Sie sind auf Seite 1von 9

Combining Economic Forecasts

Author(s): Robert T. Clemen and Robert L. Winkler


Source: Journal of Business & Economic Statistics, Vol. 4, No. 1 (Jan., 1986), pp. 39-46
Published by: American Statistical Association
Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/1391385 .
Accessed: 22/10/2013 13:52

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at .
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp

.
JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of
content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms
of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.

American Statistical Association is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to Journal
of Business &Economic Statistics.

http://www.jstor.org

This content downloaded from 152.3.102.242 on Tue, 22 Oct 2013 13:52:41 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
? 1986 AmericanStatisticalAssociation Journalof Business & EconomicStatistics,January1986, Vol.4, No. 1

CombiningEconomic Forecasts
Robert T. Clemen
College of Business Administration, University of Oregon, Eugene, OR 97403

Robert L. Winkler
Fuqua School of Business, Duke University, Durham, NC 27706

A methodforcombiningforecastsmayor maynotaccountfordependenceanddifferingprecision
among forecasts. Inthis articlewe test a varietyof such methodsin the contextof combining
forecasts of GNP from four majoreconometricmodels. The methods include one in which
forecastingerrorsare jointlynormallydistributedand several variantsof this model as well as
some simplerproceduresand a Bayesianapproachwitha priordistribution based on exchange-
abilityof forecasters. The results indicatethat a simple average, the normalmodel with an
independenceassumption,and the Bayesian model performbetterthan the otherapproaches
that are studiedhere.

KEYWORDS:Bayesiancombinationof forecasts;Averageof forecasts;Weightedaverage of


forecasts;Exchangeableforecasters;Econometricmodels;Forecastevaluation.

1. INTRODUCTION averageyields a forecasty, of the form


k
Decision makerswho have to make an assessmentabout
some uncertainfuture event often seek informationin the y = ^ik. (1)
i=l
form of forecastsconcerningthe event. For example, many
individualeconomists and variouseconometricmodels pro- No informationaboutthe precisionof the forecastsor about
duce forecastsof GNP and othereconomic variables.When dependence among the forecasts is needed to generate a
the forecastsdiverge, the decision makerwho wantsa single simple average.The fact thateach forecastreceives the same
forecastfaces the thornyproblemof combiningthe forecasts. weight 1/k, however, does imply thatthe forecastsarebeing
In this articlewe focus on the combinationof GNP forecasts treatedas if they were exchangeable.
from four majoreconometricmodels. An alternativeto an ad hoc method such as a simple
A simple procedurefor combiningforecastsis to take an average is an approachthat models the precision of the
arithmeticaverage of the forecasts. This procedureserves forecasting methods as well as their statisticalinteraction.
as a useful benchmarkand has been shown to performbetter This is in the spirit of a Bayesian approachto modeling
than some schemes that are more complicated(Makridakis informationfromexpertsor othersources(e.g., Morris1977).
and Winkler 1983). One such model (NewboldandGranger1974;Winkler1981)
A model in which forecastingerrorsarejointly normally treatsthe vectorof forecasterrorse = (i - x, x2 - x, . . .
distributedtakes into accountdependenceand differingpre- Xk - x)' as normallydistributedwith zero mean vector and
cision among forecasts(Newbold and Granger1974; Wink- positive definitecovariancematrixX, wherea primedenotes
ler 1981;WinklerandMakridakis1983). We takethis model transposition.The motivationfor the normalmodel is that
as our point of departurefrom the simple average, and we there are many sources of errorin forecastingand that as a
considerseveralvariantson the model as well as a Bayesian result the "normal theory of errors" seems applicable. In
approachwith a priordistributionbasedon exchangeability. addition, the normal distributionprovides a naturalmodel
The results indicate that the simple average, the normal for positive dependenceamongexpertsas a resultof shared
model with an independenceassumption,and the Bayesian information(Winkler 1981; Clemen 1984).
model perform better than the other approachesthat are The combinedforecastgeneratedby the normalmodel is
studied here.
Y2 = U'l-.XZ/u'Y 'u, (2)
Methodsfor combiningforecastsare discussedin Section
2, and the empirical analysis involving GNP forecasts is where u = (1, 1, . . ., 1)', = (X, X2. .. , k)', and
presentedin Section 3. Section 4 summarizesthe articleand X is an estimateof E. The combinedforecastY2 is a weighted
discusses some implicationsof our results. average of the individual forecasts xi, with the vector of
weights
2. METHODS FOR COMBINING FORECASTS W = (WI, . . . , Wk) = U' -'/U'.-lU (3)
Let x representthe variablebeing forecast, and suppose dependingon E. Thus, the estimate l, which can be deter-
we have k forecastsX-, x2 .. ., k of x. Then the simple minedfrompastdataon estimationerrors,priorinformation,

