integration is indeed a stabilizing force in the cross
Strait relationship. However, if such evidence is lacking, then a more
cautious attitude would be warranted. I consider the issue more sys
tematically in the sections that follow.

Do

Economic

Constraint
The

constraint

Ties

Act as a

in Cross-Strait
argument

Relations?

suggests

that, as economic

integration

across

the

Taiwan Strait deepens, leaders in both Beijing and Taipei should become
more hesitant in pursuing policies that might trigger a strong response
from the other side, because they become more sensitive to the economic
consequences of conflict. Though the argument should applyperhaps

by varying degreesto both sides, space limitations lead me to focus


here on Taiwan. My choice of Taiwan, rather than the Mainland, is driven
by a theoretical expectation that constraining effects should be more
prevalent in Taipei, for at least two reasons. First, asymmetries in cross
Strait economic relations suggest that Taiwan's economy should be more
sensitive to disruption than Mainland China's. Cross-Strait trade repre
sents a much larger share of Taiwan's economy simply because China's
economy is much larger. Moreover, while Taiwan's approved direct in
vestments in China now represent more than two-thirds of the island's
total outward direct investment flows, those same investments represent
less than 15 percent of the foreign direct investment flowing into China.21
Second, some recent studies suggest that constraining effects are most
likely to occur within democracies. As Christopher Gelpi and Joseph

This content downloaded from 203.78.9.149 on Wed, 11 Nov 2015 13:00:02 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Scott L. Kstner

325

Grieco write, because democratic leaders are accountable to large selec


torates, "it is especially in democracies that the delivery of a public pol

icy success such as economic growth is likely to play an important role


in affecting the tenure of leaders."22 There is thus reason to believe that,
if cross-Strait economic

integration does indeed act as a constraint in


cross-Strait political relations, these constraining effects should be espe
cially evident in Taiwanese policy (though a more extensive study would
ideally consider both Beijing and Taipei in this regard, as in principle the
constraint argument clearly appliesat least to some extentto both).
An initial, cursory examination suggests that the constraint logic
does not mesh well with some broad trends in the cross-Strait relation
ship. As Yun-han Chu has written, cross-Strait relations represent a
"perplexing duality" characterized by "the concurrent processes of eco
nomic convergence and political divergence";23 such dichotomous ten
dencies, moreover, have only intensified since Chu made those obser
vations.24 At the root of cross-Strait political tensions is the issue of
Taiwan's

sovereign status. Beijing views reunification as a core long


term objective and has threatened to go to war to prevent legal Taiwan
both current
independence. But recent Taiwanese leadersincluding
president Chen Shui-bian and former president Lee Teng-huihave,
since the early 1990s, been more assertive of Taiwan's sovereign sta
tus, and Mainland Chinese leaders worry that their ultimate aim is in
dependence. Such assertiveness has occurred despite rapidly growing
cross-Strait economic integration since the late 1980s (see Figure 1).
During the 1990s, President Lee Teng-hui embarked on "a concerted
effort to establish a separate international identity" for Taiwan,25 a pol

icy that became especially clear when Lee took a highly publicized trip
to Cornell University in 1995which in turn precipitated a serious cri
sis in cross-Strait relations. Lee risked another crisis in 1999 when he an

nounced that prior changes to the Republic of China (ROC) constitution


established the Beijing-Taipei relationship as "state-to-state, or at least
special state-to-state relations." The move provoked outrage in Beijing,
which viewed the announcement as a step toward formalizing Taiwan's
de facto independent status. Cross-Strait relations initially stabilized
after the election of Democratic Progressive Party (DPP)26 candidate

Chen Shui-bian as Taiwanese president in spring 2000: at his inaugura


tion, Chen announced that his administration would follow a policy of
"5 No's," which included no official independence for Taiwan, no pub
lic referendum on the issue of independence, no change in the ROC's
name, no adding the "special

state-to-state" relations formula into the

This content downloaded from 203.78.9.149 on Wed, 11 Nov 2015 13:00:02 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Does Economic IntegrationMake ConflictLess Likely?

326

Figure

Trade

and

Investment

Trade(billionUS$)

Flows

Across

the

Taiwan

Strait

Year
million
TaiwanInvestments
(hundred
US$) I

Note: This figure is based on official Taiwanese statistics, available from the Mainland
Investment numbers likely underreport actual flows by a
Affairs Council (www.mac.gov.tw).
substantial margin, since much Taiwanese investment in China is not reported to the Taiwan
government.

ROC constitution, and no scrapping of the National Unification Council


(which had been established in the early 1990s). However, Chen's poli
cies

toward

economic
ample,

China

more

grew

Chen

suggested

provocative

over

time,

a formula

for cross-Strait

relationsone

the

as

bilateral

island's

sovereignty

than

Lee's

country

appeared to go farther

on each side of the Strait (yi bian, yi guo)which


in asserting

even

extremely rapidly after 2001. In 2002, for ex

ties expanded

state-to-state

argument

that had enraged Beijing in 1999. Chen's decision to hold a referendum


on issues relating to Taiwan's national security at the same time as the
2004

Taiwan

nounced

presidential election

intention

to revise

termination of Taiwan's

the ROC

National

(which ultimately failed), his an


and

constitution,

Unification

more

Council

recently

his

have likewise

been viewed by Beijing as highly provocative.27 On the surface, these


trends

seem

to call

into

question

the extent

to which

growing

cross-Strait

economic ties act as a constraint on Taiwanese

policymakers.
the
absence
of
a
counterfactual
makes it nearly im
Unfortunately,
inference
from
these
broad
trends. In the
to
draw
meaningful
possible

context of a single case, it is not feasible to hold all else constant while
assessing the marginal effect of growing economic ties; as such, Tai
wan's policies are consistent with multiple explanations. For example, it

This content downloaded from 203.78.9.149 on Wed, 11 Nov 2015 13:00:02 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Scott L. Kastner

327

is possible that Taiwan's policies are more consistent with the constraint
argument than they appear at first glance. Indeed, it may be that a newly

democratic Taiwan would have been even more forceful in asserting its
sovereignty had it not been for the constraining influence of economic
integration with China. Meanwhile, it is also conceivable that economic
integration has the effect of making Taiwan's policies more provocative
from Beijing's standpoint: since economic integration raises the costs of

military conflict for both Taiwan and Mainland China, Taiwanese lead
ers know that Beijing will be less willing to resort to force, and as such
the island can get away with more.
To sort through these different possibilities, it would be useful, as
Norrin Ripsman and Jean-Marc Blanchard write, to consider the willing

ness of Taiwan "decision makers to run the risk of war in moments of


heightened crisis."28 Is there any evidence that Taiwan's leaders, during
moments of heightened tensions, have tempered their policies toward
Beijing out of worry that a cross-Strait military confrontation would be
detrimental to the cross-Strait economic relationship? Or, alternatively, is
there evidence that they have completely disregarded such concerns? I
focus here on one episode in particular: Lee Teng-hui's July 1999 char
acterization of cross-Strait relations as "special state-to-state."
Chinese officials reacted strongly to Lee's announcement, empha
sizing that Lee was "playing with fire."29 Chinese president Jiang

Zemin, in a telephone conversation with US president Bill Clinton,


warned that Lee's statement was "a very dangerous step ... toward split
ting the country," that he should "rein in at the edge of the precipice,"
and that Beijing would not abandon the possibility that it would resolve
the issue with military force.30 China put its ground forces on height

ened combat readiness beginning July 13; at the same time, Mainland
fighters began conducting more frequent air exercises near the Taiwan
Strait. The Chinese

navy also conducted exercises during August and


September.31 China clearly hoped to signal to Lee that his new formula
tion for cross-Strait relations was risking a military confrontation with
the Mainland.
However, rather than back down in the face of Beijing's response,
Lee stuck with his new formulation. In Lee's public statements, there is
no indication that he viewed cross-Strait economic ties as a constraint
or that he was deterred by the potential economic losses that Taiwan
would suffer if the crisis were to escalate to armed conflict. In fact, Lee
was openly dismissive of the possibility his actions would lead to a mil
itary conflict; when asked by reporters in August 1999 whether military
conflict was likely, Lee smiled and said "Don't worry!"32 The chairman

This content downloaded from 203.78.9.149 on Wed, 11 Nov 2015 13:00:02 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Does Economic IntegrationMake ConflictLess Likely?

