Sie sind auf Seite 1von 51

MA5076

Mathematics of Options, Futures,


and Derivative Securities II.

Daniel Spirn,
School of Mathematics,
University of Minnesota.

Options, Futures, Derivatives / January 28, 2008

Syllabus

Semester I

Semester II
1. Review of Black-Scholes

1. Mechanics of Futures Markets

2. Review of Greeks

2. Hedging Strategies Using Futures

3. Volatility Smiles

3. Interest Rate Markets

4. Basic Numerical Procedures

4. Determination of of Forward and Future Prices

5. Value at Risk
6. Time Series

5. Interest Rate Futures

7. Estimation of Volatilities and Correlations

6. Swaps

8. Credit Risk

7. Mechanics of Options Markets

9. Credit Derivatives

8. Properties of Stock Option Prices


9. Trading Strategies Involving Options

10. Exotic Options


11. Weather, energy, and insurance derivatives
12. More on models and numerical procedures

10. Binomial Trees

13. Martingales and measures

11. Wiener Processes and Itos Lemma

14. Interest Rate Derivatives

12. The Black-Scholes Model

15. Convexity, timing, and quanto adjustments

13. Options on Stock Indices, Currencies and Futures

16. Models of Short Rate


17. Heath-Jarrow-Morton

14. The Greek Letters

18. Swaps revisited

15. Volatility Smiles

19. Real Options

Options, Futures, Derivatives / January 28, 2008

Class Information
Lecture: Mondays & Wednesdays 5:00PM6:30PM.
Lecture Room: Vincent Hall 20
Office Hours: Mondays 3:00PM4:30PM
Office: Vincent Hall 112b
Contact: spirn@math.umn.edu & 612-625-1349
Textbook: Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 6th Edition, John Hull,
Prentice Hall.
Grade Information:
Homework:
Midterm:
Final:

Options, Futures, Derivatives / January 28, 2008

50 %
20 %
30 %

What is a derivative?

What is a derivative?
A financial instrument whose value derives from the value of underlying variables.
or
Financial instruments whose price and value derive from the value of assets underlying them. 1
or
Financial contracts whose value derive from the value of underlying stocks, bonds, currencies,
commodities, etc.

Examples:
Future contract for orange juice. Not the orange juice itself.
Option to buy/sell a stock. Not the stock itself.

Edmund Parker

Options, Futures, Derivatives / January 28, 2008

Asset Derivatives

Examples
Commodity Derivatives - Pork Bellies (Trading Places), Precious Metals
Equity Derivatives - Stocks / Bonds
Interest Rate Derivatives - Interest Rates
Currency Derivatives - Currency Exchange Rates (Yen vs. Euro)
Property Derivatives - Real Estate
Other More Exotic Derivatives

Options, Futures, Derivatives / January 28, 2008

Why trade derivatives?

Used to protect assets from drastic fluctuations


Covers many kinds of risk.
Allows access to financial instruments with considerably larger risk than
conventional assets (speculation).

Options, Futures, Derivatives / January 28, 2008

Financial instruments used in derivative transactions

Forwards

Futures

Options

Swaps

Options, Futures, Derivatives / January 28, 2008

Forward Contracts

Definition: A forward contract is an agreement to buy or sell an asset


at a certain time for a certain price. Usually traded in the OTC market.
One party assumes a long position by agreeing to buy the underlying asset
on a specified future date for a specified price.
The other party assumes a short position by agreeing to sell the underlying asset
on the same date and at the same price.

Definition: A spot contract is an agreement to buy or sell an asset today.


Spot contracts are for immediate delivery of the asset.
Common among currency derivatives.

Options, Futures, Derivatives / January 28, 2008

Futures Contracts

Similar to a forward contract - it is an agreement between two parties to buy or


sell an asset at a certain time in the future for a certain price.
However, futures are usually traded in exchanges.
Mechanisms by the exchange to guarantee that the contract will be honored.
Example: Chicago Mercantile Exchange (CME) trades futures on
commodities such as pork bellies, orange juice, copper, sugar, etc.
financial assets such as stock indices, currencies, Treasury bonds, etc.
Mechanisms for such exchanges will be explained next week.