39

This content downloaded from 152.3.102.242 on Tue, 22 Oct 2013 13:52:41 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
40 JOURNALOF BUSINESS& ECONOMICSTATISTICS,
JANUARY1986

or some combinationthereof, plays an importantrole in the k forecasts. This might be consideredunreasonableby some
determinationof the combined forecast. decision makers, and it can be avoided by constrainingthe
A common choice for X is a sample covariancematrix combined forecast to fall between the lowest and highest
that can be justified from the standpointof obtaininga var- forecasts,inclusive. A combinedforecastlower (higher)than
iance-minimizingcombinationof forecasts(Halperin1961) the lowest (highest) forecast can be modified by setting it
or froma Bayesianapproachusinga diffusepriordistribution equal to the lowest (highest) forecast. This approachrep-
(Geisser 1965). A potential problem in using the sample resents a compromiseof sorts in the sense that it does not
covariancematrixto estimate E is that the estimate can be totally ignore dependence, but it does keep the effect of
quite unstable unless large data sets are available for esti- dependencefrom being too extreme. Essentially, it uses the
mation. This problem is particularlypronouncedwhen the basic normal model but monitorsthe "reasonableness"of
pairwisecorrelationsare high, as often seems to be the case the combined forecastsby imposing a convexity constraint
with economic forecasts (e.g., see Section 3 of this article (forcing the combinedforecastto lie in the convex set gen-
or Figlewski and Urich 1983). eratedby the k forecasts).
We take the normal model with the sample covariance Estimatingthe weights in the normalmodelcan be thought
matrix as our point of departure.The weights assigned to of as estimating regression coefficients that must sum to
the forecastsand thus the forecaststhemselvescan be mod- one. One obvious generalizationis to relax the assumption
ified by changingthe estimatei or some otheraspectof the that the weights must sum to one. For example, we can use
procedure.We considerseveralalternativeschemes, includ- an unconstrainedapplicationof ordinaryleast squares(OLS)
ing some suggestedby Newbold and Granger(1974), some to a regressionmodel withoutan interceptterm. If the fore-
consideredby Grangerand Ramanathan(1984), and some casts are perfectly calibratedin the sense that the forecast
proposedhere and not previously studied. errorshave a zero mean vector, as assumed in the normal
The simplest modification, if it might be called that, is model, then the regression surface must pass throughthe
to vary n, the numberof data points used in the estimation origin. To allow for the possibility that this assumptionis
of E andthereforein the determinationof the weights. Using not appropriate,we can use OLS on a regressionmodel with
moredatapoints shouldlead to better,more stableestimates an interceptterm. Estimationvia OLS without an intercept
and weights, providedthatthe process generatingvectorsof termprovides more flexibility thanthe basic normalmodel,
forecast errorsis stationary.In the presence of nonstation- and OLS with an intercepttermyields even moreflexibility.
arity, however, a smaller n might be preferablebecause A more extremeapproachto the combinationof forecasts
"older" observationsmay have been generatedby a process is to assign all of the weightto a single forecast.Forexample,
with differentparametervalues. we might feel that good performanceis likely to continue,
Another way to deal with potential nonstationarityis to which suggests that all of the weight should be given to the
weight recent experiencemore heavily. For example, if the econometricmodel with the smallest erroron the previous
last n data points are used to estimate X, then we let forecast. Or, taking a contraryview, we might give all of
the weight to the model with the largesterroron the previous
(<), = flB'eitet,/Ef (4)
forecast, hoping that the poor performancewill motivate
t=l t=l adjustmentsto improvethe next forecast. When ties occur,
the weight can be divided equally among those tied for best
where f, - 1 is a smoothing parameter,eit and ej, are the or worst.
errorsfor forecastsi andj for observationt, and observation Modificationssuch as constrainingthe combinedforecasts
n is the most recent observation. Here each successively to be within the range of the individual forecasts, totally
"older" observationreceives less weight, and X can adapt ignoring correlations,applyingOLS with or withoutan in-
more quickly over time if the process is nonstationary.The terceptterm, and using the model that was best or worst on
case of , = 1 correspondsto our basic normalmodel with the previousforecastare ad hoc in nature,of course. A more
equal weight given to all observations. formal approachcan be developed in a Bayesian context,
As noted above, estimates of I are often quite unstable
using priorinformationaboutE as well as pastdata. Suppose
when the correlationsamong forecast errorsare high. The that the prior informationconcerningX can be represented
weights wi and hence the combined forecast are extremely by an inverted Wishartdensity with covariance matrix-0
sensitive to small changes in the correlations,which may be and a degrees of freedom, where a > k - 1. Furthermore,
poorly estimated because of a relatively small sample or the past dataconsist of n vectors of forecasterrorse, .. .
nonstationarity.One way to avoid this instabilityis to treat en, where ei = (eil, eil, . . ., eik)'. Then the posterior dis-
the forecast errorsas independent.To avoid complications tributionfor E is invertedWishartwith covariancematrix
caused by dependence, we can assume that X is diagonal
and set all off-diagonalelementsof to zero. This approach S* = [(al-' + nl-')/(a + n)]-' (5)
assigns weights to forecasts only on the basis of precision and degrees of freedom
and ignores correlations.
C* = a + n, (6)
If the correlationsamong forecasterrorsare not ignored,
forecasts may be assigned negative weights in some cases, where I is the sample covariancematrix(LaValle 1970).
and the combined forecast may lie outside the range of the Having revised the distributionfor l, we now returnto