328

Mainland Affairs Council at the time, Su Chi, likewise


not
mention
the cross-Strait economic relationship as a constrain
does
ing factor in his own recent account of the episode.33
of Taiwan's

Interestingly, to the extent that Taiwanese officials referenced the


economic consequences of a military confrontation with China at all
during this crisis, it was to emphasize the economic costs that Mainland
Chinanot Taiwanwould
pay For example, Lee highlighted China's
problems as he downplayed the chances Beijing would
"willy-nilly take action against Taiwan."34 Taiwan's defense minister at

economic

the time, Tang Fei, similarly argued that for the Mainland, "using force
would be a last resort, because [China is] concerned about international

pressure and economic growth."35 These sorts of comments suggest that


it increases the
increasing cross-Strait economic integrationbecause
costs of war for Chinamay actually encourage Taiwanese leaders to
adopt more provocative policies than they otherwise might. Indeed,
since his presidency ended in 2000, Lee Teng-hui has been quite explicit
in promoting this underlying logic: that increased costs of war for China

allow Taiwan more leeway on the issue of the island's sovereignty. For
example, he has pushed for a new constitution and a change in the is
land's official name, suggesting that a window of opportunity exists be
tween now and 2010 to do so. Beijing, he argues, will be preoccupied

with the 2008 Olympics and the 2010 Shanghai Expo, both of which are
important
such,

to

it won't

China's
dare

economic
start

a war

prospects
because

doing

and
so

international
would

be

status;
too

as

costly.36

statements clearly suggest that he believes economic factors


do act as a constraint on the willingness of Chinese leaders to go to war.
However, even if Lee is correct in this assessment, the effect on the un
Lee's

derlying probability of war remains indeterminate: if Taiwan is willing


increased reluc
to exploit an (economic interdependence-induced)
tance to fight a war on the part of China by moving farther in the di
rection of independence, then the decrease in China's resolve can be
negated by increased dissatisfaction with Taiwan's policies.37 Lee's

public statements suggest that he was quite willing to exploit perceived


increases in China's costs of war by pushing farther in the direction of
independence than he otherwise might. This logic, incidentally, is not
lost on Beijing: Mainland leaders appear to be quite aware that factors
increasing the potential costs of war for China may also make it easier
for Taiwan to drift toward independence. As such, they have tried to
downplay the costs of war relative to the importance that they place on
the Taiwan issue, declaring that they are willing to pay "any costs" to
check Taiwan independence.38

This content downloaded from 203.78.9.149 on Wed, 11 Nov 2015 13:00:02 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Scott L. Kastner

329

Nonetheless, I do not wish to overstate this point. I am certainly not


suggesting that growing cross-Strait economic integration is a primary
cause of Taiwan's stance on the sovereignty issue; other factors, like
domestic political dynamics in Taiwan, are far more important. Fur
thermore, I have only presented evidence from a single episode. It is
not at all clear, for example, that current president Chen Shui-bian
shares Lee's views in this regard (I have uncovered no evidence that he
does), and it is certain that the current leadership of the Kuomintang
(KMT) does not; the following section considers events under Chen
more fully in the context of transformation arguments.
More fundamentally, constraining effects can also rise indirectly in
democracies, through voters who might punish leaders who endanger
the economy by adopting risky foreign policies. Such an indirect con
straint mechanism does not necessarily preclude leaders from occasion
ally ignoring international economic flows when making foreign policy
decisions; rather, it suggests that such leaders are likely to be punished
by voters in polls and elections. Over time, such a process should lead,
on balance, to a less provocative foreign policy, though not necessarily
in a linear fashion where growing economic ties lead directly to propor
tionately fewer provocations.39 And there is certainly some evidence
that such a process could be under way in Taiwan: most Taiwanese are
opposed to risk taking in relations with the Mainland, and voters have
expressed considerable dissatisfaction with Chen Shui-bian's recent

cross-Strait policies.40 Ultimately, to dismiss with any confidence the ar


gument that economic interdependence-induced constraints reduce the
probability of a cross-Strait war, it would be necessary to show that
Lee's statements in 1999 and after are not an aberration. In isolation,
Lee's 1999 behavior only provides some reason for skepticism.

Mainland

China-Taiwan

Prospects

for Preference

Economic

and
Relations
in Taiwan

Transformation

mechanism linking economic integration to peace


centers on preference transformation. The argument, if valid here, sug
gests that increasing economic integration between Mainland China
and Taiwan should facilitate harmonization in the foreign policy objec
The second causal

tives of leaders in Beijing and Taipei. That is, unlike constraint argu
ments, which assume static preferences but a changed cost/benefit
structure, transformation arguments suggest that economic integration
can yield changes in the preferences of foreign policy decisionmakers.

This content downloaded from 203.78.9.149 on Wed, 11 Nov 2015 13:00:02 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

330

Does

Economic

Integration

Make

Conflict Less Likely?

Such change might arise via broad public opinion shifts brought on by
increasing societal contacts. Alternatively, cross-Strait commerce
might empower new coalitions less interested in sovereignty issues and
more interested in stability and trade. In this section, I focus on the Tai
wan side for the same basic reasons I did when considering constraint

arguments: since cross-Strait commerce represents a bigger portion of


Taiwan's economy than the Mainland's, any transformative effects that
arise are more likely to materialize in Taiwan first. As with the con
of transformative effects in

straint logic described above, evidence


cross-Strait relations remains ambiguous.

Growing commercial relations across the Taiwan Strait have cer


tainly led to greatly increased societal contacts between Mainland
China and Taiwan, and some argue that these contacts lay the basis for
future political reconciliation (and perhaps reunification).41 And as
Chien-min Chao notes, economic exchanges to some extent "spilled
over" into politics during the 1990s. Chao links the formation of Tai
wan's Straits Exchange Foundation and Beijing's Association for Rela
tions Across the Taiwan Strait, and their subsequent quasi-official ne
gotiations in the early 1990s, to a need to manage growing cross-Strait
exchanges.42 These sorts of political contacts, over time, can potentially
have a transformative effect by facilitating a sense of shared commu
nity.

Unfortunately,

"special

state-to-state"

these

talks

statement,

ended
and

abruptly
they

have

after

Lee

not resumed

issued
under

his
the

Chen administration.
Moreover, as Chao emphasizes, growing economic exchanges and
personnel flows across the Taiwan Strait have not been correlated with
public support in Taiwan for reunification with the Main
land.43 For example, most Taiwanese (approximately 61 percent) fa
vored maintaining the status quo in cross-Strait relations when polled
increased

in 1997, and the same percentage held that position in 2004.44 At the
same time, support for the Mainland's "one country, two systems" for
mula has remained consistently low. Furthermore, the percentage of
Taiwan citizens who consider themselves to be Taiwanese, and not Chi
nese, has grown in recent years. One poll discovered that in 1992, 26
percent of respondents considered themselves "Chinese," 17 percent
considered themselves "Taiwanese,"
and 45 percent answered "both
those
Chinese and Taiwanese."
2005,
By
answering "Chinese" had
dropped to 7 percent, while those answering "Taiwanese" had risen to
47 percent, even more than those answering "both" (42 percent).45
Of course, the same problems of making comparisons to a counter
factual, emphasized

in the previous section, apply here as well. Indeed,

This content downloaded from 203.78.9.149 on Wed, 11 Nov 2015 13:00:02 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Scott L

