Sie sind auf Seite 1von 27

CAPITAL STRUCTURE AND THE FINANCING DECISION

The Basic Financing Choices: Equity and Debt


Common Equity
Ownership of the business and the right to manage and control the enterprise
Entitled to all residual income, i.e., profits after interest, taxes, and all other prior
claims. No guarantee of financial returns
Bears the residual risks of the business, but has limited liability

Debt
A contractual obligation on repayment of principal and compensation for the use
of the capital, which are not contingent on the financial performance of the
borrower
Senior to equity claims whether on the distribution of income, or the distribution
of assets in the event of the dissolution of the business
Generally fixed and predetermined return to lenders capital; interest payments
provide a tax shield for the borrower
Repayment of principal generally follows a predetermined schedule within a
specified period (the loan period)

Preferred Equity
A type of financing that lies between debt and common equity
Technically a form of equity, but typically do not have voting rights
Senior to common equity but subordinate to debt
Often has no definite maturity, but issuer sets either a redemption option,
conversion to common equity, or buyback in the secondary market
Investor cash income is in the form of dividends which are less binding than
interest payments but are senior to common dividends. Since preferred is a form
of equity, dividend payments dont have a tax shield.

R.C. Ybaez UP Cesar E.A. Virata School of Business

The Decision Criteria


The Financial Objective: Maximize shareholder value =
maximize market value of common stock
The Financing Criteria: The capital structure and financing policies that are
supportive of corporate strategies, and which
enhance shareholder value through a superior riskreturn payoff

The Use of Debt Finance to Enhance Shareholder Value


1. Financial Leverage
Use of fixed-rate debt, or financing with a limited rate of return, to fund
investments whose rate of return exceeds the cost of financing
Cost of debt is lower than the cost of equity because of the lower risk to
creditors
Positive leverage: when rate of return on invested capital1 (ROIC) >
after-tax cost of debt
Positive leverage enhances shareholder rate of return (ROE)
ROE is higher:
- the higher the ROIC
- the lower the interest rate or cost of debt
- the higher the debt-equity ratio
Leverage amplifies the impact of changes in operating rate of return on
ROE

Invested capital is total assets less non-interest bearing, spontaneous liabilities, e.g., accounts
payable. The peso return on invested capital is net operating profits after taxes (NOPAT);
percentage return is rate of return on invested capital (ROIC). For simplicity, we assume
throughout that there are no non-operating income and assets and hence, pre-tax operating profits
= EBIT. These measures are consistent with the WACC and valuation framework.
R.C. Ybaez UP Cesar E.A. Virata School of Business

Table 1 Financial Leverage Without Tax Shield


No Debt
Debt:Equity Ratio

Debt at 8%

60:40

70:30

EBIT
Less: Tax (30%)
Net operating profit after tax
Less: Interest expense
Earnings available to common
shareholders

250,000
75,000
175,000
0

250,000
75,000
175,000
48,000

250,000
75,000
175,000
56,000

175,000

127,000

119,000

Return on Equity (ROE)


Payments to all suppliers
of capital

17.5 %

31.75 %

39.7 %

175,000

175,000

175,000

_______________________________________________________________________________

Assumed: operating assets or invested capital of P1 million, return on invested


capital (ROIC) of 17.5%, or 25% pre-tax

Table 2 ROE at Alternative EBIT and Financial Leverage


High EBIT1
No Debt
Debt:Equity Ratio

High EBIT1 High EBIT1


Moderate Debt Large Debt2

60:40

70:30

300,000
90,000
210,000
0

300,000
90,000
210,000
48,000

300,000
90,000
210,000
56,000

Earnings available to common


shareholders
210,000

162,000

154,000

21.0 %

40.5 %

51.3 %

210,000

210,000

210,000

EBIT
Less: Tax (30%)
NOPAT
Less: Interest expense (8%)

ROE
Payments to all suppliers
of capital

_____________________________________________
1

EBIT is 20% higher.