This content downloaded from 152.3.102.242 on Tue, 22 Oct 2013 13:52:41 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
CLEMENAND WINKLER:
COMBINING
ECONOMICFORECASTS 41

the combinationof forecasts. Suppose that x and l are in- growth rate forecasts (in percentageterms), and we calcu-
dependenta priori, with an improperdiffuse density for x lated the deviations from actualgrowth as determinedfrom
and an inverted Wishart density for I having covariance GNP reportedin Business ConditionsDigest. For both var-
matrix E* and a* degrees of freedom. Then the posterior iables, forecasts with four differenthorizons (1, 2, 3, and
mean for x, after the vector of forecastsx is seen, is 4 quarters)were analyzed. For example, the one-quarter
nominal GNP forecast predictsthe percentagechange (an-
Y3 = u'*-'Xl/u'I/*-U (7)
nual rate) of nominal GNP over the next quarter,whereas
(Winkler1981). Thus, the forecastfromthis Bayesianmodel the four-quarterforecast predictsthe percentagechange for
is of the same form as (2) with E* used in place of E. the three-monthperiod four quartersin the future.
The values chosen for a and S0 have implicationsfor the BEA makes only one set of forecastsper quarter,usually
combined forecast of the Bayesian model. It may be rea- early in the quarter,based in parton the first reportof GNP
sonable to specify a priori that we believe that forecasts for the previousquarter.On the otherhand,Wharton,Chase,
within a given class (e.g., generatedby econometricmodels and DRI update their forecasts each month. We attempted
or generatedjudgmentallyby economists)areexchangeable. to assemble forecasts from them that were comparableto
The priorestimate-0 of E would thus be an intraclasscor- BEA's in timing and data used in making the forecast.
relation matrix with a2i = a2 and ij = a2p for all i ?= j. The data covered the 1971-1982 period. The numberof
The effect in the applicationof (5) would be to generatea observationsavailablefor each of the two variableswas 45
covariancematrixE* for which any differencesamongfore- for four-quarterforecastsand46 for the remainingforecasts.
casters in variances or pairwise covariances are reduced. Each observationconsisted of four forecasts and the actual
The degree of the shift dependson a, which can be thought value.
of as an equivalent prior sample size. As we place more For the basic normalmodel, we used an adaptivemethod
weight on the priorinformationby increasinga, the weights to calculate the sample covariancematrixE. For any given
wi become more nearly equal. In the limit, the prior infor- forecasting situation, E was based on the preceding n ob-
mation completely dominatesthe sample information,and servationsand the weights assigned to the individualfore-
the combined forecast is a simple averageof the individual casts thereforechangedin accordancewith this moving win-
forecasts. As noted earlier, combining forecasts by means dow. We tried values of 5, 10, 15, and 20 for n. Unless
of a simple averageimplies a (usuallytacit) assumptionthat otherwise stated, the reportedresults for the normalmodel
the forecasters are exchangeable. In a different context, and its variants are based on the case of n = 20. In the
Lindley and Smith (1972) show that ridge regressionis for- model with recent experience weighted more heavily, we
mally equivalentto a Bayesian model with a priorbelief of considered/- = 1(.1)2. For the Bayesian model with the
exchangeability and note that such a belief might not be priordistributionof E based on exchangeability,we used a
reasonablein many situations.Our Bayesian model is anal- pooled estimateof a2, chose p = .7, andtriedseveralvalues
ogous to ridge regression,but exchangeabilitymay often be of a. Finally, the Bayesian model was also tried with in-
a naturalpriorassumptionin the setting of combiningfore- dependenceimposed on both the prior estimate S0 and the
casts. sample estimate S.
The calibrationof the forecastsfrom the foureconometric
3. THE COMBINATION OF GNP FORECASTS
models is of interestbecause the normalmodel (as well as
FROM FOUR MAJOR ECONOMETRIC MODELS
its variants)assumes that the forecasts are calibratedin the
WhartonEconometrics (Wharton),Chase Econometrics sense that they have expected errorsof zero. The average
(Chase), Data Resources, Inc. (DRI), and the Bureau of errorspresentedin Table 1 reveal a slight tendencyto over-
EconomicAnalysis (BEA) makequarterlyforecastsof many forecast real GNP for the longer time horizons. Of the 32
economic variables. We used their level forecasts of real averageerrors(2 variables,4 horizons,4 econometricmodels),
and nominal GNP (1970-1982) (obtained directly from however, only four were largerthan 1% in absolute value,
WhartonandBEA andfromthe StatisticalBulletinpublished and not one was significantlydifferentfrom zero at the .05
by the Conference Board for Chase and DRI) to construct level (althought = 2.01 for DRI for four-quarterforecasts

