Sie sind auf Seite 1von 248

Energy Economics and Financial Markets

Andr Dorsman John L. Simpson


Wim Westerman

Editors

Energy Economics
and Financial Markets

123

Editors
Andr Dorsman
Department of Finance
VU University Amsterdam
Amsterdam
The Netherlands

Wim Westerman
Faculty of Economics and Business
Economics, Econometrics and Finance
University of Groningen
Groningen
The Netherlands

John L. Simpson
Curtin Business School
School of Economics and Finance
Curtin University
Perth, WA
Australia

ISBN 978-3-642-30600-6
DOI 10.1007/978-3-642-30601-3

ISBN 978-3-642-30601-3

(eBook)

Springer Heidelberg New York Dordrecht London


Library of Congress Control Number: 2012944975
Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg 2013
This work is subject to copyright. All rights are reserved by the Publisher, whether the whole or part of
the material is concerned, specifically the rights of translation, reprinting, reuse of illustrations,
recitation, broadcasting, reproduction on microfilms or in any other physical way, and transmission or
information storage and retrieval, electronic adaptation, computer software, or by similar or dissimilar
methodology now known or hereafter developed. Exempted from this legal reservation are brief
excerpts in connection with reviews or scholarly analysis or material supplied specifically for the
purpose of being entered and executed on a computer system, for exclusive use by the purchaser of the
work. Duplication of this publication or parts thereof is permitted only under the provisions of
the Copyright Law of the Publishers location, in its current version, and permission for use must always
be obtained from Springer. Permissions for use may be obtained through RightsLink at the Copyright
Clearance Center. Violations are liable to prosecution under the respective Copyright Law.
The use of general descriptive names, registered names, trademarks, service marks, etc. in this
publication does not imply, even in the absence of a specific statement, that such names are exempt
from the relevant protective laws and regulations and therefore free for general use.
While the advice and information in this book are believed to be true and accurate at the date of
publication, neither the authors nor the editors nor the publisher can accept any legal responsibility for
any errors or omissions that may be made. The publisher makes no warranty, express or implied, with
respect to the material contained herein.
Printed on acid-free paper
Springer is part of Springer Science+Business Media (www.springer.com)

Foreword

The Value of Energy Economics and Financial Markets


More than ever, energy dictates our lives. Once viewed as a utility, an enabler with
limited consumer interest, energy is now the key word in our struggle for a sustainable
future. Public involvement is tremendous, ranging from household production to
smart (semi-)professional consumption management. The need for sustainability has
turned energy into a highly relevant product, even approximating a lifestyle item. It is
fair to state that when it comes to energy, we are indisputably experiencing a big shift
in value perception, stretching far further than just utilitarian or even economical
value.
Drivers for energy consumption still show significant geographical differences.
Yet, the energy transition from carbon fuels to renewables and the associated
market model changes from the background against which the current energy
market developments can be painted. The energy transition is no longer a choice
nor a wish. It is more like a force of nature that will overcome the market and will
drive the energy market participants for the next decades. To successfully make
this switch, we need optimization of existing processes, smart technology, and
decision support at all levels up to the end consumer. The value of innovation and
agile operations will determine the future value of energy.
With even single household production companies, nowadays, the markets entry
barrier has never been so low, while the market complexity has never been so high.
More than ever, we are in need of specialists with a thorough understanding of the
industry, its rules, regulations, and its specific processes. Clear frameworks, alignment of structures, and performance measurement, are all minimal requirements to
operate in this specific domain. From market design to effective operational management, in-depth knowledge is the key to successand sharing this knowledge is
the only way to increase value. Rather than exceling in isolation, market specialists
should exchange insights to jointly provide the ever so necessary clarity and guidance
to the market and its various participants.
In multiple ways, this book discusses both the value and the valuation of
energy. The well-chosen structure of themes and chapters allows the readers to
v

vi

Foreword

gain useful insights into the fundamental economic forces determining the global
energy supply and demand. It addresses transitional issues, and also explains the
connections of these to the related financial derivatives and primary markets.
GENs practice touches on many of the subjects addressed in this book: improving
the intelligibility of energy through market model analyses, process implications,
and hard-core performance indicators. Our tagline is Adding Value to Energy. For
this book specifically, I would like to stress the way its articles add value to the
evolution of the energy markets. Being a co-production between a wealth of scientists and practitioners, it supports the creation of a more uniform framework for the
different operating mechanisms in the economics and finance-related parts of the
energy sector. It is worth reading and holds an invitation from the authors, but
definitely also from me personally, to add to the insights offered and contributed to
building the firm knowledge base that will guide us to the future.
Sam Collot dEscury
CEO GEN

Contents

Introduction: Energy Economics and Financial Markets . . . . . . .


John L. Simpson, Wim Westerman and Andr Dorsman

Part I

Supply and Demand

Energy Security in Asia: The Case of Natural Gas . . . . . . . . . . .


Helen Cabalu and Cristina Alfonso

Buyer Credit Pricing for Natural Gas Exports Using


Country Risk Ratings . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
John L. Simpson

The Drivers of Energy Consumption in Developing Countries . . .


Ayhan Kapusuzoglu and Mehmet Baha Karan

Part II
5

13

31

49

Environmental Issues and Renewables

Renewable Energy Production Capacity and Consumption,


Economic Growth and Global Warming . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
Henk von Eije, Steven von Eije and Wim Westerman

73

Economics Instruments for Pollution Abatement:


Tradable Permits Versus Carbon Taxes . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
Anthony D. Owen

91

Emissions Trading and Stock Returns: Evidence from


the European Steel and Combustion Industries . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
Jeroen Bruggeman and Halit Gonenc

107

vii

viii

Contents

Part III

The Dynamics of Energy Derivatives Trading

Energy Derivatives Market Dynamics . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .


Don Bredin, amonn Ciagin and Cal B. Muckley

129

The Dynamics of Crude Oil Spot and Futures Markets . . . . . . . .


zgr Arslan-Ayaydin and Inna Khagleeva

159

10

Natural Gas Market Liberalization: An Examination


of UK and US Futures and Spot Prices . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
John L. Simpson

Part IV

175

Finance and Energy

11

Adding Oil to a Portfolio of Stocks and Bonds?. . . . . . . . . . . . . .


Andr Dorsman, Andr Koch, Menno Jager and Andr Thibeault

197

12

Imperfection of Electricity Networks. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .


Andr Dorsman, Geert Jan Franx and Paul Pottuijt

215

13

Initial Public Offerings of Energy Companies . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .


Bill Dimovski

235

Chapter 1

Introduction: Energy Economics


and Financial Markets
John L. Simpson, Wim Westerman and Andr Dorsman

Abstract Energy issues feature frequently in the economic and financial press. It
is argued that the importance of energy production, consumption and trade and
raises fundamental economic issues that impact the global economy and financial
markets. Specific examples of daily energy issues stem from various countries and
can often be related to economics and finance. It is shown that energy economics
and financial market research issues can be grouped under the themes of supply
and demand, environmental impact and renewables, energy derivatives trading, as
well as finance and energy.

Keywords Supply and demand Environmental issues and renewables


derivatives trading Finance and energy

 Energy

J. L. Simpson (&)
School of Economics and Finance, Curtin Business School,
Curtin University, Hayman Road, Bentley, Perth, WA 6845 Australia
e-mail: john.simpson@cbs.curtin.edu.au
W. Westerman
Faculty of Economics, Business, Econometrics and Finance,
University of Groningen, Nettelbosje 2, 9747 AE Groningen,
Groningen, The Netherlands
e-mail: w.westerman@rug.nl
A. Dorsman
Department of Finance, VU University, De Boelelaan 1105,
1081 HV Amsterdam, The Netherlands
e-mail: a.b.dorsman@vu.nl

A. Dorsman et al. (eds.), Energy Economics and Financial Markets,


DOI: 10.1007/978-3-642-30601-3_1, Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg 2013

J. L. Simpson et al.

1.1 Introduction
There are many critical areas of interest that relate either generally or specifically
to fossil fuels and alternatives, energy efficiency, energy independence and
security, energy safety issues, climate change, sustainability and renewables, the
transportation of energy resources, connecting energy suppliers and consumers,
electricity generation and so on. This book in some way touches all of those broad
issues explicitly or implicitly. The book cannot deal with all of the current energy
issues in detail, but it does represent a genuine effort to draw attention in applied
research in several important areas of energy economics and financial markets.
This chapter begins with a discussion of the importance of energy production,
consumption and trade and raises fundamental macro-economic issues that impact the
global economy and financial markets. The chapter then provides specific examples of
daily energy issues from various countries and relates them to economics and finance.
Energy economics and financial market research issues are related to the themes of
supply and demand, environmental impact and renewables, energy derivatives trading,
as well as finance and energy. A discussion of headlines of the several chapters of the
book shows the relevance of academic research in the area for energy economics and
financial market researchers, practitioners and policy makers alike.

1.2 The Importance of Energy in Financial Economics1


Why are energy issues in financial economics so important? The dominance of
energy in global markets is re-emphasized by the reporting of recent energy production, trade and consumption numbers. Looking first at production, the numbers
reported quantify natural energy resources extracted or produced and include coal,
gas, oil, electricity, and heat and biomass production. For gas, quantities flared or
reinjected are included. The production of hydro, geothermal, nuclear and wind
electricity is excluded from the numbers as this is considered primary production.
In 2010 world primary energy production increased by 4 %. This is significant
when it is considered that there was a 0.6 % reduction in 2009. The driving force
emanated from Asia, which was responsible for nearly half of the increase and
currently represents around 30 % of total energy production. Coincidentally
perhaps, this amount of production is the same as that for all OECD countries.
In China production grew by 8 % and represents 18 % of the total. In Russia the
growth was 6 % due largely to the growth in LNG. The OECD produced a modest
increase of 2.3 % driven primarily by growth rates in the US and to a lesser extent
in the EU. The Middle East had growth rates of 3.6 % and in Latin America the
6.6 % growth rate was mainly due to the strength of Brazil.
1

For the data in this section see Global Energy Statistical Yearbook (2011), http://
yearbook.enerdata.net.

1 Introduction: Energy Economics and Financial Markets

In regard to energy consumption, a slight reduction in 2009 was followed by a


5.5 % growth in 2010. All G20 countries experienced energy consumption growth,
underpinned by a resumption in strong OECD growth following an upturn in
economic activity. Consumption grew by 6.7 % in Japan, 4 % in Europe and
3.7 % in the US. China and India accounted for a 6 % increase with a strong
demand for all forms of energy. China is the largest consumer of energy (at 11 %
above the US) and India ranks number three.
When global trade is considered, the Middle East in 2010 again confirmed its
status as the largest net exporter of energy. Russia, due to its exports of natural gas to
Europe, increased its net exporter position and, oddly, in a time of concerns regarding
global warming and unclean energy, the US reduced its net importer position by
exporting larger amounts of coal. The net importing position of Asia deepened by a
further 15 % driven largely by China, where net imports rose by 24 % in 2010.
However, this increase was down from 55 % in 2009, perhaps showing the impact of
the GFC on Chinese industry and infrastructure growth. In Europe the trade deficit
increased by 2.9 % in 2010, impacted by increased imports of energy.
Important questions in relation to global economics and financial markets arise
out of the foregoing numbers (Energy Insights 2011). Will the global economy
demand more energy in the future? Where will the energy come from? Will large
developed countries experience electricity blackouts? In answer to the first question the view is put firmly that more energy will be demanded. For example, oil
demand is expected to increase from 70 million barrels a day to 150 million
barrels a day by 2010. Chinese and Indian demand will drive a global doubling for
numbers of automobiles by 2020 and gas demand will rapidly escalate in the Asia
Pacific with coal demand increasing significantly. Increasing global GDP, populations, wealth expectations, and standards of living will require substantially more
energy. The figures are astounding. For example, Chinas GDP will probably be
higher than that of the US by 2040. Indias GDP is also increasing rapidly.
Energy is a commodity where production and consumption are differently located. An increase in energy consumption means an increase in transport of energy, for
example, by long distance imported pipeline gas and LNG shipped by sea. Middle
Eastern oil supply though OPEC will expand as will the supplies of Russian oil. Coal
production will probably expand (mainly in India, Bangladesh, US and China). The
growth of fossil fuels exports will be less rapid due to renewables growth. For
example, solar in sunny Florida, California and Spain and wind in the UK, The
Netherlands, Denmark and parts of the US (Energy Insights 2011). Also, Australian
coal and natural gas will remain very important global energy sources over the next
few decades. Other sources such as hydrogen for hybrid automobiles may provide
inroads in replacing oil imports, but it is expected that oil prices will continue to
increase from their current levels of around USD100 per barrel.
The final broad question is whether or not the threat of electricity blackouts in
larger developed countries is real. The answer to this question is, it might be!
Capital investment in power generation has fallen behind GDP increases in most
industrialized countries and this is partly due to market liberalization where
privatized producers operate with lower spare capacity than previously. Low prices

J. L. Simpson et al.

of electricity between 1998 and 2003 did not incentivize investment, but this
perhaps is changing. In 20032004 with greater demand, higher prices, and spare
capacity shortages blackouts actually occurred in the US and in Europe.
The investment problems need to be resolved given that electricity investment is
often not perceived to be attractive at the time. The investment will probably need
to be made more attractive with some form of government involvement. Electricity
investment is capital intensive, there is a long investment time frame, it has low
expected rates of return and such investment needs to compete with other areas of
financial markets which are more attractive in risk and return characteristics.
This brings on discussion about the role of the financial markets in the energy
sector under the current circumstances. The energy markets are now the place to be.
After the bond markets in the 1950s, the stock markets in the 1960s and the 1970s, the
option market in the 1980s and the 1990s of the last century it is now the turn of the
energy markets. Bonds, stocks, and options are products created in the minds of
people. The prices of one of these products should be universally more or less the
same. Deviations in prices of the same product are due to imperfections. That is not
true for energy and energy-related products. The price of these products depends on
time and location. On top of that, transport of energyfrom production place to
consumption placeexpends energy. Financial models that are true for imaginary
goods are too simple for energy. Armed with the knowledge of the markets of
imaginary goods it is important to expand knowledge of the energy markets.
Due to the fact that consumers and producers of energy are not equally distributed
over the world, it is logical that there is an apparent value shift from consuming
countries to producing countries. However, production of oil and gas is not unlimited.
The welfare obtained by oil and gas wells will disappear when the production of fossil
energy substantially decreases. Energy producing countries look at alternatives, such
as renewables (solar and wind energy) or creating financial institutions. After the
financial crisis 20072008 there were doubts about the solvency of American and
European banks. It is unusual to many, that, over the period of the global financial
crisis, there was little discussion about the viability of Russian Banks.

1.3 Energy Economics and Financial Markets: Specific Issues


of the Day
More specific energy issues are fixed topics in the economic and financial press.
For example, one of the important recent newsworthy events in oil production and
exploration was the approval by the United States Bureau of Ocean Management
and the anticipated approval by other environmental regulatory bodies of the
re-entry by BP into oil exploration in the Gulf of Mexico. Up to four wells have
been approved and this is will be the first exploration activity by the company in
the Gulf since the explosion aboard the Deepwater Horizon rig in April 2010. This
example raises issues of a broader nature than just plain vanilla economics and
finance.

1 Introduction: Energy Economics and Financial Markets

Such developments in the real world will drive research. The above events have
an important impact on oil supply at another point when issues relating to peak oil
keep coming to the fore-front of thinking in those markets. The events in the Gulf
of Mexico also triggered questions relating to the prices and price movements in
oil markets and also in individual oil companies and supply and demand aspects,
but overwhelmingly, questions arise on the real world issue of environmental
damage, sustainability, the desirability of fossil fuels in general in preference to a
more rigorous development of renewable energy resources.
Another timely real world issue may be one where there has not been a large
amount of focus. For example, again in the United States the issue of the regulation
and control of fracking wastewater has more recently arisen. The disposal of the
water from hydraulic fracturing in shale gas and coal-bed methane operations has
raised not only positive news about alternative cleaner burning fossil fuels and
methods of extraction that add to the supply of energy resources in an era of
rapidly increasing demand, but it is very important that the environmental impact
be considered and in this case also the impact on water resources.
Alternatives for fossil energy include renewables such as wind and solar
energy. However, these energy sources are also permeated with challenges. See for
example the political and economic effect of the recent financial problems of the
US solar firm Solyndra, which experienced problems despite a substantial
government guarantee from the Democratic Obama administration. Apart from the
blow to renewables advocates in practice as well as in research, the Republican
opposition appear to feel that they have gained some political advantage to help
them push hard for the desirability of an addiction to fossil fuels.
Energy is a commodity, which means that time and location matter. As a consequence
of location differences between producers and consumers of fossil energy, transport of
energy is a major economic activity. A hot topic refers to the economics of pipeline gas
when a specific issue is raised at a time in the global economy and certainly in the
developed economies where interest rates are low and stock markets are volatile, but weak.
Yet in taxation effective environments the attractiveness of low risk, low return pipeline
gas might be an attractive investment in some countries where it is appropriate. Still, this
would probably suggest a need for study in areas that are as yet not well exploited.
An issue for Australia and other fossil fuel exporters is the important need to
diversify exports away from an excessive reliance on only two or three importing
countries. On the importers side it is important for energy importers such as countries
in Western and Eastern Europe and also Turkey to consider the diversification of their
pipeline gas supplies from one or two countries that from all possible considerations
have to be considered as high political risk countries. Stability and security of energy
supply is an important issue that may interest energy economists amongst others.
For countries such as Australia, an increasingly important exporter of natural
gas,2 the issues considered by many are whether or not Australia should sell the

It is expected that by 2020 Australia will overtake Qatar as the largest global exporter of LNG.
See Forbes (2012).

J. L. Simpson et al.

mine or focus on selling the product. Australia is a wealthy, developed, low


political risk country and is very much part of the globalization process, but
questions are arising from many economists as to the cost benefits of excessive
inward foreign direct investment in the form of equity. Cost may not only be
economic in nature. There is a strategic and a political consideration. Does dividend outflow outweigh the economic benefit if foreign equity grows too large?
Should not foreign debt investment be on offer and encouraged with attractive
coupon rates on the bond instruments, rather than raising the funds through sale of
equity? Clearly such research, especially from financial economists, is desirable.
In the densely populated Netherlands, where it is estimated that what was once
the worlds largest natural gas field, situated in the north of the country, has only
about 30 years of supply left, the energy alternatives being considered will have to
include importation of coal, oil and gas, nuclear solutions, wind and solar power
generation. However, in such a developed and democratic country the people may
be balking at the excessive costs of wind power and also the visual and noise
pollution associated. Nuclear power, although being produced in the country for a
long time, is viewed to become less attractive as an alternate source following the
2011 Japanese tsunami impact.
Lastly, by the end of 2011, the Dutch firm New Sources Energy had to postpone
plans to issue new shares in order to develop activities in the renewable energy
area, in particular solar energy. The current economic climate was blamed for this.
Indeed, at the time the Dutch economy was in a recession. This event and similar
examples shed a new light on ongoing competitive advertising campaigns by local
financial institutions, fuelling the public in its intentions to invest in an often
ethically favored renewables sector. Again, both energy economy and financial
market specialists may be asked to shed light in the darkness of apparently
confusing information.
It is clear that there are many issues that are topical and require investigation.
They are often of a complex nature, such as many of the above examples show.
This book will touch on many of the central energy economics and financial
markets issues in real life, including some of the aforementioned issues in some
way, but overall the book deals with attempted resolution of the issues with
worthwhile applied research in the above mentioned fields.

1.4 Energy Economics and Financial Markets Research:


Issues Covered in this Book
Returning now to research issues, this book starts from a general perspective and
moves to a specific perspective. The text addresses macroeconomics, microeconomics and financial markets, whereby the actual focal attention has been laid on
four groups of timely topics. Part I covers issues on supply and demand for energy.
The second part of the book has a theme of environmental issues and renewables.

1 Introduction: Energy Economics and Financial Markets

Part III examines the dynamics of energy derivatives trading. The fourth part deals
with issues on the intersection of finance and energy. In this way the book itself is
organized into a total of twelve topical chapters.
Within Part I, which deals with supply and demand, one chapter is about energy
security in Asia, highlighting inter-country differences on specifically natural gas.
Helen Cabalu and Cristina Alfonso propose a composite gas supply security index
with four indicators: a gas consumption efficiency ratio, a gas import dependency
ratio, a gas production versus consumption ratio, and a geopolitical risk index. The
composite index is used to describe the situation in six important Asian countries.
China appears to be the least vulnerable country, whereas Thailand has become the
most vulnerable country.
Another chapter covers aspects of energy pricing and the pricing of finance for
buyers of energy resources, using country risk ratings. Author John L. Simpson
assumes that natural gas export returns represent the change in the amount of
export finance that might be required as buyer credit. Using country risk ratings, a
risk premium is ascribed to this buyer credit. Evidence suggests that Chinese buyer
credit from Australia is subject to a substantially larger credit risk than US buyer
credit from the same country. It is also shown that long-term equilibrium relationships exist in the early 2000s. The author therefore concludes that country risk
needs to be considered in loan pricing for gas exports.
The final chapter of the section deals with the drivers of energy demand in
developing countries. Here, Ayhan Kapusuzoglu and Mehmet Baha Karan suspect
a growing mismatch between energy demand and supply, which underlines the
need for research. They study 19712007 data for 30 developing countries. Energy
consumption is related to measures of not just gross domestic product (GDP), but
also rural population, total population, consumer prices (CPI) and CO2 emission.
The study signals common relationships in various directions between energy
consumption and the other factors studied.
The second part of the book deals with environmental issues and renewables.
Specifically investigated in the first chapter are renewable energy production
capacity and consumption, and their effects on economic growth and global
warming. Henk von Eije, Steven von Eije and Wim Westerman study global
relationships between gross domestic product (GDP) growth, CO2 emissions, fossil
fuel consumption, renewable energy consumption and also renewable energy
production variables. The authors show that renewable energy production reduces
both fossil fuel use and economic growth in the long run.
The following chapter is written by Tony Owen. It deals with carbon pricing
instruments aimed at reducing the demand for power and stimulating low-carbon
power generation technologies. Both emission trading schemes and carbon taxes
are theoretically least cost economic instruments if it comes to tackling climate
change. Factors that can in practice lead to significant levels for one instrument
relative to the other include transparency, operating costs, public acceptability,
dynamic efficiency, revenue and distributional issues, as well as international
harmonization.

J. L. Simpson et al.

The final chapter of the second part deals with emissions trading and stock returns,
with evidence taken from the European steel and construction industries. Jeroen
Bruggeman and Halit Gonenc show that price changes of European Union emission
allowances are only positively correlated with combustion industry stock returns in
the period 20052007 (Phase 1). In the years 20082010 (the first part of Phase 2), a
positive relationship is found in the steel industry as well. The authors also show that
emission allowances exposures are independent of firms characteristics.
Part III examines the trading dynamics of the energy derivatives. It deals in one
chapter with energy derivatives market dynamics. Specifically, Don Bredin,
amonn Ciagin and Cal Muckley study EU Emissions Trading Scheme (ETS)
options and futures market dynamics in the period 20052011. The authors show
that the EU ETS derivatives markets have only matured since the start of Phase 2.
As compared to the West Texas Intermediate crude oil market, spot/future
correlations, term structures and option volatility smiles and surfaces are behaving
quite similar in these markets over time.
Then the part moves to a chapter on the dynamics of the spot and futures
markets in crude oil by zgr Arslan-Ayaydin and Inna Khagleeva. The authors
find theoretical support for the view that future prices of crude oil are equal to the
spot price of crude oil, cost of carry and the convenience yield. They also show
theoretical modeling support for the view that future crude oil prices have no
predictive power on the spot markets. The authors support the latter view with an
empirical analysis of Western Texas Intermediate crude oil markets over the
period January 1986December 2011.
Lastly, the third part has a chapter on natural gas spot and futures markets. John
L. Simpson investigates the issue of decoupling of oil and gas or rather the
influences on these prices of global and domestic economic and market factors.
Liberalization progress has been made in both the US and the UK. Yet, the author
finds that US markets are more decoupled than UK markets, with domestic gas
price factors dominating global oil price factors in the determination of the future
spot gas price. He therefore supports the view that US deregulation policies have
been more effective than those in the UK.
The final part of the book has the theme of finance and energy. The first chapter
is written by Andr Dorsman, Andr Koch, Menno Jager and Andr Thibeault. It
covers the effects of the addition of oil to a portfolio of US stocks and bonds.
Indeed, when studying the period 19892010, inclusion of oil as an asset makes
the efficient frontier and the market portfolio change. While oil does also improve
the risk-return trade-off for investors, it only presents a hedge for bondholders and
not for stockholders. The authors therefore conclude that oil is not a safe haven for
stockholders and bondholders.
This is followed by a chapter on the imperfections in electricity networks for a
number of European countries, written by Andr Dorsman, Geert-Jan Franx and
Paul Pottuijt. Energy networks (grids) used to be nationally organized, but the
national grids are increasingly linked by market coupling. In this way, interconnector capacities are automatically allocated in a way that minimizes electricity

1 Introduction: Energy Economics and Financial Markets

price differences. The authors show with evidence from Scandinavia (South), The
Netherlands, Belgium and France that market price differences indeed do diminish
during the period January 2005March 2011.
The final chapter by Bill Dimovski investigates the pricing of initial public
offerings of 158 energy companies in Australia from January 1994 to December
2010. Whilst the average underpricing returns are substantial (22 %), negative
returns are not rare. The underpricing returns negatively correlate with the amount
of equity capital raised and the engagement of underwriters. The use of underwriter
options increases the underpricing returns though. The author also finds that underpricing returns do not differ between before and after the global financial crisis
of 20072008.
The chapters selected for this book are genuine academic pieces of writing.
Such chapters investigate some of the major energy economics issues of the day.
The authors have identified topical research problems and have explained the
reasons why finding a solution to those problems is important. The authors have
followed academic practice in the provision of a relevant theoretical and literature
base from which they could derive their models and hypotheses. They have
employed conventional statistical and econometric analysis ranging from basic
descriptive analysis to advanced time series techniques to arrive at statistically
significant findings that add in either a minor or a major way to the body of
knowledge about energy economics and financial markets.

1.5 Conclusion
Various timely energy issues may attract interest. For example, inter alia, the
explosion aboard the Deepwater Horizon rig in 2010, the regulation and control
of fracking wastewater, subsidizing firms involved with renewable energy,
investments in gas pipelines, risks on energy supplier reliance, foreign equity
investment in the energy sector, energy source trade-offs in densely populated
areas and the timing of equity sales of energy firms. It is beyond the scope of this
book to cover all of these most interesting areas, yet the book directly or indirectly
touches upon these kinds of issues.
Energy economics and financial market research problems can be related to
various themes. This book embraces energy economics research questions from all
over the world, written up by a diverse team of authors. The book explores the
themes of supply and demand, environmental issues and renewables, energy
derivatives trading, as well as finance and energy. This discussion of headlines of
the several chapters of the book has been aimed to show the links between the
individual contributions as well as the relevance of academic research in the area
for energy economics and financial market researchers, practitioners and policy
makers alike. It is hoped that the readers both benefit from and enjoy the read.

10

J. L. Simpson et al.

References
Energy Insights. (2011). Energy Supply and Demand. Retrieved from: http://www.energyinsights.
net/content/articles/energysupplydemand.htm.
Forbes, A. (2012, February). The exciting future of LNGAnd how it will transform the global
gas market, European Energy Review. Retrieved from: http://www.europeanenergyreview.eu/
site/pagina.php?id=3497.
Global Energy Statistical Yearbook. (2011). Grenoble, France: Enerdata. Retrieved from: http://
yearbook.enerdata.net.

Part I

Supply and Demand

Chapter 2

Energy Security in Asia: The Case


of Natural Gas
Helen Cabalu and Cristina Alfonso

Abstract Natural gas consumption in the future is expected to increase due to its
low environmental impact, ease of use and rise in the number of natural gas-fired
power plants. This chapter measures natural gas supply security in six Asian
economies including Japan, Korea, China, India, Singapore and Thailand from
1996 to 2009. Disruptions to long term security of supply can be caused by
inadequate investments in production and transmission infrastructure, lack of
supply diversity and import dependency. A composite gas supply security index is
derived from four indicators of security of gas supply, with a higher index indicating higher gas supply vulnerability. Results show that China and India are the
least vulnerable in terms of natural gas security because of their significant
domestic gas production and small share of gas in the energy mix. Thailand is the
most vulnerable among the countries studied due to its high reliance on natural gas
to power its electricity generation industry as well as its greater exposure to
geopolitical risks. With these analyses, governments can target possible sources of
supply disruptions and mitigate their effects. Diversification is highly encouraged
to spread the risk across different import and energy sources.

H. Cabalu (&)
School of Economics and Finance, Curtin Business School, Curtin University,
GPO Box U1987WA, Perth 6845, Australia
e-mail: h.cabalu@curtin.edu.au
C. Alfonso
Centre for Research in Energy and Minerals Economics (CREME), Curtin Business School,
Curtin University, GPO Box U1987 6845 Perth, WA, Australia
e-mail: c.alfonso@curtin.edu.au

A. Dorsman et al. (eds.), Energy Economics and Financial Markets,


DOI: 10.1007/978-3-642-30601-3_2, Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg 2013

13

14

H. Cabalu and C. Alfonso

2.1 Introduction
The oil shocks in the 1970s demonstrated how vulnerable the worlds economy
was to supply interruptions and price volatility. In addition, the recent increases in
energy prices, a steady rise in global energy demand, instability in energy producing regions and the threat of terrorist strikes against energy infrastructure have
significantly led to a growing concern over energy security. Any energy infrastructureoil, coal or natural gasis often vulnerable to disruption by insufficient
supply, accident or malice. Terrorism, technical mishap, or natural disasters that
damage the energy system could be nearly as devastating as a sizeable war.
Inadequate financial resources also increase vulnerability or insecurity by limiting
supply, transmission, and reliability while increasing prices of energy imports
adversely affect the macroeconomic balance of payments, contribute inflationary
pressures, and displace other consumption and investment because short-term
demand is inelastic. In the past, long term contracts between exporters and
importers have been an important element of security of supply. However, in
recent years long term contracts have not been an adequate assurance of uninterrupted deliveries.
Energy security has emerged as a major object of the energy policy agenda and
policy makers have engaged in a wide ranging debate over how best to address
future energy requirements. Along with this emergence, energy markets have
moved towards strengthening regional co-operation and energy supplies and
sources have become more diversified. There has also been a strong trend towards
shorter contract terms or a considerable decrease in the length of contracts caused
by either market-related or regulatory-related changes. Market changes due to
government regulatory initiatives and the creation of competitive markets have led
to this trend.
While many previous studies have focused on oil, this chapter provides
evidence on security of natural gas supply in selected Asian countries. With the
growing demand for gas, supply interruptions, increasing gas prices, transportation
and distribution bottlenecks, and a growing reliance on imports over longer
distances have rekindled a debate on gas security of supply. Extending the work by
Cabalu (2010), this chapter proposes a composite gas supply security index (GSSI)
which is derived as the root mean square of the scaled values of four security of
gas supply indicators, for the period 19962009. The four security of gas supply
indicators are interrelated and the GSSI derived from 1996 to 2009 provides a
trend in the composite quantitative measure of gas security by taking into account
the interactions and interdependences between the identified set of indicators. The
GSSI captures the sensitivity of the Asian economies to developments in the
international gas market, with a higher index indicating higher gas supply insecurity or vulnerability.
The existing literature does not identify a unique methodology that is factual,
objective, unbiased, transparent and accessible, to assess and quantify energy
security. However, it is important to provide metrics by evaluating a set of

Energy Security in Asia: The Case of Natural Gas

15

parameters and indicators to assess overall natural gas supply security in the six
Asian economies of Japan, Korea, China, India, Singapore and Thailand, which
together account for almost 64 % of the total gas consumption in the AsiaPacific
region in 2010 (BP 2011). It is important for future policy making to benchmark
countries against quantified indicators and assess their gas security of supply
weakness. This chapter is divided into six sections. The sect. 2 provides a brief
background on the importance of energy security, particularly in natural gas and
includes a discussion of the vulnerabilities in the natural gas system. The sect. 3
reviews related literature on energy supply security, particularly focused on
identifying the various indicators used in the literature to indicate energy
vulnerability while Sect. 4 derives a composite gas supply security index for the
years 19962009 for the sample countries. Section 5 presents the results and
analysis and the final section concludes.

2.2 Importance of Energy Security: The Case of Natural Gas


Natural gas has become an increasingly valuable resource. Its consumption is
expected to increase significantly into the future because of its low environmental
impact, ease of use and an increase in the number of natural gas-fired power plants.
It is one of the fuels that drive the economy. The demand for it, as a replacement
for more expensive, less environmentally-friendly and less efficient resources, has
already increased significantly (Cabalu and Manhutu 2009). The world is dependent on natural gas for power generation. In 2010, it fulfilled around 24 % of the
total global primary energy demand (BP 2011). OECD countries accounted for
49 % of gas use, transition economies, especially Russia, used about 19 % with
developing countries accounting for the rest. Natural gas is forecast to be the
fastest growing energy source by 2035, with global consumption rising by more
than 52 % from 110.7 trillion cubic feet from 2008 to 168.7 trillion cubic feet in
2035. The emerging markets of Asia will be the centre of this growth where gas
consumption is projected to triple by 2035 (EIA 2011).
Natural gas is also becoming an increasingly global commodity. In the past, gas
tended to be used in the region where it is produced because of the relatively high
transport costs. However, technical developments have led to a drastic reduction in
gas liquefaction and transport costs making liquefied natural gas (LNG) competitive with traditional pipeline gas. The rapid growth in LNG use and its greater
flexibility has started to create a global market for gas. In 2010, more than 30 % of
the global natural gas supply was internationally traded with LNG shipments
showing strong growth, well above the ten-year average and making up more than
30 % of total export volume (BP 2011). The remaining share of gas sold on the
world energy market is distributed via gas pipelines. The imbalances between
supply and demand drive international trade in natural gas. On the one hand are
northeast Asian countries (i.e. Japan, Korea, Taiwan and China), which held just
over 1 % of world reserves in 2010 but accounted for almost 8 % of the demand.

16

H. Cabalu and C. Alfonso

On the other hand, the Middle East (particularly Iran and Qatar) and Russia had
around 65 % of the worlds reserves and accounted for around 25 % of the demand
in 2010 (BP 2011).
In 2010, more than 11 % of the AsiaPacific primary energy consumption was
based on natural gas. Gas market requirements are mostly met through imports,
more than 85 % of which is LNG from Malaysia, Brunei, Indonesia, Australia and
the Middle East. Japan and Korea are almost entirely dependent on LNG imports
for their gas supplies. In Japan and Korea, imported gas exchanges are based on
long term contracts of 2025 years and indexation clauses where the gas price is
directly linked to the price of crude oil, including relatively strict clauses such as
take-or-pay clauses which require importers to pay for the gas even if their
deliveries are interrupted. In Australia and New Zealand, prices are set by gas-ongas or gas-on-coal competition (IAEE 2007; IEA 2007; BP 2011).
Short-term security of gas supply is the ability to maintain gas supply despite
exceptional demand and difficult supply conditions. Disruptions to supply may be
due to physical or economic factors. Physical disruptions can occur when gas supply
is exhausted or gas production is stopped. Economic disruptions can be caused by
dramatic gas price fluctuations which in turn, are due to physical disruptions or
unanticipated price changes associated with speculative reaction to potential
disruption. Long-term security of gas supply on the other hand, is the ability to ensure
that future gas demand can be met by a combination of domestic and imported gas
supplies. Disruptions to long term security of supply are caused by inadequate
investments in production and transmission infrastructure, lack of supply diversity
and risks associated with import dependency which are geopolitical in nature. Gasimporting countries have started to examine potential responses to disruptions to
ensure security of gas supply (Dolader 2003; Costantini et al. 2007).

2.3 Energy Security and its Indicators


To date, the literature on assessing energy security has concentrated on oil and
mostly on industrialized countries. A number of studies have tried to develop a set
of energy supply security indicators to account for both short- and long-term
disruptions. Although a number of indicators have been proposed in the literature,
there is no consensus on a set of relevant indicators. As a result, time series data to
directly assess trends in energy supply security are not readily available and
policymakers have therefore relied on a number of parameters associated with
energy security to inform decision making.
Jansen et al. (2004) studied the energy supply security issue in the European
Union by constructing four long-term energy security indicators based on the
Shannon diversity index applied to eight primary energy supply sources (coal, oil,
gas, modern and traditional biofuels, nuclear, renewables and hydropower).
The indicators accounted for supply security aspects such as diversification of
energy sources in energy supply, diversification of imports with respect to

Energy Security in Asia: The Case of Natural Gas

17

imported energy sources, political stability in import sources, and the resource
base in import sources.
Similarly, Costantini et al. (2007) grouped indicators of supply security into
two categories: dependence, and vulnerability represented in physical and
economic terms. The distinction between dependence and vulnerability was made
and in their study, the physical dimension of dependence was represented by
indicators such as percentage share of net import of oil and gas in total primary
energy supply and the share of European oil and gas imports in world oil and gas
imports while the physical dimension of vulnerability was calculated in terms of
the degree of supply concentration in trade and production using the ShannonWeiner diversity index, percentage share of oil used in transportation, and
percentage share of electricity produced with gas. In terms of the economic
dimension of dependence and vulnerability, the value of oil and gas imports and
oil and gas consumption per dollar of GDP respectively, were estimated. These
indicators of the European energy system were analyzed under different energy
scenarios.
In a study by de Jong et al. (2007), a model was developed for reviewing and
assessing energy supply security in the European Union, on the basis of pre-agreed
criteria. It used two quantitative indicators and some qualitative considerations.
The first quantitative indicator, the Crisis Capability (CC) Index dealt with the risk
of sudden unforeseen short-term supply interruptions and the capability to manage
them. The second indicator, the Supply/Demand (S/D) Index covered present and
future energy supply and demand balances. Qualitative considerations included
multilateral measures for securing overall producer/consumer relations and safeguarding vulnerable transport routes for oil and gas.
A number of studies have focus on assessing energy vulnerability. Kendell
(1998) explores the meaning and value of measures of import vulnerability as
indicators of energy security, in particular, oil security in the United States. While
measures of oil import dependence showing the extent of a countrys imports may
be of interest, they offer a limited indication of energy security. Gupta (2008),
APERC (2007), and UNDP (2007) also examine the relative oil vulnerability of oilimporting countries on the basis of various factors. Using a principal component
technique, individual indicators such as domestic oil reserves relative to total oil
consumption, geopolitical oil risk, oil intensity, cost of oil in national income and
the ratio of oil consumption in total primary energy consumption are combined into
a composite index of oil vulnerability. Percebois (2007) clarifies the distinction
between vulnerability and energy dependence and presents a coherent set of indicators including import concentration, level of energy import value in output, risk
of blackout in the electricity sector, price volatility, exchange rates, and industrial
and technological factors that are used to analyze energy vulnerability. Gnansounou
(2008) defines a composite index of energy demand/supply weaknesses as a proxy
for energy vulnerability. The index is based on several indicators such as energy
intensity, oil and gas import dependency, CO2 content of primary energy supply,
electricity supply weaknesses and non-diversity in transport fuels. The assessment
of the composite index is applied to selected industrialized countries. In 2008, the

18

H. Cabalu and C. Alfonso

World Energy Council (2008) identified threats to the European economy which
could lead to potential energy crises and suggested solutions for facing related key
challenges. The study also developed a number of indicators to assess the level of
different types of vulnerability, as well as the overall vulnerability of a country or
region, including threats to physical disruption and higher energy prices.
The design of a composite index of energy security has been undertaken in
previous studies. A composite vulnerability index was developed by the World
Energy Council (2008) to benchmark and monitor European countries respective
efforts to cope with long-term energy vulnerability. Similarly, de Jong et al. (2007)
designed state-of-the-art indices of energy security risk (i.e., the Crisis Capability
Index and Supply/Demand Index) which are oriented towards a comprehensive
and analytical representation of the energy supply chain. However, the shortcoming of these approaches is the use of subjective-opinion-dominated weighting
systems and scoring rules where the weights and the rules are based on expert
judgments. In response to this shortcoming, Gnansounou (2008) proposes an
alternative method which is objective-value-oriented and statistics-based.
Gnansounou defines the composite index as the Euclidean distance to the best
energy security case represented by the zero point. The Euclidean distance is
standardized in order to get a value between 0 and 1. Following the more objective
methodology proposed by Gnansounou, Cabalu (2010) develops a composite gas
supply security index for selected Asian countries for the year 2008. This chapter
extends this previous study by calculating an annual gas supply security index for
the period 19962009 for net gas importing countries in Asia.

2.4 The GSSI for the Asian Gas Market


In line with the analysis made in Cabalu (2010), four distinct security of supply
indicators are selected for this study: gas intensity (G1), net gas import dependency
(G2), ratio of domestic gas production to total domestic gas consumption (G3) and
geopolitical risk (G4). These indicators are chosen to be the most common indicators calculated in the prior literature which have direct relevance to security of
natural gas supply.
G1 is measured as the ratio of gas consumed in an economy to gross domestic
product (GDP). It is the amount of natural gas needed to produce a dollars worth
of goods and services and provides an indication of efficient use of gas to produce
the economys output. Gas intensity (G1) is calculated as:
G1j

GCj
:
GDPj

The gas intensity of GDP of country j (G1j ) is measured as the ratio of total
natural gas consumed in country j (GCj ) to GDP of country j (GDPj ) and expressed

Energy Security in Asia: The Case of Natural Gas

19

as cubic meters per unit of GDP or m3/GDP. The countrys output of goods and
services is measured by inflation-adjusted GDP.
The relative indicator for country j associated with G1 (u1j ) is estimated as:
u1j

G1j  MinG1
:
MaxG1  MinG1

The relative indicator, u1j results in projection of G1j in the interval [0, 1].
A low value of u1j means that country j is less vulnerable or less insecure to supply
shocks compared to other countries in the study.
G2 is expressed as the ratio of net imported gas consumption to total primary
energy consumption. Net gas import dependency (G2 ) is calculated as:
G2j

GMj
:
TPECj

The gas import dependency of country j (G2j ) is represented by the ratio of net
imports of natural gas in country j (GMj ) to total primary energy consumption in
country j (TPECj ) expressed as a percentage.
Similarly, the relative indicator for country j associated with G2 (u2j ) is estimated as:
u2j

G2j  MinG2
:
MaxG2  MinG2

The above adjustment transforms the indicator to the [0, 1] interval with the
value of 0 being assigned to the country with the lowest value of the selected
security of supply indicator and least vulnerable and the value 1 is assigned to the
country with the highest value of the selected indicator and hence most vulnerable.
G3 is measured as the ratio of domestic gas production to total domestic gas
consumption. Domestic production is a better indicator of the countrys capacity to
cope with short-term supply disruption than domestic reserves as production
excludes gas from stranded reserves which cannot be tapped immediately. Ratio of
domestic gas production to total domestic gas consumption (G3 ) is calculated as:
G3j

GPj
GCj

where GPj is domestic natural gas production in country j and GCj is total natural
gas consumed in country j.
This indicator, unlike the first two, is negatively related to gas supply vulnerability or security. A high value for G3 means that country j is less vulnerable or
less insecure to supply shocks compared to other countries in the study. To
accommodate this negative relationship, the relative indicator for country j associated with G3 (u3j ) is estimated as:

20

H. Cabalu and C. Alfonso

u3j

MaxG3  G3j
:
MaxG3  MinG3

The above adjustment transforms the indicator to the [0, 1] interval with the
value of 0 being assigned to the country with the highest value of the selected
security of supply indicator and least vulnerable and the value 1 is assigned to the
country with the lowest value of the selected indicator and hence most vulnerable.
G4 represents the exposure of an economy to political risk and is measured on
the basis of two factors: diversification of gas import sources and political stability
in gas-exporting countries. Geopolitical risk (G4 ) is largely determined by the
degree of diversification of gas import sources and the associated political s
tability of these sources. Jansen et al. (2004) suggests a methodology for quantifying such risk using the adjusted Shannon diversity index. The following formula
describes this index.
X
hi mi lnmi
S
i

where:
S = Shannon index of import flows of gas, adjusted for political stability in
exporting country i;
hi = extent of political stability in exporting country i, ranging from 0 (extremely
unstable) to 1 (extremely stable); and
mi = share of gas imports from country i in total gas imports.
 
The relative indicator for country j associated with G4 u4j is estimated as:
u4j

MaxG4  G4j
MaxG4  MinG4

Like u3j , this indicator is negatively related to gas supply vulnerability or


security which means that a lower value for G4 suggests high vulnerability to
supply shocks or a worse gas supply situation (i.e., high insecurity). The above
adjustment transforms the indicator to the [0, 1] interval with the value of 0 being
assigned to the country with the highest value of the selected security of supply
indicator and least vulnerable and the value 1 is assigned to the country with the
lowest value of the selected indicator and hence most vulnerable.
The data on GDP are taken from the World Economic Outlook Database (IMF
2010). Data for natural gasdomestic production, domestic consumption and
trade movements in volume terms were taken from BP Statistical Review of World
Energy (2010, 2011). In this study, the percentile rank of an exporting country in
the World Banks Worldwide Governance Indicators for political stability for
various years is used to determine hi (Table A.1). Table 2.1 presents estimates of
the four security of supply indicators of the selected six net gas-importing countries in Asia from 1996 to 2009.

Energy Security in Asia: The Case of Natural Gas

21

High gas intensity of GDP results in larger adjustment costs and impacts on gas
supply security in the event of natural gas supply shocks. In addition, the higher
the share of imported gas in total energy demand the more vulnerable an economy
is to international gas developments. Diversification of supply sources, particularly
politically stable supply sources also reduces the risk and vulnerability to disruption. Dependence on domestically-sourced gas supply is preferred over
imported gas, as it avoids geopolitical uncertainties. In addition, the larger
domestic gas reserves relative to consumption or the larger domestic production
capabilities a country has, the smaller are the likely impacts on gas security.
It is difficult to quantify a countrys overall gas supply security using individual
indicators and it is even more difficult to synthesize different indicators. To
facilitate comparison or aggregation of several indicators, it may be better for these
to be expressed in the same units. To do this, for each of the four security indicators, a relative indicator ui , was estimated which was used to compute a composite indexthe gas supply security index (GSSI). The relative indicators are
estimated by using a scaling technique where the minimum value is set to 0 and the
maximum to 1. The value of 0 is assigned to the country with the least vulnerability or insecurity to supply disruptions and the value 1 is assigned to the country
with the most vulnerability to supply shocks. Table 2.2 presents calculations for
the relative indicators which are scaled values of the four security of supply
indicators.
The gas supply security index (GSSI) is derived as the root mean square of the
four relative indicators or scaled values of the four security of supply indicators.
s
P4
2
i1 /ij
GSSIj
4
The various relative indicators of gas security are interrelated and the GSSI
derived provides a composite quantitative measure of gas security by taking into
account the interactions and interdependences between the identified set of indicators. The GSSI captures the sensitivity of the Asian economies to developments
in the international gas market, with a higher index indicating higher gas supply
insecurity or vulnerability.

2.5 Empirical Results


The GSSI is estimated for six Asian net gas-importing economies: Japan, Korea,
China, India, Singapore and Thailand, on an annual basis from 1996 to 2009. The
final values of GSSI for the sample net gas-importing countries in Asia are plotted
in Fig. 2.1.
In the sample, China appears to be the least vulnerable country in the event of a
natural gas supply disruption. Except for the period 20052008, China consistently
registered the lowest GSSI where its major strengths are the indicators G1, G2 and

22

H. Cabalu and C. Alfonso

G3. China is rich in energy resources, particularly coal. Gas use in China is still
small and is significantly less than the use of other fossil fuels. Coal and oil
resources are utilized more extensively than natural gas for power generation and
industrial development purposes. Natural gas generally occupies a very small share
(4.0 % in 2010) in Chinas energy mix but is expected to double by 2030
(Komiyama et al. 2005; APERC 2008).
Chinas major gas fields are located in the western part of the country, making
transport to eastern demand centers difficult. The use of domestic gas production
was initially limited to areas near production sites such as in Sichuan, Liaoning
and Heilongjiang Provinces, where low cost gas is possible. However, with recent
increases in infrastructure investments on pipeline construction such as the West
East pipeline to transport inland domestic gas, demand for natural gas has
increased. Between 2005 and 2008, Chinas natural gas consumption increased by
23.8 % and it became one of the worlds top ten countries in terms of natural gas
consumption. This coincided with the period when China became relatively vulnerable. At the same time, LNG imports also started and its import dependence
increased rapidly due to a substantial rise in demand. This growth was driven
mainly by the increased use of gas for power generation, feed stock in chemical
fertilizer production and to operate oil and gas fields. Recent developments such as
the increased residential consumption due to penetration of city gas, together with
the urbanization of cities have also led to the significant increase in demand. In
addition, the Chinese government through policy and regulation has encouraged
the use of natural gas as a source of cleaner energy and a substitute for oil and
coal. While some of the rising demand will be fulfilled through increases in
domestic production, a large portion has come from pipeline and LNG imports.
Due to geographical accessibility, the small amount of imported LNG goes to
southern provinces along the coast like Guangdong and Fujian (Higashi 2009).
In 2010, China had 14 import sources compared to one import source in 2006.
However, most of the additional import sources are politically unstable which
explains Chinas relative poor performance on G4. China received its first-ever
LNG cargo in mid-2006 under a long-term contract with Australia. Australia
remains Chinas major source of LNG. Its second terminal in Fujian started
receiving cargoes from Indonesia in 2008. Another re-gasification terminal in the
Shanghai area started to import LNG from Malaysia in 2009. In the northern
inland areas of China, natural gas supply has been sourced from Qatar, Siberia,
Turkmenistan, Sakhalin and Sakha.
India ranks as the second less gas-vulnerable country in the sample. For the
period, 19962009, Indias natural gas security generally improved through time
as shown by a downward trend in its GSSI. The strength of this country is in G2
indicating a relatively low gas import dependency, and to a less extent in G1 for
having low gas intensity. In India, natural gas is a minor fuel in the overall energy
mix representing only 10.6 % of total primary energy consumption in 2010. In that
same year, Indias natural gas imports represent just over 2 % of its energy mix
and hence not reliant on imports. With coal as the major source of energy for
power generation, gas intensity of the economys GDP is low. However,

Energy Security in Asia: The Case of Natural Gas

23

opportunities exist for gas in reducing regional air pollution and providing peaking
power. For the fertilizer sector, significant opportunities exist to import cheap
fertilizer; thereby reducing domestic gas demand, but political constraints will
likely buoy gas demand. Industrial consumers will benefit from increased supplies
of LNG to replace expensive liquid fuels, but cheap coal remains the dominant fuel
for many industrial applications (Jackson 2007).
However, Indias consumption of natural gas has risen faster than any other
fuel. The power and fertilizer industries are the key demand drivers for natural gas.
With domestic gas production only large enough to satisfy almost three-quarters of
its domestic gas consumption, Indias domestic natural gas supply is not likely to
keep pace with demand. Despite major new natural gas discoveries in recent years,
the country will have to import more, either via pipeline or as LNG. With an
increase in the demand for and supply of natural gas and with many new players
entering the market, the Indian governments Petroleum and Natural Gas Regulatory Board Act of 2006 has promoted competition among market players and
stabilized natural gas supply (Thacker 2006).
The bulk of Indias natural gas production comes from the western offshore
regions, especially the Mumbai High basin. The onshore fields in Assam, Andhra
Pradesh, and Gujarat states are also major producers of natural gas. In 2010, around
24 % of supply came from imported LNG. Currently, there are two re-gasification
terminals located on the Western coast of India, Dahej and Hazira. The Dahej
terminal is being supplied from Qatar under a long term contract, supplemented by
spot cargoes from other sources. A possible source of supply for the Hazira terminal
is Australias Gorgon LNG project. In 2012, India will have two more import
terminals, Dabhol-Ratnagiri and Kochi (EIA 2012).
One interesting result is Thailands natural gas supply vulnerability. Between
1996 and 1998, Thailand was ranked third least vulnerable country, after India.
However, between 1999 and 2009, Thailand became the most vulnerable among the
country sample. The sources of insecurity come from G1 to G4. Thailands heavy
reliance on natural gas to power 70 % of its electricity generation accounts for its
vulnerability in G1. Thailands high gas intensity is facilitated by a relatively wellestablished natural gas regulatory framework where third party access in gas transmission is quite developed and means the existence of non-discriminatory access to
the gas transmission system based on tariffs reflecting costs that provide a fair and
reasonable rate of return (Chandler and Padungkittimal 2008). In addition, despite
efforts to diversify sources of natural gas imports, a substantial amount comes from
Myanmar, increasing the countrys vulnerability due to its exposure to geopolitical
risks. The government aims to reduce Thailands dependency on natural gas for
power generation as stipulated in the Power Development Plan for 20072021 (EIU
2010). However, heavy government subsidy of electricity to residential users may
make this improbable in the next few years. Thailands strength lies in G3. Natural
gas production has improved due to several developments particularly at the Arthit
field in the Gulf of Thailand and the MalaysiaThailand Joint Development Area.
The construction of a third national gas pipeline in the Gulf of Thailand was finished
in 2007 further expanding natural gas production (EIU 2010).

24

H. Cabalu and C. Alfonso

Table 2.1 Individual gas security of supply indicators 19962009


G2 (%)
Country
Years
G1 (m3/$)
China

India

Japan

Singapore

South Korea

Thailand

1996
2000
2004
2009
1996
2000
2004
2009
1996
2000
2004
2009
1996
2000
2004
2009
1996
2000
2004
2009
1996
2000
2004
2009

0.02
0.02
0.02
0.03
0.05
0.06
0.05
0.06
0.01
0.02
0.02
0.02
0.02
0.02
0.06
0.07
0.03
0.04
0.04
0.04
0.10
0.18
0.20
0.23

-0.15
-0.25
-0.11
0.15
0.00
0.00
0.69
2.42
11.17
12.75
13.41
16.96
4.27
4.48
13.32
14.31
6.77
9.02
11.92
12.81
0.00
2.35
8.07
7.86

G3 (%)

G4

108.79
111.01
104.51
96.02
100.00
100.00
91.75
75.68
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
100.00
92.21
74.83
78.81

0.49
0.00
0.00
0.67
0.06
0.00
0.02
0.71
0.99
1.09
1.13
1.27
1.04
0.74
0.62
0.34
0.47
0.85
0.94
1.10
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00

Source Authors calculations


Note G1 gas intensity, G2 net gas import dependency, G3 ratio of domestic gas production to total
domestic gas consumption, G4 geopolitical risk

Korea shows a relatively stable trend in its GSSI from 1996 to 2009. G1 and G4
are as its major strengths. To reduce the economys dependence on imported oil,
Korea introduced LNG in the 1980s to power its natural gas based city gas to the
residential sector. Since then, natural gas use has grown rapidly. Korea relies on
imported LNG for most of its natural gas, though it began producing a small
quantity from one offshore field in 2004. Korea is the second largest importer of
LNG worldwide accounting for 15 % of total LNG imports in 2010. The bulk of
Koreas LNG imports come from a much diversified group of sources which
explains its strength on G4. These 17 import sources include, among others, Qatar,
Indonesia, Malaysia, and Oman, with smaller volumes coming from Trinidad and
Tobago, Algeria, Nigeria, Belgium, Egypt, Brunei Darussalam, and Australia, and
occasional spot cargoes from elsewhere. Korean natural gas demand is shared
almost evenly between the electricity sector and the residential heating sector, with
a smaller amount consumed in petrochemical plants. With demand growing at an
average annual growth rate of 8.4 % between 2003 and 2010, Korea continues to
sign contracts for additional supplies, though most of the new LNG term contracts

Energy Security in Asia: The Case of Natural Gas

25

Table 2.2 Relative indicators of security of supply in selected net gas-importing countries in
Asia
Country
Year
u1
u2
u3
u4
China

India

Japan

Singapore

South Korea

Thailand

1996
2000
2004
2009
1996
2000
2004
2009
1996
2000
2004
2009
1996
2000
2004
2009
1996
2000
2004
2009
1996
2000
2004
2009

0.09
0.03
0.04
0.06
0.46
0.26
0.21
0.20
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.08
0.02
0.25
0.24
0.14
0.12
0.16
0.13
1.00
1.00
1.00
1.00

0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.01
0.02
0.06
0.14
1.00
1.00
1.00
1.00
0.39
0.36
0.99
0.84
0.61
0.71
0.89
0.75
0.01
0.20
0.61
0.46

0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.08
0.10
0.12
0.21
1.00
1.00
1.00
1.00
1.00
1.00
1.00
1.00
1.00
1.00
1.00
1.00
0.08
0.17
0.28
0.18

0.53
1.00
1.00
0.47
0.94
1.00
0.98
0.44
0.05
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.32
0.45
0.73
0.55
0.22
0.17
0.13
1.00
1.00
1.00
1.00

Source Authors calculations


Note u1 is the relative indicator or scaled value for G1 (gas intensity); u2 is the relative indicator
or scaled value for G2 (net gas import dependency); u3 is the relative indicator or scaled value for
G3 (ratio of domestic gas production to total domestic gas consumption); u4 is the relative
indicator or scaled value for G4 (geopolitical risk)

in the past few years with Yemen, Malaysia and Russia include more flexibility for
the purchaser in terms of the ability to lower volumes if necessary. To ensure a
stable supply of gas, Korea is also increasing LNG storage capacity at its four
existing terminals (BP 2011).
Between 1996 and 2000, Singapores GSSI fluctuated but this trend was to
stabilize thereafter. Singapores gas security of supply profile is relatively weak on
G2 and G3 particularly during the tumultuous years. The absence of domestic gas
production combined with high domestic gas consumption makes Singapore relatively vulnerable to natural gas supply disruptions. Its consumption has risen
rapidly in recent years owing mostly to government programs aimed at reducing
carbon dioxide and sulphur emissions and encouraging the use of natural gas for
power generation and petrochemical production (EIA 2007). In 2008, natural gas
accounted for almost 15 % of Singapores total primary energy demand. Singapore
relies entirely on imports to meet its natural gas requirements which are mainly

26

H. Cabalu and C. Alfonso


0.90
0.80
0.70
0.60
0.50
0.40
0.30
0.20
0.10
0.00
1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009
China

India

Japan

Singapore

South Korea

Thailand

Source Based on authors calculations

Fig. 2.1 Gas security of supply index of selected net gas-importing countries in Asia (19962009).
Source based on authors calculations

used for power generation and petrochemical production. Around three-quarters of


Singapores fuel demand for electricity production comes from natural gas. With
gas representing such a large share of electricity production energy needs, diversification of supply is an important issue. All of Singapores piped natural gas
imports come from Malaysia and Indonesia via four offshore pipelines. However,
in 2010 Singapore LNG Corporation Pte Ltd awarded a contract for the engineering, procurement and construction of Singapores first Liquefied Natural Gas
import terminal. The terminal will be a critical component of Singapores energy
infrastructure to ensure diversification of its gas supply sources and enhance its
energy security. It will have an initial capacity of 3.5 million tonnes per annum
and is targeted to be ready for start-up by year 2013 (EMA 2010).
Although Japans GSSI indicates relatively high vulnerability to supply shocks,
its trend has been consistently stable for the period 19962009. Japans security of
supply profile is relatively weak on G2 which is a measure of net import dependency, and G3 which is the ratio of domestic production to domestic consumption
of natural gas. Like Korea, Japan does not have significant domestic natural gas
reserves or production, and gas is imported in the form of LNG. Of the total
primary energy consumption in 2010, approximately 17 % is imported natural gas.
Japans demand for natural gas has been growing at an average annual growth rate
of 3.1 % between 2000 and 2010. This is due mainly to the revision of the Gas
Utility Industry Law where there has been increased competition in the industry as
market entry and prices have been deregulated. In 2010, Japan imported almost
99 % of its gas requirements and this was met entirely by LNG. LNG imports into
Japan comprised 31 % of total world LNG trade, coming mostly from Indonesia,
Malaysia, Brunei Darussalam, Australia, and Qatar. Natural gas is mainly used for
electricity generation, reticulated city gas and industrial fuels. Since Japan has

Energy Security in Asia: The Case of Natural Gas

27

placed priority on the stable and secure supply of LNG, Japanese LNG buyers have
been in general paying a higher price than buyers in Europe or the United States
under the long-term take or pay contracts with rigid terms on volume and price.
Japan lacks a national pipeline network which could interconnect its consuming
areas. The possibility of a significant disruption at one LNG terminal in Japan
poses a potential supply vulnerability issue.

2.6 Conclusion
Many factors determine gas vulnerability of an economy. Domestic production,
gas efficiency usage, volume and sources of gas imports are very crucial in
determining an economys vulnerability. The analysis in this chapter highlights
inter-country differences in individual and overall indicators of gas security
which means that country differences exist with respect to vulnerability to natural gas supply disruptions. This implies that governments need to develop
policy responses that directly address individual countries weaknesses to enable
them to handle natural gas supply disruptions. Policy measures should reduce the
probability of supply disruptions occurring and the costs of disruptions. For
instance, India and China are relatively less vulnerable to supply disruptions
compared to other countries in the sample because of their significant domestic
gas production and small share of gas in their energy mix. This means that the
two countries do not have to rely on gas imports for energy generation.
Governments could implement various measures to better cope with supply
disruptions and significantly mitigate their effects. For instance, gas import
dependence has risks associated with price volatility, natural disaster, political
blackmail and terrorism. Imported gas supplies are either pipeline bound or sea
bound LNG. These transit options are both exposed to risks but it is the degree
of having viable alternative options that defines security of supply. When gas
imports depend dangerously on too few sources, it raises a concern whether this
is compatible with a sensible policy goal of gas supply security. This concern is
exacerbated when taking geopolitical considerations into account. Hence,
diversification of gas import sources is encouraged. Other diversification measures include fuel-switching and diversifying energy mix. Diversification in fuel
types and sources would reduce the costs of supply disruptions by spreading the
risks across different import and energy sources. As Percebois (2006) and
Reymond (2007) summed it up, a country which imports the majority of its gas
at a sustainable cost and ensures the security of supply by well-diversified and
politically-stable sources will not be vulnerable.
Governments also have the option of reducing overall gas dependence by
improving gas efficiency through research and development and adoption of
technologies that reduce gas consumption or increase the efficiency of gas use,
technologies that facilitate gas exploration and production, and alternative processing technologies such as gas to liquids plant. To enhance natural gas supply

28

H. Cabalu and C. Alfonso

security, it is also important that investments in domestic gas exploration and


production activities are encouraged though joint venture projects and that gas
trade routes and sea lanes remain open and secure.