2
Assume no change in interest rate. Debt is 70% of invested capital.
3

R.C. Ybaez UP Cesar E.A. Virata School of Business

2. Tax Benefits
Financing options that produce net tax benefits enhance value
Interest payments are deductible from taxable income; on the other
hand, payments to shareholders (cash dividends) do not provide a tax
shield
REMEMBER: principal payment is not an expense!

Table 3 Financial Leverage With Tax Shield


No Debt
Debt:Equity Ratio

Debt at 8%

60:40

70:30

EBIT
Less: Interest Expense
EBT
Less: Tax (30%)
Earnings available to common
shareholders

250,000
0
250,000
75,000

250,000
48,000
202,000
60,600

250,000
56,000
194,000
58,200

175,000

141,400

135,800

Return on Equity (ROE)


Payments to all suppliers
of capital

17.5 %

35.4 %

45.3 %

175,000

189,400

191,800

ROE = r +

D
[ r kd (1 tc)]
E

where r = ROIC

[ in illustration, 17.5% = 25% (1 0.3) ]

kd = interest rate on debt


tc = corporate income tax rate
Note: In using this formula, if there are other non-equity financing, e.g.,
preferred stock, include these under the category debt
4

R.C. Ybaez UP Cesar E.A. Virata School of Business

Table 4 ROE at Alternative EBIT and Financial Leverage


with Tax Shield
High EBIT
No Debt
Debt:Equity Ratio

High EBIT
High EBIT
Moderate Debt Large Debt

60:40

70:30

300,000
0
300,000
90,000

300,000
48,000
252,000
75,600

300,000
56,000
244,000
73,200

Earnings available to common


shareholders
210,000

176,400

170,800

21.0 %

44.1 %

56.9 %

210,000

224,400

226,800

EBIT
Less: Interest expense
EBT
Less: Tax (30%)

ROE
Payments to all suppliers
of capital

Qualification 1: Increased ROE Volatility


Higher risk to shareholders due to increased ROE volatility
Negative Leverage: ROIC < after-tax cost of debt
ROE of debt option < ROE of equity option
ROE volatility for levered firm is higher:
- the higher the operating risks (the more risky the business)
- the more volatile the interest rate environment
- the higher the debt-equity ratio
- the greater the mismatch between operating and financing cash flows (in
terms of currency, interest rate basis, etc.)

R.C. Ybaez UP Cesar E.A. Virata School of Business

Table 5 Financial Leverage and Volatility of ROE


ROE at pre-tax
ROIC = 25 %

ROE at pre-tax
% Decrease
ROIC = 15 %

Unlevered (0:100)

17.5 %

10.5 %

40.0 %

Moderate Debt (60:40)

35.4 %

17.9 %

49.4%

Large Debt (70:30)

45.3 %

21.9 %

51.6 %

Table 6 Sensitivity Analysis of Moderate Debt Case


(% Change Relative to Base Case)
% Decrease in pre-tax ROIC

% Decrease in ROE

20 %

24.8 %

40 %

49.5 %

60 %

74.3 %

80 %

99.0 %

Table 7 Sensitivity Analysis of Large Debt Case


(% Change Relative to Base Case)

% Decrease in pre-tax ROIC

% Decrease in ROE

20 %

25.8 %

40 %

51.5 %

60 %

77.3 %

80 %

103.1 %

R.C. Ybaez UP Cesar E.A. Virata School of Business

EBIT-EPS Chart: analyzing the interaction between operating and


risks

financing

EPS
0.57

0.5
0.4
0.3 0.28
0.2
0.1 0.09
0
48

80

100

150

200

250 EBIT

Levered firm has steeper slope: EPS fluctuations will be larger


Break-even EBIT: EBIT level where EPSe = EPSd
EPSe for all-equity

EBIT(1 t c )
625,000

EPSd for levered equity

(EBIT 48,000)(1 t c )
250,000

Break-even EBIT = 80,000 and EPS = 0.09 for both schemes


The risk of negative leverage: what is the likelihood that EBIT will fall below
the break-even level of P80,000?
Note: include other non-equity cost of financing, e.g., dividends of preferred stocks, if
present
7

R.C. Ybaez UP Cesar E.A. Virata School of Business

Modigliani-Miller (M-M) Arbitrage: Does Debt Matter?