Table 1. Average Errorsfor IndividualForecasts

Variable Horizon Wharton Chase DRI BEA


NominalGNP 1 -.03 (-.05) -1.05 (-1.87) -.80 (-1.40) -.63 (-1.21)
2 .08 (.11) -.70 (-.91) -.36 (-.55) .02 (.03)
3 .03 (.04) -.26 (-.29) .02 (.03) -.03 (-.04)
4 -.20 (-.22) -.15 (-.16) .44 (.52) .00 (.00)
Real GNP 1 .04 (.09) -.77 (-1.65) -.29 (-.53) .10 (.22)
2 .86 (1.51) -.02 (-.03) .44 (.75) .66 (1.18)
3 .98 (1.60) .57 (.83) .90 (1.40) .97 (1.46)
4 1.16 (1.70) .97 (1.29) 1.39 (2.01) 1.22 (1.68)
NOTE: t statistics are in parentheses.

This content downloaded from 152.3.102.242 on Tue, 22 Oct 2013 13:52:41 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
42 JOURNALOF BUSINESS& ECONOMICSTATISTICS,
JANUARY1986

Table2. Autocorrelations
of Forecast Errorsfor IndividualForecasts

Variable Horizon Lag Wharton Chase DRI BEA


NominalGNP 1 1 -.11 -.09 -.32* -.17
2 .08 .22 .10 -.26
3 -.19 -.14 -.18 .06
2 1 .05 .18 .10 .01
2 .08 .22 .12 .15
3 -.01 .05 -.04 -.04
3 1 .13 .27 .30* .25
2 .14 .19 .17 .05
3 -.06 .08 .00 -.04
4 1 .10 .26 .27 .14
2 .01 .17 .11 .11
3 -.17 .06 -.06 -.02
Real GNP 1 1 -.19 -.03 -.16 -.11
2 .06 .20 .01 -.16
3 -.20 -.07 -.10 .05
2 1 -.15 .06 .07 -.07
2 -.05 .11 .06 .00
3 .00 .05 .06 .00
3 1 -.01 .26 .23 .18
2 -.04 .03 .01 .01
3 -.09 .03 -.03 -.11
4 1 .14 .22 .22 .12
2 -.12 .05 -.06 -.04
3 -.21 -.01 -.17 -.16
*Significant at the .05 level.

of real GNP was barely nonsignificant).In addition, after The normalmodel also assumes that all forecastershave
completingthe analysis describedbelow, we calibratedthe errorsthat are free of autocorrelation.From the autocorre-
forecasts by adjustingfor their average errorand then re- lations given in Table 2 and visual inspectionsof residual
peated the analysis with the calibratedforecasts. The com- patterns,this appearsto be a reasonableassumption.Most
bined forecastsbased on the calibratedforecastsperformed of the autocorrelationswere very close to zero. There was
slightly worse than those based on the raw forecasts. Thus, a slight tendencytowardpositive (but small) first-orderau-
it appearsthatthese four econometricmodels do a relatively tocorrelationsfor three-andfour-quarter-aheadforecastsand
good job in terms of calibration,which is what we would negative (but even smaller) first-orderautocorrelationsfor
expect of premiereconometricmodels. one-quarter-ahead forecasts.

Table3. MADand MSEfor IndividualForecasts and CombinedForecasts

Simple Normal Independence Convexity OLS,No


Variable Horizon Wharton Chase DRI BEA Average Model Model Constraint Intercept OLS Best Worst
MAD
NominalGNP 1 3.68 3.77 3.84 3.75 3.55 4.23 3.57 3.98 4.38 4.51 3.95 3.58
2 4.48 5.24 4.30 4.64 4.56 4.65 4.54 4.65 4.67 4.95 4.35 4.90
3 5.27 6.30 5.28 5.10 5.32 5.32 5.26 4.98 5.20 5.30 5.20 5.74
4 5.65 5.79 5.32 5.46 5.45 6.56 5.57 6.19 6.41 5.57 5.38 5.18
Real GNP 1 2.86 2.95 3.12 2.91 2.88 3.14 2.85 3.03 3.26 3.52 3.35 2.88
2 3.45 3.89 3.52 3.62 3.54 3.66 3.54 3.71 3.34 3.38 3.36 3.58
3 3.59 4.17 3.60 3.70 3.59 4.13 3.58 3.79 3.86 3.87 3.67 4.03
4 3.53 3.96 3.63 4.06 3.59 4.19 3.63 3.86 4.38 4.41 3.98 3.64
MSE
NominalGNP 1 18.94 21.57 19.63 20.41 18.17 25.28 18.37 22.07 27.03 30.65 21.24 19.48
2 29.79 42.26 29.06 34.78 31.94 34.64 31.77 34.87 35.84 42.54 30.49 38.73
3 44.56 55.83 40.44 40.82 43.76 42.19 43.10 40.48 41.90 42.63 40.92 48.82
4 63.89 53.55 44.67 45.48 47.91 76.54 50.94 69.57 55.51 45.04 49.86 44.75
Real GNP 1 11.63 12.53 14.29 12.36 11.25 13.74 11.15 13.08 14.97 18.73 16.38 12.17
2 17.92 21.98 17.12 18.88 17.77 19.59 17.78 19.64 18.30 21.38 17.06 18.85
3 22.01 25.99 20.09 24.50 21.85 27.09 21.88 24.94 25.06 26.54 23.98 25.50
4 23.59 26.43 20.94 25.82 22.30 30.99 23.36 25.48 27.85 28.63 22.68 22.72

