Sie sind auf Seite 1von 20

Perils of the Internal Rate of Return

The two most-used measures for evaluating an investment are the net present
value and the internal rate of return. (Two earlier tutorials discussed these
concepts. See the tutorials list for links to tutorials for discounting future income
and the internal rate of return.)
It is often assumed that higher is better for both of the net present value and the
internal rate of return. In particular, it is usually stated that investments with
higher internal rates of return are more profitable than investments with lower
internal rates of return.
However, this is not necessarily so. In some situations, an investment with a lower
internal rate of return may be better, even judged on narrow financial grounds, than
an investment with a higher internal rate of return. This interactive lecture explores
why and when this reversal takes place.
To review, both the net present value and the internal rate of return require the idea
of an income stream, so let's start there. An income stream is a series of amounts
of money. Each amount of money comes in or goes out at some specific time,
either now or in the future. The income stream represents the investment; the
income stream is all you need to know for financial evaluation purposes.
In real life, individuals, charitable institutions, and even for-profit businesses have
social or other goals when selecting investments. For businesses, the benefits of
community good will are no less real for being difficult to measure precisely. For
enterprises with social as well as financial goals, the measures discussed here are
still useful: They tell you how much it costs you to advance your social goals.

Here is an income stream example, from the interactive lecture about the internal
rate of return.
Year

Income amounts

-$1000

$200

$200

$200

$200

$200

$200

Here we see seven points in time and, for each, a dollar inflow or outflow. At year
0 (now), the income amount is negative. Negative income is cost, or outgo. In this
example, the negative income amount in year 0 represents the cost of buying and
installing the machine.
In the future, at years 1 through 6, there will be net income of $200 each year.
All of the amounts in the income stream are net income, meaning that each is
income minus outgo, or revenue minus cost. In year 0, the cost exceeds the revenue
by $1000. In years 1 though 6, the revenue will exceed the cost by $200.
This investment evidently has no salvage value. That is, there is nothing that can be
sold in year 6, the last year. If there were, the amount that could be realized from
the sale would be added to the income amount for year 6.
For simplicity, all my examples have the incomes and outgoes at one-year
intervals. Real-life investments can have income and expenses at irregular times,
but the principles of evaluation are the same.
Now let's discuss our two measures in connection with this income stream:

Net Present Value

The net present value of an income stream is the sum of the present values of the
individual amounts in the income stream. Each future income amount in the
stream is discounted, meaning that it is divided by a number representing the
opportunity cost of holding capital from now (year 0) until the year when income
is received or the outgo is spent. The opportunity cost can either be how much you
would have earned investing the money someplace else, or how much interest you
would have had to pay if you borrowed money. See the interactive lecture on
discounting

future

income for

more

explanation.

That

tutorial

has

nifty spreadsheet setup for calculating present values that you can copy and use in
your own spreadsheet.
The word "net" in "net present value" indicates that our calculation
includes the initial costs as well as the subsequent profits. It also reminds
us that all the amounts in the income stream are net profits, revenues
minus cost. In other words, "net" means the same as "total" here.
The net present value of an investment tells you how this investment compares
either with your alternative investment or with borrowing, whichever applies to
you. A positive net present value means this investment is better. A negative net
present value means your alternative investment, or not borrowing, is better.
Consider again this income stream:
Year

Income amounts

-$1000

$200

$200

$200

$200

$200

$200

Let's assume that the discount rate (the interest rate that you could earn elsewhere
or at which you could borrow) will not change over the life of the project. This
makes the calculation simpler. With this assumption, we can use the usual formula:

Present Value of any one income amount = (Income amount) / ( (1 + Discount


Rate) to the a power)
a is the number of years into the future that the income amount will be received (or
spent, if the income amount is negative).
The net present value (NPV) of a whole income stream is the sum of these present
values of the individual amounts in the income stream. If we still assume that
income comes or goes in annual bursts and that the discount rate will be constant in
the future, then the NPV has this formula:

Varying future interest rates


The future interest rate does not have to be constant for this theory to apply. The
interest rate can vary, but that makes the formulas messier. For example, if r1 is the
expected interest rate next year, and r2 is the expected interest rate the year after
that,

then

the

present

value

today

of

I2 income

in

year

is

I2/(1+r1)(1+r2).
The I 's are income amounts for each year. The subscripts (which are also the
exponents in the denominators) are the year numbers, starting with 0, which is this
year. The discount rate -- assumed to be constant in the future -- is r. The number
of years the investment lasts is n.
Three properties of the net present value of an income stream are:

1. Higher income amounts make the net present value higher. Lower income
amounts make the net present value lower.
Try it yourself. Click on a box in the Income row. Edit the number there, deleting
or

adding

some

digits.

Then

press

Enter.