(assuming perfect capital markets and zero taxes)
Company A (Unlevered) Company B (Levered)
(P600,000 debt at 8%)
Operating income
Interest Expenses
Earnings to Common

P 175,000
0
175,000

P175,000
48,000
127,000

Cost of Equity (ke)


Value of Equity (Ve)
Value of Debt (Vd)
Value of Firm (V=Ve + Vd)

15.75%
1,111,111
0
1,111,111

20.0%
635,000
600,000
1,235,000

15.75%
0

14.17%
150%

Cost of capital (WACC)


Debt/Equity Ratio

Consider now an investor who owns 1% of Company B:


he has an equity of P6,350 on which he earns annually P1,270
this corporate equity is leveraged up to 1.5x of equity at a cost of 8%
Suppose he now:
sells his shares in Company B (gets P6,350 cash, loses P1,270 income)
borrows P6,000 at 8%, i.e., assumes personal leverage equivalent to 1% of B's
debt and hence is leveraged to the same degree as B.
buys 1% of Company A's equity for P11,111.11 - hence, releasing P1,238.89 of
his personal funds
Net returns to the investor:
Investment income (P11,111.11 x 15.75%)
Less interest (P6,000 x 8%)
Net income

P 1,750
(480)
P1,270

Investor is obviously better off selling the levered stock and substituting personal
leverage and investing in the unlevered stock. This arbitrage operation will drive B
prices down and/or A prices up. The process must stop at a point where the market
value (and cost of capital) of both firms will be equal.

R.C. Ybaez UP Cesar E.A. Virata School of Business

The Combined Effect of Corporate and Personal Taxes


Operating Income (P 1)
Paid out as interest

Corporate Tax

None

tc

Income after corporate


tax

1 tc

Personal Tax

td

te(1 tc)

(1 td)

(1 te)(1 tc)

Income after all taxes


tc
td
te

or paid out as dividend

= corporate tax rate


= personal tax rate on lenders interest income
= personal tax rate on shareholders dividend income

Corporations benefit from the corporate tax shield, but the interest income may be taxed at
the personal level. Investors presumably decide on the basis of after-tax returns. A higher
tax on interest income means investors will avoid lending unless interest rates increase to
compensate for the higher tax. Thus, taxes on interest income reduce the advantage of
corporate debt. Taxes on equity income on the other hand increase the advantage of
corporate debt.
Debt will have a net tax advantage if :

(1 td) > (1 tc) (1 te) or T = 1

(1 t c )(1 t e )
>0
(1 t d )

It can be shown that the value contribution of debt is TVd. Note that if personal taxes are
disregarded, the value contribution of debt is tcVd.

Other qualifications to the tax benefit from debt: taxes on secondary trading of
securities, alternative tax shelters of the enterprise, etc.

R.C. Ybaez UP Cesar E.A. Virata School of Business

Qualification 2: Risk of Default and Financial Distress


Operating, Investment and Financing Cash Flow, Year 1
Average EBIT
No
Debt
Earnings after Tax

Moderate
Debt

Low EBIT1
No
Debt

Moderate
Debt

175,000

141,400

105,000

71,400

50,000

50,000

50,000

50,000

Investment (Capex and


working capital)

( 50,000)

( 50,000)

( 30,000)

( 30,000)

Operating & invest. CF

175,000

141,400

125,000

91,400

Depreciation

Payment of Principal2
Cash Surplus (Deficit)

(120,000)
175,000

21,400

(120,000)
125,000

( 28,600)

____________________
1

Pre-tax ROIC of 15%, or 40% lower than average pre-tax ROIC

Assuming equal principal payments over a 5-year term, 8% interest rate

Risk of default and financial distress is higher


- the higher the operating risks (the more risky the business)
- the higher the debt-equity ratio
- the greater the mismatch between operating and financing cash flows (i.e.,
mismatch in maturity, currency, etc.)
- the less liquid are assets; the lower the proportion of tangible assets