This content downloaded from 152.3.102.242 on Tue, 22 Oct 2013 13:52:41 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
CLEMENAND WINKLER: ECONOMICFORECASTS
COMBINING 43

Results for the individualeconometricmodels and many lations and differencesamongerrorvariancesresultedin the
of the combiningmethodsare summarizedin Table 3. Mean normalmodel placingnegative weights on some of the fore-
absolutedeviations(MAD's) and meansquareerrors(MSE's) casts. The weights and the combined forecasts are highly
are given for the eight variable/horizoncombinations.In all sensitive to small changes in the estimatedcorrelations,as
cases where fitting was involved, the evaluationwas based in multicollinearityproblems in general. To illustratethis
entirely on forecasts not used in the fitting process. To in- notion, some extremecases with n = 5 are shown in Table
clude the fitting datawould give the more complex methods 5. In Case 4, for example, the forecastsrangedfrom 3.258
an unfair advantage. Facilitatingcomparisonsfurther, we to 8.456 and the actual value was 6.804, but the weights
calculatedall values of MAD and MSE for exactly the same ranged from -2.364 to 3.355 and the combined forecast
set of forecastoccasions. Thatis, when some occasions were from the normalmodel was -9.012.
used to fit a particularcombining method, these occasions The poor performanceof the basic normalmodel is not
were excluded in the evaluationof all methods. surprising.The potentiallyseriousmulticollinearityproblem
The intent of this article is to study combined forecasts andpreviousempiricalresults(e.g., WinklerandMakridakis
rather than individual forecasts. We note, however, that 1983) led us to expect difficulties. The next questionis the
Whartonand DRI tendedto have lower values of MAD and extentto which the variationson the normalmodel discussed
MSE thanthe othertwo models andthatChasehadthe worst in Section 2 improvedmatters.The convexityconstraintthat
overallperformanceof the four. The foureconometricmodels forces the combined forecast to lie within the range of the
demonstratedgreateraccuracywhen forecastingreal GNP individual forecasts resulted in some improvementin per-
than when forecastingnominal GNP, with the discrepancy formancein terms of either MAD or MSE, as can be seen
increasingfor the longer horizons. As anticipated,the fore- fromTable3. Overthe eight variable/horizoncombinations,
cast accuracygenerallydecreasedas the lead time increased. the averagereductionin MAD fromthe MAD for the normal
The simple averageperformedquite well in this study, as model was 4.5%, and the average reductionin MSE was
can be seen from Table 3. If the "best" individualmodel 6.9%. The simple average, however, yielded average re-
could be identifiedon each forecastoccasion, it would out- ductions of 9.2% in MAD and 17.6% in MSE.
performthe simple average. Since such identificationmay Imposingan independenceassumptionby settingthe off-
not always be feasible, the simple averageprovides an al- diagonal elements of E equal to zero yielded very good
ternativethat yields good performanceand is very robust results. The values of MAD and MSE shown in Table 3 for
(Makridakisand Winkler 1983). The values of MAD and the independencemodel are comparableto those for the
MSE for the simple average were roughly comparableon simple average. The independencemodel providedaverage
an overall basis to those for the betterindividualmodels. reductionsof 9.2% in MAD and 17.4% in MSE when com-
In contrastto the simple average, our basic normalmodel paredwith the basic normalmodel. The good performance
fared poorly. For every other variable/horizoncombination of this approachis consistent with previous studies (e.g.,
except three-quarter-ahead forecasts of nominal GNP, the Newbold and Granger 1974 and Winkler and Makridakis
normal model had a higher MAD and a higher MSE than 1983).
the simple average, andthe differencewas often substantial. Using (4) to place moreweight on recentobservationsdid
It is instructiveto explore the reasonsfor this poor perform- not lead to large improvementsover the basic normalmodel.
ance. In our data set, the pairwise correlationsof forecast Some values of MAD and MSE decreased, while others
errorswere very high. In all, we can estimate48 correlations increased;to conserve space, we will not present detailed
(6 pairwise combinationsand 8 variable/horizoncombina- results. Slight improvementsoccurredfor f near 1 (e.g.,
tions). These correlations,which are given in Table4, were a 2.2% reductionin MAD when /f = 1.1). Largervalues
uniformly high, ranging from .82 to .96. The high corre- of f reduced the performancedrastically (e.g., a 23.4%