Appendix

Table A.1 Political risk rating of selected gas-producing countries, selected years
Country
Political stability
Algeria
Australia
Bahamas
Bahrain
Belgium
Bermuda
Brunei
Cambodia
Canada
China
Denmark
Egypt
Equatorial Guinea
Finland
France
Germany
Hong Kong SAR, China
India
Indonesia
Iran
Ireland
Italy
Japan
Korea, North
Korea, South
Kuwait
Malaysia
Myanmar
Netherlands
Nigeria
Norway

1996
0
81
81
21
90
..
92
10
79
33
95
17
19
96
78
92
44
15
15
24
88
75
75
6
42
44
58
13
95
8
94

2000
4
90
86
49
82
69
91
22
85
36
96
34
41
100
74
91
75
25
6
32
97
78
83
41
48
64
52
9
99
10
97

2004
9
83
79
47
75
77
96
30
78
39
86
20
32
99
63
71
80
24
6
17
90
62
83
38
59
53
58
14
84
5
93

2009
13
76
78
41
74
72
95
25
85
30
86
25
43
96
66
77
82
13
24
8
84
65
83
35
52
59
47
7
83
4
92
(continued)

Energy Security in Asia: The Case of Natural Gas

Table A.1 (continued)


Country

Political stability

Oman
Pakistan
Philippines
Qatar
Russia
Saudi Arabia
Singapore
Sweden
Switzerland
Thailand
Trinidad and Tobago
United Arab Emirates
United Kingdom
United States
Yemen

58
9
25
55
16
26
73
94
96
48
57
70
77
78
14

29

76
16
20
82
24
47
81
96
98
60
49
73
79
87
11

75
6
12
78
17
20
87
96
92
33
46
68
61
51
5

75
0
11
89
22
33
90
88
92
15
45
81
55
59
2

Source World Bank (2009). Political risk ratings range from 0 for high risk to 100 for low risk

References
APERC (Asia Pacific Energy Research Centre). (2007). A quest for energy security in the 21st
century: Resources and constraints. Tokyo, Japan: Institute of Energy Economics.
APERC (Asia Pacific Energy Research Centre). (2008). APEC energy overview 2007. Tokyo,
Japan: The Institute of Energy Economics.
British Petroleum (BP). (2010). BP statistical review of world energy June 2010. Retrieved from
http://www.bp.com/liveassets/bp_internet/globalbp/globalbp_uk_english/
reports_and_publications/statistical_energy_review_2008/STAGING/local_assets/
2010_downloads/statistical_review_of_world_energy_full_report_2010.pdf)
British Petroleum (BP). (2011). BP statistical review of world energy June 2011. Retrieved from
http://www.bp.com/statisticalreview
Cabalu, H. (2010). Indicators of security of natural gas supply in Asia. Energy Policy, 38, 218225.
Cabalu, H., & Manhutu, C. (2009). Vulnerability of natural gas supply in the Asian gas market.
Econ Anal Policy, 39(2), 255270.
Chandler, A., & Padungkittimal, N. (2008). Thai power sector. Retrieved from http://
www.ctlo.com/TPS-2.htm
Costantini, V., Gracceva, F., Markandya, A., & Vicini, G. (2007). Security of energy supply:
Comparing scenarios from a European perspective. Energy Policy, 35, 210226.
de Jong, J., Maters, H., Scheepers, M., & Seebregts, A. (2007). EU standards for energy security
of supply: Updates on the crisis capability index and the supply/demand index quantification
for EU-27. The Netherlands: Energy Research Centre of the Netherlands and Clingendael
International Energy Programme.
Dolader, J. (2003, June). Gas security of supply in a liberalised market. Paris: IEA.
Economist Intelligence Unit. (2010, November). Thailand: Energy report. Retrieved from http://
www.eiu.com/index.asp?layout=ib3Home&pubtypeid=1142462499
Energy Market Authority (EMA). (2010). LNG terminal development. Singapore: EMA.
Retrieved from http://www.ema.gov.sg/page/21/id:50/
Energy Information Administration (EIA) (2007). Energy Profile of Singapore, in Encyclopaedia
of Earth.Retrieved from http://www.eoearth.org/article/Energy_Profile_of_Singapore

30

H. Cabalu and C. Alfonso

Energy Information Administration (EIA). (2011). Annual energy outlook 2011: With projections to
2035. Washington, DC: EIA. Retrieved from http://www.eia.gov/forecasts/aeo/pdf/0383(2011).pdf/
Energy Information Administration (EIA). (2012). Energy Profile of India, in Encyclopaedia of
Earth. Retrieved from http://www.eoearth.org/article/Energy_profile_of_India
Gnansounou, E. (2008). Assessing the energy vulnerability: Case of industrialised countries.
Energy Policy, 36, 37343744.
Gupta, E. (2008). Oil vulnerability index of oil-importing countries. Energy Policy, 36, 11951211.
Higashi, N. (2009, June). Natural gas in China: Market evolution and strategy. (Working Paper
Series). Paris, France: International Energy Agency.
International Association for Energy Economics (IAEE). (2007). Natural gas: Is there a
decreasing trend? IAEE Newsletter, 16 (Third Quarter).
International Energy Agency (IEA). (2007). Natural gas market review 2007: Security in a
globalising market to 2015. Paris, France: International Energy Agency.
International Monetary Fund (IMF). (2010). World economic outlook database. Washington, DC:
IMF. Retrieved from http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/weo/2009/01/weodata/index.aspx
Jackson, M. (2007, October). The future of natural gas in India: A study of major consuming
sectors (Working Paper #65). Stanford, CA: Program on Energy and Sustainable Development, Stanford University.
Jansen, J. C., van Arkel, W. G., & Boots, M. G. (2004). Designing indicators of long-term energy
supply security. Petten, The Netherlands: ECN.
Kendell, J. (1998). Measures of oil import dependence. Washington, DC: Energy Information
Administration, U.S. Department of Energy. Retrieved from http://www.eia.doe.gov/oiaf/
archive/issues98/oimport.html
Komiyama, R., Zhidong, L., & Ito, K. (2005). World energy outlook in 2020 focusing on Chinas
energy impacts on the world and Northeast Asia. International Journal of Global Energy
Issues, 24(34), 183210.
Percebois, J. (2006). Dpendance et vulnrabilit: deux faons connexes mais diffrentes
daborder les risques nergtiques. (Cahiers de recherch CREDEN, No. 06.03.64).
Montpellier, France: CREDEN.
Percebois, J. (2007). Energy vulnerability and its management. International Journal of Energy
Sector Management, 1, 5162.
Reymond, M. (2007). European key issues concerning natural gas: Dependence and vulnerability.
Energy Policy, 35, 41694176.
Thacker, S. (2006). Recent Indian petroleum, petroleum products and natural gas regulations.
Hydrocarbon World, 2324.
United Nations Development Programme (UNDP). (2007). Overcoming vulnerability to rising oil
prices: Options for Asia and the Pacific. Bangkok: UNDP Regional Centre.
World Bank. (2009). Worldwide governance indicators19962008. Washington, DC: World
Bank. Retrieved from http://info.worldbank.org/governance/wgi/index.asp
World Energy Council. (2008). Europes vulnerability to energy crises. London, United Kingdom.

Chapter 3

Buyer Credit Pricing for Natural Gas


Exports Using Country Risk Ratings
John L. Simpson

Abstract It is important for exporters of commodities, including natural gas, to


price their exports correctly in times of excess demand. It is equally important for
providers of buyer credit for importers of natural gas to price the finance for the
shipments correctly. Pricing buyer credit is vital for the lenders goals, which
includes shareholder wealth maximization if the lender is a bank or a corporation,
but, more importantly pricing credit is important for the optimization of the risk
and return relationship and the diversification of unsystematic risks in export loan
assets. In this chapter, the price of natural gas from a gas exporting country, such
as Australia, is deemed to be the amount of export finance that might be required
as buyer credit. Export returns thus represent the change in the amount of export
finance required by buyers. A higher buyer credit change means a greater amount
of credit required. Using country risk ratings, a risk premium is ascribed to this
buyer credit in order to avoid mispricing of exports and buyer credit in times of
excess demand for gas and thus buyer credit. Importer country examples of the US
and China are investigated. It is posited that country risk ratings can determine the
magnitude of the risk premium to be applied to buyer credit, consistent with risk/
return trade-off theory.

Keywords Export Pricing Buyer credit Risk Ratings Gas China United
States

J. L. Simpson (&)
School of Economics and Finance, Curtin Business School,
Curtin University, GPO Box U1987, Perth, WA 6845, Australia
e-mail: john.simpson@cbs.curtin.edu.au

A. Dorsman et al. (eds.), Energy Economics and Financial Markets,


DOI: 10.1007/978-3-642-30601-3_3,  Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg 2013

31

32

J. L. Simpson

3.1 Introduction
Spot natural gas exports are largely paid for in cash, however, in some instances,
buyer credit is provided either by the exporter, or by the exporters bank or by a
syndicate of banks led by the exporters bank or by a government export, finance
and insurance agency in the exporters country. Such an agency (e.g., Export
Finance and Insurance Corporation of Australia or EFIC) may alternatively provide
direct loans to the gas buyer. Sometimes this latter arrangement is part of the
exporting contract, where the exporter has undertaken to, not only ship the goods,
but to find suitable finance for the buyer for the full amount of the export price. The
export finance might be provided through the Eurocurrency market at a margin
(spread) above the interbank offered rates. The margin is commensurate with
perceived country credit risk, but other factors will enter into calculations. For
example, interest rate policy by global economic powerhouses such as the US has a
significant bearing on debt spreads. For emerging countries with high debt to gross
national income levels, spreads have been found to increase beyond normal risk
premia by six to sixty-five basis points (Dailami et al. 2008).
This paper, for the purpose of a basic analysis, focuses on the basic spreads or
country risk premia derived from risk ratings. Economic and financial risk
components are accounted for in a general sense through composite country risk
ratings which of course include political risk ratings. The question is what size
credit risk premium (spread) should be applied to the finance? That is, what size of
credit risk premium should be added to a prime/reference interest rate? The latter
is assumed the same for all borrowers and assumed constant for the purposes of
this study. The amount of buyer credit equates to the total shipment export price,
assuming one hundred per cent of the sales contract is to be financed. The size
of the credit risk premium relates to the risk and return maxim originally applied in
the securities industry to portfolio theory expounded by Markowitz (1959).
As credit providers add more and more loan assets to their portfolios, whose
returns are less than perfectly positively correlated there is a greater opportunity to
diversify away the unsystematic risk of the portfolio. That is, as soon as the spread
is determined, credit providers also need to include an appropriately weighted
mixture of high and low credit risk loans in their portfolios to diversify their
unsystematic risks.
It should be noted that exports may be priced differently to buyer credit margins
or credit risk premia. Most natural gas exports from Australia are priced according
to a basic relationship with gas prices and the price of oil. This relationship is
discussed later in the chapter. However, the point is reinforced that a benchmark
gas export price equates to the amount of buyer credit needed and the amount of
credit requires the addition of a credit risk margin to the base interest rate.
The question then arises as to how the credit risk premium is to be quantified
assuming finance is available in the first place. Ford (2010), a senior economist
with EFIC, commenting on their behalf at a corporate and business banking forum,
made the point that whilst the global economic condition is worrying, banks and

Buyer Credit Pricing for Natural Gas Exports

33

government export agencies willingness to provide and price trade finance to


assist exporters to export, is conditional on micro-economic factors such as credit
quality of importers, but also on macro-economic factors such as, levels of risk of
political upheavals and other country risk factors such as risks of economic
collapse, risks of potential devaluations or risks of the imposition of exchange
controls.
International banks (and government export agencies such as EFIC) apply
country risk ratings to the calculations of their credit risk premia for international
loans. Country risk ratings represent the ability and/or the willingness of a country
to service its international commitments. The country risk ratings have three
components. Economic and financial risk ratings (which reflect the ability of a
country to service debt) and political risk ratings (which reflect the willingness of a
country to service debt). This study deals with a composite country risk rating
made up of economic, financial and political risk ratings components.
As mentioned, export prices reflect the amount of buyer credit required. The
examination of gas export price relationships and level series risk ratings presents
problems of non-stationary data and serial correlation in the errors of the relationships. Therefore, in order to avoid such problems, the chapter first deals
analytically with export returns, which in turn reflect the changes in amounts of
credit required and changes in risk ratings. Export returns Rg are calculated by
subtracting the value of a gas export price index Pgt1 from the value of that export
price index at time t and dividing the resultant number by the value of the gas price
index at time t  1.
That is,
Rgt Pgt  Pgt1 =Pgt1

3:1

As the returns of the gas price index equate to the changes in the amount of
export/buyer credit required (DCgt ), then.
DCgt Pgt  Pgt1 =Pgt1

3:2

This number can be treated endogenously in a univariate model where the


export returns (that is, the changes in credit required) for each selected importing
country are a function of the change in the country risk ratings. If higher positive
changes are found in buyer credit then a greater amount of buyer credit is needed.
The first model can then be advanced to provide an optimal lag in order to
verify the relationship between export prices and country risk and to demonstrate
that country risk ratings are one of the drivers of export/buyer credit required.
If this is the case, country risk ratings can be quantitatively applied to the amounts
of buyer credit so that such credit is correctly priced. In this chapter, examples of a
country (e.g., Australia) exporting natural gas to China and the United States
(representing two powerful global economies that have a need to import gas and
perhaps finance those imports) are used to compare the financing of those exports
for high and low country risk economies respectively. The introduction (Sect. 3.1)
is followed by a theory and literature review as background in Sect. 3.2.

34

J. L. Simpson

Section 3.3 discusses the methodology and data. Section 3.4 explains the model
and reiterates the issues. This is followed by Sect. 3.5 which provides the results
and this is followed by a conclusion in Sect. 3.6.

3.2 Background
The fundamental position of the paper is that less credit risky countries, in accordance with the tenets of financial economics and the risk/return trade-off, should pay
less for buyer credit or finance for the purchases of all imported products including
natural gas. It is posited that country risk needs to be incorporated into buyer credit
premia for energy export finance. A search of the literature relating to buyer credit for
energy exports does not reveal extensive empirical work in this area. Of course, there
are other factors that influence loan pricing for all exported products, not only natural
gas. These factors relate, for example, to strategic market penetration, periods of
financing required and economies of scale.
Unusually, loan pricing mistakes as well as export pricing mistakes can be
made in times of excess demand for commodities such as natural gas (that is, the
exports or the export/buyer credit might be under-priced). Loan interest rate
benchmarks generally relate the price of credit to various credit risks over and
above costs of funds. These risk premia may be discounted deliberately in times of
excess demand so that the buyer can be induced to buy the product being financed.
The exported product may also be discounted in price. That is, export pricing as
well as loan pricing in an inefficient and imperfect market may be similarly
distorted.
For example, a large gas export deal negotiated in around 2002 by Australia
with China was under-priced in terms of the optimal relationship with oil prices.
However, the Australians involved negotiated a large export contract in a potentially large market. They thereby created an export momentum and thus may have
been conscious of an initial need to buy market share. If buyer credit was
required in this instance it is safe to assume that country credit risk premia
applicable to China would also have been significantly reduced to create less
expensive financing.
Nevertheless, the Chinese deal was negotiated during times of excess demand
when Australia should have been a loan price-maker and an export price-maker
and China, as an economy in transition with higher levels of country risk, should
have been the price- taker. Clearly the Australians bought the business to gain a
market toehold and a precedent was set. But, loyalty of buyers in the longer
term is not guaranteed and is also improbable in times of excess supply. It should
be stated that recent export pricing of Australian gas to China has been more in
line with the global market. It is argued that this should extend to buyer credit
where credit risk premia should be more in line with the market and in accordance
with the risk/return maxim.

Buyer Credit Pricing for Natural Gas Exports

35

Whilst export contract formulae or specific export contract prices are not in
general for public knowledge, natural gas pricing for importing countries is
receiving greater attention as more countries move over to gas energy. The method
of pricing of natural gas is known to differ from region to region. The pricing is
usually linked to oil prices, but which oil prices are they linked to? In Asia (e.g.,
Japan) the import price formula is thought to be based on a basket of crude oil
prices commonly referred to as the Japanese Crude Cocktail (JCC). The UK and
Europe may base their gas prices on Brent oil.
Another danger with the Chinese precedent from Australias view is that in
times of excess supply, other countries will want a similar deal to that written with
China during times of excess demand. For example, Eng (2006) attempts to build a
case for the adoption by New Zealand of the lower bound Chinese pricing model
for possible gas imports from Australia. These New Zealand imports may not
necessarily be sourced from Australia, but the distance from Australian natural gas
fields to New Zealand compares to that from Australia to China. It is, however,
understandable that New Zealand would want to negotiate a lower credit price,
if finance is required, due to its lower level of country risk. This study does not
examine the relationship of export prices and buyer credit to the price of oil. The
chapter merely seeks to test the relationship between buyer credit and risk ratings
of two countries to assist in the calculation of appropriate buyer credit risk premia.
The economic and financial components of country risk are measurable and
objectively assessed, but the overall assessment of country risk is difficult because
political risk is difficult to assess. Political risk is subjective in its assessment. It is
based on opinions relating to political outcomes. Risk rating agencies have
attempted to develop further the method of quantification of this component of
country risk. As mentioned this study examines the country risk ratings which
combine economic, financial and political risk ratings.
Significant progress in regulatory reform has been achieved in developed
economies (for example, the US) and generally in these countries, country risks are
lower. There is a greater choice of natural gas contracts through deregulation and
restructuring within many countries. For example, in the US since 1984 there has
been a separation of natural gas supply from interstate pipeline transportation,
deregulated natural gas production and the wholesale market, and competition has
been introduced in interstate pipeline transportation. Privatization is increasingly
being seen as a means of improving efficiency and increasing investment. Lower
country risks are therefore expected to be associated with developed economies
with deregulated natural gas markets (Juris 2005).
There is a connection between market integration and political risk. It follows
that there is also a connection between export prices (and thus the amount of buyer
credit if needed), loan pricing and the country risks in the buyer country. Asche
et al. (2000) find that cointegration tests show the different border prices for gas to
Germany move proportionally over time. This indicates integration of the German
gas market. Asche et al. also study whether or not there are large price differences
between gas from Norwegian, Dutch and Russian exporters. They find differences

36

J. L. Simpson

in mean prices and the reasons for the price differences are ascribed to differences
in volume flexibility and perceived political risk.
Hartley and Medlock (2005) commence a comprehensive study on the political
and economic influences on the future market for natural gas by recognizing that
required rates of return on investments in energy infrastructures vary geographically. They provide a base case, which assumes that the required rates of return
match those sought in similar US projects. It follows that higher risk borrowing
countries will also face higher required rates of return on buyer credit. Selected
scenarios (representing a range of political actions as well as economic outcomes)
are compared to the base case to ascertain the affect of such factors on the global
gas market.
When Hartley and Medlock (2005) calculate risk-adjusted returns for gas
projects they use data from the International Country Risk Guide (ICRG) as well
as a data series on the risk premium on lending provided by the World Bank. They
construct a gas investment risk index using pure political risk scores obtained
from the ICRG (2011). Hartley and Medlock (pp. 2728) find that increased
gas trade will enhance interactions between regional gas markets and promote
arbitrage and global pricing over time. For example, it is apparent that supply
infrastructure and demand growth in North East Asia will significantly influence
the developing global market for natural gas.
In the absence of an official global benchmark gas export price, the specification
of an interim export benchmark gas export price is proposed, that might be used by
a gas exporting country such as Australia. The change in export/buyer credit
required is derived from this price index. In deciding which benchmark to use as a
proxy the following questions are considered: Which is the most developed and
deregulated market and thus the most likely global leader in global gas market
integration? Which market is by far the greatest consumer of natural gas? Which
market supplies itself to the greatest degree? Which market is showing the greatest
transition from, for example, coal and oil fired power generation for industry?
Which market has an established benchmark for natural gas prices? Finally, is it
feasible for another gas trading country to use such a benchmark for its natural gas
export pricing?
For the sake of analysis, but for the above reasons and in the absence of a
suitable alternative, this chapter examines the use of the USs Henry Hub natural
gas price as the benchmark for export pricing of Australias natural gas. Such a
price series needs to be seasonally adjusted as Australia and the US have different
seasonality and storage factors operating. It also requires conversion into Australian dollars.
The natural gas price benchmark in the Americas is the Henry Hub (HH). This
price is determined at a physical location in Louisiana USA and has a greater
potential than the National Balancing Point (NBP) price in the UK as a candidate
to become a global benchmark price for natural gas (Mazighi 2005). This is
because more gas in the UK market is sold on long-term contracts with prices
indexed to oil. Even though the HH is said to show less normality in fluctuation

Buyer Credit Pricing for Natural Gas Exports

37

than the NBP price, the US is the largest market (estimated in 2005 at more than
660 billion cubic meters compared to around 100 billion cubic meters in the UK).
If the US market is by far the largest market in the world then it is conceivable
that the price mechanism in that market may be more representative, in a global
sense, than other pricing mechanisms such as the NBP. The HH prices are also
quoted on the New York Mercantile Exchange (NYMEX) on a daily basis. The
HH gas price index, for the sake of analysis, is selected in this chapter as the proxy
for a natural gas export price which could be adopted by a major natural gas
exporting country such as Australia.

3.3 The Methodology and Data


The HH natural price represents a standardized quantity and quality of gas in terms
of percentage methane content, heat value per cubic meter, and percentage content
of carbon dioxide and other impurities. In this study, analysis of daily data is not
possible because country risk scores are reported on a monthly basis. The HH
monthly gas price is obtained from the DataStream database and reflects prices at
the close of business each month from 31 January 2002 to 30 December 2005. This
period is selected because it is expected that results will not be distorted by the
rapid increases in world energy prices from 2006 to 2008. The study period is
selected to merely provide an example of how risk premia for buyer credit might
be calculated in times of relatively stable energy prices.
The proxy for country risk is taken as the country risk rating published by the
International Credit Risk Group (ICRG 2011). The data are extracted monthly (as
at the close of business each month) for the same period as the monthly gas price.
The country risk rating is made up of the following components. Economic risk
ratings reflect strengths and weaknesses for a country in its GDP per head, real
GDP growth, annual inflation rate, budget balance as a percentage of GDP and
current account balance of payments as a percentage of GDP. In the composite
country risk rating the economic risks are ascribed a 25 % weighting.
The financial risk rating reflects the ability of a country to finance its official,
commercial and trade debt obligations taking into account such factors as foreign
debt as a percentage of GDP, foreign debt as a percentage of exports of goods and
services, net international liquidity as a percentage of import cover and exchange
rate stability. In the composite country risk rating the financial risk component is
ascribed a weighting of 25 %.
The political risk ratings are 50 % weighted in the ICRG composite risk ratings
scores and the political risk ratings are based on factors defined in the Appendix.
They reflect a countrys perceived political stability by ascribing comparable
ratings to, for example, government stability, socioeconomic conditions, investment profile, internal conflict, external conflict, corruption, military in politics,
religious tensions, law and order, ethnic tensions, democratic accountability and
bureaucratic quality.

38

J. L. Simpson

The composite risk ratings therefore represent country risk which combines
economic, financial and political factors to reflect very high, high, moderate, low
and very low riskiness in the rated countries. The ICRG ratings are preferred in
this study because there is a suitably weighted political risk component in the
composite scores. The method of composite risk calculation is described in ICRG
(2011). The categorization of risk is as follows: Very High Risk: 049.9; High
Risk: 5059.9; Moderate Risk: 6069.9; Low Risk: 7079.9; Very Low Risk;
80100.
The composite risk ratings in ICRG are rated monthly for each country from
zero to one hundred in terms of riskiness. In country risk ratings through ICRG, the
higher the risk score, the lower the risk. In this study the 10 % level of statistical
significance is selected over the full analysis due to the limitation of small sample
sizes.

3.4 The Model


The natural gas export returns are denoted Rg . As noted in Eqs. 3.1 and 3.2, Rg
equates to the change in export credit required (DCg ). These variables reflect the
percentage change in gas export prices and they also reflect the change in the
amount to be borrowed if buyer credit is to be provided for the entire export price.
The change in country risk for a country i at time t (denoted DSCRi ) is proxied by a
variable based on ICRG composite risk ratings. The following equation represents
the first basic model to be tested in this study;
DCgt agt bgt DSCRit egt

3:3

In this case the regression intercept is agt , (representing the base spot gas export
returns or the base change in export/buyer credit required). The regression coefficient is bgt . This coefficient represents the contributions of the change in
composite risk in a particular country to the base export returns and the base
change in amount of export/buyer credit required. That is, it represents the contributions of the change in risk ratings to the changes in amounts required for
financing. The error term, egt represents the contribution to the inter-temporal
changes in export/buyer credit required not explained by an importing countrys
risk factors.
The most important part of this analysis is when Eq. 3.3 is re-specified by level
series variables into a Vector Auto Regressive Model (VAR) by optimally lagging
all of the variables on the right hand side of the equation and testing for cointegration. If cointegration is evident, testing is again undertaken in the framework of
a Vector Error Correction Model (VECM). If cointegration remains evident,
causality (exogeneity) tests may also be undertaken. The risk ratings in the United
States and China may be treated, as in a single multivariate model, as variables that
interact with the buyer credit variable.

Buyer Credit Pricing for Natural Gas Exports

39

HH
16
14
12
10
8
6
4
2
I

II

III

2002

IV

II

III

2003

IV

II

III

2004

IV

II

III

IV

2005

Note HH is the Henry Hub gas price, used for the sake of analysis, as thenatural gas exporter
country price.

Fig. 3.1 Henry Hub gas prices, 20022005

Excess demand conditions are expected to prevail in the global gas industry for
at least the next decade as infrastructures and investment build up. In times of
excess supply, prices of gas will fall as more suppliers compete to sell their
product. In times of excess supply the prices will naturally fall and the consumer/
importer will, under normal conditions, select the lowest price. The exporter is
likely to become a price-taker under this market condition. This study provides for
an export price-maker scenario in times of excess demand where it is possible to
cost in a country risk premium to an export price and therefor the pricing of any
buyer credit.

3.5 Results
Preliminary results are shown in Figs. 3.1, 3.2 and 3.3. Trends of the level series
gas prices and the raw country risk ratings for the United States and China are
illustrated. Figure 3.1 shows that gas prices have demonstrated a degree of
stability with only a steady rise over the period of the study and only two outliers,
perhaps reflecting seasonal or storage factors.
Results show that over the study period the mean of gas prices is $6.09, the
median is $5.77, the minimum is $2.49, and the maximum is $15.00. The standard

40

J. L. Simpson
PRCHINA
65
64
63
62
61
60
59
58
I

II

III

IV

2002

II

III

IV

2003

II

III

IV

2004

II

III

IV

2005

Note PRCHINA refers to raw country risk ratingsfor China.

Fig. 3.2 Country risk ratings for China

PRUS
84

82

80

78

76

74

72
I

II

III

2002

IV

II

III

IV

2003

Note PRUS denotes raw country risk ratings for the US.

Fig. 3.3 Country risk ratings for the US

II

III

2004

IV

II

III

2005

IV

Buyer Credit Pricing for Natural Gas Exports

Table 3.1 Changes in


export/buyer credit required
on country risk changes in
China

41

Statistic

Value

Adjusted R squared
Coefficient
Standard error
t-statistic
DW

0.0804
-3.9556
1.6373
-2.4160
2.2893

Note Results are significant at the 10 % level


Table 3.2 Changes in
export/buyer credit required
on country risk changes in US

Statistic
Adjusted R squared
Coefficient
Standard error
t-statistic
DW

Value
0.0095
-1.4858
1.0206
-1.4559
2.1936

Note Results are significant at the 10 % level

deviation is 2.6587. The JarqueBera statistic at 29.2064 indicates that the


distribution has problems with Kurtosis (5.3059) and Skewness (1.5489).
Over the study period the mean rating for China is 62.0043, median 61.7000,
maximum value is 64.5000, minimum value is 58.7000, and standard deviation is
1.5290. The JarqueBera statistic at 1.2350 indicates that the distribution of ratings
does not suffer from excess skewness (-0.0785) or Kurtosis (2.2215).
For the US, the mean is 78.1298, median 77.5000, maximum 83.7000, minimum 73.7000, and standard deviation 2.3750. The JarqueBera statistic at 4.3508
indicates no major excesses of skewness (0.7181) or kurtosis (2.6019).
With regard to Figs. 3.2 and 3.3, it needs to be remembered that the higher the
score in country risk ratings the lower the country risk. Whilst descriptive statistics
demonstrate that country risks over the period of the study, are lower in the US
than in China (mean of 78.1298 in US vs. 62.0043 in China), the ratings in the US
have been slightly more volatile than in China (standard deviation 2.3750 vs.
1.5280). Both distributions of ratings for China and the US do not exhibit statistically significant (at the 10 % level) excesses of kurtosis and skewness. Overall, it
could be concluded that, in level series, China is of moderate riskiness but the
ratings are gradually improving over the period of the study commencing at a level
of around 59/100 and ending the period on a level around 64/100. However, in the
US, whilst the ratings suggest very low riskiness, it could be argued that country
risks are increasing, commencing the study period at a level of around 82/100 and
finishing at a level of around 77/100.
Initial tests reveal problems with uniformity and normality of the gas prices but
no similar problem with raw country risk ratings. The next stage of the analysis is
regression analysis of unlagged changes in prices and ratings. The change in prices
is converted to returns, but it is recalled that export returns also represent changes
in the amount of buyer credit needed.

42

J. L. Simpson

Table 3.3 Results of unit root tests


Variable
Test statistic: Level series

Test statistic: First differences

Gas price (buyer credit)


Country risk China
Country risk United States
Regression residual

-7.5979a
-7.7860a
-7.5403a
-7.6062a

-2.2249
-2.9239b
-2.0546
-3.2646b

Note a denotes significant at 1; b significance at 5 %. The ADF critical values are -3.5847, 2.9281 and -2.6022 for significance levels of 1, 5 and 10 % respectively

Tables 3.1 and 3.2 contain the results of the regression analysis for changes in
buyer credit required for China and for the US respectively. It is noted that the
explanatory power is not strong for each country model. However, the independent
variables in each case are statistically significant at the 10 % level. The DurbinWatson (DW) test statistic (Durbin and Watson 1971) reveals that serial correlation is not a problem in the errors and thus that the results are not spurious. White
tests reveal that heteroskedasticity is not persistent in the errors as the F statistics
of 0.3426 for China and 0.0438 for the US are not statistically significant at the
10 % level for China and the US respectively. The t-statistics and coefficients
show a negative relationship between country risk changes and gas export returns
in both the United States and in China.
Tables 3.1 and 3.2 show that the explanatory power of the models is lower in
the case of the US than that in China, thus indicating that country risk ratings
changes are more important in the case of China (a higher country risk country).
The results show that the change in country risk in China has a stronger relationship with the changes in the amount of Australian gas export credit required
than that with United States country risk changes (The adjusted R Squared value in
the case of China is approximately 8 % and that for the US is around 1 %).
The sign of the t-statistic indicates that as there is a reduction in the country risk
score changes (meaning higher risk), the changes in gas export credit required
(equating to export returns) increase. This is consistent with risk/return trade-off
theory (a lower risk rating reflects lower returns). However, these models are
unlagged and therefore do not provide an indication of long-term equilibrium
relationships nor do they confirm the exogeneity of the changes in risk ratings.
Augmented Dickey Fuller (ADF) unit root tests (Dickey and Fuller 1981)
results are included in Table 3.3.
The results show that each of the level series gas prices and country risk ratings
are non-stationary series and that the series in changes in buyer credit required and
changes in country risk ratings and the errors of those relationships are stationary.
The level series prices and raw ratings thus are integrated non-stationary
processes. A VAR and VECM are specified in a single model (inclusive of US as
well as Chinese data) in order to apply and confirm VAR based Johansen cointegration (Johansen 1988) and Granger causality tests (Granger 1988).

Buyer Credit Pricing for Natural Gas Exports

43

Table 3.4 Cointegration of export buyer credit required and country risk scores in the US and
China
Hypothesized number of cointegrating
Eigenvalue Statistic Critical
Probability
equations
value
Cointegration rank test (trace test)a
None
At most 1
At most 2
Cointegration rank test (maximum eigenvalue
None
At most 1
At most 2

0.460489
0.350097
0.148269
test)b
0.460489
0.350097
0.148269

53.17430 29.79707
26.02229 15.49471
7.061307 3.841466

0.0000
0.0009
0.0079

27.15201 21.13162
18.96098 14.26460
7.061307 3.841466

0.0063
0.0084
0.0079

Note A linear deterministic trend is assumed. The lag interval is 12 obtained from Akaike,
Schwartz and Hainan-Quinn information criteria.
a
Trace test indicates 3 cointegrating equations at the 0.05 level
b
Maximum eigenvalues indicate 3 cointegrating equations at the 0.05 level

Table 3.4 shows evidence of cointegration in this model. The variables in the
longer-term exhibit similar stochastic trends and together come to equilibrium on
an optimal lag of 12 months.
Table 3.5 contains evidence that Granger causality runs from country risks in
China to the amount of buyer credit required with significance at the 1 % level.
There is no evidence that causality runs from US country risks to the buyer credit
required variable.
There is evidence of joint causality of the US and Chinese variables at the 5 %
level of significance (however, as stated, considered individually the risks in China
are the statistically significant exogenous force at the 1 % level). There is no
statistically significant evidence of reverse causality from the buyer credit required
variable to the Chinese and US risk ratings variables.
Overall, the implications for loan pricing are that exporters of natural gas need
to examine the contribution of country risks to the variability of export returns
(changes in buyer credit required). These results may be supported when optimally
lagged models are also considered and when these models confirm long-term
equilibrium relationships and short term dynamics in exogeneity.

3.6 Discussion
This chapter has not explored other more specific factors that may widen the
spreads in international buyer credit financing, such as those related to country
economic and financial risk that affect overseas buyers ability to service their debt.
For example, high debt to gross national income levels as argued by Dailami et al.
(2008) cause an increase in risk that a country cannot service its debt. The
corollary is that the borrower, who may be financially sound, is unable to repay

44

J. L. Simpson

Table 3.5 Granger causality/block exogeneity wald tests


Dependent variable: Export/buyer credit
Excluded

Chi-sq

US country risk
China country risk
All

0.957900
11.34101
12.12399

lag

Probability

2
2
4

0.6194
0.0034
0.0165

the debt because foreign exchange has been frozen. Thus economic and financial
risk components need to be combined with political risk components in order to
properly price buyer credit. The chapter deals with this issue by considering
country (composite) risk ratings which include economic, financial and political
risk components. Portfolio theory (Markowitz 1959) is also vital as credit
providers strive to diversify away the unsystematic or country specific component
of total country risk when lending across countries.
The importance of political risk in natural gas export markets has previously
been supported in continental Europe studies such as Asche et al. (2000) and,
Hartley and Medlock (2005). The latter also find relationships between investment
and bank lending returns and political risk. Support is found for a significant effect
of country risk on gas export returns (and thus on the amount of export credit
required) and lending and energy infrastructures investment including natural gas.
They also provided evidence for a wide range of political scenarios and economic
outcomes that could have an influence on a global gas market price.

3.7 Conclusion
The study reported in this chapter finds that changes in country risk scores for both
China and the United States are statistically significant variables in a gas export
returns/buyer credit model, which might be suitable for adoption by Australian gas
exporters and Australian providers of export/buyer credit. Risk ratings are
important inputs to assist in the pricing of buyer credit. Evidence is produced that
country risk changes in China have a substantially larger contribution to the gas
export-returns/buyer-credit variability than those in the US. This is an indication
that country risk factors may be an important consideration in ascribing credit
premia for China where the acceptable market rate of interest would attach a risk
premium at least eight times greater than that attached to the same reference
interest rate for the United States. This information is inferred from indications of
the comparative size of the single period unlagged regression parameters in
significant adjusted R2 values and, specifically, t-statistics.
In the context of this study involving gas exporters (and gas export credit
providers) and two large and powerful economies in the US and China as
importers, stronger evidence is provided in tests of cointegration and causality. It is

Buyer Credit Pricing for Natural Gas Exports

45

found that, in a single optimally lagged model, each of the series studied produce
similar stochastic trends and move to stability in the longer term. A long-term
equilibrium relationship exists. In addition, the US and Chinese country risk
variables, when interacting are exogenous in such a model, and, as such, these
variables lead gas export returns (and thus buyer credit) variables on a lag of
12 months with China risk ratings being the greater exogenous force.
Overall, the study suggests that country risk needs to be considered in loan
pricing for gas exports. Credit providers also need to focus on the goals of the firm
not only in shareholder wealth maximization, but also in the diversification away
of the unsystematic risks (country specific risks) associated with loan asset portfolios. This may suggest a direction for future buyer credit pricing for Australian
and other exporters of natural gas as the global market becomes more informationally efficient, as more countries deregulate their gas markets and import greater
volumes of this form of energy in partial replacement of oil imports. Global natural
gas market efficiency will mean substantially more of the natural gas export buyer
credit pricing will be decided by economic, financial and political risk factors.
Further research may be undertaken to compare the explanatory power of the
models in this chapter with those that include specific economic and financial
indicators that indicate the ability of countries and importing companies to service
debt along with pure political risk indicators.

3.8

Appendix

Definitions and explanations of pure political risk components (ICRG 2011).


Government stability ratings are an assessment of a governments ability to
remain in office by carrying out declared policy plans. The subcomponents of this
factor are government unity, legislative strength and popular support. According to
the ICRG ratings, socio-economic conditions relate to pressures that conspire to
constrain government action or to fuel social dissatisfaction. The subcomponents
in this category are the level of unemployment, the degree of consumer confidence
and the level of poverty.
The investment profile factor affects the risk to investment not covered by
other political, economic and financial components and is made up of contract
viability and expropriation, profit repatriation, and payment delays.
Internal conflict is an assessment of political violence in a country and its
impact on governance. The highest rating means that there is no armed or civil
opposition to the government and the government does not engage in arbitrary
violence (either direct or indirect) against its own people. Under this rationale the
lowest scores would apply to those countries where there is ongoing civil war. The
subcomponents of this risk factor are thus, civil war or coup threats, terrorism or
political violence, and civil disorder.
External conflict measures are an assessment of the risk to the incumbent
government from foreign action, which includes non-violent external pressure

46

J. L. Simpson

(e.g., diplomatic pressure, withholding of aid, trade restrictions, territorial disputes,


and sanctions) to violent external pressure (such as, cross-border disputes and allout war). The subcomponents of this category of pure political risk are crossborder conflict, and foreign pressures.
Corruption is an internal assessment of the political system. Corruption distorts the economic and financial environment and reduces the efficiency of government and business in the way foreign direct investment is handled. Corrupt
practices enable people to assume positions of power through patronage rather
than ability. By so doing, an inherent instability is introduced into the political
process. Examples of corruption include special financial payments and bribes,
which ultimately may force the withdrawal of or withholding of a foreign
investment. However, excessive patronage, nepotism, job reservations, favor for
favors, secret party funding, and suspiciously close ties between government and
business have a lot to do with corruption. A black market can be encouraged with
these forms of corruption. The potential downside is that popular backlash may
lead to the rendering of the country ungovernable.
Military in politics is a problem because the military are not democratically
elected. Their involvement in politics is thus a diminution of accountability. Other
substantial ramifications are that the military becomes involved in government
because of an actual or created internal or external threat. Government policy is
then distorted (for example, defense budgets are increased at the expense of other
pressing budgetary needs). Inappropriate policy changes may be a result of military blackmail. A full-scale military regime poses the greatest risk. Business risks
may be reduced in the short-term but in the longer-term the risk will rise because
the system of governance is susceptible to corruption and because armed opposition in the future is likely. In some cases, military participation will represent a
symptom rather than a cause of higher political risk.
Religious tensions emanate from the domination of society and or governance
by a single religious group that seeks to replace civil law and order by religious
law. Other religions are excluded from the political and social process. The risk
involved in such scenarios involves inexperienced people dictating inappropriate
policies through civil dissent to outright civil war.
The law and order components are assessments of the strength and impartiality of the legal system and popular observance of the law respectively.
Ethnic tensions relate to racial, nationality or language divisions where
opposing groups are intolerant and unwilling to compromise.
The democratic accountability component is a measure of how responsive
government is to its people. The less responsive it is the greater the chance that the
government will fall. This fall will be peaceful in a democratic country but possible violent in a non-democratic country. The institutional strength and the quality
of the bureaucracy is a measure that reflects the revisions of policy when governments change. Low risk in this area applies to countries where the bureaucracy

Buyer Credit Pricing for Natural Gas Exports

47

has the strength and expertise to govern without major changes in policy or
interruptions in government services. That is, bureaucracies have a degree of
autonomy from political pressure with an established independent mechanism for
recruitment and training.

References
Asche, F., Osmundsen, P., & Tveteras, R. (2000). European market integration for gas? Volume
flexibility and political risk. (CESifo Working Paper No. 358). Munich, Germany: CESifo
Group.
Dailami, M., Masson, P. R., & Padou, J. J. (2008). Global monetary conditions versus country
specific factors in the determination of emerging market debt spreads. The Journal of
International Money and Finance, 27, 13251336.
Dickey, D. A., & Fuller, W. A. (1981). Likelihood ratio statistics for autoregressive time series
within a unit root. Econometrica, 49, 10221057.
Durbin, J., & Watson, G. S. (1971). Testing for serial correlation in least squares regression. III.
Biometrica, 58, 119.
Eng, G. (2006). A formula for natural gas pricing. Ministry for Economic Development New
Zealand. Retrieved from http://www.med.govt.nz/Templates/multipageDocumentTOC___
23939.aspx.
Ford, B. ((2010, October)). International economic developments and trade finance. Sydney,
Australia: Background remarks for the trade finance panel at the AB +F corporate and
business banking forum.
Granger, C. W. J. (1988). Some recent developments in a concept of causality. Journal of
Econometrics, 39, 199211.
Hartley, P., & Medlock, K. B. (2005). Political and economic influences on the future world
market for natural gas (Geopolitics of Gas Working Paper). Retrieved from http://
www.rice.edu/energy/publications/docs/GAS_PoliticalEconomicInfluences.pdf.
ICRG. (2011). International country risk guide. East Syracuse NY: The PRS Group Inc.
Retrieved from www.prsgroup.com/ICRG_methodology.aspx.
Johansen, S. (1988). Statistical analysis of cointegration vectors. Journal of Economic Dynamics
& Control, 12, 231254.
Juris, A. (2005). The development of markets in the UK gas industry. (Policy Research Working
Paper). Washington, DC: World Bank, Private Sector Department.
Mazighi, A. E. H. (2005). Henry Hub and national balancing point prices: What will be the
international gas price reference? OPEC Review, 29, 219230.
Markowitz, H. (1959). Portfolio selection: Efficient diversification of investments. New Haven,
CT: Yale University Press.

Chapter 4

The Drivers of Energy Consumption


in Developing Countries
Ayhan Kapusuzoglu and Mehmet Baha Karan

Abstract This paper examines the issues associated with the causal relationships
between the energy consumption and the factors (rural population, total population,
gross domestic product, consumer price index and carbon dioxide emission), with the
greatest impact on energy consumption as demonstrated in the literature, for 30
developing countries. Data for the period 19712007 are used with a Granger
causality test. In the light of obtained findings, the present study reveals common
relationships in various directions between energy consumption and the other factors. These results can be explained by factors such as energy markets, resources,
population etc. for individual countries. The findings of the study have significant
policy implications and are therefore of potential interest to policymakers.
Keywords Energy consumption
Causality Developing countries

 Macroeconomic indicators  Cointegration 

4.1 Introduction
Energy, which has become one of the significant inputs in the economic development process, has gained further importance with the spread of globalization. As
a result, countries energy consumption (demand)and their dependence on energy
have rapidly increased Stern and Cleveland (2004).
A. Kapusuzoglu (&)
Yildirim Beyazit University, Ankara, Turkey
e-mail: ayhkap@gmail.com
M. B. Karan
Hacettepe University, Ankara, Turkey
e-mail: mbkaran@hacettepe.edu.tr

A. Dorsman et al. (eds.), Energy Economics and Financial Markets,


DOI: 10.1007/978-3-642-30601-3_4,  Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg 2013

49

50

A. Kapusuzoglu and M. B. Karan

A US Energy Information Administrations energy report predicts that the total


energy consumption of 495.2 quadrillionbtu in 2007 will rise to 738.7 quadrillionbtu in 2035 with an annual increase of 1.4 %on average. As for the distribution
of these estimated figures among OECD and non-OECD countries, the energy
consumption in OECD countries, which was 245.7 quadrillionbtu in 2007, is
estimated to rise to 280.7 quadrillionbtu in 2035 with an annual increase of 0.5 %
on average, while the energy consumption in non-OECD countries, which was
249.5 quadrillionbtu in 2007, is predicted to rise to 458 quadrillionbtu in 2035,
with an average annual increase of 2.2 % (U.S. EIA 2010).
Although energy consumption in developing countries is still much lower than
the international standards, there has been a rise parallel to industrialization efforts
and income levels. The elasticity coefficient calculated to reveal the relationship
between economic development and energy consumption both in developed and
developing countries assumes values close to one which means an increase of 1 in
energy consumption can only be possible by an overall economic growth of 1 %,
particularly for developing countries. In developed countries, on the other hand,
the elasticity coefficient computed between energy consumption and Gross
National Product (GNP) is usually smaller than one (Kulali 1997). The difference
between developed and developing countries with respect to the relationship
between energy consumption and GNP growth mainly stems from the increasing
need for energy in developing countries (Guvenek and Alptekin 2010).
According to the International Energy Outlook published by the US E.I.A. (2010),
on the basis of the previous energy consumption values and estimates until 2035 for
non-OECD countries, it is estimated that the highest increase will occur in the nonOECD Asian countries led by China and India with an increase of 118 % between
2007 and 2035. For the period in question, energy consumption is expected to
increase by 82 in Middle Eastern countries, 63 in Central and South America and
Africa, and 17 % in Russia and other former Soviet countries, while the lowest rate of
increase is predicted for non-OECD European and Eurasian countries.
A number of research papers have demonstrated that the increase in energy
consumption results mainly from the economic development of countries (e.g.,
Soytas and Sari 2003; Hatemi and Irandoust 2005; Lee 2006; Ang 2007; Odhiambo 2010).These results are also confirmed by Kapusuzoglu and Karans
(2010) study. In particular, the ecological approach explaining the relationship
between energy and economic growth places a greater emphasis on the relationship between relative energy and economic growth when compared to the neoclassical approach, noting that energy is a key factor in economic growth.
A recent research paper indicates the importance of population growth and the
ensuing developments in the transportation industry, along with the increase in
economic activity, in determining energy consumption (Sohtaoglu et al. 2007). In
fact, the report published by Shell (2011) predicts a triple increase in global energy
consumption over the next 40 years, revealing that increasing industrialization,
urbanization, infrastructure development and use of transportation in developing
countries as well as China and India with substantial populations, are the most
significant factors triggering energy consumption.

4 The Drivers of Energy Consumption

51

The presence of energy dependence in developing countries brings about the possibility of a mismatch between energy supply and demand. Such a possibility may well
have a potential to affect the level of economic activity and energy demand (consumption). In this context, it will contribute to the research predicting global oil demand
if the drivers of energy consumption in developing countries could be identified.
This study mainly aims to identify the fundamental drivers of energy consumption levels in developing countries and to reveal the causality relationships
between these drivers and energy consumption levels. The energy consumption
levels of the countries under study as well as other certain factors make up the
basic variables of the study, which will be analyzed separately for each country.
There is limited research available in the empirical literature that examines the
relationship between energy consumption and the main economic drivers for
developing countries, and most studies limit their analysis to a single variable. In
this respect the difference between this study and others, and its main contribution
to the literature, is that it examines a multitude of variables having potential
relationships with energy consumption levels. In addition, the study covers a large
number of developing countries and separately analyzes each country, which
allows more exhaustive and realistic results on the subject.

4.2 Theoretical Background


The literature that explains the relationship between energy and economic growth
presents two significant opposite approaches (the neoclassical and the ecological).
These theories are particularly important in explaining the causality relationship
between energy and economic growth. The explanations related to the theories are
given below.

4.2.1 Neoclassical Approach


The neoclassical approach mainly regards an economic structure as a closed system.
Products are manufactured using capital and labor, and are exchanged between firms
and customers. In this process, economic growth is planned to be achieved by
increasing the inputs of labor and human capital. Furthermore, this economic
approach posits that technological innovation or increased capital and labor quality
will also contribute to achieving economic growth. The neoclassical approach has
recently highlighted natural resources, which are examined in two categories,
namely renewable and non-renewable resources (Ockwell 2008). The emphasis of
the neoclassical theory of growth on the energy factor was made possible by the
endogenous growth models, the literature on public expenditure (Barro 1988) and
human capital (Lucas 1988), and the works of neoclassical economists such as
Hamilton (1983), Burbridge and Harisson (1984) and Aytac (2010).

52

A. Kapusuzoglu and M. B. Karan

The neoclassical growth model encompasses three mainstream models. The


first simply deals with technological change, the second with natural resources,
and the third with technology and natural resources combined. According to the
first mainstream categories of the model, all economies grow until they reach an
equilibrium level, the point where further returns to capital are no longer possible.
Growth beyond equilibrium is then only achievable by increasing returns to
existing capital via improvements in technology. Economic growth is a transition
period during which a country progresses toward a steady state, and an underdeveloped economy with low capital stock per worker can achieve a rapid growth
while increasing its capital stock. Accordingly, the neoclassical growth model
supposes that the only reason for sustained economic growth is technological
progress (Solow 1956; Aghion and Howitt 1998; Stern and Cleveland 2004).
According to the second mainstream model, most natural resources exist in
limited amounts around the world, and they are largely non-renewable, which
adversely affects sustainability, a crucial factor in the process of economic growth
and development. Technological and institutional conditions determine whether
sustainability is possible. Technical conditions collectively refer to renewable or
non-renewable resources, the initial amounts of capital and natural resources, and
smooth substitutability between inputs; while the institutional environment
involves the market structure, the system of property rights and the system of
values concerning the prosperity of future generations. Certainly, sustainability
will be technically possible in cases where renewable resources exist or at least
when there is no population increase. Nevertheless, there is a tendency among
mainstream economists to assume that sustainability is technically possible unless
proven otherwise (Solow 1993, 1997; Stern and Cleveland 2004).
According to the final model, both natural resources and technological change
are determinants of growth. As well as substituting between man-made and natural
capital, the possibility of technology improving the output per unit of natural or
man-made capital and labor is considered as an additional means by which growth
can be sustained (Stern and Cleveland 2004). Technological improvements indicate a higher production per unit resource in the future (Smulders 2004).
All three of the above conventional models of economic growth consider
energy to be an intermediate good rather than a primary input into production.
The three models reveal that decoupling economic growth from energy use is a
reasonable possibility, subject, in the case of the latter two models, to various
sustainability constraints being conformed to with regard to the consumption of
natural capital (Ockwell 2008).

4.2.2 Ecological Approach


The economists maintaining the ecological approach criticize the views put forward in the neoclassical approach. The ecological view argues that the closed
system approach adopted by the neoclassical approach is unrealistic and the

4 The Drivers of Energy Consumption

53

economic system should be considered as an open global system. The ecological


view considers the economy as a sub-system of thermodynamics, basing its
arguments upon the law of thermodynamics (Ockwell 2008). Odum and Odum
(1976) conducted a significant study on the subject, which addresses the question
of the origin of economic growth and economic relations through a bio-physical
perspective, and revealed a strong correlation between energy consumption and
gross national product in the US (Aytac 2010).
Re-producibility is one of the main concepts of a production economy. Certain
product inputs cannot be re-produced while a certain cost must be incurred to reproduce others within the system of economic production. While capital, labor and
natural resources are re-producible factors of production, energy is a non-re-producible factor (Stern 1999). Since energy is non-re-producible, its role in the
process of economic growth is highly emphasized by ecological economists.
The first law of thermodynamics (law of conservation) implies the mass-balance principle (Ayres and Kneese 1969). In order to obtain a certain material
output, a greater or equal amount of material is used as an input, and the residual
amount is waste material. Therefore, every production process manufacturing
material outputs requires a minimum amount of input. The second law of thermodynamics (efficiency law) argues that a minimum amount of energy is needed
to carry out the transformation of matter. Every production process involves the
transformation or movement of matter in some way. Although certain elements or
chemicals can be substituted, it is required to move or transform matter, which
therefore brings out the need for energy (Stern 1997; Stern and Cleveland 2004).
In alternative ecological economic models, energy is the only primary factor of
production. There is a certain energy supply decomposed (but not used due to the law
of energy conservation) in the process of service delivery. However, the energy
available at any period needs to be externally determined (Stern 1999). The factors of
capital and labor are treated not as stocks, but instead as flows of capital consumption
and labor services. These flows are calculated in terms of the embodied energy use
associated with them, and the overall value added to the economy is considered as the
rent corresponding to the energy used in the economy (Costanza 1980; Hall et al.
1986; Gever et al. 1986; Kaufmann 1987). Therefore, the prices of the outputs should
be determined by the embodied energy cost (Hannon 1973).
Finally, according to the ecological approach, energy is a fundamental factor
enabling economic production. Some commentators even argue that energy availability actually drives economic growth, as opposed to economic growth resulting in
increased energy use (e.g. Cleveland et al. 1984). From this perspective, the possibility
of decoupling energy use from economic growth seems more limited (Ockwell 2008).

4.3 Literature
There is no consensus on the relationships between energy consumption and
economic growth or their mutual effects.The empirical evidence does not yet exist

54

A. Kapusuzoglu and M. B. Karan

to provide conclusive support for the claims of either the ecological or neoclassical
schools of thought. The trend in recent years suggests that the possibility of
decoupling energy use from economic growth has in fact been achieved largely by
a switch away from the direct use of low quality fuels such as coal to higher
quality fuels and energy inputs, electricity in particular (Cleveland et al. 1984;
Kaufmann 1992, 2004; Stern 1993; Stern and Cleveland 2004).
The causality relationship between energy consumption and economic growth
was first realized by Kraft and Kraft (1978), who detected the presence of a
causality relationship from economic growth to energy consumption. The causality
relationship between energy consumption and economic growth can be classified
under four groups.
The first group is the uni-directional causality relationship from energy consumption to economic growth. It is noted that in this relationship, an increase in
energy consumption positively contributes to economic growth. This is the most
commonly observed direction of the relationship in the literature. The second one
is the uni-directional causality relationship from economic growth to energy
consumption, which demonstrates that policies in favor of energy consumption
have a positive effect or at least do not have any negative effect on economic
growth. This type of relationship implies another most common relationship
between energy consumption and economic growth.
The third group is the bi-directional causality relationship between energy
consumption and economic growth, in which both variables influence each other.
Finally, there is no causality relationship between energy consumption and economic growth and the variables in question do not affect one another. On the other
hand, some studies have shown that certain factors, apart from economic growth,
directly or indirectly influence energy consumption in developing countries.
These studies examine the indirect impacts of factors such as rural population,
total population, consumer price index and CO2 emission upon the process of
energy consumption via their direct effects on energy consumption and economic
growth (Ang 2007; Akinlo 2008; Bentham and Romani 2009; Kebede et al. 2010;
Odhiambo 2010).
Tables 4.1 present the results of the empirical studies conducted on the presence and direction of causality relationships between energy consumption and
economic growth. It is clear that causality relationships exist in all but seven
developing country studies and in all but two developed country studies.
When Table 4.1 is considered, it contains findings in relation to studies conducted in developing countries. As is apparent in the field literature in this context,
there are differences in relation to existence and direction of the revealed causality
relations. While studies of Fatai et al. (2004); Narayan and Singh (2007); Odhiambo (2010) contain a causality relationship from energy consumption to GDP
and studies by Odhiambo (2010) and Kapusuzoglu and Karan (2010) contain a
causality relationship from GDP to energy consumption; in the studies of Murry
and Nan (1996), Wolde-Rufael (2006) and Kebede et al. (2010) it is revealed that
no causality relationship exists between the variables.

19501992
19501992
19701990
19521999
19611997
1965-2000
19702002
19602001
19602001
19602001

G-7

Korea
Shanghai
Canada
Sweden
Korea
G-11

Kebede et al. (2010)


Kapusuzoglu and Karan (2010)
(b) Developed countries
Soytas and Sari (2003)

Oh and Lee (2004)


Wolde-Rufael (2004)
Ghali and El-Sakka (2004)
Hatemi and Irandoust (2005)
Yoo (2005)
Lee (2006)

Narayan and Singh (2007)


Odhiambo (2010)

Wolde-Rufael (2006)

Fatai et al. (2004)

19701990
19701990
19701990
19601999
19601999
19712001
19712001
19712001
19712002
19722006
19722006
1972-2006
19722006
19802004
19752006

India
Zambia
Philippines
Indonesia
India
Algeria
Congo Rep.
Kenya
Fiji Island
Congo
Kenya
S. Africa
Kenya
Sub-Africa
Turkey

(a) Developing countries


Murry and Nan (1996)

(continued)

GDP?Energy consumption in France, Germany and Japan


Energy consumption?GDP in Italy and Korea
Energy consumption?GDP in Korea
Energy consumption?GDP in Shanghai
Energy consumption$GDP in Canada
GDP?Energy consumption in Sweden
Electricity consumption$GDP in Korea
Energy consumption$GDP in US
Energy consumption?GDP in Belgium, Canada, Holland and Switzerland
GDP?Energy consumption in France, Italy and Japan

No causality
No causality
No causality
Energy consumption?GDP in Indonesia
Energy consumption?GDP in India
No causality
No causality
No causality
Electricity consumption?GDP in Fiji Island
GDP?Energy consumption in Congo
Energy consumption?GDP in Kenya
Energy consumption?GDP in S. Africa
Price?Energy consumption in Kenya
No causality in Central Africa
GDP?Electricity consumption in Turkey

Table 4.1 Empirical findings on the causality between energy (and electricity) consumption and economic growth
Author(s)
Country
Period
Direction of causality

4 The Drivers of Energy Consumption


55

Country

ASEAN
G-7
France

US
New Zealand

Table 4.1 (continued)


Author(s)

Yoo 2006
Zachariadis (2007)
Ang (2007)

Payne (2009)
Barleet and Gounder (2010)

19712002
19602004
19602000
19602000
19492006
19602004

Period
Electricity consumption$GDP in Singapore
No causality in Canada, Germany, UK and US
GDP?Energy consumption in France
GDP?CO2 in France
No causality in US
GDP?Energy consumption in New Zealand

Direction of causality

56
A. Kapusuzoglu and M. B. Karan

4 The Drivers of Energy Consumption

57

When Table 4.1 is considered, it contains findings in relation to studies conducted in developed countries and the findings of these studies also display differences. Studies of Soytas and Sari (2003); Hatemi and Irandoust (2005); Lee
(2006); Ang (2007), and Barleet and Gounder (2010) reveal a causality relationship from GDP to energy consumption, and studies of Oh and Lee (2004); WoldeRufael (2004); Lee (2006) and Yoo (2006) reveal a causality relationship from
energy consumption to GDP. No causality relationships were found between
variables in the studies of Zachariadis (2007) and Payne (2009).

4.4 Data Set and Methodology


The data set used in the study is annual based for the period 19712007 for about
thirty developing countries1 identified in the IMF (2010) report. The main factors
associated with energy consumption in the literature often includegross domestic
product (Apergis and Payne 2010; Kapusuzoglu and Karan 2010; Wolde-Rufael
2009), rural population (Kebede et al. 2010), total population (Bentham and Romani
2009), consumer price index (Akinlo 2008; Odhiambo 2010) and CO2 emissions
(Ang 2007). The GDP figures of countries are highly important for the level of energy
consumption. Depending on income level, new needs arise, accompanied by new
means to meet them. Within this cycle, various relationships may exist between GDP
and energy consumption. The total population in a country also indicates the total
number of consumers in that country. Thus, it has a significant effect on the amount of
energy consumed and the energy consumption per country.
Similarly, the population distribution and urbanization rates in a country are
particularly important for the industrialization process and the energy consumption
created by this process. The consumer price index of a country is a crucial indicator in gaining insight about the flexibility of energy-demanding consumers
toward energy prices, and particularly in cases where the energy price data are not
available for a country. Finally, CO2 emission figures of countries indicate the
amount of harmful gases in those countries. This amount of gas is closely related
to the amount of consumed energy or energy consumption in all cases, though it
varies with the quality of the consumed energy. In the light of the above explanations, the present study has brought together the level of energy consumption
and all the above-mentioned factors to examine the causality relationship between
the level of energy consumption and the other factors.
The data used in the study include energy demand (EDkt of oil equivalent),
gross domestic product (GDPper capita in constant 2000 US$), rural population
(RP), total population (TP), consumer price index (CPI2005 = 100), and carbon
1

These countries are;Algeria, Argentina, Bolivia, Cameroon, Congo, Costa Rica, Cote Dlvoire,
Egypt, El Salvador, Gabon, Ghana, Honduras, India, Korea, Malaysia, Mexico, Morocco,
Nigeria, Pakistan, Paraguay, Senegal, Sri Lanka, Sudan, Syria, Thailand, Togo, Trinidad Tobago,
Turkey, Uruguay and Venezuela.

58

A. Kapusuzoglu and M. B. Karan

dioxide emission (CO2kg/2000 US$ of GDP), which were obtained from World
Development Indicators (2011).
Since other countries, notably among developing countries, lacked data for the
period of analysis, these countries were excluded from the study. The main limitation of the study is the limited amount of data, which results from the very
comprehensive sample and variables of the study.
The econometric methods used in the present study bear a parallel to the
approaches used in the above previous studies. Before proceeding with the analysis, the natural logarithms of the data are first taken. Next, stationarity analysis is
performed, the first stage of which consists of the correlogram test. On the other
hand, in the decision-making process about the stationarity of the data, an Augmented Dickey-Fuller (ADF-1979) testthe most commonly used parametric test
and the Philips-Perron (PP-1988) testwhich takes into consideration structural
breaks and trends that possibly occur in time seriesare applied. Grangers (1969)
Causality test is performed to determine the presence and direction of the causality
relationship between the variables.

4.5 Empirical Results


4.5.1 Unit Root Test
Before conducting an analysis with time series data, it is first necessary to
investigate whether these series are stationary. Stationarity analysis is also known
as unit root test. A series without any unit root problems is called a stationary
series. There is the possibility of a spurious regression problem when working with
non-stationary time series. In this case, the result obtained through regression
analysis does not reveal the real relationship (Gujarati 1999). In models constructed by using non-stationary time series, certain problems occur and a nonexistent relationship between the variables is misrepresented as existent. Various
parametric and non-parametric tests have been developed to investigate whether a
series is stationary or of it involves a unit root.
Although there are different unit root tests to investigate the stationarity of
series, the (ADF-1979) test is the most commonly used. In this test, the first
difference of the variable is regressed upon its own lag value and the lag values of
its first differences to test whether the ADF coefficient is zero. One of the most
important points to be considered when performing the ADF test is to determine
the appropriate lag length. The Akaike (AIC) and Schwarz (SIC) information
criteria are often used to determine lag length.
Another unit root test to determine stationarity is called the Phillips and Perron
(1988) test. The distribution theory as the basis for the Dickey-Fuller tests assumes
that errors are statistically independent and have a constant variance. The PhilipsPerron approach relaxes these assumptions concerning error distribution. In other

4 The Drivers of Energy Consumption

59

words, the statistics of this test indicate the Dickey-Fuller t-statistics are modified
by taking into account the less constraining nature of the error process (Enders
1995).
An examination of the results of the unit root tests performed for each country
and for each variable shows that the variables are not stationary of the same order
for all countries. Therefore, it was not possible to apply Johansen or EngleGranger cointegration tests to investigate the presence of any long-term relationship between the variables.

4.5.2 Cointegration Test and Granger Causality Test


A linear combination of two or more non-stationary series results in a cointegration between these stationary series. The Johansen Cointegration Test aims to
determine whether there is cointegration between a group of non-stationary series.
However, to perform Johansens cointegration test, all variables such as A1, A2,,
An whose future values are to be estimated together should share the same order of
cointegration. To put it differently, a cointegration test can be applied when all
non-stationary time series have the same number of unit roots (Lee 1997).
If any cointegration relationship exists between the dependent and independent
variable in the composed model then it is understood that there is at least one
directional causality relationship (Granger 1969) and, in the case of determination
of a cointegration relationship indicating existence of long term relationship
between variables, the causality relationships are required to be analyzed by means
of the Vector Error Correction Model (VECM) (Chimobi and Igwe 2010). However, if cointegration does not exist between variables, the causality relationships
are studied by using the standard Granger (1969) causality test. In the light of the
explanations expressed above, the causality relationship is studied by using the
standard Granger causality test in this study since Johansen or Engle-Granger
cointegration tests could not be realized.
The standard Granger causality is defined as follows: X is said to Grangercause Y if Y can be better predicted using the histories of X than it can by not using
the histories of X. Below is the equation of a model with two variables.
x t a0

k
X

a1 xti

i1

yt b0

k
X
i1

k
X

a2 ytj u1t

4:1

b2 xtj u2t

4:2

j1

b1 yti

k
X
j1

In the equations, u1t and u2t denote error terms which do not exhibit zero means,
a finite covariance matrix and series correlation; and k denotes the lag number for
both variables. After validating the equation, the relationship is formulated as from

60

A. Kapusuzoglu and M. B. Karan

Table 4.2 Granger causality test results (energy consumption-rural population)


Countries
Independentdependent
Independentdependent

Algeria
Argentina
Bolivia
Cameroon
Congo
Costa Rica
Cote Dlvoire
Egypt
El Salvador
Gabon
Ghana
Honduras
India
Korea
Malaysia
Mexico
Morocco
Nigeria
Pakistan
Paraguay
Senegal
Sri Lanka
Sudan
Syria
Thailand
Togo
Trinidad Tobago
Turkey
Uruguay
Venezuela

Energy consumption-rural
population

Rural population-energy
consumption

Prob.

Causality

Prob.

Causality

3.187a
1.978
1.195
1.644
0.752
1.135
0.201
5.501c
0.577
1.815
5.998c
0.384
1.510
2.096
1.045
0.119
6.861c
0.094
5.063c
1.458
1.781
2.685a
1.050
1.129
2.211a
0.560
0.409
1.516
0.874
1.816

0.055
0.155
0.316
0.210
0.530
0.334
0.818
0.009
0.567
0.158
0.001
0.684
0.237
0.140
0.364
0.887
0.003
0.962
0.004
0.247
0.185
0.066
0.362
0.336
0.098
0.645
0.667
0.235
0.427
0.180

Yes
No
No
No
No
No
No
Yes
No
No
Yes
No
No
No
No
No
Yes
No
Yes
No
No
Yes
No
No
Yes
No
No
No
No
No

0.536
4.951b
1.552
0.414
0.122
0.355
4.714b
0.016
3.076b
7.542c
7.943c
0.345
2.231
8.675c
0.897
2.562a
1.952
2.975b
2.700a
4.911c
2.130
1.941
1.743
1.097
2.306a
2.026
0.086
1.183
2.611a
0.598

0.590
0.013
0.228
0.664
0.946
0.703
0.016
0.983
0.060
0.0004
0.0003
0.710
0.124
0.001
0.418
0.093
0.159
0.049
0.054
0.007
0.185
0.146
0.192
0.346
0.087
0.133
0.917
0.320
0.090
0.555

No
Yes
No
No
No
No
Yes
No
Yes
Yes
Yes
No
No
Yes
No
Yes
No
Yes
Yes
Yes
No
No
No
No
Yes
No
No
No
Yes
No

Direction

UD
UD

UD
UD
UD
UD
BD

UD

UD
UD
UD
BD
UD

UD

BD

UD

UDUni-directionalCausality; BDBi-directional Causality


, b , c represent the statistical significance levels of 10, 5 and 1 % respectively

X to Y. The analyses reveal whether two variables influence each other with lag
effects, and if they do, whether this causality is uni-directional (from X to Y or
from Y to X) or bi-directional(both from X to Y and from Y to X).
In the process of applying the Granger causality test in the study, the causality
relationship between energy consumption and other variables is investigated for
each country in construct pairs. First, the causality relationship is examined
between energy consumption and rural population. The results of the analysis (see
Table 4.2) reveal that there is an inter-variable causality relationship in 16

4 The Drivers of Energy Consumption

61

Table 4.3 Granger causality test results (energy consumption-total population)


Countries
Independentdependent
Independentdependent

Algeria
Argentina
Bolivia
Cameroon
Congo
Costa Rica
Cote Dlvoire
Egypt
El Salvador
Gabon
Ghana
Honduras
India
Korea
Malaysia
Mexico
Morocco
Nigeria
Pakistan
Paraguay
Senegal
Sri Lanka
Sudan
Syria
Thailand
Togo
Trinidad Tobago
Turkey
Uruguay
Venezuela

Energy consumption-total
population

Total population-energy
consumption

Prob.