10

R.C. Ybaez UP Cesar E.A. Virata School of Business

Long-term liquidity needs to be managed


- match assets and liabilities: match operating cash flow with debt service
(short-term financing is cheaper but increases default risk)
- matching cash flows may require lengthening maturities, grace periods,
bullet repayments, etc.
- use financing instruments with flexible cash flow requirements, e.g.,
preferred stocks, convertibles, etc.
- maintain liquidity reserves in cash and near-cash assets, excess borrowing
capacity, etc. (dont run out of cash)
Qualification 3: Direct and Indirect Costs of financial distress
Direct Costs: Administrative costs, cost of lawyers, auditors, financial advisers,
etc., as the two parties attempt to resolve a conflict situation2
Indirect Costs
loss of market share and increased business risk. If safety, health, quality
and/or after-market relationships are important concerns, customers may
take their business elsewhere
loss of key employees who are concerned about job security
loss of suppliers: particularly those who need to invest long-term, e.g., who
invest in specialized equipment, or must hire specialized skills or spend on
specialized training to do business with borrower
(these ideas are often referred to as the stakeholder theory)

Weak regulatory structure and poor enforcement of bankruptcy laws impact on these costs. In
February 2010, 10 years after the bill was first filed, the Financial Rehabilitation and Insolvency
Act was finally passed.

11

R.C. Ybaez UP Cesar E.A. Virata School of Business

reduced flexibility to address operating problems. Creditors will want to


conserve and secure assets. Their actions could restrict the ability of the
borrower firm to manage and redeploy assets, or dispose of assets
valuable management time is diverted to dealing with creditors and
receivers
dynamics of competition may become less predictable. Competitors, smelling
blood, may launch predatory attacks (e.g., price war). Or the distressed firm
may itself initiate a price war to grab market share and raise cash in the
short run

12

R.C. Ybaez UP Cesar E.A. Virata School of Business

Qualification 4: Agency Costs and Loan Covenants


Option and agency theories suggest that levered firms may attempt to
maximize shareholder value at the expense of creditors
Some ways that borrowing firms can do this:
- owner-borrower will resist liquidation: playing for time
- underinvestment in positive NPV projects
- asset substitution that increases the riskiness of the business (e.g., investing
in high risk, negative NPV projects)
- bias for short-term investments
- the dilution of the claims of existing creditors through the issuance of
additional debt of higher or equal priority: bait and switch
- excessive withdrawals by shareholders: take the money and run via cash
dividends, share repurchases, DOSRI loans, excessive compensation for
owner-managers, sweetheart deals with subsidiaries/affiliates
Loan covenants: the fine print of loan agreements that guard against such
types of borrower misbehavior and the resulting dilution in the value of
creditor claims
To the borrowing firm, covenants are an added burden/cost:
- reduce flexibility and dilute control, e.g., restrictions on investments
- ultimately costly as creditors may pass on their monitoring and
enforcement cost to the borrower by way of higher interest rates
If lenders are not convinced that the borrower will comply, or if
enforcement cost is too high, lenders will simply not provide funding

13

R.C. Ybaez UP Cesar E.A. Virata School of Business

The Case of the Financially Distressed Company

Capital

Periodic Cash Flow


2
3
4

Book value

1,000,000

175,000

Debt (8%, 5
years)

600,000

Equity

400,000

(168,000)

65,000

65,000

65,000

(158,400) (148,800)

(139,200) (129,600)

The firms cost of capital is 15.75%


PV of firm = PV of future cash flows =

175,000
65,000
+
= 507,731
1.1575 0.1575(1.1575)

So,
1. Firm is not yet in default on its debt, but it will default by year 2 if there is no significant
improvement in operating cash flows.
2. In fact, the value of the firm is less than its liabilities in essence, the firm is bankrupt!
The value of the equity in theory is zero; in PV terms, only creditors capital has any
significant value. (Option theory however says that the market value will not be zero for
as long as shareholders remain the legal owners. Equity value in this case is purely option
value)
Now, it is often the case that a financially distressed company may still have profitable
investment opportunities (i.e., NPV > 0), or maybe even a plan to restructure operations.
But this will now require external financing.
Suppose one such investment opportunity has the following cash flow:
Period
Cash flow

0
(85,000)

35,000

35,000

35,000

35,000

35,000

At the current cost of capital, PV of future CF is P115,272 for an NPV of P30,272