Table4. PairwiseCorrelationsof Forecast ErrorsFromDifferentEconometricModels

NominalGNP Real GNP


Horizon Wharton Chase DRI Wharton Chase DRI
1 Chase .90 .90
DRI .91 .88 .86 .84
BEA .83 .82 .82 .90 .85 .82
2 Chase .88 .90
DRI .90 .92 .93 .93
BEA .87 .89 .93 .90 .90 .91
3 Chase .92 .90
DRI .95 .96 .92 .95
BEA .94 .94 .96 .94 .93 .93
4 Chase .88 .91
DRI .88 .95 .92 .93
BEA .87 .94 .94 .92 .93 .90

This content downloaded from 152.3.102.242 on Tue, 22 Oct 2013 13:52:41 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
44 JOURNALOF BUSINESS & ECONOMICSTATISTICS,
JANUARY1986

Table5. Examplesof Cases WithNegative Weightsand ExtremeForecasts

Forecasts (Weights)
NormalModel Actual
Case Wharton Chase DRI BEA CombinedForecast Value
1 11.470 8.860 8.171 12.422 16.375 7.725
(-.591) (1.431) (-1.997) (2.157)
2 12.488 8.908 8.954 12.278 -5.193 13.116
(-1.616) (5.980) (- .909) (- 2.455)
3 7.648 5.753 6.164 -1.108 18.381 3.026
(-3.002) (-.451) (6.720) (-2.267)
4 8.456 7.395 3.258 7.564 -9.012 6.804
(-2.364) (.116) (3.355) (-.107)

increase in MAD when fl = 1.8). It may be that the pro- and some increases in values of MAD and MSE. Any im-
cess was relatively stable. Moreover,highervalues of / re- provementswere relativelyminor, however. The resultsdo
sultedin less weightbeing attachedto "older" observations, not justify reducingn below the initial value of 20.
therebyreducingthe effective sample size and exacerbating Relaxing the constraintthat the weights sum to one and
the multicollinearityproblem. Imposingthe convexity con- adding an interceptterm yielded the results shown in the
strainton the forecasts generatedusing (4) eliminatedthe columnsheaded "OLS, No Intercept"and "OLS" in Table
drastic reductionsin performancewith large f, but did not 3. Neither approachperformedvery well. The most general
lead to large improvementsover the basic normal model. model, with unconstrainedweights and an interceptterm,
Finally, using (4) and also imposing an independenceas- was roughly comparableto the basic normal model. The
sumptionhad very little effect as comparedwith using the modelwithoutthe intercepttermwas slightly,butonly slightly,
independenceassumptionwithout (4). On balance, placing better. Neither of the OLS approachescame close, on an
more weight on recentobservationsdid not prove helpful in overall basis, to the simple average or the normal model
this study. with the independenceassumption.This evidencerunscounter
For tne above results, 2 and the resultingforecastswere to the claim of Grangerand Ramanathan(1984) that "the
based on the preceding n = 20 observationsin any fore- common practice of obtaininga weighted averageof alter-
casting situation. We also tested all of the combined fore- native forecasts should . . . be abandonedin favour of an
casting approacheswith n = 5, 10, and 15. The resultsfor unrestrictedlinear combinationincludinga constant term"
the smaller values of n were similar to those for placing (p. 201).
more weight on recentobservations.With an independence The last two columns in Table 3 correspondto the use of
assumption,changing n appearedto have very little effect. the forecastfrom the econometricmodels with the best and
Without independence,reducing n led to some reductions worst forecasts, respectively, on the previous forecasting

Table6. MADand MSEforthe Bayesian Model, Withand WithoutIndependenceAssumption

20
Variable Horizon 4 10 20 50 100 (withindependence)
MAD
NominalGNP 1 3.92 3.77 3.68 3.60 3.57 3.56
2 4.43 4.45 4.48 4.52 4.54 4.55
3 4.78 4.95 5.07 5.19 5.25 5.29
4 6.04 5.83 5.69 5.60 5.56 5.53
Real GNP 1 2.93 2.84 2.84 2.85 2.86 2.87
2 3.58 3.56 3.55 3.54 3.54 3.54
3 3.62 3.55 3.54 3.56 3.58 3.59
4 3.69 3.62 3.63 3.63 3.63 3.63
MSE
NominalGNP 1 21.62 20.07 19.24 18.62 18.40 18.27
2 31.79 31.39 31.39 31.58 31.72 31.83
3 38.66 40.11 41.33 42.55 43.10 43.44
4 60.61 55.98 53.57 51.64 50.78 50.22
Real GNP 1 12.12 11.57 11.34 11.23 11.22 11.22
2 18.46 18.12 17.96 17.84 17.80 17.77
3 22.86 22.16 21.92 21.84 21.83 21.85
4 25.82 24.53 23.99 23.64 23.48 23.26