The NPV box on the right shows the net present value, which is the total of the
amounts in the boxes in the Discounted row. (The total may be slightly off, due to
rounding.)
2. If profits come sooner, the net present value is higher. If profits come later, the
net present value is lower.
Try it yourself. This applet lets you move the income amounts to later or earlier.
You can see how that changes the net present value of the income stream.
3. Changing the discount rate changes the net present value. For an investment
with the common pattern of having costs early and profits later, a higher discount
rate makes the net present value smaller.
Try it yourself. Click on the discount rate box and change the number there. Then
press
You

Enter.
can

also

change

the

income

amounts,

if

you

want.

To summarize what was just illustrated, the net present value is higher if the
income amounts are larger, or if they come sooner, or if the discount rate is lower.
The net present value is lower if the income amounts are smaller, or if they come
later, or if the discount rate is higher.
Internal Rate of Return

In the example we've been using, if you keep the income amounts at their original
-1000, 200, 200, 200, 200, 200, and 200, and set the discount rate to 0.0547, the net
present value becomes 0. This discount rate, 0.0547 or 5.47%, is the internal rate
of return for this investment -- it is the discount rate that makes the net present
value equal 0. You can try this below, by setting the discount rate to 0.0547.
If you now raise any of the income amounts in years 1 through 6 (feel free to edit
an income amount and see for yourself), you will need a higher discount rate to
bring the net present value back to 0. That would seem to imply that projects with
higher incomes have higher internal rates of return.
Similarly, if you lower any of the income amounts in years 1 through 6, then a
lower discount rate will be needed to bring the net present value back up to 0. That
would seem to imply that projects with lower incomes have lower internal rates of
return.
These seeming implications are actually often true, if the projects being compared
have about the same shape, with the costs coming early and the benefits coming
late, and if the projects being compared switch from net outgo to net income at
about the same time. Otherwise, though, the implications might not be true.
Before we go on to that, a little review:
Which of these measures (net present value and internal rate of return) requires you
to

know

the

future

income

and

outgo

amounts?

Which of the measures requires you to know what the discount rate will be in the
future?

The internal rate of return does not require you to predict future discount rates.
That would seem to make the internal rate of return the more useful (or less
uncertain) measure. Sometimes, though, the internal rate of return can fool you.
Contradictory Results
A few years ago, the New England Journal of Medicine published a study that
evaluated various types of professional education as if they were financial
investments.
The article is: Weeks, W.B., Wallace, A.E., Wallace, M.M., Welch, H.G., "A
Comparison of the Educational Costs and Incomes of Physicians and Other
Professionals," N Engl J Med, May 5, 1994, 330(18), pp. 1280-1286.
The idea was to see if doctors were overpaid, by considering primary and specialty
medical education as investments and comparing them with investing in education
in business, law, and dentistry (but not university professors -- that would have
been too embarassing). Adjustments were made for differences in average working
hours. The authors found that primary medicine was the poorest investment of all
of these. Specialty medicine did better, but was not out of line with the other
professions.
In the results was this oddity: By the criterion of the net present value of lifetime
educational costs and income benefits, specialist physicians tied for highest with
attorneys. Both were ahead of business school graduates. However, by the
criterion of the internal rate of return, specialty physicians, with a 21% average
return, were well behind the attorneys' 25% average return, while the business
school graduates' 29% average return was the highest of all. The present value and
the internal rate of return ranked the alternatives differently!

By the way, since this article's 1994 publication, managed care has forced specialty
physician incomes down by perhaps one-third. This has sharply lowered the
investment value of a specialty medical education.
The NPV Curve
One way to understand how the net present value and the internal rate of return can
give seemingly different advice is to use what I will call the net present value
curve, or NPV curve. The NPV curve shows the relationship between the discount
rate and the net present value for a range of discount rates. The present value at a
given discount rate, such as 5%, and the internal rate of return are each points on
the NPV curve.
The NPV curve, the relationship between the discount rate and the net present
value

has

formula

that

can

be

written

like

this:

This, of course, is the formula we saw already for the net present value, for
annualized costs and revenues and a constant discount rate. Each I is an income
amount for a specific year. The subscripts (which are also the exponents in the
denominators) are the year numbers, starting with 0, which is this year. The
constant discount rate is r. The number of years the investment lasts is n. In
Weeks's study of professionals' incomes, n was about 44, because costs and
incomes were calculated from age 21 to age 65.

We'll use an example with an n of 6, so the formula fits on your screen:

This is our machine investment example that we have been using all along.
The NPV is

function

of r.

Graphed,

it

looks

like

this:

The blue curve shows the net present value for discount rates (r) from 0 to 0.1 (0%
to 10%). The red dots are the two points we get from our measures. The left red
dot shows the net present value at the discount rate of 0.05 (5%). The right red dot
shows the internal rate of return, because it is where the curve crosses the
horizontal line indicating an NPV of 0. That right red dot is between the 0.05 and
0.06 marks on the r axis, so the internal rate of return is between 0.05 and 0.06.
(The actual internal rate of return is about 0.0547, as we saw earlier.)