Questions:
1. Will existing shareholders be willing to infuse the additional financing? Would other
investors be willing to? Would creditors? Under what general terms?
2. What feasible options are there to manage the debt overhang and service the debt? Under
what general terms?
14

R.C. Ybaez UP Cesar E.A. Virata School of Business

The Shortsighted Investment Problem


Cash Flows of Textronics
Debt Due

From Existing
Assets

From ShortTerm Project

From LongTerm Project

Year 1 P100 million

P 50 million

P 50 million

P 20 million

Year 2

60 million in
favorable state

0 million

40 million

40 million

10 million in
unfavorable state
To simplify the illustration, assume that the risk-free rate is zero, both cash flows are certain, and
the long-term project has a higher PV than the short-term project.
The cash flow from existing assets on the other hand is certain for year 1, but uncertain for year 2.
The probability of favorable vs. unfavorable state in year 2 is 50:50.
If Textronics chooses the long-term project:

NPV will be higher, but


company will not be able to service debt in year 1 from operating cash flow (P100 million vs.
P70 million); it will need to borrow P 30 million in subordinated debt
If the new debt is subordinated to existing debt, the firm must promise to pay P50 million in
year 2. This ensures an expected value of P30 million: (50% x P50 m) + (50% x P10 m).
Notice that in the unfavorable state, existing debt can still be paid (P10 m + P40 m vs. P40 m)
but only P10 m will be available for subordinated debt.

If Textronics chooses the short-term project:

NPV will be lower


it will be able to meet its debt obligations in year 1 (P100 million outflow vs. P100 million
inflow)

What project will Textronics pursue? If year 2 results in an unfavorable state, Textronics will
default regardless of the project it pursues and the value of equity will be zero. If year 2 results in
a favorable state, the value of the firms equity is:
P 10 m if the long-term project is taken: (P60 m + P40 m) (P40 + P50)
P 20 m if the short-term project is taken: P60 m P40 m
Textronics will therefore choose the short-term project. Shareholders gain at the expense of
existing creditors who are better off if the long-term project is chosen.
15

R.C. Ybaez UP Cesar E.A. Virata School of Business

Bankruptcy and Liquidation Decisions of Firms


with More Than One Class of Debt
Mayer Inc. has no cash flow in the current period, but will have cash flows of P1.5 million next
year if the economy is favorable and P0.5 million if the economy is unfavorable (with equal
probabilities for the two states). Assuming risk neutrality and a zero discount rate, the operating
value of the firm is therefore P1 million.
Also assume that if the firm were liquidated immediately, it would generate P1.2 million in
proceeds. Hence, if the firm were financed entirely with equity, shareholders would choose to
have the firm liquidated immediately.
The firms debt obligations are listed below. The venture capitalist is subordinated to the other
creditors.

Debt Obligations

Debt Holders
Venture Capitalist

Immediate

Next Year

P 150,000

P 1,000,000

200,000

Mayer will be forced into bankruptcy if it cannot meet its P150,000 current obligation. If this
happens, all of its debt obligations become due immediately and the debt holders will take control
of the firm. The payoffs shows clearly that debt holders will want to liquidate because they can
still be paid in full. Note that the junior debt held by the venture capitalist will only get back
P50,000 of the P200,000 debt owed them by Mayer (P1.2 million liquidation value less senior
debt of P1.15 million). Shareholders get nothing.

Payoff in the Event of Liquidation

Debt Holders
Venture Capitalist
Stockholders

16

P 1,150,000
50,000
0

R.C. Ybaez UP Cesar E.A. Virata School of Business

The table below suggests that both shareholders and the venture capitalist have an incentive to
avoid liquidation - even though the firms value is maximized if the firm is liquidated. For
example, the venture capitalist might be persuaded to infuse an additional P150,000 cash to pay
off the immediate claim of debt holders. Shareholders would be willing to pay very high interest say P100,000, or an effective rate of 67%.
The venture capitalist would effectively invest P200,000 (cash infusion of P150,000 plus
foregone liquidation proceeds of P50,000) for a 50% chance to earn P450,000. He would receive
zero otherwise, for an expected value of P225,000.
Shareholders have a 50% chance of receiving P50,000 which is better than a zero value if the firm
is liquidated immediately.
Note that debt holders are worse off since they effectively forego P1 million today (P1.15 million
from liquidation, minus P150,000 immediate payment they would have received anyway) in
exchange for a payoff with an expected value of P750,000.
Payoffs in the Event of a Cash Infusion