This content downloaded from 152.3.102.242 on Tue, 22 Oct 2013 13:52:41 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
CLEMENAND WINKLER:
COMBINING
ECONOMICFORECASTS 45

occasion. These relativelysimple approachesdid reasonably and some of its variants. As a result, all three approaches
well. "Best" improved on the basic normal model by an are quite robust.
average of 6.4% in MAD and 12.2% in MSE. Somewhat Our results concerning the performanceof the different
surprisingly,"Worst"did almostas well, with averagegains combinationschemes are similarto resultsobtainedby Mak-
of 6.1% in MAD and 10.6% in MSE. Neither of these ridakis and Winkler (1983) and Winkler and Makridakis
schemes performedquite as well as the simple average or (1983). Of particularinterest is the fact that we have con-
the normal model with the independenceassumption, but sideredforecastsfrom econometricmodels ratherthanfrom
they were betterthan the normalmodel with the convexity time-seriesextrapolationmethods.The relativelystrongper-
constraintand much betterthan the OLS schemes. formanceof the simple average for combiningforecastsof
The final approachused was the Bayesian model with a GNP shouldbe of comfortto decision makerswho regularly
prioriexchangeability,which generatedcombinedforecasts combine individual econometric forecasts by simple aver-
from (7). This model was run for several values of a (the aging. Withoutsufficientdatato estimatevariancesprecisely
equivalent prior sample size) with and without the inde- (or in the event of nonstationarity),the assumptionthatfore-
pendence assumption. Some results are shown in Table 6. castersareperfectlyexchangeable(same variance,samecor-
The values of MAD and MSE were somewhatbut not highly relations) would appearto be a reasonableassumptionas
sensitive to the choice of a for the nonindependentcase, long as the forecastersare all in the same "league." Under
with any slight edge going to the higher values of a. With this exchangeability,the appropriatecombining rule is the
the independence assumption, the results were extremely simple average.
insensitive to the choice of a, and only the case of a = 20 The Bayesian model presentedhere also utilizes an ex-
is shown in Table 6. Note that in contrastto the results in changeabilityassumptionfor the priordistributionbut then
Table 3, there was not much difference between the inde- combinesthis priordistributionwith sampleinformation.To
pendent and nonindependentcases. The prior information the extent thatthe sampleinformationsuggeststhatthe fore-
appearedto have a strong stabilizing effect that produced casters should not be viewed as exchangeable,the weights
great improvementsin the nonindependentcase. In general, based on the posteriordistributionmay move away from the
the Bayesian model performedmuch better than the basic prior startingpoint of equal weights. The decision maker
normalmodel andsome of its variants.Overall,the Bayesian can controlhow quickly the sample informationcan change
model was roughly comparableto the simple average and mattersby the choice of a, the equivalentpriorsamplesize.
the normalmodel with the independenceassumption. As a -> oo, the Bayesian combined forecast approachesa
simple average. Of course, the prior distributionneed not
rest on an exchangeabilityassumption,but in many fore-
4. SUMMARY AND DISCUSSION
casting situationsthe forecasterswill be viewed as similar
In this articlewe have comparedthe performanceof sev- enough to make such an assumptionreasonable. Another
eral methodsfor combiningGNP forecastsfrom four major option might be to assume exchangeabilityonly within sub-
econometric models. These methods range from a simple sets of the forecasters,particularlywhen the forecastersare
averagethrougha normalmodel with severalad hoc variants of different "types" (e.g., a subset of forecastsfrom econ-
to a Bayesian model. In an overall comparisonof the meth- ometricmodels, a subsetof judgmentalforecasts,or a subset
ods, threeapproachesperformedbetterthanthe others.These of forecastsfrom extrapolationmethods). In any event, the
three were the simple average, the normal model with an Bayesian model provides a formal procedurefor including
independenceassumption,and the Bayesian model (with or prior information,and the simple average is one possible
without the independenceassumption). The basic normal outcome of this procedure.
model performedpoorly, and adjustmentssuch as varying In contrastto the simple averageand the Bayesianmodel,
the numberof data points used in the estimationprocess, which have a solid rationalewhen exchangeabilityof fore-
weighting recent observationsmore heavily, and imposing castersseems reasonable(eitherexclusively or suitablymod-
a convexity constrainton the combined forecasts had rela- ified by sample information),the normal model with the
tively minor, if any, impact on the performance. independenceassumptionis more difficult to justify. The
The three "successful" techniques in this study share forecast errorsfor the four econometricmodels considered
some commoncharacteristics. The simpleaverage,of course, here are clearly not independent,nor did we expect them to
forces the weights assigned to the forecaststo be equal. The be independent.The degreeof dependenceis very high. The
Bayesian model, with its a priori exchangeabilityassump- independenceassumptionjust happens to be an ad hoc as-
tion, takes the weights that would be used withoutthe prior sumptionthat workswell in this case (andprobablyin many
informationand "shrinks"themtowardequality.The larger other cases also). Independenceforces the weights to lie in
a is, the more the weights move toward equality. The in- the unit interval,and barringvery large differencesin fore-
dependenceassumptiondoes not lead to equal weights per cast accuracy among the forecasters, the weights will be
se, but as long as the k forecasterrorvariancesare relatively quite close. Thus, although exchangeabilityappearsto be
similar, as was the case here, the weights will be reasonably more reasonablethan independencein the economic fore-
close to each other. All three of these approachesavoid the casting situation,the two assumptionstend to lead to similar
extremeweights thatcan occur with the basic normalmodel combined forecasts.