Kastner

331

it may be that burgeoning economic ties across the Taiwan Strait have
slowed the development of a separate Taiwanese identity. This point is
made by Yun-han Chu: though he concludes there is little evidence that
economic

integration is transforming Taiwan public opinion in a deci


sive way toward a prounification consensus, he does argue that growing
economic integrationand the changed image of China as a vibrant
economy to which Taiwan's future will be hitchedhas acted as a brake
on the growth in a separate Taiwan identity.46And even though the per
centage of Taiwan citizens self-identifying as exclusively "Taiwanese"

has grown in recent years, most Taiwan citizens continue to oppose the
adoption of policies that might trigger war with China (as noted in the
previous section).47
While evidence of broad economic interdependence-induced opin
ion shifts in Taiwan remains, in my opinion, quite limited, it is nonethe
less clear that expanding cross-Strait economic ties have generated a
growing constituency in Taiwan with a direct stake in the cross-Strait
economic
advocated

relationship. Moreover, this constituency has, by and large,


a foreign policy less confrontational toward China than that

of the current Taiwan leadership. The Taiwanese government estimates


that roughly 1 million Taiwanesemostly
and their
businesspeople
familiescurrently live in Mainland China,48 while a 2004 Ministry of
Economic Affairs poll found that nearly 77 percent of Taiwan manu
facturers have investments in Mainland

China.49 A recent media poll


likewise found that a majority of Taiwan-listed and over-the-counter
companies surveyed had invested in Mainland China in 2002.50 The
poll found that 80 percent of those surveyed believed that economic
and political relations across the Taiwan Strait are closely related and
that improved political relations are essential for Taiwan's economy.
Meanwhile, 73 percent supported resumption of cross-Strait talks
under the rubric of the 1992 consensus.51
Anecdotal evidence tells a similar story. Business leaders often em
phasize the importance of maintaining good relations with the Main
land. After Chen's 2004 reelection, a spokesman for the General Cham
ber of Commerce suggested that "empowered by the people's mandate,

President Chen should strive for better cross-Strait relations."52 In the


run-up to that election, numerous Taiwan businesspeople in China ex
pressed dissatisfaction with Chen's confrontational cross-Strait policies,
many emphasizing that Chen's policies caused instability, which was
bad for the economic relationship.53 Noting that many corporations
backed Chen in 2000, the secretary-general of the Taiwan Business
men's Association

in Dongguan (a popular investment locale for Taiwan

This content downloaded from 203.78.9.149 on Wed, 11 Nov 2015 13:00:02 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Does Economic IntegrationMake ConflictLess Likely?

332

firms), concluded that "they made a mistake and they see that cross
Strait relations have only got worse in the past four years."54
Furthermore, as the constituency with a stake in the cross-Strait
economic relationship has grown, politicians in Taiwan have appealed
to that group more directly. In the 2000 presidential election campaign,
all three main candidatesChen
Shui-bian, Lien Chan, and James
the
to
cross-Strait
improve
political and economic
Soongpromised

environment. Chen, the least likely to take such a position given his
party's proindependence platform, told a group of Taiwan businesspeo
ple with interests in China that "the two sides should cooperate on a re
ciprocal basis and remove the political factors hampering their eco
nomic

that they
development."55 All three candidates emphasized
would liberalize cross-Strait investment policies and strive to open di
rect links between the two economies.56 In 2004, the pan-blue57 ticket
of Lien and Soong made even broader appeals: they promised, for ex
ample, to help build schools to educate the children of Taiwan busi
nesspeople in China so that those children would have the same educa
tion as children in Taiwan.58
Nevertheless, though Chen did liberalize investment policy early in
his first term, he has continued to pursue a political agenda clearly at
odds with Beijing, despite the opposition to that agenda from those
with

an

economic

stake

in China.

In a 2003

interview,

Chen

was

blunt

when asked about business demands for closer ties across the Taiwan
Strait: "As for the welfare of some businessmen, or politicians, or indi
viduals, these must absolutely come after the welfare of the overall na
tion."59 In part because of his cross-Strait policies, Chen's support in
the business community was more tenuous in 2004, and he ran his re
election campaign without the backing of some prominent magnates
who had supported him in 2000.60 Yet Chen's campaign was still suc

cessful; indeed, he increased his vote share from under 40 percent in


2000 to over 50 percent in 2004. Chen succeeded in part because he
was able to craft a winning coalition that included both those seeking
to build a stronger Taiwanese identity and those who are threatened,
economically, by growing commercial links with Mainland China. The
same cross-Strait policies that have managed to alienate those with in
vestments in China from Chen have likely served to increase his sup
port among protectionist interests (such as farmers and relatively un
skilled laborers) who are more concentrated in southern Taiwan.61
Whether economic integration across the Taiwan Strait will effect a
broader transformation in Taiwan's
objectives

foreign policy goals, bringing those


into greater harmony with Beijing's own goals, remains un

This content downloaded from 203.78.9.149 on Wed, 11 Nov 2015 13:00:02 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Scott L. Kastner

333

clear. However, growing economic ties have certainly generated a new


constituency in Taiwanese politics that has a vested interest in cross
Strait stability and that favors foreign policy goals that are less at odds
with Beijing than the goals of the Chen administration; this con
stituency, moreover, has clearly become an important component of the

KMT-centered pan-blue coalition.62 Though Chen Shui-bian won re


election in 2004 while making only limited appeals to actors with a
vested interest in China's economy, as cross-Strait economic ties con
tinue to develop, it is quite plausible that this constituency will become
an indispensable component for future winning coalitions in Taiwan.

The

Economic

in Cross-Strait

Signaling
Relations

Argument

The information effects of economic

interdependence can potentially


arise through two distinct processes. First, integration into global mar
kets can make threats more costly, and hence more credible, by scaring
off international investors.63 Second, economic interdependence, by
making it possible to impose costly economic sanctions, gives policy
makers a greater range of signals through which to demonstrate resolve
without resorting to war. My focus here is on this second process, since
it arises from bilateral economic

flows rather than integration into


markets
In
the
more
cross-Strait context, the argument
global
generally.
that
economic
reduces
the likelihood of war be
integration
proposes
cause Mainland China now has the ability to impose very costly eco
nomic sanctions against Taiwan, giving it the capacity to display a high
level of resolve; if it were not for extensive cross-Strait economic ties,
Mainland China would have to rely on military force to signal a simi

lar level of resolve. In other words, the argument does not predict that
crises will necessarily be less likely as a result of economic integration.
Rather, it suggests that when crises do emerge, they will be less likely
to escalate to military conflict. An examination of Mainland China's in
centives and actual signaling behavior vis--vis Taiwan, however, pro
vides reasons to be at least somewhat skeptical of the argument's rele
vance in this case.
I have already described, briefly, Mainland China's response to Lee
Teng-hui's two-states theory in 1999. Chinese leaders had responded in
a similar fashion after Lee's Cornell trip four years earlier. China un
dertook missile tests in the sea north of Taiwan in summer 1995 and in
August and November staged two large-scale military exercises. In the

This content downloaded from 203.78.9.149 on Wed, 11 Nov 2015 13:00:02 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Does Economic IntegrationMake ConflictLess Likely?

334

run-up to Taiwan's firstpresidential election in early 1996, the Mainland


undertook two more sets of military exercises, along with missile tests
only 35 kilometers off the Taiwanese coast.64 In both 1995 and 1999,
Chinese leaders canceled quasi-official talks scheduled to be held be
tween the two sides. In early 2000, moreover, Beijing issued a strongly
worded white paper that was highly critical of Lee Teng-hui. The paper
also suggested that the island's continued delay on reunification would

be a legitimate cause of war, a possibility that had not been emphasized


in previous statements on the matter.65 Both the 1995-1996
and the
1999-2000

episodes are representative of Beijing's general efforts to


signal a resolve to fight a war rather than accept a formally independent
Taiwan.
In light of the economic signaling argument, however, what is most
striking about Mainland China's signaling behavior is the extent to
which Beijing tries to avoid spillover into cross-Strait commercial rela
tions. Even as cross-Strait relations declined drastically throughout the
second half of 1995, China tried to assure Taiwanese investors that their
rights and interests on the Mainland would not be affected. For exam
ple, Association for Relations Across the Taiwan Straits (ARATS) pres
ident Wang Daohan told Taiwan investors that "although political rela
tions across

the Taiwan Straits are strained, economic and trade


...
are not strained and are still developing."66 Tang Shubei,
cooperation
then executive vice-chairman of ARATS, likewise noted that despite

tensions, "Taiwan investors' rights and interests on the Mainland are not
affected in any way."67 A similar pattern emerged during the 1999 crisis.
Deputy director of the Taiwan Affairs Office Li Bingcai remarked, for
that

example,

"no

matter

what

happens

...