Options, Futures, Derivatives / January 28, 2008

Options Contracts

The third type of derivative we will discuss is an options contract. These are
divided into two types:
A call option entitles the holder the right to buy the underlying asset by a
certain date for a certain price.
A put option entitles the holder the right to sell the underlying asset by a
certain date for a certain price.
Some more terminology:
The price in the contract is the strike price or the exercise price.
The date in the contract is known as the expiration date or maturity.

Options, Futures, Derivatives / January 28, 2008

10

Types of options

American options can be exercised at any time up to the expiration date.


European options can be exercised only on the expiration date.
Mathematics involved in American options is more difficult than European options.

One contract is usually an agreement to buy or sell 100 shares.

Note an option is exactly that - an option to exercise the right to buy or sell.
The holder of the option does not need to exercise the option.

Options, Futures, Derivatives / January 28, 2008

11

Participants in Options Markets

Four types of participants in the Options markets, as yet:


Buyers of calls

a long position

Sellers of calls

a short position

Buyers of puts

a long position

Sellers of puts

a short position

Selling an option is also known as writing the option.

Options, Futures, Derivatives / January 28, 2008

12

Types of derivative traders in the market

Hedgers - use derivatives to reduce risk in the market from potential future
market movements.
Speculators - trade derivatives to bet on the future direction of a market
variable.
Arbitrageurs - take offsetting positions in two or more instruments to lock in a
profit. (usually short-lived)

Options, Futures, Derivatives / January 28, 2008

13

Arbitrageurs

Third important group of traders in derivatives. Involves locking in riskless profit


by simultaneously entering into transactions in two or more markets.

Mostly possible when future prices become out of line with spot prices.
Transaction costs may gobble up most of the profit for small investments, but
large financial institutions could profit. Furthermore, arbitrage opportunities are
quickly lost.
Useful for determining the monetary value of certain derivatives.

Options, Futures, Derivatives / January 28, 2008

14

Wiener Processes and It


os Lemma

More sophisticated approach to modeling the behavior of assets underlying derivatives - view
motion as a stochastic process.
A stochastic process is a process where future evolution is described by probability distributions.
Two types: discrete-time stochastic process changes values at discrete time steps. A
continuous-time stochastic process changes value at any time.
Stochastic process can be continuous variable or discrete variable. A continuous-variable process
can take any value within a certain range. (motion of a particle in fluid). A discrete-variable
process can take only certain prescribed values. (coin flips)
Markov Process is a stochastic process where only present value of a variable is relevant for
predicting the future. Coin flips are Markovian. If we flip the coin 30 times and comes up heads 30
straight times, next flip still 50/50 chance.

Options, Futures, Derivatives / January 28, 2008

15

Normal Distribution

Let (, )(x) denote the normal distribution. Then satisfies


(x)
1

(, )(x) = e 22
2

Probability of sum of

Options, Futures, Derivatives / January 28, 2008

16

Normal Distribution

N (, ) =

(, )(s)ds

N (, )(+) = 1

Consider a random number x (0, 1) then most likely within the middle of the curve, if we undo
it.
Sums of two normal distributions mean zero is a normal distribution with mean zero and variance
thats the sum of the two variances. Proof: next time.
Options, Futures, Derivatives / January 28, 2008

17

Continuous-Time Stochastic Processes

Consider a Markov stochastic process. Suppose that the current value is 10 and the change in
its value during 1 year is (0, 1).
After two years? The change in two years is a some of two one year Markov stochastic process
with mean zero and standard deviation 1.
Therefore, the sum is
a normal distribution with mean zero and variance 1 + 1 = 2. Thus the
standard deviation is 2.
Consider now the change in the variable during 6 months. The variance of the change in the
value of the variable during 1 year equals the variance of the change during the first 6 months
plus the variance of the change during the second 6 months.
We assume they are the same. Then variance
of change during a 6-month period must be
0.5.
Thus, the standard deviation of the change is 0.5. Thus 6-month distribution is (0, 0.5).
Consider a small time step t = N1 , during which each period is an independent normal
distribution. Then sum of the variances are equal to 1, so each variance should be t.