Causality

Prob.

Causality

0.681
4.919c
0.103
6.982c
4.578c
0.392
0.483
9.121c
3.606b
0.950
2.450a
2.402a
1.197
4.452b
1.060
0.355
13.227c
3.346b
4.313c
3.028b
2.055
2.693a
0.259
0.227
4.145b
0.248
1.713
0.817
3.524b
1.475

0.611
0.004
0.980
0.0007
0.006
0.812
0.747
0.0001
0.019
0.452
0.073
0.077
0.316
0.042
0.397
0.703
0.000008
0.026
0.009
0.046
0.118
0.065
0.900
0.797
0.011
0.907
0.179
0.526
0.028
0.243

No
Yes
No
Yes
Yes
No
No
Yes
Yes
No
Yes
Yes
No
Yes
No
No
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
No
Yes
No
No
Yes
No
No
No
Yes
No

3.222b
2.423a
7.059c
0.455
0.322
5.921c
1.760
4.795c
0.398
1.977
5.509c
2.664a
2.202
1.155
1.529
1.643
1.481
3.740b
2.801b
2.516a
1.589
2.015
1.635
0.789
1.015
1.143
1.029
2.064
1.908
3.841b

0.029
0.076
0.0007
0.767
0.860
0.001
0.169
0.005
0.807
0.130
0.002
0.057
0.128
0.290
0.225
0.210
0.238
0.016
0.048
0.079
0.209
0.135
0.197
0.463
0.419
0.360
0.412
0.117
0.152
0.020

Yes
Yes
Yes
No
No
Yes
No
Yes
No
No
Yes
Yes
No
No
No
No
No
Yes
Yes
Yes
No
No
No
No
No
No
No
No
No
Yes

Direction

UD
BD
UD
UD
UD
UD

BD
UD

BD
BD

UD

UD
BD
BD
BD

UD

UD

UD
UD

UDUni-directionalCausality; BDBi-directional Causality


, b , c represent the statistical significance levels of 10, 5 and 1 % respectively

countries, and there was no such relationship in the remaining 14. As for the
countries involving a causality relationship, there is a uni-directional relationship
from energy consumption to rural population in four countries (Algeria, Egypt,
Morocco and Sri Lanka), a uni-directional relationship from rural population to
energy consumption in nine countries (Argentina, Cote Dlvoire, El Salvador,
Gabon, Korea, Mexico, Nigeria, Paraguay and Uruguay), and a bi-directionalcausality relationship between energy consumption and rural population in three
countries (Ghana, Pakistan and Thailand).

62

A. Kapusuzoglu and M. B. Karan

Table 4.4 Granger causality test results (energy consumption-gross domestic product)
Countries
Independentdependent
Independentdependent
Direction

Algeria
Argentina
Bolivia
Cameroon
Congo
Costa Rica
Cote Dlvoire
Egypt
El Salvador
Gabon
Ghana
Honduras
India
Korea
Malaysia
Mexico
Morocco
Nigeria
Pakistan
Paraguay
Senegal
Sri Lanka
Sudan
Syria
Thailand
Togo
Trinidad Tobago
Turkey
Uruguay
Venezuela

Energy consumption-GDP

GDP-Energy consumption

Prob.

Causality

Prob.

Causality

0.348
1.845
2.505a
1.006
2.743a
3.568a
1.695
4.561b
2.124
9.879c
2.977a
2.540a
1.792
0.588
2.291
0.121
4.433b
1.378
1.594
1.107
1.594
0.147
2.736a
2.223
0.056
3.545a
1.093
0.761
1.775
2.551a

0.790
0.183
0.068
0.423
0.080
0.067
0.200
0.018
0.137
0.00007
0.066
0.095
0.183
0.448
0.139
0.729
0.042
0.248
0.208
0.343
0.215
0.703
0.080
0.145
0.945
0.068
0.348
0.389
0.175
0.094

No
No
Yes
No
Yes
Yes
No
Yes
No
Yes
Yes
Yes
No
No
No
No
Yes
No
No
No
No
No
Yes
No
No
Yes
No
No
No
Yes

3.669b
0.119
2.241a
0.805
2.027
0.365
1.847
2.973a
2.172
1.408
4.100b
1.565
2.416
2.170
7.500c
0.289
3.955a
0.855
3.669b
0.392
1.941
9.520c
0.336
4.119a
1.228
3.635a
0.917
0.864
2.300a
1.962

0.024
0.731
0.094
0.534
0.149
0.549
0.175
0.066
0.131
0.261
0.026
0.225
0.106
0.150
0.009
0.594
0.055
0.361
0.018
0.678
0.172
0.004
0.716
0.051
0.307
0.065
0.410
0.359
0.099
0.158

Yes
No
Yes
No
No
No
No
Yes
No
No
Yes
No
No
No
Yes
No
Yes
No
Yes
No
No
Yes
No
Yes
No
Yes
No
No
Yes
No

UD

BD

UD
UD

BD

UD
BD
UD

UD

BD

UD

UD
UD
UD

BD

UD
UD

UDUni-directional causality; BDBi-directional causality


, b , c represent the statistical significance levels of 10, 5 and 1 % respectively

It can be concluded from the results of the causality relationship testing


between energy consumption and total population (see Table 4.3) that there is an
inter-variable causality relationship in 19 countries, which is lacking in the
remaining 11. As for the countries involving a causality relationship, there is a unidirectional relationship from energy consumption to total population in eight
countries (Cameroon, Congo, El Salvador, Korea, Morocco, Sri Lanka, Thailand
and Uruguay), a uni-directional relationship from total population to energy
consumption in four countries (Algeria, Bolivia, Costa Rica and Venezuela), and a

4 The Drivers of Energy Consumption

63

Table 4.5 Granger causality test results (energy consumption-consumer price index)
Countries
Independentdependent
Independentdependent
Direction

Algeria
Argentina
Bolivia
Cameroon
Congo
Costa Rica
Cote Dlvoire
Egypt
El Salvador
Gabon
Ghana
Honduras
India
Korea
Malaysia
Mexico
Morocco
Nigeria
Pakistan
Paraguay
Senegal
Sri Lanka
Sudan
Syria
Thailand
Togo
Trinidad Tobago
Turkey
Uruguay
Venezuela

Energy consumption-CPI

CPI-Energy consumption

Prob.

Causality

Prob.

Causality

1.410
0.627
2.141
0.333
2.532a
1.453
0.652
4.805c
0.822
7.315b
0.018
1.414
7.336c
5.928c
4.730b
3.131a
0.155
1.622
13.975c
2.916a
0.101
0.004
1.499
5.055b
4.780b
0.319
0.749
5.502c
3.169a
2.262

0.261
0.603
0.135
0.567
0.096
0.249
0.425
0.005
0.448
0.010
0.892
0.258
0.002
0.003
0.036
0.058
0.695
0.214
0.00005
0.069
0.751
0.944
0.239
0.012
0.036
0.575
0.393
0.009
0.056
0.121

No
No
No
No
Yes
No
No
Yes
No
Yes
No
No
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
No
No
Yes
Yes
No
No
No
Yes
Yes
No
No
No
Yes
No

1.356
0.404
2.107
2.527
0.665
1.843
0.377
1.261
1.325
0.343
1.626
0.784
1.325
2.141
4.070a
0.759
0.820
0.431
0.903
2.589a
0.823
4.024a
3.257a
1.420
0.115
2.641
1.830
1.825
2.089
1.404

0.277
0.750
0.139
0.121
0.521
0.163
0.543
0.312
0.280
0.561
0.210
0.465
0.280
0.118
0.051
0.476
0.371
0.653
0.415
0.091
0.370
0.053
0.052
0.257
0.736
0.113
0.185
0.178
0.141
0.261

No
No
No
No
No
No
No
No
No
No
No
No
No
No
Yes
No
No
No
No
Yes
No
Yes
Yes
No
No
No
No
No
No
No

UD

UD

UD

UD
UD
BD
UD

UD
BD

UD
UD
UD
UD

UD

UDUni-directional causality; BDBi-directional causality


a b c
, , represent the statistical significance levels of 10, 5 and 1 % respectively

bi-directional causality relationship between energy consumption and total population in seven countries (Argentina, Egypt, Ghana, Honduras, Nigeria, Pakistan
and Paraguay).
It is clear from the results of the causality relationship between energy consumption and GDP (see Table 4.4) that an inter-variable causality relationship
exists in 17 countries, while the remaining 13 countries lack such a relationship.
As for the countries involving a causality relationship, there is a uni-directional
relationship from energy consumption to GDP in six countries (Congo, Costa Rica,
Gabon, Honduras, Sudan and Venezuela), a uni-directional relationship from GDP

64

A. Kapusuzoglu and M. B. Karan

Table 4.6 Granger causality test results (energy consumption-CO2 emission)


Countries
Independentdependent
Independentdependent
Energy consumption-CO2
Algeria
Argentina
Bolivia
Cameroon
Congo
Costa Rica
Cote Dlvoire
Egypt
El Salvador
Gabon
Ghana
Honduras
India
Korea
Malaysia
Mexico
Morocco
Nigeria
Pakistan
Paraguay
Senegal
Sri Lanka
Sudan
Syria
Thailand
Togo
Trinidad
Tobago
Turkey
Uruguay
Venezuela

Direction

CO2-Energy consumption

Prob.

Causality F

Prob.

Causality

7.776c
0.681
1.105
0.031
1.216
3.190b
0.002
3.027a
2.139
0.328
7.874c
3.411a
14.932c
5.363b
8.821c
2.589a
8.342c
2.718
131.319c
1.552
0.034
0.292
1.096
8.490c
4.695b
10.062c
0.355

0.008
0.414
0.300
0.969
0.277
0.039
0.961
0.091
0.135
0.570
0.008
0.073
0.00003
0.026
0.005
0.062
0.006
0.108
0.0000000000005
0.221
0.854
0.592
0.302
0.006
0.016
0.003
0.555

Yes
No
No
No
No
Yes
No
Yes
No
No
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
No
Yes
No
No
No
No
Yes
Yes
Yes
No

0.00075
0.031
14.114c
1.810
2.537
0.739
1.328
0.00069
9.833b
4.395b
1.764
0.231
4.139b
1.516
2.416
3.568b
7.566c
0.000003
5.314b
0.951
0.314
0.035
13.236c
8.126c
1.163
0.484
0.309

0.978
0.860
0.0007
0.1810
0.120
0.538
0.257
0.979
0.0005
0.043
0.193
0.633
0.025
0.226
0.129
0.020
0.009
0.998
0.027
0.336
0.578
0.852
0.0009
0.007
0.326
0.491
0.581

No
No
Yes
No
No
No
No
No
Yes
Yes
No
No
Yes
No
No
Yes
Yes
No
Yes
No
No
No
Yes
Yes
No
No
No

UD

UD

UD

UD
UD
UD
UD
UD
BD
UD
UD
BD
BD

BD

UD
BD
UD
UD

0.752
0.489
3.622b

0.391
0.617
0.039

No
No
Yes

1.428
1.608
0.774

0.240
0.217
0.470

No
No
No

UD

UDUni-directional causality; BDBi-directional causality


, b , c represent the statistical significance levels of 10, 5 and 1 % respectively

to energy consumption in six countries (Algeria, Malaysia, Pakistan, Sri Lanka,


Syria and Uruguay), and a bi-directional causality relationship between energy
consumption and GDP in five countries (Bolivia, Egypt, Ghana, Morocco and
Togo).
As is seen from the results the causality relationship between energy consumption and CPI (see Table 4.5), a causality relationship exists between the
variables in 14 countries, while there is no such relationship in the remaining 16.
With regard to the countries with a causality relationship, 10 countries (Congo,

4 The Drivers of Energy Consumption

65

Egypt, Gabon, India, Korea, Mexico, Pakistan, Syria, Thailand and Uruguay) have
a uni-directional relationship from energy consumption to CPI, two countries (Sri
Lanka and Sudan) have a uni-directional relationship from CPI to energy consumption, and two countries (Malaysia and Paraguay) have a bi-directional causality relationship between energy consumption and CPI.
As is clearly seen from the results of the causality relationship between energy
consumption and CO2 (see Table 4.6), 19 countries involve an inter-variable
causality relationship, which the remaining 11 countries lack. As for the countries
with a causality relationship, 10 countries (Algeria, Costa Rica, Egypt, Ghana,
Honduras, Korea, Malaysia, Thailand, Togo and Venezuela) have a uni-directional
relationship from energy consumption to CO2, four countries (Bolivia, El Salvador, Gabon and Sudan) have a uni-directional relationship from CO2 to energy
consumption, and five countries (India, Mexico, Morocco, Pakistan and Syria)
have a bi-directional causality relationship between energy consumption and CO2.

4.6 Conclusion
The present study investigates the causality relationship between energy consumption and the factors with the greatest impact on energy consumption as
demonstrated in the literature (rural population, total population, gross domestic
product, consumer price index and carbon dioxide emission) for 30 developing
countries between 1971 and 2007.
As suggested in the literature, quite complex and different causality relationships
are found among the variables in question (Soytas and Sari 2003; Fatai et al. 2004; Oh
and Lee 2004; Ghali and El-Sakka 2004; Yoo 2005; Hatemi and Irandoust 2005; Lee
2006; Yoo 2006; Ang 2007; Narayan and Singh 2007; Odhiambo 2010; Barleet and
Gounder 2010; Kapusuzoglu and Karan 2010) and there is no causality relationship
in certain circumstances (Murry and Nan 1996; Wolde-Rufael 2006; Zachariadis
2007; Payne 2009; Kebede et al. 2010). In the light of the results, it is clear that the
presence or absence of such relationships originate from the country specific characteristics rather than from the impact of variables. To put it differently, factors
including energy security of countries, their proximity to raw materials, potentials for
industrialization, energy production capacities, economic development levels,
population and its distribution are highly important in the process.
The results of the analyses revealed total population (19 countries) and CO2
emission (19 countries) as the variables with the highest causality relationships with
energy consumption for the developing countries under study. These results conform
to expectations as the population of countries also signifies the number of consumers
they have. Therefore, possible rises or declines in population are expected to have a
close relationship with energy consumption. The amount of CO2 emission is also
closely correlated with energy consumption. The amount of CO2 emission, which
could be explained as the harmful gases produced as a result of energy consumption,
varies with the changes in consumption levels. However, the change in the amount of

66

A. Kapusuzoglu and M. B. Karan

CO2 emission may not be directly proportional to energy consumption. Since the
same amount of output can be obtained by using smaller amounts of energy through
country energy efficiency and quality levels, less energy consumption needs less
energy production, thus also producing less CO2 emissions.
The consumer price index (CPI) was found to be the variable with the least
causality relationship with energy consumption for the countries under study. The
consumer price index is a variable used to indicate the impact of energy prices upon
the level of energy consumption. Moreover, it also provides insight into the flexibility
of the energy-demanding consumer units in these countries toward energy price. On
the basis of the results, it could be argued that the developing countries under study
have lower levels of flexibility toward energy prices, or in other words, energy
consumption levels are not strongly affected by the changes in energy prices.
By examining the analysis results in terms of GDP, a crucial indicator in the
process of economic growth, it is concluded that there exists a causality relationship
between energy consumption and GDP in 17 of the countries under study. Of the two
fundamental approaches examining the relationship between energy and economic
growth, the ecological approach, which considers energy as the main factor in the
process of economic growth, applies to the countries involving such a relationship;
while in the countries lacking such a relationship, the neoclassical approach is valid
as it does not regard energy as a crucial factor of production and simply focuses on
capital and labor as the main factors of production.
As a result, the present study reveals common relationships in various directions between energy consumption and the other factors. These results can be
explained by factors such as energy markets, resources, population for individual
countries. Therefore, empirical evidence on economic growth in the developing
countries over recent years can be explained by the ecological approach and it
seems at first sight to suggest some degree of decoupling. These results indicate
highly complicated relationships between the variables. Obviously, it is difficult to
make a generalization based on these results, and to arrive at a conclusion by
grouping the developing countries under study. Still, it may be possible to interpret
inter-variable relationships by considering the specific characteristics of individual
countries. It can be argued that the policy makers of developing countries should
also include the other socio-economic factors when considering the issue of energy
consumption by being aware that GDP is not the sole determining factor and
should take into consideration these other factors in any analytical models they
establish in relation to energy consumption.

References
Aghion, P., & Howitt, P. (1998). Endogenous Growth Theory. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Akinlo, A. E. (2008). Energy consumption and economic growth: Evidence from 11 Sub-Sahara
African countries. Energy Economics, 30, 23912400.
Ang, J. B. (2007). CO2 emissions, energy consumption and output in France. Energy Policy, 35,
47724778.

4 The Drivers of Energy Consumption

67

Apergis, N. & Payne, J.E. (2010). Renewable energy consumption and ecnomic growth: Evidence
from a panel of OECD countries. Energy policy, 38, 656660.
Ayres, R. U., & Kneese, A. V. (1969). Production, consumption and externalities. American
Economic Review, 59, 282297.
Aytac, D. (2010). Enerji ve ekonomik byme iliskisinin ok degiskenli VAR yaklasm ile
tahmini.Maliye Dergisi, 158, 482495.
Barleet, M., & Gounder, R. (2010). Energy consumption and economic growth in New Zealand:
Results of trivariate and multivariate models. Energy Policy, 38, 35083517.
Barro, R. J. (1988). Governmentspending in a simple model of endogenous growth. (NBER
Working Paper, No. 2588). Washington, DC: NBER.
Bentham, A., & Romani, M. (2009). Fuelling growth: What drives energy demand in developing
countries. The Energy Journal, 30(3), 147170.
Burbridge, J., & Harrison, A. (1984). Testing for the effects of oil-price rises using vector auto
regression. International Economic Review, 25, 459484.
Chimobi, O. P., & Igwe, O. L. (2010). Budget deficit, money supply and inflation in Nigeria.
European Journal of Economics, Finance and Administrative Sciences, 19, 5260.
Cleveland, C. J., Costanza, R., Hall, C. A. S. & Kaufmann, R. (1984). Energy and the U.S.
economy: A biophysical perspective. Science, 225(4665), 890897.
Costanza, R. (1980). Embodied energy and economic valuation. Science, 210, 12191224.
Dickey, D., & Fuller, W. (1979). Distribution of the estimators for autoregressive time series with
a unit root. Journal of the American Statistical Association, 74(366), 427431.
Enders, W. (1995). Applied Econometric Time Series. New York, NY: John Wiley & Sons.
Fatai, K., Oxley, L., & Scrimgeour, F. G. (2004). Modelling the causality relationship between
energy consumption and GDP in New Zealand, Australia, India, Indonesia, The Philippines
and Thailand. Mathematics and Computers in Simulation, 64, 431445.
Gever, J., Kaufmann, R. K., Skole, D., & Vorosmarty, C. (1986). Beyond Oil: The Threat to Food
and Fuel in the Coming Decades. Cambridge, MA: Ballinger.
Ghali, K. H., & El-Sakka, M. I. T. (2004). Energy use and output in Canada: A multivariate
cointegration analysis. Energy Economics, 26, 225238.
Granger, C. W. J. (1969). Investigating causality relations by econometric models and crossspectral methods. Econometrica, 37(3), 424438.
_
Gujarati, D. N. (1999). Temel ekonometri (ev. U. Senesen ve G.G. Senesen). Istanbul,
Turkey:
Literatr Yaynlar.
_ kisi: OECD lkelerine
Guvenek, B., & Alptekin, V. (2010). Enerji Tketimi ve Byme Ilis
_ kin Bir Panel Veri Analizi. Enerji, Piyasa ve Dzenleme, 1(2), 172193.
Ilis
Hall, C. A. S., Cleveland, C. J., & Kaufmann, R. K. (1986). Energy and resource quality: the
ecology of the economic process. New York, NY: Wiley Interscience.
Hamilton, J. D. (1983). Oil and the macro economy Since World War II. Journal of Political
Economy, 91, 228248.
Hannon, B. (1973). The structure of the ecosystem. Journal of Theoretical Biology, 41, 535546.
Hatemi, A., & Irandoust, M. (2005). Energy consumption and economic growth in Sweden: A
leveraged bootstrap approach, (19652000). International Journal of Applied Econometrics
and Quantitative Studies, 2(4), 8798.
IMF (2010). International Monetary Fund emerging and developing economies list, World
economic outlook database. Washington, DC: IMF. Retrieved from http://www.imf.org.
Kaufmann, R. K. (1987). Biophysical and Marxist economics: Learning from each other.
Ecological Modelling, 38, 91105.
Kaufmann, R. K. (1992). A biophysical analysis of the energy/real GDP ratio: Implications for
substitution and technical change. Ecological Economics, 6, 3556.
Kaufmann, R. K. (2004). The mechanisms for autonomous energy efficiency increases: A
cointegration analysis of the US energy/GDP ratio. Energy Journal, 25(1), 6386.
Kapusuzoglu, A., & Karan, M. B. (2010). An analysis of the co-integration and causality
relationship between electricity consumption and gross domestic product (GDP) in the

68

A. Kapusuzoglu and M. B. Karan

developing countries: An empirical study of Turkey. Business and Economics Research


Journal, 1(3), 5768.
Kebede, E., Kagochi, J., & Jolly, C. M. (2010). Energy consumption and economic development
in Sub-Sahara Africa. Energy Economics, 32, 532537.
Kraft, J., & Kraft, A. (1978). On the relationship between energy and GNP. Journal of Energy
and Development, 3, 401403.
Kulali, I. (1997). Elektrik Sektrnde zellestirme ve Trkiye Uygulamas. Ankara, Turkey: DPT.
Lee, U. (1997). Stock market and macroeconomic policies: New evidence from Pacific basin
countries. Multinational Finance Journal, 1(1), 273288.
Lee, C. C. (2006). The causality relationship between energy consumption and GDP in G-11
countries revisited. Energy Policy, 34, 10861093.
Lucas, R. (1988). On the mechanics of economic development. Journal of Monetary Economics,
22, 342.
Murry, D. A., & Nan, G. D. (1996). A definition of the gross domestic productelectrification
interrelationship.The. Journal of Energy and Development, 19(2), 275283.
Narayan, P. K., & Singh, B. (2007). The electricity consumption and GDP nexus for the Fiji
Islands. Energy Economics, 29, 11411150.
Ockwell, D. G. (2008). Energy and economic growth: Grounding our understanding in physical
reality. Energy Policy, 36, 46004604.
Odhiambo, N. M. (2010). Energy consumption, prices and economic growth in three SSA
Countries: A comparative study. Energy Policy, 38, 24632469.
Odum, H., & Odum, E. (1976). Energy basis for man and nature. New York, NY: McGraw-Hill
Company.
Oh, W., & Lee, K. (2004). Causality relationship between energy consumption and GDP
revisited: The case of Korea 19701999. Energy Economics, 26, 5159.
Payne, J. E. (2009). On the dynamics of energy consumption and output in the US. Applied
Energy, 86, 575577.
Phillips, P. C. B., & Perron, P. (1988). Testing for unit root in the time series regression.
Biometrika, 75(2), 335346.
Shell (2011). Shell Energy Scenarios to 2050 Report. Retrieved from http://www.static.shell.com/
static/aboutshell/downloads/aboutshell/signals_signposts.pdf.
Smulders, S. (2004). Endogenous technical change, natural resources and growth. In R. Ayres, D.
Simpson, & M. Toman (Eds.), Scarcity and growth in the new millennium. Washington, DC:
Resources for the Future.
Sohtaoglu, N. H., Diz, I., & Erbas, M. F. (2007). Enerji Kaynaklarnn Arz ve Talebine Ynelik
Kresel Egilimlerin Tarihsel Srete Karslastrmal Analizi. Trkiye 10. Enerji Kongresi,
Dnya Enerji Konseyi Trk Milli Komitesi. Retrieved from http://www.dektmk.org.tr/pdf/
enerji_kongresi_10/Nazif_Hulagu.pdf.
Solow, R. M. (1956). A contribution to the theory of economic growth. Quarterly Journal of
Economics, 70, 6594.
Solow, R. M. (1993). An almost practical step toward sustainability. Resources Policy, 19,
162172.
Solow, R. M. (1997). Reply: Georgescu-Roegen versus Solow/Stiglitz. Ecological Economics,
22, 267268.
Soytas, U., & Sari, R. (2003). Energy consumption and GDP: Causality relationship in G-7
countries and emerging markets. Energy Economics, 25, 3337.
Stern, D. I. (1993). Energy use and economic growth in the USA. Energy Economics, 15,
137150.
Stern, D. I. (1997). Limits to substitution and irreversibility in production and consumption: A
neoclassical interpretation of ecological economics. Ecological Economics, 21, 197215.
Stern, D. I. (1999). Is energy cost an accurate indicator of natural resource quality? Ecological.
Economics, 31, 381394.
Stern, D. I., & Cleveland, C. J. (2004). Energy and economic growth. (Rensselaer Working
Papers in Economics, No. 0410). Troy, NY: Rensselaer Polytechnic Institute.

4 The Drivers of Energy Consumption

69

US E.I.A. (2010). US Energy Information Administration (EIA) international energy statistics


database, annual energy outlook 2010.Washington, DC: US Department of Energy. http://
www.eia.doe.gov.
Wolde-Rufael, Y. (2004). Disaggregated industrial energy consumption and GDP: The case of
Shanghai 19521999. Energy Economics, 26, 6975.
Wolde-Rufael, Y. (2006). Electricity consumption and economic growth: A time series
experience for 17 African countries. Energy Policy, 34, 11061114.
Wolde-Rufael, Y. (2009). Energy consumption and economic growth: The African experience
revisited. Energy Economics, 31, 217224.
World Development Indicators. (2011).World Development Indicators Database. Washington,
DC: World Bank. Retrieved from http://databank.worldbank.org/ddp/home.do.
Yoo, S. H. (2005). Electricity consumption and economic growth: Evidence from Korea. Energy
Policy, 33, 16271632.
Yoo, S. H. (2006). The causality relationship between electricity consumption and economic
growth in the ASEAN countries. Energy Policy, 34, 35733582.
Zachariadis, T. (2007). Exploring the relationship between energy use and economic growth with
bivariate models: New evidence from G-7 countries. Energy Economics, 29, 12331253.

Part II

Environmental Issues and Renewables

Chapter 5

Renewable Energy Production Capacity


and Consumption, Economic Growth
and Global Warming
Henk von Eije, Steven von Eije and Wim Westerman

Abstract This chapter estimates the interrelationships between growth in Gross


Domestic Product (GDP), carbon dioxide (CO2) emissions in interaction with the
consumption of fossil fuel and renewable energy consumption in a global context.
In such a system the variable of renewable energy production capacity is introduced. It is found that growth in this variable has a significant effect on the growth
of renewable energy consumption. This is the case for instantaneous unilateral
regressions as well as for a vector error correction model. For the latter model the
finding is that renewable capacity reduces fossil fuel use after some years, while it
also reduces economic growth. This suggests a difficult trade-off between applying
renewables capacity for CO2 reductions, while also trying to maintain economic
growth.

The authors are associate professor at the Faculty of Economics and Business of the University
of Groningen, energy analyst at the Groningen-based Energy Delta Institute, and assistant
professor of the Faculty of Economics and Business of the University of Groningen,
respectively.
H. von Eije (&)  W. Westerman
University of Groningen, P.O. Box 800 9700 AV, Groningen, The Netherlands
e-mail: j.h.von.eije@rug.nl
S. von Eije
Energy Delta Institute, P.O. Box 11073 9700 CB, Groningen, The Netherlands

A. Dorsman et al. (eds.), Energy Economics and Financial Markets,


DOI: 10.1007/978-3-642-30601-3_5, Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg 2013

73

74

H. von Eije et al.

5.1 Introduction
Economic growth requires energy consumption. Because energy consumption still
mainly comes from the fossil fuels, carbon dioxide (CO2) emissions occur. Such
emissions are very likely to generate global warming effects.1 Global warming
threatens the fundamentals of living for many, through lower access to water, food,
health, land, and the environment as well as sudden climate changes (Stern 2006).
It is thus of utmost importance to reduce CO2 emissions by diminishing the
magnitude of fossil fuel consumption. However, humanity is assumed to benefit
from economic growth.2 It is therefore relevant to increase the use of substitutes
for fossil fuel consumption and the capacity to produce such substitutes in order to
reduce CO2 emissions while retaining economic growth.
Relationships between energy consumption and economic growth have been
studied for a long time by many authors. In economics the first attempts are based
on including energy in the production function together with labor, capital and
materials. Later various types of energy are distinguished (Fuss 1977) and dynamic
relationships are studied (Pindyck and Rotemberg 1983). The relationships are also
studied the other way around, namely when energy consumption is derived from
the demand for a firms produced output (Berndt and Wood 1975). Also energy
prices are considered to influence output (McMillin and Smyth 1994). The various
causal relationships suggest the idea that the relationships may not be unilateral,
but bi-directional. New techniques, like the Granger causality and Vector Error
Correction models, nowadays enable researchers to study such mutual interactions
too (Alam et al. 2011; Apergis and Payne 2009; Chontanawat et al. 2008). This
paper builds upon the existing literature and extends it by incorporating the consumption of renewable energy and the production capacity of renewable energy.3
It appears that, no academic literature exists that takes into account both renewable
energy consumption and renewable energy generating capacity in the context of
economic growth. This work is therefore in line with the call for new approaches
as suggested in the literature review of Ozturk (2010).
1

While it is a fact that most of the CO2 emissions are not man-made, it is assumed that the
equilibrium of CO2 generation and CO2 use may be disturbed if humanity adds the CO2
embedded in fossil fuels to the atmosphere.
2
Economic growth may also have negative externalities not related to CO2 emissions, like the
destruction of tropical forests and habitats, the extinction of species, and environmental pollution.
3
The term renewable energy is preferred to alternative energy. Alternative energy sources
have not been considered so previously. Historically the use of wood and other plant products was
the major source of energy, and it is still an important source of energy in many developing
countries. Later, wind energy and water power became important energy sources. It will be clear
that these sources would then not be considered to be alternative sources. Only now, after the
industrial revolution where the massive use of coal, gas and oil became the major sources of
worldwide energy production, one may call them alternative energy uses, because they do not use
the fossil fuels generated during the ages of the existence of the world. Nowadays, also solar
energy, tide and wave based electricity and waste based sources of energy production are also
included amongst the (alternative or) renewable sources.

5 Renewable Energy Production Capacity and Consumption

75

There is a possible feedback of CO2 emissions on economic growth as described in


the Stern Review (Stern 2006) in the very long-run. Because there is only data available
for the medium-run (namely 19712008), the interactions of CO2 emissions on economic growth and fossil and renewable energy consumption are not considered.
Therefore a two-step procedure is followed. First a study is made of the relationships
between the major variables unilaterally. It is then found that the growth of fossil fuel
consumption and the growth of Gross Domestic Product (GDP) significantly increase
CO2 emission growth. The growth of fossil fuel consumption is strongly influenced by
economic growth. Finally, the growth of renewable capacity has a marginal significant
positive effect on the growth of renewables consumption, while growth in the latter
significantly increases the growth of renewable energy capacity.
Second, the interactions between the major variables are studied using an error correction model with one lag and one cointegration factor. The results indicate that fossil fuel
consumption reacts relatively fast to deviations from the equilibrium. Fossil fuel consumption is not only negatively influenced by the price offossil fuels, but also by growth in
renewable energy capacity. Renewable consumption reacts slowly to deviations from the
equilibrium. However, when renewable generating capacity increases by 1 %, an increase
of 0.3 % of the consumption of renewables will take place the next year. The GDP
adjustment to deviations from the equilibrium (coefficient of 0.395) is somewhat slower
than the reaction of fossil fuel consumption. Interestingly, it is found that growth in
renewables consumption negatively affects the growth in GDP. Renewable capacity is
mildly reacting to disturbances from the equilibrium. If renewable capacity growth has
been large last year, it is likely that this is also the case this year. With respect to the
medium-run effects, the focus is on the impact of renewable production capacity. An
increase in renewables capacity reduces fossil fuel consumption in the medium-run by
about 0.3 % per year. An increase in fossil fuel capacity reduces GDP in the medium-run
by about 0.45 % per year. These figures suggest that there may be a difficult tradeoff. More
renewable energy consumption results in lower CO2 emissions, but also in lower growth.
Section 5.2 indicates that renewable energy generation through hydro power is
the major source of renewable energy measured and that the substitute of fossil fuelbased electricity generation has had lower fixed costs. Section 5.3 summarizes the
main interactions between economic growth, fossil and renewable fuel producing
capacity and fossil and renewable fuel consumption. Section 5.4 presents the data
and the primary relationships between economic growth, oil prices, fossil fuel
consumption, and renewable fuel consumption on CO2 emissions. Section 5.5 discusses the medium-term and short-term interaction effects between fossil and
renewable fuel consumption, energy prices, renewable energy generating capacity
and GDP. Section 5.6 presents the conclusions and recommendations.

5.2 Renewable Hydroelectric Energy


Energy consumers do not necessarily want to consume energy, but they want to
gain the benefits that energy brings. These can be roughly divided into (1)

76

H. von Eije et al.


12,000,000
10,000,000
8,000,000
6,000,000
4,000,000
2,000,000
0
1975

1980

1985

1990

ECON
RENCON

1995

2000

2005

NUCON
FOSC

Fig. 5.1 Total energy consumption and its major constituents in ktoe, (World, 19712008).
Source Data downloaded from the World Data Bank from the World Bank (http://
databank.worldbank.org/ddp/home.do). ECON is total energy consumption, FOSC is fossil fuel
consumption, NUCON is nuclear energy consumption, RENCON is all renewable energy
consumption

transport, usually by using oil, (2) heat demand, usually provided by gas in
developed countries, and (3) the use of electric appliances, for which electricity is
provided by nuclear sources, gas, coal and to a lesser extent oil. Each form of
renewable energy substitutes for one or more of these fuels. Figure 5.1 indicates
that energy consumption is still based primarily on fossil fuels and that the use of
renewables shows an upward trend too, except for the drop in 1990.4
Biomass is the largest source of renewable energy used globally. It can serve as
a substitute for each type of end use demand, though it is mainly exploited to
substitute heat demand in the form of cooking and heating houses. This form of
renewable energy, in contrast to the others, is mostly utilized in developing
countries. However, the consumption of biomass in developing countries for
heating and cooking is not captured by global overviews of renewable energy
consumption. The reason is that, in contrast to the other renewable sources, it is not
traded, and certainly not in formal markets. The most important source for measured renewable energy consumption originates from hydropower.
Figure 5.2 shows the consumption of energy by fuel type. The total contribution
of renewable energy is only 7.8 % (rounded to 8 % in Fig. 5.2). This share in turn

The World Bank database reports a large decline in renewable energy consumption in 1990. It
is likely that this is caused by a different approach in measuring such consumption. After 1990 the
gradual trend in renewable energy is visible again.

5 Renewable Energy Production Capacity and Consumption

77

30%
Oil
Natural Gas

5%

1%

8%

24%

6%

Coal
Nuclear Energy
Hydro electricity

34%

Renewables

Fig. 5.2 World consumption by fuel type, 2010. Source Data from BP (2011)

is dominated by hydropower, which provides 6.46 % (rounded to 6 %) of total


world primary energy consumption.
The overwhelming part of tradable renewable energy represented in world
energy databases is thus renewable electricity. Since the interest is in the substitution of fossil fuels by renewable energy, the focus is on this form of renewable
energy use and generation capacity from now on. When it is assumed that other
renewable energy consumption and production capacity is a time invariant fixed
factor of hydroelectric energy consumption and production capacity, the results
also hold for the whole sector of renewable energy, as the calculations are
insensitive to proportional relationships with the base variables. As far as these
relationships are not time invariant, they are left for further research, as a detailed
analysis of all the other forms of renewable energy consumption and capacity and
their interactions lies outside the scope of this chapter.
The US Energy Information Administration (EIA 2011) cost breakdowns show
a considerable share of variable operation and maintenance costs. In comparison to
coal and gas fired power generation, hydro power generation has a very low share
of variable operation and maintenance costs. The fixed costs of renewable electricity generation may, however, have been higher. This is, inter alia, caused by the
fact that fossil electricity generation technology is well developed and much
further on the learning curve than its renewable counterpart. Moreover, fossil
electricity generation has in general larger economies of scale. Finally, much of
the fossil electricity generating capacity is already written down by depreciation.
When comparing the fixed costs of fossil electricity generation to renewable
electricity generation it is customary to analyze the levelized costs. These costs
represent the present value of the total costs of building and operating a generating
plant over an assumed financial life and duty cycle, converted to equal annual
payments and expressed in terms of real dollars to remove the impact of inflation.
Levelized cost comprise overnight capital cost, fuel cost, fixed and variable
operating and manufacturing cost, financing costs, and an assumed utilization rate
for each plant type. The US Energy Information Administration (EIA 2011)
compares such levelized costs of electricity generating technologies, assuming a
30 year cost recovery period and a weighted average cost of capital of 7.4 %.
Based on these assumptions, hydropower levelized costs are larger than the

78

H. von Eije et al.

levelized costs of fossil fuel generating capacity. Only when for carbon intensive
technologies, a 3 % points increase in the cost of capital is added to represent the
projected carbon price, the levelized costs are comparable.
Until now, renewable electricity generation capacity has thus been more expensive to build than fossil electricity generation capacity. A shift from the traditional
fossil fuel electricity generation to renewable electricity generation may have made
the electricity use on a macro-economic level more expensive and it may therefore
have had a negative impact on economic growth. Moreover, many governments are
willing to subsidize renewable energy projects. This will influence decision making
by private actors and shift the focus to renewable energy projects, but on the macro
level, at which this analysis is performed, subsidies are only a reallocation of public
means that could have been used to make a positive contribution to economic growth,
instead of stimulating uneconomical decision making. It is therefore even possible
that subsidies for renewable production capacity options have aggravated any negative impact of renewables on economic growth.

5.3 Proposed Relationships Between Economic Growth


and CO2 Emissions
It is assumed that relationships exist between economic growth, renewable energy
production capacity, fossil and renewable energy consumption, and carbon dioxide
emissions. The major relationships are presented in Fig. 5.3. The figure also shows
the relevant position of the price of fossil fuels. In this model it is assumed that the
proven reserves and the capacity to produce fossil fuels are exogenous. The figure
also shows major feedback mechanisms.5
It can be seen from Fig. 5.3 that economic growth increases the price of fossil
fuels, while an increase in the price of fossil fuel reduces fossil fuel consumption.
Fossil fuel consumption will of course increase CO2 emissions but is also needed
to increase economic growth. A higher price of fossil fuels furthermore increases
the capacity of renewable energy production and an increase in renewable capacity
generates renewable energy consumption. The latter will reduce fossil fuel consumption and can also be used to generate economic growth. Yet, less fossil fuel
consumption alone will make the economic growth decline.

Obviously there are many more determinants for the generation of renewable energy, like
population growth, technological development, global politics on the availability of oil, local
politics on the stimulation of renewable energy sources, and the availability of capital and of
natural resources needed to generate capacity for renewable energy production. Here a
simplification is made by equating the price of renewable energy to the price of fossil energy. Of
course subsidies on renewable energy and CO2 emission costs may influence the price of nonfossil fuels, while also autonomous demand changes may have their impact. Furthermore, fuel
switching other than from fossil fuel to renewable energy has been ignored. Finally, in the figure
the impact of nuclear energy is discarded.

5 Renewable Energy Production Capacity and Consumption

79

Economic growth

Fossil fuel
reserves and
production
capacity

Fossil fuel prices

Fossil fuel
consumption

Renewable
energy
production
capacity

Renewable energy
consumption

CO2
Emissions

Fig. 5.3 The major relations between economic growth and CO2 emissions

Additionally, included in Fig. 5.3 is the assumption that an increase in


renewable energy generation and consumption will reduce the generation and
consumption of fossil fuels and therefore reduce CO2 emissions. Yet, as renewable
electricity generation is on average more expensive than fossil electricity generation capacity, it is assumed that an expansion of renewable electricity generation
capacity will have a negative impact on economic growth. It is not assumed that
there is in the medium run a negative feedback of CO2 emissions on economic
growth as described for the long run in the Stern Review (Stern 2006).

5.4 Data
Annual data for the world is retrieved and we require that at least data are available
for 2008. A search is made for data that goes back as many years as possible. Data
from the Statistical Review of World Energy 2011 of British Petroleum (BP 2011)
on CO2 emissions and for fossil fuel prices are used.6 Data are gathered from the
World Bank on GDP (in fixed US dollars of the year 2000), energy consumption
and energy production (in ktoe), and the combustible renewables and waste use (in

The Data of the World Bank on CO2 emissions started in 1960, but ended in 2007. The value of
CO2 emissions presented by BP started in 1965 and ended in 2009. During overlapping years the
emissions reported by BP are on average 0.1 % larger than emissions recorded by the World
Bank. Energy prices are measured by real oil prices in dollars per barrel against US 2009 prices (a
series which goes back to 1861).

80

H. von Eije et al.

metric tons of oil equivalent).7 Also downloaded is the percentage of energy


consumption based on fossil fuel consumption from the World Bank and this is
multiplied by 0.01 and by total energy consumption. This gives the amount of nonfossil fuel consumption. Nuclear power consumption is excluded from non-fossil
fuel consumption, but data is available on nuclear power production only from
1980. Nevertheless, estimates for the period from 1971 to 1979 are made in the
following way. Calculate the ratio of nuclear energy production based on the data
from the U.S. Energy Information Administration (EIA) to the total electrical
energy production downloaded from the World Bank database. This ratio increases
from 8.4 % in 1980 to 16.8 % in 1996 and declines afterwards. A regression
analysis is then applied which finds a trend of 0.5 % per year between these years.
Therefore, the percentage of nuclear energy all the years back from 1980 is
reduced by the 0.5 %. Then we calculate the nuclear energy production for the
years 19711979 forward by multiplying the resulting percentage with the total of
electricity production from the World Bank. Next, the transmission and distribution losses of electrical energy retrieved from the World Bank are subtracted and
the resulting nuclear energy consumption is reframed in ktoe. Finally, the nuclear
energy consumption from the non-fossil fuel consumption is subtracted in order to
get the data on renewable energy consumption.
For the capacity of renewable energy, data on Total Renewable Electricity
Installed Capacity (Million Kilowatts) from the U.S. Energy Information
Administration (EIA) is used. This represents the electricity capacity from
hydroelectric, geothermal, wind, solar and biomass and waste. This thus excludes
the use of biomass and waste in so-called green gasses. This variable is only
available from 1980 onwards, however, it is calculated for the period from 1971
onward, because data on electricity production are available since 1971 and
capacity and production are likely to develop together. Therefore the relation
between electrical capacity (multiplied by 24 h and 365/366 days per year) and
electrical production in the years 1980 and 2008 is calculated. The electrical
efficiency ratio rises from 47.0 % in 1980 to 49.7 % in 2008. Then the structural
trend in the electrical efficiency ratio is measured with regression analysis and the
reduced ratio for the years preceding 1980 is calculated with 1980 as a benchmark.
The calculated electricity efficiency ratios then give the electric capacity estimate

The complement of the fossil fuel consumption percentage thus includes nuclear energy. For
the combustible renewables and waste measured in kiloton oil equivalent there are no data
available for 2007 and 2008. The data for these years is extended by using the percentage of these
fuels in energy use for 2007 and 2008, also provided by the World Bank. Because the numbers
presented are not fully consistent with the derivation of the same number from the percentages
and energy use, the kiloton oil equivalent levels are used which are calculated from the
percentages and the kiloton levels directly presented by the World Bank for 2006 to make the
data for 2007 and 2008 consistent with the previous numbers.

5 Renewable Energy Production Capacity and Consumption

81

Table 5.1 Characteristics of the variables, (World, 19712008)


Mean
Median
Maximum
Minimum

Std. Dev.

JBP

LCO2
LGDP
LECON
LFOS
LNONFOS
LRENCON
LRENCAP
LPRICE
DLCO2
DLGDP
DLECON
DLFOS
DLNONFOS
DLRENCON
DLRENCAP
DLPRICE

0.177
0.327
0.198
0.186
0.270
0.188
0.341
0.520
0.019
0.013
0.017
0.020
0.026
0.029
0.016
0.306

0.564
0.347
0.518
0.478
0.156
0.287
0.452
0.700
0.810
0.917
0.658
0.790
0.000
0.000
0.041
0.000

10.010
30.792
15.934
15.724
14.265
14.045
14.058
3.671
0.019
0.031
0.021
0.020
0.026
0.020
0.036
0.057

10.028
30.821
15.964
15.753
14.345
14.088
14.109
3.570
0.020
0.033
0.021
0.021
0.028
0.023
0.032
0.026

10.359
31.333
16.292
16.082
14.627
14.351
14.655
4.574
0.055
0.063
0.058
0.062
0.066
0.045
0.080
1.155

9.695
30.226
15.570
15.404
13.692
13.633
13.395
2.543
-0.026
0.004
-0.010
-0.022
-0.100
-0.141
0.015
-0.665

The table presents the characteristics of 38 annual observations. Variables preceded by L are
logarithmic transformations, and variables preceded by DL are first differences of logarithmic
transformations (and thereby start in 1972). CO2 is the CO2 production in kiloton, GDP is gross
domestic product in dollars at constant prices of 2000, ECON is energy consumption in ktoe, FOS
is fossil fuel consumption in ktoe, NONFOS is non-fossil fuel consumption in ktoe, RENCON is
all renewable energy consumption, RENCAP is the installed renewable electricity capacity,
PRICE is the price of fossil fuel. JBP represents the probability of the JarqueBera test on
normality

for the preceding years.8 Next a study is made of the percentage of total renewable
electricity in total electricity production for the period 1980 until 2008. This ratio
is 23.5 % in 1980 and 22.8 % in 2008 and it has a marginal, but significant, annual
decline of 0.056 %. Next the renewable energy percentage in total electricity
capacity each year before 1980 is reduced by 0.056 %. Then, the total calculated
electricity capacity is multiplied by the outcomes in order to get the renewable
capacity for the years 19711980. When first differences are taken, the database
starts in 1972, implying that there is a maximum of 37 years of observations. The
characteristics of the natural logarithm and of the differences in the natural logarithm for the data are presented in Table 5.1.
Figure 5.4 shows the growth in CO2 emissions, in relation with the growth of
GDP and the growth in energy consumption. The figure indicates that economic
growth and primary energy consumption are strongly related, while the

Corrections are made for leap years. This procedure implies that the electrical capacity is
calculated based on the assumption that 1980 was a normal electrical production and
electricity capacity year, that the relation between production and capacity is not cyclical before
1980 and that the development in production is capable of measuring the development in
electrical capacity.

82

H. von Eije et al.


.08

.06

.04

.02

.00

-.02

-.04
1975

1980

1985
DLCO2

1990
DLGDP

1995

2000

2005

DLFOS

Fig. 5.4 The development of the relative annual change in carbon dioxide emissions, GDP and
primary energy consumption (World, 19722008). DLCO2 is the annual change in the natural
logarithm of CO2 emissions, DLGDP is the annual change in the natural logarithm of GDP,
DLFOS is the annual change in the natural logarithm of fossil fuel consumption

consumption of fossil fuels and CO2 emissions are very strongly related.9 A
remarkable aspect of Fig. 5.4 is that the shifts in economic growth coexist with
larger fluctuations in primary energy consumption and in CO2 emissions. If there
would be a unilateral instantaneous causation from GDP growth to primary energy
consumption, it would imply that the energy elasticity of worldwide GDP is larger
than one. This effect is, however, not significant, as the standard error is even
larger than the difference between the coefficient and one. To a smaller extent this
is also the case for the relationship between primary energy consumption and CO2
emissions, but also here these effects are not significantly different from one.

5.5 Interactions Between the Variables


First we study the relations between the variables and CO2 emissions unilaterally.
Table 5.2 presents the estimates of the effect of economic growth, fossil and
renewables consumption, renewable capacity and fossil fuel prices on CO2
emissions. These equations assume that there is a unilateral instantaneous

This is caused by the fact that the use of each type of fossil fuels has its own standard global
average CO2 emission consequences. Per TJ (terajoule = 1012 joules) coal emits 94,600 kg CO2,
oil 73,300 kg CO2, and gas 56,100 kg CO2 (BP 2011).

0.189
(0.092)**
0.828
(0.065)***
0.102
(0.106)
0.003
(0.003)
-0.089
(0.069)
-0.015
(0.018)
-0.002
(0.003)
37
0.94
0.492
(0.077)***
0.091
(0.150)
-0.001
(0.003)
0.082
(0.109)
0.004
(0.026)
0.017
(0.005)***
37
0.67
-0.175
(0.169)
0.005
(0.005)
0.159
(0.190)
-0.005
(0.029)
-0.019
(0.006)***
37
0.68

1.152
(0.222)***

0.007
(0.007)
0.190
(0.102)*
-0.161
(0.003)***
0.015
(0.007)**
37
0.89

0.143
(0.232)
-0.118
(0.116)

-0.597
(3.885)
1.243
(1.253)
-0.097
(0.094)
37
0.09

-2.226
(5.114)
3.506
(2.401)
7.066
(7.902)

(5)
DLPRICE

0.046
(0.031)
0.014
(0.010)
37
0.31

0.268
(0.385)
0.221
(0.275)
0.391
(0.188)**
-0.001
(0.008)

(6)
DLRENCAP

The first letter (D) represents the annual change, the second letter (L) is the natural log transformation, CO2 is the fossil fuel CO2 production in kiloton, FOS
is fossil fuel consumption in ktoe, RENCON is renewable energy consumption in ktoe. GDP is gross domestic product in US dollars at constant prices of
2000. PRICE is the price of fossil fuel. RENCAP is the installed renewable electricity capacity in million kilowatts. HAC robust standard errors are provided
in parentheses below the coefficients. * , ** , and *** represent significance at 10, 5, and 1 % respectively

Observations
R-squared

Constant

DUM90

DLRENCAP

DLPRICE

DLRENCON

DLFOS

DLGDP

Table 5.2 The statistical dependence of the relative changes in the relevant variables, (World, 19712008)
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
DLGDP
DLFOS
DLRENCON
DLCO2

5 Renewable Energy Production Capacity and Consumption


83

84

H. von Eije et al.

relationship between the independent variables and CO2 emissions. A dummy


variable for the year 1990 is included, because the data are influenced by an
unexplainable large decrease in the percentage of renewable fuel consumption,
which resumes to a new trend afterwards (see also Fig. 5.1). In column (1) of
Table 5.2 the coefficient of the annual change in the natural log of Fossil fuel
consumption (DLFOS) is 0.828 and highly significant. Also the growth in GDP
(DLGDP) is significantly influencing the CO2 emissions. Studying the instantaneous relations between the other variables, column (2) shows that growth in GDP
(DLGDP) is positively influenced by fossil fuel consumption, but that the other
variables, except for the constant term, are insignificant. According to column (3)
the growth in fossil fuel consumption (DLFOS) significantly depends on economic
growth (DLGDP). The coefficient is even larger than one, but not significantly so,
because the standard error is larger than the difference between the coefficient and
one. Renewable energy consumption (DLRENCON) is according to column (4)
positively influenced by an increase in the growth of renewable generating
capacity (DLRENCAP). Energy prices are not affected significantly by any of the
major variables. Finally, column (6) shows that growth in renewable energy
consumption (DLRENCON) increases the growth of renewable production
capacity.
The relations presented in Table 5.2, however, do not show the full picture.
First, not all variables are included as a system, while Fig. 5.3 also suggests that
feedback mechanisms may exist. Moreover, reactions between the variables may
not occur simultaneously, but they may take some time to occur. Finally, the
equations presented in Table 5.2 do not take long-term relationships into account,
while it is quite possible that all the underlying variables move in the same
direction. In that case the estimates of the growth variables may improve if one is
able to incorporate the impact of long run equilibrium on the estimates. For that
reason the simple vector error correction model is applied, which reads as:
X
X
DYi;t
ai DY i;t1 bi
ci Yi;t1 ei;t
5:1
where the summation is over is, representing the five variables Y (LFOS,
LNONFOS, LGDP, LPRICE and LRENCAP). The ai represent the coefficients of
the short term reaction of the variables Yi,t between each other over time. The cis
capture the long run (equilibrium) relations between the variables, where it is
customary to normalize the first of these coefficients to one. Finally the coefficients
bi represent the speed of adjustment of the variables back to equilibrium, namely
the proportion of last periods equilibrium error that is corrected for.
The vector error correction model (Eq. 5.1) is applied to estimate the relations
between the five variables.10 Before proceeding, a test is applied to determine if
10

Use of panel models (as used for example by Mahadevan and Asufu-Adjaye (2007); Apergis
and Payne (2009), and Sadorsky (2009)) is not considered for this analysis; also because
equilibrium equations and reactions of the various variables may be very different for different
countries, even if one includes panel intercepts.

5 Renewable Energy Production Capacity and Consumption

85

Table 5.3 Test on the validity and the type of error correction model (World, 19712008)
No constant no trend

Intercept only

Intercept and trend

Panel A Augmented DickeyFuller tests (between parenthesis the probability)


LFOS
2.775
0.130
-2.782
(0.998)
(0.964)
(0.213)
LRENCON
4.193
-1.789
-2.110
(1.000)
(0.380)
(0.524)
LGDP
14.565
-1.219
-4.241
(1.000)
(0.656)
(0.010)
LPRICE
0.827
-2.062
-2.032
(0.886)
(0.260)
(0.565)
LRENCAP
3.291
2.371
-1.887
(1.000)
(1.000)
(0.638)
Lag

LogL

LR

FPE

Panel B Lag tests based on a VAR analysis


0
190.436
NA
0.000
1
424.810
386.027
0.000
2
452.364
37.279
0.000
3
474.793
23.748
0.000
0.000*
4
531.272
43.190*
Test Type

No Intercept
No Trend

Intercept
No Trend

AIC

SC

HQ

-10.908
-23.224
-23.374
-23.223
-25.075*

-10.684
-21.877*
-20.905
-19.632
-20.361

-10.831
-22.765
-22.532
-21.998
-23.467*

Intercept
No Trend

Intercept
Trend

Intercept
Trend

3
1

5
1

Panel C Johansons cointegration test based on one leg


Trace
3
5
2
Max-Eig
0
0
0
*
indicates lag order selected by the criterion
LR: sequential modified LR test statistic (each test at 5 % level)
FPE: Final prediction error
AIC: Akaike information criterion
SC: Schwarz information criterion
HQ: Hannan-Quinn information criterion
Critical values in panel C based on MacKinnon-Haug-Michelins

these relations are cointegrated. This requires that each of the variables should
have a unit root. Table 5.3, Panel A, shows the adjusted DickeyFuller tests and it
shows that the existence of a unit root can only be rejected for the natural log of
GDP if an intercept and a constant term is assumed.
Second, the lag structure is determined. Table 5.3, Panel B, shows various VAR
tests for different sized lags. While most of these tests conclude on the use of four
lags, the Schwartz information criterion suggests the use of one lag. Because the
interpretation of a set of equations with one lag is more economical and because it
is an annual dataset and only a relatively small number of observations, only one
lag is used. Finally, the Johanson cointegration test based on one lag is used to
study how many cointegration factors might be needed (Table 5.3, Panel C). Again
for economical reasons, though the results again differ, only one cointegration
factor is applied. The vector error correction results are presented in Table 5.4.

86

H. von Eije et al.

Table 5.4 Vector error correction results for the period (World, 19712008)
Panel A The contegrating equation
LFOS(-1)
LRENCON(-1)

1.000
0.666
[6.417]
LGDP(-1)
-2.831
[-12.378]
LPRICE(-1)
-0.024
[-3.179]
LRENCAP(-1)
-0.459
[-3.604]
TREND
0.071
[10.543]
C
67.215
Panel B Error correction model
DLFOS
bi
0.517
[4.230]c
DLFOS(-1)
0.303
[1.239]
DLRENCON(-1)
0.169
[-1.334]
DLGDP(-1)
-0.095
[-0.251]
DLPRICE(-1)
-0.015
[-2.010]*
DLRENCAP(-1)
-0.317
[-1.728]a
C
0.0305
[4.045]c
DUM90
0.029
[2.125]b
R-squared
0.647
Adj. R-squared
0.558
Akaike AIC
-5.608
Schwarz SC
-5.257
Log likelihood
Akaike information criterion
Schwarz criterion

DLRENCON
0.148
[1.782]a
-0.098
[0.586]
0.057
[0.665]
-0.016
[-0.064]
0.005
[0.867]
0.305
[2.437]b
0.017
[3.316]c
-0.164
[-17.690]c
0.924
0.905
-6.375
-6.023
486.300
-24.461
-22.438

DLGDP
0.395
[5.770]c
-0.013
[-0.094]
-0.138
[-1.940]a
0.297
[1.405]
-0.008
[-1.806]*
-0.175
[-1.705]
0.031
[7.297]c
0.002
[0.307]
0.719
0.649
-6.768
-6.416

DLPRICE
-3.078
[-1.172]
10.516
[2.002]*
4.310
[1.583]
-8.137
[-1.002]
-0.102
[-0.623]
6.319
[1.603]
-0.200
[-1.235]
0.140
[0.480]
0.320
0.149
0.528
0.879

DLRENCAP
0.276
[2.635]b
-0.225
[-1.075]
0.083
[-0.767]
0.073
[0.224]
0.007
[1.123]
0.418
[2.662]b
0.024
[3.694]c
-0.012
[-0.993]
0.528
0.410
-5.918
-5.566

The letter (D) represents the annual change, the letter (L) is the natural logarithmic transformation, FOS is fossil fuel consumption in ktoe, RENCON is renewable energy consumption in
ktoe. GDP is gross domestic product in US dollars at constant prices of 2000. PRICE is the price
of fossil fuel. RENCAP is the installed renewable electricity capacity in million kilowatts. (-1)
indicates that the variable is one year lagged. TREND is a time trend and C is the constant of the
equation. DUM90 is a dummy that takes the value of 1 in the year 1990, and zero otherwise. bi
represents the speed of adjustment of the variables back to equilibrium. The t-values are shown in
brackets below the coefficients. a , b , and c represent significance at 10, 5, and 1 % respectively

5 Renewable Energy Production Capacity and Consumption

87

Being the first to test the relations with renewable capacity, a test is undertaken
to determine if the use of renewable capacity in this system of equations is significant. It is tested to see if it can be excluded from the cointegration relation. This
gives a Chi-square with a p-value of 0.026. This means that the renewable capacity
from the equilibrium system cannot be excluded. Next step is a test to see if the
adjustment speed of the renewable capacity can be left out. This gives a Chi-square
with a p-value just below 0.050, also implying that the adjustment speed coefficient should be incorporated.
For the error correction part, relatively high adjusted R-squareds for the growth
rates of fossil fuel consumption (0.558), renewable energy consumption (0.905) and
GDP (0.649) are found. The lowest explanatory power goes to the energy prices.
The t-value presented in the error correction part of the table can be used to
evaluate the significance of the ai. These coefficients indicate how the variables
react to each other in the short run. Critical 10 % significant t-values with 36
observations and 8 coefficients in the equation are 1.701, while the critical values
for 5 and 1 % are 2.048 and 2.763. Here, the significant coefficients are discussed.
It is found that the fossil fuel consumption reacts relatively fast to deviations of the
equilibrium relation (coefficient of 0.517). Fossil fuel consumption is, moreover,
negatively influenced by the energy price, though the coefficient is small (-0.015).
Fossil fuel consumption is also negatively influenced by growth in renewable energy
capacity (-0.317). Fossil fuel consumption has an autonomous growth of 3.050 %.
Finally, the dummy that corrects for a possible misspecification of the World Bank
data of the fossil fuel use percentage is significantly positive.
Renewable consumption is slowly reacting to deviations from the equilibrium
(0.148), while one percent production capacity growth results the next year in a
0.3 % increase of the consumption of renewables. Also, there is an autonomous
trend of 1.7 % per year. The 1990 dummy is negative and highly significant for
renewable energy consumption.
GDP adjustment to distortions of equilibrium (coefficient of 0.395) is somewhat
slower than the reaction of fossil fuel consumption. Contrary to expectations, it is
found that growth in renewables consumption negatively affects the growth in
GDP (coefficient -0.138). An increase in fossil fuel prices negatively affects GDP
growth. GDP growth is also more than 3 % autonomous.
For the price of fossil fuels, only a 10 % significant positive effect of the growth
in the use of fossil fuels is found, but this coefficient is large (10.516).
Renewable capacity is mildly (coefficient 0.276) reacting to disturbances from
the equilibrium. If renewable capacity growth has been large last year, it is likely
that this is also the case this year (coefficient of 0.418).11 Renewable capacity is,
finally, also growing autonomously at 2.4 % per year.

11

While Marquez and Fuinhas (2011) find a persistency in renewable energy consumption, such
a positive relationship between the current and last years change in renewable energy
consumption are not found. In the present model these effects are captured through renewable
energy generation capacity.

88

H. von Eije et al.


Response to Generalized One S.D.Innovations
Response of LFOS to LRENCAP
.006

.004

.002

.000

-.002

-.004
1

10

10

Response of LGDP to LRENCAP


.001
.000
-.001
-.002
-.003
-.004
-.005
-.006
1

Fig. 5.5 Generalized response graphs for fossil fuel consumption and GDP caused by impulses
of renewable capacity (World, 19712008)

In Fig. 5.3 it is assumed that there would be a negative effect of renewable


energy consumption and indirectly also of fossil fuel capacity on fossil fuel consumption. In unilateral instantaneous regression analyses of growth relations, it is
found that renewable energy consumption growth is indeed significantly and
positively influenced by growth of renewable capacity (coefficient of 0.190). When
the possibility that there are lagged effects is considered and that there is an
equilibrium system for the five variables studied, a similar relationship is found: an
increase in the growth rate of renewable capacity positively influences

5 Renewable Energy Production Capacity and Consumption

89

consumption of renewables. The coefficient is then 0.305 %. In such a model


moreover, there is a direct effect of renewable capacity on fossil fuel consumption
with a coefficient of -0.317.
It is also relevant to study the medium-term relationships. Therefore, the
equilibrium equation and the reactions of the coefficients to changes in the equilibrium are incorporated. Figure 5.5 shows the generalized response of fossil fuel
consumption and of economic growth to a change in renewables capacity. Here it
is found that a one standard deviation innovation in renewables capacity in the first
instance increases fossil fuel consumption, but reduces fossil fuel consumption in
the medium run by about 0.3 % per year. The impact of renewable energy capacity
on GDP is in the medium run in the same direction and somewhat larger. An
increase in fossil fuel capacity reduces GDP in the medium run by about 0.45 %
per year. The figure thus suggests that there may be a difficult trade off. More
renewable consumption results in lower CO2 emissions, but also in lower growth.

5.6 Conclusions and Recommendations


Economic growth requires fuel consumption. Nowadays the majority of this
consumption originates from fossil fuels and thus by definition CO2 emissions
increase. Such emissions may be reduced if renewable energy consumption substitutes fossil fuel consumption. This chapter tests whether there are significant
relations between economic growth, fossil fuel consumption, fossil fuel prices and
renewable energy consumption. As a new intermediary variable, renewable production capacity is incorporated. Only if renewable capacity increases, renewable
energy may substitute fossil energy consumption and only then the dependence on
fossil fuels may decline (except for the use of nuclear energy).
The major scientific finding of this research is that renewables capacity cannot be
left out in studying the system of interactions. The major practical finding is that an
increase in renewables energy production capacity reduces fossil fuel consumption,
but it also reduces GDP, at least in the medium term. Though the causes are not
studied in depth, it is found in Sect. 5.2 that renewables energy production capacity
has relatively larger fixed costs than fossil fuel generating capacity (e.g. caused by
less experience on the learning curve, higher costs of depreciation, and lower
economies of scale). When confronted with a choice to make the same product
(energy) at different cost, the choice for the high cost product (renewable energy)
results in a lower economic growth. Of course, if renewables gain momentum,
similar effects may also reduce their costs in the medium to long term. Moreover, if
increased costs of CO2 reduction make fossil fuels more expensive over time, the
effects found here may get opposite signs in future research.
This research is the first to study the relations between economic growth, fossil
and renewables consumption and renewables production capacity. The introduction of renewables capacity proves to be relevant and may also be considered in
further research. It is therefore suggested the determinants of renewable energy

90

H. von Eije et al.

capacity be studied more closely in future approaches. Furthermore, the negative


impact of renewables capacity on GDP in the long run could be further investigated. In this paper the price of fossil fuels is related to oil prices. These are
variable costs of fossil fuel use, but variable costs of renewable energy sources
could be incorporated in future research. Moreover, a deeper analysis of the fixed
costs of both fossil fuel and renewable energy generating capacity might be
included in future research. Then also the impact of subsidies that favor the use of
renewables generating capacity would merit attention; not only on the micro level,
but in particular on the macro level. Finally, this paper relates renewable generating capacity to the major source of measurable renewable energy, namely
hydropower. Other forms or renewable energy and their relative impact on the use
of fossil fuels, on each other, and on economic growth would become an interesting line of further research.