This content downloaded from 152.3.102.242 on Tue, 22 Oct 2013 13:52:41 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
46 JANUARY1986
JOURNALOF BUSINESS & ECONOMICSTATISTICS,

The resultspresentedhere for methodsof combiningfore- REFERENCES


casts are consistent with the message given in Makridakis
Clemen, R. T. (1984), "Modeling Dependent Information:A Bayesian
et al. (1984) for extrapolationmethods: simpler methods
Approach," unpublishedPh.D. dissertation,IndianaUniversity.
performwell in comparisonto more complex methods. A Figlewski, S., and Urich, T. (1983), "Optimal Aggregation of Money
promising researchtopic concerns the robustnessof these SupplyForecasts:Accuracy,Profitabilityand MarketEfficiency," Jour-
results on combiningforecastsin situationswhere perform- nal of Finance, 28, 695-710.
ance differs more substantiallyand consistently among in- Geisser, S. (1965), "A Bayes Approachfor CombiningCorrelatedEsti-
mates," Journal of the AmericanStatisticalAssociation, 60, 602-607.
dividual forecastersand a simple average thereforeseems Granger,C. W. J., and Ramanathan,R. (1984), "ImprovedMethodsof
less appealing.Greaterdifferencesin individualperformance CombiningForecasts," Journal of Forecasting, 3, 197-204.
would lead to greater differences in the weights with an Halperin,M. (1961), "Almost LinearlyOptimumCombinationof Unbiased
Estimates," Journalof the AmericanStatisticalAssociation, 56, 36-43.
independenceassumptionand with the Bayesianmodel. The
individualdifferencesmight enable the scheme of using the LaValle, I. H. (1970), An Introductionto Probability, Decision, and In-
ference, New York:Holt, Rinehartand Winston.
best forecasterfrom the previous forecast to performwell. Lindley, D. V., and Smith, A. F M. (1972), "Bayes Estimatesfor the
Moreover, if the differences are relatively consistent, the LinearModel," Journal of the Royal StatisticalSociety, Ser. B, 34, 1-
normal model variantssuch as the OLS approachesmight 41.
do better, although the presence of high dependence will Makridakis, S., Andersen, A., Carbone, R., Fildes, R., Hibon, M.,
Lewandowski,R., Newton, J., Parzen,E., andWinkler,R. (1984), The
always create difficulties for these methods. ForecastingAccuracy of Major TimeSeries Methods, Chichester,Eng-
land: John Wiley.
ACKNOWLEDGMENTS Makridakis,S., and Winkler,R. L. (1983), "Averagesof Forecasts:Some
EmpiricalResults," ManagementScience, 29, 987-996.
This researchwas supportedin partby National Science Morris, P. A. (1977), "Combining Expert Judgments:A Bayesian Ap-
FoundationGrants IST8018578 and PRA8413106 and by proach," ManagementScience, 23, 679-693.
Indiana University. We are grateful to George Jaszi and Newbold, P., and Granger,C. W. J. (1974), "ExperienceWith Forecasting
UnivariateTime Series and the Combinationof Forecasts," Journal of
DonaldStraszheimfor providingthe forecastsfromthe BEA
the Royal Statistical Society, Ser. A, 137, 131-164.
and Whartonmodels, respectively, and to the referees for Winkler, R. L (1981), "Combining ProbabilityDistributionsFrom De-
helpful suggestions. pendentInformationSources," ManagementScience, 27, 479-488.
Winkler, R. L., and Makridakis,S. (1983), "The Combinationof Fore-
[ReceivedJuly 1984. RevisedMay 1985. ] casts," Journal of the Royal StatisticalSociety, Ser. A, 146, 150-157.

This content downloaded from 152.3.102.242 on Tue, 22 Oct 2013 13:52:41 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Das könnte Ihnen auch gefallen