Sie sind auf Seite 1von 6

DECISIONS & GAMES

Lecture Twelve Slides

Alternative definitions of renegotiation-proofness in repeated games


30
40
60

30
1800, 1800

40
1500, 2000

2000, 1500
1800 900
1800,

1600, 1600
1200 800
1200,

60
900, 1800
800, 1200
0 0
0,

An SPNE in an infinitely repeated game is strongly renegotiationproof if and only if, after a unilateral deviation by any player in any
period t , the specified post-deviation continuation SPNE payoffs of
all non-deviating players are no less than what their continuation
SPNE ppayoffs
y
would be iff the deviation did not occur in pperiod t.
An SPNE in an infinitely repeated game is weakly renegotiation-proof
if and only if, after a unilateral deviation by any player in any period t,
the specified post-deviation continuation SPNE payoffs of all nondeviating players are no less than what their continuation payoffs
would be if the deviation occurred in every period after t.

Repeated Cournot Game: renegotiation-proofness of grim strategy


30
40
60

30
1800, 1800

40
1500, 2000

2000, 1500
1800 900
1800,

1600, 1600
1200 800
1200,

60
900, 1800
800, 1200
0 0
0,

Each player starts with 30 and continues to play 30 so long as all


have played 30 in the past; if any player plays a volume 30 in
any period , each player plays 40 in all future periods.
In the infinitely repeated Cournot game, the grim strategy
is not strongly renegotiation-proof but is weakly renegotiation-proof
since while 1800/(1 ) > 1600/(1 )
it is true that 1600/(1 ) > 1500/(1 )

Arijit Sen | IIM Calcutta | 2016

DECISIONS & GAMES

Lecture Twelve Slides

Summary: Grim strategy in Infinitely Repeated Cournot Game


Firm B
P = 140 - Q
TC = 20q

Firm A

30

30
1800, 1800

40
1500, 2000

60
900, 1800

40
60

2000, 1500
1800, 900

1600, 1600
1200, 800

800, 1200
0, 0

A & B compete in infinitely-repeated volume-setting given = (dp)(0,1)


Consider the grim strategy with punishment of perpetual Nash reversion:
Each player starts with 30 and continues to play 30 so long as all
have played 30 in the past; if any player plays a volume 30 in
any period , each player plays 40 in all future periods.
periods.
The punishment threat is credible,
effective when > ,
and weakly renegotiation-proof
and trivially coalition-proof
[a punishment threat rationally sustains collusion iff its credible & effective]

Trigger strategy in Infinitely Repeated Cournot Game


Firm B
P = 140 - Q
TC = 20q

Firm A

30

30
1800, 1800

40
1500, 2000

60
900, 1800

40

2000, 1500

1600, 1600

800, 1200

60

1800, 900

1200, 800

0, 0

A & B compete in infinitely-repeated volume-setting given = (dp)(0, 1)


Consider trigger strategy with punishment of T-period Nash reversion:
Each player starts with 30 and continues to play 30 so long as all
have played 30 in the past; if any player plays a volume 30 in
anyy p
period ,, each p
player
y p
plays
y 40 for next T p
periods ((and then
revert to cooperation).
The punishment threat is credible, effective when is sufficiently high,
and weakly renegotiation-proof
One can check whether a trigger strategy is effective by considering a
one-shot deviation from cooperation; but when it is not effective the
optimal way to cheat will involve multiple deviations

Arijit Sen | IIM Calcutta | 2016

DECISIONS & GAMES

Lecture Twelve Slides

4 questions regarding infinitely repeated cooperation dilemmas


For a proposed set of strategies that aim to sustain a collusion
target, how do we determine whether the strategies constitute an
SPNE of the infinitely repeated game that rationally sustains (i.e.,
credibly and effectively sustains) the desired collusion target?
Consider a proposed set of SPNE strategies which is found to
rationally sustain a desired collusion target (i.e., the incorporated
threats are credible and effective). How do we determine whether
the proposed SPNE is renegotiation-proof?
For any given value of and a specific collusion target, how do we
d
determine
i whether
h h there
h exists
i any credible
dibl andd effective
ff i
punishment strategies that will rationally sustain the collusion target
as an SPNE? [Research by Dilip Abreu addresses this question]
And, when there are more than two players, how do we determine
whether the proposed SPNE is coalition-proof?