Next Year States of the Economy


Immediate

Favorable

Unfavorable

Debt Holders

P 150,000

P 1,000,000

P 500,000

Venture Capitalist

150,000

450,000

50,000

Stockholders

Can the shareholders of Mayer be persuaded to infuse additional equity of P150,000? Not likely,
there is no incremental gain for them - the payoff from an infusion is P300,000 in a favorable
state, and zero in an unfavorable state, or an expected value of P150,000.

17

R.C. Ybaez UP Cesar E.A. Virata School of Business

Examples of Loan Covenants


Standard Covenants
1. Monitoring disclosures and furnishing of regular financial reports.
Undertaken by credit rating agencies in the case of bonds
2. Financial ratio requirements liquidity, debt ratios, etc.
3. Conservation and maintenance of assets property taxes, insurance,
equipment maintenance, etc.
4. Collateral secures claim of senior creditors, especially in the event of
liquidation. Mitigates other possible borrower misbehavior
Covenants intended to deter asset substitution
1. Collateral requirement prevents sale of asset wherein cash proceeds may
then be reinvested elsewhere, or its use to acquire more debt
2. Restrictions on investments in unrelated businesses, mergers, acquisitions
Covenants to deter attempts to take the money and run
1. Restrictions on cash dividends and the repurchase of stocks, on
compensation to owner-managers, DOSRI advances, etc.
2. Restrictions on transactions with subsidiaries and affiliates
Protective covenants need to be monitored and enforced, which can be costly.
Also, covenants alone cannot solve all possible borrower-creditor conflicts.
Alternative approaches include:
Security design
Short term debt vs long term debt
Bank and privately placed debt vs bonds

18

R.C. Ybaez UP Cesar E.A. Virata School of Business

The Trade-Off Theory of Capital Structure

There is an optimal capital structure that results from balancing tax


shield benefits vs bankruptcy and agency costs
In theory, capital structure is optimal at the minimum WACC. In
practice, firms likely aim for a credit rating corresponding to the
target capital structure, rather than target WACC
In general, higher debt-ratios for firms with:
stable businesses, mature businesses (lower operating risk). This
implies that firms in the same industry will have comparable capital
structures
high profitability (more taxable income to shield)
more tangible assets (collateral, lower risk of asset substitution)
more liquid assets
regulated firms (regulatory oversight lowers risk for creditors,
transparency)

Other Financing Sources of Value


1. Regulatory Constraints and Regulatory Costs
Avoidance of regulatory constraints/costs
2. Transactions Cost, Liquidity and Trading Costs
Transactions costs of external finance, particularly capital market (nonbank) transactions. Internally generated funds, i.e., retained earnings, do
not have transactions costs
Liquidity investors value liquidity, e.g., via a secondary market,
especially liquidity of long-term securities
Taxes and fees on secondary trades can reduce liquidity
19

R.C. Ybaez UP Cesar E.A. Virata School of Business

3. Information Asymmetry and Financial Signaling


Information asymmetry: insiders (managers and major shareholders)
know more than outsiders (creditors/investing public)
Disclosure laws, financial reporting rules and third-party evaluation, e.g.,
credit rating agencies, mitigate the information asymmetry
The lemon problem: investors/lenders worry that the firm will take
advantage of their superior information. Market could react by
underpricing debts/equity issues of the firm
The information value of business decisions: what firms do (more than
what they say) can signal to capital markets the financial health and
prospects of the firm