Imagine we have another possible investment, which has this NPV equation:

This investment is like the first, except that the net profit in years 1 through 6 is
$220 per year, rather than $200. I would say that this investment has a similar
"shape" to the first, because the costs and profits come at the same times. Also, the
size of the initial outlay is the same for both. The only difference is the amount of
profit.

Here's

graph

with

both

investments

on

it:

The green curve is the second investment. It is above and parallel to the first
investment's blue curve. The left orange dot shows the net present value of the
second investment at the discount rate of 0.05. The net present value there is a
little over $100. This is higher than the left red dot, so the net present value

at r=5% of the green-line investment is higher than the net present value at r=5%
for the blue-line investment.
The right orange dot shows where the second investment's curve crosses the
NPV=0 line. This is well to the right of the first investment's internal rate of return
dot. The internal rate of return for the second investment is much higher (further to
the right).
In this example, our two measures, the net present value at r=0.05 and the internal
rate of return, tell us the same thing. They both say the second investment is
better. A look at the graph above confirms that the second investment is better at
all discount rates, so it is fair to say that the second investment is unequivocably
better than the first.
Can You Do Both Investments?
Doing an investment increases your wealth if its net present value is greater than 0
at the discount rate relevant to you. If your discount rate is less than 5.47%, both
NPV curves are in positive territory, and you should do both, if you can.
Sometimes, though, the alternative investments are mutually exclusive. For
example, there may be two ways to build a dam across a particular river. You can
do one or the other, but not both. There may be several alternative ways to address
a workplace safety problem. There is no point to doing more than one if any one
way solves the problem. Deciding on a professional education involves somewhat
mutually exclusive choices. A few people do go to medical school and then law
school, but the additional return from the second degree is not the same as what
someone going to law school fresh out of college would expect.

If you can only do one investment, you should choose the one with the highest net
present value at the discount rate appropriate to you. A problem with that advice,
though, is that discount rates can change with general economic conditions. You
are therefore more confident about choosing one investment over another if your
chosen investment has a higher net present value over a broad range of possible
discount rates. In our example so far, the green-line investment has a higher net
present value at all discount rates, so we would choose it with confidence.
Regardless of what happens in the future to discount rates, we'll be better off with
the green-line investment than with the blue-line investment.
Can NPV Curves Cross?
Yes, they can. If the NPV curves cross, then the choice of investment depends on
the discount rate.
To create an example, I'll change the blue line investment so that its profits come
much later. This increases the effect of the discount rate on the net present value.
Below are the two income streams, now. Also shown are their net present values at
a 5% discount rate and their internal rates of return.
Year

NPV at Internal
0.05

rate of

discount return
rate
Green

line -

investment
Blue

$117

0.086

$1550 $157

0.076

$1000

line -

investment

$220 $220 $220 $220 $220 $220

$1000

$0

$0

$0

$0

$0

(modified)
The green line invesment has the higher internal rate of return, but the blue line
investment has the higher net present value at a 5% discount rate. Our two
measures are giving us opposite advice!

The graph shows what's going on, by showing the Net Present Value curves for
both investments for discount rates between 0% and 10%. The curves cross at a
discount rate of about 0.064, or 6.4%.
Now, to choose which investment we want to do, assuming we cannot do both, we
have to make a guess about what future discount rates will be. If we expect
discount rates to be less than 6.4%, where the curves cross, we choose the blue line
investment. For discount rates above 6.4%, but below 8.56% (the internal rate of
return of the green line investment -- the discount rate at which the net present
value of the green line investment is $0), we choose the green line investment. At
higher discount rates than 8.56%, we don't do either, because the net present values
are below $0 for both investments.

If Costs Come Later Than Profits


If costs come later than profits, the NPV curve can tilt the other way, making it
even more problematic to use the internal rate of return to compare investments.
Costs can come later than profits if an investment creates environmental problems
that will have to watched or cleaned up later. Nuclear power plants are a good
example. After about 40 years of service (sometimes less than that), they become
too contaminated with radiation to continue in service. They must then be closed
and either guarded where they are for thousands of years or dismantled and moved
to a disposal site.
Consider this income stream:
Year

Income amounts

-$200

$200

$200

$200

$200

$200

-$900

I've reduced the initial cost, but added a big cost at the end. Let's see what a
difference this makes in how the NPV changes when the discount rate changes. In
the applet below, the starting discount rate 5%. The net present value (NPV) is $6. That's negative six dollars, so if your discount rate really were 5%, you would
not want to do this investment.
Try changing the discount rate, by clicking in the discount rate box and changing
the 0.05 to something else. Try 0.04 or 0.03. In the examples above, the NPV goes
up when the discount rate is lowered. Is that true for this project? Then try 0.06 or
0.07.