we

will

continue

our

un

remitting efforts to promote the development of cross-Straits economic


relations."68

These

sorts

of assurances

appear

at least

somewhat

incon

sistent with the economic

signaling argument. Rather than take advan


of
the
increased
tage
opportunity afforded by economic integration to
send credible signals by imposing or threatening economic sanctions,
Beijing sent signals that emphasized military threats and exercises.
This pattern of separating economics from politics changed some
what after Chen Shui-bian's victory in the 2000 election. In the months
following both the 2000 and the 2004 Taiwan presidential elections,
Mainland officials targeted "green" Taiwanese businessesthose
that
had supported Chen and the DPPfor harassment.69 In spring 2000,
several prominent businesses that had supported Chen in the election
faced unexpected audits and surprise inspections in China.70 After
Chen's

win in the 2004 election, Mainland

officials were somewhat

This content downloaded from 203.78.9.149 on Wed, 11 Nov 2015 13:00:02 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Scott L. Kstner

335

more explicit, warning that China "does not welcome" green busi
nesses, while openly attacking one such business by name: the Chi Mei
Corporation of prominent Chen supporter Hsu Wen-lung.71

Nonetheless, while China's behavior here suggests a greater will


ingness to interfere in the development of cross-Strait economic rela
tions for political reasons, only a small number of prominent Chen sup
porters have been affected. Taiwan businesses in China generally

denied that they faced increased harassment after Beijing's 2004 warn
ings directed at green Taiwan investors.72 This view was echoed by the
chairman of Taiwan's Mainland Affairs Council, Joseph Wu, who em
phasized in June 2004 that Beijing had "done little to harass" pro-DPP
Taiwan businesses

in China.73 Even the Chi Mei Corporation stressed


that its operations were running normally in Mainland China.74 Cer
tainly Beijing has given no indications that its criticism of green Tai
wan businesses is a harbinger of a greater willingness to sanction Tai
wan investors in order to signal resolve. To the contrary, top Mainland
officials, in fall 2004, redoubled their efforts to reassure Taiwan busi

nesses operating in China. Politburo Standing Committee member Jia


Qinglin visited Taiwanese factories in Fujian province and encouraged
local officials to protect the rights of those investors. Director of the
Taiwan Affairs Office Chen Yunlin likewise

emphasized the impor


ties: "We must step up co-operation to
create better conditions for Taiwanese investment in the motherland."75

tance of cross-Strait economic

Vice-premier Wu Yi expressed similar sentiments in her own trip to Fu


jian province in September.76
What are we to make of Beijing's general aversion to signaling re
solve via economic sanctions against Taiwan? One possible interpreta

tion of this behavior is both straightforward and consistent with the eco
nomic signaling argument. Sanctioning Taiwanese businesses would be
extremely costly for Beijing. Sanctions would undermine an economic
relationship from which China has benefited enormously and might also
hamper China's ability to attract investment from other locations. As
such, China might view this signaling device as a last resort, something
to be used only when war is imminent. Indeed, some Chinese analysts
clearly view economic sanctions as a potentially useful coercive device

that could be deployed instead of or prior to military force. For exam


ple, a 2004 China Daily article noted that several Taiwan affairs experts
in China supported economic sanctions against Taiwan as a means to
halt the island's drift toward independence.77 A 2004 report issued by a

Chinese Academy of Social Sciences Institute of Taiwan Studies analyst


concluded that full-scale economic sanctions could paralyze Taiwan's

This content downloaded from 203.78.9.149 on Wed, 11 Nov 2015 13:00:02 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Does Economic IntegrationMake ConflictLess LikelyP

336

economy within two months and suggested that Beijing could use eco
nomic sanctions instead of war as a way of blocking Taiwanese inde
pendence.78 Hu Angang, director of the Center for China Studies at
Tsinghua University, recently echoed these sentiments by arguing that
comprehensive economic sanctions could be used to block Taiwan in
dependence: "We don't need to attack [Taiwan]. We just [need to] sus

pend trade for one week."79 To the extent that Beijing views economic
sanctions as a last-resort measure to signal resolve before undertaking a
military attack, deepening economic ties make war less likely by mak
ing this last-resort signal more credible.
But a second interpretation strikes me as equally plausible: leaders
in Beijing view economic sanctions against Taiwan as extremely unap
pealing not simply because they are costly and would damage China's
economy, but also because the nature of cross-Strait political relations
makes economic

sanctions counterproductive to Beijing's cross-Strait


is
not simply trying to deter Taiwanese independence.
policies. Beijing
China's long-term goal is reunification, and the actors in Taiwan who
would be hurt most by economic sanctionsthose businesses with a
large stake in the China marketalso happen to be, on balance, quite
pragmatic on the issue of Taiwan's sovereignty (as discussed in the pre
vious section). Ultimately, if Beijing is going to achieve its goals vis-
vis

Taiwan,

ercion

unless

it hopes

to conquer

the island

and

rule

it through

co

alone

(which would be extraordinarily costly), it needs


allies
there (or, if not allies, at least actors who might acqui
long-term
esce to Mainland authority). Taiwan businesses with Mainland invest
ments are the most obvious
stake in China.

candidates,

because

they already have a

Indeed, it is clear that Beijing has promoted cross-Strait economic


integration at least in part because it hopes to encourage the sorts of
transformative effects discussed in the previous section. A slogan com
monly used to describe Beijing's strategy in this regard is to "peddle

politics through business, to influence government through the people


[yi s hang eu zheng, yi min eu guan]."so In other words, Beijing may be
reluctant to signal resolve using economic sanctions in part because it
hopes that economic ties will ultimately have a transformativeor at
least a constrainingeffect on Taiwan politics. And such reluctance
could carry over into a serious crisis, even though such a crisisif pro
voked by Taiwanwould
indicate that economic ties had failed to
achieve

a transforming effect on Taiwanese politics. Given Beijing's


long-term goal of unification, Chinese leaders would have strong incen
tives to avoid antagonizing the Taiwan business community even in the

This content downloaded from 203.78.9.149 on Wed, 11 Nov 2015 13:00:02 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Scott L. Kastner

337

event of war. Viewed in this light, Beijing might well do its best to pro
tect Taiwanese investors even if a war were to erupt in the Taiwan Strait.

Of course, my discussion here is highly speculative. In the end, it is


probably not possible to determine, definitively, whether the signaling
logic applies in this case unless a serious cross-Strait crisis actually

erupts. Only then would it be possible to observe whether Chinese lead


ers would in fact be willing to utilize economic sanctions as a means to
signal their resolve before resorting to military force. But there is good
reason to be at least somewhat skeptical that they would.

Conclusion
While increasing economic integration across the Taiwan Strait is typ
rela
ically viewed as a stabilizing force in Mainland China-Taiwan
tions, my analysis here suggests that a more cautious attitude may be
warranted. I have considered

three distinct causal pathways through


which growing economic ties could yield a reduced likelihood of mili
tary violence in cross-Strait relations. While I did not rule out any of
the three causal pathwaysand it is quite possible that one or more is
in fact operating to reduce the probability of military conflict in the Tai
wan Straitneither did I find unambiguous

evidence in favor of any of


the three pathways.
First, I found reason to be skeptical that the constraining properties
of economic interdependence are reducing the danger of military con
flict in the Taiwan Strait. Indeed, some statements by former president

Lee Teng-hui suggest that Taiwanese leaders may paradoxically be


come marginally more willing to take a strong stance on the sover

eignty issue as deeper economic integration increases the costs of mil


itary conflict for both sides. However, my analysis did not rule out a
constraining effect either: for example, in choosing to focus on Taiwan,

I did not consider whether economic ties act as a constraint on Beijing.


Moreover, I suggested that Lee's behavior could have been an aberra
tion, and it is also possible, of course, that constraining effects have be
come more salient as economic

ties have continued to develop during

the Chen administration.