The standard deviation then is t.

Uncertainty is proportional to square root of time.

Options, Futures, Derivatives / January 28, 2008

18

Wiener Processes

We continue letting t 0 carefully! This is called the Wiener process or Brownian motion. It is
a Markov stochastic process with mean zero and variance 1.0 per year. Therefore, it has
1. Change z during a small period of time t is

z =  t
where  has a standardized normal distribution (0, 1). Therefore, z has a normal
distribution with
mean of z = 0

standard deviation of z = t
variance of z = t.
2. Values of z for any two different short intervals of time t are independent. Therefore, z
follows a Markov process.

Options, Futures, Derivatives / January 28, 2008

19

Wiener Process cont.

Measure the value of z(T ) z(0) over a long period of time T .


View as a sum of N small changes over small time changes t, i.e.
N
X

T
i t
N =
= z(T ) z(0) =
t
i=1

where i for i {1, . . . , N } are distributed (0, 1). The is are independent of each other.
Then z(T ) z(0) is normally distributed with

mean of [z(T ) z(0)] = 0


variance of [z(T ) z(0)] = N t = T

standard deviation of [z(T ) z(0)] = T .

Options, Futures, Derivatives / January 28, 2008

20

Approximating Wiener Process

Options, Futures, Derivatives / January 28, 2008

21

Approximating Wiener Process

Options, Futures, Derivatives / January 28, 2008

22

Approximating Wiener Process

1. Expected length of the path followed by z in any time interval is infinite!


2. Expected number of times z equals any particular value in any time interval is
infinite!

Options, Futures, Derivatives / January 28, 2008

23

Wiener Process

Self-similar structure. Lies in C 0, 2 .


Options, Futures, Derivatives / January 28, 2008

24

Generalized Wiener Process

The mean change per unit time for a stochastic process is known as the drift rate.
The variance per unit time for a stochastic process is known as the variance rate.
A generalized Wiener process for a variable x can be defined in terms of dz as

dx = adt + bdz
where adt is the expected drift rate of a per unit time.
Holds since dx = adt =

dx
dt

= a. Therefore,

x = x0 + at
After time T the variable x travels T units.

Options, Futures, Derivatives / January 28, 2008

25

Generalized Wiener Process

The term b dz regarded as noise added to the system, which is b times a Wiener process.
In a small time interval t, the change x in the variable of x is given by

x = at + b t
where has a standard normal distribution.

mean of x = at

standard deviation of x = b t
variance of x = b2t.
The same argument show that the change in the value of x in any time interval T is normally
distributed with

mean of x = aT

standard deviation of x = b T
variance of x = b2T .

Options, Futures, Derivatives / January 28, 2008

26

Generalized Wiener Process

Options, Futures, Derivatives / January 28, 2008

27

It
o Process

A generalized Wiener process in which the parameters a and b are functions of the value of the
underlying variable x and t. An It
o process can be written as

dx = a(x, t)dt + b(x, t)dz


Both the expected drift rate and the variance rate of an It
o process are liable to change over time.
In a small time interval between t and t + t, the variable changes from x to x + x, where

x = a(x, t)t + b(x, t) t


Thus b2 is the variance and a is the mean during the interval between t and t + t.

Options, Futures, Derivatives / January 28, 2008

28

Process for a stock price


Discuss the process that models stock movements for a nondividend paying stock:
Expected drift
is constant
Stock price
If S is the stock price a time t, then the expected drift rate in S should be assumed to be S
for some constant parameter .
So in short period of time t the expected increase in S should be St.