4. Financial Engineering and Financial Innovation


As in any business, product innovations can be important sources of
value. Financing instruments that address an unmet demand for certain
return or risk characteristics can create value for the firm. Or products
that match the riskiness of the product with the risk management
capabilities of the investor
Financial innovations can mitigate information asymmetry (e.g.,
convertibles), reduce transactions cost (e.g., shelf registration), enhance
liquidity (e.g., ETFs), mitigate specific types of risks (e.g., reinvestment
risk is avoided via zero coupon bonds), permit specific risks to be traded
(e.g., credit default swaps that trade credit risks), etc.
Caveat for issuers of innovative securities: financial products generally
dont have patent protection, so issuers should cash in quickly on their
innovations
Caveat for investors: the complexity of a financial product is not
necessarily an indication of a well-crafted product. Maybe the products
complexity is deliberate to mask the true value, or risk, of the product
(examples are the subprime securities like CDOs and CDO-squared)

20

R.C. Ybaez UP Cesar E.A. Virata School of Business

5. Corporate Control
Capital structure choices impact on corporate control
Corporate control is the power to direct and manage the business. Its
value derives mainly from the value of management.
For example, hostile takeovers often lead to changes in management and
to asset restructuring, disposal of poorly performing assets changes
whose aim is to increase cash flow and/or reduce risk
Via a pyramid structure, control rights are partially delinked from cash
flow rights. This can be a financing advantage: minority equity, like debt
capital, can be tapped without unduly diluting controlling shareholders
control rights (see chart)
The dark side of corporate control: pyramiding provides opportunities
for controlling shareholders to expropriate value from minority
shareholders (an agency conflict similar to that faced by creditors)
9 diversion of resources to companies owned by the controlling shareholders
9 transfer of resources at terms/price disadvantageous to the target company
9 acquisition of additional cash-flow rights, e.g., warrants at below fair value
issued directly to the controlling shareholders or indirectly through
companies owned by controlling shareholders
9 access to firms technology, management systems, business intelligence, etc.
that are beneficial to the controlling shareholders business interests.
9 above-normal compensation and perks for controlling shareholders who
serve as officers/directors

These can be mitigated by regulations that protect the rights of minority


shareholders
One international study has half of its Philippine sample operating
through the pyramid structure. Another study shows that the greater the
difference between control rights and cash flow rights, the lower is
shareholder value

21

R.C. Ybaez UP Cesar E.A. Virata School of Business

Illustration of Pyramiding: Leveraging Control


Base Structure

Pyramid Structure
Assume P100 equity
Holding company
Minority

Founders

25%

75%

P20

P60

Minority

Founders

Minority

Holding co.

40%

60%

20%

80%

P40

P60

P20

P80

Alternatively,
Holding company
Minority

Minority

22

Founders

30%

70%

P15

P35

Holding co. Founders

25%

50%

25%

P25

P50

P25

R.C. Ybaez UP Cesar E.A. Virata School of Business

Scenario: Additional minority equity of P20; total dividends of P10


Base Structure

Pyramid Structure
Holding company
Minority

Founders

25%

75%

P20

P60

1.67

Addl.
Minority Founders
Minority
50%
P20

P40

5.00
P10

5.00

Minority

5.00

Holding co.

50%

33%

67%

P60

P40

P80

3.33

6.67

P10

1. The new equity reduces founders ownership to a fragile 50% in the base
case; in the pyramid structure, they retain effective control
2. Founders get exactly the same dividends in both structures (note: typically,
dividends to corporate shareholders are exempt from taxes)
23

R.C. Ybaez UP Cesar E.A. Virata School of Business

A Recap of Trade-Off Theory


Implies an optimal capital structure (debt-to-equity ratio):
a tradeoff between tax benefits from leverage versus financial distress costs
Some Implications of Trade-Off Theory
The optimal debt ratio is higher:
1. the less risky the business. This suggests firms in the same business (hence,
of comparable business risk) will tend to have similar debt ratios
2. the more profitable is the business (need for tax shield)
3. the greater the proportion of tangible assets (collateral) in total resources
Debt ratios will be lower for firms with significant growth opportunities. (asset
substitution problems for creditors).
Trade-off theory suggests that capital structure will adjust to changes in tax
rates and the tax structure
Stakeholder Theory: businesses that require long-term relationships with
customers and other stakeholders will avoid risky debt, e.g., firms with high
value employees with specialized skills/knowledge; firms where safety/health,
after-market service, replacements parts are crucial to buyer choice; firms who
rely heavily on long-term suppliers and subcontractors, etc.
Firm Size and Leverage: high debt-ratios for large firms?
economies of scale; capital market transactions have significant fixed costs
large firms more likely to have diversified cash sources, have market power,
etc. which are good attributes to the lender
larger firms also tend to be listed companies; disclosure rules mitigate
information asymmetry problem