Meanwhile, though there is little reason to believe that cross-Strait
economic ties have so far induced a transformation in the foreign pol
icy goals of either China or Taiwan, there is some evidence that the
processes that could produce such a transformation may be
under way in Taiwan. Surging cross-Strait trade and investment flows
causal

This content downloaded from 203.78.9.149 on Wed, 11 Nov 2015 13:00:02 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

338

Does Economic IntegrationMake ConflictLess Likely?

have generated a growing constituency in Taiwan that has a vested in


terest in cross-Strait peace and stability. Politicians, particularly from
the pan-blue camp, have appealed directly to this constituency during
election campaigns on the island. If the number of voters and busi
nesses in Taiwan that have a stake in the cross-Strait economic rela

tionship continues to grow, it may become more difficult for politicians


who take a strong stance on the sovereignty issue to win future elec

tions in Taiwan. Here too, however, caution is warranted. Many in Tai


wan are also threatened by cross-Strait economic integration, and Chen
Shui-bian was able to win the 2004 presidential campaign in part be
cause he appealed to these voters. It is thus still too early to tell whether
a new constituency benefiting from cross-Strait economic integration
will become an essential part of future winning coalitions in Taiwanese
politics. But while such an outcome is not inevitable, an economic in
terdependence-induced transformation in the goals of Taiwanese poli

cymakers does appear to be a very plausible future possibility.


Finally, it is not clear that the causal mechanism specified in the bi
lateral version of the economic signaling argumentthat economic ties

make it possible to demonstrate resolve by imposing costly economic


sanctions, thereby reducing uncertainty that could lead to waris op
erative in the Taiwan Strait. Indeed, Mainland China has generally tried

its best to avoid signaling resolve in a way that harms cross-Strait eco
nomic ties. It is possible, of course, that Beijing is simply reserving a
signal like economic sanctions for a worst-case scenario as a last resort
before turning to military force. If so, then economic ties are in fact a
stabilizing force in cross-Strait relations for the reasons specified in the
economic signaling argument. But it is not clear that China would ever
use economic sanctions as a signal. While sanctions would undoubt
edly be a strong signal that might lead Taiwan to back down in a crisis,
such a signal would also harmand likely alienateTaiwanese
actors
in the business community, who tend to be least supportive of indepen
dence to begin with. As such, economic sanctions could be counterpro
ductive to Beijing's longer-term goal of reunification. In other words,
it is quite plausible that Beijing would try to protect Taiwan businesses

operating in China even in the event of a cross-Strait war; if so, the


processes specified in the argument would not prevent military conflict
in the Taiwan Strait.
This study seems to suggest that optimism concerning the stabiliz
ing impact of economic integration on cross-Strait relations may be
misplaced, but I do not wish to be overly pessimistic on this score.
Though I found only limited evidence that any of the causal processes

This content downloaded from 203.78.9.149 on Wed, 11 Nov 2015 13:00:02 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

339

Scott L. Kastner

linking economic integration to peace is currently operating in the Tai


wan Strait, my analysis did not rule out any of these processes, and I
also did not rule out the possibility that these effects will arise or be
come more pronounced in the future. It remains quite plausible, for ex
ample, that economic integration may come, over time, to have a trans
formative impact on Taiwanese
hence on Taiwan's
politicsand
foreign policy. Nonetheless, my analysis does suggest reason for cau
tion; at a minimum, it should not be taken for granted that economic in
tegration does indeed reduce the likelihood
confrontation.

L. Kastner

Scott
Politics

is an assistant

at the University

in the Department

professor

of Maryland,

of a cross-Strait military

Park.

College

of Government

and

the 2005-2006

During

academic
China
His

research
fellow
in the Princeton-Harvard
year, he was a visiting
and the World Program,
Woodrow
Wilson
Princeton
School,
University.
research
interests
include
international
and Mainland
political
economy

China-Taiwan
Political

relations.

His

articles

International

Studies,

have

Studies

recently

in Comparative

appeared
and

Quarterly,

Studies.

Security

Notes
For helpful
Chad

I wish

comments,
Xu

to thank Thomas

Christensen,

Stephan

Haggard,

and the anonymous


reviewers.
1. See, for example,
Tain-Jy Chen and C. Y. Cyrus Chu, "Cross-Strait
nomic Relations:
Can They Ameliorate
the Political
Problem?"
in Muthiah
Rector,

Xin,

Presidential
gappa, ed., Taiwan's
tions in the Twenty-first Century
Karen

M. Sutter, "Business

for Cross-Strait
"Growing
Paul J. Bolt,

Issues

mise,"

Asian

and

NY:

Across
42,

Survey

Economic

"Economic

Ties

Studies

and Cross-Strait

Democratization

(Armonk,

Dynamism

Relations,"

Cross-Strait

Politics:

Integration,"
Across the Taiwan

37, no. 2 (2001):

Eco
Ala
Rela

M. E. Sharpe, 2001), pp. 215-235;


the Taiwan
Strait: The Implications
no. 3 (2002):
Cal Clark,
522-540;
46, no. 4 (2002):

Orbis

Strait: Buying

80-105;

Quansheng

Time

753-766;

for Compro

Zhao,

"Beijing's

Dilemma with Taiwan: War or Peace?" Pacific Review 18, no. 2 (2005): 238;
Qingxin

Ken Wang,

in the Taiwan
111-124;

'Taiwanese

Greg Mastel,

and the Prospect

NGOs

Strait," Australian

Journal

"China,

Taiwan,

of International
and the World

"Economic

Ties";

Chen

and

Chu,

Reunification

Affairs 54, no. 1 (2000):

Trade

ingtonQuarterly24, no. 3 (2001): 45-56.


2. Bolt,

of National

Organization,"

"Cross-Strait

Economic

Wash
Rela

tions."
3. Clark,

2004

tant secretary

of state

ical

we

dialogue,

Cross-Strait

"Growing

4. In his April

Economic
on Taiwan

testimony

James

encourage

Kelly

Integration."
before

former assis
Congress,
that "in the absence
of a polit
interactions
of
to increase
bilateral

emphasized

the two

sides

This content downloaded from 203.78.9.149 on Wed, 11 Nov 2015 13:00:02 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Does Economic IntegrationMake ConflictLess LikelyP

340

sort.

every
ceeding

contacts

ple

there

Clearly,

also

may

and

See

Times,

Taipei

exchanges

no.

41,

Quarterly
sessing

Bruce

International
Oneal,

and

Peace:

Organizations

Norton,

6. John

J. Mearsheimer,

Norton,

2001);

York:
mercial

Still

Under

M.

Peace,"
and John

Russett
and

Tragedy
of Great
and Jean-Marc

Power

International

from

Evidence

1914

Politics

(New

F. Blanchard,

Ripsman

Fire:

John R. Oneal

Bruce

Interdependence,

"As

Reduces

2001).

The

Norrin

Liberalism

Russett,

Trade

of the Liberal

Effects

469-485;

Democracy,

York:

(New

Fixed

55, no. 2 (2001):

Organization

Triangulating

The

Clean:

Right:
Studies

Bruce

Specifications:
36, no. 4 (1999):
423^442;

Research

"Clear

Were

International
and

Oneal

eco
political,
mutual under

Liberals

Classical

1950-1985,"

John R.

267-294;

of Peace

Russett,

"The

Conflict,

spokesman

or misunderstand

with Alternative

Peace

Journal

Conflict,"

at increasing
to increasing

Russett,

and

2 (1997):

the Liberal

aimed

p. 1.

by pro

of transportation

with a view

1, 2006,

sides

Department

expansion

support

of miscommunication

the chances

Interdependence,

Democracy,

for both

increasing
people-to-peo
at www.state.gov/p/
online

a State

2006,

"We
the Strait

across

February
and Bruce

5. John R. Oneal

and

as follows:

cultural

The

Comments

In January

and diminishing

standing
ing."

and

benefits

links.

shipping

tensions."

links

communication
social

and

ease

eap/rls/rm/2004/31649.htm.
summarized
US policy
nomic,

be economic

would

aviation

with direct

and

1936,"

"Com

Security

Stud

ies 6 (1996/97): 4-50.


7. Kenneth

N.

Waltz,

of International

Theory

Politics

(Princeton:
9. See,

Path

to Peace

33, no.

1 (1996):
Peace?

10.