Expected return =

If volatility of the stock is zero then model implies

S = St
In the limit t 0,

dS = Sdt
or

dS
= dt
S
Then

ST = S0 e
Options, Futures, Derivatives / January 28, 2008

29

Process for a stock price

Including volatility then expect: variability of the percentage return in a short period of time t is
the same regardless of the stock price. This suggests that the standard deviation of the change in
a short period of time t should be proportional to the stock price and leads to

dS = Sdt + Sdz
or

dS
= dt + dz
S

(1)

We use (1) to price stocks. Here is the volatility and is the expected return rate.
Limiting case of the random walk we saw with binomial trees.

Options, Futures, Derivatives / January 28, 2008

30

Discrete-Time Model

Discrete-time version of the model is

S
= t +  t
S

(2)

so the change in the stock value over a short period of time is

S = St + S t
Variable S is the change in the stock price S over a small interval of time t and  has a
standard normal distribution (normal distribution with = 1 and = 0).
is the expected rate of return by the stock in a short period of time t.
is the volatility of the stock price.

Options, Futures, Derivatives / January 28, 2008

31

Discrete-Time Model

Left-hand-side of (2) is the return provided by the stock in a short period of time.

Term t is the expected value of the return

Term  t is the stochastic component of the return. Variance is 2t (consistent with


the definition of volatility defined earlier).

Then S/S is normally distributed with mean t and standard deviation t, so

S
(t, t)
S

Options, Futures, Derivatives / January 28, 2008

32

Parameters

The development of the pricing model depends on and so far.


For derivatives that depend on the stock, not important to have . However, very important to
have . We saw this with binomial tree pricing.
The standard
deviation of the proportional change in the stock price in a small interval of time t

is t. The standard deviation of the proportional change


in the stock price over a relatively
long period of time T is T .

Options, Futures, Derivatives / January 28, 2008

33

It
os Lemma

An It
o process is one in which the drift and the volatility depend on both x and t. Suppose x is an
It
os process then

dx = a(x, t)dt + b(x, t)dz


where dz is a Wiener process and a, b are functions of x and t. Then x has a variance b2.
It
os Lemma states that a function G of x and t follows the following process:
!
2
G
G
G
1 G 2
dt
+
dG =
a+
+
b
bdz
x
t
2 x2
x
In particular G is an It
o process with drift rate

G
G
1 2G 2
a+
+
b
2
x
t
2 x
and variance

G 2 2
b
x
Options, Futures, Derivatives / January 28, 2008

34

It
os Lemma - formal argument

Assume G is a function of two variables x and t then we can formally take a power series expansion

G
1 2G
2G
1 2G
G
2
2
3
x +
t +
(x)
+
(xt)
+
(t)
+
O(
)
G =
x
t
2 x2
xt
2 t2
An It
o process satisfies

dx = a(x, t)dt + b(x, t)dz


where dz is a Wiener process. Then approximately (at the discrete level) we have

x = a(x, t)t + b(x, t) t.


Then returning to G we have

G
G
1 2G
2G
1 2G
2
2
3
G =
x +
t +
(x)
+
(xt)
+
(t)
+
O(
)
2
2
x
t
2 x
xt
2 t
i G
G h
=
at + b t +
t
x
t
h
i2
i 1 2G
1 2G h
2G
2
3
+
at
+
b
t
+
t
at
+
b
t
+
(t)
+
O(
)
2
2
2 x
xt
2 t
Expand out:
Options, Futures, Derivatives / January 28, 2008

35

It
os Lemma - formal argument

i G
G h
G =
at + b t +
t
x
t
h
i2
i 1 2G
2G
1 2G h
2
3
t
+
t
+
+
at
+
b
t
at
+
b
(t)
+
O(
)
2 x2
xt
2 t2

G
= tb
x
"
#
2
G
G
2 21 G
+ t
a+
+b 
x
t
2 x2
"
#
2
3
1 G
+ (t) 2 2ab
2 x2
"
#
2
2
2
G
1 G
2
21 G
3
+ (t) a
+
a
+
+
O((t)
)
2 x2
xt
2 t2
"
#
2
3
G
G
G
2 21 G
a+
+b 
t +
b t + O((t) 2 )
=
2
x
t
2 x
x