What

happens

to

the

NPV?

(Keep the discount rates reasonably small, like between 0.00, which is 0%, and 0.3,
which is 30%.)
The relationship between the discount rate and the NPV is the reverse of what we
see with "normal" investments! With this kind of income stream, higher discount
rates make the net present value bigger, and lower discount rates make the net
present value smaller.
Before leaving the applet above, see if you can find the internal rate of return, the
discount rate that makes the net present value equal to $0.
Here

is

the

NPV

graph:

The left blue dot shows the net present value at a 5% (0.05) discount rate. It is at $6

on

the

net

present

value

scale.

The right blue dot is where the curve crosses the discount rate axis, which is where
the net present value is $0. The discount rate here, 0.054 (5.4%), is the internal
rate of return.

Or, at least, it fits the standard definition of internal rate of return. However, unlike
the usual situation, this project is profitable at interest rates above this IRR and
unprofitable at interest rates below this IRR.
Suppose we have an alternative project which also has this shape, with a big cost at
the end, but slightly lower profits in the intermediate years. I'll call the new
alternative

Year

the

"green

line

investment."

NPV

at Internal

0.05

rate

discount

return

of

rate
Red

line -

investment
Green

$200

line -

investment

$200

$200 $200 $200 $200 $200 -

-$6

0.054

-$27

0.070

$900
$195 $195 $195 $195 $195 $900

The green line investment has a lower NPV than the red line investment at all
discount rates, because it has lower profits in years 1 through 5, and the same costs
in years 0 and 6. In particular, as the table above indicates, it has a lower NPV at
the 0.05 discount rate. The graph below shows the NPV curves for both
investments, with the green line lying below the red line at all discount rates.

The green line investment is clearly inferior, but it has the higher internal rate of
return. The green line investment's IRR is 0.07. The red line investment's is 0.054.
Thus, for projects with big late costs, the better projects will have lower internal
rates of return, the opposite of the rule for normal projects that have their costs
early and their positive returns later.
Now let's discover something even more strange. Here's another applet that lets
you change the discount rate and see the effect on the red line investment's value.
This one, though, allows you to take the discount rate over 0.3 (30%) and all the
way up to 1.0 (100%). Those rates are much higher than, hopefully, we will ever
see in the U.S., but they are theoretically possible, and they show a strange
phenomenon.
Try raising the discount rate to 0.3, and notice what happens to the net present
value. Then, raise the discount rate some more above that. In which direction does
the

NPV

move

See if you can find the second IRR, where the NPV is zero again!

now?

Here's the NPV curve for the red line investment for discount rates from 0% to
100%.

At discount rates below 0.054, the NPV is negative, and this investment is worse
than

doing

nothing.

At a discount rate of 0.054, the NPV is 0. The first IRR for this investment is
0.054.
If the discount rate rises above 0.054, the NPV turns positive, and this investment
switches

to

being

profitable.

At a discount rate of 0.262 (26.2%), the NPV for this investment reaches its
maximum. If the discount rate rises further than that, the NPV falls.
The NPV reaches 0 again at a discount rate of 0.86. This is the second IRR for this
investment.

If the discount rate were rises even more, above 0.86, the NPV turns negative
again. This investment reswitches to being unprofitable.
Lesson: The NPV curve gives better guidance than the IRR alone
The lesson I would like you to get from this is that the internal rate of return, by
itself, can fool you. If the investments you are considering have different shapes
(that is, very different timing of costs and benefits) or if the project has large late
cleanup costs, then the higher-IRR-is-better rule can steer you to the wrong
investment. Ideally, you want the NPV curve, if you want to evaluate an
investment.
Additional notes
My use of the terms "switch" and "reswitch" refers to the reswitching controversy
of the 1960's. This was between economists in Cambridge, England, and
Cambridge, Massachusetts, over whether capital markets can be analyzed just like
other commodity markets. The English economists, led by Joan Robinson, argued
that capital markets were special because of the possibility of reswitching, which
raises basic questions about the standard view that the return to owning capital is a
society's reward for abstaining from consumption.
Some economists would say that only the second of our IRR's is the true IRR, by
defining the IRR as the place where the NPV is 0 and where the NPV is falling.
The problems with that are: (1) this distinction is usually lost in practice, and (2)
by making the pattern of costs and profits more complex, I can make up an
investment that has multiple discount rates where the NPV is 0 and the NPV is
declining.

The oldest discussion of this tutorial's issues that I have found in the economics
literature is Lorie JH, Savage LJ, "Three Problems in Capital Rationing," Journal
of Business, Vol. 28, October 1955.

Das könnte Ihnen auch gefallen