Model

66, no. 4 (2004):


and

Ripsman

of Peace
Illusion:

Research
Does

Trade

of Michigan
Omar
Press,
2002);
"Trade
Still Follows
the
Reuveny,

in a Simultaneous

of Politics

Journal

Interdependence:

Journal

The Liberal

Barbieri,

University
and Rafael

Pollins,

of Politics

for example,

See,

11. For
Gerald
Study

of Interdependence

and

1155-1179.
Liberalism

"Commercial

Blanchard,

and

and

duction,"

Recent

Journal

and

Brian

in Mansfield

Conflict:

Mansfield

Conflict:

Research,"

Mansfield

Conflict,"

D.

New

economic

linking

and

Peace:

and

Brian

Advances,

of Conflict

Assessing

of Peace

Journal

M.
Open

36,

Pollins,

"Interdependence

Pollins,

Economic

and

and

Debate

4 (1999):

Directions

for

Edward
An Intro

Conflict:

(Ann

and
in the

of Interde

834859;

Interdependence

Enduring

no.

Study

45 (2001):

and

Barbieri

Directions

"The

Questions,

Resolution

on an

New

Research

Pollins,

M.

Perspectives

interdependence

Katherine

Interdependence";

"Globalization

Edward

Future

arguments

"Economic

Barbieri,

of Trade

pendence

of various

reviews

see

Schneider,

387^104;

tional

M.

Conflict?"

Fire."

to peace,

D.

Arbor:

(Ann
Brian

G. Keshk,

Katherine

29^4-9;

Flag: The Primacy


Armed Conflict,"
Under

of Interstate

or a Source

Promote
M.

and International

for example,
Joanne Gowa, Allies, Adversaries,
Princeton
Press,
1994).
University
"Economic
for example,
Katherine
Barbieri,

8. See,
Trade

MA:

(Reading,

Addison-Wesley, 1979).

and

Interna

Arbor:

versity of Michigan Press, 2003), pp. 1-28.

This content downloaded from 203.78.9.149 on Wed, 11 Nov 2015 13:00:02 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Uni

L. Kastner

Scott

12. Mansfield
consider

and Pollins,
and Conflict."
Studies
that
"Interdependence
effects include
Dale C. Copeland,
'Trade
types of contingent
the Outbreak
of Peace:
Dtente
1970-74
and the End of the

different
and

Expectations

341

Cold War 1985-91," SecurityStudies 9, no. 1/2(1999/2000): 15-58; Christopher


Interdependence,
Gelpi and Joseph M. Grieco, "Economic
and the Liberal Peace,"
in Mansfield
and Pollins, Economic
International
and

tutions,
national

the Balance

"Trade

Trade

Blocs,

of Power:

20 (1996):

Security

Paul

pp. 4459;

Conflict,

42-76;

A. Papayoanou,

and World

Britain,

Germany,
D. Mansfield

13. This

sort of argument
liberals

Oneal,

Triangulating

dorsed

by Jacob

such

can

War

International

Conflict,"

Peace,

in the works

be found

as Richard

Cobden

I," Inter

Organiza

of nineteenth-century
see Russett and

(for an overview,
More

127-129).

pp.

Viner, International

and
Insti

and Jon C. Pevehouse,

tion 54, no. 4 (2000): 775-808.


commercial

State,

Interdependence
"Interdependence,

Edward

and International

Flows,

the Democratic

Economics

the argument

recently,

IL:

(Glencoe,

is en

Free Press,

1951),

in Solomon
William
"Con
Polachek,
p. 261. The argument is further developed
24 (1980):
and Solomon
flict and Trade," Journal of Conflict Resolution
55-78;
William

John Robst,

Polachek,

and Yuan-Ching

the Trade-Conflict
dependence:
Extending
The argument
405-422.
36, no. 4 (1999):
sett and Oneal
"Economic

Interdependence,
Economic

Pollins,

14. Papayoanou,
and

Gelpi
Liberal

Grieco,

15. Paul

A.

and

Costs,

and Oneal,

Scott

Policy
157-187.

L.

in Mansfield

Conflict,

and

127-147.

pp.

and the Balance

of Power";
and

State,

the

Peace.

Triangulating

and

Papayoanou

tial Enemy:
the U.S.
Assessing
Studies
9, no. 1/2 (1999/2000):

by Rus

see Jack Levy,

the Democratic

Interdependence,

Inter

Research

in work

analysis,

Peace,"

International
Institutions,

"Interdependence,
"Economic

Russett

Peace";

and

and

of Peace

prominently

For a critical

Opportunity

Interdependence

Journal

appears

Peace).

Triangulating

(e.g.,

"Liberalism

Chang,

Model,"

Kastner,

with

"Sleeping

of Engagement

with

the Poten

China,"

Security

16. On this version


field

of the preference
transformation
see Mans
argument,
and Conflict,"
"Interdependence
p. 3. Viner (International
to endorse
it himself, attributes this sort of
p. 261), while declining
of Cobden's
to the Manchester
school.
Some
writings
argument

and

Pollins,

Economics,
sociological
do indeed

this type of effect, though constraint


are more
arguments
suggest
1
See Richard
Political
vol.
Rout
Cobden,
(London:
Writings,

prominent.
The

Manchester

School
Karl

Elsewhere,

1960).
nication

as a condition

Karl

Deutsch

W.

lantic

Area

On the Manchester

pp. 465-466.

1995),

ledge,

and

(Princeton:

of Economics
Deutsch
facilitating

the formation

collaborators,

Political

Princeton

Commerce

and

of security

on domestic
How

of social

Press,
commu

communities.

See

the North

At

1957).

political

Trade

D. Grampp,

University

and

Community
Press,

University

Coalitions:

see William

Stanford

the importance

emphasizes

17. On the effects of commerce


Rogowski,

school,

(Stanford:

coalitions,

Affects

see Ronald

Domestic

Political

Alignments(Princeton: Princeton UniversityPress, 1989).


18. Etel
ton University

Solingen,
Press,

Regional
1998);

Etel

Orders
Solingen,

at Century's

Dawn

"Internationalization,

(Princeton:

Prince

Coalitions,

This content downloaded from 203.78.9.149 on Wed, 11 Nov 2015 13:00:02 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

and

Does Economic IntegrationMake ConflictLess Likely?

342

Conflict

Regional

and Cooperation,"

and International

dependence
economic

National

of California

ley: University

and

Press,

1945);

Relations,

rity Studies

9, no.

1/2 (1999/2000):

and Foreign

Economic

itics
Uses

of Economic

sula

Patrick

523-541.

Abdelal

British

McDonald

Trade

(Berke

and Jonathan

Kirshner,

Interests,"

S. Skalnes,

"Grand

19.

On

World Pol
Strategy in the 1930s,"
and Scott L. Kastner,
"Strategic
Policies
on the Korean
Penin
Engagement
of Peace

Research

that free trade

Erik Gartzke,

no.

tional

3 (1999):

Annual

20. Erik Gartzke,


About

(low

43, no. 5 (2006):


barriers),

protectionist

and

"War,

International

national

"How

4 (1999):

D.

Interna

1-30.
Thoughts

Gartzke

and

Externalities

Inter
Quan

Li,

of Economic
Erik

561-586;

"Economic

and Inter
Interdependence
James
55, no. 2 (2001):
391-438;

Organization

James

and

A Few

47, no. 4 (2003):

Quarterly

Affect Conflict?"

Trade

481489;

Source
of Costly
and International

Morrow,

Journal

"Assessing

of Peace

Research

36,

the Role

of Trade

as a

and Pollins, Economic


Interdependence
Arthur A. Stein, "Trade and Conflict:
Un
pp. 89-95;
and
Interstate
in
Mansfield
and
Pollins,
Strategic
Signaling,
Disputes,"
and International
On sanc
Interdependence
Conflict, pp. 111-126.

certainty,
Economic
tions

Could

Political

"Ra

Economic

Pollins,

Erik

or

3 (1995):

2002):

Just Lucky:
and

of

Organization

Theory

5 (June

pp. 96-110;

Boehmer,

International

Conflict,"

D. Morrow,

Were

Positive

Studies

Li, and Charles

Quan

Liberals

Hand:

International

Globalization,"
Gartzke,

Science

in Mansfield

Conflict,

49,

clout
Trade

Fearon,
no.