Options, Futures, Derivatives / January 28, 2008

36

It
os Lemma - formal argument

Therefore,
"
#
2
3
G
G
G
2 21 G
G =
a+
+b 
b t + O((t) 2 )
t +
2
x
t
2 x
x
Since is a normal distribution, then the variance 2 is 1. Thus 1 = E(2) (E())2 = E(2).
Therefore, the expected value of 2t is t (small fluctuations cancel out) and hence
nonstochastic! Take the limit as t 0 then get formally
"
#
2
G
G
G
21 G
dG =
a+
+b
dt
+
bdz
x
t
2 x2
x

Options, Futures, Derivatives / January 28, 2008

37

It
os Lemma: Modeling stock movements

We argued that a reasonable model of stock movements should be

dS = Sdt + Sdz
with and constants.
From Itos Lemma we can consider a process G that depends on t and S . Then
!
2
G
G
1 G 2 2
G
dG =
S +
+

S
dt
+
Sdz
S
t
2 S 2
S
so both S and G are affected by dz - the noise in the system.

Options, Futures, Derivatives / January 28, 2008

38

Lognormal Property

Recall that our model requires

dS = Sdt + Sdz
with and constants.
Define G = ln S then

1
G
=
S
S

2G
1
=

S 2
S2

G
=0
t

by It
os Lemma we have
!
2
G
G
1 G 2 2
G
dG =
S +
+

S
Sdz
dt
+
S
t
2 S 2
S

1
1 1 2 2
1
=
S + 0 +
S dt + Sdz
S
2 S2
S
!
2

dt + dz
=
2
Options, Futures, Derivatives / January 28, 2008

39

Therefore, G follows a generalized Wiener process with


2

Drift = 2
Variance = 2

Options, Futures, Derivatives / January 28, 2008

40

Lognormal Property

Therefore, the change in ln S between 0 and a future time T is normally distributed with mean
2
( 2 )T and variance 2T . Hence:

"
ln ST ln S0

T, T

or

"
ln ST ln S0 +

T, T

This implies that log of the stock price is normally distributed:


A variable has a lognormal distribution if the natural log of the variable is normally distributed.

The standard deviation of the logarithm of the stock price is T .

Options, Futures, Derivatives / January 28, 2008

41

Derivation of Black-Scholes-Merton Differential Equation

We are now in position to derive the Black-Scholes or Black-Scholes-Merton differential equation.


We build the model via a riskless portfolio, as we did for binomial trees. As for binomial trees, we
carry some stock along with shorting the option. The amount of stock changes instantaneously.
Special assumptions are required:
1. The stock price follows the process defined earlier for and :

dS
= dt + dz
S
2. Short selling of securities with full use of proceeds is permitted
3. There are no transactions costs or taxes. All securities are perfectly divisible
4. There are no dividends during the life of the derivative
5. There are no riskless arbitrage opportunities
6. Security trading is continuous
7. The risk-free rate of interest, r , is constant and the same for all maturities

Options, Futures, Derivatives / January 28, 2008

42

Derivation of Black-Scholes-Merton Differential Equation

Recall our process for a continuous stock movement modeled on an Ito process with expected gain
and volatility .

dS = Sdt + Sdz
Let f be the price of a call option that depends on S . The variable f depends, then S and t. Then
!
2
f
f
1 f 2 2
f
df =
S +
+

Sdz
S
dt
+
2
S
t
2 S
S
Recall the discrete-time analogues as

S = St + S t
and so the discrete version of It
os Lemma is:
!
2

f
f
1 f 2 2
f
S +
+
S
S t
f =
t +
S
t
2 S 2
S

Options, Futures, Derivatives / January 28, 2008

43

Derivation of Black-Scholes-Merton Differential Equation

We now build a portfolio that will eliminate the stochasticity of the process. The appropriate
portfolio (as we will see) is