References
Alam, M. J., Begum, I. A., Buysse, J., Rhaman, S., & Van Huylenbroeck, G. (2011). Dynamic
modeling of causal relationship between energy consumption, CO2 emissions and economic
growth in India. Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews, 15(6), 32433251.
Apergis, N., & Payne, J. E. (2009). Energy consumption and economic growth in Central
America: Evidence from a panel cointegration and error correction model. Energy Economics,
31, 211216.
BP. (2011). Statistical Review of World Energy 2011. Retrieved from http://www.bp.com/
sectionbodycopy.do?categoryId=7500&contentId=7068481.
Berndt, E. R., & Wood, D. O. (1975). Technology, prices, and the derived demand for energy.
Review of Economics and Statistics, 57(3), 259268.
Chontanawat, J., Hunt, L. C., & Pierse, R. (2008). Does energy consumption cause economic
growth? Evidence from a systematic study of over 100 countries. Journal of Policy Modeling,
30, 209220.
Energy Information Administration (EIA). (2011). Annual Energy Outlook 2011. Retrieved from
http://www.eia.gov/forecasts/aeo/pdf/0383(2011).pdf.
Fuss, M. A. (1977). The demand for energy in Canadian manufacturing: An example of the
estimation of production structures with many inputs. Journal of Econometrics, 5, 89116.
Mahadevan, R., & Asufu-Adjaye, J. (2007). Energy consumption, economic growth and prices: A
reassessment using panel VECM for developed and developing countries. Energy Policy
Volume, 35(4), 24812490.
Marquez, A. C., & Fuinhas, J. A. (2011). Drivers promoting renewable energy: A dynamic panel
approach. Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews, 15(3), 16011608.
McMillin, W. D., & Smyth, D. J. (1994). A multivariate time series analysis of the United States
aggregate production function. Empirical Economics, 19, 659673.
Ozturk, I. (2010). A literature survey on energy-growth nexus. Energy Policy, 38(1), 340349.
Pindyck, R. S., & Rotemberg, J. J. (1983). Dynamic factor demands and the effects of energy
price shocks. American Economic Review, 73, 10661079.
Sadorsky, P. (2009). Renewable energy consumption, CO2 emissions and oil prices in the G7
countries. Energy Economics, 31(3), 456462.
Stern, N. (2006). Stern Review: The economics of climate change. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge
University Press. Available from: http://www.hm-treasury.gov.uk/stern_review_report.htm.

Chapter 6

Economics Instruments for Pollution


Abatement: Tradable Permits
Versus Carbon Taxes
Anthony D. Owen

Abstract Contemporary energy policy issues are dominated, directly and indirectly, by major concerns at both local and global levels of environmental degradation arising from combustion of fossil fuels. The advent of carbon pricing
(either through an emissions trading scheme or a carbon tax) represents an attempt
to impose a cost on consumers that will limit such degradation (i.e. the deleterious
impacts of climate change) to scientifically-determined acceptable levels. The
resulting higher cost of fossil fuel combustion for power generation should induce
a reduction in the demand for power (the demand effect) whilst simultaneously
stimulating investment in competitively-priced low carbon power generation
technologies (the supply effect). At least in theory, the trading of emission
permits can be shown to be a least-cost economic instrument for meeting a
specified level of reduction of carbon dioxide. However, a carbon tax possesses the
same property. In this chapter the relative merits of these two instruments will be
assessed, paying particular attention to factors that could, in practice, lead to
significant levels of inefficiency for one instrument relative to the other.

The author acknowledges financial research support from Santos Ltd.


A. D. Owen (&)
UCL International Energy Policy Institute,
220 Victoria Square, Adelaide, SA 5000, Australia
e-mail: tony.owen@ucl.ac.uk

A. Dorsman et al. (eds.), Energy Economics and Financial Markets,


DOI: 10.1007/978-3-642-30601-3_6,  Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg 2013

91

92

A. D. Owen

6.1 Introduction
The twentieth century witnessed historically unprecedented rates of growth in
energy systems, supported by the widespread availability of fossil fuel resources.
During the second half of the century, however, concerns associated with high
levels of fossil fuel dependence began to surface. Two issues were of particular
significance: the impact of modern energy systems on the environment and
security issues associated with fuel supply lines.
Environmental concerns had been evident in more localized areas for many
hundreds of years. Ancient Rome burned wood and Emperor Neros tutor, Seneca,
complained of the bad effect that smoke had on his health and of smoke damage to
temples, whilst anecdotal evidence indicates that air pollution had been a concern
in England as early as 1352 when a ban was introduced on coal burning in London.
Today, local pollution from energy systems remains a threat to the health of the
living environment. However, in the latter decades of the twentieth century, pollution resulting from combustion of fossil fuels became a global concern, with the
publication of credible scientific evidence that the planets climate was changing
as the result of a buildup of so-called greenhouse gases in the atmosphere.
The proposal to impose taxes on pollution, whilst more recent, is also far from
new, having been advanced at the turn of the last century by the famous British
economist Arthur Cecil Pigou as a means of reducing Londons famous fogs (or
smogs). Pigou (1920) observed that pollution imposed uncovered costs on third
parties that were not included in ordinary market transactions. His proposal was to
tax pollution by means of a so-called externality tax1 in order to internalize within
ordinary market transactions the damages caused by pollution. At the time Pigous
proposal was regarded as an academic curiosity, but several generations later it
was rejuvenated as the core of the polluter pays principle.
Historically, regulatory instruments have been the basic mechanism for
enacting environmental policy throughout the industrialized world. Environmental
quality has been seen as a public good that the state must secure by preventing
private agents from damaging it. Direct regulation involves the imposition of
standards (or even bans) regarding emissions and discharges, product or process
characteristics, etc., through licensing and monitoring. Legislation usually forms
the basis for this form of control, and compliance is generally mandatory with
sanctions for non-compliance.
More recently, the use of market-based economic instruments has emerged as a
more flexible alternative to the traditional command-and-control regulatory
approach to controlling emission of pollutants in market-based economies. Such
instruments can generally be divided (generically) into taxes and emission permits,
although both categories contain a large array of distinctly different forms of
instruments depending on the ultimate intention of their application.

Also known as a Pigouvian tax.

6 Economics Instruments for Pollution Abatement

93

Contemporary energy policy issues are dominated, directly and indirectly, by


major concerns at both local and global levels of environmental degradation
arising from combustion of fossil fuels. Even countries with relatively modest
fossil fuel requirements, such as the poorer nations of Africa, Asia, and the South
Pacific, could experience significant adverse consequences if the worlds
requirement for energy from fossil fuels does not abate within a relatively short
time frame.
Ironically, the very mechanism that has encouraged excessive environmental
damage in much of the world, and hence contributed significantly to its accompanying high social coststhe market placeis seen as one important avenue by
which environmental objectives and targets could possibly be met at a lower cost
than by traditional regulatory measures. However, to do so effectively, the market
failures that have contributed to so much of the problem in the first place need to
be corrected.
In this chapter the logic underpinning the use of economic instruments (which
may be loosely grouped as taxation and permit based) for addressing various
energy policy objectives is described. It is contrasted with direct regulation that
has been the dominant method to date, and the applicability of the tools through
which the objectives of policy are to be achieved. Various economic instruments
have also been designed for use outside of the energy sector, but in the context of
natural resources management.
The next section discusses two theoretical constructs that should be familiar to
economists but appear to have attracted little attention in the climate change
debate. The first distinguishes between damage costs and control costs in the
context of the optimal level of pollution. The second considers the difference in
economic efficiency between carbon emissions permits and carbon taxes for
achieving the optimal level of emissions of greenhouse gases in the context of
uncertainty.

6.2 The Optimal Level of Pollution


Figure 6.1 illustrates that the optimal level of pollution for an economy lies at the
intersection of the marginal abatement cost (MAC) and marginal damages (MD)
curves (both assumed to be known). In the absence of any pollution charge, firms
would have no incentive to abate pollution and hence the total quantity of the
economys emissions would be MP (i.e. where the marginal abatement cost is zero)
with a corresponding level of damage resulting from this pollution equal to the
area (A ? B ? C). From societys point of view, however, the optimal level of
pollution would be at M*, that is, where the marginal abatement cost is equivalent
to the damage arising from the pollution. Assuming known abatement and damage
cost curves, either an emissions trading scheme or a carbon tax will result in a total
abatement cost equivalent to the area B in order to restrict total damages to the
area C, yielding a net gain to society equivalent to area A. Clearly any further

94
Fig. 6.1 The optimal level
of pollution for an economy

A. D. Owen
$

MAC
MD

A
*

D
C
0

MA

B
M*

MP

Emissions

abatement would be inefficient, as the marginal cost of abatement would exceed


the marginal damage cost.
This figure also illustrates the equivalence of a carbon tax and tradable emissions permits. If the optimal level of pollution is at point M*, then the issuing
authority should issue a corresponding number of permits to ensure they amount to
a total level of emissions of M*. Since, in equilibrium, all firms in the economy
will face the same marginal abatement cost, then the cost of permits for all firms
will be l*. The tax property works in the reverse of this process; the tax is set at l*
and hence the total level of emissions is M*.
In practice, both M* and l* will be unknown. Thus, if an issuing authority
issues too few permits (say, MA), then emissions will have to be reduced to a point
below the optimal level and prices will rise accordingly (to lA), and vice versa.
For taxes, the authority controls the price (i.e. the tax rate) rather than the quantity
of emissions. If it sets the tax rate higher than l* (at say lA) then emissions will be
reduced below their optimal level (MA), and vice versa. Thus errors in issuing the
optimal level of emissions permits impact on the price of the permits, whereas
errors in setting the price (i.e. the tax rate) impact on the quantity of emissions.
It follows that the authority can either fix the price or the quantity, but not both.2
When calculating the damages arising from an externality, (A ? B ? C)
therefore represents the total damage cost. If added, on a unit basis, to the private
cost of the product creating the emissions the sum is the total resource cost. In the
context of cost-benefit analysis, it is the total resource cost that is assessed. In the
context of climate change policy, however, it is the total mitigation or control cost
(B) that is assessed. The distinction is important in a practical context, since it
would be rather illogical to spend more on controlling the cost of pollution than the
damage it creates (i.e. reducing emissions below M*)!
These two economic instruments are now considered in detail.
2

However, a hybrid scheme is possible whereby if the price of permits reaches a predetermined
price ceiling the latter becomes the fixed permit price (effectively, therefore, a carbon tax). The
initial years of the Australian Clean Energy Future Plan has this arrangement in place to avoid
price spikes in the early years of the permit trading regime and, as a consequence, reduce price
volatility risks for potential investors in power generation assets.

6 Economics Instruments for Pollution Abatement

95

6.3 The Taxation Approach


The taxation approach requires the regulatory authority to set a pollution tax at a
level that will (hopefully) ensure that a predetermined standard will be met (or, at
least, not exceeded) through the normal operations of the marketplace. Generally,
the tax is simply designed to achieve a specific standard rather than attempting to
reflect the unknown value of marginal net damages to the environment. In the case
of carbon dioxide (CO2) emissions the carbon tax would be expressed in terms
of dollars per tonne of CO2 emitted by the polluter.
However, deriving the optimal level of the Pigouvian tax is a daunting task.
The required comprehensive statistical compendium of CO2 externality-generating
activities and their ultimate contribution to marginal net damages would be vast,
while quantifying such consequences would itself be a controversial task. The
problem is further complicated by the fact that the optimal level of tax on an
externality-generating activity is not equal to the pre-tax marginal net damage it
generates, but rather to the damage it would cause after the level of the activity has
been adjusted to its optimal level. For example, suppose that each additional
unit of consumption of electricity causes $1.00 worth of damage, but that after
installation of emission control devices and other optimal adjustments, the marginal social damage is reduced to $0.50. The correct value of the Pigouvian tax is
$0.50 per unit of output, which corresponds to the optimal situation. A tax of
$1.00 per unit of output would reduce emissions beyond the range where the
marginal benefit of decreasing emissions exceeds its marginal cost. This makes
determination of the optimal level of tax even more difficult.
An alternative is to attempt to reach the optimal level of tax through an iterative
procedure. An initial approximation to the tax level could be made and adjusted
periodically in response to changes in damage levels. As output and damages are
modified, so too could be the level of tax. Ultimately, such a procedure would
hopefully converge to the optimal level. However, again, information requirements are a major constraint, particularly the lack of knowledge of incremental
costs and damages. In addition, economic activity cycles would ensure that the
optimal level is a moving target.
Resolution of this problem is generally achieved through a combination of
standards and taxes. A regulatory authority specifies maximum desirable CO2
emission levels that are conducive to meeting a countrys obligations under the
Kyoto Protocol or other commitments if not a liable party. Taxes (or emission
prices) are then levied to achieve this objective.
Although this combination of standards and prices will not, in general, lead to
Pareto-optimal levels of the relevant activities, it can be shown that, under
appropriate conditions, it is the least cost method of achieving the required standard, even though detailed data on the costs of emission reduction are unavailable.
This is shown diagrammatically in Fig. 6.2, where pollution reduction (or abatement) is measured on the horizontal axis and its associated cost and levels of
taxation on the vertical axis.

96

A. D. Owen

Fig. 6.2 Taxes as a low-cost


method of achieving a
standard

MAC1, MAC2, and MAC3 are marginal abatement cost curves for three different plants producing the same product, with different technologies reflected by
the different curves. They slope upwards from left to right indicating that the cost
of the marginal unit of pollution abatement increases as the total required reduction increases. Clearly, Plant 3 has the lowest abatement costs and Plant 1 the
highest. For simplicity assume that:
S1 S2 S3 3S2 and S1 S2 S2 S3
One way of achieving a given standard of pollution abatement, say 3S2, is to
instruct each plant to abate pollution by an amount 0S2. Under such circumstances,
Plant 1 would go to point A, Plant 2 to point B, and Plant 3 to point C, thus
achieving a total reduction of 3S2.
However, clearly their costs of pollution are very different. By imposing a tax
equal to t* the same total pollution abatement result can be achieved, but at lower
overall cost of compliance. Plant 1 now goes to point X, Plant 2 to point B, and
Plant 3 to point Y. The overall desired level of pollution abatement has been
achieved, with plants having the cheapest abatement options reducing more than
those with higher cost options. Thus, to the right of S1, it is cheaper for Plant 1 to
pay the tax rather than abate pollution, whereas for Plants 2 and 3 abatement
remains cheaper (until points B and Y are passed, respectively).
Now both standards and tax have achieved the same overall standard of 3S2.
However, the total compliance cost differs.
Under standards the total compliance cost is 0AS2 ? 0BS2 ? 0CS2; whilst
under taxation the total compliance cost is 0XS1 ? 0BS2 ? 0YS3. Subtracting the
latter from the former gives S1XAS2-S2CYS3

6 Economics Instruments for Pollution Abatement

97

which is always positive. Thus standards setting incurs greater total abatement
costs than taxation to achieve the same standard.
In practice, a problem arises because the tax is based on plant emissions rather
than the cost of the impact of the emissions on the affected population. For
example, emissions from a coal-fired power plant located by the coast may have
significantly less impact on local communities than one situated inland if the
prevailing winds blow the pollutants from the former offshore (although other sorts
of problems may arise, such as acid rain falling on neighboring countries). Thus
some form of differential tax based on location (as a surrogate for impact) must be
levied. While this will complicate the issue, the combination of standards and
taxes still retains its advantage of not requiring calculation of damage arising from
the emissions. However, in the context of GHG emissions, the problem is dealing
with a uniform mixing pollutant. Thus whilst damages will vary across countries,
that damage is independent of the source of the pollutant. It follows that a uniform
tax is appropriate for emissions of CO2 (and other GHGs).
In addition to its least-cost property, taxation has the advantage of flexibility in
dealing with a range of environmental externalities (as opposed to direct regulation). Further, once in place, tax rates can readily be varied to reflect changing
standards, whereas changes in regulatory requirements would frequently require
new legislation to be enacted. However, in practice, the use of taxation as an
instrument for environmental regulation has been very limited.
The question of setting the precise level of tax to achieve the desired environmental target or objective depends on a reasonably precise knowledge of the
magnitude of the relevant energy demand elasticities. Estimates of elasticities of
demand for energy (and individual fuels) in individual countries vary widely, and
are generally based on econometric models estimated using data which do not
undergo changes of the magnitude in energy prices suggested in the context of the
imposition of a carbon tax. Since a carbon tax will vary by carbon content of fuel,
it is also necessary to know inter-fuel substitution elasticities as well as the
standard income and price elasticities. Whether or not these objections represent a
serious flaw in the entire concept of modeling the economic impact of carbon taxes
is an important question. Even if such an exercise is thought to produce estimates
that are believed to be reasonably reliable, it is clear that the sheer magnitude of
the revenue that would be generated by such a tax requires a general (rather than
partial) equilibrium approach in the econometric modeling component of any
study of the ultimate impact of the tax and use of the revenue raised by it.
The fact that a carbon tax cannot yield a precise level of CO2 emission
reductions for a given rate of tax should not be viewed as an argument against its
implementation, since it is a stock and not a flow of pollutant. In other words,
damages are related to the atmospheric concentrations, not to the flow of emissions. Therefore if the carbon tax does not achieve the expected reduction in
emissions in one period, there will be time to adjust the tax in subsequent periods.
However, therein lays another problem!
Setting an appropriate level of carbon tax (either nationally or globally)
depends critically on accurate estimation of the level of world economic activity

98

A. D. Owen

and relative real incomes. Changes in energy prices have had (in the past) a
complex and asymmetric influence on the level of world economic activity. Since
the precise level of tax to meet a given emissions target cannot be achieved, it is
imperative that some form of partial adjustment mechanism be present to ensure
that changes in the rate of the carbon tax do not generate violent fluctuations in
GDP with a resulting loss of business confidence.
Since almost all economic activities involve, directly or indirectly, use of energy
derived from fossil fuels, reducing emissions of CO2 can be achieved in a relatively
simple manner by taxing the carbon content of the fuels. Since a carbon tax will vary by
the carbon content of each fossil fuel, inter-fuel substitution between both fossil and
non-fossil fuels will occur as will substitution of other (now relatively cheaper) factors
of production (e.g. labor and capital) for fossil fuels. This process will be enhanced if
investment in energy saving technologies, or non-carbon emitting energy sources, is
encouraged through the fiscal regime. In addition, since carbon taxes will always be
present as long as carbon-based fuels are used, there is a continuing financial incentive
to develop alternative energy technologies or carbon disposal technologies.

6.4 Tradable Permits


The system of marketable emission permits allows the regulatory authority to
determine the total quantity of emissions, but leaves the precise allocation of the
source of such emissions to market forces. This is in marked contrast to the
Pigouvian tax where a fee is levied which is equivalent to the marginal social
damage of the emissions. In theory both instruments produce optimal results, but
in practice they may yield significantly different outcomes.
The logic underlying a tradable permits scheme is illustrated in Fig. 6.3. The
aggregate (over all polluters) marginal abatement cost (MAC) curve is the cost to
the polluters of reducing pollution by one unit. The horizontal axis measures the
level of pollution and the number of pollution permits which, for simplicity, are
assumed to be measured in a common unit. Thus one permit is required to permit
production of one unit of pollution. Clearly, the optimal number of permits that the
regulatory agency should issue to yield the socially optimal level of pollution is
0Q*, with a vertical permit supply function indicating that the issue is independent
of price. Thus the equilibrium price of permits will be P*. However, 0Q* is clearly
unknown, so in practice the regulator will inevitably set the number of permits at a
level which corresponds to a sub-optimal position. The extent to which this error
can compromise the attraction of tradable permits for optimal control of pollution
will be considered in the section on the efficiency of economic instruments.
The principle behind emissions trading is extremely simple. A regulatory
authority explicitly sets a target level of emissions covering all sources of emissions
in an industry, a region, or even a country. Permits are then auctioned or issued to
each source according to its emissions at some agreed baseline datea process
referred to as grand fathering. Sources are then free to trade the permits, which

6 Economics Instruments for Pollution Abatement

99

Fig. 6.3 Tradable permits


for optimal control of
pollution

then command a market price. Sources with low (i.e. below the market price)
abatement costs will have an incentive to sell permits and abate their emissions.
Conversely, sources with unit abatement costs above the market price will have an
incentive to purchase permits in the market. Assuming sources minimize their total
production costs, and the market for permits is competitive, it can be shown that the
overall cost of achieving the emissions target will be minimized.
Notwithstanding the drawbacks and problems associated with regulation and taxation as instruments for pollution control, they are both founded on well-worked and
familiar structures. Regulation and taxation are familiar tools to both industry and the
general public. However, with tradable permits a new market is being established,
largely on the basis of a theoretical model, with little practical experience to date.
Major questions that surround the implementation of a tradable permits scheme are:
How should the permits be allocated?
Should the initial allocation be auctioned, leased, or given away?
Who should be permitted to trade in permits? For example, should an environmental group be permitted to purchase permits and effectively withdraw
them from the marketplace?
To what extent must monitoring be undertaken to ensure that emissions are
correctly recorded (and what should be the penalties for non-compliance)?
What will be the cost of the administrative infrastructure required to facilitate
trading and associated activities (including prevention of collusive activities in
the permits market)?
To what extent must details of permit transfers (i.e. quantity, price, ownership,
etc.) be made publicly available?
Should there be a grace period at the end of each year to allow for permit
transfers in order to achieve compliance (and how long should it be)?

100

A. D. Owen

Fig. 6.4 Hypothetical example of a cap-and-trade scheme showing gains from trade

In Fig. 6.4 a hypothetical example of a cap-and-trade scheme showing gains from


trade between two countries is illustrated. Marginal abatement costs for Country A
are assumed to be higher than those for Country B at low levels of emission
reduction, but increase at a slower rate as further reductions in emissions are
required. Assume that both countries adopt the same required level of emissions
reduction, SR. If the price of emissions permits is set at $P/unit, then country A can
meet all of its obligations at less than the prevailing price of permits. Country B,
however, can only abate at a cost of less than $P up to a reduction of S*. In the
absence of trade, country B would have to spend an amount on permits equivalent to
the area S*SRdfe. However, if Country A abates to S* at a cost of SRS*bac, it can sell
all permits generated by this abatement for $P/unit, giving it a net gain equivalent to
the area abc. Correspondingly, Country B can purchase its shortfall at a total cost of
S*SRde, a net saving equivalent to the area def. Thus both countries have gained
from trading, taking advantage of their different MAC curves.

6.5 Combined Taxes and Permits


It is apparent from the above analysis that, in the presence of uncertainty, taxes and
permits are likely to produce sub-optimal, and probably significantly different,
results. In order to combine the benefits of both schemes whilst at the same time
offsetting their individual weaknesses, it is possible to build a hybrid control
instrument that utilizes tradable permits supplemented by emissions taxes and a
subsidy.
The key concern with tradable permits is that the cost of meeting the fixed level
of emissions (i.e. the amount for which permits have been issued) may be
unreasonably greater than initially perceived. If emissions charges are introduced

6 Economics Instruments for Pollution Abatement

101

as an option to permits, then they will effectively place a ceiling on the price at
which permits can be traded. The scheme is designed to guard against extreme
misjudgment of the optimal level of emissions set as part of the process of
determining the aggregate value of the issued permits.
The mechanics of the scheme are as follows: the agency issues a predetermined
number of tradable emission permits for which a market emerges and a permit price is
determined (which is assumed to be equivalent to a cost of P per unit of emissions). At
the same time, the agency charges an emissions fee equivalent to (say) F per unit of
emissions. The latter can be paid irrespective of whether or not the polluter has tradable
permits. In addition, the agency is willing to provide a subsidy of S per unit of emissions for any unused permits. It follows, that in equilibrium, it must be that: S B P B F.
This must hold because if P were greater than F, no permits would be purchased, rather it would be cheaper to pay the emissions tax, so P would be forced
to fall. Conversely, if S exceeded P, it would be prudent to purchase as many
permits as were available, yielding a profit of (SP) per unit; although it is very
unlikely that anyone would be willing to sell a permit at that price!
Note that if S = 0 and F = ?, both subsidy and emissions taxes are effectively
eliminated and the system reverts to a pure permits scheme. It also reduces to a
pure taxation system if S = F = T, were T is the magnitude of the tax, which is
the level to which the price of a permit will be automatically driven. Thus, if either
the pure permit or pure taxation scheme is optimal, the maximization calculation will automatically ensure the elimination of the mixed system.
The operation of the mixed system provides an effective insurance for dealing
with situations where, presumably unknown to the regulator, permits or taxes fair
badly. In circumstances where permits would have performed badly, it would pay the
polluter under the mixed scheme to act in a way that transformed it into a taxation
regime. For example, if the regulator issues permits (to a value of q*) based on an
estimated cost of pollution reduction which is too high, then q* could be far below the
optimum level of pollution reduction. Conversely, if the regulator underestimates the
cost of pollution, q* will be correspondingly excessive. Now if the actual marginal
cleanup cost is higher than F, it will pay polluters operating under the mixed
arrangement to emit more than the permits allow and to pay the tax (F) on all
emissions that exceed those covered by their permit holdings. If, however, cleanup
costs turn out to be lower than S, it will pay polluters to continue to reduce their
emissions and hold their excess permits unused in return for the subsidy payment.

6.6 Efficiency of Economic Instruments


Taxes and tradable permits are equivalent instruments in a setting of perfect
certainty. But under particular forms of uncertainty the two approaches to environmental management may yield very different outcomes. It is possible to relax
the assumption that the MAC curve is known and allow for uncertainty of its
location. When this is done, circumstances where taxes are to be preferred to

102

A. D. Owen

permits (and vice versa) can be derived.3 Relaxing the assumption that the MD
curve is known does not change the relative merits of taxes and permits since they
are coincident in their effects on abatement.
The attractive property of tradable permits is that, in the absence of cheating, a
specified maximum level of pollution can be guaranteed irrespective of the cost
associated with reaching this level. Similarly, pollution charges or taxes guarantee
that the marginal cost of emissions control will be equivalent to the level of the tax
imposed, irrespective of the size of the resulting quantity of emissions. Thus, if a
government agency adopted a system of marketable permits it can be assured of
meeting the stipulated level of emissions, but the associated cost could be surprisingly high. In contrast, if the agency employs an emissions tax it can be certain
about the resulting marginal control cost (irrespective of the true cost function),
but it may be significantly adrift from its desired level of emissions.
Essentially the problem stems from the agencys ignorance of its marginal cost
curve. If it overestimates, then emissions reduction will generally be inadequate
under a system of permits and excessive under taxes if both are initially set at their
perceived optimum levels. The reverse will be true if the marginal cost curve is
underestimated. This is shown diagrammatically in Fig. 6.5.
It is assumed that the marginal damages (MD) of emissions curve is known with
certainty, but that the marginal abatement cost (MAC) curve is unknown. The
regulator anticipates that MAC2 is the true curve, when in fact it is MAC1; that is,
the regulator has overestimated the MAC curve. The regulator will therefore select
a tax of 0t1, or will issue permits to the value of 0S1 emissions. But the optimal
reduction in emissions is 0S* and hence too many permits have been issued,
equivalent to S*S1 emissions reduction. The corresponding reduction brought
about by the tax will be 0S2, thus leading to a shortfall of emissions reduction
measured by S2S*. Thus the efficiency loss in using taxes under this form of
uncertainty is equivalent to the area shown in light shading. The corresponding
loss in efficiency with permits is equivalent to the area shown in dark shading.
Note that the slope of the MD curve is less than the slope of the two MAC curves.
Figure 6.6 illustrates the same situation of an error in estimating the true MAC,
but in this example the slope of the MD curve is greater than the slope of the two
MAC curves. Now the efficiency losses have been reversed, with taxes being
preferable to permits in this case.
In general, it can be shown that when the MD and MAC curves are linear,
tradable permits and taxes will produce the same absolute distortion when the
regulator miscalculates the MAC curve if the absolute values of the slopes of the
two curves are equal. If the absolute value of the slope of the MAC curve is less
than that of the MD curve, permits will lead to a smaller distortion, and vice versa.

This explanation is based upon results derived by Weitzman (1974). A number of studies have
also addressed the relative merits of taxes as opposed to emissions trading schemes in the
presence of uncertainty; for example, Nordhaus (1994), Hoel and Karp (2002), and Newell and
Pizer (2003).

6 Economics Instruments for Pollution Abatement

103

Fig. 6.5 Uncertainty about


control costs I

So which is the more likely outcome in reality in the context of emissions of


GHGs? The benefits of emission reduction are related to the stock of GHGs in the
atmosphere, whereas the costs of emission reduction are related to the flow of
GHG emissions. Thus the marginal cost of abatement is highly sensitive to the
current level of abatement (steep curve); while the decline in marginal damage
arising from abatement is essentially invariant to the current level of abatement
(flat curve). Thus a tax is the preferred instrument.4

6.7 Relative Merits in Practice


Since, in theory, taxes and tradable permits are equivalent economic instruments,
the practical aspects of the two must be examined in order to determine a preference. These are summarized in Table 6.1, the last line of which, arguably, gives
the dominant reason why permits are more likely than taxes to achieve the holy
grail of a climate change regime: a single global price for carbon, effectively
making CO2 emissions a globally traded commodity.

However, if one also allows for uncertainty over its slope then the preference of taxes over
permits is expressed in terms of unknown parameters: a result that has little practical use (see
Quirion (2005) for further details).

104

A. D. Owen

Fig. 6.6 Uncertainty about


control costs II

6.8 Concluding Comments


This Chapter has discussed the relative merits of taxes and tradable permits for
tackling climate change through the reduction of emissions of GHGs into the
atmosphere. It has been noted that, although the two instruments are equivalent in
theory, they can have very different properties in practice.
Although conceptually both economic instruments are relatively simple to
comprehend, the actual implementation of a carbon pricing regime has proven to
be problematic. Emissions trading is a relatively novel policy option when compared to regulation or taxation, but its intuitive appeal has also been its weakness.
Policy makers face an array of policy instrument design issues that interact in
complex and sometimes unforeseen ways. In addition, developments in climate
science lack the precision that policy makers require to permit long-run emission
reduction targets to be put in place which would give industry some degree of
certainty for investment in low carbon technologies.
The Kyoto Protocol was an attempt to impose legally binding GHG-reduction
commitments from the industrialized nations of the world. Expressed in millions of
tonnes of CO2-equivalance, addressing such quantitative targets was ideally suited to
the concept of tradable permits. The global cap on GHG emissions is set on the basis of
scientific evidence of damages arising from such emissions over time, and the required
reductions to meet this acceptable target are allocated across liable countries.
However, experience to date has illustrated how uncertain the costs and distributional consequences of emissions trading schemes can be. The European

6 Economics Instruments for Pollution Abatement

105

Table 6.1 Relative merits: taxes and tradable permits


Carbon taxes
Tradable permits
Transparency
Transparent and simple for domestic
application.
Operating (transaction) costs
For many applications can use existing tax
structure (e.g. excise duty on fuel), thus
minimizing operating costs.
Public acceptability
Revenue can be used to offset existing
inefficient taxes or to compensate poorer
sections of the community. Politically
unpopular, and demonized in many
countries in the 1990s.

Specific emissions target that is intuitively easy


to understand and facilitates direct control.
Design of a new market and its infrastructure,
thus incurring significant administrative and
compliance costs. Requirement to ensure a
competitive market in permits.
If permits are auctioned, revenue can be used to
offset existing inefficient taxes or to
compensate poorer sections of the
community. Cost of permits represents
another cost of production and therefore less
visible than taxes.

Dynamic efficiency
Encourages adoption of low-carbon
Encourages adoption of low-carbon
technologies, but requires adjustment of tax
technologies, but allocation criteria for new
rates as economy expands or contracts.
entrants may involve high set-up costs,
particularly if permits are grandfathered.
Revenue and distributional issues
If tradable permits are auctioned, then taxes and permits are equivalent in terms of revenue
raising potential, and hence there is no difference in their distributional impacts. If a
proportion (or all) of the permits are allocated to emitters free of charge, then revenue will fall
correspondingly. Emitters would receive windfall gains.
International harmonization
Difficult to impose globally and hidden
Quantitative caps permit transparency for
subsidies could offset its impact.
international harmonization, ideally
delivering a single carbon price.

Union emissions trading scheme has been operating for six years, with a third
phase about to be finalized for the period 20132020. Although some lessons from
European Union experience now appear reasonably clear, others are still veiled in
uncertainty and confusion. Of particular concern is the potential for volatile prices
for emissions permits and their dampening impact on long-term investment
decisions, a problem exacerbated by the Global Financial Crisis and its aftermath.
Taxation, however, also has its practical drawbacks, as noted in Table 6.1. In
particular, in the context of a global scheme for reducing CO2 emissions, carbon taxes
would lack the transparency of quantitative emissions targets and avoidance in the
form of hidden subsidies could threaten the integrity of any such global agreement.5

In fact the subsidies need not be hidden since a social welfare argument may be made for
protecting certain industries or sections of society from the impact of carbon pricing. The IEA
(2010) estimated that worldwide fossil fuel consumption subsidies amounted to US$557 billion in
2008, so this is not a trivial issue.

106

A. D. Owen

As mentioned earlier, the ultimate goal for any carbon pricing regime is to
make carbon an internationally traded commodity. For this to happen, all of the
worlds major carbon emitting nations must have mandatory domestic carbon
emission ceilings in place. Without such a global accord, carbon emission
reduction targets based upon domestic production emissions ignores the emissions
embodied in traded goods imported from non-participating countries. Thus, whilst
production of carbon in the European Union has fallen significantly since the
introduction of its emissions trading scheme, there is evidence that supports a
conclusion that no corresponding fall has occurred in its embodied
consumption!6

References
Helm, D., & Hepburn, C. (Eds.). (2009). The economics and politics of climate change. Oxford:
Oxford University Press.
Hoel, M., & Karp, L. (2002). Taxes versus quotas for a stock pollutant. Resource and Energy
Economics, 24, 367384.
International Energy Agency (IEA). (2010). World energy outlook. Paris: IEA/OECD.
Newell, R. G., & Pizer, A. W. (2003). Regulating stock externalities under uncertainty. Journal of
Environmental Economics and Management, 45, 416432.
Nordhaus, W. D. (1994). Managing the global commons. Cambridge: MIT Press.
Pearce, D. W., & Turner, R. K. (1990). Economics of natural resources and the environment.
London: Harvester Wheatsheaf.
Pigou, A. C. (1920). The economics of welfare. London: Macmillan.
Quirion, P. (2005). Prices vs. quantities in a second-best setting. Environmental and Resource
Economics, 29, 337360.
Weitzman, M. (1974). Prices vs. quantities. Review of Economic Studies, 41, 477491.

This issue is addressed, at least partially, in the context of emissions embodied in exports from
China in Chapter 8 of Helm and Hepburn (2009).

Chapter 7

Emissions Trading and Stock Returns:


Evidence from the European Steel
and Combustion Industries
Jeroen Bruggeman and Halit Gonenc

Abstract This chapter examines the impact of price changes of European Union
Emission Allowances (EUAs) on stock returns of a sample of firms operating in
the European steel and combustion industries. After the introduction of an
EU-wide CO2 emissions trading system in 2005, the first phase of the emission
plans was completed in 2007 and the process of the second phase is still evolving.
The empirical analysis of this paper covers both the first and second phases to deal
with capturing time variances for the importance of the trading scheme. It is found
that EUA price changes are positively correlated with stock returns of firms
operating only in combustion industries over the first phase (20052007).
However, there is evidence of a significant impact of EUA price changes on stock
returns of firms from both combustion and steel industries during the sample
period in the second phase (20082010). Firm size, age and leverage are also
examined to explain the size of emission trading exposures across firms. The
finding is that neither of these variables appears to be a significant determinant.
This evidence indicates that EUA exposure is independent of firms characteristics.
Keywords EU emission allowance
intensive industries

 Emission trading  Stock returns  Energy-

J. Bruggeman  H. Gonenc (&)


Faculty of Economics and Business, University of Groningen, Nettelbosje 2,
9747 AE Groningen, The Netherlands
e-mail: h.gonenc@rug.nl

A. Dorsman et al. (eds.), Energy Economics and Financial Markets,


DOI: 10.1007/978-3-642-30601-3_7, Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg 2013

107

108

J. Bruggeman and H. Gonenc

7.1 Introduction
The European Union (EU) considers climate change to be one of the greatest
environmental, social and economic threats facing the planet. Therefore, the EU
plays a leading role in the negotiations for international action against climate
change, in particular for the Kyoto Protocol (Kemfert et al. 2006). Whereas
participant countries are committed to reducing the emissions of greenhouse gases
by about 5 % during the period 20082012, compared to that in 1990 as the first
target, the EU is committed to 8 % reduction (Lund 2007; Oberndorfer 2009;
Gronwald et al. 2011). The EU Emission Trading Scheme (ETS) has evolved from
the 2000 Green Paper1 to what is now regularly characterized as the flagship of the
European Climate Change Program (Ellerman & Joskow 2008). The EU ETS
covers 27 countries with about 12,000 installations, including energy-production
facilities such as power utilities and oil refineries as well as energy-intensive
industries such as iron, steel, paper and minerals (Hassan & Molho 2009).
The ETS allocates carbon emission allowances (in tons of CO2) to firms in a
specific industry. The system allows firms to buy or sell pre-allocated allowances
on climate exchanges. Over a five-year trading period (20082012), the estimation
is that the value of permits accruing to the top ten companies will rise to 3.2
billion. This value represents the market value of the total number of permits, and
exceeds by a third the total EU budget for the environment and is more than double
the funding announced in the European Energy Program for Recovery (EEPR) for
renewable and clean technologies over the same period (Pearson 2010). In 2007,
allowance trading exceeded 2.1 billion tons of CO2 worth 35 billion (IETA
2008). Even if the permits are not directly sold on for profit, the value will still
remain on the companys balance sheets. ArcelorMittal, the worlds biggest steel
maker, continues to dominate this ranking by far, with a surplus of 31 million EU
allowances in 2010. At the current EUA price of 17, this surplus represents a
selling value of more than 500 million. These developments indicate that as a
response to the rise in prices of EUAs in future years the values of assets will
possibly increase (Pearson 2010). However, whether the price changes in emission
trading increase firms market values is an empirical question.
This chapter investigates the reflection of the economic importance of the EU
and aims to find a sufficient answer for the following question: What is the
influence of trend of emissions trading prices on firms operating in the European
Combustion and Steel Industries with regard to their stock returns? The aim is to
show significant exposure of trading pricing on the firm value. As an extension, for

The 2000 Green Paper was adopted by the European Commission on 29 November 2000 to
determine policies for a long-term energy strategy. The main issue addressed in the Green Paper
is that the EU must rebalance its supply policy by clear action in favor of a demand policy. With
regard to demand, the Green Paper is calling for a real change in consumer behavior being more
respectful of the environment. With regard to supply, the development of new and renewable
energies is the key to change with regard to global warming.

Emissions Trading and Stock Returns

109

the further effects of emissions trading, the relationships between price changes of
ETS and the production capability and competitiveness of sample firms are also
examined. Furthermore, size is used along with leverage ratio for possible firms
characteristics to explain the level of pricing exposure.
The EU ETS was implemented in 2005 with an introduction phase until the end
of 2007, which is defined as Phase 1 in this chapter. Phase 2 is planned for the
period 20082012. The empirical analysis is able to cover this phase only until 31
December 2010 because of data availability. This chapter extends the studies by
Oberndorfer (2009) and Veith et al. (2009), where the authors search for the
influence of the EU ETS on the energy sector (in this chapter also referred to as the
combustion sector) for Phase 1, by arguing that there would be differences intraphases. Veith et al. (2009) find a positive relationship between combustion firms
share price and EUA prices for the first phase. Oberndorfer (2009) supports their
view and adds additional insights to be considered for the second phase of the EU
ETS. In addition, this chapter carries such analysis from one industry, the
combustion industry, to another one, the steel industry. Both Oberndorfer (2009)
and Veith et al. (2009) only investigate the combustion sector, but the results may
not necessarily apply to all other sectors involved in emissions trading. The steel
industry is one of the most energy-intensive industries with an annual energy
consumption of about 5 % of the worlds total energy consumption. In addition,
the steel industry accounts for 34 % of total world greenhouse gas emissions
(Xu and Cang 2010). For industries within the ETS, the EU cap-and-trade scheme
imposes extra costs and may, as a worst case scenario, even affect the competitiveness of energy-intensive industries in Europe (Lund 2007). This makes the
steel industry extremely interesting because this sector should notice the effects
from the trading more than any other. By investigating the steel industry in both
the first and second phases of the EU ETS, this study aims to show if there are
differences compared to the electricity producing firms.
This chapter is structured as follows: Sect. 7.2 provides background information
on the ETS and the implementation periods with the changes they bring.
Section 7.3 outlines the hypotheses and the reasoning behind them. Section 7.4
highlights the methodological approach. Section 7.5 provides the results and
interpretations, and finally Sect. 7.6 concludes.

7.2 The European Emission Trading Scheme


The EU ETS is motivated by the economic theory that market based policy tools
encourage the development and adoption of pollution abatement technology and
enable emissions reductions more efficiently than command and control style
regulation (Anderson & Di Maria 2011; Pearson 2010). The ETS, as described by
the European Council in 2003, allocates carbon emission allowances (in tons of
CO2) to corporations, which then can buy or sell allowances. Thus, the right to

110

J. Bruggeman and H. Gonenc

emit CO2 has now become a tradable commodity and is a factor of production that
is subject to price changes (Gronwald et al. 2011).
The basic idea of emissions trading is to limit the amount of emissions by
creating rights to emissions and to make these rights, called allowances, tradable.
The scarcity of emission allowances gives them a market value and those emitters
whose avoidance costs are lower than the market value of allowances will reduce
their emissions and buy fewer certificates or sell excess emissions rights, and vice
versa for other emitters (Kemfert et al. 2006; Mansanet Bataller et al. 2007;
Gronwald et al. 2011). Thus, a lack of allowances requires a company to either buy
a sufficient amount of EUAs or to invest in some plant-specific process
improvements (Gronwald et al. 2011).

7.2.1 The process


The process begins with the development of a National Allocation Plan (NAP) by
each member state for each trading period. In the NAP, a member state proposes
and justifies the total number of allowances created for the trading period, provides
a list of covered installations, and explains how those allowances are to be
distributed. Therefore, the EU ETS can be seen as 27 largely independent trading
systems that have agreed to make their allowances commonly tradable and to
adhere to certain common criteria and procedures in order to make the system
work (Ellerman & Joskow 2008; Pearson 2010).
The ETS consists of three phases that coincide with the phases of the Kyoto
Protocol. For instance, the second phase of the EU ETS coincides with the Kyoto
Protocols second phase, first commitment period 20082012. On the other hand,
the EU ETS was enacted before the Kyoto Protocol and became legally binding in
international and EU law and it would have become operational even if the Kyoto
Protocol had not entered into force in February 2005 (Ellerman & Joskow 2008).

7.2.1.1 Phase 1: 20052007


Recognizing their lack of experiences with cap and trade, EU leaders initially
decided to cover only one gas (CO2) and a limited number of sectors (Ellerman &
Joskow 2008). During this first phase there were many problems with setting
appropriate EUA levels for companies. The difficulty of choosing an appropriate
total number of member states was enhanced by problems with data, sector definitions, and the use of projections. Predictions of emissions were uncertain, no
baseline data was readily available, and therefore a misallocation (including overallocation) was likely to occur (Ellerman & Joskow 2008).
Despite the short time period of the trial phase, and the modest ambition for
emission reductions during the trial period, some reductions occurred in emissions
from the covered sectors. The system worked as it was envisioneda European-

Emissions Trading and Stock Returns

111

wide carbon price was established, businesses began incorporating this price into
their decision-making, and the market infrastructure for a multi-national trading
program is in place (Ellerman and Joskow 2008).

7.2.1.2 Phase 2: 20082012


During this phase of the EU ETS, running from 2008 to 2012, companies still
receive free allocations of EUA permits (Pearson 2010). However, in the first phase,
approximately 95 % of allowances were distributed to installations for free, while
the remaining were sold by auction. The amount of allowances to be auctioned is to
be increased to 10 % in the second phase (Hassan and Molho 2009; Pearson 2010).
Many countries did not fully utilize the 10 % maximum auctioning.2 This means
that the countries gave away EUAs for free to their corporations instead of
auctioning them off. The aim would be to protect the competitive position of their
industries.
The EU-wide cap on allowances is determined by using the average total
quantity of allowances issued by Member States in Phase 2 as a starting point, and
then applying a linear emission reduction factor of 1.74 % for each subsequent
year (Hassan & Molho 2009; Gronwald et al. 2011). The annual quantity of
allocated emission allowances is limited and already specified by the EU-Directive
until 2020 (Gronwald et al. 2011). The cap represents an emission reduction of
21 % compared to 2005 emissions as the most cost effective contribution of the
EU ETS to the overall 20 % reduction target set by the European Council in
March, 2007.

7.2.1.3 Phase 3: 20132020


The EU ETS imposes several changes in this phase such as increasing emission
reduction targets on installations, phasing out free allocation by installing an
auction-based system, and broadening the scheme to more industrial sectors and
greenhouse gases. The scheme is broadened and will include nitrous oxide as well.
Allowances will be allocated in a different manner in the future. Auctioning is set
to become the basic method of allocating allowances from 2013 onwards, unless
there are rules for free allocations (Hassan and Molho 2009; Gronwald et al. 2011).

For example, the percentages of cap auctions in the first and second phases are as follows for
the following member states: Denmark 5 and 0; Hungary 2.5 and 2.3; Lithuania 1.5 and 2.9;
Ireland 0.75 and 0.5; Austria 0 and 1.2; Belgium 0 and 0.3; Germany 0 and 8.8; Netherlands 0 and
4; UK 0 and 7 (Ellerman & Joskow 2008).

112

J. Bruggeman and H. Gonenc

7.3 Theoretical Background and Hypotheses


This chapter examines the theoretical relationships between changes in emission
trading prices and stock returns of a sample of firms operating in the European
steel and combustion industries for both the first and second phases of the EU ETS.
Changes in commodity prices should affect firm value (exposure) due to their
impact on corporate cash flows as input and output factors of the corporate
operations. A commodity as an input factor should induce a negative commodity
price exposure, while its use as an output factor should lead to a positive exposure.
Commodity price risk that has not been hedged may negatively (positively) affect
stock returns of corporations in industries for which a certain commodity represents an important input (output) factor in the production process (Bartram 2005).
In addition, there may be important indirect effects on the value of firms to their
shareholders resulting from the impact of commodity price changes on customers,
suppliers or competitors and thus the competitive position of companies (Bartram
2005). Veith et al. (2009) specifically mention that this link is also present in the
EUA trade based on the fact that pollution certificates affect firms cost structure.
Since those certificates will be used as the firm produces more, they are very
similar to components of costs of production. Thus, a price increase in carbon will
alter the outlay for additional certificates, and then this will change the firms
future income.
There is also a possibility of a positive link between stock returns and the
changes in emissions trading prices; firms have the ability to pass through the extra
costs and add a surplus due to their strong market positions. This argument is
relevant, especially, for the combustion industry. Kara et al. (2008) report that the
EU emissions trading have a price increasing effect on electricity prices in Finland.
For Germany, Zachmann & von Hirschhausen (2008) show that carbon price
changes are passed through to wholesale power prices. Reinaud (2007) concludes
that there is no universal answer on how the EU ETS has affected electricity prices,
at least some evidence for the CO2 cost pass-through into electricity prices was
provided during the abrupt fall of the CO2 price in May 2006. The fall by 10 per
ton of CO2 was immediately followed by a drop in wholesale electricity prices by
510/ per MWh in several markets. Reinaud (2007) further argues that this
electricity price adjustment is directly attributable to the CO2 price fall, since it
was not connected to other energy market movements that could also affect
electricity prices (Gronwald et al. 2011). A different study conducted by Sijm et al.
(2006) concludes that companies are including the opportunity costs of emissions
trading in their products even when they are granted for free. They calculate the
pass through rate varying between 60 and 100 % for wholesale power markets in
Germany and The Netherlands. Because the emissions allowances are granted for
free these percentages are windfall profits for the industry. Veith et al. (2009) go
further and state that the companies are able to achieve regulatory rents.

Emissions Trading and Stock Returns

113

7.3.1 Hypotheses with Respect to Phase 1


Based on above argument it is expected there will be a positive effect of emission
trading price changes on stock returns of firms in the European steel and combustion industries. Therefore, the first main hypothesis is as follows:
Hypothesis 1 Stock returns for the European steel and combustion companies
are positively correlated to price changes of emissions trading in Phase 1.
With regard to the sample period, sub-periods are created for both phases. The
first phase is split up into three periods based on a large price drop in April 2006
which occurred after the EU Commission pointed out that the first period aggregate allocation had been too generous (Veith et al. 2009). Period 11 is the period
in Phase 1 before the major price drop in April 2006, from 27 June 2005 until
25 April 2006. Period 12 captures the period during this price decline, and runs
from 26 April 2006 until 10 May 2006. Third and final sub-period of Phase 1
(Period 13) is the period after the price declines stop, from 11 May 2006 to 31
August 2007.
Hypotheses related to the impact of price changes induced by emissions trading
on stock returns in the periods of Phase 1 are as follows:
Hypothesis 1a Stock returns for the European steel and combustion companies
are positively correlated to price changes of emissions trading in Period 11 of
Phase 1.
It is highly likely that this effect continues to be held for a period when trading
price declines dramatically. In late April 2006, the market reacted to the information of an excess supply in emission rights with a severe decline in spot prices.
The spot contracts plummet, recovered for several months and finally decline to
values nearing zero after October 2006 (Veith et al. 2009). According to Oberndorfer (2009) the EUA prices were highly significant for companies during the
April price drop. This progress leads to the following hypothesis;
Hypothesis 1b Stock returns for the European steel and combustion companies
are positively correlated to price changes of emissions trading in Period 12.
Veith et al. (2009) predict that, for the period after the sharp decline in
allowance prices the ETS coefficient will not yield any significant results. A reason
for this insignificance might be the carbon market effects: the spot price for CO2
allowances plummeted from almost 30 in April 2006 to around 0.03 at the end
of the first trading period in early 2008, due to the publication of a first phase
oversupply. In addition, the EUAs could not be banked to the following period.
Neither attribute will cause a negative effect on corporate net income nor will they
affect economic decision making (Veith et al. 2009).
Hypothesis 1c There is no significant relationship between stock returns for the
European steel and combustion companies and price changes of emissions trading
in Period 13.

114

J. Bruggeman and H. Gonenc

Table 7.1 Endowment status of firms in combustion and steel industries


Combustion industry
Steel industry
Firms

Phase 1

Phase 2

Firms

Phase 1

Phase 2

E-on Kraftwerke GMBH


ENBW Energie Baden
RWE power
Endesa
Gas natural SA
Iberdrola
Grobkraftwerk Mannheim Ag
EDP Energia
CEZ
GDF Suez
EVN
EDF
Fortum
Centrica
Verbund
Public power corporation
SSE
Eni
BASF
Drax
Average

-7.03
-8.20
-3.12
-25.83
-43.18
-27.19
-13.75
10.39
4.98
-12.04
-29.79
12.05
0.81
20.53
-30.42
0.11
-12.44
0.44
-13.17
-33.54
-6.85

-25.70
-19.04
-48.51
-7.71
-19.63
-4.70
-13.08
2.72
6.75
-22.65
8.39
-9.02
-30.11
-26.58
-18.77
-10.13
-5.41
9.69
15.20
-55.84
-10.63

ArcelorMittal
ThyssenKrupp
Voestalpine
Salzgitter
Rautaruukki
SSAB Svenskt Stal
Vallourec
Outokumpu
Viohalco
Hoganas
Acerinox
Schmolz-Bickenbach
Sandvik
Tenaris
Sidenor

30.41
13.66
2.61
2.75
6.35
84.55
11.59
42.52
48.06
36.56
9.52
3.15
11.98
10.82
48.06

56.45
41.39
-2.16
36.02
18.32
120.61
104.57
80.61
72.40
45.89
63.46
40.22
-1.83
-71.22
72.40

Average

22.47

43.19

Source Carbonmarketdata.com
This table reports the difference between allocated and verified EUAs in percentages for both Phases
1 and 2. Negative values indicate the shortages, and positive values are for excess of EUAs

7.3.2 Hypotheses with Respect to Phase 2


There is a much stronger emissions cap in the second phase compared to the first
phase, as is expected from early analysis of the National Allocation Plans of the
ETS member states (Oberndorfer 2009), which may also increase the economic
consequences of emission regulation under the EU ETS. Table 7.1 reports the
difference between allocated and verified EUAs in percentages for the sample
firms in both combustion and steel industries.
Most companies in the combustion industry have a shortage of EUAs in Phase 1 of
the EU ETS and for Phase 2 the relative shortage of EUAs increased industry wide.
They will need to buy more EUAs as compared to Phase 1 leading to more significance.
Thus, looking at the endowment status of the combustion industry, it is argued that the
second phase of the ETS will hold more significance because the difference between
allocation and verification has become larger. The Iron and Steel industries are
especially over allocated since they had already made significant cuts in emissions due
to improved technologies (Pearson 2010). The second phase shows a higher level of
over allocation compared to the first phase. The second hypothesis tests this statement:

Emissions Trading and Stock Returns

115

Hypothesis 2 Stock returns for the European steel and combustion companies
are positively correlated to price changes of emissions trading in Phase 2.
Phase 2 covers the period of the recent economic and financial crisis where
asset and commodity prices are dramatically affected. Therefore, sub-periods are
also created during Phase 2 to be able to capture the role of this unfortunate event.
The first period, Period 21, runs from 27 February 2008 to 31 July 2009, the
second, Period 22, from 01 August 2009 to 31 December 2010. Gronwald et al.
(2011) note that the relationship between EUA returns and other financial variables
is particularly strong during the financial crisis. They find a stronger dependence
between EUA futures returns and most of the considered variables during the
global financial crisis. This confirms general results on asset returns from financial
markets exhibiting higher dependence during periods of extreme economic or
market downturn.
Hypothesis 2a Stock returns for the European steel and combustion companies
are positively correlated to price changes of emissions trading in Period 21 of
Phase 2.
Initial over-allocation to these industries has since been compounded by the
negative effects of global recession on production. During this period, many
companies find themselves in a position, in which they have far more permits to
pollute than they require (Pearson 2010). This leads to expectation that the second
period of Phase 2 will play no significant role in price changes in emission trading.
Hypothesis 2b There is no significant relationship between stock returns for the
European steel and combustion companies and price changes of emissions trading
in Period 22.

7.3.3 Hypotheses with Respect to Production Levels


The ETS with its volatile spot markets seriously undermines companies profitability and possibly leads to a reduction in production. It is likely that the ETS
would generate changes in trade flows as imports into the EU from countries with
no carbon constraints would naturally increase, so that exports decrease, and
therefore, it would slow down investments in Europe. This discussion leads to the
following hypothesis;
Hypothesis 3 Steel production in Europe is negatively correlated to emission
trading price changes.

7.3.4 Hypotheses with Respect to Firms Characteristics


Companies have possibilities to hedge versus EUA price exposure. There are
futures and options traded on the markets. Furthermore, there are options to set up
foreign projects rendering EUA rebates through the CER program which would

116

J. Bruggeman and H. Gonenc

mean less exposure and more certainty for the corporations. CER stands for
Certified Emission Reduction. It allows emission reduction projects conducted in
developing countries to generate carbon credits which can be used in the EU ETS.
Nance et al. (1993) argue that firm size, a proxy for economies of scale in hedging
costs, is related to hedging incentives. Larger firms that have access to risk
management expertise, or that have economies of scale in hedging costs, are more
likely to hedge than smaller firms (Haushalter 2000). Thus, hedging seems to be
driven by economies of scale, reflecting the high fixed costs of establishing risk
management programs (Jin and Jorion 2006). As a result, bigger corporations
should be less exposed to exchange-rate risk (He and Ng 1998). However, there
are circumstances where smaller firms have more incentive to hedge than larger
firms; for instance, smaller firms will hedge more, because they face greater
bankruptcy costs (Haushalter 2000). Thus, the effect of firm size on exchange-rate
exposure is ambiguous and shall be empirically determined (He and Ng 1998).
Thus, the following hypothesis is formulated:
Hypothesis 4 Steel and combustion companies with a relative large market
value face lower emission price exposure.
Smith and Stulz (1985) argue that hedging can reduce the probability that a firm
will go bankrupt and thereby reduce the expected costs of financial distress. They
employ a firms long-term debt ratio to measure its probability of financial distress.
Ceteris paribus, firms with a higher level of debt tend to face larger expected costs
of financial distress and hence have a greater desire to engage in hedging activities.
Therefore, the role of debt level on emission price exposure is also examined:
Hypothesis 5 More leveraged steel and combustion corporations are more
exposed to emissions price fluctuations than less leveraged steel firms.
In the analysis testing Hypotheses 4 and 5, age of the firm is controlled for its
role on the choice of hedging. On one hand, older firms are more likely to hedge
than younger firms because managers in older firms have more experience and
expertise in risk management. Moreover, larger firms have economies of scale in
hedging costs. On the contrary, younger firms are also likely to have more
incentive to hedge than older firms. Younger firms bear higher bankruptcy costs,
and therefore, may tend to hedge more.

7.4 Methodology and Data


7.4.1 Methodology
Financial risks for nonfinancial institutions consistbroadly definedof unexpected
changes in foreign exchange rates, interest rates or commodity prices (Bartram
2005). EUAs are considered to be commodities for consumption (Daskalakis
et al. 2009). The economic commodity price exposure is the effect of unexpected
changes of commodity prices on the value of the firm (Jorion 1990; He & Ng 1998;

Emissions Trading and Stock Returns

117

Bartram 2005). As such, EUA price exposure is the elasticity of stock returns with
respect to unanticipated changes of the price of EUAs.
Building on earlier work of Jorion (1990), which is widely used in many later
studies such as Bartram (2005) and Oberndorfer (2009), a two level regression
model is used to determine the extent of commodity price exposure by steel and
combustion firms:
Step 1 is the standard methodology to capture the impact of price changes of
emission trading on stock returns as shown by the following regression model;
Rit ai b1 Rmt b2 RSct e

7:1

where:
Rit = daily return on the common stock of firm i in period t,
Rmt = daily return on the market portfolio in period t,
RSct = daily return on spot contracts emission allowances in period t,
e = the error term.
The coefficients b1 and b2 capture the market risk as well as the exposure
towards the trade in pollution rights. The market portfolio controls for the impact
of unexpected macroeconomic changes. In addition to these basic factors, changes
in the steel price for the steel industry and the oil and gas prices for the combustion
firms are added into Eq. 7.1.
Rit ai b1 Rmt b2 RSct b3 Steel e

7:2

Rit ai b1 Rmt b2 RSct b3 ROil b4 RGas e

7:3

where:
RSteel = daily price change on steel,
ROil = daily price change on oil,
RGas = daily price change on gas.
Step 2 captures the effects of firms characteristics with respect to size and
leverage on the coefficient of emissions allowances, namely (b2), which is
obtained from the coefficients of regressions in step one for each firm. Using
ordinary least squares cross-sectional regression analysis the determinants of the
estimated exposures are related by:
b1 ai a1 Sizei a2 Leveragei e

7:4

7.4.2 Data
Powernext (now Bluenext) accounted for almost 79 % of the spot market transactions in the EU ETS (Daskalakis et al. 2009). Data were collected for the prices
of EUAs from Bluenext as it is the most used and complete set of data for the spot

118

J. Bruggeman and H. Gonenc

EUA market. Moreover, Mansanet Bataller et al. (2007) indicate that EUA prices
have developed very similarly in all marketplaces, so that the choice of marketplace should not be crucial for the analysis. Although future or forward prices are
less affected by very short-run demand and supply fluctuations and therefore less
noisy in comparison to spot prices (Oberndorfer 2009), in line with Oberndorfer,
the settlement price is used instead of an EUA future from the EEX as there is little
trade in futures in comparison to the spot market.
EUA spot pricing data from 27 June 2005 until 31 December 2010 was
collected. As explained in the section on the hypotheses, several sub-periods in
Phases 1 and 2 of the ETS are used: Phase 1 of the ETS is the first period as a
whole from 27 June 2005 to 31 August 2007. This Phase 1 period is split-up
because of the April 2006 crash in EUA prices into a pre, during and post the crisis
period. It commences in the last days of April and thus Period 11 runs from 27
June 2005 to 25 April 2006; the Period 12 runs from 26 April 2006 until 10-May
2006, and the Period 13 from 11 May 2006 to 31 August 2007. For Phase 2, data
from 27 February 2008 to 31 December 2010 is used. The starting date is the first
day the new EUAs. The period is split into two sub-periods to see the impact of the
global financial crisis. Period 2-1 starts on 27 February 2008 and ends on 31 July
2009, and Period 2-2 runs from 1 August 2009 to 31 December 2010. Panel A of
Table 7.2 provides a general view of all these sample periods and total number of
observations used in the analysis.
Panel B of Table 7.2 reports summary statistics for sample firms characteristics. According to mean and median values of size, leverage and age, the sample
firms in the combustion industry use more debt, and are younger than those in the
steel industry, while firms in both industries are similar in size.
The Community Independent Transaction Log (CITL) is the definitive EU ETS
resource created by the European Commission and contains all records of issuance, transfer, cancellation, retirement and banking of allowances that take place
in the registry. Additionally, data for companies in the carbon trading markets are
gathered from the carbon market data website, which is the official data provider
for this market. They provide free access to the official EU ETS database, a tool
designed for all carbon market players.
To create a sample of firms, first a search of the list of companies from
DataStream is made. The largest publically traded companies in the combustion
and steel industries in Europe are collected. The names of these firms are then
cross-referenced with emissions data. Daily stock prices are collected from Yahoo
Finance, Google Finance, and Datastream. For market returns, the local index from
where the company is headquartered is used. Steel prices are calculated by using
the Dow Jones steel index from Yahoo Finance. For oil prices, the London Brent
Crude Oil Index is used. Generally, UK and continental gas prices are closely
related due to arbitrage possibilities (Oberndorfer 2009). Natural gas prices are
collected from the ICE Natural Gas prices as one month forward contracts, in line
with Oberndorfer (2009). Monthly steel production data per country and region is
collected from the World Steel Association website.

Emissions Trading and Stock Returns

119

Table 7.2 Sample descriptive statistics


Sample periods Combustion industry Steel industry
Variables
Combustion industry (N = 20)
Mean
Panel A: Sample
Period 11
Period 12
Period 13
Phase 1Full
Period 21
Period 22
Phase 2Full
Panel B: Sample
Size
Leverage
Age

Median

Beginning period Ending period


Steel industry (N = 15)
Mean

periods and the total number of observations


3,086
2,414
27-6-2005
189
126
26-4-2006
6,547
4,310
11-5-2006
10,722
6,850
27-6-2005
7,011
4,920
27-2-2008
7,217
5,040
1-8-2009
14,228
9,960
27-2-2008
statistics
6.98
7.6
6.93
0.66
0.64
0.54
43.95
26
67.17

Median
25-4-2006
10-5-2006
31-8-2007
31-8-2007
31-7-2009
31-12-2010
31-12-2010
6.77
0.52
50

Firms size is the log of total assets. Financial leverage is the ratio of the end-of-year book value
of long-term debt to the end-of-year market value of the firm. Both variables are collected from
Datastream. Firms ages are collected from web sources

Firm size is measured by taking the log of total assets at the beginning of the
periods of Phases 1 and 2. Financial leverage is defined as the ratio of the end-of-year
book value of long-term debt to the end-of-year market value of the firm. Since book
value of equity is influenced by accounting conventions applied in different countries, market value of equity in is used calculating leverage. Moreover, a market value
leverage measure is commonly used in the corporate finance literature. Variables to
calculate those characteristics are collected from Datastream.

7.5 Empirical Results


7.5.1 Results for Phase 1 and Hypothesis 1
The results from regression analysis for Hypothesis 1, capturing the periods of
Phase 1, are presented in Table 7.3. The table is divided into two parts, the left part
is for the results of the combustion industry, and the right part is for the steel
industry. Panels A, B, C, and D of Table 7.3 report the results for the full period,
and the three sub-periods, respectively.
The estimated coefficients of the variable RSct in Panel A show that stock returns
of firms in the combustion industry are affected positively by the changes in price of
EUAs, and this effect is significant at the 5 % level. This result is consistent with the
finding of both Oberndorfer (2009) and Veith et al. (2009) who also find a significant
positive correlation for the combustion industry. On the other hand, there is no
significant effect of EUA prices in the steel industry in Phase 1.