24

R.C. Ybaez UP Cesar E.A. Virata School of Business

The Free Cash Flow Problem


An agency problem: managers (the agent) self-interest may run counter to
the best interest of shareholders (the principal)
Example: managers may overinvest. Their compensation/perks tend to be
higher, the greater the resources and the larger the organization they
control
Debt can mitigate this - debt service requirements reduce free cash and the
opportunities for managers to use the cash on unprofitable projects and on
perks; while loan covenants restrict managers ability to use the cash
The Empirical Evidence:
Is Trade-Off Theory Supported by Actual Practice?
1. Trade-off theory would suggest that more profitable firms will have higher
debt ratios since debt can be used to shield profits from taxes. Data however
show that debt ratios are lower for the more profitable firms (US and Phils).
2. Data also show that debt ratios vary widely among firms in the same
business or industry (US)
3. There is a general reluctance among firms to tap the equity market (US)
4. Empirical research show that share prices react negatively to corporate
announcements to tap the capital market (e.g., via bond issues and new
shares). Price reaction is greater for equity issues than for bond issues (US)
5. Firms with significant growth opportunities have higher debt ratios (US and
Phils). Recall that trade-off theory suggest the reverse on the premise that
lenders are wary of asset substitution risks when a firm has significant
growth options

25

R.C. Ybaez UP Cesar E.A. Virata School of Business

An Alternative Theory: The Pecking Order Hypothesis


Information asymmetry (managers and insiders know more than other
stakeholders) is a much more important consideration than tax benefits. The
key consequence of information asymmetry is the potential underpricing of
securities when the firm raises external financing.
Rather than aim for an optimal debt ratio, firms follow a pecking order: (1)
internal finance (2) debt (bank loans first, then bonds) (3) quasi-equity such as
preferred stocks (4) new issues of common shares
Implications of Pecking Order Hypothesis
1. Not all firms will have a target capital structure, i.e., an optimal debt ratio
2. The firms debt ratio will simply be the byproduct of the firms ability to
generate internal finance (from profits) and its demand for funds
(investments and dividends). Thus, firms in the same industry can have very
different debt-ratios
3. The more profitable the firm, the lower its debt ratio since firms will prefer
to tap internally generated funds rather than external sources
4. If a firm has to tap external funding, go for the safer options first, i.e.,
lower risk of underpricing: debt before equity, bank loans before bonds.
Hence, when firms resort to financing choices that are near the bottom of the
pecking order, e.g., new equity issues, this sends negative signals to investors
5. Financial slack (liquid assets and borrowing capacity) is important: it
minimizes the need to issue new equity (the choice at the bottom of the
pecking order). The maintenance of financial slack generally leads to
conservative financing policies
6. Firms with significant growth opportunities will tend to have higher debt
ratios. Firms which are very profitable but have limited growth
opportunities will tend to pay off debt first

26

R.C. Ybaez UP Cesar E.A. Virata School of Business

Where is Capital Structure Theory Today?


At present, there is no single theory that can explain all the variations we
observe about firms capital structures. The two main theories disagree on
whats more important to firms. Some factors are more important to some
types of firms and less so for others, which can lead to highly divergent choices
of financing.
Modiglian and Miller remind us that figuring out the optimal capital structure
shouldnt matter that much. Brealey and Myers argue that value derives
largely from good investment choices, less so on the financing choices firms
make. A firm should therefore choose a financing structure that best supports
its investment program and business strategy, while ensuring that its financing
choices dont lead to financial distress and the failure of an otherwise
profitable enterprise.

27

R.C. Ybaez UP Cesar E.A. Virata School of Business

Das könnte Ihnen auch gefallen