-1 option
f
S
shares ( =

fu fd
S0 uS0 d

is the Delta hedge found in binomial trees)

which changes continuously over time. Let be the value of the portfolio then

= f +

f
S

and be the value of the portfolio in the time interval t then

= f +

Options, Futures, Derivatives / January 28, 2008

f
S
S

44

Derivation of Black-Scholes-Merton Differential Equation

Then

f
= f +
S
S
!
"
#
2
f
f
1 f 2 2
f
S +
+
Sz

S
t
+
=
2
S
t
2 S
S
f
+
[St + Sz]
S
"
#
2
1 2 2 f
f
+ S
=
t
t
2
S 2

Note that does not depend on dz , therefore there is no risk during time t! Thus the
portfolio must instantaneously earn the same rate of return as other short-term risk-free securities.
If it earned more than this return, arbitrageurs could make a riskless profit by borrowing money to
buy the portfolio; if it earned less they could make a riskless profit by shorting the portfolio and
buying risk-free securities. Thus:

= rt
Options, Futures, Derivatives / January 28, 2008

45

Derivation of Black-Scholes-Merton Differential Equation

where r is the risk-free rate. Then

"

f
1 2 2 f
f

+ S
t = f +
S t
t
2
S 2
S
so

f
f
1 2 2 2f
+ rS
+ S
= rf
pt
S
2
S 2

(3)

Equation (3) is the Black-Scholes partial differential equation. Any solution corresponds to the
price of a derivative overlying a particular stock.
In order to specify further what the derivative is, we use a boundary condition to constrain it.

Options, Futures, Derivatives / January 28, 2008

46

Boundary conditions for European call options:

f = max{S K, 0}
when t = T . Boundary conditions for European put options:

f = max{K S, 0}
when t = T . The portfolio created is riskless only for infinitesimally short periods.

Options, Futures, Derivatives / January 28, 2008

47

Tradeable Derivatives
Any function f (S, t) that satisfies (3) is the theoretical price of a derivative that could be traded.
If a derivative with that price existed, then there would be no arbitrage opportunities
Conversely if a function f (S, t) does not satisfy (3) then it cannot be the price of a derivative
without creating arbitrage opportunities.
Example: Let f (S, t) = eS then ft = 0, fS = eS , and fSS = eS then
ft + rSfS + 12 2fSS = rSeS + 21 2eS 6= reS . Thus this cannot be a derivative of a stock price.
On the other hand

f =

2 2r (T t)

then

2
ft = 2r f

fS =

fSS = 2
Options, Futures, Derivatives / January 28, 2008

2 2r (T t)

S2

2 2r (T t)

S3

= rSfS = rf
2 2
2
=
S fSS = f
2
48

Tradeable Derivatives

so

2 2
2
2
ft + rSfS +
S fSS = f + 2rf rf + f = rf
2
which is the Black-Scholes differential equation. This the price of a derivative that pays off
time T .

Options, Futures, Derivatives / January 28, 2008

1
ST

at

49

Black-Scholes Pricing Formulas

The Black-Scholes formulas for the price at time 0 of a European call option on a
non-dividend-paying stock and for a European put option on a non-dividend paying stock are

rT

N (d2)

rT

N (d1)

c = S0N (d1) Ke
and

p = KN (d2) S0e

ln

S0
K

ln

S0
K

d1 =

d2 =

where

2
+ r+ 2 T

2
+ r 2 T

= d1 T

and N (x) is the cumulative probability distribution function.


Options, Futures, Derivatives / January 28, 2008

50

Black-Scholes Pricing Formulas

The variables c and p are the European call and put prices, S0 is the current stock price at time 0,
K is the strike price, r is the continuously compounded risk-free rate, is the stock price
volatility, and T is the time to maturity of the option. Why?
Options, Futures, Derivatives / January 28, 2008

51

Das könnte Ihnen auch gefallen