International

"Bargaining

of Political

Peace,"

and the Invisible

Peace,

Powell,

Classical

and

James

Organization

Is in the Error Term,"


Robert

"The

for example,

see,

International

Review

Interdependence

dependence

no.

"War

567-587;

Conflict,"

of war,

for War,"

Explanations

379-414;
53,

models

bargaining

Secu

Strategy

rather than trade per se, has the effect of increasing


the relative political
actors most likely to oppose
war: Patrick J. McDonald,
"Peace
Through
Free Trade?"
Journal of Conflict Resolution
547-572.
48, no. 4 (2004):
tionalist

Al

effect. See

Kahler

Journal

argues

Inter
cultivate

Grand

Miles

582-616;

Economic

sometimes

of National

Lars

119-156;

Interdependence:
the Taiwan
Strait,"

and Across

Rawi

and the Definition

Policy:

no. 4 (1998):

50,

Countries

a transforming
the Structure of Foreign

Power

Economic

"Strategy,

and Pollins,

pp. 60-85.
in order to harness

ties with other states

bert O. Hirschman,

in Mansfield

Conflict,

as costly

Princeton

in Mansfield

Signals,"

Conflict,

see also

signals,

Press,

University

rots: Transaction

David

Conflict

Costs,

Economic

Baldwin,

Daniel

1985);

Statecraft

W. Drezner,

"The

and Economic

Expectations,

(Princeton:

Trouble

with Car

Inducements,"

Se

on the Mainland

Af

curityStudies 9, no. 1/2 (1999/2000): 188-218.


21. According
fairs Council

to official
page:

investments

approved
percent

Web

of the island's

11.5 percent

Taiwan

statistics

in China

totaling

total approved

of total foreign

direct

(available
in 2004,

www.mac.gov.tw),

US$6.94

outward

investment

22.

Gelpi

Papayoanou,

and

Grieco,

Peace,"

"Economic

p. 49.

"Interdependence,

See

also

which

billion,

Institutions,

67

represented

in China

in that year, but only


(which totaled over $60

Interdependence,
Russett

government

investment

billion in 2004).
and the Liberal

the Taiwan

and Oneal,

the Democratic
Triangulating

and the Balance

State,
Peace;

of Power."

This content downloaded from 203.78.9.149 on Wed, 11 Nov 2015 13:00:02 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Scott L. Kastner

343

23. Yun-han
of Taiwan's
Mainland
Chu, "The Political
Economy
Policy,"
in Suisheng
the Taiwan
Strait: Mainland
and
China,
Zhao, ed., Across
Taiwan,
the 1995-1996
Crisis (New York: Routledge,
1999),
p. 164.
24. On these dichotomous
see also Suisheng
tendencies,
Zhao, "Economic
and

Interdependence
wan

Strait

25. Yun-han
and Yun-han
26. The

DPP

that direct

for future

precedent

1991

officially

the questions

worries

Beijing

ical

Strait,

because

it was

28. Norrin

M.

asked
referenda

referenda
widely

on

national

on Taiwanese
and

F.

29.

for example,

See,

Xinhua

Remarks,"
30.

"Jiang

"China's

News

Overcoming

and

over

Taiwan

Inter

Leader's

an Option

Taiwan,"

Against

France

Agence

July 19, 1999.

Presse,

31. 'Taiwan
British
32.

Defence

Broadcasting
"Lee Tells

33. Indeed,

Corporation
Taiwan:
Don't

Su writes

of the two-states
envoy

Worry,"

that the group

China

harmful
were

approaching

News,

responsible

viewed

critical,

argument

Daohan's

Wang

More Serious,"
Report: Threat from Beijing
Worldwide
October
31, 1999.
Monitoring,

Ministry

theory, of which he is highly


ing economic
exchangesas
land

Methodolog

Interdependence

Indignant

Re

"Qualitative

July 14, 1999.

Agency,
of Force

Use

Says

Military

referendum

voters.

and Conflict:

national Conflict, p. 315.

set

may

The

Blanchard,

Economic

innocuous,

issues

independence.

Jean-Marc

Interdependence
in Mansfield
and Pollins,

independence.

appeared

security

by Taiwanese

boycotted

Ripsman

Taiwanese

supported

in the referendum

on Economic

Hurdles,"

ment

of the Tai

Analysis
21-40.

pp.

Sense of Beijing's
Taiwan:
The
"Making
Policy Toward
Relations
the Jiang Zemin
Era," in Hung-Mao
During
Under Jiang Zemin (Boulder:
Chu, eds., China
Lynne Rien

has since

27. Though

search

the Taiwan

Chu,

ner, 2000), p. 205.

failed

A Background

Divergence:
Across

of Cross-Strait

Prospect
Tien

Political

in Zhao,

Crisis,"

12, 1999.

August

for crafting

cross-Strait

for Taiwan.

As

to interfere

with

the two-states

exchangesinclud
if the announce

such,

events

such

this would

trip to Taiwan,

as Main

not be a bad

thing.See Su Chi, Weiji bianyuan: Cong liangguolun dao yibian yiguo (Taipei:
Tianxia, 2003), p. 85.
34.

Taipei

35.

Times, August
31,
Taipei
See Taipei
Times, October

36.

37. The
Affect
dence

and

40.

International
Xuetong,

thank

S. Niou,

p. 1.

p. 4.
p. 1.

13, 2003,

that developed
Li,

and

in Morrow,

Boehmer,

"How

Could

"Economic

Trade

Interdepen

Conflict."
of the Policy

"Origins
China
one

Taiwanese

cent are opposed

1999,

in Gartzke,

Strategy
reviewer

an anonymous

For example,

dents support
M.

and

Independence.'"
39.1

10, 1999,

September

here parallels

logic

Conflict?"

38. Yan
wan's

Times,

recent

for making
found

Price

Any

July 20,

to Contain

2004,

72 percent

be achieved

of respon

peacefully,

73 per

See Emerson
trigger a war with China.
and
Its
Policy
Implications,"
Independence

would

Taiwan

Tai

pp. 39-42.

this point.

that, while

if it could

independence

if independence

"Understanding

study

to 'Pay

Newsletter,

This content downloaded from 203.78.9.149 on Wed, 11 Nov 2015 13:00:02 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Does

344

Asian

no.

44,

Survey

Chen's

Economic

recent

4 (2004):
one

policies,

Make

Integration

voter unhappiness
Regarding
that only 15 percent supported

555-567.
found

survey

Conflict Less Likely?

with
Chen

Shui-bian's 2006 decision to abolish the National Unification Council, while 57


would
percent were at least a little worried that the decision
Poll conducted
sion in cross-Strait
relations.
by the local TV
able

online

cause

increased

station

ten
avail

TVBS,

at www.tvbs.com.tw/FILE_DB/DL_DB/sophia_tsai/200602/sophia

_tsai-20060209124200.pdf (accessed June 21, 2006). Meanwhile, Chen's ap


even before the first family became
engulfed
plummeting
and electoral
Robert Ross attributes recent public opinion

proval ratings began


in scandal
allegations.
setbacks

for Chen

and

the DPR

in part to the KMT's

(KMT),
Chen's

continued

dence

Movement,"
41.

See,

42.

Chien-min

China

Foreign

Chao,
Poll

Robert

Party
by the Nationalist
the Mainland
(in contrast to
'Taiwan's

Ross,

85, no. 2 (2006):

Fading

Indepen

141-148.

NGOs."

Economic

to a Congenial

"Economic

successes

to engage

"Taiwanese

Wang,
"Will

Chao,

2 (2003): 285-286.
44.

See

Affairs

for example,
Lead

recent

willingness

provocations).

and Taiwan
43.

and

Between

Integration

Political

Culture?"

Asian

Mainland

Survey

43, no.

Integration."

conducted

for the Mainland

Affairs

Council

(www.mac.gov.tw).

The

61 percent who favored


the status quo includes
both those who say they
want to maintain
and those who want to maintain
the
the status quo indefinitely
status quo for now and decide
sometime
in the future which path to pursue.
45.