A: Full period of Phase 1


0.024
1.141
0.037
-0.010
B: Period 11 of Phase 1
0.025
0.686
0.048
0.008
C: Period 12 Phase 1
0.03
0.793
-0.077
-0.003
D: Period 13 of Phase 1
0.029
1.283
0.049
-0.022
RSct
Rmt
RSteel

RSct
Rmt
RSteel

RSct
Rmt
RSteel

RSct
Rmt
RSteel

(0.01)c
(0.00)c
(0.01)c
(0.03)b
(0.00)c
(0.00)c
(0.35)
(0.97)
(0.13)
(0.00)c
(0.62)
(0.36)

Variables

(0.07)a
(0.00)c
(0.54)
(0.45)

p values

Steel industry

-0.002
0.701
0.271

0.016
0.766
0.32

0.067
0.913
1.128

0.004
0.779
0.216

(0.93)
(0.00)c
(0.00)c

(0.38)
(0.04)b
(0.01)c

(0.00)c
(0.00)c
(0.00)c

(0.77)
(0.00)c
(0.00)c

p values

This table presents the estimated coefficients and p values of coefficients in the following regressions: (1) Combustion industry, Rit = ai ? b1 Rmt ? b2
RSct ? b3 RSteel ? e, and (2) Steel industry, Rit = ai ? b1 Rmt ? b2 RSct ? b3 ROil ? b4 RGas ? e. Rit is daily return on the common stock of firm i in
period t, Rmt is daily return on the market portfolio in period t, RSct is daily return on spot contracts emission allowances in period t. Variables Roil, RGas,
and RSteel are the changes in prices of commodities of oil, gas and steel. a , b , c denote statistical significance at 1, 5, and 10 % levels, respectively

Panel
RSct
Rmt
Roil
RGas
Panel
RSct
Rmt
Roil
RGas
Panel
RSct
Rmt
Roil
RGas
Panel
RSct
Rmt
Roil
RGas

Variables

Table 7.3 Regression results for Phase 1


Combustion industry

120
J. Bruggeman and H. Gonenc

Emissions Trading and Stock Returns

121

The first period of Phase 1 (Panel B) is associated with a positive and significant
relationship between both industries stock returns and EUA price changes. This is
in line with expectations and can be explained by the over-allocation in the steel
industry and the pass through possibilities of the combustion industry due to their
market power. Following the previous research by Oberndorfer (2009), a positive
correlation is also expected for the combustion industry in this period. He finds
evidence for a particularly strong impact of EUA price changes on electricity stock
returns during the period of market shock in April/May 2006. His findings seem to
hold for the combustion and steel industries.
The results regarding Period 12 (Panel C) indicates no significant effect of
price changes of EUA on stock returns for firms in the steel industry, but this effect
is significant for firms in the combustion industry. Thus, the steel industry might
not be able to sell off any of its surplus EUAs rendering them worthless, especially
because they cannot be banked or used in the following phase causing the insignificance for this period.
The results from Period 13 (Panel D) are consistent with the hypothesis,
indicating that there should be no significant relationship between stock returns
and price changes of EUAs.

7.5.2 Results for Phase 2 and Hypothesis 2


Because of a tighter EUA cap, the expectations for this second phase are that it would
hold more restrictions and thus higher significance. Then the financial crisis set in
during which time the correlation should be more visible than normal. The results
from regression analysis for Hypothesis 2, capturing the periods of Phase 2 are
presented in Table 7.4. This table is structured the same as Table 7.3, it consists of
two parts presenting the combustion industry on the left and the steel industry on the
right. Panel A, B, and C, of Table 7.4 report the results for the full period, and the two
sub-periods determined by the financial crisis starting at the end of 2007.
There are statistically significantly positive effects of EUA prices on stock
returns of the sample of European firms in both the steel and combustion industries. The results in Panel A capture this effect in the full period of Phase 2. The
results corresponding to the first period draws the same conclusion (Panel B).
Many countries chose to protect the competitiveness of their industrial sectors by
giving them allocations based on generous business-as-usual projections which
incorporated estimates of future growth (Pearson 2010). When the future growth
estimates changed because of the crisis, the over-allocation increased. The EUA
prices slowly decline in this phase because of the vast amount of EUAs building up
during the crisis seems to be sufficient to last companies a long time and, therefore,
demand for additional EUAs falls.
In line with expectations, there is no significant effect of emission price changes
on stock returns in the second period of Phase 2 (Panel C). The price of EUAs
seems stable, but it is roughly half the price of the first period in Phase 2. Thus, a

122

J. Bruggeman and H. Gonenc

Table 7.4 Regression results for Phase 2


Combustion industry
Variables

Panel A: Full period of Phase 2


0.035
RSct
Rmt
0.707
Roil
0.06
RGas
-0.001
Panel B: Period 11 of Phase 2
0.045
RSct
Rmt
0.734
Roil
0.071
RGas
-0.008
Panel C: Period 12 Phase 2
0.002
RSct
Rmt
0.635
Roil
0.025
RGas
0.005

Steel industry

p values

Variables

p values

(0.01)c
(0.00)c
(0.00)c
(0.88)

RSct
Rmt
RSteel

0.049
0.976
0.109

(0.00)c
(0.00)c
(0.00)c

(0.04)b
(0.00)c
(0.00)c
(0.58)

RSct
Rmt
RSteel

0.060
0.998
0.106

(0.00)c
(0.00)c
(0.00)c

(0.86)
(0.00)c
(0.08)a
(0.31)

RSct
Rmt
RSteel

0.016
0.925
0.109

(0.34)
(0.00)c
(0.00)c

This table presents the estimated coefficients and p values of coefficients in the following
regressions: (1) Combustion industry, Rit = ai ? b1 Rmt ? b2 RSct ? b3 RSteel ? e, and (2)
Steel industry, Rit = ai ? b1 Rmt ? b2 RSct ? b3 ROil ? b4 RGas ? e. Rit is daily return on the
common stock of firm i in period t, Rmt is daily return on the market portfolio in period t, RSct is
daily return on spot contracts emission allowances in period t. Variables Roil, RGas, and RSteel
are the changes in prices of commodities of oil, gas and steel. a , b , c denote statistical significance at 1, 5, and 10 % levels, respectively

lot of companies are royally over allocated as a consequence of the crisis period
and do not need to buy emission rights for years. Or at least it has become a lot
cheaper than during the first period of Phase 2. The profits decline to a minimum
and the significance for the corporations disappears. In fact, for the ETS to generate real incentives for net cuts to emissions in the iron and steel sector, it has to
make up for the over-allocation to the sector thus far, and which has been compounded by the recent recession, by mandating much greater cuts in the period
from 2013 to 2020 (Pearson 2010). A number of improvements for the EU ETS
have already been agreed, such as increased auctioning from 2013 onwards. But
with the banking of permits between phases, there is likely to be a significant
hangover effect from Phase 2. This could weaken and undermine the effectiveness
of the ETS from 2013 onwards.

7.5.3 Results for Steel Production, Hypothesis 3


Unreported results show that, inconsistent with expectations for Hypothesis 3,
there does not seem to be a relationship between EUA price changes and steel
production. One explanation might be that steel is ordered in advance and it might
take some time for the EUA price change to have an impact.

Emissions Trading and Stock Returns

123

7.5.4 Results for the Role of Firms Characteristics,


Hypotheses 4 and 5
To test Hypotheses 4 and 5, firm size and leverage ratio are regressed against firms
exposure coefficients from the variable of RSct that is calculated with Step 1 of the
analysis. Age of the firm is used as the control variable. According to unreported
results, both size and financial leverage do not have an impact on the EUA exposures.
The expectation is to find a significant effect of at least firm size because large firms
have more political influence on EUA allocation. Another reason would be economies of scale; the larger the company the more resources available and lower costs of
hedging. But the results do not support this view. Only the steel industry in the first
phase shows a weak significance. The leverage is insignificant for all periods.
According to the theory, more leveraged companies tend to hedge more against risk
resulting in less significance for EUAs. However, the results indicate this is not the
case. The control variable age doesnt have a significant effect either, except that it
has a negative and significant effect on exposure for firms in the steel industry only
during the sample period covering Phase 2. The interpretation of this evidence as that
EUA exposure is determined independently of firms characteristics.

7.6 Conclusions
This chapter addresses the question of whether price changes of trading EUAs
have an effect on stock returns and whether this effect differs over time. The
empirical analysis is designed to be able to answer these two questions by creating
several separate sub-periods within the two phases of the EU ETS. The investigation considers a sample of firms from the European steel industry in addition to
firms in the combustion industry.
For sub-period one in Phase 1, the introduction phase of the EU ETS, it is found
that there is a statistically significant effect of price changes of emission trading on
stock returns for both the combustion and steel industries. During the EUA price
crisis, period two of Phase 1, the results provide mixed findings; the effect is
statistically significant for firms in the combustion industry, but not for firms in the
steel industry. The question needing to be answered is what the difference might be
between the steel and combustion industry that makes them different during this
crisis period? It is suggested that the explanation is that the steel companies were
unable to sell their EUAs in this period because of the large supply of EUAs on the
market, while the combustion industry still had to buy EUAs. The third sub-period
of Phase 1, the post-crisis period, is expected to hold no significance due to over
allocation and low EUA prices until the period ends.
Phase 2, which consists of two sub-periods, is also examined. In sub-period one,
price changes of emission trading have a statistically significant impact on stock
returns for both the combustion and steel industry. In this phase, the over-

124

J. Bruggeman and H. Gonenc

allocation is building up, and EUA prices gradually fall. For sub-period two there
are no significant effects for both industries because of the huge amount of unused
EUAs that have built up during the financial crisis.
Production and EUAs do not seem to be related which could be explained by
the fact that many orders are placed in advance and will thus not react fast on
changing EUA prices. Furthermore, the insignificant estimated coefficients of
corporate size and leverage indicate that those variables are not related to the
exposures of trading price of EUA.
A positive effect of emissions trading on the stock value of companies has
important implications for policy makers. The ETS is supposed to make companies aware of their emissions and polluting activities by letting them pay for their
waste. The proposed changes in the third phase go a long way because combustion
companies will be forced to buy all their EUAs from an auction. However, it is
noted that they will be able to pass through the additional costs just as they have
done over recent years. Then there is the case of the energy intensive industries.
They have negotiated that they will receive free allocations for Phase 3 as well
thus ensuring windfall profits for years to come.
Period 13 shows contradictory evidence for the two industries. The difference
is likely to be caused by the fact that one industry is a net buyer and the other is a
net seller of EUAs. The combustion industry could buy from various sources
holding excess EUAs because of the over-allocation while the steel industry had a
hard time selling their excess EUAs to the few buyers left in the market. The fact is
that the combustion industry was still spending money while the steel industry was
not able to create additional income through their EUAs.
For future research, it would be interesting to redo the analyses with a complete
data set from Phase 2, which covers the period 20082012. Additional insight is
necessary in the second trading phase. Literature on the first phase is plentiful, but
the effects for the second phase are relatively unknown. As this chapter plays a
leading role for this phase, it would be interesting to have future research confirm
or share new insights into these industries and their relationships to the EU ETS for
the later period of the second phase.
As reported by Mansanet Bataller et al. (2007), EUA prices have developed
very similarly in all marketplaces. According to those authors, the choice of
marketplace should not be crucial while researching the effects of the EU ETS.
However, it is the only study claiming this fact and it would be interesting to see if
this holds for the second phase.

References
Anderson, B., & Di Maria, C. (2011). Abatement and allocation in the pilot phase of the EU ETS.
Environmental and Resource Economics, 48(1), 83103.
Bartram, S. M. (2005). The impact of commodity price risk on firm valuean empirical analysis
of corporate commodity price exposures. Multinational Finance Journal, 9, 161187.

Emissions Trading and Stock Returns

125

Daskalakis, G., Psychoyios, D., & Markellos, R. (2009). Modeling CO2 emission allowance
prices and derivatives: Evidence from the European trading scheme. Journal of Banking and
Finance, 33, 12301241.
Ellerman, A. D., & Joskow, P. L. (2008). The European Unions emissions trading system in
perspective. Arlington: PEW Centre on Climate Change.
Gronwald, M., Ketterer, J., & Trueck, S. (2011). The dependence structure between carbon
emission allowances and financial marketsa copula analysis (Working paper No. 3418).
Munich, Germany: CESinfo.
Hassan, M., & Molho, N. (2009). Phase III of the EU emissions trading scheme: Your Q&A
quide. London: CMS Cameron McKenna LLP Publications.
Haushalter, D. G. (2000). Financing policy, basis risk, and corporate hedging: Evidence from oil
and gas producers. Journal of Finance, 55, 107152.
He, J., & Ng, L. K. (1998). The foreign exchange exposure of Japanese multinational
corporations. Journal of Finance, 53, 733753.
IETA. (2008). State and trends of the carbon market 2008. Washington DC: World Bank CF
Research Report.
Jin, Y., & Jorion, P. (2006). Firm value and hedging: Evidence from U.S. oil and gas producers.
Journal of Finance, 61, 893919.
Jorion, P. (1990). The exchange-rate exposure of U.S. multinationals. Journal of Business, 63,
331345.
Kara, M., Syri, S., Lehtila, A., Helynen, S., Kekkonen, V., Ruska, M., et al. (2008). The impacts
of EU CO2 emissions trading on electricity markets and electricity consumers in Finland.
Energy Economics, 30, 193211.
Kemfert, C., Kohlhaas, M., Truong, P. T., & Protsenko, A. (2006). The environmental and
economic effects of European emissions trading. Climate Policy, 6, 441455.
Lund, P. D. (2007). Impacts of EU carbon emission trade directive on energy-intensive
industriesIndicative micro-economic analyses. Ecological Economics, 63, 799806.
Mansanet Bataller, M., Pardo, A., & Valor, E. (2007). CO2 prices, energy, and weather. The
Energy Journal, 28, 7392.
Nance, D. R., Smith, C. W., & Smithson, C. W. (1993). On the determinants of corporate
hedging. Journal of Finance, 48, 267284.
Oberndorfer, U. (2009). EU emission allowances and the stock market: Evidence from the
electricity industry. Ecological Economics, 68, 11161126.
Pearson, A. (2010). The carbon rich list: The companies profiting from the EU Emissions Trading
Scheme. London, UK: Sandbag Climate Campaign CIC.
Reinaud, J. (2007). CO2 allowance and electricity price interaction, impact on industrys
electricity purchasing strategies in Europe. (IEA information paper), Paris, France: OECD/
International Energy Agency.
Sijm, J., Neuhoff, K., & Chen, Y. (2006). CO2 cost pass through and windfall profits in the power
sector. (Cambridge Working Papers in Economics No. 0639). Cambridge, UK: Faculty of
Economics, Cambridge University.
Smith, C. W., & Stulz, R. M. (1985). The determinants of firms hedging policies. Journal of
Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 20, 391405.
Veith, S., Werner, J. R., & Zimmermann, J. (2009). Capital market response to emission right
returns: Evidence from the European power sector. Energy Economics, 31, 605613.
Xu, C., & Cang, D. (2010). A brief overview of low CO2 emission technologies for iron and steel
making. Journal of Iron and Steel Research International, 17(3), 17.
Zachmann, G., & von Hirschhausen, C. (2008). First evidence of asymmetric cost pass-through of
EU emissions allowances: Examining wholesale electricity prices in Germany. Econonic
Letters, 99, 465469.

Part III

The Dynamics of Energy Derivatives


Trading

Chapter 8

Energy Derivatives Market Dynamics


Don Bredin, amonn Ciagin and Cal B. Muckley

Abstract This chapter examines the EU Emissions Trading Scheme options and
futures markets dynamics during the period 20052011. Observations on returns,
volatilities and volumes on derivative instruments are studied. In addition, spot/
future correlations, term structures and option implied volatility smiles and surfaces
are examined. The aim is to ascertain whether the behavior of the EU ETS derivatives
markets can be compared to that of commodity markets, specifically the developed
West Texas Intermediate (WTI) crude oil derivatives market. The results indicate
that the EU Emissions Trading Scheme derivatives markets have matured markedly
since the start of Phase 2 of the Scheme, with rising volumes and declining return
volatilities. Spot/future correlations, term structures and option volatility smiles and
surfaces exhibit comparable behavior over time, albeit with certain discrepancies,
with that found in the developed WTI crude oil derivatives market. These results are
valuable both for traders of EU allowances and for those policy makers seeking to
improve the design of the EU Emissions Trading Scheme.

Keywords CO2 EU ETS


Volatility Volume

 Futures  Market dynamics  Options  Returns 

D. Bredin  . Ciagin  C. B. Muckley (&)


School of Business, Ucd Michael Smurfit Graduate Business School,
Carysfort Avenue, Blackrock, Co. Dublin, Ireland
e-mail: ei.dcu@niderb.nod

A. Dorsman et al. (eds.), Energy Economics and Financial Markets,


DOI: 10.1007/978-3-642-30601-3_8, Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg 2013

129

130

D. Bredin et al.

8.1 Introduction
The European Union Emissions Trading Scheme (ETS) was established in 2005 as
the cornerstone of the EU effort to comply with the demands of the Kyoto protocol. The protocol, adopted in 1997, aims to reduce the worlds CO2 emissions to
pre-1990 levels by the year 2020. The idea behind the scheme is to incentivize
reduced carbon emissions by creating a Europe-wide market in CO2 emissions
where allowances can be traded between countries and companies. The pilot Phase
of the EU ETS ran from 2005 to 2007, while the Phase 2 (Kyoto) is running from
2008 to 2012 and the Phase 3 will run from 2013 to 2020. This chapter seeks to
analyze the rapidly growing CO2 derivatives markets that have developed as a
result of the creation of the ETS.
This study is the first to comprehensively examine the dynamics of the ETS
derivatives markets for both Phases 1 and 2. Although there is some research of this
nature examining Phase 1 of the EU ETS, the uncertainty, primarily as a result of the
limitations on inter-period banking, means that a Phase 2 analysis should be more
informative. The primary aim is to investigate whether the market has changed since
the end of Phase 1 and whether there is any evidence of the emergence of maturing
market dynamics. Apart from investigating evidence of a maturing market, another
question addressed is whether the EU emissions market can be seen to exhibit
commodity like behavior. This is a research question which has been alluded to in
much of the literature but there is no consensus on whether EU emissions contracts fit
in this category (see, Bredin and Muckley 2011a, b). The study adopts oil derivatives,
specifically West Texas Intermediate (WTI) crude oil futures and options, as
benchmarks to analyze the development of the ETS derivatives markets. ETS
derivatives, and futures in particular, have overtaken the spot market in terms of
trading volume, and so an analysis of derivative behaviors will be more informative.
The research finds that volatility declined dramatically in Phase 2 while the
correlation between spot and futures contracts stabilized at a high level. It also
finds the term structure of futures prices to indicate contango, contradicting previous findings for typical commodity markets which find evidence of backwardation (see Pindyck 2001; Considine and Larson 2001a, b; Milonas and Henker
2001). In contrast, the current analysis of the term structure of futures prices for the
WTI crude oil data indicates periods of contango and periods of backwardation.
This echoes the findings of Escobar et al. (2003) who also find very little evidence
of consistency in term structures of oil futures over time. Consistent with Samuelson (1965) there is evidence to indicate a declining term structure of both EUA
and oil volatility. In the options market a clear development in the volatility smiles
and surfaces in Phase 2 relative to Phase 1 is observed. The Phase 2 analysis
indicates consistent volatility smiles and a persistent forward skew, with the
number of contracts traded approaching levels observed in the WTI crude oil
options market. Overall the results are clearly indicative of an increased maturity
and stability in the EU ETS derivatives markets. With the exception of the future
term structure, the EUA derivatives behavior is generally consistent with the WTI

8 Energy Derivatives Market Dynamics

131

crude oil derivatives markets.1 This chapters description of market developments


as well as the empirical results will be of interest to both policy makers and market
practitioners.
The remainder of this chapter is structured as follows. Section 8.2 describes in
detail the structure and growth of the EU ETS, including a survey of the research
that has been undertaken in the area. Section 8.3 reports the analysis of the EU
ETS futures market with a specific focus on returns, volatilities and volumes in the
market. Section 8.4 presents the analysis of the EU ETS options market including
analysis of option volatility smiles and surfaces. Finally, Sect. 8.5 presents the
conclusion.

8.2 The EU Emissions Trading Scheme


The EU ETS was created in 2005 as the cornerstone of the EU effort to comply
with the demands of the Kyoto protocol. The scheme seeks to allow low emitters
to profit by selling on their excess emission allowances while high emitters are
punished by having to pay for more allowances. Mills (2008) highlighted how
market based systems such as this can help counter the effects of climate change in
two ways. First by improving the efficiency of schemes aimed at reducing emissions and so allocating capital to green technologies and second, by cutting the
costs of adaption to climate change.
The EU ETS covers approximately two billion tons of CO2 emissions per
annum and is applied to over 11,000 industrial installations in the 27 EU countries
along with Norway, Iceland and Liechtenstein. In terms of the structure of the
marketplace, the trading of spot EU allowances (EUAs) takes place mainly
through Bluenext in Paris and Nordpool, the Nordic power market, these two
representing 70 % and 20 % respectively of transactions in 2006 (Daskalakis et al.
2009). EUA futures are traded primarily on ICE Futures Europe in London
(previously known as the European Climate Exchange), Nordpool, and also on the
European Energy Exchange in Leipzig. The underlying asset of the futures contract in all these exchanges is 100 spot EUAs with December contracts being by
far the most liquid (Bloch 2010). Options are also actively traded on EUA futures
having been first introduced by the ECX in October 2006.
In 2006 the EU ETS accounted for approximately 97 % of global emissions
transactions, highlighting the dominance of the EU scheme in the global carbon
market (Mansanat-Bataller and Pardo 2008). Chevalier and Sevi (2009) highlight
the fact that ECX futures are by far the most heavily traded emissions contract.
Since its inception, the growth of the EU ETS market has been quite remarkable
1

It is noteworthy that, according to Europol, the European law-enforcement agency, the marked
development in these statistics, for the EU ETS derivatives markets, occurred despite a backdrop
of Europe having lost about 7.4 billion euros in taxation revenue for the 18 months prior to
December 2009 because of CO2 VAT trading fraud.

132

D. Bredin et al.

with the volume of transactions in the market going from 252 million tons in 2005
to 1.5 billion tons in 2007 (Chevalier et al. 2009). Fusaro (2007) estimated,
assuming that commodities usually trade at between 6 and 20 times the underlying
market, that the value of the global carbon market could grow to over $3 trillion in
the future, clearly illustrating the growth potential in this market.
In recent years the ETS has continued to grow with total ETS volumes,
including spot, forward and option markets, reaching 7.025 billion tons of CO2 in
2010, a 7 % increase on 2009. In terms of market composition, spot volumes fell
54 % in 2010 to 603 million tons, representing 9 % of the total ETS volume. In
contrast to this, option volume grew to 14 % of the market to overtake spot for the
first time while EUA futures, forwards and options combined, accounted for over
75 % of the total market (Chestney 2011).2
Recent figures also illustrate the dominance of exchanges in the trading of EUAs
with exchange volumes jumping 23 % to 3.84 billion tons in 2010 to account for over
55 % of the market while over the counter (OTC) volumes fell 8 % on 2009 to make
up under 45 % of the market. Significantly for this study, ICE Futures Europe, the
exchange from which the data is taken, was the dominant exchange accounting for
3.4 billion tons or 89 % of total exchange volume (Chestney 2011).

8.2.1 ETS Phase 1 Analysis


Although the ETS remains an emerging market, its high profile and political, economic and environmental significance has resulted in a large volume of research.
This research is largely focused on assessing market development in Phase 1 of the
scheme. The first phase of the scheme was quite problematic with allowances being
over allocated culminating in the price of emissions allowances collapsing to below
10 cents in September 2007, following highs of over 30 Euro in 2006.
The spot price of EUAs is plotted in Fig. 8.1. The figure illustrates the persistent fall in the spot price over 2007 and the eventual price collapse in the latter
half of 2007. Relative stability returned with the move to Phase 2.
The price collapse in Phase 1 was partly the result of over-allocation compounded by a prohibition on the banking of allowances between Phases. Following
on from these problems Daskalakis and Markellos (2008) find that the behavior of
the market in Phase 1 was not consistent with weak form efficiency. The authors
argue that this was as a result of market immaturity and also the restrictions
imposed on short-selling and on banking of emission allowances between Phases.
Some of these restrictions were relaxed in Phase 2 with the prohibition on banking
between Phases being dropped.3.

The balance consisted of spot along with UN-backed credits.


It is important to note that in Phase 1 only inter-period banking of allowances was prohibited,
there were no restrictions on intra-period banking.

8 Energy Derivatives Market Dynamics

133

Fig. 8.1 Spot prices for EU allowances

Looking at the effectiveness of the first phase in achieving its goal of reduced
emissions it can be seen that it may not have been entirely successful. Bloch
(2010) described the results of the early stages of the ETS as lackluster.
The author argues that the ETS is subject to extreme price volatility as a result of the
complete inelasticity of supply of permits and high inelasticity of demand over the
short-term. Bloch (2010) also points out that the scheme has been possibly marred
by rent-seeking behavior with participants seeking to maximize revenue rather than
focusing on emissions reduction. Lowrey (2006) highlights the centrally important
element of the scheme being the establishment of a market determined price for
CO2 allowances. This market price should serve as an incentive to reduce emissions
and to invest in low carbon technologies. Closely linked to this idea, Paolella and
Taschini (2008) discuss how the primary aim of the scheme should be to produce a
scarcity of allowances leading to an upward price trend. Clearly there was no
scarcity of allowances in Phase 1 and the collapse of the spot price led Newbury
(2009) to conclude that the Phase 1 EU ETS was not delivering the stable carbon
price necessary for long-term, low-carbon investment decisions.

8.2.2 ETS Price Determinants


Another strand of the literature in the area has focused on investigating the primary
drivers of CO2 prices. While some of the work supports the argument that the EUA
prices are driven by market fundamentals which affect the production of CO2
(Bunn and Fezzi 2007; Mansanet-Bataller et al. 2007), other work argues in favor
of a time-series approach (Benz and Truck 2008; Seifert et al. 2008; Paolella and
Taschini 2008).
Concentrating on the first approach, Christiansen et al. (2005) identify the
primary drivers in the market as economic growth, energy prices, and weather
conditions. Additional work by Kara et al. (2008) finds that the relationship

134

D. Bredin et al.

between these drivers and the price of CO2 emissions reflects evidence of reverse
causality with CO2 exerting a significant influence on the prices of power, gas and
several other emission related commodities and activities.
The papers of Delarue et al. (2008) and Ellerman and Feilhauer (2008) show
that energy prices are the most important driver of CO2 prices with high energy
prices leading to an increase in carbon prices. However, Kanen (2006) highlights
the role of Brent crude as a driver of carbon prices (via its impact on natural gas
and power prices). Drawing on these studies, Brent crude is examined as the
benchmark to compare with the ETS market. Finally, while the early literature on
ETS price drivers focused on Phase 1, Bredin and Muckley (2011a) note that in
Phase 2, stable relationships formed between allowances and theoretically consistent determinants. There had been virtually no evidence of this stability using
Phase 1 samples.

8.2.3 ETS Derivatives and Market Dynamics


In this study daily ECX futures and options data is used as opposed to looking at
spot data. This is motivated by the higher volume of futures transactions and also
the fact, as highlighted by Alberola et al. (2009), that the spot price has so far
proved less robust than futures in terms of signaling. A number of studies have
assessed the impact of derivatives on the underlying EUA market and on environmental policy. Chevallier et al. (Chevallier et al. 2009) examine the introduction of EU ETS in 2006, with results indicating no destabilizing effect on the
underlying futures market. Bohringer et al. (2008) go so far as to argue that
overlapping regulatory instruments should be avoided in order to achieve efficiency in global environmental policy. These authors argue that the main risk for
industrials operating in the ETS is CO2 price changes and this also serves as the
primary incentive for reducing emissions. If these risks can be hedged easily with
derivatives, Bohringer et al. (2008) argue that derivatives may soften the regulatory impact of the ETS.
In terms of market dynamics, much of the work has again focused on Phase 1 of
the ETS. Investigating the term structure of ECX spot and futures prices between
2005 and 2006 Borak et al. (2006) find a dynamic term structure over time but
conclude that since March 2006 ECX futures prices are in contango. This contradicts the findings from other commodity markets which find evidence of
backwardation (Pindyck 2001; Milonas and Henker 2001).
Investigating the term structure of commodities forward price volatility Samuelson (1965) finds a typically declining term structure in futures volatility with
increasing maturities. Borak et al. (2006), however, find that in the early stages of
the EU ETS the term structure of futures volatility was again dynamic. The authors
sample is relatively short and runs from October 2005 to September 2006 and at
different stages in their study the term structure ranges from decreasing to flat to
increasing. There is little consistency in the results and no evidence of strong

8 Energy Derivatives Market Dynamics

135

dynamics developing in the relationship between spot and futures volatility.4 This
is not surprising given the short sample period and the considerable uncertainty
throughout Phase 2. Overall the results reported by Borak et al. (2006) contradict
the literature in this area and provided ambivalent results on the Samuelson effect.
Borak et al. (2006) conclude that EUA price behavior in spot and futures markets
is substantially different to that in commodities markets.
Borak et al. (2006) also examine the correlation between spot and futures prices
and find a very strong correlation between spot and Phase 1 futures prices, with
reduced correlations for Phase 2 futures. The correlations also decline as there is a
movement out of the maturity spectrum, indicating that investors opinions about
distant time periods are less affected by short-term spot movements. Finally, Borak
et al. (2006) also find that futures expiring in the same phases exhibit very strong
correlations.
Other papers which have looked into the volatility and price dynamics of the
ETS include Benz and Truck (2009) and Paolella and Tachini (Paolella and
Taschini 2008) which both examine the price behavior of EUAs indicating different models for the dynamics of short-term EUA spot price behavior. Benz and
Hengelbrock (2008) were the first to extend this type of analysis to the futures
market, examining the price behavior, liquidity and correlations in different EUA
contracts.5 This study, based around Phase 1 data finds that transaction costs and
spreads had fallen rapidly in 2007 while trading volumes and intensity had
increased markedly. Recent studies indicate the existence of a convenience yield in
the EU ETS market (Uhrig-Homburg and Wagner 2009; Rittler 2011). Both
studies examine the relationship between spot and futures prices in the EU ETS,
with Uhrig-Homburg and Wagner (2009) adopting daily data and Rittler (2011)
adopting both daily and transaction (tick) level data. The authors find evidence of
long-run (or cointegrating) relationships, a convenience yield and price discovery
via futures markets (rather than spot markets).

8.3 Futures Analysis


In this chapter the development of the EU emissions derivatives market is
examined using WTI crude as a benchmark for comparison. In order to carry out
the analysis, December ECX futures and WTI crude futures contracts are used
with maturities in each year from 2005 to 2012. The December contract is used
because, as discussed earlier, it is by far the most liquid contract. In addition, the
December contract was the only one traded in 2005, the first year of the EU
4

Borak et al. (2006) also find evidence of a weakly increasing term structure when examining
Phase 2 instruments.
5
Bredin, Hyde and Muckley (Bredin et al. 2009) examine the microstructure behaviour of
trading volume, return volatility and transaction duration (time between consecutive trades) for
Phase 1 and the initial contract of Phase 2 using transaction level data.

136

D. Bredin et al.

Trading scheme. The price and volume data for all the ECX contracts started in
April 2005 although many of the later maturing contracts were not actively traded
during the early stages of their existence.

8.3.1 Futures Volumes


The first step in the analysis is to investigate the volumes of ECX futures contracts
traded over the last 5 years in order to determine the growth of the market since
inception.
As illustrated in Table 8.1, there has been substantial growth in the market
between Phases 1 and 2. The market took off slowly with less than 10,000
December futures contracts traded between April and July 2005. In the same April
to July period in 2007 almost 100,000 futures contracts were traded meaning the
market had tripled in the space of two years. In the years 2008, 2009 and 2010
volumes traded in the April to July period reached 200,000, 450,000 and 950,000
respectively. Clearly this was a period of enormous growth with volumes more
than doubling every year since the start of the scheme. Interestingly this growth
has not slowed down at all since the start of Phase 2. The evidence seems to
indicate that the busiest period for the trading of particular futures contracts is
around 6 months before their expiry. Also of interest is the lack of activity in nonDecember contracts with trading volumes close to zero particularly in more recent
years. As illustrated in the appendices, total volume of the March 10 future was
only 17 contracts compared to over 2 million for the December 10 future. Similarly low volumes occurred across all other non-December futures in the sample.

8.3.2 Futures Returns


The second step is to examine returns in the market as an indication of overall
market behavior over the last five years.
Table 8.2 reports the average continuously compounded daily return for all
ECX 20052011 December futures contracts for the sample period from 2005 until
the end of 2010.
The returns indicate that in Phase 1, agents holding ECX futures would have
been exposed to prices falls in 2006 and towards the end of the first phase in 2007.
In the final three months of Phase 1 the December 2007 futures contract had a
spectacularly weak average daily return of -4.99 %. Looking at the second phase,
and daily returns since 2007 on all the contracts with Phase 2 expiry, it can be seen
that the market settled down a huge amount. Average daily returns in this period
were between -0.40 % and 0.40 % for all bar one of the quarters. This is very
much in line with the type of return behavior seen in the returns of WTI crude

8 Energy Derivatives Market Dynamics

137

Table 8.1 ECX December futures volumes


ECX Volume Dec-05 Dec-06 Dec-07 Dec-08 Dec-09
2005 AprJun
8,439
1,190
JulSep
10,7 12
1,488
OctDec
5,067 10,944
2006 JanMar
27,851
AprJul1
35,606
JulSep
18,845
OctDec
13,747
2007 JanMar
AprJun
JulSep
OctDec
2008 JanMar
AprJun
JulSep
OctDec
2009 JanMar
AprJun
JulSep
OctDec
2010 JanMar
AprJun
JulSep
OctDec
24,218 109,671

110
1,197
2,555
5,433
7,044
6,484
24,568
22,457
11,254
2,649
9,021

45
365
135
865
5,711
4,766
28,221
47,428
83,365
94,620
85,862
137,594
173,644
197,534
99,370

0
20
0
10
241
59
281
623
3,856
7,448
6,054
7,827
15,215
34,821
108,897
339,461
340,192
290,623
178,391

Dec-10

0
0
0
0
0
10
57
35
571
3,127
2,327
3,414
6,376
7,461
12,074
29,320
44,849
47,395
231,813
489,128
740,989
413,504
292,319
92,772 959,525 1,334,019 2,324,769

Dec-11 Totals
0
9,784
0
13,782
0
18,701
10
34,169
0
48,602
0
30,164
0
66,874
0
70,543
499
99,545
1,573 109,417
860 104,124
2,196 151,031
6,848 202,083
5,836 245,652
8,335 228,676
19,021 387,802
18,861 403,902
16,4 78 354,496
40,051 450,255
58,422 547,550
124,468 865,457
79,509 493,013
246,261 538,580
629,228 5,474,202

futures.6 This provides evidence of the stability and maturity of the ECX market
since the start of Phase 2.

8.3.3 Spot and Futures Volatility


The next step in the analysis is to examine volatility in the ETS spot and futures
market.
Figure 8.2 indicates evidence of large spot return volatility, particularly
towards the end of Phase 1. However, returns stabilize considerably in Phase 2.
Attention now turns to the futures market, where a range of summary statistics
are reported and discussed across different contracts for both Phases 1 and 2 of the
EU ETS.

The summary statistics for WTI December futures returns are reported in the Appendix to this
chapter, see Table 5.8.

138

D. Bredin et al.

Table 8.2 ECX December futures returns


ECX Avrg
Dec-05
Dec-06
Dec-07
Return
(%)
(%)
(%)
2005 AprJun
JulSep
OctDec
2006 JanMar
AprJun
JulSep
OctDec
2007 JanMar
AprJun
JulSep
OctDec
2008 JanMar
AprJun
JulSep
OctDec
2009 JanMar
AprJun
JulSep
OctDec
2010 JanMar
AprJun
JulSep
OctDec

0.22
0.14
-0.04

0.26
0.13
0.38
0.20
-0.91
-0.4 1
-1.61

0.27
0.12
0.42
0.21
-0.91
-0.44
-1.87
-2.89
-2.59
-0.83
-4 .99

Dec-08
(%)

Dec-09
(%)

Dec-10
(%)

Dec-11
(%)

0.28
0.07
0.15
0.50
-0.71
-0.31
-0.06
0.18
0.13
0.22
-0.15
0.38
-0.02
-0.33
-0.75

0.28
0.07
0.15
0.53
-0.69
-0.30
-0.06
0.17
0.12
0.23
-0.15
0.38
0.01
-0.35
-0.88
0.24
0.11
0.00
0.00

0.28
0.06
0.15
0.55
-0.68
-0.30
-0.06
0.16
0.10
0.23
-0.15
0.38
0.02
-0.36
-0.88
0.27
0.08
0.00
-0.18
0.14
-0.07
0.11

0.28
0.06
0.15
0.57
-0.67
-0.29
-0.06
0.15
0.09
0.24
-0.14
0.38
0.04
-0.35
-0.89
0.29
0.09
-0.02
-0.19
0.13
-0.09
0.11
-0.10

Table 8.3 reports the summary statistics for the December 2007 and the
December 2010 futures. The December 2010 futures summary statistics are
reported both over the full sample (February 2006November 2010) as well as
individually for both Phases 1 and 2. For comparison the summary statistics for
WTI futures are also reported. As can be seen, the standard deviation (over 8 %
per day) of the December 2007 contracts for Phase 1 is extremely high compared
to both the WTI and the December 2010 contract. This compares to the WTI
standard deviation of 1.4 % and indicates the levels of volatility in the ECX
market in what was its most difficult and volatile period. Looking across the life of
the December 2010 contract it can be seen that the standard deviation of daily
returns on this contract fell to 2.67 % in comparison with 1.76 % for the WTI
December 2110 futures for the same period. The dramatic fall in standard deviations is due to the move from pilot to full implementation and the relaxation of
the no-banking rule for Phase 2.
Examining the December 10 futures behavior over the two phases yields an
interesting comparison, in particular in relation to the WTI comparison. The
standard deviation of the ETS futures for a Phase 1 sample is 3.02 %. This reflects
the fact that this contract was for delivery in Phase 2, meaning that it wasnt

8 Energy Derivatives Market Dynamics

139

Fig. 8.2 Volatility of daily spot returns

Table 8.3 Summary Statistics: Oil & ETS Futures


Dec- 07 Futures Summary Stats (Feb-06Nov- Dec-10 Futures Summary Stats (Feb-06Dec07)
07)
ECX

WTI

Mean
-0.0131
0.0007
Median
0
0.0013
Mode
0
0
Standard Deviation
0.0818
0.0141
Skewness
0.1911
-0.1786
Kurtosis
12.2179
3.4955
Dec - 10 Futures Summary Stats (Feb-06 to
Nov-10)
ECX
WTI
Mean
-0.0048
0.001
Median
0
0.294
Mode
0
0
Standard Deviation
0.0267
0.0176
Skewness
-0.7356
-0.037
Kurtosis
15.7172
0.5206

ECX

WTI

Mean
-0.0019
0.0055
Median
0.0021
0.0003
Mode
0
0
Standard Deviation
0.0302
0.0115
Skewness
-1.2879
-0.1005
Kurtosis
21.4549
3.0201
Dec - 10 Futures Summary Stats (Feb-06 to
Nov-10)
ECX
WTI
Mean
-0.0067
-0.0019
Median
0
0.0008
Mode
0
0
Standard Deviation
0.0242
0.0205
Skewness
-0.0473
0.0019
Kurtosis
5.285
4.4034

impacted as strongly by the collapse in the EUA prices at the end of Phase 1. This
compared with a WTI standard deviation of 1.15 % in the same period. Since the
start of the second phase, the standard deviation of daily returns for December 10
futures fell to 2.67 % while the WTI contract had a standard deviation of 1.76 %.
This confirms that a more stable market developed with less volatility than the
erratic first phase. Another point of note is that the standard deviations have fallen
to a level much closer to those of the benchmark commodity.
In addition to these findings it can also be seen that large changes in the
skewness and kurtosis are exhibited by EUA returns since the early stages of

140

D. Bredin et al.

Table 8.4 ETS futures standard deviations


ECX Standard Dec-05
Dec-06
Dec-07
Dev
(%)
(%)
(%)
2005 AprJun
JulSep
OctDec
2006 JanMar
AprJun
JulSep
OctDec
2007 JanMar
AprJun
JulSep
OctDec
2008 JanMar
AprJun
JulSep
OctDec
2009 JanMar
AprJun
JulSep
OctDec
2010 JanMar
AprJun
JulSep
OctDec

3.69
2.03
2.34

3.75
2.00
2.30
1.46
10.25
2.48
3.92

3.77
2.06
2.28
1.39
10.07
2.46
5.13
10.04
8.05
11.02
35.34

Dec-08
(%)

Dec-09
(%)

Dec-10
(%)

Dec-11
(%)

3.69
2.59
2.42
2.32
5.70
2.01
2.86
3.18
2.70
1.92
1.68
2.06
2.05
2.38
3.41

3.64
2.59
2.45
2.40
5.67
1.92
2.82
3.05
2.67
1.83
1.64
2.01
2.07
1.92
1.68
2.06
2.05
2.38
3.41

3.59
2.57
2.42
2.43
5.61
1.87
275
2.97
2.87
2.21
1.63
1.97
2.08
2.23
2.93
4.61
2.43
2.02
2.34
1.61
2.06
1.33
1.15

3.54
2.54
2.43
2.72
5.56
1.87
267
2.90
2.62
1.69
1.62
1.91
2.05
2.18
2.88
4.52
2.40
1.98
2.28
1.56
2.03
1.32
1.11

trading scheme. For example from Table 8.3, the December 2007 contract has a
kurtosis of over 12 compared to only 3.5 for the December 2007 WTI future. This
indicates that EUA futures have a relatively fat tailed, low distribution compared
to the more normally distributed WTI future. The implication is that EUA returns
have infrequent, but large deviations from the mean, as opposed to frequent
modest departures for WPI.
The EUA December 10 futures contract indicate similar behavior in Phase 1 of
the scheme with high kurtosis of 21 relative to the WTI future, while the EUA
returns were also very strongly negatively skewed during this period. However,
looking at the behavior of the EUA December 10 contract for Phase 2, there is
evidence of extremely mild negative skew and low kurtosis, which is consistent
with that of the WTI market. Again this clearly illustrates the relative maturity of
the EUA market in Phase 2 as its behavior move into line with that of the
benchmark commodity market.
Table 8.4 reports the standard deviations of daily returns on a quarterly basis
for all December contracts from 2005 to 2011. Evidence of large volatility in
Phase 1 of the scheme is again reported, with standard deviations as high as
35.34 % for the last three months of 2007. In Phase 2, there is persistent evidence

8 Energy Derivatives Market Dynamics

141

of a maturing market, with lower and more persistent standard deviations. Also a
clear disconnect between the volatility of Phase 1 and Phase 2 expiry contracts can
be seen.7
Overall the findings on volatility are unambiguous, with all indicators pointing
to a more stable market over the last few years. The market has become far more
stable in Phase 2 and there is evidence that the changes in market structure since
the end of Phase 1 are proving very effective. Comparison with the WTI Crude
market provides further evidence of EUA market development, with consistent
levels of volatility emerging in both markets.

8.3.4 Relationship Between Spot and Futures Prices


In order to examine the relationship between spot and futures prices the correlation
coefficients between daily spot and future returns is examined. As discussed in
Borak et al. (2006) they first examined these correlations in 2006 based on data
from October 2005 to September 2006 finding evidence of extremely high correlations, over 0.99 between spot and futures prices in Phase 1.8 For Phase 2
futures the correlations fall dramatically but are still significantly large, between
0.6 and 0.8. The authors conclude that the correlation is decreasing with maturity,
indicating that investors opinions about the distant time periods are less affected
by short term spot movements.9 Their work is built on here using data for the
period from 2005 to 2011.10
Although Borak et al.(2006) use prices to conduct their correlation analysis, it is
felt prudent to look at the correlations in continuously compounded daily returns.
Table 8.5 reports the correlations between spot and futures daily returns for
Phase 1 (20052007) and Phase 2 (20082012) of the EU ETS. Consistent with the
findings of Borak et al. (2006) the Phase 2 futures returns exhibit very strong
correlations with one other. It is also observed that there is a generally decreasing
correlation with increasing maturity. In Phase 1 however, the findings are somewhat different. First, in 2006 there is a high correlation with spot (0.808). While
lower than the correlations reported by Borak et al. (2006), the present results are
likely to be influenced by the higher volatility towards the end of 2006 which is not
part of the Borak et al. (2006) sample. In contrast, for the 2007 future there is an
extremely low correlation of 0.212. However, this result is not surprising given the
erratic market behavior in 2007. Finally, the Phase 2 contracts much higher

7
See Bredin, Hyde and Muckley (Bredin et al. 2009) for an intra-day volatility and volume
analysis of Phase 1 and early Phase 2 EUA December expiry futures contracts.
8
Borak et al. (2006) used prices to conduct their correlation analysis.
9
Borak et al. (2006) also find that futures prices within the same Phase exhibited stronger
correlations.
10
The sample of data used here is considerably larger than that adopted by Borak et al. (2006).

142

D. Bredin et al.

Table 8.5 ECX spot and futures returns correlations


Delivery
Spot
2005
2006
2007
2008
Spot
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012

0.600
1

0.808
0.980
1

0.212
0.964
0.980
1

0.014
0.809
0.522
0.090
1

2009

2010

2011

2012

0.018
0.798
0.513
0.088
0.981
1

0.019
0.798
0.507
0.086
0.967
0.989
1

0.019
0.844
0.500
0.085
0.948
0.971
0.969
1

0.018
0.768
0.492
0.083
0.932
0.956
0.955
0.988
1

correlations are explained by the fact that they are based on a longer sample period
than the 2007 future. This meant that the relationship between spot and futures
recovered in Phase 2 and has been far more stable in the last few years.
Comparing these results to the WTI Crude market a far more consistent and
high correlation across all oil contracts with correlation again decreasing with
maturity is evident. As is the case with volatility and returns ECX spot/futures
correlation behaviors seem to again be reflecting WTI Crude much more since the
beginning of Phase 2.

8.3.5 Term Structures of Futures Prices and Volatility


Building on the work above, the term structures of both price and volatility in the
EU ETS are investigated. The term structures indicate the relationship between
EUA futures price and volatility against the term to expiration of these contracts.
Figure 8.3 displays the term structure of emission allowance futures prices with
yearly maturities from 2006 to 2014. Specifically, presented are the futures prices
for each trading day in the month of April in years 2006, 2007, 2008, 2009 and
2010, the observed prices are connected by a line.11 Hence there are 20 to 24 lines
in each of the graphsthe different lines represent different trading days in the
month of April. The month of April is chosen due to the fact that operators are
required to surrender sufficient allowances to cover their previous years emissions
by the 30th of April each year. For this reason one would expect April to be a
particularly active period in the ETS market.
Clearly seen from the 2006 plot is the early volatility in the market, with the
term structures from April 2006 exhibiting no consistent behavior. Even within the
month of April the term structure varies wildly between different days. In 2007 it is
clear to see the impact of the ECX price collapse and the ban on banking between
11

Qualitatively similar term structures are present in 2009. These are available from the authors
on request.

8 Energy Derivatives Market Dynamics


Table 8.6 ECX March contract volumes
ECX Volume
Mar-06
Mar-07
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010

143

Mar-08

Mar-09

Mar-10

Mar-11

435
3334

0
68
1362

0
20
12
1795

0
0
0
0
847

3769

1430

1827

847

0
0
0
0
10
7
17

0
0
0
0
0
10
10

Dec-09
(%)

Dec-10
(%)

Dec-11
(%)

1.32
1.13
1.01
1.36
1.34
0.95
0.96
1.34
1.74
2.10
3.12
3.89
3.04
1.94
2.22
1.93

1.33
1.12
1.03
1.31
1.34
0.94
0.90
1.24
1.70
1.99
2.87
3.20
2.51
1.56
1.72
1.46
1.50
1.93
1.57
1.74

1.35
1.13
1.05
1.30
1.34
0.93
0.88
1.21
1.68
1.95
2.80
2.86
2.29
1.42
1.53
1.39
1.34
1.74
1.36
1.14

Table 8.7 WTI December futures standard deviations


WTI Standard
Dec-06
Dec-07
Dec-08
Dev
(%)
(%)
(%)
2006 JanMar
AprJun
JulSep
OctDec
2007 JanMar
AprJun
JulSep
OctDec
2008 JanMar
AprJun
JulSep
OctDec
2009 JanMar
AprJun
JulSep
OctDec
2010 JanMar
AprJun
JulSep
OctDec

1.42
1.35
1.45
1.97

1.32
1.19
1.11
1.61
1.48
1.12
1.45
2.07

1.30
1.13
1.02
1.43
1.36
0.99
1.09
1.59
1.86
2.28
3.47
4.53

Qualitatively similar term structures are present in 2009. These are available from the authors on
request

phases with a flat term structure at the short end where the Phase 1 futures prices
had converged on zero. In 2008, 2009 and 2010 consistent increasing term
structures are observed which provides further evidence of the maturity of the
market in Phase 2. The term structures from April 2008, April 2009 and April 2010
look almost identical and the market is clearly in contango as can be seen from the
increasing futures prices for all maturity periods.

144

D. Bredin et al.

Table 8.8 WTI December futures average returns


WTI Avrg Return Dec-06
Dec-07
Dec-08
(%)
(%)
(%)
2006 JanMar
AprJun
JulSep
OctDec
2007 JanMar
AprJun
JulSep
OctDec
2008 JanMar
AprJun
JulSep
OctDec
2009 JanMar
AprJun
JulSep
OctDec
2010 JanMar
AprJun
JulSep
OctDec

0.21
0.01
-0.41
-0.39

0.26
0.04
-0.22
-0.22
0.21
0.11
0.22
0.44

0.21
0.03
-0.15
-0.21
0.23
0.02
0.14
0.14
0.48
0.19
-0.98
-1.74

Dec-09
(%)

Dec-10
(%)

Dec-11
(%)

0.19
0.02
-0.13
-0.18
0.21
0.01
0.11
0.17
0.44
0.26
-0.85
-0.48
0.00
0.34
0.19
0.24

0.18
0.02
-0.12
-0.15
0.18
0.04
0.09
0.18
0.41
0.28
-0.73
-0.43
0.06
0.29
0.15
-0.12
0.17
-0.18
0.03
0.03

0.18
0.01
-0.13
-0.12
0.16
0.05
0.09
0.19
0.40
0.28
-0.67
-0.42
0.08
0.27
0.13
-0.09
0.15
-0.16
0.04
0.17

Qualitatively similar term structures are present in 2009. These are available from the authors on
request

The results support the findings of Borak et al. (2006) with evidence both of a
much more settled and consistent market in Phase 2 and also evidence of
increasing term structures in each period.
Figure 8.4 reports the term structure of futures volatility for all 3 month periods from
the years 2006 to 2009 for spot and futures prices for delivery from 2005 to 2012. Overall
the results in Fig. 8.4 are quite intuitive. The results for Phase 1 are quite dynamic, but
are generally consistent with those reported by Borak et al. (2006). However, for Phase 2
there is evidence of a weakly declining term structure in ECX futures volatility with
maturity. This result is in keeping with Samuelsons (1965) findings.

8.4 Options Analysis


This section analyses the development of the EUA options market using WTI
Crude options as a benchmark for comparison. The analysis on options involves
examining the implied volatility smiles and surfaces in the EUA options market as
an indication of market development since 2006. The option price data adopted is
the exchange traded ECX options traded on ICE Futures Europe in London. The
analysis involves examining snapshots from the options markets during different

8 Energy Derivatives Market Dynamics

145

Table 8.9 WTI December futures VOLUMES


WTIVOLUME DEC-06 DEC-07 DEC-08
2006 JanMar
AprJun
JulSep
OctDec
2007 JanMar
AprJun
JulSep
OctDec
2008 JanMar
AprJun
JulSep
Oct Dec
2009 JanMar
AprJun
JulSep
OctDec
2010 JanMar
AprJun
JulSep
OctDec

82,270
324,876
2,012,976
2,582,757

21,718
146,640
351,531
488,262
683,033
1,045,992
3,031,371
3,190,314

4,274
36,972
100,807
206,619
293,315
428,891
631,966
526,075
736,991
1,017,666
2,777,140
2,812,657

DEC-09

DEC-10

2,453
12,018
31,350
64,479
75,280
104,420
151,485
187,022
272,013
432,161
473,930
464,408
545,931
731,885
2,494,281
2,707,020

1,791
4,686
11,074
20,202
30,181
32,019
59,805
74,356
103,752
131,030
140,612
147,125
192,955
222,488
365,184
367,202
616,590
984,339
3,037,636
2,805,307
5,002,879 8,958,861 9,573,373 8,750,136 9,348,334

DEC-11

TOTALS

850
753
2,827
5,734
17,626
12,666
29,569
38,963
34,858
42,252
34,340
36,279
46,694
45,413
78,594
96,809
154,080
239,219
490,133
784,926
2,192,585

113,356
525,945
2,510,565
3,368,053
1,099,435
1,623,988
3,904,196
4,016,730
1,147,614
1,623,109
3,426,022
3,460,469
785,580
999,786
2,938,059
3,171,031
770,670
1,223,558
3,527,769
3,590,233
43,826,168

It is important to note that trading in the December WTI Futures contracts normally ceased in
mid-November in their years of maturity. As a result of this the standard deviations, returns and
volumes for these contracts in their final three months are based around a smaller sample
Table 8.10 Correlation between WTI futures returns
Delivery
2006
2007
2008
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011

0.786
1

0.698
0.844
1

2009

2010

2011

0.671
0.778
0.898
1

0.657
0.738
0.826
0.863
1

0.656
0.722
0.788
0.798
0.929
1

periods in Phases 1 and 2 and comparing them with the considerably more mature
WTI options market.

8.4.1 Volatility Smiles


Volatility smiles involve graphing the implied volatility of options with the same
underlying asset and maturity against their strike prices. Volatility smiles are
adopted to identify how the market prices options with different strikes and hence
the different levels of moneyness in existence in the EUA market. Given volatility

146

D. Bredin et al.

April 2006

2
-1

ec

n-

Ju

-1

12

11
D

ec

n-

Ju

ec

-1

10

n-

Ju

ec

-0

09

8
-0

Ju

n-

08

ec

n-

Ju

ec

-0

07

6
-0

n-

Ju

ec
D

Ju

n-

06

Price

Futures Term Structure:


35
30
25
20
15
10
5
0

Delivery Period
April 2007

ct

-1

2
O

r-1
Ap

ct

-1

1
r-1

-1
ct

Ap

0
Ap

r-1

-0
ct

r-0
Ap

ct

-0

8
r-0
Ap

7
-0
ct

Ap

r-0

Price

Futures Term Structure:


35
30
25
20
15
10
5
0

Delivery Period
April 2008

-0
Ju 8
n09
D
ec
-0
9
Ju
n1
D 0
ec
-1
0
Ju
n11
D
ec
-1
1
Ju
n12
D
ec
-1
2
Ju
n1
D 3
ec
-1
3
Ju
n14
D
ec
-1
4

ec

Price

Futures Term Structure:


35
30
25
20
15
10
5
0

Delivery Period
Fig. 8.3 Term structures for EUA futures prices

smiles can be examined across a number of different expiries, the development of


the market from Phase 1 to Phase 2 can be traced out. A typical volatility smile
shows implied volatility increasing as options go more and more in and out of the
money, forming a curve in the shape of a smile. The implied volatility smile can be
interpreted as showing that there is a greater demand for heavily ITM or OTM
options over ATM options ceteris paribus.

8 Energy Derivatives Market Dynamics

147
April 2009

Ju
n11
D
ec
-1
1
Ju
n12
D
ec
-1
2
Ju
n13
D
ec
-1
3
Ju
n14
D
ec
-1
4

Ju
n09
D
ec
-0
9
Ju
n10
D
ec
-1
0

Price

Futures Term Structure:


35
30
25
20
15
10
5
0

Delivery Period
April 2010

4
ec

-1

14
D

n-

3
Ju

ec

-1

13
D

n-

2
Ju

-1
ec
D

Ju

n-

12

1
-1
ec
D

n-

11

0
Ju

-1
ec
D

Ju

n-

10

Price

Futures Term Structure:


35
30
25
20
15
10
5
0

Delivery Period
Fig. 8.3 continued

One common type of volatility smile is the reverse volatility skew. This is the case
where implied volatilities are higher for low strike prices (ITM calls/OTM puts) than
they are for high strike prices (ITM puts/OTM calls). This shape is common in both
equity and some commodity markets. An intuitive explanation for this pattern is that
investors are generally concerned about market crashes and expect more volatility
when the price is falling than when the price is rising. Another variant on the volatility
smile that is common among commodities is known as a forward skew. This is where
implied volatility is increasing with strike price. The forward skew pattern is common for options on commodities because in many commodity markets, unlike equity
markets, shocks generally lead to upward price trends, making investors more wary
of rising prices than price falls. This drives up demand for in the money calls creating
a premium for these options and leading to an upward skew.
8.4.1.1 WTI Crude Volatility Smiles
The first step in analyzing the volatility smiles is to examine the smiles on different
options in 2007. Is it the case that standard smiles are emerging during early Phase
1 and particularly are there any commodity like features? Before examining the
EUA markets, a sample of WTI volatility smiles is observed as an indication of
typical commodity option behavior.

148

D. Bredin et al.

Volatility Term Structure


4 Quarters 2006

Return Volatility

25%

Dec-Feb
20%

Mar-May
Jun-Aug

15%

Sep-Nov
10%
5%
0%
Spot

Dec-06 Dec-07 Dec-08 Dec-09 Dec-10 Dec-11 Dec-12

Delivery Period
Volatility Term Structure
4 Quarters 2007

Return Volatility

25%

Dec-Feb
20%

Mar-May

15%

Jun-Aug
Sep-Nov

10%
5%
0%
Spot

Dec-07 Dec-08 Dec-09 Dec-10 Dec-11 Dec-12

Delivery Period
Volatility Term Structure
4 Quarters 2008

Return Volatility

25%

Dec-Feb
20%

Mar-May

15%

Jun-Aug
Sep-Nov

10%
5%
0%
Spot

Dec-08

Dec-09

Dec-10

Dec-11

Delivery Period

Fig. 8.4 Term structure of EUA futures volatilityall periods

Dec-12

8 Energy Derivatives Market Dynamics

149

Volatility Term Structure

4 Quarters 2009

25%
Return Volatility

Dec-Feb
20%

Mar-May

15%

Jun-Aug
Sep-Nov

10%
5%
0%
Spot

Dec-09

Dec-10

Dec-11

Dec-12

Delivery Period

Fig. 8.4 continued

Fig. 8.5 Implied volatility smile for WTI options in October 2007

Figure 8.5 displays the implied volatility smiles of WTI options with maturities in
December 2007, 2008, 2009 and 2010 based on data from October 2007. The figure
indicates that the WTI options are exhibiting exactly the type of reverse skew that is
discussed earlier, with higher implied volatilities for low strike options and a smooth
curve across all strikes. This is clearly a mature and liquid market, with options
actively traded across a wide variety of strikes. The smiles on the December 2008,
2009 and 2010 expiring options are all classic volatility smiles. Of note in the Fig. 5.5
is how the smile for the December 2007 option shows some inconsistency with the
other options. This is not an uncommon phenomenon and it is a result of the fact that,
being closer to maturity, this option would be subject to unusual market forces and
price distortions. Another point to consider when observing these WTI options is the
wide range of strikes which are actively traded in the market.

150

D. Bredin et al.

Fig. 8.6 Implied volatility smiles for ECX options in October 2007

8.4.1.2 ECX Volatility Smiles-Phase 1


In order to examine the behavior of EUA options in the first phase of the EU ETS
identical analysis to the above is adopted. Again, four volatility smiles are plotted,
based on data from October 2007 for December options with maturities in four
different years. Given EUA options were only introduced in late 2006, only one
option contract for Phase 1 is observed.
Figure 8.6 displays the average implied volatility smiles for ECX options with
maturities in December 2007, 2008, 2009 and 2010 based on data from October 2007.
Examining the December 2007 contract, it can be seen that the implied volatility is
static and extremely low across all strikes. This does not in any way resemble what
would be considered reasonable option market behavior as discussed above. The
same result is obtained for the September 2007 contract, another Phase 1 expiring
option. At first glance these results appear to be incorrect; however, they are perfectly
consistent with market behavior. By February 2007 the spot market had fallen to
levels well below one Euro, the lowest strike price on the option market however was
one Euro meaning that all calls were out of the money and all puts were in the money.
Given that it was widely realized in 2007 that spot would remain almost worthless
until Phase 2 and the result is the static relationship reported above. Looking at prices
as opposed to implied volatilities it can be seen that by October 2007 all calls and puts
were trading at or very near the present value of their moneyness. The implications
are that given the late introduction of the EUA option, markets had very little chance
to develop in Phase 1 of the EU ETS.
Going on to analyze the behavior of Phase 2 expiry options for a Phase 1
sample of data, very little consistency in the results is evident, although there is

8 Energy Derivatives Market Dynamics

151

Fig. 8.7 Implied volatility smiles for ECX options in October 2010

some mild evidence of volatility smiles in these markets. This is not surprising,
given the early stages of the EUA market and the options market in particular.

8.4.1.3 ECX Volatility Smiles-Phase 2


This section examines the ECX Volatility Smiles in Phase 2 of the EU ETS.
Figure 8.7 displays the average implied volatility smiles for EUA options with
maturities in December 2010, 2011, 2012 and 2013 based on data from October 2010.
There are clear signs that the EUA option market has matured since the start of Phase
2. Across all four contracts there is clear evidence of a volatility smile developing,
resembling that of the WTI market, although not as cleanly curved. The pattern is
very closely replicated across all four maturities, a positive sign indicating stability
and maturity of the market. Interestingly, in contrast to the WTI Crude options, all of
the ECX contracts exhibit a forward skew. While this is clear evidence of the
maturity of the ECX option market, it is worth noting that the range of strikes and
maturities being actively traded is nowhere near as large as the WTI option market.12
Obviously there has been some development in the market between Phase 1 in
2007 and Phase 2 as observed in 2010. There is now a pronounced and consistent
smile clearly visible across all the contracts and the forward skew, although not
echoing the results from the WTI Crude market, is perfectly reasonable for a commodity market. The forward skew results indicate that traders feel that shocks are
more likely to lead to price increases than price falls, which is a further indication of
market development.
12

The thin range of strikes has the implication of displaying the sharp trough on the smile.

152

D. Bredin et al.

Fig. 8.8 WTI implied volatility scatter on the 11th of September 2007

8.4.2 Implied Volatility Scatters


The idea of an implied volatility surface is to expand on the implied volatility smile
adding the extra dimension of time to maturity by including options of differing
maturities. This gives a complete view of the whole market on a particular date, and
allows a view of how the market treats both moneyness and maturity in terms of
pricing. Usually the implied volatility surface will feature a volatility smile or skew
as discussed above coupled with decreasing implied volatilities for longer maturing
options. The reason for the decreasing implied volatility as time to maturity increases
is that short term price shocks could lead to near maturity options rapidly moving in
and out of the money. This is not a major issue for options with a long time to expiry
where there is much more time for the market to correct itself.
Given the immature nature of the EUA market, especially in its early Phases,
and the lack of market depth it is believed that examining a volatility surface
would be misleading and would give the impression of a liquid and complete
market across all maturities and strikes. This analysis uses an implied volatility
scatter rather than a surface in order to analyze these markets.13,14.

8.4.2.1 WTI Volatility Scatter


The first step in this section is to analyze the implied volatility scatter for the WTI
Crude market in September 2007 as a basis for comparison with the EUA results.
13

Building volatility surfaces involves a large amount of interpolation and the surfaces would
primarily consist of prices and implied volatilities that are not available in the market.
14
The equivalent surfaces are reported in the Appendix, Figs. 8.118.14.

8 Energy Derivatives Market Dynamics

153

Fig. 8.9 ECX implied volatility scatter on the 11th of September 2007

Fig. 8.10 ECX implied volatility scatter on the 12th of July 2010

A very consistent surface with no major kinks and with many contracts of
differing maturities all behaving similarly is reported in Figure 8.8. In addition, the
near expiry options have a slightly higher implied volatility for all strikes which is
consistent with the discussion above. This smooth and consistent implied volatility
behavior illustrates the stability, maturity and liquidity of the WTI Crude option
market.

154

D. Bredin et al.

Fig. 8.11 WTI implied volatility scatter on the 4th of January 2011 (Excluding near maturity
options for clarity)

8.4.2.2 ECX Volatility Scatter-Phase 1


Moving now to an examination of the implied volatility scatter of the EUA option
market from September 2007, the Phase 1 sample.
Figure 8.9 indicates how underdeveloped the market was at this early stage,
with only a small number of contracts being actively traded and no clear pattern
emerging. Note that the Phase 1 contracts still have a flat smile while the later
maturing contracts have elements of a smile, but no consistency. One factor that is
consistent with the developed market comparison is the falling implied volatility
for longer maturity options. This result is consistent with the earlier findings that
the spot price collapse of Phase 1 seriously hindered the early development of the
ECX option market.

8.4.2.3 ECX Volatility Scatter-Phase 2


The final step in the analysis is to examine the implied volatility scatter of the ECX
Option market from September 2010, the Phase 2 sample.
Figure 8.10 reports the implied volatility scatter for EUA options in July 2010.
The figure indicates that there are considerably more contracts being traded
leading to a much more consistent looking scatter plot. More importantly it can be
seen that the implied volatility smiles of all the contracts closely resemble one
another.15 While the market is clearly not complete or fully mature, this scatter

15

One interesting fact to note is how the number of strikes actively traded increases as the
maturity of the options increases.

8 Energy Derivatives Market Dynamics

155

Fig. 8.12 WTI implied volatility surface on the 11th of September 2007

Fig. 8.13 ECX implied volatility surface on the 11th of September 2007

does support the finding that the EUA options market has developed since its early
Phase 1 difficulties. Although it is nowhere near the WTI Crude market in terms of
depth or breadth, the EUA market would now appear to be exhibiting mature
option market behavior.