Infinitely Repeated Cournot Game : use of simple penal codes


Firm B

Firm A

30

30
1800, 1800

40
1500, 2000

60
900, 1800

40
60

2000, 1500
1800, 900

1600, 1600
1200, 800

800, 1200
0, 0

Define the following three codes (following Dilip Abreus research):


1. Cooperation Code C = (30; 30) in every period
2. Penal Code PA= (30; 60) in every period [Stackelberg reversion]
3. Penal Code PB = (60; 30) in every period
Then consider the following three-phase
three phase strategy profile:
Each firm starts by playing according to the cooperation code C;
a deviation by Firm A from any ongoing code either C or PA or PB
requires the firms to play according to PA from then on forever;
a deviation by Firm B from any ongoing code either C or PA or PB
requires the firms to play acc. to PB from then on forever

Arijit Sen | IIM Calcutta | 2016

DECISIONS & GAMES

Lecture Twelve Slides

30

30
1800, 1800

40
1500, 2000

60
900, 1800

40
60

2000, 1500
1800, 900

1600, 1600
1200, 800

800, 1200
0, 0

Consider strategy profile {C= (30; 30); PA= (30; 60); PB= (60; 30)}
- This strategy profile is simple in that the penal code for firm i is the
same irrespective of how and when it cheats
- This strategy profile employs optimal penal codes because the
punished player is held to his maximin payoff
Conclusions: The proposed simple strategy profile rationally sustains
(i.e., credibly and effectively sustains) the maximal cooperation
target{30, 30} if > 2/11.
The proposed simple strategy profile is strongly renegotiation-proof
since p.v. payoff to firm I under the penal code PJ = 1800/(1- )
Here, maximal collusion {30, 30} can be rationally sustained only if
> 2/11 since the proposed strategy specifies optimal penal codes

30

30
1800, 1800

40
1500, 2000

60
900, 1800

40
60

2000, 1500
1800, 900

1600, 1600
1200, 800

800, 1200
0, 0

Consider strategy profile {C= (30; 30); PA= (30; 60); PB= (60; 30)}
Proof that the strategy profile rationally sustains {30, 30}
whenever > 2/11. :
For > 2/11, the strategy profile is
credible as it is SPNE in both punishment phases PA and PB
and effective as it is SPNE in cooperation phase C
collusion constraint in either phase: 1800/(1-) > 2000 + 900./(1- )

Arijit Sen | IIM Calcutta | 2016

DECISIONS & GAMES

Lecture Twelve Slides

Repeated Advertising Game (a game in strategic complements)


Firm B

low

low
50, 50

medium
32, 60

high
25, 55

Firm A med

60, 32

40, 40

26, 42

high

55, 25

42, 26

30, 30

Firms A and B compete in a repeated advertising game for T periods


given = dp (0, 1), where in each period each firm can set one of
three ad expenditure levels: low ad, or medium ad, or high ad
Unique SPNE for any T finite:
Irrespective of past history, each firm sets high ad in every period
T-fold repetition of the unique stage-game Nash eqm

Repeated Advertising Game : grim strategy


Firm B

low
Firm A med

high

low
50, 50

medium
32, 60

high
25, 55

60, 32
55, 25

40, 40
42, 26

26, 42
30, 30

Given (0,1) & T=, consider following grim strategy:


Each player starts with low and continues to play low so long as
all have played low in the past; if any player plays ad exp low
in any period , each player plays high in all future periods.
Collusion constraint : 50/(1 ) > 60 + 30./(1 ) > 1/3
Conclusions: The grim strategy rationally sustains the maximal
cooperation target{low, low} if > 1/3.
The grim strategy is neither strongly nor weakly renegotiation-proof
Maximal collusion {low, low} can be sustained in an SPNE only if
> 1/3 because the grim strategy specifies optimal penal codes

Arijit Sen | IIM Calcutta | 2016

DECISIONS & GAMES

Lecture Twelve Slides

Optimal Penal Codes in Repeated Cooperation Dilemmas


strategic
substitutes

30

30
1800, 1800

40
1500, 2000

60
900, 1800

40

2000, 1500

1600, 1600

800, 1200

60

1800, 900

1200, 800

0, 0

Cooperation target: (30; 30); optimal penal codes: PA = (30; 60), PB = (60; 30)
Result: Cooperation target (30; 30) is sustainable if and only if > 2/11
Optimal penal codes are strongly renegotiation-proof
strategic
compliments

low

low
50, 50

medium
32, 60

high
25, 55

medium

60, 32

40, 40

26, 42

high

55, 25

42, 26

30, 30

Cooperation target: (low; low); optimal penal codes: PA = PB = (high; high)


Result: Cooperation target (low; low) is sustainable if and only if > 1/3
Optimal penal codes are not renegotiation-proof

Arijit Sen | IIM Calcutta | 2016

Das könnte Ihnen auch gefallen