See

in

"Changes

the

Taiwanese/Chinese

of Taiwanese

Identity

Tracked

in Surveys
National
by the Election
Study Center,"
Chengchi
available
at http://esc.nccu.edu.tw/eng/data/data03-2.htm.
sity, Taiwan,
cites other polls that point to similar trends.
("Economic
Integration")
46.

Yun-han

Cross-Strait
that members
view

nese,

Asian

National
44,

Survey

younger
generation
as both Chinese
and Taiwanese:

under

are more

likely than others to


for example,
58 per
as both Taiwanese
and Chi

in 2002,

thirty-five saw themselves


who identified
themselves

age

to 35 percent
compared
47. See note 40.
48.

Far

Economic

Eastern

Review

(FEER),

only

as Taiwanese.
p. 23.

19, 2004,

February

49. Taipei Times, November 13, 2004, p. 10.


50.

The

Government's

poll

was

conducted

Mainland

by TVBS.

Policy:

See

Legislators,"

"Business

Dissatisfied

Central

Taipei

News

April 25, 2002. In Foreign Broadcast Information Service-China


China), April 26, 2002.
51.
Central
tions

"Business
News

at Hong

Kong,

The
held

interpretation

as to what

nies

a consensus

that such

with

Dissatisfied

Agency.

1992

China"

ever

was

Government's

consensus,

that there
"one

was

Mainland

supposedly

one

means.

Chao

and the Prospect


of
Identity Politics
no. 4 (2004):
Chu notes
484-512.

of Taiwan's

themselves

cent of those

"Taiwan's

Chu,

Relations,"

as

Univer

China,
Chen

but each

(FBIS

Policy,"

reached

Shui-bian's

with
Agency,

side

Taipei

in negotia
had

its own

government

reached.

52. Taipei Times, March 21, 2004, p. 24.

This content downloaded from 203.78.9.149 on Wed, 11 Nov 2015 13:00:02 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

de

Scott L. Kastner

345

53. See, for example,


remarks by Yangda
Air Conditioning
man
general
in "Investors
Commercial
Ties with China
Fu
ager Liu Zhenlong,
Say Close
ture of Taiwan,"
March
In FBIS
16, 2004.
France-Presse,
Hong Kong Agence

China, March 17, 2004.


54.

South

55.

'Taiwan

Presidential

Agence

France-Presse,

China,"
56.

South

57.

The

coalition

China

China

58.

The

businesses

Lien-Soong

in China)

is blue.

coalition

is called

politics

The

DPP-centered

because

the DPP's

printed a pamphlet
list of promises.

campaign

that had

a long

Business

Ties

with

p. 11.

12, 2000,

in Taiwan

flag

the pan-green

for Closer

8, 2000.

March

Post,
alliance

the KMT's

because

Calls

February

Morning

p. 6.

10, 2004,

February

Candidate

KMT-centered

is called

while,

Post,

Morning

the pan-blue
mean

alliance,
flag is green.

for Taishang

(Taiwan

59. FEER, July 31, 2003, p. 12.


60.

FEER,

other

prominent

Chen

thor's

interviews

with officials
and

Taiwan's

kept

analysts,

"Sinicization

Chen,

Ming-chi
Integration

and

and

2004

of the Evergreen
Yung-fa,

March

Times,

in 2000

supporters

head

Chang

shipping
company),
Lien in 2004.
Taipei

but endorsed

61.

The

largest

2000

nomic

p. 22.

19, 2004,

February

tion (Taiwan's

20,

a lower

Chen

in 2004.

profile

in

p. 5. Some

2004,

Au

June 2004.

Taipei,

Its Discontents:

Presidential

Corpora

supported

Cross-Strait

Eco

and

Issues

Election,"

Stud

ies 40, no. 3/4 (2004): 334-341.


62.

for example,

See,

63. Integration
sons

other

that China

and

was

(PNTR)
authors
harm
gress

would

hence

more

(New

Taiwan

York:

PNTR.

approve

to Taiwan.

Reduce

International

and

Katherine

Rowman

64. Sheng

States

This

the US

Taiwan
against
and hence
make

danger
Erik Gartzke

See

eds.,

& Littlefield,

2003),

Dilemma:

and

pp.

relations

Organization.
at the time
it less

Quan
Petter
and

Globalization

at the

Congress
trading

the threats

in Nils

Conflict,"

Barbieri,

China's

Lijun,

a military

made

for rea

Li

normal
permanent
to enter the World Trade
directed

credible

argue, for example,


confrontation
during the

in part because

in the United

image

and

more

China

prepared
threats

Movement."

Independence
threats

Gartzke

to avoid

able

elections

granting

that Chinese

Fading

can make

investors.

credible

Can

Schneider,

markets

scaring
were

considering
status as China

argue
China's

ization

simply
Taiwan

to the 2000

run-up
time

than

"Taiwan's

Ross,

into global

likely

The
would
Con

more
Li,

and
costly
"How
Global

Gleditsch,
Armed

Gerald
Conflict

123-140.

The Taiwan

Issue

Institute

(Singapore:

of Southeast Asian Studies, 2001); Michael D. Swaine, "Chinese Decision


making Regarding Taiwan, 1979-2000," in David M. Lampton, ed., The Mak
ing of Chinese
(Stanford:

Foreign

Stanford

and

University

65. For the white

paper,

Security

Policy

in the Era

Press,

2001),

pp. 289-336.

"Text

of PRC

White

Paper,"

of Reform,

1978-2000

in FBIS-China,

Feb

ruary23, 2000.
66. Xinhua, October 29, 1995. In FBIS-China, October 31, 1995, p. 71.
67. Tzu-li wan-pao, July21, 1995. In FBIS-China, July 31, 1995, p. 90.

This content downloaded from 203.78.9.149 on Wed, 11 Nov 2015 13:00:02 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Does Economic IntegrationMake ConflictLess Likely?

346

68.

"Official

Taiwan

Assures

Investors

of Greater

Xinhua,

Protection,"

13, 1999.
9, 1999. In FBIS-China,
September
September
69. Why "green"?
See note 57.
70. International
Herald
Tribune, June 28, 2000, p. 1 ; author's

interviews

with officials, Taipei, winter 2001.


71.

bu

Women

"Zhang

Minqing:

"Taiwan

Businessmen

'lse'

huanying

taishang,"

Renmin

Heat

from Bei

Wang, May 31, 2004 (www.people.com.cn/GB/shizheng/1026/2533052.html).


72.
jing,"

Central

Taipei

News

in Mainland
June

Agency,

China
23,

Not

2004.

Feeling

In FBIS-China,

June

24,

2004.
73. Taipei Times, June 9, 2004, p. 3.
74.

"Chi
Central

Taipei
75.

South

76.

"Wu

ation,"

Beijing

September
77.
2004

Mei's

Plant

in China

News

Agency,

China

Morning

Operating

June 7, 2004.
October

Post,

Yi Urges

Improvement
Xinwen
Zhongguo

Normally:

September

Spokesman,"

June 9, 2004.

p. 7.
Economic

22, 2004,

in Cross-Strait
She,

Group

In FBIS-China,
Trade,
13,

Cooper
In FBIS-China,

2004.

29, 2004.
"Pro-independence

Investors

Not

Welcome,"

China

Daily,

June

22,

(www.chinadaily.com.cn/english/doc/2004-06/22/content_341316.htm).

78. Ibid.

79. "China
8,

2006.

In

Economist
Taiwan

Says

Security

Trade

War Can

Research

Break

Taiwan,"

Reuters,

March

(http://taiwansecurity.org/Reu/2006/

Reuters-080306.htm).
80.
vergence,"
CNN.com,

for example,
p. 27. See also
June 6, 2001

See,

Zhao,
Willy

"Economic
Wo-Lap

Lam,

Interdependence
"The Business

and Political
of Reunification,"

(http://archives.cnn.com/2001/WORLD/asiapcf/east/

06/06/willy.reunif).

This content downloaded from 203.78.9.149 on Wed, 11 Nov 2015 13:00:02 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Di

Das könnte Ihnen auch gefallen