8.5 Conclusion
In this chapter, the dynamics of the EU ETS derivatives markets are examined.
Specifically, the behavior of the ETS futures and options markets using WTI crude

156

D. Bredin et al.

Fig. 8.14 ECX implied volatility surface on the 12th of July 2010

oil futures and options as a benchmark are assessed. The futures market saw
volumes increasing rapidly from the markets inception while volatility fell dramatically in Phase 2. Skewness and kurtosis of returns have also fallen dramatically, while the correlation between spot and futures prices has settled at a high
level in Phase 2, indicating an emerging stability in the market. The term structure
of futures prices is found to indicate contango, while the term structure of futures
volatility is declining and so is consistent with the Samuelson (1965) effect. The
term structures of futures volatility for WTI crude oil also declines. In contrast, the
term structure of futures prices for WTI crude oil exhibits periods of contango and
periods of backwardation. Most studies examining commodities indicate that the
term structure of futures prices tend to exhibit backwardation (Pindyck 2001;
Considine and Larson 2001a, b; Milonas and Henker 2001).
In the options market clear development in the volatility smiles and scatters in
Phase 2 relative to Phase 1 are observed. The Phase 2 analysis shows consistent
smiles and scatters and a persistent forward skew indicating that market participants are more fearful of sudden price increases than price falls. This is contrary to
the findings for the WTI options market which shows a reverse skew. In addition,
the volume of trading for the EUA option market has clearly developed rapidly
over the last three years.
Overall the results are indicative of an increased maturity and stability in the
EU ETS derivatives markets. Both the futures and options markets have developed
significantly since Phase 1. The price and volatility behavior of both markets is
generally consistent with other functioning commodity derivatives markets, such
as the WTI Crude derivatives markets. These findings indicate that the EU has
been successful in its establishment of these ETS derivatives markets despite the
disorder that marred the early stages of both the futures and options markets.

8 Energy Derivatives Market Dynamics

157

References
Alberola, E., Chevallier, J., & Cheze, B. (2009). Emissions compliances and carbon prices under
the EU ETS: A country specific analysis of industrial sectors. Journal of Policy Modelling, 31,
446462.
Benz, E., & Hengelbrock, J. (2008). Liquidity and price discovery in the European CO2 futures
market: An intraday analysis (Working Paper). Bonn: Bonn Graduate School of Business.
Benz, E., & Truck, S. (2009). Modelling the price dynamics of CO2 emissions allowances.
Energy Economics, 1, 415.
Bloch, D. (2010). A note on emissions trading: The pricing of carbon derivatives (Working
Paper). Paris: Universit Paris VI Pierre et Marie Curie.
Bohringer, C., Koschel, H., & Moslener, U. (2008). Efficiency losses from overlapping regulation
of EU carbon emissions. Journal of Regulatory Economics, 33, 299317.
Borak, S., Hardle, W., Truck, S., & Weron, R. (2006). Convenience yields for CO2 emissions
allowance futures contracts (Working Paper). Berlin: Humboldt-University of Berlin.
Bredin, D., Hyde, S., & Muckley, C. (2009). A microstructure analysis of the carbon finance
market. Paper presented at the Finsia/Melbourne Centre for Financial Studies Banking and
Finance Conference, Melbourne, Australia. Retrieved from http://www.melbournecentre.
com.au/Finsia_MCFS/2009/Papers for website/25_Hyde_Carbon_Futures_Trading.pdf.
Bredin, D., & Muckley, C. (2011a). An emerging equilibrium in the EU Emissions Trading
Scheme. Energy Economics, 33, 353362.
Bredin, D., & Muckley, C. (2011b). The price forming process in energy markets. In A. Dorsman,
W. Westerman, M. B. Karan, & . Arslan (Eds.), Financial Aspects in Energy: The European
Perspective (pp. 88107). Berlin: Springer-Verlag.
Bunn, D. W., & Fezzi, C. (2007). Interaction of European carbon trading and energy prices,
(Working Paper 63). Milan: Fondazione Eni Enrico Mattei.
Chestney, N. (2011). EU CO2 market strong in 2010, volume up 7 pctreport, Reuters, [Online 13/
01/2011]. Retrieved from http://in.reuters.com/article/2011/01/13/idINIndia-54143320110113.
Chevallier, J., & Sevi, B. (2009). On the realized volatility of the ECX CO2 emissions 2008
futures contract: Distribution, dynamics and forecasting (Working Paper). Paris: Universit
Paris X Nanterre.
Chevallier, J., Sevi, B., & Le Pen, Y. (2009). Options introduction and volatility in the EU ETS
(Working Paper). GRANEM.
Christiansen, A., Arvanitakis, A., Tangen, K., & Hasselknippe, H. (2005). Price determinants in
the EU emissions trading scheme. Climate Policy, 5, 1530.
Considine, T. J., & Larson, D. F. (2001a). Uncertainty and the convenience yield in crude oil
price backwardations. Energy Economics, 23, 533548.
Considine, T. J., & Larson, D. F. (2001b). Risk premium on inventory assets: The case of crude
oil and natural gas. Journal of Futures Markets, 21, 109126.
Daskalakis, G., Markellos, R. N. (2008). Are the European carbon markets efficient? Review of
Futures Markets, 17(2), 103128.
Daskalakis, G., Psychoyios, D., & Markellos, R. N. (2009). Modelling CO2 emission allowance
prices and derivatives: Evidence from the European trading scheme, Journal of Banking and
Finance, 33, 12301241.
Delarue, E. D., Ellerman, A. D., & Dhaeseleer, H. (2008). Short-term CO2 abatement in the
European power sector (Working Paper No. 08.008). Cambridge, MA: CEEPR, MIT.
Ellerman, A. D., & Feilhauer, S. (2008). A top-down and bottom-up look at the emissions
abatement in Germany in response to the EU ETS (Working Paper No. 08-017), Cambridge,
MA: CEEPR, MIT.
Escobar, M., Hernandes, N., & Seco, L. (2003). Term structure of commodities futures,
forecasting and pricing. Toronto, Canada: RiskLab, University of Toronto. Retrieved from
http://www.risklab.ca/seco/Commodities term structures.pdf.

158

D. Bredin et al.

Fusaro, P. C. (2007, September). Energy and environmental hedge funds, Commodities Now,
11(3), 6163. Retrieved from http://www.commodities-now.com/publications/commoditiesnow/publication/7.html.
Kanen, J. L. M. (2006). Carbon trading and pricing, London. UK: Environmental Finance.
Publications.
Kara, M., Syri, S., Lehtila, A., Helynen, S., Kekkonen, V., Ruska, M., et al. (2008). The impacts
of EU CO2 emission trading on electricity markets and electricity consumers in Finland.
Energy Economics, 30(2), 193211.
Lowrey, C. (2006). A changing environment. FOW Energy, Spring, 2426.
Mansanet-Bataller, M., & Pardo, A. (2008). What you should know about carbon markets.
Energies, 1, 120153.
Mansanet-Bataller, M., Pardo, A., & Valor, E. (2007). CO2 prices, energy and weather. The
Energy Journal, 28, 7392.
Mills, P., (2008). The greening of markets. Finance and Development, 45(1). Washington, DC: IMF.
Milonas, N., & Henker, T. (2001). Price spread and convenience yield behavior in the
international oil market. Applied Financial Economics, 11, 2336.
Newbury, D. (2009). The role of carbon markets in preventing dangerous climate change. House
of Commons: Environmental Audit Committee Publications.
Paolella, M. S., & Taschini, L. (2008). An econometric analysis of emission trading allowances.
Journal of Banking & Finance, 32, 20222032.
Pindyck, R. (2001). The dynamics of commodity spot and futures market: A primer. The Energy
Journal, 22, 129.
Rittler, D. (2011). Price discovery and volatility spillovers in the European Union Emissions
Trading Scheme: A high-frequency analysis. Journal of Banking & Finance, 36, 774785.
Samuelson, P. (1965). Proof that properly anticipated prices fluctuate randomly. Industrial
Management Review, 6, 4149.
Seifert, J., Uhrig-Homburg, M., & Wagner, M. (2008). Dynamic behavior of CO2 spot prices.
Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 56, 180194.
Uhrig-Homburg, M., & Wagner, M. (2009). Futures price dynamics of CO2 emission allowances:
An empirical analysis of the trial period. Journal of Derivatives, 17, 7388.

Chapter 9

The Dynamics of Crude Oil Spot


and Futures Markets
zgr Arslan-Ayaydin and Inna Khagleeva

Abstract This chapter centers on the question of whether futures markets can be
used in the competitive price discovery in crude oil markets. On the one hand, the
survey in this chapter uncovers considerable evidence on the theoretical
perspective that future prices of crude oil is equal to the spot price of crude oil,
plus the cost of carry plus the endogenous convenience yield. On the other hand,
through the empirical findings built on the Alquist and Kilian (2010) model, this
chapter concurs with the previous studies documenting that futures crude oil prices
are uninformative for forecasting spot crude oil prices.
Keywords Crude oil market

 Price discovery

9.1 Introduction
With a consumption level increasing steadily each year and reaching around
85 million barrels per day, crude oil is one of the most important commodities in
the world. Moreover, crude oil consumption represents a significant proportion of
. Arslan-Ayaydin (&)
Department of Finance, University of Illinois at Chicago, University Hall, 601 South
Morgan, Chicago, IL 60607, USA
e-mail: orslan@uic.edu
. Arslan-Ayaydin
Department of Finance, Hacettepe University, University Hall, 601 South Morgan, Chicago,
IL 60607, USA
I. Khagleeva
Department of Information and Decision Sciences, University of Illinois at Chicago,
University Hall, 601 South Morgan, Chicago, IL 60607, USA
e-mail: ikhagl2@uic.edu

A. Dorsman et al. (eds.), Energy Economics and Financial Markets,


DOI: 10.1007/978-3-642-30601-3_9, Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg 2013

159

160

. Arslan-Ayaydin and I. Khagleeva


% Coefficient of Variation
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
1920 -30 1940 -50 1950 -60 1960 -70 1970 -80 1980 -90 1990 -00 2000 -09

Source: Centre for Global Energy Studies (CGES), 2011

Fig. 9.1 Oil price volatility by decades.

the deficits in current accounts of many countries. Furthermore, what happens to


the crude oil industry reverberates across the entire economies of many countries
because macroeconomic forecasts rely on its prospective evolution. Even,
Hamilton (2009) provides evidence that to a certain extent the price of crude oil
can be used for predicting recessions.
Being a very important strategic natural resource, crude oil is also an underlying asset for many financial instruments such as options and futures. Last, but not
least, the health of many businesses such as, airlines and the automobile industries
depends on accurate forecasting of future and spot crude oil prices. From a micro
level, most industries depend directly on forecasts of oil prices in order to
formulate their strategic decisions such as; capital budgeting, pricing or capital
structure. For this reason, understanding the dynamics of crude oil spot and future
markets seems to be crucial so that it would be beneficial to evaluate its influence
in many economies and on other financial assets.
Figure 9.1 depicts the high price volatility in crude oil by decades. The figure
explicitly shows that extreme conditional volatility is mainly experienced in the
last 40 years. These prolonged sharp movements in crude oil prices in either
direction have damaging influences on economies. While sharp increases cause
inflation in energy importing countries, sudden decreases create serious budgetary
problems for energy exporting countries. Because of these facts, the financial
industry has designed a wide variety of derivative instruments to facilitate risk
management in crude oil markets. However, future contracts remain as the most
popular. Moreover, crude oil represents the worlds largest futures market for a
physical commodity.
To predict future spot crude oil prices and hence minimize their risk, policymakers, producers and arbitrageurs refer to futures markets. There is a vast literature
discussing the role of future prices in forecasting crude oil prices, in other words
measuring the market efficiency. Specifically, in efficient markets futures price at

The Dynamics of Crude Oil Spot and Futures Markets

161

time t of a contract maturing at time T is the expected spot price at time T. The
studies by Crowder and Hamed (1993) and Herbert (1993) are the leading works
investigating the properties of the spot and forward prices of commodities in the
long run, through cointegration. Moosa and Al-Loughani (1994) shows that future
prices of crude oil are efficient and unbiased predictors of spot prices. Similarly by
using 1-month, 3-month and 6-month contracts, Gulan (1998) concludes that spot
prices of crude oil can be efficiently predicted by the futures market.
However, these results are not confirmed in some recent findings, such as
(Chinn et al. 2005) and (Chernenko et al. 2004), both of which apply MincerZarnowitz regressions to assess the forecast accuracy of their models, and more
recently by (Huang et al. 2009). Similarly, (Kaufmann and Ullman 2009) find no
direct link between the WTI1 spot market and the New York Mercantile Exchange
(NYMEX) futures market.
This chapter centers on the unreached consensus in the previous literature on
the linkage between future price and spot price of crude oil. The second part of the
chapter questions if the futures prices of crude oil are equal to the spot price plus
the cost of carry (cost of storage and interest rate) plus the endogenous convenience yield. In Sect. 9.2, both theoretical models and empirical findings following
the evidence of Kaldor (1939) are discussed. In Sect. 9.3 the relationship between
future and spot prices of crude oil will be dealt with considering the theoretical
model of Alquist and Kilian (2010). Empirical testing of the results obtained by
(Alquist and Kilian 2010) is provided through extending the sample period of
crude oil prices for contracts having a 1-month horizon (Sect. 9.4). Finally
Sect. 9.5 concludes the chapter.

9.2 The Relationship Between Future and Spot Prices


for Crude Oil
It is widely noted in the literature that there are important differences between
equity and bond futures and commodity futures.2 The studies mostly stress the
role played by the convenience yield for situations where future prices of
commodities are below their spot prices.3 To be more specific, if a financial
asset is not paying any dividend then its future price must be equal to the
sum of its spot price and the cost of carrying it over the life of the futures
contact. If the asset is paying a dividend then it has to be deduced from the
carrying cost. Kaldors model (Kaldor 1939) has the pioneering indication that

West Texas Intermediate (WTI) is a grading system for crude oil to be used as a benchmark in
crude oil pricing and it is the underlying commodity of crude oil futures contracts in the Chicago
Mercantile Exchange.
2
For a detailed discussion on the differences, see (Routledge et al. 2000).
3
See, among others, (Carlson et al. 2007).

162

. Arslan-Ayaydin and I. Khagleeva

the future price of crude oil is equal to the spot price of crude oil plus the
cost of carry (cost of storage and interest rate) plus the endogenous convenience yield.

9.2.1 The Importance of Convenience Yield for the Crude Oil


Market
Brennan (1991) views the convenience yield as a dividend accruing to the
holder of the spot commodity but not to the holder of the futures contract. When
supply of a good is constrained it appears to be more profitable to hold the good
rather than owning a contract or derivative instrument. From this perspective,
convenience yield can be defined as the benefit from holding spot crude oil, which
accrues to the owner of the spot commodity. Put differently, convenience yield is
related with advantage of owning a commodity rather than purchasing it whenever
the commodity is needed. Convenience yields are driven by relative scarcity and
inventory serves as a state variable summarizing the effect of past supply and
demand. When the supply level is high then the convenience yield is expected to
be negative. On the contrary, a sudden drop in future supply and increase in
demand at the same time would yield a positive convenience yield. Coppola
(2007) specifically emphasizes the importance of convenience yield for the crude
oil market, not only due to its being a relatively scarce non-renewable resource,
but also because of the strategic benefit from owning the commodity.
While investigating the relationship between future and spot prices of storable
commodities, Kaldor (1939) and (Working 1949) specifically identified the
convenience yield parameter. Whereas, the mean reversion is detected in spot
prices of crude oil by (Bessembinder et al. 1995), (Casassus and Collin-Dufresne
2005) separate the mean reversion due to a positive relationship between convenience yield and the spot price relationship and covariation of risk premium with
prices and show the former plays a superior role in explaining the mean reversion.4
Additionally, the advantage of convenience yield is also reflected by highlighting
its role in giving the opportunity to exploit short run arbitrage potentials.
The foundation of the theoretical model on the relationship between spot and
future prices, while considering the emphasized role of convenience yield, is
established by the Two Factor Model of Gibson and Schwartz (1990). The
assumption in the model is that the spot price of crude oil (S), its instantaneous
convenience yield (d) and lastly the time to maturity (s)5 determine the price of a
crude oil contingent claim. Moreover it is also assumed that both convenience

It must be noted that, through a reduced-form model, Casassus and Collin-Dufresne (2005)
show that when the spot price is high, the convenience yield is high as well and hence pushes the
spot price back toward a long-term mean. However this conclusion is derived under the
assumption of risk neutrality.
5
s = T-t.

The Dynamics of Crude Oil Spot and Futures Markets

163

yield and spot price of oil follow a joint diffusion process and the spot price of
crude oil has a lognormal stationary distribution such as the following;
dS
ldt r1 dz1 ;
S

9:1

dd ka  ddt r2 dz2

9:2

In the above expression, dz1  dz2 qdt in which q is the correlation coefficient
between these two Brownian motions, namely dz1 and dz2.
The above expression centers on the mean reversion pattern. With the further
assumption that the price of oil contingent claim B(S, d, s) is a two-times
continuously differentiable function of S and d. In order to identify the instant price
change, Gibson and Schwartz (1990) use Its Lemma to give:
dB BS dS Bd dd  Bs ds 0:5BSS dS2 0:5Bdd dd2 BSd dSdd;


dB Bs  0:5BSS r21 S2 BSd Sqr1 r2 0:5Bdd r22 BS lS Bd ka  ddt
r1 SBS dz1 r2 Bd dz2
9:3
With the elimination of market imperfections and uncertainty of interest rates
the price of this claim must satisfy the partial differential equation:
0:5BSS S2 r21 0:5Bdd r22 BSd Sqr1 r2 BS Sr  d
Bd ka  d  kr2   Bs  rB 0

9:4

In the above expression, market price per unit of convenience yield risk is
denoted as k. Given that in perfect market conditions there is no arbitrage possibility, the price of a futures contact F(S, d, s) on one barrel of crude oil deliverable
at time T will satisfy the partial differential equation:
0:5FSS S2 r21 0:5Fdd r22 FSd Sqr1 r2 FS Sr  d
Fd ka  d  kr2   Fs 0

9:5

Therefore the equation indicated above will be subject to the initial condition:
F S; d; 0 S

9:6

However, from the perspective of convenience yield, the reason that the linear
relationship between future and spot prices for crude oil may not hold is pointed
out by Williams and Wright (1991). These authors provide evidence that contrary
to the general view, inventories might be held profitably even without the existence of convenience yield when the future prices are not high enough, compared
to the relative prices to justify the average holding costs. However the loss
incurred by holding costs are likely to be compensated by time differences in
desired quality of crude oil or expected future increases in transport and storage
costs, which are positive capital gains.

164

. Arslan-Ayaydin and I. Khagleeva

The other component explaining the relationship between future and spot prices
is the cost of carry, which is the cost associated with holding the commodity until
the delivery date. Such costs include; the opportunity cost of holding the crude oil,
the cost of funding, the cost of storing the crude oil in a tank, and the cost of
insuring the commodity while held. The general definition of the cost of carry is it
is equal to the cost of financing a commodity plus the storage cost minus income
earned on the commodity. Bekiros and Dicks (2007) highlight the role played by
the cost of carry with the following relationship that indicates the relationship
between spot prices and future prices.
F SecyT

9:7

In the above equation cost of carry and convenience yield are represented by
c and y respectively. While T is the time to maturity, and e is Eulers number.
According to this equation, because convenience yield and cost of carry is
constant, an increase in spot prices must in turn increase future prices. Otherwise
arbitrage takes place and hence equilibrium is restored eventually between spot
and future prices.
Finally, in the light of the Kaldor model, Caporale et al. (2010) study future
contracts with different maturities between 1990 and 2008. As shown by Fig. 9.2,
the null of no contribution is strongly rejected for the futures market, which
represents the dominant market in terms of price discovery, with the spot market
acting as a satellite trading venue in the terminology of Hasbrouck (1995). For this
reason, the authors provide evidence on the linkage between future and forward
contracts. However, they document that the price discovery decreases considerably
as the maturity of the futures contract increases.

9.2.2 Contrary Evidences on Predictive Power of Future


Crude Oil Prices for Spot Prices of Oil
Under the financial market efficiency hypothesis, future prices are optimal forecaster of spot prices. This hypothesis requires that the average forecasting error is
zero and there are no profitable arbitrage opportunities. On the contrary, Pindyck
(1993) establishes that, under the assumption of risk-averse market participants,
futures prices are systematically biased. Altogether, despite the theoretical
evidence provided by the Two Factor Model, a consensus has not been reached for
the forecasting performance of futures prices. The results of Bopp and Lady
(1991), Abosedraa and Baghestani (2004) and Chinn et al. (2005) are at odds by
suggesting that using futures prices to forecast crude oil prices is not as effective as
it is suggested by the Two Factor Model.
Alquist and Kilian (2010) explicitly show that future crude oil prices do not
outperform a random walk forecast. They study the period of January 1991
through February 2007 by using daily spot and futures prices for crude oil. Their

The Dynamics of Crude Oil Spot and Futures Markets

165

Fig. 9.2 Time-varying price discovery measures. Source (Caporale et al. 2010). Notes Panel A
reports the time-varying spot markets contribution to price discovery (on the left) and the
associated p-value for the test of the null of no contribution of that market to price discovery (on
the right). Panel B reports the time-varying 1-month future markets contribution to price
discovery (on the left) and the associated p-value for the test of the null of no contribution of that
market to price discovery. The dashed line indicates the 10 % level threshold. The horizontal axis
reports daily observations from 2 January 1990 to 31 December 2008, for a total of 4,758 datapoints: observations #1,000, #2,000, #3,000, #4,000 correspond roughly to the end of December
1993, 1997, 2001 and 2005, respectively

results show that a no change model for prices of crude oil, which uses the current
price at time t to forecast for a particular horizon, outperforms a futures-based
model. Alquist and Kilian (2010) base their result on the variability between crude
oil futures prices and spot prices, which is caused by marginal convenience yield.

9.3 Empirical Evidence on the Predictive Power of Future


Prices for Spot Price of Oil
In order to ensure complete understanding of this phenomenon, in this section
empirical evidence is provided on the finding of Alquist and Kilians (2010) model
by conducting an analysis of current market data. Put differently, Alquist and
Kilian (2010) evaluate the forecast ability of future prices by using monthly oil
future prices. Given that their data ends at February 2007, their evaluation is
updated by extending the analysis until December 2011. Alquist and Kilian (2010)
analyze the predictability for the varied time horizons of one, three, six, nine and
twelve months. However, here, forecasting models are considered for only the
horizon of one month because, as pointed out by Caporale et al. (2010), the linkage

166

. Arslan-Ayaydin and I. Khagleeva

Fig. 9.3 Volatility of crude oil price. Note Volatility is estimated using exponentially weighted
moving average smoothing with the daily decay rate of d = 0.005. An exponentially weighted
2
^2t drt1
^t is the
moving average estimator ofvariance
is defined as; r
1  d^
r2t1 , where r


volatility at day t; rt1 log

st1
st2

is the logarithmic return from the close of the day t-2 to the

close of the day t-1

between the spot and future crude oil market decreases as maturity becomes
longer.
As also emphasized by Ates and Huang (2011), especially after the year 2007,
crude oil prices exhibit high volatility, with monthly price in USD per barrel
increasing from $53.40 in January 2007 to $132.55 in July 2008, yet plummeting
to $41.76 in February 2009. Specifically, Fig. 9.3 plots the exponentially weighted
moving average (EWMA) of the volatility of the daily spot prices of crude oil.
Moreover, Fig. 9.4 displays the spread between spot and future prices of crude oil.
The sample period in both figures is between December 1986 and January 2010.
Both the high increase in volatility of spot prices after the year 2007 shown in
Fig. 9.3 and the escalation of the spread which becomes more emphasized after
2007, underline the importance of incorporating the recent data set into the
analyses.
All datasets are obtained from the webpage of the Energy Information
Administration (EIA) and the WTI price of crude oil available for delivery at
Cushing, OK6 is used. In the analysis, the beginning of the time series is when
crude oil futures were first traded on the NYMEX, namely 1 January 1986. The
data ends on 21 December, 2011, totaling 312 months.
As for the future prices, the price associated with a one-month futures contract
is determined as the value at the end of the month, which is the price at which the
contract was traded closest to the last trading day of the month. This way there is
the ability to match, as closely as possible, future prices with spot prices at the end
of the month. For crude oil, each contract expires on the third business day prior to
the 25th calendar day of the month preceding the delivery month. If the 25th
calendar day of the month is a non-business day, trading ceases on the third
business day prior to the business day preceding the 25th calendar day. After a

It is pointed out by Alquist et al. (2011) that it is possible to obtain qualitatively similar results
by using Brent spot and future prices. Vansteenkiste (2011) also indicates that modeling based on
prices of WTI and those of Brent should not substantially affect the analysis although these two
prices do not fluctuate in line with one another over time.

The Dynamics of Crude Oil Spot and Futures Markets

167

Fig. 9.4 Spread between spot and futures prices of crude oil, $ per barrel

contract expires, Contract 1 for the remainder of that calendar month is the second
following month.
Here the Alquist and Kilian (2010) estimation is extended and updated by the
h
most current data set through a forecast horizon of one month. In the models, Ft
is denoted as the current (at time t) nominal price of the futures contract maturing
in h periods. The current nominal price of oil is St and the expected future spot
price at date t ? h, conditional on information available at t, is Et Sth .
The random walk model, which implies that changes in spot price are unpredictable, establishes the benchmark for forecasts based on future prices. Therefore,
according to Model 1, as specified below, only the current spot price of crude oil is
the best forecast of its spot price.
^
Sthjt St

h 1 month

Model 1

However, according to Model 2, future oil prices are best predicted by oil
futures prices.
h
^
Sthjt Ft

h 1 month

Model 2

According to the Model 3, the spot price of oil can be forecasted through the
spread between the sport price and futures price given that this spread indicates the
probability of the direction of the price of oil. The spread is expected to be an
indicator of the expected change in the spot price if the futures price becomes
h
equal to the expected spot price. This can be obtained .by dividing Ft
h

Et Sth  by St and then the result becomes Et Sth =St Ft

St . Henceforth, the

following alternative models by Alquist et al. (2011) are analyzed in order to


investigate the forecasting accuracy of the spread.
h

. i
h
^
St
h 1 month Model 3
Sthjt St 1 ln Ft
Model 3 provides the simplest form of equilibrium. However when the
assumption of zero intercept is relaxed, as in the Model 4, the likelihood of spread
to be a biased predictor will be allowed.
h

. i
h
^
a ln Ft
St
h 1 month Model 4
Sthjt St 1 ^

168

. Arslan-Ayaydin and I. Khagleeva

However, in Model 5, the proportionality restriction is relaxed.


h

. i
^ Fth St
^
Sthjt St 1 bln
h 1 month Model 5
When not only the unbiasedness but also proportionality restrictions are relaxed
Model 6 is obtained.
h

. i
^ Fth St
^
Sthjt St 1 ^
a bln
h 1 month Model 6
^ represent least squares estimates that are
^ and b
In Models 4, 5 and 6, both a
obtained in real time from recursive regressions. The predictive accuracy of
Models 1 to 6 with horizons of 1 month are compared. The benchmark is a random
walk without drift.

9.4 Results
Which of the forecasting model is the most accurate may depend on the loss
function of the forecaster.7 The predictive performance of the models is evaluated
by using two approaches. The first approach compares forecasting ability of a
candidate model
 to that of the
.random walk without drift model using a percent
b
error, Pthjt Sth  S thjt Sth , as a loss function where ^Sthjt is the h-stepahead-forecast. For an overall accuracy measure, the Root Mean Squared Percent
Error (RMSPE) is computed,
v
u T
u1 X
p2th;t
RMSPE t
T

t1

Furthermore, the DM test of Diebold and Mariano (1995) is used in order to


evaluate the hypothesis that the difference, in terms of expected losses, between
forecasts of the benchmark model and each of the six Models is zero against the
alternative that each Model is better. The second approach is based on Pesaran and
Timmermanns success ratio statistic (1992), which determines the relative
frequency with which a forecasting model correctly predicts the sign of the change
in spot price. The null hypothesis for this statistic assumes no association between
realized and forecast direction of changes in spot prices.
Table 9.1, shows the results obtained for 1-month ahead forecast (h = 1) error
diagnostics for WTI prices of crude oil. In the table, p-values are shown in
parentheses. The first set of results is on the oil futures prices as predictors of oil
spot prices. The first two rows of the table document that, at the 1-month

For details see Elliott and Timmermann (2008) and Alquist et al. (2011).

The Dynamics of Crude Oil Spot and Futures Markets

169

Table 9.1 1-Month-ahead recursive forecast error diagnostics


RMSPE
Model
S^thjt
1
2

St
1

Ft

Success ratio

9.03
0.998

n.a.
0.435

h

. i
1
St 1 ln Ft
St

(0.499)
0.998

(0.989)
0.435

h

. i
1
St 1 ^
St
a ln Ft

(0.499)
1.488

(0.989)
0.500

(0.506)
1.413

(0.714)
0.493

(0.504)
1.359

(0.544)
0.497

(0.505)

(0.516)

5
6


. i
^ Ft1 St
St 1 ^
a bln

. i
^ Ft1 St
St 1 ^
a bln

Notes All Root Mean Squared Percent Error (RMSPE) results are presented as ratios relative to
the benchmark no-change forecast model, for which the actual RMSPE is reported. i.e., Model 1
has RSMPE equal to 9.03 % and Model 2 has RMSPE equal to 0.998 9 9.03 % & 9.01 %. pvalues are reported in parentheses below the respective statistic. The forecast evaluation period is
January 1986December 2011. The initial estimation window for recursive regressions of Models
4 to 6 is January 1986December 1986. All p-values in the RSMPE column refer to pairwise tests
of the null of equal predictive accuracy with the no-change benchmark model and are based on
the DM-test of Diebold and Mariano (1995) using N(0,1) critical values. The success ratio
statistics of Pesaran and Timmermann (1992) in the last column are defined as the fraction of
forecasts that correctly predict the sign of the change in the price of oil. The null hypothesis for
this statistic assumes no association between realized and forecasted direction of changes in spot
prices. This test cannot be applied when there is no variability in the predicted sign. In such a case
the statistic is reported as n.a

specification, Models 2 and 3 are slightly better than the benchmark Model 1 given
that their RMSPE is 0.998 of that of Model 1. However, these tiny improvements
are not statistically significant.
Consequently, it cannot be concluded that a random walk forecast is more
biased than the futures forecast. Moreover, for all models the success ratio is not
statistically significant. The results for the extended and updated period coincide
with those of Alquist and Kilian (2010) since it is found that accuracy of prediction
by futures prices on crude oil is not statistically significantly higher than the simple
no change forecasts.
The second set of results presented in Rows 3 to 6, report on the oil future
spreads as predictors of future spot prices. Here, an alternative analysis is
conducted by using recursively estimated spread regressions to generate forecasts
of oil price. Again, the results show that there is no systematic difference between
the RMSPE of the random walk forecast and that of the spread-based forecasts.
Furthermore, it is observed that when based on the RMSPE, Models 4 to 6 are
actually worse than Models 1 to 3. The p values of both the RMSPE and the

170

. Arslan-Ayaydin and I. Khagleeva



Fig. 9.5 Percent errors of forecasts. Notes Percent error = 100 Sth  ^
Sthjt Sth , where ^
Sthjt
is the h-step-ahead-forecast. Here, h = 1 month

success ratio are not statistically significant and hence there is no statistically
significant gain in predicting performance of the spread models either.
Altogether, the findings with the updated sample period are broadly consistent
with the empirical results in Alquist and Kilian (2010), in that no evidence is
obtained to indicate that future crude oil prices are more accurate predictors of the
nominal price of crude oil than simple no-change forecasts. Therefore, it is
concluded that in practice, the price of crude oil futures is not the most accurate
predictor of the spot price of crude oil.
To be more specific, Fig. 9.5 shows the time series of percent errors for Models 1
(benchmark), 3 and 5. These three models are representative of others as they are
similar in their predictive performance. The Figure supports the main message of
Table 9.1 in the sense that, visually, none of the models has lower percent errors
than the benchmark model. In addition, this plot gives a historical performance of
forecasts by depicting that the predictive power of all models worsens at times of
high levels of price instability in markets. For example, during the first Gulf War in
the early 1990s, the percent errors of all models rise and exceed almost 50 %

The Dynamics of Crude Oil Spot and Futures Markets

171

particularly in Model 5. Even larger forecast biases occur during the 20072008
financial crisis, when all models systematically fail to predict the plunge in oil prices
and show errors as large as 100 %particularly Model 5.

9.5 Conclusions
The behavior of crude oil prices in the last several decades has attracted wide
attention and created a debate on the predictability of prices. Armed with the
strategic importance of crude oil as a commodity, this chapter centers on the
questions of whether futures markets can be used in the competitive price
discovery in crude oil markets. Sadly, previous studies provide contrasting views
on the unbiasedness of future prices in predicting the spot prices in crude oil
markets.
On the one hand, the survey in this chapter uncovers considerable evidence on
the finding that future prices of crude oil are equal to the spot price of crude oil
plus the cost of carry plus endogenous convenience yield. On the other hand,
through a detailed explanation of the Alquist and Kilian (2010) model, this chapter
also concurs with previous studies documenting that, even with the possibility of
arbitrage, future crude oil prices do not have any predictive power for spot prices.
To clarify this issue from a practical perspective, empirical results on the
relationship between future and spot future prices of crude oil are provided by first
treating the current level of futures prices as the predictor and next by basing the
analysis on the spread. Using an extended and thus updated sample set, the results
reconcile with those of (Alquist and Kilian 2010), who document large and timevarying deviations of crude oil futures prices from the spot price of oil, as
measured by the futures spread. In parallel to this, no reliable evidence is found to
show that oil futures prices significantly lower the RMSPE relative to the
no-change forecast.
Overall this chapter provides an illustration of the forgoing conflicting
discussions on the price dynamics in the crude oil market. By showing theoretical
arguments on this issue and providing the empirical evidence based on current
market data, the chapter points out that futures should be used with caution in
predicting spot crude oil prices.

References
Abosedraa, S., & Baghestani, H. (2004). On the predictive accuracy of crude oil futures prices.
Energy Policy, 32, 13891393.
Alquist, R., & Kilian, L. (2010). What do we learn from the price of crude oil futures? Journal of
Applied Econometrics, 25, 539573.
Alquist, R., Kilian, L., & Vigfusson, R. J. (2011). Forecasting the price of oil. International
finance discussion papers 1022, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System (U.S)

172

. Arslan-Ayaydin and I. Khagleeva

Ates, A., & Huang, S. C. (2011). The evolving relationship between crude oil and natural gas prices:
Evidence from a dynamic cointegration analysis. Pennsylvania Economic Review, 18(1), 19.
Bekiros, S. D., & Dicks, C. G. H. (2007). The relationship between crude oil spot and future
prices: Cointegration, linear and nonlinear causality (CeNDEF Working Papers, 0711).
Amsterdam: University of Amsterdam.
Bessembinder, H., Coughenour, P., & Smeller, M. (1995). Mean reversion in equilibrium asset
prices: Evidence from the futures term structure. Journal of Finance, 50, 361375.
Bopp, A. E., & Lady, G. M. (1991). A comparison of petroleum futures versus spot prices as
predictors of prices in the future. Energy Economics, 13(4), 274282.
Brennan, M. J. (1991). The price of convenience and the valuation of commodity contingent
claims. In D. Lund & B. ksendal (Eds.), Stochastic models and option values (pp. 3371).
Amsterdam: Elsevier.
Caporale, G., Ciferri, D., & Girardi, A. (2010). Time-varying spot and futures oil price dynamics
(Working Paper), Uxbridge, United Kingdom: Center for Empirical Finance, Brunel
University.
Carlson, M., Khokher, Z., & Titman, S. (2007). Equilibrium exhaustible resource price dynamics.
Journal of Finance, 62, 16631703.
Casassus, J., & Collin-Dufresne, P. (2005). Stochastic convenience yield implied from
commodity futures and interest rates. Journal of Finance, 60, 22832331.
CGES (2011). http://www.cges.co.uk/
Chernenko, S.V., Schwarz, K. B., & Wright, J. (2004). The information content of forward and
futures prices: market expectation and the price of risk. (International Finance Discussion
Paper No: 808). Washington, DC: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.
Chinn, M. D., LeBlanc, M., & Coibion, O. (2005). The predictive content of energy futures: An
update on petroleum, natural gas, heating oil and gasoline. (Working Paper 11033).
Washington, DC: NBER.
Coppola, A. (2007). Forecasting oil price movements: Exploiting the information in the futures
market. Journal of Futures Markets, 28(1), 3456.
Crowder, W., & Hamed, A. (1993). A cointegration test for oil futures market efficiency. Journal
of Futures Markets, 13(8), 933941.
Diebold, F. X., & Mariano, R. S. (1995). Comparing predictive accuracy. Journal of Business and
Economic Statistics, 13, 253263.
Elliott, G., & Timmermann, A. (2008). Economic forecasting. Journal of Economic Literature,
46, 356.
Gibson, J., & Schwartz, E. (1990). Stochastic convenience yield and the pricing of oil contingent
claims. Journal of Finance, 45, 959976.
Gulan, G. (1998). Efficiency in the crude oil futures market. Journal of Energy, Finance and
Development, 3(1), 1321.
Hamilton, J. D. (2009). Causes and consequences of the oil shock of 200708. Brookings Papers
on Economic Activity, 1, 215261.
Hasbrouck, J. (1995). One security, many markets: Determining the contributions to price
discovery. Journal of Finance, 50, 11751199.
Herbert, J. H. (1993). The relation of monthly spot to futures prices for natural gas. Energy, 18,
11191124.
Huang, B.-N., Yang, M. J., & Hwang, C. W. (2009). The dynamics of a nonlinear relationship
between crude oil spot and futures prices: A multivariate threshold regression approach.
Energy Economics, 31(1), 9198.
Kaldor, N. (1939). Speculation and economic stability. Review of Economic Studies, 7, 127.
Kaufmann, R. K., & Ullman, B. (2009). Oil prices, speculation, and fundamentals: Interpreting
causal relations among spot and futures prices. Energy Economics, 31, 550558.
Moosa, I. A., & Al-Loughani, N. E. (1994). Unbiasedness and time varying risk premia in crude
oil futures markets. Energy Journal, 16(2), 99105.
Pesaran, M. H., & Timmermann, A. (1992). A simple nonparametric test of predictive
performance. Journal of Business and Economic Statistics, 10, 461465.

The Dynamics of Crude Oil Spot and Futures Markets

173

Pindyck, R. S. (1993). The present value model of rational commodity pricing. Economic
Journal, 103, 501530.
Routledge, B., Seppi, D., & Spatt, C. (2000). Equilibrium forward curves for commodities.
Journal of Finance, 55, 12971338.
Vansteenkiste, I. (2011). What is driving oil futures prices? Fundamentals versus speculation
(Working Paper, No. 1371). Frankfurt, Germany: European Central Bank.
Williams, J., & Wright, B. (1991). Storage and commodity markets. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press.
Working, H. (1949). The theory of price of storage. American Economic Review, 39, 12541262.

Chapter 10

Natural Gas Market Liberalization:


An Examination of UK and US Futures
and Spot Prices
John L. Simpson

Abstract The study reported in this chapter builds on previous studies of the
extent of decoupling of oil and gas markets and thus the degree of deregulation of
the gas sector in each country. It examines both UK and US oil and gas spot and
futures market data. Spot gas and gas futures data from the respective domestic
markets represent domestic factors and oil prices from global datasets represent
global factors. Cointegration and exogeneity tests indicate that US markets have
achieved a greater degree of decoupling with domestic gas price factors dominating global oil price factors in the determination of the future spot gas price.
Therefore, it can be concluded that whilst progress in liberalization has been made
in both markets, US deregulation policies have been more effective than those in
the UK.

Keywords Gas Oil Pricing


Decoupling Deregulation

 Futures  Spot  Cointegration  Causality 

10.1 Introduction
The theory of market liberalization implies that oil and gas prices should decouple
as deregulation of natural gas markets progresses. This chapter increases the scope
of past studies (e.g., the study for the UK by Panagiotidis and Rutledge 2007), by
making a comparison of the US and the UK markets and by examining both spot

J. L. Simpson (&)
School of Economics and Finance, Curtin Business School,
Curtin University, GPO Box U1987 Perth, WA 6845, Australia
e-mail: john.simpson@cbs.curtin.edu.au

A. Dorsman et al. (eds.), Energy Economics and Financial Markets,


DOI: 10.1007/978-3-642-30601-3_10, Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg 2013

175

176

J. L. Simpson

and future oil and gas market variables. Findings depend on whether the data is
lagged or unlagged; level series prices, changes in prices or returns; spot prices or
futures prices or a combination thereof. The study reported in this chapter
examines these combinations of techniques and variables in order to seek clarity in
the relationships.
The central research issues covered (and to be expanded in Sect. 10.3) are
whether or not US and UK gas markets have decoupled, or what is the degree of
decoupling, as an indication of whether or not deregulation policies are working
and therefore whether or not domestic factors dominate global factors in the
deregulation process. The results of the study reported in this chapter demonstrate
that, in any similar investigation in the future, it is deemed important to control for
global factors (in oil price futures) and domestic factors (in gas price futures
markets, as the embodiment of the influence of country specific economic forecasts, and seasonality and storage). Following this introduction (Sect. 10.1) the
chapter is planned to cover a background of theory and literature (Sect. 10.2) and
issues to be tested, a specification of the models and a description of the methodology (Sect. 10.3), a description of the data (Sect. 10.4), a report on the findings
(Sects. 10.5 and 10.6) and a conclusion (Sect. 10.7).

10.2 Background
Liberalization of gas markets implies the removal of the nexus between oil and gas
prices. Macro- and micro-economic reforms encourage gas on gas competition.
Gas and oil prices decouple and welfare advantages accrue to consumers as gas
prices fall. The Law of One Price should apply (as revisited by Asche 2000), where
prices of homogenous goods from different producers and suppliers move together.
Price differentials only indicate differences in transportation costs and quality in
that product. This implies that there should be no connection between oil and gas
prices. The strict assumption for the operation of this law is that the goods are:
global commodities; do not change their nature; that prices are determined by the
free flow of supply and demand; and that the markets are informationally efficient
so that the prices reflect all available information.
This is not the case in reality because of the differences in strength and structure
of oil and gas markets, but for the sake of analysis, this paper will assume that the
commodities oil and gas are global commodities, but that oil markets, being the
dominant source of power globally, are more global in their behavior than gas
markets and that gas markets remain more influenced by domestic factors, such as
seasonality and storage in the countries studied.
Of course, the influence of governments in the countries studied is greater on
the gas markets than on the oil market. It may be that in order to avoid price setting
by governments in gas markets that the prices of gas contracts are linked to oil
prices. It may also be that gas and oil, both being used for power and heating
would imply a natural nexus (assuming that heating equipment and power

10

Natural Gas Market Liberalization

177

machinery is readily exchangeable for both oil and gas). In that case the decoupling of the gas and oil markets could be caused by a change, for example, in the
price of gas. These are separate issues that could be addressed in future studies.
The fact remains that the liberalization of gas markets means that such linkages,
for any reason, will need to disappear.
Forward markets in any commodity, should reflect market expectations, which
are impacted by domestic economic forecasts as well as seasonality and storage
influences. In the context of a comparison of US and UK gas markets, the central
issue of concern in this chapter is whether or not oil and gas markets have
decoupled and thus whether or not global factors (embodied in spot and futures oil
prices) or domestic factors (embodied in gas futures markets) dominate.
The US and the UK are two important Western economies that have undertaken
positive steps to deregulate their markets. The US gas market is around six times
larger than the UK market in terms of volumes consumed. Deregulation of gas
markets in the US began in 1984 with a separation of natural gas supply from
interstate pipeline transportation, deregulated natural gas production and the
wholesale market, and competition was introduced in interstate pipeline transportation. In the UK in 1986, the British government privatized British Gas and
further reforms required the unbundling of supply and transportation and the
releasing of some gas supplies to competitors. However, this chapter does not go
into an in-depth analysis of the specifics of deregulation policies.
The connection between natural gas and oil markets, the degree of integration
and the corresponding volatility and similarity in volatility of these markets, has
been extensively studied. For example, Krichene (2002), in a supply and demand
model examined world markets for crude oil and natural gas and finds that both
markets became highly volatile following the oil shock of 1973. Ewing et al.
(2002) look at time varying volatility in oil and gas markets across markets and
find that common patterns of volatility emerge that might be of interest to financial
market participants.
Adeleman and Watkins (2005) find a degree of stochastic similarity of movement in oil and gas reserve prices for the period 19822003 in the US using market
transaction data. A study by Regnier (2007) of crude oil, petroleum, and gas prices
over a period from 1945 to 2005 finds that these prices are more volatile than
prices for 95 % of products sold by domestic producers with oil prices showing
greater volatility since the 1973 oil crisis.
In relation to the direct real world connection between oil and gas prices, a
party-to-party gas price bargaining model is expounded and partly proven by
Okogu (2002). Other more recent work, for example, Burger et al. (2008), finds
that long-term gas contracts in Japan and South Korea are linked to crude oil prices
and discuss price formulae using oil indexation for European gas markets. The
Okogu model, for example, posits that one of the principles of gas pricing is to
relate the price of gas to its value in the market for oil as the major competing fuel.
The implication of such a model is that market power by State or privately owned
monopolies can extract rent from consumers of gas when oil is the only other
source of energy.

178

J. L. Simpson

Eng (2006), in debating the price that New Zealand should pay for its natural
gas imports from Australia, alluded to the differences in the Japanese and Chinese
pricing models for Australian natural gas. Both pricing models show the accepted
relationship between oil and gas prices, based on data from such sources as the
AsiaPacific Energy Research Centre and the Institute of Energy Economics of
Japan. Again these export pricing models imply a strong connection between oil
and gas prices.
The evidence on decoupling of oil and gas markets is mixed. Serlitis and
Rangel-Ruiz (2004) explore common features in North American energy markets
in shared trends and cycles between oil and gas markets. The study examined
Henry Hub Gas prices and crude oil prices and finds decoupling of oil and gas
prices as a result of deregulation in the US. Silverstovs et al. (2005) investigate the
degree of integration of natural gas markets in Europe, North America and Japan
in the period early 1990s2004 using a principal components and a cointegration
approach where oil and gas markets interacted. They find high levels of gas market
integration within Europe, between Europe and Japan as well as within the North
American market.
Mazighi (2005) noted that the UKs National Balancing Point (NBP) gas price
was significantly related to oil prices. There is also evidence of a statistically
significant relationship between oil and gas prices and industrial stock prices.
Using regression analysis to test the long-term behavior of the UK BP gas prices
he also finds a relationship between the changes in the volume of manufactured
production. As oil is used as a source of industrial power it follows that there is a
relationship between industrial stock prices as well as alternative energy prices.
Mazighi (2005) finds that more than 80 % of gas price changes in the US market
were not driven by their fundamental values. Other factors such as oil price
changes need to be considered to account for gas price changes. However, Mazighi
(2005) suggests that, in the long term and in accordance with economic theory, the
evolution of prices of natural gas and any other homogenous commodity is guided
by its supply and demand.
Asche (2006) also examines whether or not decoupling of natural gas prices
from prices of other energy commodities (such as oil and electricity) had taken
place in the liberalized UK and in the regulated continental gas markets after the
Interconnector had integrated these markets after 1998. Asche finds that monthly
price data from 1995 to 1998 indicated a highly integrated market where wholesale
demand appeared to be for energy generally, rather than specifically for oil or gas.
By 2003 the UK gas market was highly liberalized, according to Panagiotidis and
Rutledge (2007), who investigated the relationship between UK wholesale gas
prices and Brent oil prices over the period 19962003 to test whether or not orthodox
liberalization theory applied and whether or not oil and gas prices had decoupled.
Using cointegration techniques and tests of exogeneity of oil prices through impulse
response functions, their findings generally do not support the assumption of
decoupling of prices in the relatively highly liberalized UK market. The results may
at least have indicated that progress in deregulation had been made.

10

Natural Gas Market Liberalization

179

Studies of the connection between oil and gas markets have suffered because of
the use of spot prices only, when a growing body of evidence impresses the need to
take into account gas price expectations embodied in futures prices and thus prices
that capture forecasts of macro-economic data, as well as seasonality and storage
factors. In doing so these studies also demonstrate whether global factors (that is,
oil prices and oil futures prices) or domestic factors dominate (that is, gas futures
prices).
For example, one of the early studies to examine the relationship of monthly
spot to futures prices for natural gas in the US is Herbert (1993). According to this
study, accurate forecasts of spot gas prices could be obtained by regressing the
spot price for a delivery month on the futures contract price for the same month.
Whilst the general conclusion is that the gas market was inefficient, it is clear that
deregulation in US gas markets is having an effect with gas price expectations thus
strongly affecting gas prices.
A later joint study by Herbert and Kreil (1996) finds inefficiency in US gas
markets, which was addressed in part by the establishment of a second futures
market. They note that there is an active unregulated derivatives market in which
options and swaps are traded. Herbert and Kreil feel that the market changes
enable better responses to changes in market conditions, but that there are still
concerns relating to the allocation of pipeline space. Prices for gas and transport
are not transparent and some industry practices impede further progress in liberalization. They acknowledge however, that the US market is large and diverse and
that the regulatory authorities are at least trying to craft rules to improve business
behavior and performance.
Root and Lien (2003) use hedge ratios (which determine the effectiveness of a
hedge) and examine the relationship between futures and spot prices. Model
specification is important and the study investigates the appropriateness of using a
threshold cointegrated model of the natural gas markets as the basis for hedging
and forecasting. They conclude that whilst the threshold model is appropriate for
longer-term futures contracts it does not offer much improvement in hedging or
forecasting efficiency. Modjtahedi and Movassagh (2005) find spot and futures gas
prices are non-stationary with trends due to positive drifts in the random walk
components of the prices. They find that market forecast errors are stationary and
that futures prices are less than expected future spot prices (implying futures prices
are backward dated). They also find that the bias in futures prices is time varying
and that futures have statistically significant market timing ability.
Wong-Parodi et al. (2006) compare the accuracy of forecasts for natural gas
prices as reported by the Energy Information Administrations short-term energy
outlook (STEO) and the futures market for the period 19982004. They find that
on average the Henry Hub is a better predictor of natural gas prices than the STEO.
Economic modelers are also advised to compare the accuracy of their models to
the futures market. Other studies have examined the influence of seasonality and
storage factors.
Mu (2007) examined how weather shocks impact asset price dynamics in the
US natural gas futures market revealing a significant weather effect on the

180

J. L. Simpson

conditional mean and volatility of gas futures returns. Marzo and Zagaglia (2007)
modeled the joint movements of daily returns on one month futures for crude oil
and natural gas using a multivariate GARCH1 with dynamic conditional correlations and elliptical distributions. They find that the conditional correlation between
the futures prices of natural gas and crude oil had risen over the preceding 5 years,
but the correlation was low on average over most of the sample suggesting that
futures markets do not have an established history of pricing natural gas as a
function of oil market developments. Geman and Ohana (2009) remind their
readers that it is central in the theory of storage, that there is a role for inventory in
explaining the shape of the forward curve and spot price volatility in commodity
markets. They find that the negative relationship between price volatility and
inventory is globally significant for crude oil and the negative correlation applies
only during periods of scarcity and increases for natural gas during winter months.
The present study thus compares price and price change relationships in each of
the US and the UK to include the period of the global financial crisis. The issues
covered in this chapter relate to US and UK market comparisons of progress in gas
market decoupling. More specifically;
1. Are unlagged spot oil price changes, the gas futures price changes and gas spot
price change relationships significant and positive?
2. In optimally lagged data, are the level series price relationships significant and
positive?
3. In lagged data are there significant long-term cointegrating relationships in spot
oil prices and spot and gas futures prices?
4. In short-term dynamics, which markets are the significant exogenous forces in
the lagged models?
5. In both long- and short-term relationships, do domestic factors (gas futures
prices) significantly dominate global factors (spot oil and oil futures prices) in
each gas market?
The focus remains as to whether or not natural gas market liberalization policies
and deregulation legislation in the US and the UK are working. If domestic factors
dominate (that is, if gas futures prices dominate global oil and oil futures prices)
great progress has been made in market liberalization.

10.3 The Models and Methodology


In preliminary analysis, an unlagged model of first differences of the price index
series in daily data is examined over a full period from 1 January 2001 to 31 May
2010 for the US.

Generalised Autoregressive Conditional Heteroskedasticity model.

10

Natural Gas Market Liberalization

181

For the UK, due to an incomplete dataset, the full period is from 2 June 2003 to
31 May 2010. The relative connectivity between oil, spot gas and gas futures price
changes is examined. The preliminary analysis provides information on the
strength of the relationships in each spot natural gas market.
Based on evidence from the studies of the nexus between oil and gas prices
(e.g., Krichene 2002; Ewing et al. 2002; Okogu 2002; Serlitis and Rangel-Ruiz
2004; Adeleman and Watkins 2005; Mazighi 2005; Asche 2006; Eng 2006;
Regnier 2007; Panagiotidis and Rutledge 2007) and taking into account gas futures
price interaction (e.g., Modjtahedi and Movassagh 2005; Mu 2007; Marzo and
Zagaglia 2007 and Geman and Ohana 2009), the following unlagged and lagged
models are proposed for testing. The unlagged model is as follows:
DPgst at b1t DPost b2t DPgft et

10:1

where:
DPgs t ; DPgf t and DPost are the changes in the spot gas price, the gas futures
price and the spot oil price respectively in each of the country markets.
In the main analysis, optimally lagged level series data are initially examined in
a vector autoregressive model2 (VAR) for each of the US and UK markets. Once it
is ascertained that the variables are I(1) and optimally lagged, a vector error
correction model (VECM) is used in order to confirm cointegration and test
causality. The VECM is a re-parameterized version of the unrestricted VAR and is
appropriate when the variables are I(1) and cointegrated. In the presence of I(1)
variables, but no cointegration, causality would be studied from the VAR model
specified in first differences.
Thus, based on Eq. 10.1, initially specified in level series, the following model
(Eq. 10.2) in functional form is tested. Note, all variables on the right hand side of
the equation are specified in both an unlagged and a lagged form from t  1 to
t  n with n as the optimal lag deduced from lag exclusion tests and lag order
information criteria. The endogenous variable is also lagged on the right hand side
of the equation.
Pgst f Post ; Pgf

10:2

An additional model is specified in Eq. 3 to specifically examine the influences


of global versus domestic influences in each market. An up-to-date comparison of
US and UK gas markets is provided that takes into account the relationship
between future spot gas prices and gas futures as well as oil futures prices, in order
to further capture the impact of country specific and global influences respectively.
The interaction of spot and futures markets is examined as mentioned earlier by
several researchers (e.g., Herbert 1993; Herbert and Kreil 1996; Modjtahedi and

A prominent pioneer of research into autoregressive time series processes including exogeneity
and causal ordering is Christopher Sims. The example of related work published is Sims (1977).

182

J. L. Simpson

Movassagh 2005; Wong-Parodi et al. 2006; Mu 2007; Marzo and Zagaglia 2007;
and Geman and Ohana 2009).
Thus, the analysis now moves to Eq. 10.3. Optimally lagged level series data
are again examined in a VECM for each of the US and UK markets in order to
confirm tests of long-term equilibrium relationships and to test for short-run
dynamics and exogeneity. Based on the above-mentioned evidence the following
lagged model in functional form is proposed for testing:
Pgfst f Pgf ; Pof

10:3

where:
Pgfs ; Pgf and Pof represent level series prices of future spot gas, gas futures and
oil futures at times t lagged to t  n where n represents the optimal lag based on
information criteria working from lags t  1 to t  n.

10.4 The Data


The study in this chapter considers a full period of daily data from the beginning of
January 2001 to the end of May 2010. For Eqs. 10.1 and 10.2, daily price data for the
full period of the study are obtained from the DataStream database for all of the
variables in the models. The full period for the US is from 1 January 2001 to 31 May
2010. Note, that due to missing data, the full period for the UK is from 2 June 2003 to
31 May 2010. It is possible that a limitation of the study is that, due to missing NBP
data the results could be influenced by the fact that the US data set is larger.
It is accepted that the spot markets for oil and gas are relatively small. Most of
these commodities are traded in long-term contracts. It may be that the real oil
price is reflected in the oil futures price and Eq. 10.3 controls for this possibility.
The proxy for spot gas prices in the US is the Henry Hub (HH) gas price. The HH
is an index in dollars per million cubic meters of British Thermal Units. The delivery
point is a pipeline interchange near Erath, Louisiana, where a number of interstate
and intrastate pipelines interconnect through a header system operated by the Sabine
Pipe Line. It is also the standard delivery point for the NYMEX natural gas futures
contract in the US. It is considered a representative indicator of US gas prices.
The proxy for the spot gas price in the UK is the National Balancing Point
(NBP) gas prices UK or London. The NBP is a virtual trading location for the sale
and purchase and exchange of UK natural gas. It is the pricing and delivery point
for the Intercontinental Exchange (ICE) natural gas futures contract. It is the most
liquid gas trading point in Europe and is a major influence on the price that
domestic consumers pay for their gas at home. Gas at the NBP trades in pence per
therm. It is similar in concept to the Henry Hub in the United States, but differs in
that it is not an actual physical location. The NBP is considered to be a suitable
proxy for UK gas prices.

10

Natural Gas Market Liberalization

183

The proxy for spot oil prices is the Organization of the Petroleum Exporting
Countries (OPEC) oil prices. The justification for the use of this proxy follows.
The OPEC cartel (cartel means a formal/explicit agreement among competing
firms) consists of net oil-exporting countries primarily made up of Algeria,
Angola, Ecuador, Iran, Iraq, Kuwait, Libya, Nigeria, Qatar, Saudi Arabia, the
United Arab Emirates, and Venezuela at the time of writing. The cartel has
maintained its headquarters in Vienna since 1965 and hosts regular meetings
among the oil ministers of its Member Countries. Indonesia withdrew in 2008 after
it became a net importer of oil, but stated it would likely return if it became a net
exporter in the world again. The OPEC prices are the logical drivers of all other oil
prices, because of the market power of the group of net oil-exporting countries that
collectively control the exports of around 40 % of the worlds oil requirements.
These oil prices, though formed through the market power induced by cartel
behavior, are considered the major driver of and therefore a suitable proxy for the
global crude oil price.
The proxy for the UK gas futures price is the ICE London or UK natural gas
futures prices for six months. It is a Reuters continuation series, which gives the
data for 6 months forward. The proxy for the US gas futures price is the NYMEX
natural gas futures prices for six months, which is a six month forward rate. It
starts at the sixth nearest contract month, which forms the first values for the
continuous series until the first business day of the nearest contract month when, at
this point, the next contract month is taken.
These gas futures prices are considered representative of UK and US gas futures
markets respectively. The gas futures prices selected are a proxy for gas market
price expectations as the data embody various global and country economic
forecast data and information that impact domestic price expectations such as,
exchange rates, inflation, interest rates, growth rates and also storage factors and
seasonal effects on gas demand in the US and in Europe and the UK.
In order to test Eq. 10.3, the following data are used. Daily price data for
4 February 200330 November 2009 are obtained from the DataStream database
for all of the variables in the models for each country market. The spot and futures
prices are described above, but the newly specified endogenous variable is the
future spot gas prices for both the US and the UK. To obtain the future spot gas
prices, spot gas prices (HH and NBP gas prices) are brought forward by six
calendar months to coincide with the commencements of the sample period for
both gas futures and oil futures. Specifically spot gas price data from 4 February
2003 to 4 August 2003 are deleted from the data, thus removing six calendar
months of data from the spot gas price data sets so that spot gas price data may be
brought forward by the above period to coincide with the commencement of the
gas futures price data on the 4 February 2003. The full dataset of prices used to test
Eq. 10.3 now run from 4 February 2003 to 30 November 2009.
The proxy for the global oil futures prices applicable to the US and the UK are
provided in the NYMEX light Sweet Crude Oil futures index and the Brent Crude
Oil futures index. The price calculation method for each index is near month
change at the beginning of the first of the month. Each is a continuous series and a

184

J. L. Simpson

perpetual series of oil futures prices starting at the nearest contract month until
either the contract reaches its expiry date or until the first business day of the actual
contract month. At this point the next contract month is taken.
Prior to reporting the findings of this study the issues addressed in this chapter
as stated previously in Sect. 10.2 are repeated here for the convenience of readers.
1. Are unlagged spot oil price changes, the gas futures price changes and gas spot
price change relationships significant and positive?
2. In optimally lagged data, are the level series price relationships significant and
positive?
3. In lagged data are there significant long-term cointegrating relationships in spot
oil prices and spot and gas futures prices?
4. In short-term dynamics, which markets are the significant exogenous forces in
the lagged models?
5. In both long- and short-term relationships, do domestic factors (gas futures
prices) significantly dominate global factors (spot oil and oil futures prices) in
each gas market?

10.5 Preliminary Findings


It is initially useful to see how the level series prices for the variables in the model
behave over the full period of the study. Figure 10.1 indicates the price movements
of oil (denoted OILOPEC). Note that all figures in this chapter are sourced from
the data in the study described in Sect. 10.4. In Figs. 10.2, 10.3, 10.4 and 10.5 the
abbreviations OFUS, OFUK, WORLDS, GFUS and GFUK denote oil futures US,
oil futures UK, the World Stock Market Index, gas futures US, and gas futures UK
respectively. Note for all variables the prices are on the vertical axis and time in
years is on the horizontal axis. The OFUS prices are in US dollars per barrel, the
OFUK prices are in US dollars per barrel, the WORLDS is an index in US Dollars,
the GFUS is in US dollars per million cubic meters of British Thermal Units and
the GFUK is in UK pence per therm. As most measurements are in US dollars
inflation and exchange rate effects are not taken into account in this study, with
standardization introduced through logarithmic transformation of price changes.3
Figures 10.1 and 10.2 show that oil prices, spot or future are more correlated
with global economic indicators (World Stock Market index in Fig. 10.3) than gas
futures prices in Figs. 10.4 and 10.5. However, they also show some co-movement
of gas futures prices in the US and the UK, possibly due to similar northern
hemisphere seasonality effects with any differences possibly due to different
3

Inflation rate and exchange rate differences between the US and the UK are not assumed to be
major influences over the full period of this study. Thus it is assumed that a reasonable degree of
purchasing power parity and interest rate parity exists between the US and the UK over the full
period of the study.

10

Natural Gas Market Liberalization

185

OILOPEC

160
140
120
100
80
60
40
20
0
01

02

03

04

05

06

07

08

09

Fig. 10.1 Oil prices. Note OILOPEC is the OPEC oil price index sourced from DataStream.
Prices on the vertical axis are quoted in US Dollars per barrel. The vertical axis denotes years
160
140
120
100
80
60
40
20
2003

2004

2005

2006
OFUK

2007

2008

2009

OFUS

Fig. 10.2 Oil futures prices

storage effects in each country. These graphs provide initial evidence that the gas
futures markets in both countries do not track global economic indicators to the
extent that oil prices do and their respective peaks and troughs indicate that
domestic macro-economic and other factors in seasonality and storage are the
major influences on these prices.
With regard to Eq. 10.1, the findings of the analysis of unlagged differenced
data are reported as preliminary findings as follows: preliminary analysis of all

186

J. L. Simpson

WORLDS
1.800
1.600
1.400
1.200
1.000
800
600
2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

Fig. 10.3 Global stock market prices


GFUS
16
14
12
10
8
6
4
2
2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

Fig. 10.4 Gas futures prices US

unlagged level series for both the US and the UK and in all periods of the study
indicates skewness and kurtosis problems, which indicate lack of normality and
uniformity (tests from Jarque and Bera 1987).
This is a violation of the assumptions of ordinary least squares (OLS) regressions and indicates, in turn, problems in serial correlation of the errors for each of
the regression relationships. First differencing removes the problems of serial
correlation in the errors of the first difference relationships (according to DW tests
(Durbin and Watson 1971), but White tests indicate that heteroskedasticity problems remain in the errors thus indicating model misspecification. An autoregressive conditional heteroskedasticity (ARCH) model is deemed more suitable for
analysis. The results of this analysis are reported in Table 10.1.

10

Natural Gas Market Liberalization

187
GFUK

12.000
10.000
8.000
6.000
4.000
2.000
0
2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

Fig. 10.5 Gas futures prices UK

Table 10.1 Results of spot gas first differenced models


Regression
Adjusted R z Statistic:
Standard error
model
squared
spot oil/gas of regression
(Eq. 10.1)
futures
US spot gas
0.2061***/
0.8609***
UK spot gas
0.1866***/
0.8782***

Durbin
Watson
statistic

Variance
equation
coefficient
ARCH/GARCH

0.0366***

10.4862***/

10.8608***

0.3572***

2.0778***

0.0039***

1.1086/

4.9908***

5.2515

2.2574***

Note Significance levels for spot oil z statistics and ARCH/GARCH terms are at 1 %, no asterisk
means no significance
***
denotes significant at 1 % level

Serial correlation problems are not evident and thus do not detract from the
reliability of the models parameters, as indicated by DW statistics. The z statistics
for each of spot oil and gas futures in the US are positive and statistically
significant at the 1 % level. In the UK, only the gas futures variable is significant.
In unlagged data, it is evident that the US gas market has not decoupled with the
oil market. However, the z statistics for US gas futures are also significant at the
1 % level. This indicates that economic forecasts, seasonality and storage factors
embodied in US gas futures price changes are important in US gas markets. This
evidence indicates that, though the nexus between gas and oil prices has not been
broken, sound progress has been made in deregulation of US gas markets as seen
in the connection between gas futures price changes and spot gas price changes.
Global as well as domestic factors appear to be at work in US gas markets when
unlagged data are considered.

188
Table 10.2 Unit root tests
Variable
Equation 10.1: US spot gas
Spot oil
US gas futures
US spot gas errors
Equation 10.1: UK spot gas
Spot oil
UK gas futures
UK spot gas errors

J. L. Simpson

t statistic
(level series prices)

t statistic
(first differences)

-3.2471**
-1.3347
-1.8914
-2.9969**
-4.6458***
-1.4947
-2.0604
-5.0251***

-30.8007***
-25.2201***
-50.5273***
-30.5471***
-23.7836***
-22.1242***
-40.8704***
-23.6352***

Note No asterisk means non-significance. ADF test results are shown.

**

at 5 % and at

***

1%

Evidence of decoupling in the UK gas market is provided in unlagged data with


the lack of significance of the spot oil price change variable. The explanatory
power in the models is lower for the UK spot gas market. The z statistics for the
UK gas futures variable is statistically significant. In unlagged data for the UK, the
nexus between oil and gas appears to have been broken and gas price expectations
embodied in gas futures price changes are significantly related to UK spot gas over
the full period of the study. Domestic factors appear more important in UK gas
markets when unlagged data are considered.
In the next stage of the preliminary analysis the level series, the first differenced
series and the respective errors of these relationships for each country and each
period under study are tested for stationarity using Augmented Dickey and Fuller
(ADF) tests (Dickey and Fuller 1981). The results of these tests are shown in
Table 10.2.
Table 10.2 results indicate overall, that the level series and errors of the level
series relationships are non-stationary and the first differenced series and the errors
of the first differenced relationships are stationary. This enables a conclusion that,
in each case for each country and for each period under study, the processes are
integrated and non-stationary and this in turn enables a move to the main analysis.
That is, to apply all level series to a VAR based Johansen cointegration test
(Johansen 1988). If cointegration is present, a VECM is specified to confirm longterm relationships and to test short-term dynamics of those relationships in
Granger Causality tests (Granger 1988).

10.6 Main Findings


To seek greater clarity in findings, this part of the analysis deals with optimally
lagged data for Eqs. 10.2 and 10.3. In order to commence the testing of Eq. 10.2,
lag order and lag exclusion tests are conducted to ascribe an optimal lag for
cointegration and causality testing. The models are initially tested for stability over
all periods of the study for both US and UK markets using stability condition tests.

10

Natural Gas Market Liberalization

189

Table 10.3 Optimal lags and cointegration and causality test results
Model
Number of cointegrating
Optimal
Granger causality
relationships according to Trace lag order (Chi square statistic)
and Eigenvalue tests
in days
Equation 2: 1**
US spot
gas

4***

Equation 2: 1**
UK spot
gas

3***

US gas futures causes US spot gas


(346.2631***).
No significant causality between
spot oil and US spot gas.
Within the model and over the full
period, US gas futures
significantly cause spot oil
(127.8207***)
No significant causality from UK gas
futures to UK spot gas.
No significant causality between
spot oil and UK spot gas.
Within this model, spot oil causes UK
gas futures (8.5459*) and UK gas
futures causes spot oil
(83.7156***). The latter driver
relationship is stronger according
to the magnitude of the Chi square
statistic.

Note The Johansen cointegration tests take the assumption that there is a linear deterministic
trend in the data. Optimal lags are decided based on the majority significance of the Likelihood
Ratio, the Final Prediction Error, and the Akaike, Schwarz and Hannan-Quinn information criteria. The number of cointegrating equations is based on both maximum eigenvalues and trace
statistics. In the number of cointegrating relationships, no asterisk means no significance.
*
denotes significance at the 10 % level, ** at the 5 % level and *** at the 1 % level. The
causality tests show similar levels of Chi Square statistical significance

The findings are that the models are stable, with no root lying outside the relative
unit root circle. The results for the lag order and the cointegration and causality
tests are shown in Table 10.3.
In both markets in the long term there is evidence of cointegration over the full
periods of the studies. This represents evidence that whilst short-term causal
relationships may show decoupling evidence (where there appears no causal
relationship between spot oil and spot gas), there remains a long-term cointegrating relationship between oil and gas prices and gas futures prices, whereby
these variables move in a similar way and come together to stability. This
represents evidence that in the long term the markets have not fully decoupled and
that in both markets deregulation policies still have some distance to go in
achieving full gas market liberalization. However, in the US it is evident when
lagged data are considered that domestic factors in gas futures prices have a
greater impact on spot gas prices than in the UK.
There is also evidence within the models, of causality between gas futures and
spot oil for both markets. Overall, in the short-term there is evidence of decoupling
in both markets, but the nexus between oil and gas futures prices is not fully
broken.

190

J. L. Simpson

Table 10.4 Unit root tests for variables in future spot gas price and price change relationships
Variable
t statistic
t statistic
(level series prices)
(first differences)
US future spot gas:
US Oil futures
US gas futures
Errors US Future Spot Gas
UK future spot gas
UK gas futures
UK Oil futures
Errors UK Future Spot Gas

-2.500
-1.603
-2.080
-2.764*
-4.6334***
-1.975
-1.410
-5.301***

-40.037***
-44.428***
-42.147***
-40.848***
-22.659***
-38.839***
-44.611***
-22.583***

Note No asterisk means non-significance. ADF test results are shown. * Significance levels are at
10 %, *** 1 %. The critical values for the ADF unit root tests are at 1 % (-3.434), at 5 % (2.863) and 10 % (-2.568) levels of significance

With regard to the testing of Eq. 10.3 the following results are reported. It is
recalled that Eq. 10.3 treats the future spot gas price endogenously against the gas
futures price and the oil futures price. The level series of each price index, the first
differenced series and the respective errors of these relationships for each country
and each period under study are tested for unit roots. The results of these tests are
shown in Table 10.4.
Table 10.4 results indicates, that the level series and errors of the level series
relationships are non-stationary processes and the first differenced series and the
errors of the first differenced relationships are each stationary at the 1 % level of
significance.
This enables a conclusion that in each case, for each country, the processes are
integrated and non-stationary and this in turn enables a move to the second part of
the main analysis. That is, to apply all level series to a VAR. As with the testing of
Eq. 10.2, when Eq. 10.3 is considered it is noted that, if I(1) variables are found to
be cointegrated the VAR is re-specified into a VECM and tests run to confirm
cointegration and to test causality.
Again lag order tests are conducted to ascribe an optimal lag for cointegration
and causality tests. The models are initially tested for stability over the full period
of the study for both US and UK markets using stability condition tests. The
findings are that the Eq. 10.3 models are also stable, with no root lying outside the
relative unit root circle. The results for the lag order, cointegration and causality
tests are shown in Table 10.5.
On testing of Eq. 10.3 the findings are that there are no significant long-term
equilibrium (cointegrating) relationships between the variables in the US model.
This represents evidence of decoupling of oil and gas. When the future spot gas
price is treated endogenously, as specified, there is no evidence of dual or one-way
causality running between that variable and US gas futures and oil futures. This
too represents evidence of decoupling of oil and gas. Within the model, when the
US gas futures variable is treated endogenously, causality runs from future spot
gas US to gas futures US at the 10 % level of significance. In the latter case it is

10

Natural Gas Market Liberalization

191

Table 10.5 Results: Optimal lags and cointegration and causality tests for future spot gas price
relationships
Model Number of cointegrating
Optimal
Granger causality
relationships according to Trace lag order
and Eigenvalue tests
in days
US

UK

When the future spot gas price is treated


endogenously, as specified there is
no evidence of dual or one way
causality running between that
variable and gas futures US and oil
futures US.
Within the model, when gas futures US
is treated endogenously, causality
runs from future spot gas US to gas
futures at the 10 % level of
significance.
When the specified future spot gas UK
variable is treated endogenously,
dual causality exists between oil
futures UK and the future spot gas
price UK, but the greater causal
influence is from the future spot
gas price UK to the oil futures
price UK with Chi Squared values of
8.019 compared to 5.669.
Significance levels are at 10 %.
Within this model when gas futures UK
is treated endogenously, future spot
gas UK causes gas futures UK at
the 5 % level of significance. Dual
causality exists between oil futures
UK and gas futures UK with the
stronger
causality running from oil futures UK
to gas futures UK at the 1 %
significance level (with Chi Square
Values at 17.981 compared to
15.134).

Note The future spot gas prices in the US and the UK respectively are treated endogenously. The
Johansen cointegration tests take the assumption that there is a linear deterministic trend in
the data. Optimal lags are decided based on the majority significance of the Likelihood Ratio, the
Final Prediction Error, the Akaike, Schwarz and Hannan-Quinn information criteria. The number
of cointegrating equations is based on both maximum eigenvalues and trace statistics. In the
number of cointegrating relationships, no asterisk means no significance. The causality tests show
similar levels of Chi Square statistical significance

evident that when the future spot gas US price changes the gas futures US price
changes in the same direction within two days. This too represents evidence of
decoupling of oil and gas in US markets.
When the future spot gas UK variable is treated endogenously, there is a longterm equilibrium (cointegrating) relationship between the variables in the model.

192

J. L. Simpson

This represents evidence that in the UK, oil and gas markets have not decoupled.
In addition, dual causality exists between oil futures and the future spot gas price
UK, but the greater causal influence is from the future spot gas price UK to the oil
futures price with Chi Square values of 8.019 compared to 5.669. Significance
levels are at 10 %. This too represents evidence that in the UK, oil and gas markets
have not fully decoupled.
Within this model, when the gas futures UK variable is treated endogenously,
the future spot gas price UK causes gas futures UK at the 5 % level of significance.
This represents evidence of decoupling and the interplay of domestic factors in the
determination of future spot gas prices, however, dual Granger causality exists
between oil futures UK and gas futures UK with the stronger Granger causality
running from oil futures to gas futures UK at the 1 % significance level (with
Chi Square values at 17.981 compared to 15.134). This again does not represent
evidence of full decoupling of the UK future spot gas price with global factors
(oil futures) influencing domestic future gas prices.

10.7 Conclusion
The theoretical base for this chapter lies in the re-visitation of market liberalization
theory by Asche (2000), but focuses on updating and expanding past studies. For
example, a UK cointegration and causality study by Panagiotidis and Rutledge
(2007). Just as mixed evidence is produced by the authors reviewed, mixed
evidence is provided in the study in this chapter. The findings depend on whether
the data are lagged or unlagged, level or differenced, inclusive of spot prices and
gas futures prices or of future spot gas prices, and oil futures and gas futures prices.
The chapter commences with the assumption that there exists a relationship
between oil and gas prices as implied, for example, by Okogu (2002), Burger,
Graeber and Schindlmayr (2008) and Eng (2006). Mazhigi (2005) finds the UK gas
price is significantly related to oil prices. Researchers such as Krichene (2002),
Ewing et al. (2002), Adeleman and Watkins (2005) and Regnier (2007) find that
oil and gas markets possess similar trends in stochastic volatility.
The importance of gas futures in their embodiment of price expectations based
on economic, seasonal and storage information is put forward by researchers such
as Herbert (1993), Herbert and Kreil (1996), Modjtahedi and Movassagh (2005),
Mu (2007), Marzo and Zagaglia (2007) and Geman and Ohana (2009). Serlitis and
Rangel-Ruiz (2004), find decoupling of oil and gas prices as a result of deregulation in the US. Siliverstovs et al. (2005) find high levels of gas market integration
within Europe and North America. Asche (2006) finds that monthly price data
from 1995 to 1998 in the UK indicate a highly integrated gas market. The findings
of Panagiotidis and Rutledge (2007) generally do not support the assumption of
decoupling of prices in the relatively highly liberalized UK market, but imply that
progress is being made in deregulation policies.

10

Natural Gas Market Liberalization

193

The results of the testing of unlagged data in the study for this chapter indicates
that, though the nexus between gas and oil prices has not been broken (oil price
changes also are a significant determinant), sound progress has been made in
deregulation of US gas markets as seen in the connection of gas futures price
changes to spot gas price changes. Global as well as domestic factors initially
appear to be at work in US gas markets. In the UK, at least in unlagged data, the
nexus between oil and gas appears to have been broken and gas price expectations
embodied in gas futures price changes are significantly related to UK spot gas over
the full period of the study. Domestic factors are also more important in UK gas
markets in unlagged data.
However, the analysis of unlagged data does not provide a clear picture of longterm equilibrium relationships and short-term dynamics. When lagged data are
examined, evidence is produced that, in the long term, the markets have not fully
decoupled (cointegrating relationships exist in both US and UK markets) and that
in both markets deregulation policies still have some distance to go in achieving
full gas market liberalization. However, in the US it is evident, that domestic
factors in gas futures prices have a greater impact on spot gas prices than in the
UK. Therefore, more clarity is required on oil and gas price relationships.
Consequently, the study finally takes into account lagged relationships between
future spot gas prices, oil futures prices and gas futures prices and the results have
achieved greater clarity. Also tested is whether or not gas futures prices are a good
predictor of future gas prices. Whilst there is no strong evidence for this, it is
evident through cointegration and exogeneity testing, that US gas markets have
largely decoupled and that domestic forces in gas price expectations (in other
words US macroeconomic forecasts, seasonality and storage factors), play a major
role in the relationship with the future spot gas price. There is again no strong
evidence that UK futures prices are good predictors of future spot prices. In the UK
cointegration and exogeneity testing show that the nexus between oil and gas
futures markets has not been fully severed. Thus global factors in the oil futures
market have much to do with the maintenance of that connection.

References
Adeleman, M. A., & Watkins, G. C. (2005). US Oil and natural gas reserve prices, 19822003.
Energy Economics, 27, 553571.
Asche, F. (2000). European market integration for gas? Volume flexibility and political risk
(Working Paper No. 358). Munich, Germany: CESinfo
Asche, F. (2006). The UK Market for Natural Gas, Oil and Electricity: Are the Prices Decoupled?
The Energy Journal, 27(2), 2740.
Burger, M., Graeber, M., & Schindlmayr, G. (2008). Managing energy risk: An integrated view
on power and other energy markets. Chichester: Wiley.
Dickey, D. A., & Fuller, W. A. (1981). Likelihood ratio statistics for autoregressive time series
within a unit root. Econometrica, 49, 10221057.
Durbin, J., & Watson, G. S. (1971). Testing for serial correlation in least squares regression.III.
Biometrika, 58, 119.

194

J. L. Simpson

Eng, G. (2006). A formula for LNG pricing, Ministry for Economic Development New Zealand.
Retrieved from http://www.med.govt.nz/Templates/multipageDocumentTOC___23939.aspx.
Ewing, B. T., Malik, F., & Ozfidan, O. (2002). Volatility transmission in the oil and natural gas
markets. Energy Economics, 24, 525538.
Geman, H., & Ohana, S. (2009). Forward curves, scarcity and price volatility in oil and natural
gas markets. Energy Economics, 31, 576585.
Granger, C. W. J. (1988). Some recent developments in a concept of causality. Journal of
Econometrics, 39, 199211.
Herbert, J. H. (1993). The relation of monthly spot to futures prices for natural gas. Energy, 18,
11191124.
Herbert, J. H., & Kreil, E. (1996). US natural gas markets: How efficient are they? Energy Policy,
24, 15.
Jarque, C. M., & Bera, A. K. (1987). A test for normality of observations and regression residuals.
International Statistical Review, 55, 163172.
Johansen, S. (1988). Statistical analysis of cointegration vectors. Journal of Economic Dynamics
& Control, 12, 231254.
Krichene, N. (2002). World crude oil and natural gas: A demand and supply model. Energy
Economics, 24, 557576.
Marzo, M., & Zagaglia, P. (2007). A note on the conditional correlation between energy prices:
Evidence from future markets. Energy Economics, 30, 24542458.
Mazighi, A. E. H. (2005). Henry Hub and national balancing point prices: What will be the
international gas price reference? OPEC Review, 29, 219230.
Modjtahedi, B., & Movassagh, N. (2005). Natural gas futures: Bias, predictive performance, and
the theory of storage. Energy Economics, 27, 617637.
Mu, X. (2007). Weather, storage and natural gas price dynamics: Fundamentals and volatility.
Energy Economics, 29, 4663.
Okogu, B. E. (2002). Issues in global natural gas: A primer and analysis. (Working Paper No.
40). Washington, DC: IMF.
Panagiotidis, T., & Rutledge, E. (2007). Oil and gas markets in the UK: Evidence from a
cointegration approach. Energy Economics, 29, 329347.
Regnier, E. (2007). Oil and energy price volatility. Energy Economics, 29, 405427.
Root, T. H., & Lien, D. (2003). Can modeling the natural gas futures market as a threshold
cointegrated system improve hedging and forecasting performance? International Review of
Financial Analysis, 12, 117133.
Serlitis, A., & Rangel-Ruiz, R. (2004). Testing for common features in North American energy
markets. Energy Economics, 26, 401414.
Silverstovs, B., LHegaret, G., Neumann, A., & von Hirschhausen, C. (2005). International
market integration for natural gas? A cointegration analysis of prices in Europe, North
America and Japan. Energy Economics, 27, 603615.
Sims, C. A. (1977). Exogeneity and causal ordering in macroeconomic models. In C. A. Sims
(Ed.), New methods in business cycle research (pp. 2343). Federal Reserve Bank of
Minneapolis: Minneapolis.
Wong-Parodi, G., Dale, L., & Lekov, A. (2006). Comparing price forecast accuracy of natural gas
models and futures markets. Energy Policy, 34, 41154122.

Part IV

Finance and Energy

Chapter 11

Adding Oil to a Portfolio of Stocks


and Bonds?
Andr Dorsman, Andr Koch, Menno Jager
and Andr Thibeault

Abstract The work of Markowitz in the early 1950s triggered a revolution in the
investment management world. The concept of efficient portfolios and efficient
frontier gave an important impulse to the development of modern finance. Ever
since, the concept of efficient portfolios has been widely applied in many environments. While originally restricted to stock markets, applications have been
developed in the field of e.g. the optimisation of energy distribution (Letzelter
2005). In the last decade, asset managers look at the opportunity to improve their
expected return-risk trade off by adding commodities to their portfolio of stocks
and bonds. In this chapter we look at the contribution of oil to such a portfolio.
The goal of this paper is to investigate if the addition of oil to an investment
portfolio can improve an efficient set of traditional investments in stocks and bonds.
We believe that given the counter cyclicality of oil returns compared to the stock
market, that the inclusion of such assets should improve the risk-return trade-off.
It appears that oil is not a safe haven for stockholders and bondholders. Oil is not a
hedge for stockholders, but it does present a hedge for bondholders. When adding
oil to the portfolio we see a change in efficient frontier and market portfolio.
Holders of portfolios of bonds and stocks can improve their risk-return trade off by
enlarging their portfolio with an investment in oil.
Keywords Safe haven

 Hedging portfolios  Efficient frontier

A. Dorsman (&)
VU University Amsterdam, Amsterdam, The Netherlands
e-mail: a.b.dorsman@vu.nl
A. Koch  M. Jager
Stachanov, Amsterdam, The Netherlands
A. Thibeault
Vlerick, Management School, Ghent, Belgium

A. Dorsman et al. (eds.), Energy Economics and Financial Markets,


DOI: 10.1007/978-3-642-30601-3_11,  Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg 2013

197

198

A. Dorsman et al.

11.1 Introduction
Mandelbrot (1963, 1966) showed that stocks are neither normally nor log-normally
distributed. The condition of (log-) normality has become more and more
restrictive. The 2007/2008 global financial crisis and the stock price developments
after the 2011 earthquake and tsunami in Japan show that outliers are more frequent than one might expect under the (log-) normal condition. In other words,
there is obesity in the tail. It is also possible that an asset is not or negatively
correlated with another asset whenever market developments are difficult. Holders
of the second asset see, in that case, the first asset as a safe haven. There is some
evidence (Baur and Lucey 2009; Baur and Dermott 2010) that gold is a safe haven
for some stockholders, but not for bondholders.
The goal of this chapter is to investigate whether the addition of oil to a
traditional portfolio of stocks and bonds can improve the risk-return trade-off.
Adding oil to a portfolio of stocks and bonds can be interesting for portfolio
holders if it improves the expected risk-return trade-off.
Thus, our research investigates the impact of adding oil to a portfolio of bonds
and stocks. We are more specifically interested to look at oil as a safe haven, at oil
as a hedge for stockholders and bondholders and at the impact of oil on the
efficient frontier of a portfolio made of stocks, bonds, and oil. To conduct the
empirical tests, we use indices made of risk free U.S. government bonds, of
common stocks from Standard and Poor and of an oil index.
The statistical analysis is performed with the use of Oracle Crystal Ball software. The software is used to characterise the distribution of returns for our three
indices, to estimate the correlations between these indices, and to derive the
efficient frontier for our portfolios. In our analysis, we also consider the consequences of obesity in the tails.
The structure of this chapter is as follows. We start with a review overview in
Sect. 11.2. In Sect. 11.3 the data is described. The empirical results are presented
in Sect. 11.4. Section 11.5 contains a short summary and our conclusions.

11.2 Literature Review


One of the problems with bond and stock portfolios is the heavy tail in the returns,
to which for example Mandelbrot (1966) already drew attention. However, during
the 2007/2008 financial crisis, the problem became more visible. Kousky and
Cooke (2009) examined several datasets of damages from natural disasters and
concluded that fat tails exist, as do tail dependence and/or micro-correlations.
Micro-correlations are small, positive correlations between variables. Kousky and
Cooke give the example of the El Nio effect causing fires in Australia and floods
in California. These authors looked at this problem from the perspective of an
insurance company. Insurance companies reduce their risk by diversifying their

11

Adding Oil to a Portfolio of Stocks and Bonds?

199

portfolios. However, fat tails, tail dependency and micro-correlations reduce the
effect of diversification in an insurance portfolio.
For over a decade now, institutional investors try to reduce risk by diversifying
their portfolios with commodities. For example, gold can be a safe haven asset to
this purpose.1 Baur and Lucey (2009) make a distinction between a hedge, a
diversifier and a safe haven asset. A hedge is an asset that is uncorrelated or even
negatively correlated with another asset or portfolio. A diversifier is an asset that is
positively (but, not perfectly) correlated with another asset or portfolio, and a safe
haven is an asset that is uncorrelated or negatively correlated with another asset or
portfolio in times of market stress and turmoil. In the case of a safe haven,
correlations are different at times of large price falls on stock and bond markets.
Baur and Lucey (2009) analyze the role of gold in combination with stocks and
bonds for the markets of the US, the UK and Germany. They find evidence that
gold is a safe haven for stockholders, but not for bondholders. Baur and McDermott (2010) enlarged the study of Baur and Lucey (2009) to include other markets.
However, they only looked at the relationship between gold and stocks, and not to
the interactions between gold and bonds. They find that gold is a safe haven for the
well-developed European countries and the US, but not for Japan, Australia,
Canada and in the countries of Brazil, Russia, India and China (BRIC group),
which are all deemed to be at a similar stage of newly advanced economic
development. The acronym has come into widespread use as a symbol of the shift
in global economic power away from the developed G7 economies towards the
developing world.2 Also oil can be seen as a safe haven. In times of a substantial
price decreases on the stock markets not only gold, but also oil may increase in
price.
Arouri and Nguyen (2010) examined oilstock market relationships over the
last turbulent decade. Steering clear previous empirical investigations, which have
largely focused on broad-based national and regional market indices, they investigate short-term linkages on an aggregate level as well as on the sector by sector
level in Europe. Their main finding is that the responses of stock returns to oil
price changes differ greatly depending on the industry.
Geman and Karroubi (2008) look at the diversification effect brought by crude
oil futures contracts into a portfolio of stocks. They prefer oil futures because it is
the most liquid of commodity futures. However, introducing futures into the
database introduces new problems. Firstly, the maturity of a future is limited. At a

Another commodity is real estate. For example Chua (1999) studied the role of international
real estate in a mixed-asset portfolio while attempting to control for higher taxes, transaction
costs and asset management fees incurred when investing in real estate, as well as the appraisal
smoothing in real estate return indices.
2
In 2005 Goldman Sachs defined The Next Eleven (or N-11). The N-11 are eleven countries
Bangladesh, Egypt, Indonesia, Iran, Mexico, Nigeria, Pakistan, Philippines, South Korea, Turkey
and Vietnamidentified by Goldman Sachs investment bank as having a high potential of
becoming, along with the BRICs, the worlds largest economies in the twenty first century.
ONeill (2001)

200

A. Dorsman et al.

certain moment, one has to switch to a future with a longer maturity. Their finding
is that, in the case of distant maturities futures (e.g., 18 months), the negative
correlation effect is more pronounced regardless whether stock prices increase or
decrease. This property has the merit to avoid the hurdles of a frequent roll-over
while being quite desirable in the current trendless equity markets.

11.3 The Data


We study bond, stock, and oil returns. The period observed is 19892010. In this
period, the general movement of the stock market was sometimes very positive
while in other sub-periods the stock prices fell rapidly. In the 1980s, stock prices
showed positive economic development. After two oil crises in the 1970s, the
stock market began booming in the 1980s. There was a large price fall in stock
prices in October 1989 and again in October 1998. At the beginning of the twenty
first century, we experienced the dot.com crisis and, in 2008, the global financial
crisis. It is interesting to see if these different developments during the observed
period also led to different optimal portfolios. Therefore we look at periods with a
window of 10 years, starting with 19891998, then 19901999, and finally
20012010.
In our study we are using the following daily data:

US Treasury bonds 10 years


Government bonds (code: MLUS10P)
Standard and Poors (S & P) 500 (code: S19658)
West Texas Intermediate (code: RWTC)

Our bond and stock indices are corrected to include interest and dividend
payments. All data are priced in dollars. Therefore we have no currency problem.
There are several types of crude oil. For example, light, sweet crude is of
greater use in production of gasoline, naphtha, propane and butane. Heavy sour
crude is used mainly to produce heavy heating oil, asphalt and bitumen.
Accordingly, the different types of crude require their own specific refineries and
refining processes. Heavy sour crude needs more refinery processing than does the
lightest and sweetest form, meaning that people are unwilling to pay as much for
heavy sour crude as for light sweet crude. As a result, prices of the various types of
oil differ. For that reason the price of West Texas Intermediate (WTI) crude will
most of the time differ from, for instance, Dubai crude. It is understood that this
difference does not remain steady over time, but varies as a result of many factors
such as available refining capacity and reserves. Our choice to select the WTI Oil
is arbitrary. Therefore, at times we will also check with the Brent Crude Oil.
Most oil contracts are bilateral between demanders and suppliers. Only a
limited part is traded on the spot market. Therefore the price on the spot market is
not a good indicator of the real oil price. As an alternative we use the WTI Oil
futures prices. However, by using futures we are also introducing the problems of

11

Adding Oil to a Portfolio of Stocks and Bonds?

201

backwardation and contango. A commodity can switch from backwardation to


contango and vice versa. (See, for example, Umutlu et al. (2011) in relation to the
electricity market).
The data examined are values for the US treasury bonds (T bonds), which are an
indicator of the risk free interest rate; government bonds for the bond market, the
S&P 500 for the stock market and WTI Oil for the oil market. All data are
denominated in US dollars.
Commodities are real goods, which makes them different from bonds and
stocks. Arbitrage reduces possible price differences in bonds and stocks. If the
prices of bonds or stocks in New York are higher than in London, arbitrageurs will
sell in New York and buy in London till the price differences are (nearly) zero. The
price of commodities, however, depends on location. Transport costs lead to price
differences between locations that cannot be removed by arbitrage.
Another difference between commodities on one hand and stock and bonds on
the other hand is that the price of commodities can have a seasonal component. In
the case of oil we see a peak during the summer (driving season) and in the winter
(heating).
The following hypotheses are tested.
H1 Oil is not a safe haven for stockholders and bondholders.
We expect that oil has zero or negative correlation with stocks and/or bonds
during periods with negative stock and/or bond returns
H2 Oil is not a hedge for stockholders and bondholders.
We expect that oil has zero or negative correlation with stocks and/or bonds.
H3 The efficient frontier will not change when we add oil as an alternative
investment opportunity for the component stocks and bonds.
We expect that adding oil to a portfolio of stocks and bonds will add value. In
other words: the efficient frontier will change as for every point on the efficient
frontier the risk becomes lower or the expected return becomes higher.
H4 The market portfolio of oil, bonds and stocks is constant during the observed
period.
We expect that the weights in the optimal portfolio for oil, stocks and bonds
will not change substantially during the observed period.

11.4 Empirical Results


Before starting with the econometric analyses we will have a short look at the
figures and descriptive analysis of bonds, stocks and oil individually. The reason
for comparing the graphs of bonds, stocks and oil is that a quick scan can
sometimes improve the econometric analyses. During the observed period the

202

A. Dorsman et al.

graph of the bond, Fig. 11.1a, shows an upward trend for bonds caused by a global
decreasing of the interest rate. During the period 19892010 the development of
stocks (Fig. 11.1b) and oil (Fig. 11.1c) differ from the development of bonds. The
graph of the stocks shows the effect of the internet crisis in 20012002 and the
financial crisis in 20072008. The internet crisis in 20012002 had no influence on
the price of the oil, but the financial crisis in 20072008 had. The time series
presented in Fig. 11.1a (bonds), b (stocks) and c (oil) show substantial volatility.
By comparing these figures we see sometimes a co-movement (financial crisis) in
stocks and oil) and sometimes an independent development of the stock price and
the oil price. Our general conclusion is that specific cyclical or counter cyclical
patterns cannot be identified and neither can the potential for diversification.
However, the individual evolution of each time series can be explained by market
developments. Perusal of the price development of stocks (Fig. 11.1b) reveals large
prices decrease in 2000/2002 and again in 2007/2008. These periods refer to the
internet crisis and the financial crisis respectively. During the internet crisis, oil
prices did not move significantly, while during the financial crisis the oil price
dropped dramatically. The bond prices in Fig. 11.1a exhibit a steady growth during
the observed period. Only during the financial crisis the bond prices got hit substantially, but not as severely as the stock prices and the oil prices. As previously
inferred, these figures lead to a mixed interpretation. It is not clear from inspection of
these graphs, whether oil is a safe haven or a hedge for stock and/or bondholders.
The returns on oil prices, stock prices and bond prices are not normally distributed, because in all cases the minimum values of oil, stocks and bonds are zero.
Therefore we usein line with other researchersthe log-returns instead of
normal returns to get distributions that are not capped. Table 11.1 contains a
summary of the descriptive analysis of the log-returns on oil prices, stock prices
and bond prices. In Appendix we give some of these statistics for each of the years
of the observed periods.
Table 11.1 shows that during the observed period the mean values of bonds,
stocks and oil do not differ much. However, the standard deviation of bonds is
substantially lower than the standard deviation of stocks, which is again substantially
lower than the standard deviation of oil. This ranking makes sense if one considers
the relative riskiness of each instrument. The Hill estimator is used to determine
whether or not there is obesity in the tails. The Hill estimator estimates the aparameter of a Pareto distribution (see Kousky and Cooke 2009). Based on the logreturn distributions, it becomes clear that neither stocks nor oil exhibit fat tails.
Resnick (2007) finds that only when the log-returns are Pareto-distributed the Hillestimator works well. In the cases of other distributions, Resnick finds that the results
of the Hill-estimator are unstable. We find a Hill-estimator of a for bonds, stock and
oil of 3.6, 3.2 and 2.7 respectively, which indicates that there is obesity in the tails.
The bond index shows a distribution close to the normal distribution. The
kurtosis of the bond distribution is with 2.26 relatively low and the skewness, 0.20, differs not much from zero. Also for the stock index we see a small skewness,
-0.23. However, the stock index exhibits a significant kurtosis of 9.46, more than
three times that of a normal distribution. The departure from normality is even

11

Adding Oil to a Portfolio of Stocks and Bonds?

(a)

203

2000
1800

Index bonds

1600
1400
1200
1000
800
600
400
200
0
12/31/88

12/31/92

12/31/96

12/31/00

12/31/04

12/31/08

12/31/04

12/31/08

12/31/04

12/31/08

Date

(b)

3000

Index stocks

2500
2000
1500
1000
500
0
12/31/88

12/31/92

12/31/96

12/31/00

Date

(c)

160
140

Index oil

120
100
80
60
40
20
0
12/31/88

12/31/92

12/31/96

12/31/00

Date

Fig. 11.1 a The price development of bonds during the period 19892010. b The price
development of stocks during the period 19892010. c The price development of oil during the
period 19892010

204

A. Dorsman et al.

Table 11.1 Descriptive statistics of the log returns of oil, stocks and bonds
Parameter
Bond
Stock

Oil

Number of observations
Mean (%)
Standard error of mean (%)
Median (%)
Standard deviation (%)
Variance (%)
Skewness
Kurtosis
Jarque-Bera
Hill estimator
Sum (%)
Minimum (%)
Maximum (%)

5741
0.029
0.032
0.000
2.448
0.060
-0.94
17.23
71822.21
2.7
166.779
-40.048
16.410

5741
0.032
0.008
0.039
0.581
0.003
-0.20
2.26
1255.81
3.6
181.891
-3.173
3.810

5741
0.035
0.015
0.033
1.138
0.013
-0.23
9.46
21462.71
3.2
199.310
-9.460
10.958

more significant for the oil index with a skewness of -0.94 and a kurtosis of 17.23.
These departures from normality necessitate a further investigation for the
appropriate distribution. We conclude that the bond distribution does not deviate
much from the normal distribution, while the oil price cannot be described by a
normal distribution. The stock index is somewhere in between.
In order to determine the efficient frontier and the optimal portfolio composition, conventional portfolio theory has been applied. The data have not been
modeled with a probability density function (PDF), but the real data are used in the
model. An analysis of the data shows that neither the stock, nor the bonds, and oil
returns contained fat tails. The as which have been determined for the various
asset classes are well and above two, which indicates that there are no undefined
first and second statistical moments. This proves that both the mean and the
variance of the data are defined. For real fat tails these moments are not defined
and the statistics change as more data are added. In case a would have been
smaller than two, no stable variance or standard variation would be available. The
consequence of an undefined variance would be that the portfolio does not apply.
Diversification and portfolio theory are based on the idea taking advantage of the
difference in variance. Fat tails with undefined second moments (variance) smash
the foundation on which the portfolio theory is built.
Using Oracle Crystal Ball software we learn that the log-distributions are not
normal, but follow a student t-distribution. In the Markowitz portfolio theory the
standard deviation of a portfolio is a function of the standard deviation, weights
and correlations of the components of the portfolio. Also, in the case of a student tdistribution, this equation holds. In Table 11.2 we present the correlations between
oil, stocks and bonds.
Perusal of the results for the entire period 19892010 reveals that the correlation between bonds and stocks is negative (-0.101). Also the correlation
between bonds and oil is negative and even smaller. However, during the whole
period the correlation between stocks and oil is positive (0.055).

11

Adding Oil to a Portfolio of Stocks and Bonds?

205

Table 11.2 The correlations between oil, stock and bonds during the period 19892010
Years
Bond-stock
Bond-oil
Stock-oil
1989
1990
1991
1992
1993
1994
1995
1996
1997
1998
1999
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
1989-2010

0.237
0.489
0.395
0.206
0.375
0.616
0.497
0.612
0.236
-0.273
0.272
-0.056
-0.124
-0.532
-0.330
-0.037
0.010
0.101
-0.385
-0.392
-0.298
-0.486
-0.101

0.009
-0.289
-0.267
-0.045
-0.055
-0.200
0.052
0.007
0.013
-0.043
-0.087
-0.152
-0.060
-0.183
0.141
0.073
-0.022
0.022
-0.032
-0.300
-0.412
-0.368
-0.143

-0.014
-0.347
-0.243
0.060
-0.033
-0.181
0.027
-0.048
-0.105
0.080
-0.032
-0.061
-0.065
0.147
-0.255
-0.099
-0.044
0.006
0.062
0.258
0.458
0.651
0.055

The correlations are not constant during the observed period. In the cases of
bonds and stocks, the correlation is negative in 10 years and positive in 12 years
and moves between -0.532 in 2002 and +0.616 in 1994 respectively. In 15 of the
22 yearly observations the correlation between bonds and oil is negative and
fluctuates from a minimum in 2009 of -0.412, to a maximum in 2003 of +0.141.
The correlation between stocks and oil in 13 years is negative with a minimum of
-0.347 in 1990 and in 11 years, positive with a maximum of +0.651 in 2010.
Next, in an optimisation exercise the ideal portfolio is determined in terms of
returns for a given risk level. Different portfolio compositions with varying percentages of stocks, bonds, and oil are considered. For each composition the return
and standard deviation is calculated according to portfolio theory. The total return
is given by:
X
r
w i ri
11:1
in which ri is the return of component i and wi the percentage of component i with
respect to the total portfolio. The variance of the total portfolio is
X
X
2 2
r2
w
r

2
wrwrq
11:2
i
i
i
i6j i i j j ij

206

A. Dorsman et al.

Table 11.3 Oil as a safe


haven for stockholders and/or
bondholders

Parameter

Mean

t-value

a
b0
b1
b2
b3
b4
b5
b6
b7
Durbin-Watson

0.001
-0.066
-1.003
1.691
-0.129
-0.363
-0.657
2.244
-4.843
2.04

1.802
-1.551
-0.984
1.443
-0.105
-4.694
-0.333
1.021
-1.549

in which ri is the standard deviation of component i and the correlation qij between
components i and j. The return is plotted against the standard deviation in a cluster of
points in which each point is a certain composition. The efficient frontier follows
from the upper line of this cloud of points. The market portfolio follows from the
composition with the highest expected return-risk ratio in which the gain is the
difference between the return of the portfolio and the return of US Treasury bonds.
After the quick scan of the individual graphs of bonds, stocks, and oil and the
descriptive statistics of the individual variables, we now look at advanced modelling techniques that allow for the inclusion of fat tail phenomena, tail dependence, and micro-correlations are required. Due to the fact that we look at the
attributive value of oil to a portfolio of bonds and stocks we take the oil price as
response variable (dependent variable) and the bonds price and stock price as
explanatory variables (independent variables). We also add to the equation
quantile variables to test the influence of extreme variables.
To test hypothesis H1 we estimate the parameters of the following equation:
Roil a b0 Rstock; q100 b1 Rstock; q10 b2 Rstock; q5
b3 R stock; q1 b4 Rbond; q100 b5 Rbond; q10
b6 Rbond; q5 b7 R bond; q1 e

11:3

Where:
R (oil) = the log-return of oil
R (stock, qx) = log return of stocks that are in the x % lower quantile
R (bond, qy) = log return of bonds that are in the y % lower quantile
e = error term
In case of a safe haven all the parameters b0,, b7 have to be negative. A
negative value means that the associated parameter is a hedge for oil.
In Table 11.3 we present the test results of Eq. (11.3). Only b4 is significantly
different from zero.3 Therefore we do not reject hypothesis H1 (that oil is not a
3

The values found for R2 are irrelevant for Eq. (11.3) since the function is only locally linear
and not globally. Calculating the adjusted R only makes sense when the function is linear over the
whole domain of variables.

11

Adding Oil to a Portfolio of Stocks and Bonds?

Table 11.4 Oil as a hedge


for stockholders and/or
bondholders

207

Parameter

Mean

t-value

a
b1
b2
Durbin-Watson
Adjusted R2

0.000
0.089
-0.585
2.02
0.0222

1.390
3.147
-10.597

safe haven for stockholders and bondholders). When we apply the Brent Oil future
(code: OILBREN) instead of the WTI future we obtain the same conclusions when
testing hypothesis H1.
We use the following regression equationn to test our hypothesis H2 (that oil is
not a hedge for stockholders and bondholders).
R oil a b1 R stock b2 R bond e

11:4

Where:
R (oil) = the log-return of oil
R (stock) = log return of stocks
R (bond) = log return of bonds
e = error term
If oil is a hedge for stockholders and bondholders, the variables b1 and b2 are
\= 0.
Based on these results we reject hypotheses H2 (that oil is not a hedge for
stockholders and bondholders) in case of stocks as well as bonds. Also in testing
hypothesis H2 we used also Brent Oil instead of WTI. This replacement had no
influence on our conclusions. In Table 11.4, the adjusted R2 is close to zero which
means that the uncertainty of the coefficients a, b1 and b2 is high. Consequently,
the conclusions regarding H2 are not reliable.
In Fig. 11.2 we present the efficient frontier in the cases of stocks and bonds and
stocks, bonds and oil respectively. Tables 11.5 and 11.6 present for the various
sub-periods the weights of the components in the market portfolio in case this
portfolio does not contain respectively contains an investment in oil.
Figure 11.2 shows that adding oil to a portfolio of stocks and bonds means that
the efficient frontier moves upwards. From Table 11.5 we see that the optimal
portfolio without oil has 24 % stocks, 76 % bonds, an expected return of 0.0032, a
standard deviation of 0.000025 and an expected return-risk ratio of 11.9. The
optimal portfolio with oil, Table 11.6, has 6 % oil, 21 % stocks, 73 % bonds, an
average return of 0.00032, a standard deviation of 0.000022 and an expected
return-risk ratio of 14.0. Comparing the two portfolios, we see a small reduction of
risk and a small (nearly zero) increment of return when we add oil to the portfolio.
When we apply oil Brent future (code: OILBREN) instead of WTI (see appendix
Tables A4) we see that the optimal portfolio with oil has 8 % oil, 15 % stocks,
77 % bonds, an average return of 0.000189 a standard deviation of 0.0000254 and
an expected return-risk ratio of 7.1. The addition of Oil Brent futures exhibits a
greater change in the efficient frontier.

208

A. Dorsman et al.

Fig. 11.2 The efficient frontier for portfolios of stocks and bonds (lower graph) and the efficient
frontier for portfolios of oil, stocks and bonds (top graph) over period 1989 till 2010
Table 11.5 The weights of stock and bonds in the market portfolio without oil for each of the
sub-periods
Period
Stock (%) Bond (%) Mean
Standard deviation Expected return-risk ratio
19891998
19901999
19912000
19922001
19932002
19942003
19952004
19962005
19972006
19982007
19992008
20002009
20012010
19892010

27
31
25
24
20
24
23
23
22
22
14
16
21
24

73
69
75
76
80
76
77
77
78
78
86
84
79
76

4.9E-04
4.2E-04
4.3E-04
3.5E-04
3.4E-04
3.2E-04
3.7E-04
2.9E-04
2.9E-04
2.6E-04
2.5E-04
2.3E-04
2.0E-04
3.2E-04

2.4E-05
2.5E-05
2.3E-05
2.4E-05
2.4E-05
2.5E-05
2.4E-05
2.3E-05
2.1E-05
2.0E-05
2.4E-05
2.6E-05
2.6E-05
2.5E-05

19.8
15.7
17.4
13.7
13.5
12.0
14.9
11.7
13.1
12.2
10.0
8.4
7.5
12.9

Our third hypothesis is H3 (that the efficient frontier will not change when we add
oil as an alternative investment opportunity for the components stocks and bonds).
Based on our results we accept this hypothesis. Holders of portfolios of stocks and
bonds can improve their expected return-risk ratio by adding oil to their portfolio.
To test our fourth hypothesis, (that the market portfolio of oil, bonds and stocks
is constant during the observed period), we examine the weights of the portfolios
for every sub-period of 10 years. We started with the period 19891998, then
19901999, etc. till 20012010. In Tables 11.5 and 11.6 we present also the
weights of oil, stock and bonds for these sub-periods. The weight of oil moves
from 4 % (several sub-periods) to 8 % (20012010). We do not reject the fourth
hypothesis. Holders of portfolios of stocks and bonds who want to diversify their
portfolio with oil could opt for a 6 % oil, 21 % stock and 73 % bond split. This
distribution is more or less stable during the observed period.

11

Adding Oil to a Portfolio of Stocks and Bonds?

209

Table 11.6 The weights of oil, stock and bonds in the market portfolio for each of the subperiods
Period
Oil (%)
Stock (%)
Bond (%)
Mean
Standard
Expected
deviation
return-risk ratio
19891998
19901999
19912000
19922001
19932002
19942003
19952004
19962005
19972006
19982007
19992008
20002009
20012010
19892010

4
5
4
4
5
6
5
6
5
7
7
7
8
6

27
30
24
23
18
22
22
22
21
20
12
14
17
21

69
65
72
73
77
72
73
72
74
73
81
79
75
73

4.6E-04
4.0E-04
4.1E-04
3.4E-04
3.4E-04
3.2E-04
3.7E-04
2.9E-04
2.9E-04
2.8E-04
2.7E-04
2.5E-04
2.3E-04
3.2E-04

2.2E-05
2.3E-05
2.2E-05
2.3E-05
2.2E-05
2.3E-05
2.2E-05
2.2E-05
2.0E-05
1.9E-05
2.3E-05
2.4E-05
2.5E-05
2.2E-05

20.6
16.8
18.1
14.2
14.2
13.0
15.8
12.8
14.0
14.0
11.5
9.7
8.9
14.0

11.5 Summary and Conclusions


Over the last two decades, institutional investors have been diversifying their
portfolios by including therein investments in commodities. One of the main
commodities is oil. For benchmark reasons the market also developed commodity
indices.
In this chapter we have looked at the impact of adding oil to a portfolio made up
of stocks and bonds on the set of efficient portfolios. To derive the set of efficient
portfolios, three value based indices have been used: Government bonds S&P 500
for stocks and West Texas Intermediate for oil. Our choice of a value based index
for stocks and bonds is based on the same rationale as for the CRISP data base,
namely to avoid the complex tax treatment of dividend and interest payments.
The conclusions are as follows:
1. Not with standing adding oil to a portfolio of stocks and/or bonds mitigates the
negative portfolio returns in case of extreme negative stock and/or bond returns,
oil is not a safe haven.
2. However, a second finding shows that although oil cannot be considered as a
safe haven, oil can serve as a hedge for both stocks and bonds.
3. Finally, adding oil to a portfolio of stocks and bonds improves the risk-return
trade-off of the efficient frontier. So, for a fixed expected return we get less risk
and/or for a fixed risk we get more expected return.
4. During the period 20012010 the distribution of oil (6 %), stocks (21 %) and
bonds (73 %) in the portfolio are more or less stable.

210

A. Dorsman et al.

During the observed period 19892011 the markets were confronted with a
serious price falls. These occurred in the option markets in 1989, the internet crisis
in 20012002 and the financial crisis in 20072008 and the euro-crisis in
20102011. The impact of the first two crises on the real world was limited, while
the last two crises seriously damaged global markets and therefore affected also the
oil price.
Also we see that emerging markets (for example the BRIC and next-11
countries) and commodity countries like Australia show a different economic
development than the mature countries in Europe and the US. This study was limit
to US-based data. Further study has to show whether the results found in this
chapter also can be found for other periods and other countries.

A.1 Appendix
Table A.1 Descriptive statistics of the daily log returns of oil for every year during the observed
period 19892010
Year
Mean (%) Median (%) Standard deviation (%) Minimum (%) Maximum (%)
1989
1990
1991
1992
1993
1994
1995
1996
1997
1998
1999
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
19892010

0.0906
0.1015
-0.1521
0.0075
-0.1223
0.0869
0.0369
0.1076
-0.1475
-0.1460
0.2887
0.0176
-0.1152
0.1735
0.0159
0.1106
0.1307
0.0001
0.1734
-0.2925
0.2208
0.0540
0.0291

0.1555
0.0000
0.0000
0.0000
-0.1450
0.0841
0.0000
0.2204
-0.1136
-0.1789
0.3224
0.1779
0.0000
0.0767
0.0000
0.1609
0.0707
0.0474
0.1233
-0.0707
0.1269
0.0000
0.0000

2.1807
3.7504
3.5109
1.2312
1.5353
1.7942
1.2575
2.4417
1.7758
2.8957
2.1848
2.6968
2.6915
2.1525
2.4389
2.2517
1.9894
1.7194
1.9171
3.8357
3.3682
1.7110
2.4480

-14.5131
-17.4480
-40.0478
-7.1345
-6.7555
-7.1924
-6.2365
-9.1199
-4.5261
-11.5463
-7.1541
-12.9400
-16.5445
-6.2753
-11.5404
-7.6977
-4.8965
-4.3478
-4.7942
-12.5952
-13.0654
-5.1170
-40.0478

8.6385
13.5724
12.6819
4.9381
4.7982
6.5426
3.3114
9.4076
5.3060
14.2309
6.5372
8.1129
8.0748
6.1330
6.3004
5.9621
6.7362
5.2189
7.3689
16.4097
13.1363
4.1633
16.4097

11

Adding Oil to a Portfolio of Stocks and Bonds?

211

Table A.2 Descriptive statistics of the daily log returns of stocks for every year during the
observed period 19892010
Year
Mean (%) Median (%) Standard deviation (%) Minimum (%) Maximum (%)
1989
1990
1991
1992
1993
1994
1995
1996
1997
1998
1999
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
19892010

0.1059
-0.0121
0.1019
0.0280
0.0368
0.0050
0.1227
0.0789
0.1103
0.0963
0.0732
-0.0367
-0.0485
-0.0957
0.0966
0.0394
0.0184
0.0564
0.0205
-0.1763
0.0900
0.0538
0.0347

0.1212
0.0812
0.0000
0.0073
0.0038
0.0159
0.0864
0.0381
0.1062
0.1090
0.0000
-0.0134
0.0000
-0.1406
0.1008
0.0474
0.0496
0.0789
0.0590
0.0000
0.1428
0.0741
0.0336

0.8132
0.9976
0.8850
0.6008
0.5341
0.6095
0.4852
0.7315
1.1271
1.2595
1.1178
1.3780
1.3233
1.6073
1.0552
0.6855
0.6378
0.6211
0.9901
2.5385
1.6869
1.1184
1.1382

-6.3115
-3.0432
-3.7257
-1.8685
-2.4129
-2.2425
-1.5499
-3.1307
-7.1130
-7.0419
-2.8456
-6.0044
-5.0114
-4.2408
-3.5859
-1.6416
-1.6857
-1.8489
-3.5255
-9.4595
-5.4254
-3.9657
-9.4595

2.7386
3.1761
3.6641
1.5541
1.9198
2.1409
1.8609
1.9289
4.9894
4.9708
3.4830
4.6673
4.9007
5.5754
3.4849
1.6229
1.9557
2.1379
2.9009
10.9582
6.8575
4.3064
10.9582

Table A.3 Descriptive statistics of the daily log returns of bonds for every year during the
observed period 19892010
Year
Mean (%) Median (%) Standard deviation (%) Minimum (%) Maximum (%)
1989
1990
1991
1992
1993
1994
1995
1996
1997
1998
1999
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004

0.0666
0.0240
0.0648
0.0292
0.0609
-0.0297
0.1029
-0.0038
0.0534
0.0487
-0.0345
0.0707
0.0158
0.0594
0.0094
0.0283

0.0626
0.0000
0.0478
0.0232
0.0460
0.0000
0.0584
0.0000
0.0526
0.0395
-0.0291
0.0877
0.0326
0.0951
0.0812
0.0455

0.4691
0.5317
0.4391
0.4097
0.4592
0.6101
0.4956
0.5941
0.4714
0.5241
0.5348
0.4809
0.6475
0.6000
0.6627
0.5329

-1.6727
-2.1669
-1.3497
-0.9646
-1.2375
-3.1343
-1.6156
-2.8071
-1.6538
-2.1514
-1.8114
-1.2402
-2.1747
-1.7950
-2.0644
-2.1188

2.0513
1.6311
1.8120
1.3717
1.2663
2.0846
1.8163
1.4998
1.7770
1.4138
1.3261
1.4957
2.1312
1.7745
1.7125
1.8362
(continued)

212

A. Dorsman et al.

Table A.3 (continued)


Year
Mean (%) Median (%) Standard deviation (%) Minimum (%) Maximum (%)
2005
0.0241
2006
0.0072
2007
0.0362
2008
0.0832
2009
-0.0535
2010
0.0342
19892010
0.0317

0.0444
0.0422
0.0146
0.0475
0.0138
0.0182
0.0385

0.4551
0.3809
0.4960
0.8467
0.9465
0.8117
0.5815

-1.4505
-1.0720
-1.4191
-3.1728
-2.7796
-2.4081
-3.1728

1.0420
1.1992
1.7360
2.8990
3.8105
2.6871
3.8105

Table A.4 The weights of oil, stock and bonds in the market portfolio for each of the subperiods
Period
Oil (%) Stock (%) Bond (%) Mean
Standard
Expected return-risk
deviation ratio
19891998
19901999
19912000
19922001
19932002
19942003
19952004
19962005
19972006
19982007
19992008
20002009
20012010
19892010

4
5
3
4
5
5
4
5
5
7
7
8
10
6

27
30
25
23
18
23
22
22
21
20
13
14
17
22

69
65
72
73
77
72
74
73
74
73
80
78
73
72

4.6E-04
4.0E-04
4.1E-04
3.4E-04
3.4E-04
3.2E-04
3.7E-04
2.9E-04
2.9E-04
2.8E-04
2.7E-04
2.5E-04
2.4E-04
3.2E-04

2.1E-05
2.3E-05
2.2E-05
2.3E-05
2.3E-05
2.4E-05
2.3E-05
2.2E-05
2.0E-05
1.9E-05
2.3E-05
2.4E-05
2.5E-05
2.2E-05

20.7
16.8
17.9
14.2
14.1
12.8
15.7
12.7
14.0
14.1
11.3
9.7
9.3
14.1

References
Arouri, M. E. H., & Nguyen, D. G. (2010). Oil prices, stock markets and portfolio investment:
Evidence from sector analysis in Europe over the last decade. Energy Policy, 38(8),
45284539.
Baur, D.G., & Lucey, B.M. (2009). Is gold a hedge or a safe haven? An analysis of stocks, bonds
and gold, working paper
Baur, D. G., & Dermott, T. K. (2010). Is gold a safe haven? Journal of Banking and Finance, 34,
18861898.
Chua, A. (1999). The role of international real estate in global mixed-asset investment portfolios.
Journal of Real Estate Portfolio Management, 3(2), 129137.
Geman, H., & Kharoubi, C. (2008). WTI crude oil futures in portfolio diversification: The timeto-maturity effect. Journal of Banking and Finance, 32(12), 25532559.
Kousky, C., & Cooke, R.M. (2009). The unholy trinity: fat tails, tail dependence, and microcorrelations. RFF Discussion paper, November (rev.) 2009. Washington DC, Resources for
the Future

11

Adding Oil to a Portfolio of Stocks and Bonds?

213

Letzelter, J.C. (2005). Finding the efficient frontier: Power plant portfolio assessment.
Proceedings of the 2005 Crystal Ball User Conference, June 13, 2005
Mandelbrot, B. (1963). The variation of certain speculative prices. Journal of Business, 36,
394419.
Mandelbrot, B. (1966). Forecasts of future prices, unbiased markets and martingale models.
Journal of Business, 39, 242255.
ONeill, J. (2001). Building better global economic BRICs, Global Economic papers no: 66,
Goldman Sachs
Resnick, S. (2007). Heavy tailed phenomenal: Probabilistic and statistical modelling. New York:
Springer.
Umutlu, G., Dorsman, A., & Telatar, E. (2011). Day-ahead market and futures market. In A.B.
Dorsman et al. (Eds.), Financial Aspects in Energy (pp. 109128). London: Springer

Chapter 12

Imperfection of Electricity Networks


Andr Dorsman, Geert Jan Franx and Paul Pottuijt

Abstract In the past, energy networks (grids) were nationally organized. The
grids were linked by interconnectors. The capacities of the interconnectors were
limited and only used to counter an imbalance in one of the grids. Governments
fixed the prices and there was no energy price risk. Liberalization of the market
introduced prices that fluctuate every moment; with the liberalization, energy price
risk was introduced. The more volatile the energy prices, the larger the risk for
market participants. Market coupling links the former nationally organized
markets, which may cause a reduction in the volatility of the energy prices. At first
the TSOs (Transmission System Operators) sold connector capacity by so called
explicit auction, separate from the electricity auction. With the mechanism of
explicit auction it was relatively easy to realize a market based allocation of scarce
limited interconnector capacity on adjacent borders. Explicit auctions however do
not realize the optimal result. In due time, they are replaced by so-called implicit
auctions where the interconnectors capacities are automatically allocated in such
a way that electricity price differences between countries are minimized. This
implicit mechanism is also referred to as market coupling. In this chapter the effect
of market coupling on market prices is investigated in the observed period,
1 January 200531 March 2011, for Scandinavia (South), The Netherlands,
Belgium and France. It is found that due to market coupling the price differences
between the markets diminish.
Keywords Electricity market

 Interconnectors  Coupling  Perfect markets

A. Dorsman (&)  G. J. Franx


VU University Amsterdam, Amsterdam, The Netherlands
e-mail: a.b.dorsman@vu.nl
P. Pottuijt
Gen B.V, Utrecht, The Netherlands

A. Dorsman et al. (eds.), Energy Economics and Financial Markets,


DOI: 10.1007/978-3-642-30601-3_12, Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg 2013

215

216

A. Dorsman et al.

12.1 Introduction
In a perfect market all buyers and sellers have access to the same price information
and they can exercise their transactions orders against the same conditions (Porter
1980). To realize the best position for the buyers and sellers all trade has to be
concentrated as much as possible. Pagano (1989) argues that since the depth of
liquidity of a market depends on the entry decisions of all potential participants,
each trader assesses them according to conjectures about entry by others. He
argues that if trade is equally costly across markets, this externality leads to the
concentration of trade in one market. Stoll (2001) discusses the problem of market
fragmentation. This topic arose in the USA where several option markets developed. He wrote that heads of Goldman Sachs, Merrill Lynch and other companies
testified on the need for a central order book. Also in Europe a need is felt to
concentrate market transactions. For example, in The Netherlands in the sixties of
the last century the law determined that all transactions have to be traded on the
Amsterdam stock exchange, now Euronext Amsterdam. However, by doing so not
only the liquidity improves, but also monopolies are being created. A monopoly
does not feel the necessity to invest in new developments.
After the merger in 2000 between the stock exchanges of Amsterdam, Brussels
and Paris there was a need for one law for the new entity. The Dutch law was
adjusted and became in line with the French law. One substantial change was that
the condition that every buyer and seller in The Netherlands has to trade on the
Amsterdam Stock Exchange (Euronext Amsterdam) was skipped. On 1 November
2007 The European Union (EU) introduced the Markets in Financial Instruments
Directive (MIFID). The effect of MIFID was that new markets were allowed.
Alternative markets make use of this change in the law. In 2006 ChI-X started
and in 2011 TOM. By using cheaper ICT systems these new markets could
compete with Euronext. The condition of Pagano that trade was equally costly
across markets was no longer met. Cost-based competition between markets leads
to better prices for the market traders. In 2010, Chi-X was the second stock
exchange after the London Stock Exchange in terms of volume of trades in Europe
(Menkveld 2011).
The European electricity markets are more or less in the same situation as the
stock markets fifty years ago. Creating one market where all the bids and asks are
concentrated gives the best prices and contributes to market transparency.
Historically the electricity networks (grids) were nationally organized. The general
policy today is to link the several electricity markets to get the best prices.
Liberalization of the European electricity market started in Norway in 1991.1 In
that year the Norwegian Parliaments decision to deregulate the market for trading
of electricity became operational. In 1993 Statnett Marked AS was established as
an independent company. After a joint venture with Sweden, the company was
1

Information about the history of Nord Pool can be found on http://www.nordpoolspot.com/


about/history

12

Imperfection of Electricity Networks

217

renamed as Nord Pool ASA. Finland joined in 1998. In 2004 and 2007 respectively, East Denmark and West Denmark joined Nord Pool. In this chapter
Scandinavia is referred to instead of the countries Norway, Sweden, Finland and
Denmark. Other European countries followed Scandinavia in the process of
liberalization. Among the first followers was The Netherlands. The Dutch electricity market has started with the modification of the Electricity Act in 1999. The
approach of liberalizing the Dutch electricity market was a phased approach,
where the first step was to open the wholesale markets for competition, followed
by a second phase focusing on smaller scale industries/large business, and finalized
by a third stage of opening of the market for small businesses and domestic
customers. Looking at the power exchanges, it can now be said that Nord Pool
(Scandinavia) and APX (The Netherlands) are also among the front-runners. The
advantage of APX is that it is situated more in the geographical center of Europe.
In the past the location of the power market was not important. Every country
had its own network (grid). However, with the liberalization the wish to create an
efficient electricity market in Europe became stronger. To realize this goal it was
necessary to reduce the hurdles (imperfections). However, electricity has some
special physical characteristics impacting the trading and price formation
(Shahidehpour and Alomoush 2001).
Compared to stocks and bonds, the law of one price does not hold. The price of
electricity depends on time and location. On top of that, electricity is not easy to
store. Geographical barriers can influence the building of the grid. In flat countries
like (large parts of Belgium) and The Netherlands the construction of the grid is
easier than in countries like Italy, where it is difficult to cross the Apennines with
cables. The grids in flat countries are therefore more comparable to the web of a
spider, while in countries like Italy the physical form of the grid is more comparable to a lattice. The construction of a spider web is less sensitive to local
power problems than the construction of a lattice. It is not surprising that there was
an increase of interconnectors mainly between flat countries, such as the Southern
part of Norway, The Netherlands, Belgium, France and Germany. From a technical
perspective they are easier to realize than in mountainous areas.
The TSO of every country is responsible for the power balance in the grid at
any moment. Two developments make this responsibility more difficult; namely
the process of connecting the grids and the increase in solar and wind energy.
In the past, interconnectors were only used to avoid imbalances in one of the
grids. With the liberalization of the electricity markets, the capacity of interconnectors became available for market participants by explicit auction. The sale of
the capacity of interconnectors to market participants reduces the opportunities for
the TSOs to get their grid in balance. The supply of solar and wind energy is not
constant over time. If the sun shines, the supply of solar energy is high, otherwise
the supply of solar power is much lower or zero. It is similar for wind energy.
The TSO has to manage this volatility in supply. If solar and wind energy
represent only a small part of the total supply of electricity, this volatility is easy to
manage. However, the larger the contribution of solar and wind energy in total, the
more difficult the task of the TSOs. It is easier to manage the fluctuations in wind

218

A. Dorsman et al.

and solar energy in a large market than in several relatively small markets. From
this perspective, the physical integration of networks is important too. For
example, if wind production creates overproduction (compared to the demand) in
one grid, the characteristic of electricity that it cannot be stored, leads to the
situation that the overproduction needs to be transported outside that particular
grid. In the case that that cannot be done, the imbalance in supply in that grid leads
to grid-instability risk or even black-outs.
Interconnectors between grids can function as an exit point in such situations of
overproduction due to renewable energy (e.g. the situation where there is too much
wind/solar energy). Ideally, the interconnectors are of such capacity that they can
always make sure a surplus of generated energy can be transported away from the
grid(s) where there is overproduction.
A very interesting example in this respect is the plan of Belgian and German TSOs
to construct the first interconnector between Belgium and Germany. Historically,
there has not been such an interconnector (possibly due to a geographical hurdle: The
Ardennes), but the actual development of increasing grid integration makes it timely
for this newly-planned interconnector. On the one hand, it can contribute to enhanced
grid security/stability (see above) but it can also contribute to enhanced trading
market integration (more possibilities to trade between trading zones). With this
development, the traditional nationally orientated networks are now becoming interlinked grids where TSOs have a shared responsibility for the European network.
The goal of the liberalization of the electricity markets is to get good working
electricity markets with efficient electricity prices. In such a market, all relevant
information is direct and fully absorbed in the prices. The efficiency of markets can
be promoted by reducing hurdles (imperfections) to bring demand and supply
together. One of the hurdles is that market participants have a substantial influence
on the price. These market participants can cause a deviation from the efficient
price. In other words, liberalization of the power markets does not only mean the
start of a power exchange, but also means that enough participants individually can
have no influence on the price; they are price takers. Another hurdle is the
interconnector capacity between the grids. If their capacity is limited, the price
development of the several grids can also deviate from optimal price development.
Before proceeding to the next section, a distinction must be made between two
methods of auctions for interconnector capacity, namely the methods of explicit and
implicit auction. A more detailed description between these two auction types can be
found in Dorsman et al. (2011). In short these mechanisms comprise the following:

12.1.1 Explicit Auctions


Under an explicit auction, market participants can bid for the TSO offered transmission capacity for transporting electricity between adjacent markets. Transmission capacity can be offered via an explicit auction mechanism for long-term
capacity (yearly and monthly auctions), for day-ahead capacity and for intra-day

12

Imperfection of Electricity Networks

219

capacity. For this chapter the focus is only on day-ahead capacity since this is by
far the most liquid, transparent and representative market.
After acquiring the transmission capacity via the explicit day-ahead auction, the
market participant can start scheduling the import or export energy flows that they
want to execute. Explicit auctioning mechanisms produce sub-optimal outcomes
(see Dorsman et al. 2011).

12.1.2 Implicit Auctions


On the implicit market, the TSOs do not offer the capacity to individual market
participants, but put it at the disposal of linking international day-ahead energy
markets. This means that no individual participants options are created as in the
explicit auction. The TSO offers interconnector capacity to the trading zones
participating in an implicit market coupling scheme and not to individual market
participants. Under implicit auctions, the market participants put their bids and
asks at the Local Power Exchange. These bids and offers are amongst others based
on the published available interconnector capacities, but are also based on price
influencing factors such as weather. Based on the order books of PXs (power
exchanges) and based on the available interconnector capacities, the implicit
auction then determines the optimal energy flows and prices in the region of
participating trading zones.
The implicit market contributes more to a perfect market because the interconnector capacities are not given to the market parties directly, which might
cause different usage of (scarce) capacity compared to what is most desirable from
the perspective of social economic welfare (see Dorsman et al. 2011). Implicit
market coupling also leads to more competitive energy markets since it provides a
higher/clearer level of transparency and also removes entry barriers connected to
cross-border trade. Cross-border trade initially was a two-step activity under the
explicit auction mechanism (acquiring capacity and then scheduling the energy
flow), but has now become a one-step activity under the implicit auction mechanism (only trading at the local power exchange is needed).
The structure of the remainder of this chapter is as follows. Data description will
take place in Sect. 12.2. In Sect. 2.3 the research hypotheses are postulated. Section 12.4 contains the results of the empirical study. Summary and conclusions are
part of Sect. 12.5.

12.2 Data
Day-ahead prices are obtained from APX-Endex for the Dutch market, from
Belpex for the Belgian Market, from Epexspot for the French market and from
Nord Pool for the Scandinavian market. The observed period is 1 January 2005

220

A. Dorsman et al.

until 31 March 2011. This period has been chosen because the following events
could be analyzed.
1. 21 November 2006: Market coupling of Belgium, France and The
Netherlands
2. 5 May 2008: NorNed cable
3. 9 November 2009: Implicit coupling2 on cables of Germany and the Nordic
region.
4. 9 November 2010: implicit coupling of Belgium, France, The Netherlands,
Germany and Luxembourg. Interim implicit coupling between regions CWENordic.
5. 1 April 2011: BritNed cable.
1. 21 November 2006: Market coupling of Belgium, France
and The Netherlands
This event is important because individual energy markets already existed in
the separate regions. These markets were, however, connected via the
sub-optimal mechanism of explicit auctions and also the maturity of the
markets was not as it is today. With the start of the market coupling between
these markets, the worlds first implicit market coupling became a fact,
realizing an integrated and increased trading region.
2. 5 May 2008: NorNed cable
The study of this event is important, since a new connection (that is, the
580 km underwater NorNed cable) enables direct trading of electricity
between the Nordic region and the Dutch markets. The impact of this cable on
the both markets is significant; on the one hand the cable allows the Dutch
market to import cheap hydro-power during peak-hours. On the other hand,
the cable allows the surplus of Dutch coal-based electricity during nighttime
hours to be used in the Nordic market, which saves usage of hydro-power
electricity during those hours. This saved hydro-power electricity can be used
at moments with higher power demands. Although started as an explicit
auction, the coupling of the Nordic market with the energy markets in continental Europe has already led to very good results in optimizing price formation and usage of scarce interconnection capacity between the participating

CWE and Nordic market regions were coupled based on an interim implicit coupling
mechanism since a quick solution for implicit market coupling of these regions needed to be
available at the time of starting CWE MC. This interim solution produces better results than the
other available solution at that time for coupling the regions concerned, which was not sufficient
to be continued when CWE MC would GO-live. The interim variant for coupling CWE and
Nordic regions is planned to be replaced by an enduring solution (NWE Enduring market
coupling) that will realize the final, optimal results for coupling CWE, Nordic (and also UK)
markets.

12

Imperfection of Electricity Networks

221

markets. The second step goal of the NorNed cable is to include it in an


explicit auctioning mechanism (see Event 4).
3. 9 November 2009: Implicit coupling on cables in Germany and the Nordic
region
This event is of interest since it can tell more about the market impacts due to
the implementation of an implicit market coupling schema on the already
existing cables between Germany and Denmark, and between Germany and
Sweden.
4. 9 November 2010: implicit coupling of Belgium, France, The Netherlands,
Germany and Luxembourg. Interim implicit coupling between regions
CWE-Nordic.
This event is important to study since it can be considered as the largest step
taken so far in European market integration. Not only does it mean the
extension of the implicit market coupling scheme from the Trilateral Market
Coupling (TLC) region (which includes Belgium, France and The Netherlands)
to the Central Western European region (CWE), this step also involves the
implementation of an interim implicit market coupling scheme between the
CWE and Nordic region.
5. 1 April 2011: BritNed cable
Before April 2011, there was no cable for direct electricity trading between
The Netherlands and the UK. Although market characteristics between these
two countries are not that fundamentally different as they are between The
Netherlands and the Nordic Region, it is certainly expected that that the
connection of the BritNed cable to the continental electricity markets will
have an impact on markets functioning at both ends of the cable.
In order to avoid seasonal effects, the influence of an event on the prices and
volatilities is investigated by comparing the data over a period of one year before
and one year after the event. Events 3, 4 and 5 are important in the context of the
efficiency of European energy markets. However, these three events are not
investigated in this study because the instances of the events are too late in time in
order to obtain sufficient data. With regard to Event 3 the necessary data from
Denmark and Germany could not be obtained. Therefore this chapter is event.

12.3 Research Hypotheses


As mentioned, the Nordic region had an integrated, functioning energy market
since 1991. In continental Europe, energy markets at that time were not even
liberalized. Around the turn of the century European energy markets became more
liberalized and developed to locally organized markets. The market coupling
process started on 21 November 2006 with the trilateral market coupling (TLC) of
the power exchanges in Belgium, France and The Netherlands. This trilateral
market coupling was followed by several market integration events within the

222

A. Dorsman et al.

continental European market and between the continental European and the Nordic
regions.
In this chapter the following issues are examined. It is important to consider
whether or not:
1. Market coupling reduces the difference in daily price volatility between the
grids.
2. Market coupling reduces the price difference between the grids.
The supply of electricity in The Netherlands is very inflexible, which causes
high peak and low off-peak prices. In Scandinavia, electricity is generated by
means of hydro-power. Therefore, the storage of electricity is easier and cheaper in
Norway than in The Netherlands. Linking the Scandinavian and the Dutch systems
will have an equalizing influence on the price of electricity in The Netherlands,
which means that the gap between peak and off-peak prices will decrease. The
hours 8:0020:00 are peak hours and 0:008:00 h plus 20:0024:00 h are off-peak
hours.
The off-peak prices in The Netherlands are lower than in Scandinavia. During
night-time, electricity flows from The Netherlands to Scandinavia. Since on
average the electricity price in Scandinavia is substantially lower, it can be seen
that, in The Netherlands during daytime, the electricity flows from Scandinavia to
The Netherlands and during nighttime the flow is in reverse.
The first hypothesis to test is:
H1 Market coupling does not influence the difference in daily price volatility
between the grids.
In this study, daily price volatility is defined as the sample standard deviation
over a 24 h period (24 prices).
Also the influence of market coupling on off-peak and peak prices is investigated. In the case where market coupling has an effect on prices, it is expected that
the electricity prices of the relevant grids show a larger co-movement and a
smaller difference during off-peak and peak hours.
H2 Market coupling does not influence the price difference during off-peak hours
between the grids.
H3 Market coupling does not influence the price difference during peak hours
between the grids.
Note that every coupling has its own dynamics. For example, the coupling
between Scandinavia and The Netherlands will differ from the coupling between
The Netherlands, Belgium and France. Differences in price formation and also
differences in power generation in each country/region make every coupling
unique. Therefore, the hypotheses must be tested for every specific coupling
moment.

12

Imperfection of Electricity Networks

(a)

223

Difference in Daily Volatility Netherlands - France

400,00

EUR

300,00

200,00

100,00

0,00

-100,00

-200,00

-300,00

-400,00

-500,00

-600,00

(b)

Price Difference Netherlands-France (Off Peak)

EUR

100,00

50,00

0,00

-50,00

-100,00

-150,00

-200,00

-250,00

Fig. A.1 The difference in volatility (a), off-peak prices (b) and peak prices (c) between The
Netherlands and France in the period 21 November 200521 November 2007

224

A. Dorsman et al.

(c)

Price Difference Netherlands-France (Peak)

200,00

EUR

150,00

100,00

50,00

0,00

-50,00

-100,00

Fig. A.1 continued

12.4 Empirical Research


12.4.1 Event 1: 21 November 2006: Market Coupling Between
Belgium, France and The Netherlands
Before 21 November 2006, there was no electricity market in Belgium. Therefore,
only the markets in The Netherlands and France can be compared before and after
the moment of coupling.
Figure A.1 plots the difference in the volatility (Fig. A.1a), the price difference
during off peak hours (Fig. A.1b) and during peak hours (Fig. A.1c) between The
Netherlands and France in the period 21 November 200521 November 2007. To
avoid seasonal effects, a comparison is made between the full year before the
moment of coupling and the full year after the moment of coupling. Looking at
these graphs, the visual interpretation is that (ignoring outliers) the difference in
volatility and the difference in prices are smaller after the moment of coupling than
before. The results of the two-sample Kolmogorov test (Table 12.1) and the twosample Wilcoxon test (Table 12.1) are presented to underpin the visual
interpretation.
The two-sample Kolmogorov test compares two samples from different populations and tests the null-hypothesis that both populations have the same distribution function. This test does not require any specific shape of both population

12

Imperfection of Electricity Networks

225

Table 12.1 a Kolmogorov tests and b Wilcoxon tests on the difference in daily volatility,
difference in prices during off-peak and peak hours between The Netherlands and France, one
year before and one year after 21 November 2006
Daily Volatility
Off peak
Peak
Test statistics (NL-FR)
Most extreme differences

Absolute
Positive
Negative

KolmogorovSmirnov Z
Asymp. Sig. (2-tailed)
MannWhitney U
Wilcoxon W
Z
Asymp. Sig. (2-tailed)

0.441
0.044
-0.441
5.959
0.000

0.364
0.099
-0.364
4.923
0.000

0.463
0.049
-0.463
6.255
0.000

34,634.000
101,429.000
-11.225
0.000

48,353.000
115,148.000
-6.410
0.000

34115.000
100,910.000
-11.407
0.000

Grouping variable: year


Table 12.2 a Kolmogorov tests and b Wilcoxon tests on the difference in daily volatility,
difference in prices during off-peak and peak hours, between The Netherlands and Norway, one
year before and one year after 5 May 2008
Test statistics (NL-NO)
Daily volatility
Most extreme differences

KolmogorovSmirnov Z
Asymp. Sig. (2-tailed)
MannWhitney U
Wilcoxon W
Z
Asymp. Sig. (2-tailed)

Absolute
Positive
Negative

Off peak

Peak

0.129
0.066
-0.129
1.745
0.005

0.108
0.035
-0.108
1.455
0.029

0.181
0.063
-0.181
2.450
0.000

64,933.000
131,728.000
-0.652
0.514

60,479.500
127,274.500
-2.212
0.027

61,018.500
127,813.500
-2.024
0.043

Grouping variable: year

distributions, whereas the two-sample Wilcoxon test for equality of medians


requires two population distributions of the same shape. This condition is not
always met in this research. Especially Figs. A.3a, b and c show very differently
shaped distributions of the volatility and price differences between The Netherlands and France.
The Kolmogorov tests in Table 12.1 show significant differences between the
distribution in price differences, as well as in the difference in volatility, one year
before and one year after the moment of coupling, 21 November 2006. See also
Figs. A.3 which show fundamentally different cumulative distributions before and
after the event. The price and volatility differences decreased substantially after 21
November 2006. The Wilcoxon tests in Table 12.1 confirm these results. The data
therefore demonstrates that next to the harmonization of price levels due to the

226

A. Dorsman et al.
Difference in Daily Volatility Netherlands-Norway (KRS)

(a)
400,00

350,00

300,00

EUR

250,00

200,00

150,00

100,00

50,00

0,00

(b)

Price Difference Netherlands-Norway (Off Peak)

100,00

80,00

EUR

60,00

40,00

20,00

0,00

20,00-

40,00-

Fig. A.2 The difference in volatility (a), off-peak prices (b) and peak prices (c) between The
Netherlands and Norway in the period 5 May 20075 May 2009

market coupling, also a harmonization of price volatility can be observed. Especially the harmonization of price volatility confirms that one integrated market has

12

Imperfection of Electricity Networks

(c)

227

Price Difference Netherlands-Norway (Peak)

500,00

EUR

400,00

300,00

200,00

100,00

0,00

-100,00

Fig. A.2 continued

been realized after this first market coupling (harmonized volatility levels mean
that markets seem to mimic each other).

12.4.2 Event 2: 5 May 2008: NorNed Cable


Looking at the graphs of the differences in the volatility (Fig. A.2a), the prices
during off peak hours (Fig. A.2b) and the prices during peak hours (Fig. A.2c),
between The Netherlands and Norway in the period 5 May 20075 May 2009, the
visual interpretation is that, ignoring outliers, the differences in volatility and the
differences in prices are smaller after the moment of coupling than before,
although the differences are not as clear-cut as The NetherlandsFrance comparison The results of the Kolmogorov test (See Table 12.2) and the Wilcoxon test
(Table 12.2) are presented to underpin the visual interpretation.
The Kolmogorov tests in Table 12.2 show significant distribution differences
between 20072008 and 20082009, but with much higher p-values than was the
case in the NetherlandsFrance comparison. In Table 12.2, the Wilcoxon tests
show even less significant differences between 20072008 and 20082009. With
respect to the daily volatility, there is no significant difference between the
medians during the 20072008 and 20082009 periods. Figure A.4a (Appendix
A.4) gives more insight into the volatility differences. Although the medians
appear to differ little, the upper tails of both distributions differ a lot. Large
differences in volatility occurred only before 5 May 2008.

228

A. Dorsman et al.

(a)

Empirical Cumulative Distributions of the Daily Volatility Difference NL-FR


22 november 2005 -21 november 2006

22 november 2006 -21 november 2007

1,00

Cumulative Probablity P(X<=y)

0,90
0,80
0,70
0,60
0,50
0,40
0,30
0,20
0,10

-100,00

-75,00

-50,00

-25,00

0,00

25,00

50,00

75,00

100,00

Daily Volatility Difference NL-FR

(b)

Empirical Cumulative Distributions of the Price Difference NL-FR during Off Peak Hours
21 november 2005 -22 november 2006

22 november 2006 -21 november 2007

1,00

Cumulative Probablity P(X<=y)

0,90
0,80
0,70
0,60
0,50
0,40
0,30
0,20
0,10
0,00
-25,00

-20,00

-15,00

-10,00

-5,00

0,00

5,00

10,00

15,00

20,00

25,00

Price Difference NL-FR

Fig. A.3 Cumulative distributions difference between The Netherlands (NL) and France (FR) in
daily volatility (a), off-peak hours (b) and peak hours (c) one year before and one year after the
moment of coupling 21 November 2006

In Fig. A.3 the cumulative distributions of the difference between The


Netherlands and France in daily volatility (Fig. A.3a) and of the price difference
during off-peak (Fig. A.3b) and peak hours (Fig. A.3c) one year before and one
year after the moment of coupling on 21 November 2006 are presented. The
cumulative distributions shift to the left can be observed, which means that differences in volatility and the differences in off-peak and peak prices are becoming

12

Imperfection of Electricity Networks

(c)

229

Empirical Cumulative Distributions of the Price Difference NL-FR during Peak Hours
22 november 2005 - 21 november 2006

22 november 2006 - 21 november 2007

1,00

Cumulative Probablity P(X<=y)

0,90
0,80
0,70
0,60
0,50
0,40
0,30
0,20
0,10
0,00
-100,00

-75,00

-50,00

-25,00

0,00

25,00

50,00

75,00

100,00

Price Difference NL-FR

Fig. A.3 continued

smaller due to the market coupling. Looking at Fig. A.4a, a clear-cut switch to the
left cannot be observed for the differences in volatilities between The Netherlands
and Norway (apart from the upper tail). Therefore a closer examination was made
of the individual price developments in off-peak and peak hours for The Netherlands and Norway (See Fig. A.5). From a perusal of the Dutch figures it can be
seen that, except from some extremes/outliers, the connection of the NorNed cable
on 5 May 2008 had little impact on the volatility in the Netherlands. However, the
volatility in Norway increased significantly.
In Table 12.3 the KolmogorovSmirnov test and also the Wilcoxon test
(Table 12.3) show that this increase in volatility for Norway is significant. In
Table 12.3, the two sample Wilcoxon test gives the same picture.
The increase in volatility in Norway is in line with expectations. During peak
hours the flow goes from Norway to The Netherlands, which means that in Norway
the supply of electricity decreases when the price is high, resulting in higher prices
during peak hours. On the other hand, during off-peak hours the flow goes from
The Netherlands to Norway. In other words, when the electricity price in Norway
is low, the supply increases by the cable, resulting in lower prices during off-peak
hours. Due to the NorNed cable, the Norwegian volatility in electricity prices
increased substantially, because the price difference between peak and off-peak
hours increased significantly. This was not the case in The Netherlands, where
only the extreme volatilities disappeared after 5 May 2008.
Before the implicit coupling in Event 1 (Belgium, France and The Netherlands)
there was already an exchange of electricity between the countries (explicit
coupling). Therefore the impact of the introduction of implicit coupling was less
than in Event 2 (Norway and The Netherlands) where before the implicit coupling

230

A. Dorsman et al.

(a)

Empirical Cumulative Distributions of the Daily Volatility Difference NL-NO


6 may 2007 - 5 may 2008

6 may 2008 - 5 may 2009

1,00

Cumulative Probablity P(X<=y)

0,90
0,80
0,70
0,60
0,50
0,40
0,30
0,20
0,10
0,00
-25,00

0,00

25,00

50,00

75,00

100,00

125,00

150,00

Daily Volatility Difference NL-NO

(b)

Empirical Cumulative Distributions of the Price Difference NL-NO during Off Peak Hours
6 may 2007 - 5 may 2008

6 may 2008 - 5 may 2009

1,00

Cumulative Probablity P(X<=y)

0,90
0,80
0,70
0,60
0,50
0,40
0,30
0,20
0,10
0,00
-20,00 -15,00 -10,00 -5,00

0,00

5,00

10,00 15,00

20,00

25,00 30,00

35,00

40,00

45,00

50,00

Price Difference NL-NO

Fig. A.4 Cumulative distributions difference between The Netherlands (NL) and Norway (NO)
in daily volatility (a), off-peak hours (b) and peak hours (c) one year before and one year after the
moment of coupling 21 November 2006

no exchange in electricity between these two countries existed. It is possible that in


Event 2 traders could not immediately fully understand the (price) implications of
the implicit coupling and had to learn by doing.
In Event 2 statistical outcomes in the above analysis already demonstrate a
decrease in Dutch volatility and a decrease in the price difference (peak-prices)

12

Imperfection of Electricity Networks

(c)

231

Empirical Cumulative Distributions of the Price Difference NL-NO during Peak Hours
6 may 2007 - 5 may 2008

6 may 2008 - 5 may 2009

50,00

100,00

1,00

Cumulative Probablity P(X<=y)

0,90
0,80
0,70
0,60
0,50
0,40
0,30
0,20
0,10
0,00
-25,00

0,00

25,00

75,00

125,00

150,00

175,00

200,00

Price Difference NL-NO

Fig. A.4 continued


Table 12.3 a The Kolmogorov tests and b Wilcoxons tests on the daily volatility in the Dutch
and in the Norwegian electricity prices separately one year before and one year after 5 May 2008
NL volatility
NO volatility
Test statistics (NL-NO)
Most Extreme Differences

KolmogorovSmirnov Z
Asymp. Sig. (2-tailed)
MannWhitney U
Wilcoxon W
Z
Asymp. Sig. (2-tailed)

Absolute
Positive
Negative

0.097
0.097
-0.063
1.312
0.064

0.218
0.218
0.000
2.949
0.000

64,446.000
131,607.000
-0.823
0.411

46,684.000
113,845.000
-7.045
0.000

Grouping variable: year

between Norway and The Netherlands, both after the introduction of the NorNed
cable. The observed period for this event study is one year before the event and
one year after the event (T-1, T ? 1). Due to the effect of specifically choosing
the (T-1, T ? 1) approach for this chapter, the market learning effect after
introduction of such a fundamental change in the North-Western energy markets is
also included in the analysis/outcomes. Especially the first half-year after introduction of the NorNed cable could be qualified as being new to the market,
meaning that market participants still needed to find out the optimal usage and
value for them of the cable. If an event study had been set up for one year periods

232

A. Dorsman et al.

(a)

Empirical Cumulative Distributions of the Daily Volatility Netherlands


6 may 2007 - 5 may 2008

6 may 2008 - 5 may 2009

1,00

Cumulative Probablity P(X<=y)

0,90
0,80
0,70
0,60
0,50
0,40
0,30
0,20
0,10
0,00
0,00

25,00

50,00

75,00

100,00

125,00

150,00

Daily Volatility NL

(b)

Empirical Cumulative Distributions of the Daily Volatility Norway (Krs)


6 may 2007 - 5 may 2008

6 may 2008 - 5 may 2009

1,00
0,90
0,80
0,70

Title

0,60
0,50
0,40
0,30
0,20
0,10
0,00
0,00

5,00

10,00

15,00

Title

Fig. A.5 The volatility in Dutch electricity prices (a) and Norwegian electricity prices (b) during
period 5 May 20075 May 2009

before and after the introduction of the NorNed cable, but running in the periods
[T-1.5, T-0.5] and [T ? 0.5, T ? 1.5], the results would show even lower
volatility for the Dutch market and also an even lower price difference (peakprices) between Norway and The Netherlands. This strengthens the conclusions
drawn in Event 2.

12

Imperfection of Electricity Networks

233

12.5 Conclusion
In the past, the capacities of interconnectors were limited. After the liberalization
of the electricity markets these limitations became hurdles (imperfections) that
may cause inefficient electricity prices. In Europe it can be seen that the capacity
of existing interconnectors is enlarged and that new interconnectors are built. Also,
the way of auctioning the capacity of interconnectors has changed from explicit to
implicit auction which has led to more integrated markets. Five major events have
taken place during the last five years: The market coupling in Belgium, France and
The Netherlands; the NorNed cable; the implicit coupling on cables between
Germany and the Nordic region; the implicit coupling of Belgium, France, The
Netherlands, Germany and Luxembourg and the BritNed cable.
In this chapter the influence of Events 1 and 2, are analyzed: Market coupling
between Belgium, France and The Netherlands and the NorNed cable. The first
event reduces the differences in prices between The Netherlands and France during
off-peak and peak hours as well as the volatility in the price differences. Also, the
price differences between The Netherlands and Norway decreased significantly
after opening the NorNed cable. However due to the NorNed cable, Norwegian
prices during peak hours increased and during off-peak hours decreased, causing
the volatility to increase. Overall the NorNed cable creates value in Europe, but the
increasing daily volatility does not benefit the electricity consumers in Norway.
Overall it can be seen that an increasing integration of the European electricity
networks, reduces hurdles and creates a market where price inefficiencies are
decreasing.

References
Dorsman, A. B., van Montfort, K., & Pottuijt, P. (2011). Market perfection in a changing energy
environment. In A. Dorsman, W. Westerman, M. B. Karan, & . Arslan (Eds.), Financial
aspects in energy: A European perspective (pp. 7184). Heidelberg: Springer.
Feller, W. (1948). On the Kolmogorov-Smirnov limit theorems for empirical distributions.
Annals of Mathematical Statistics, 19, 177189.
Kolmogorov, A. N. (1933). Sulla determinazione empirica di una legge di distribuzione. Giornale
dellInstituto Itaiano degli Attuari, 4, 8391.
Mann, H. B., & Whitney, D. R. (1947). On a test of whether one of two random variables is
stochastically larger than the other. Annals of Mathematical Statistics, 18(1), 5060.
Massey, F. J, Jr. (1951). The Kolmogorov-Smirnov test of goodness of fit. Journal of the
American Statistical Association, 46, 6878.
Menkveld, A. J. (2011). High frequency trading and the new-market makers. Unpublished
manuscript. Retreived from http://ssrn.com/abstract=1722924.
Pagano, M. (1989). Trading volume and asset liquidity. Quarterly Journal of Economics., 104(2),
255274.
Porter, M. E. (1980). Competitive strategytechniques for analyzing industry and competitors.
New York: The Free Press.

234

A. Dorsman et al.

Shahidehpour, M., & Alomoush, M. (2001). Restructured electrical power systems: Operation,
trading, and volatility. New York: Marcel Dekker.
Smirnov, V. I. (1939). On the estimation of the discrepancy between empirical curves of
distribution for two independent samples. Bulletin Mathmatique de lUniversit de Moscou,
2, fasc. 2, 316.
Stoll, H. R. (2001). Market fragmentation. Financial Analysts Journal, 57(4), 1620.
Wilcoxon, F. (1945). Individual comparisons by ranking methods. Biometrics Bulletin, 1(6),
8083.

Chapter 13

Initial Public Offerings of Energy


Companies
Bill Dimovski

Abstract This study analyses 158 energy company initial public offerings (IPOs) in
Australia from January 1994 to December 2010, including the period of the global
financial crisis (GFC). The study finds that energy company IPOs had an average
22.0 % underpricing and that those IPOs that sought to raise more equity capital and
engaged underwriters had lower underpricing. There is also evidence that suggests
energy company IPOs that offered options to their underwriters had higher underpricing returns, effectively cancelling the lower underpricing effect of the underwriting itself. The energy IPOs that raised equity capital after the 2007/8 global
financial crisis do not appear to have offered on average, significantly different
underpricing returns to their investors compared to those energy IPOs that raised
capital prior to this GFC period. The findings of this study offer insights for issuers
who seek to lower underpricing, for underwriters involved in the capital raising and
for investors who are looking to invest in Australian energy company IPOs.
Keywords Underpricing

 Energy  IPOs

13.1 Introduction
Initial public offerings (IPOs) of equity capital are a common occurrence in
financial markets around the world. Companies wanting equity capital and seeking
to list on a stock exchange may sell their shares to institutional and individual
investors. These investors in turn will seek to earn a reasonable rate of return on
B. Dimovski (&)
School of Accounting, Economics and Finance, Deakin University,
Geelong, Victoria 3216, Australia
e-mail: wd@deakin.edu.au

A. Dorsman et al. (eds.), Energy Economics and Financial Markets,


DOI: 10.1007/978-3-642-30601-3_13,  Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg 2013

235

236

B. Dimovski

their investment. This return will be able to be realized by the investors from the
very first moment of listing. This financial transaction seems simple enough and
normal enough, except that the returns achieved by investors in IPOs historically
have been substantial and in some cases breathtaking. What makes the returns look
even more remarkable is the fact that they are achieved on the first day of the
companys shares being listed on the stock exchange.
IPOs have been discussed in the finance literature for over 30 years. The major
focus has often been on the anomaly of IPOs demonstrating this common and
persistent finding of underpricing. Underpricing is the term used when the issue
price of the shares of a company, raising equity capital from the public and seeking
to list on a stock exchange, is below the closing price of the shares on the first day
of listing. As such, underpricing theoretically allows subscribing investors the
opportunity of making this return on the first day of listing. The international
evidence as examined in Ritter (2003) and Loughran et al. (1994) (but regularly
updated with the most recent update being November 8, 2011) has documented
that subscribing investors made handsome double-digit (for example US IPOs
16.8 %, UK IPOs16.2 %, Turkish IPOs10.6 %, Greek IPOs50.8 %) or
even triple-digit (for example Chinese IPOs137.4 %) statistically significant
positive first day returns, on average. These studies are generally however, of
industrial company IPOs.
The main purpose of this paper is to investigate the underpricing of energy
company IPOs in Australia from January 1994 to December 2010, noting that the
Australian energy sector is important to Australia and to the world. The Australian
energy sector was capitalized at A$176 billion and comprised 12 % of the market
capitalization of the entire Australian Stock Exchange (2012). Australia is the
worlds largest coal exporter and a major supplier of liquefied natural gas and
uranium to world markets (see www.asx.com.au for more detail). While the World
Federation of Exchanges (2009 and 2010) ranked the ASX slightly outside the top
ten largest stock exchanges in the world by market capitalisation, the ASX was the
third largest in the world by capital raised by initial and secondary capital raisings
during 2009, behind the New York Stock Exchange (NYSE) and the London Stock
Exchange (LSE) and the fourth largest in the world in 2008 behind the NYSE, LSE
and the Hong Kong Stock Exchange. Even though the ASX moved behind China
and India in terms of initial and secondary capital raisings (due to their rapid
industrial growth) in 2010, the World Federation of Exchanges consistently ranks
the ASX among the global leaders in capital raisings. The ASX (2010) reports that
energy company IPOs constituted 24 % of all ASX IPOs in 2008 and 20 % of all
ASX IPOs in 2009. The importance of the Australian market in terms of equity
capital raising and the importance of the Australian energy sector more broadly,
makes the Australian market an extremely useful market to investigate the initial
public offerings of energy company IPOs.
A second purpose of the study is to utilize a sufficiently large number of
observations so as to draw useful conclusions. Two previous studies into natural
resource IPOs in Australia only made fleeting mention of energy IPOs because of
the small sample sizes. How (2000) identified 2 solid fuel IPOs and 13 oil and gas

13

Initial Public Offerings of Energy Companies

237

IPOs (amongst 130 other natural resource IPOs) during 1979 to 1990 and advised
average underpricing returns of 106.5 and 47.3 % respectively for investors
subscribing to these IPOs. Using a very small sample size, the study suggested the
underpricing of energy IPOs was much larger than industrial company IPOs.
Dimovski and Brooks (2004) investigated 19 energy IPOs (amongst 96 other
natural resource IPOs) from 1994 to 1999 and reported an average underpricing
return of 8.3 %. Given a later but also small sample size, the second study
suggested the underpricing of energy company IPOs was much lower than
industrial company IPOs.
The data set of 158 energy company IPOs used in this study is significantly
greater than these previous Australian studies. In brief, these 158 energy IPOs
raised over $2.6 billion of public equity capital from January 1994 to December
2010.
There are three parties involved in the IPO transaction that may be particularly
interested in the results of this study. The three parties are the initial subscribers,
the company issuing the equity and the underwriters engaged in guaranteeing the
success of the capital raising. Given the mean underpricing returns reported from
energy IPOs in Australia, this study suggests that if theoretically, the initial
subscribers were able to buy into every IPO, they could theoretically, have earned
significant returns in a short space of time by investing in these IPOs. (It is worth
noting here, however, that Rock (1986) suggests a winners curse where more
informed investors are able to acquire more of the more profitable, higher
underpriced issues than the less informed investors who may well be left with the
lower underpriced or even overpriced issues.) The results also suggest that issuers
could consider some of the characteristics of the offer and the parties involved in
the IPO process that may be related to lower levels of underpricing. Finally, while
underwriters are not mandatory for capital raising in Australia, they are often used
by issuers to guarantee a certain amount of capital will be raised. Not only will
underwriters want to maximize the amount of wealth retained by their issuing
company client but they will also want to sell appropriately priced shares to their
investor clients. This study may help underwriters provide better advice to both
parties.
This study also follows a highly influential paper in the IPO literature by Beatty
and Ritter (1986). They argue that the lower the uncertainty about the value of an
IPO, the lower the underpricing needed to attract subscribers. Given the linkage
between uncertainty and underpricing, this study seeks to identify the factors that
might influence uncertainty and hence underpricing. A more recent paper by Brau
and Fawcett (2006) uses survey evidence from 336 chief financial officers who
concur with Beatty and Ritter (1986) that underpricing compensates investors for
taking risk.
The third purpose of this study is to investigate whether energy IPOs are seen to
be riskier and more uncertain about their cash flows than other Australian IPOs.
The energy IPOs in this study show a 22 % mean underpricing to subscribing
investors. This is broadly similar but slightly less than the underpricing of 29 %
reported in Dimovski et al. (2011) for Australian industrial company IPOs from

238

B. Dimovski

1994 to 2004. It is also interesting to note the results from underpricing studies
focusing on other sectors. In the real estate investment trust (REIT) sector in
Australia, Dimovski and Brooks (2006) report a mean 2.6 % underpricing of REIT
IPOs, while with Australian infrastructure IPOs, Dimovski (2011) reports a mean
underpricing of 3.5 %but both are not statistically significantly different to a
zero underpricing. These latter two sectors appear to be seen as less risky IPO
investment sectors than energy IPOs. Additionally, Dimovski and Brooks (2008)
investigate the underpricing of gold mining IPOs in Australia and report a mean
underpricing of 13.3 %interestingly quite a bit lower than the underpricing of
industrial company IPOs in Australia and significantly lower than the underpricing
returns of gold mining IPOs prior to 1991.
The results of this study suggest that if the issue is underwritten, underpricing is
lower and that energy IPOs that seek to raise more equity capital have lower
underpricing. There is also some evidence that suggests energy company IPOs that
offered options to their underwriters had higher underpricing, effectively cancelling the lower underpricing effect of the underwriting itself. Interestingly, the
energy IPOs that raised equity capital after the 2007/8 global financial crisis (GFC)
do not appear to have offered significantly different underpricing returns, on
average, to the subscribers compared to those energy IPOs that raised capital prior
to this GFC period.
The plan of this paper is as follows. In Sect. 13.2 we briefly summarise some of
the underpricing literature. Section 13.3 presents the data and methods.
Section 13.4 reports the results. Section 13.5 makes some concluding comments.

13.2 Related Literature


This section is in two parts. The first part discusses the major theoretical explanations for underpricing and the second part summarizes some previous resources
IPO research.

13.2.1 Theoretical Explanations for Underpricing


Regrettably there isnt just one theoretical explanation for underpricing; many
theories have been offered to explain underpricing. Most of the theories suggest
that the issuer and the underwriter deliberately and knowingly underprice, or that
the subscriber to the new issue expects the issue to be underpriced.
The first three explanations here are sometimes referred to as the information
asymmetry explanations. Baron (1982) suggests that underwriters have superior
information of the market conditions and the demand for the new IPOs shares. For
the underwriter to raise the required equity capital for the IPO entity, the entity
allows the underwriter to determine the issue price, which allows for underpricing.

13

Initial Public Offerings of Energy Companies

239

Rock (1986) suggests there are two categories of investors that seek shares in
IPOsthe informed and the uninformed. He argues that the informed (and likely
more influential) investors crowd out the uninformed (and likely less influential)
leaving the uninformed buying more of the less profitable issues. In order to
compensate the uninformed for this winners curse and to induce subscribers to
future IPOs, issuers underprice. The third explanation is by Allen and Faulhaber
(1989) and by Welch (1989). They argue that underpricing encourages subscribing
investors to see the quality of the IPO firm which later allows the firm to make
subsequent equity issues at a higher price. As such, these companies recoup some
of that underpricing.
The next three explanations suggest an underwriter monopsony power because
underwriters have significant control over the price at which the IPOs shares are
offered. Tinics (1988) insurance hypothesis argues that underpricing is like an
insurance policy protecting the underwriters and the issuing firm from lawsuits.
Chalk and Peavy (1987) suggest that underwriters might issue shares to preferred
clients but then recoup this favor by charging higher fees later for services to such
clients. Benveniste and Spindt (1989) argue that underwriters allow new issues to
be underpriced to encourage investors to subscribe to the IPO to fill the new issue.
Investors otherwise will simply wait until listing to purchase the shares.
Ruud (1993) suggests that underpricing may not be a deliberate decision prior
to the listing. She suggests that underwriters actually price support the issue after it
is listed. This is unlikely in Australia because price support activities by underwriters are illegal under the Corporations Law of Australia.
Except for Ruud (1993), all of the explanations broadly suggest that uncertainty, issue price and underpricing are related. However, it was Beatty and
Ritters (1986) paper that more formally argued that reducing the uncertainty
about an IPOs valuation reduces the need for underpricing. Since that study
researchers have found that lower underpricing is associated in IPO firms:

with higher issue prices [Chalk and Peavy (1987)].


that employ higher quality underwriters [Carter and Manaster (1990)]
that employ higher quality auditors [Beatty (1989)]
which have existing borrowing relationships [James and Wier (1990)]
which have high earnings potential [Koop and Li (2001)]
that are venture capital backed but not covered by an all-star analyst [Liu and
Ritter (2011)

13.2.2 Previous Australian Natural Resource IPO Research


There are two major papers examining the underpricing of natural resource IPOs in
Australia. The first was by How (2000) who investigated 130 resource IPOs over
the 1979 to 1990 of which 100 were gold IPOs, 15 were Other Metals, 2 were
Solid Fuels and 13 were Oil and Gas. The average underpricing returns to
subscribers were 119.5, 76.9, 106.5 and 47.3 % respectively.

240

B. Dimovski

Dimovski and Brooks (2004) extended Hows (2000) work by investigating


96 natural resource IPOs from 1994 to 1999. They reported average underpricing
returns to subscribers of 11.3, 56.1, 24.7 and 8.3 % for the 53 Gold IPOs, 23 Other
Metals, 1, Diversified Resources and 19 Energy IPOs respectively.
There was another study by Brailsford et al. (2001) who examined the
Australian IPO market from 1976 to 1997 in aggregate, particularly investigating
any evidence of unusually high or low volumes of IPO offerings. A total of
$27.870 billion of equity capital was raised over this 22 year period. Their sample
showed an average initial day underpricing return of 46.5 % for the broader group
of resource IPOs while their sample of industrial entity IPOs showed an average
underpricing return of 23.3 %.

13.3 Data and Methods


A total of 158 Australian energy IPOs listed on the Australian Stock Exchange
from January 1994 to December 2010. The primary source of the data for this
study was the Connect 4 Company Prospectuses database.
This study extracted variables from each of the energy company IPO
prospectuses for the above period. Most of these variables have been found useful
in explaining the level of underpricing return in previous studies. The variables to
be tested are defined as follows:
The issue price (ISSUEPRI) [Chalk and Peavy (1987); Ibbotson et al.(1994)];
the logarithm of the total capital raised (LNTOTAL) [Ibbotson et al. (1994)];
A time to list (TIMETOLIST) variable that records the number of days from the
date of the prospectus to the day of listing [Lee et al. (1996b)];
the underwritten (UWRITTEN) variable is a (0 or 1) dummy variable reflecting
no underwriter (0) or an underwriter (1) was used in the IPO [Dimovski and
Brooks (2004) and adapted from the underwriter reputation variables in Carter
and Manaster (1990)];
A UOPTIONS dummy (0 or 1) variable with a value of 1 if share options were
available to the underwriter, or 0 if not [Dunbar (1995); Dimovski and Brooks
(2004)];
A INDEPACC dummy (0 or 1) variable with a value of 1 if the IPO used a big 5
accountant, or 0 if not [Dimovski and Brooks (2004)];
A SHOPTIONS dummy (0 or 1) variable with a value of 1 if share options are
offered to subscribers, or 0 if not [Schultz (1993), Jain (1994); How and Howe
(2001)];
A POST2007 dummy (0 or 1) variable with a value of 1 if the IPO was offered
in 2008, 2009 or 2010, or 0 if the IPO was offered earlier, to reflect IPOs that
sought to list after the global financial crisis [Valentine and Gordon (2009)].
An ordinary least squares regression model is performed on the data. The
dependent variable is underpricing return (RETURN). This is the closing price of

13

Initial Public Offerings of Energy Companies

241

the shares (plus any options) on the first day of listing minus the issue price, the
result of which is then divided by the issue price. Closing prices were obtained
from the FinAnalysis database.
The regression model with underpricing return as the dependent variable is:
RETURN b0 b1ISSUEPRI b2LNTOTAL b3TIMETOLIST b4UWRITTEN
b5UOPTIONS b6INDEPACC b7SHOPTIONS b8POST2007 e

13:1
where all the variables are as defined previously, the bs are unknown
parameters to be estimated and e is assumed * N (0, r2).
The ISSUEPRI and LNTOTAL variables are commonly used in underpricing
studies. They are both expected to be negatively related to RETURN. In regard
issue price, Chalk and Peavy (1987) examined 649 US IPOs from 1975 to 1982.
They found that the group of IPOs priced at US$1 or less, had an underpricing
return (of 56.4 %) almost five times higher than for the next pricing group (of
11.95 %). Tinic (1988) also argued that the offering price per share is a proxy for
ex ante uncertainty.
In regard the size of the issue, Beatty and Ritter (1986) use data from 1028 U.S.
IPOs during 1977 to 1982 and argued that the size of the issue was a proxy for
ex ante uncertainty about the value of the firm. They confirm that smaller offerings
are more speculative and more highly underpriced than larger offerings. Chalk and
Peavy (1987) similarly report a negative relationship between underpricing and
size. Michaely and Shaw (1994), in their study of 947 IPOs in the United States
between 1984 and 1988 also identify that underpricing was lower in larger
companies. The study by Ibbotson, Sindelar and Ritter (1994) with U.S. IPO data
dating back to 1960 confirmed that on average, larger IPOs were less underpriced
than smaller IPOs. In the Australian context, How et al. (1995) in their study of
340 Australian industrial IPOs from 1980 to 1990, similarly found that larger firms
were significantly less underpriced.
The UWRITTEN and INDEPACC variables test whether the use of an
underwriter or a top 5 independent accountant respectively, is useful in reducing
the level of uncertainty about the IPOs value and hence its underpricing. Carter
and Manaster (1990) confirmed that lower first day returns were associated with
higher reputation underwriters (using U.S. data collected between 1979 and 1984).
They suggest this was because the higher reputation underwriters accepted lower
risk issues. Carter et al. (1998) reaffirm this lower underpricing, higher underwriter
reputation relationship in an expanded study of U.S. IPOs over 1979 to 1991.
Michaely and Shaw (1994) in their study of 947 U.S. IPOs also found that those
managed by higher reputation underwriters have lower initial returns. In Australia,
IPOs do not need to be underwritten to list, nor do underwriters have a reputation
index. The UWRITTEN variable does however test whether the simple fact of
being underwritten does indeed influence underpricing returns.
In regard the quality of the auditor/accountant, Beatty (1989) suggested that the
costs of hiring a prestigious auditor (defined then as one of the Big 8 accounting

242

B. Dimovski

and audit firmsPrice Waterhouse, Coopers and Lybrand, Ernst and Whinney,
Arthur Anderson, Arthur Young & Co., Peat Marwick Mitchell, Deloitte Haskins
and Sells and Touche Ross) were justified by having lower underpricing. Michaely
and Shaw (1995) followed with a study that concluded that IPOs associated with
more prestigious auditors (the Big 8 accounting/audit firms) were less risky
because those auditors sought to protect their reputation capital. They argued that
good firms were willing to pay the higher fees charged by the Big 8 firms, so that
the issuing companys quality was more accurately revealed to the market.
The Big 8 were reduced to a Big 5 by 2001 due to mergers amongst the Big 8.
The Big 5 were PwC (Pricewaterhouse Coopers), KPMG, Deloitte Touche
Tohmatsu, Ernst and Young and Arthur Anderson (and then to a Big 4 when Arthur
Anderson folded in 2002 following the Enron collapse). For the purposes of this
study, the Big 5 nominated accounting firms are utilized since they most adequately
reflect those used by energy IPOs during the period of the study.
The TIMETOLIST variable is expected to have a negative coefficient as in Lee
et al. (1996b). This suggests more highly underpriced issues are subscribed to,
more quickly.
The SHOPTIONS variable tests the Schultz (1993) hypothesis that these so
called package IPOs minimize agency costs so that if the firms forecasted
performance is not up to expectations, the future expected equity capital from
those options does not flow into the firm. As such, SHOPTIONS is expected to be
negatively related to RETURN. Interestingly, How (2000), in her study of
Australian mining IPOs over the period 1979 to 1990 did not find that the type of
IPO, whether packaged or share only, was significantly related to the level of
underpricing.
Dunbar (1995) using data on 182 U.S. IPOs that offered underwriter warrants
(options) found that underwriters compensated with warrants do not increase
underpricing. It is expected that if underwriters are willing to accept options
(UOPTIONS) to buy more shares they are likely to be more certain about the value
of the IPO before listing. As such, UOPTIONS is expected to be negatively related
to RETURN.
This study treats all the explanatory variables as exogenous. The issue price, the
size of the capital raising, whether the issue is underwritten (not the choice of a
specific underwriter), whether underwriter options are offered, whether a big 5
accountant is employed (not the choice of a specific big 5 accountant) and whether
share options are offered to subscribers are all identified in the prospectus and as
such, predetermined. Australian IPOs are generally fixed price IPOs meaning that
the price is known at the outset and since the issue takes around 57 days on
average from the date of the prospectus to the date of listing we would expect these
variables to be exogenous. Additionally, we also know whether the issue is before
the period of the global financial crisis.
Ljundqvist and Wilhelm (2002) and Lowry and Shu (2002) examine the
endogeneity of some right hand side variables in book build environments where
the issue price is not finalized until the investment order book is filled and the IPO
ready to list. The only variable that may cause some endogeneity concern in this

13

Initial Public Offerings of Energy Companies

243

present study, is the time to list variable. However even with this variable, the
issue needs to fill first and then the stock lists, often 1014 days later. Locating a
suitable instrumental variable is likely to prove difficult but the time to list variable
is not significant in any case.
Two specific hypotheses might be tested. Given that a great many of these
energy IPOs are involved in exploration, we can formally suggest a first hypothesis
that Australian energy IPOs are more risky than industrial company IPOs and as
such should provide higher underpricing. Additionally POST2007 is a new
variable that is included to test if energy IPOs that raised equity in the GFC period
offered significantly higher underpricing. This can be formalized into a second
hypothesisthat the mean underpricing return for energy IPOs is significantly
higher after 2007.

13.4 Results
Table 13.1 reports the summary statistics for the data set. The mean underpricing
return was 22.0 % while the median was 6.5 %. Because this is a sample, a t test
testing if the true mean underpricing return could be zero, is undertaken. The
resultant t-statistic is 5.64 (much larger than 2 for a 95 % confidence level)
suggesting that the mean underpricing return of Australian energy IPOs is statistically significantly greater than zero. It is worth restating, however, that these
mean and median return measures include the returns theoretically able to be made
from selling the newly listed shares and the subscriber options (if any) for each of
the IPOs, at the closing price of the shares and the options on the first day of
listing. This method is consistent with Schultz (1993), Jain (1994) and How and
Howe (2001).
One IPO was underpriced 295 % while one was overpriced by 35 %. Overpricing occurs when the subscription price paid by investors is higher than the
closing price of the stock on the first day of trading. While overpricing is not a
happy occasion for investors and may be considered an uncommon occurrence, it
was not at all uncommon amongst these energy IPO offerings. The company still
lists on the stock exchange and given the amount of capital raised is what it sought
to raise, the company can still do what it proposed to do in its prospectus. A total
of 47 of the 158 energy IPO observations were overpriced, 11 showed a 0 % return
and 100 were underpriced. As such, underpricing occurred in nearly 2/3rds of the
sample. The standard deviation of returns was 49.0 % reflecting quite a considerable measure of dispersion.
The issue price ranged from 20 cents to $5.96 with the median being 20 cents.
In Australia, since 1 July 1998 shares in companies are simply offered at an
issue price, no longer using the terms of par or nominal values and no
longer allowing accounting entities to record a share premium reserve account
reflecting amounts paid for the shares over and above the old par or nominal value.

244

B. Dimovski

Table 13.1 Summary statistics for the underpricing of energy IPOs in Australia Jan 1994 to
December 2010
Variable
158 observations
Median
Std Dev
Min
Max
Panel A
Mean
Return
Issue Price ($)
Total Raised ($m)
Time to list (days)
Underwritten (0 or 1)
Uoptions (0 or 1)
Indep Account (0 or 1)
Share options (0 or 1)

0.220
0.401
16.690
57.278
0.342
0.108
0.336
0.304

0.065
0.200
7.000
50.000
0.000
0.000
0.000
0.000

0.490
0.581
3.826
30.663
0.476
0.311
0.474
0.461

-0.350
0.200
0.300
3.000
0.000
0.000
0.000
0.000

2.950
5.960
400.000
282.000
1.000
1.000
1.000
1.000

Panel B
Return
Issue Price ($)
Total Raised ($m)
Time to list (days)
Underwritten (0 or 1)
Uoptions (0 or 1)
Indep Account (0 or 1)
Share options (0 or 1)

3 outliers removed
0.175
0.400
16.842
57.458
0.342
0.108
0.342
0.310

0.050
0.200
7.000
50.000
0.000
0.000
0.000
0.000

0.371
0.586
3.861
30.906
0.476
0.314
0.476
0.464

-0.350
0.200
0.300
3.000
0.000
0.000
0.000
0.000

1.475
5.960
400.000
282.000
1.000
1.000
1.000
1.000

Any old (pre 1998) share premium reserve accounts were transferred to the share
capital account.
This study uses issue price to mean the price at which the new IPO shares are
offered to the public. The vast majority of these energy IPO shares are offered at
20 and 25 cents (over 100 of the 158), which is a typical resource stock issue price in
Australia. The $5.96 price is a highly unusual issue price for a resource stock but that
is the price that Aston Resources Limited priced the shares in their IPO in their $400
million IPO capital raising. This also happened to be the highest individual capital
raising in this data set and was managed by Goldman Sachs, Macquarie Capital
Advisors, Credit Suisse and BKK Partners. Aston Resources Ltd happened to be
overpriced by 4.7 %. Other 100 or more million dollar capital raisings include
Novus Petroleum Ltd, Roc Oil Co Ltd, Excel Coal Ltd, and ERM Power Ltd. Their
underpricing was 10, 10, -2 (overpriced) and 3.4 % respectively.
The mean average capital raising by these energy IPOs was $16.69 million with
the smallest being $300,000 to the largest being $400 million. Around 86 % of the
energy IPO entities raised $5 million or less. Around 34 % of the IPOs (54 in
number) used underwriters to guarantee the success of the capital raising and
around 34 % of the firms (53 in number) used a top 5 accounting firm. They were
not the same firms. Only 10.8 % of the IPOs (17 in number) offered options to
underwriters to subscribe for more shares while 30.4 % (48 in number) offered
options to subscribers. There were only 24 IPOs that sought IPO equity capital
during 2008 to 2010 (with only six energy IPO offerings in 2008).

13

Initial Public Offerings of Energy Companies

245

Table 13.2 Regression results for the underpricing of energy IPOs in Australia Jan 1994 to Dec
2010
Outliers Removed #
158 IPOs
155 IPOs
C
ISSUEPRI
LNTOTAL
TIMETOLIST
UWRITTEN
UOPTIONS
INDEPACC
SHOPTIONS
POST2007
R Squared
Adj R Squared
Jarque Bera
White Test
Reset Test

Coef.

Pr.

Coef.

Pr.

1.698
0.076
-0.078
-0.002
-0.150
0.158
-0.170
-0.150
-0.153
0.103
0.055
622.601
19.208
2.582

0.038
0.412
0.136
0.185
0.153
0.269
0.064a
0.086a
0.171

1.470
0.086
-0.072
-0.001
-0.192
0.225
-0.086
-0.068
-0.077
0.120
0.072
83.938
50.017
3.142

0.005
0.142
0.035b
0.540
0.001c
0.032b
0.144
0.302
0.326

0.000
0.995
0.070

0.000
0.091
0.055

statistically significant at the 10 % level, b statistically significant at the 5 % level,


statistically significant at the 1 % level
# White heteroskedasticity consistent coefficients and p-values

Panel B of Table 13.1 excludes the outliers. The mean underpricing return is
now 17.5 % for the remaining 155 observations and the median is 5.0 %. The
standard deviation of returns falls to 37.1 %. The summary statistics for the other
variables remain broadly the same.
Tables 13.2, 13.3 and 13.4 report the ordinary least squares (OLS) regression
results. There were three observations that were over 3.5 standard deviations from
the mean return. These outlier observations were removed from the model and
modified regression results reported. This identification of outliers over 3.5 standard deviations is consistent with How (2000). These three observations showed a
224, 240 and 295 % first day return. Interestingly, there have been more highly
underpriced IPOs than these amongst other Australian IPOsDiamond Rose and
Western Diamond Corporation reported 545 and 500 % first day returns respectively while Australian industrial companies, CDS Technologies and Advanced
Engine Components reported 370 and 340 % first day returns respectively. Even
excluding the three energy IPO outliers in this data set, the mean average
underpricing is still over 17.5 % for the remaining sample of 155 energy IPOs.
A variety of standard regression diagnostics are reported. In testing for
non-normal errors, a JarqueBera statistic is reported, although the relatively large
sample size suggests normality is unlikely to be problematic. In testing for
heteroskedasticity, a White (1980) test is applied and robust results reported where
necessary using White corrected standard errors and the resultant p-values. The
affected heteroskedasticity-consistent affected column of results are identified with

246

B. Dimovski

Table 13.3 Regression results for the underpricing of energy IPOs in Australia Jan 1994 to Dec
2010fewer variables
Outliers Removed #
158 IPOs
155 IPOs
C
ISSUEPRI
TIMETOLIST
UWRITTEN
UOPTIONS
INDEPACC
SHOPTIONS
POST2007
R Squared
Adj R Squared
JarqueBera
White Test
Reset Test

Coef.

Pr.

Coef.

Pr.

0.489
0.001
-0.002
-0.192
0.158
-0.180
-0.136
-0.134
0.090
0.047
612.696
15.983
3.414

0.000
0.998
0.193
0.055a
0.274
0.050b
0.119
0.229

0.354
0.016
-0.001
-0.231
0.223
-0.096
-0.056
-0.060
0.100
0.057
81.155
4.290
7.349

0.010
0.667
0.557
0.000c
0.034b
0.101
0.403
0.439

0.000
0.975
0.040

0.000
0.015
0.013

statistically significant at the 10 % level, b statistically significant at the 5 % level,


statistically significant at the 1 % level
# White heteroskedasticity consistent coefficients and p-values

Table 13.4 Regression results for the underpricing of energy IPOs in Australia Jan 1994 to Dec
2010fewer variables
Outliers Removed #
158 IPOs
155 IPOs
C
LNTOTAL
TIMETOLIST
UWRITTEN
UOPTIONS
INDEPACC
SHOPTIONS
POST2007
R Squared
Adj R Squared
Jarque Bera
White Test
Reset Test
a

Coef.

Pr.

Coef.

Pr.

1.352
-0.055
-0.002
-0.145
0.139
-0.153
-0.149
-0.132
0.102
439.005
616.355
18.001
0.3.237

0.053
0.212
0.149
0.165
0.326
0.087a
0.088a
0.224

1.077
-0.046
-0.001
-0.185
0.202
-0.066
-0.067
-0.054
0.111
0.069
89.463
50.626
5.364

0.012
0.073a
0.497
0.001c
0.053a
0.256
0.309
0.471

0.000
0.944
0.023

0.000
0.007
0.012

statistically significant at the 10 % level, b statistically significant at the 5 % level,


statistically significant at the 1 % level
# White heteroskedasticity consistent coefficients and p-values

13

Initial Public Offerings of Energy Companies

247

the hash (#) symbol at the top of the column in each of the three regression model
tables. The econometric software used to compute these robust results was EViews 7.
In testing for omitted variables or model misspecification, a Ramsey Reset test is
applied and reported. While the Durbin-Watson statistic is a useful diagnostic test
when an independent variable is a lagged value of the dependent variable, it is not
required here. This data set does not need to be ordered and the error term is not
correlated across observations; the independent and dependent variables are distinct.
For the overall model in Table 13.2, the results of the regression analysis
suggest that the LNTOTAL, UWRITTEN and UOPTIONS variables have
explanatory power with regard to the amount of underpricing return. The
ISSUEPRI and LNTOTMIL variables are however fairly highly correlated at
0.646 and multicollinearity may be a problem in our analysis hence the models are
run again with either one of the ISSUEPRI (in Table 13.3) or LNTOTAL (in
Table 13.4) variable.
Table 13.3 is without only the LNTOTAL variable and reports the UWRITTEN
and UOPTIONs variables as useful. Table 13.4 is without only the ISSUEPRI
variable and reports the UWRITTEN, OPTIONS and LNTOTAL variables as
useful. It appears that those Australian energy IPOs that are underwritten, benefit
substantially in terms of lower underpricing by about 20 %. What is interesting,
however, is that those energy company IPOs that offer options to the underwriters
appear to counteract the lower underpricing by about 20 %. There is also some
evidence to suggest that the greater the amount of capital sought, the lower the
underpricing.

13.5 Conclusion
This study examined 158 energy IPOs in Australia for the period January 1994 to
December 2010. What it found is that the mean underpricing return for these IPOs
is 22.0 % and statistically significant. The overall results of this study support the
findings of previous studies in that, IPOs on average, underprice, including energy
IPOs. While the implications suggest that investors will theoretically earn profits
by investing in these IPOs and selling on the first day of listing, recall that in
47 cases investors paid more by subscribing for shares through the prospectus than
they could buy the shares for at the closing price on the first day and in 11 cases,
their underpricing return was zero. Clearly, not all subscribers are going to be
making substantial first day returns on every issue and as Rock (1986) suggested,
nor would every subscriber be able to invest an equivalent amount into every issue
so as to take advantage of these averages. Also clear is that pricing new issues is
not easy and precise.
The results are broadly in line with recent Australian resource and industrial
company IPO studies [Brailsford et al. (2001), Dimovski and Brooks (2004) and
Dimovski et al. (2011)] and broadly in line with other international industrial
company IPO studies summarized in Ritter (2003) and Loughran et al. (1994)

248

B. Dimovski

updated to Nov 8, 2011. To the authors knowledge, however, this is the first large
sample energy IPO underpricing study reported.
The model used to investigate variables that might help explain the level of
underpricing in this industry sector is also particularly useful. An important finding
in the study for new issuers, underwriters and subscribing investors is that those
energy IPO firms that used underwriters had substantially lower underpricing, but
that the use of underwriter options increases underpricing. While some US studies
have suggested that the use of higher reputation underwriters is negatively related
to underpricing, just the use of underwriters having a negative influence on
underpricing is an interesting and useful finding. The UOPTIONS variable is
unexpectedly positive. This is contrary to the initial hypothesis and to Dunbars
(1995) US evidence, the allocation of options to underwriters appears to increase
the underpricing return amongst energy IPOs.
The other finding that larger issues are likely to have lower underpricing is
consistent with prior industrial company IPO studies. It is also interesting to note
that those energy company IPOs that sought to list after the global financial crisis
do not appear to have offered, on average, significantly different underpricing
returns to their investors compared to those energy IPOs that raised capital prior to
this global financial crisis period.
The underpricing returns made by subscribers to energy company IPOs, from
the issuing companys viewpoint, can be considered as an indirect cost to the
company itself. That is, the IPO entity has foregone raising the capital that the
subscribing investors have theoretically profited from (given the closing price on
the first day of trading). The expression sometimes used is money left on the
table by the IPO.
In terms of future research, it would be useful to consider factors influencing the
direct costs of raising the IPO equity capitalthe costs of underwriting,
accounting, legal fees and other expenses. This strand of research could follow Lee
et al. (1996a) with their broad US study on the costs of raising capital.
A second useful future research area would be to examine the longer-term
return performance of these energy company IPOs following their listing. It could
investigate the magnitude of returns an investor may have made from the IPO
investment in the longer term after having made (on average) initial day underpricing returns. Alternatively, if the investor had not received a sufficient allocation (or any allocation at all), in the IPO, whether an investment on the first day is
an appropriate and profitable strategy. Curiously, the consistent broad observation
(around the world) regarding IPOs is that their relative returns compared to the
market or matching firms (in size and industry) in the longer term is poor. The
energy sector, however, has not been specifically reported. A range of early
evidence on the longer-term return performance of IPOs generally is discussed in
Loughran et al. (1994) and more recently in Bradley et al. (2008).

13 Initial Public Offerings of Energy Companies

249

References
Allen, F., & Faulhaber, G. R. (1989). Signaling by underpricing in the IPO market. Journal of
Financial Economics, 23, 303324.
ASX (2012). An international centre for resources capital (n.d.). Retrieved March 14, 2012 from
http://www.asx.com.au/images/resources/resources_brochure.pdf.
Australian stock exchange (2010). ASX: An international centre for resources capital, pp. 18.
Baron, D. P. (1982). A model of the demand for investment banking advising and distribution
services for new issues. Journal of Finance, 37(4), 955976.
Beatty, R. P. (1989). Auditor reputation and the pricing of initial public offerings. The Accounting
Review, 64, 693709.
Beatty, R. P., & Ritter, J. R. (1986). Investment banking, reputation, and the under pricing of
initial public offerings. Journal of Financial Economics, 15(12), 213232.
Benveniste, L. M., & Spindt, P. A. (1989). How investment bankers determine the offer price and
allocation of new issues. Journal of Financial Economics, 24, 343362.
Bradley, D., Chan, K., Kim, J., & Singh, A. (2008). Are there long run implications of analyst
coverage for IPOs? Journal of Banking and Finance, 32, 11201132.
Brailsford, T. J., Heaney, R. A., & Shi, J. (2001). The cyclical behaviour of the IPO market in
Australia. Accounting Research Journal, 14(1), 1734.
Brau, J. C., & Fawcett, S. E. (2006). Initial public offerings: An analysis of theory and practice. ,
61(1), 399436.
Carter, R. B., Dark, F. H., & Singh, A. K. (1998). Underwriter reputation, initial returns, and the
long run performance of IPO stocks. Journal of Finance, 53, 285311.
Carter, R., & Manaster, S. (1990). Initial public offerings and underwriter reputation. Journal of
Finance, 45(4), 10451067.
Chalk, A. J., &Peavy, J. W. III (1987). Initial public offerings: Daily returns, offering types and
the price effect. Financial Analysts Journal, 43(5), 6569.
Dimovski, W. (2011). The pricing of infrastructure initial public offerings: Evidence from
Australia. Journal of Property Research, 28(1), 314.
Dimovski, W., & Brooks, R. (2004). Initial public offerings in Australia 1994 to 1999. Recent
Evidence of Underpricing and Underperformance, Review of Quantitative Finance and
Accounting, 22, 179198.
Dimovski, W., & Brooks, R. (2006). The pricing of property trust IPOs in Australia. Journal of
Real Estate Finance and Economics, 32(2), 185199.
Dimovski, W., & Brooks, R. (2008). The underpricing of gold mining initial public offerings.
Research in International Business and Finance, 22, 116.
Dimovski, W., Philavanh, S. and R. Brooks, R. (2011). Underwriter reputation and underpricing:
Evidence from the Australian IPO market, review of quantitative finance and accounting, 37,
409-426.
Dunbar, C. G. (1995). The use of warrants as underwriter compensation in initial public offerings.
Journal of Financial Economics, 38, 5978.
How, J. C. Y. (2000). The initial and long run performances of mining IPOs in Australia.
Australian Journal of Management, 25, 95118.
How, J. C. Y., & Howe, J. S. (2001). Warrants in initial public offerings: Empirical evidence.
Journal of Business, 74(3), 433458.
How, J. C. Y., Izan, H. Y., & Monroe, G. S. (1995). Differential information and the underpricing
of initial public offerings: Australian evidence. Accounting and Finance, 35, 87105.
Ibbotson, R. G., Sindelar, J. L., & Ritter, J. R. (1994). The markets problems with the pricing of
initial public offerings. Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, 7(1), 6674.
Jain, B. A. (1994). The underpricing of unit initial public offerings. Quarterly Reviews of
Economics and Finance, 34, 309325.
James, C., & Wier, P. (1990). Borrowing relationships. Intermediation and the cost of Issuing
public securities, Journal of Financial Economics, 29, 149172.

250

B. Dimovski

Koop, G., & Li, K. (2001). The valuation of IPO and SEO firms. Journal of Empirical Finance, 8,
375401.
Lee, I., Lochhead, S., Ritter, J., & Zhao, Q. (1996a). The costs of raising capital. Journal of
Financial Research, 19(1), 5974.
Lee, P. J., Taylor, S. L., & Walter, T. S. (1996b). Australian IPO pricing in the short and long run.
Journal of Banking & Finance, 20(7), 11891210.
Liu, X., & Ritter, J. R. (2011). Local underwriter oligopolies and IPO underpricing. Journal of
Financial Economics, 102, 579601.
Ljundqvist, A. P., & Wilhelm, W. J. (2002). IPO allocations: Discriminatory or discretionary?
Journal of Financial Economics, 65, 167201.
Loughran, T., Ritter, J.R. and Rydqvist, K. (1994) Initial public offerings: International insights.
Pacific-Basin finance Journal, 2(23), 165199. Updated November 8, 2011.
Lowry, M., & Shu, S. (2002). Litigation risk and IPO underpricing. Journal of Financial
Economics, 65, 305339.
Michaely, R., & Shaw, W. H. (1994). The pricing of initial public offerings: Tests of adverseselection and signaling theories. Review of Financial Studies, 7(2), 279319.
Michaely, R., & Shaw, W. H. (1995). Does the choice of auditor convey quality in an initial
public offering. Financial Management, 24(4), 1530.
Ritter, J. R. (2003). Differences between European and American IPO markets. European
Financial Management, 9, 421434.
Rock, K. (1986). Why new issues are underpriced. Journal of Financial Economics, 15(12),
187212.
Ruud, J. S. (1993). Underwriter price support and the IPO under pricing puzzle. Journal of
Financial Economics, 34(2), 135151.
Schultz, P. (1993). Unit initial public offerings: A form of staged financing. Journal of Financial
Economics, 34, 199229.
Tinic, S. M. (1988). Anatomy of initial public offerings of common stock. Journal of Finance,
43(4), 789822.
Valentine, T., & Gordon, C. (2009). Economics in focus: The global financial crisis. Pearson
Education Australia.
Welch, I. (1989). Seasoned offerings, imitation costs, and the underpricing of initial public
offerings. Journal of Finance, 44, 421450.
White, H. (1980). A heteroskedasticity-consistent covariance matrix estimator and a direct test
for heteroskedasticity. Econometrica, 48(4), 817838.
World federation of exchanges (2009). Market highlights (2009) Retrieved March 14, 2012, from
http://www.google.com.au/search?q=WFE+market+highlights+2009&ie=utf-8&oe=utf8&aq=t&rls=org.mozilla:en-US:official&client=firefox-a.
World federation of exchanges (2010). Market highlights (2010) Retrieved March 14, 2012, from
http://www.scribd.com/doc/53724659/2010-WFE-Market-Highlights.

Das könnte Ihnen auch gefallen