Sie sind auf Seite 1von 17

Marketing Strategy and the Internet:

An Organizing Framework
P, Rajan Varadarajan
Manjit S. Yadav
Texas A&M University

Competitive strategy is primarily concerned with how a 9 Lower information search costs for buyers
business should deploy resources at its disposal to achieve 9 Diminished information asymmetry between sellers
and maintain defensible competitive positional advan- and buyers
tages in the marketplace. Competitive marketing strategy 9 Electronic spatial proximity of buyers and sellers
focuses on how a business should deploy marketing re- 9 Greater temporal separation between time of pur-
sources at its disposal to facilitate the achievement and chase and time of possession of physical products
maintenance of competitive positional advantages in the purchased in the electronic marketplace
marketplace. In a growing number of product-markets, the 9 Greater temporal proximity between time of pur-
competitive landscape has evolved from a predominantly chase and time of possession of digital products pur-
physical marketplace to one encompassing both the chased in the electronic marketplace
physical and the electronic marketplace. This article
presents a conceptual framework delineating the drivers Paralleling these developments, the business literature
and outcomes of marketing strategy in the context of com- has witnessed a number of new additions to its lexicon
peting in this broader, evolving marketplace. The pro- (e.g., e-business, e-commerce, e-procurement, e-services,
posed framework provides insights into changes in the e-customer relationship management, e-alliance partner
nature and scope of marketing strategy; specific industry, relationship management, e-supplier relationship man-
product, buyer, and buying environment characteristics; agement, e-supply chain management, etc.). Concur-
and the unique skills and resources of the firm that as- rently, scholarly research in marketing has focused on
sume added relevance in the context of competing in the such issues as new models of communication (Hoffman
evolving marketplace. and Novak 1996), buyers' and sellers' incentives to partici-
pate in the electronic marketplace (Alba et al. 1997; Burke
1997; Grewal, Comer, and Mehta 2001), and the migration
of products to the electronic marketplace (Peterson,
In a growing number of product-markets, the competi- Balasubramanian, and Bronnenberg 1997; Yadav and
tive landscape has evolved from a predominantly physical Varadarajan 2001). The contextual relevance of factors
marketplace to a broader marketplace encompassing both such as industry structure characteristics (e.g., market dis-
the physical and the electronic marketplace. The emer- persion and market thinness), product characteristics (e.g.,
gence of the electronic marketplace has been associated product digitizability), and buying environment (e.g., in-
with a number of developments, including the following: formation search costs) for competing in the electronic
marketplace have also been explored in recent research
9 Greater information richness of the transactional (Alba et al. 1997; Bakos 1991, 1997; Balasubramanian,
and relational environment Krishnan, and Sawhney 2000; Benjamin and Wigand
1995; Blattberg and Deighton 1991; Burke 1996;
Journal of the Academy of Marketing Science. Gurbaxani and Whang 1991; Hoffman and Novak 1996,
Volume 30, No. 4, pages 296.312.
DOI: 10.1177/009207002236907 1997; Lynch and Ariely 2000; Rayport and Sviokla 1994).
Copyright 9 2002 by Academy of Marketing Science. Contributions from strategy (e.g., Porter 2001), manage-
Varadarajan, Yadav/ STRATEGYAND THE INTERNET 297

ment information systems (e.g., Adam and Yesha 1996; Konsynski (1982), interorganizational information sys-
Huber 1990; Malone 1997; Malone, Yates, and Benjamin tems span organizational boundaries, linking firms to their
1989; Weill and Broadbent 1998), economics (e.g., Bakos customers and/or suppliers. This view of the electronic
199 t, 1997; Brynjolfsson and Seidmann 1997; Gurbaxani marketplace, while useful, appears restrictive in two
and Whang 1991; Shapiro and Varian 1999), and technol- respects. First, the term interorganizational information
ogy (e.g., Clark 1996; Oliver 1996) complement the above system seems to suggest an infrastructure created by and
research streams in marketing. for organizations. In reality, the role played by consumer-
Against this backdrop, this article focuses on the impli- controlled access devices (e.g., personal computers and
cations for marketing strategy of a competitive landscape personal digital assistants) continues to increase. There-
that is evolving from a physical marketplace to one encom- fore, in conceptualizing the electronic marketplace, the
passing both the physical and the electronic marketplace. broader term networked information system seems more
More specifically, our objectives are to appropriate than the seemingly restrictive term inter-
organizational information systems. Second, the nature
delineate the nature and scope of competitive mar- and scope of activities that occur in the electronic market-
keting strategy in reference to competing in the place often extend well beyond the "exchange of informa-
physical and the electronic marketplace; and tion about prices and product offerings." In fact, what
develop a conceptual framework that delineates rep- often transpires after the exchange of information--a
resentative industry structure, firm, product, buyer, transaction and other activities related to the transaction--
and buying environment characteristics pertinent represent important functions that are also facilitated by
to competing in the physical and the electronic the electronic marketplace and should, therefore, be noted.
marketplace. While the specific implementation of such functions may
vary across firms, any conceptualization of the electronic
The remainder of this article is organized as follows. marketplace must more fully encompass the scope of
First, we provide a brief overview of the evolving elec- activities that may occur in such a setting. Accordingly, we
tronic marketplace and extant perspectives on competitive conceptualize the electronic marketplace as a networked
strategy. Second, building on extant literature, we present information system that serves as an enabling infrastruc-
a conceptual framework focusing on selected drivers and ture.for buyers and sellers to exchange information, trans-
outcomes of competitive strategy. Third, we present a re- act, and perform other activities related to the transaction
finement and extension of the general framework by delin- before, during, and after the transaction. A brief elabora-
eating certain additional industry structure, firm, product, tion of this conceptualization follows.
buyer, and buying environment characteristics that are par- As can be noted, an electronic marketplace performs
ticularly pertinent to competing in an electronic market- essentially the same set of functions as a physical market-
place (and, by extension, in the new competitive landscape place--both bring buyers and sellers together. While they
that encompasses both the physical and the electronic mar- both share this important common purpose, electronic and
ketplaces). The proposed framework focuses on new chal- physical marketplaces do have certain distinguishing
lenges and opportunities for ongoing producer firms characteristics. The most obvious salient difference, of
(legacy businesses) as they seek to understand the implica- course, is that the enabling infrastructure is electronic
tions of the evolving marketplace for competitive market- rather than physical. This difference, in turn, leads to a
ing strategy. number of other differences that are worth mentioning.
For instance, variations such as the following are increas-
ingly prevalent in the electronic marketplace: private elec-
THE ELECTRONIC MARKETPLACE: tronic marketplaces that serve either multiple buyers and a
CONCEPTUALIZATION AND EVOLUTION seller (e.g., buyers purchasing tickets directly from an air-
line's Web site) or multiple sellers and a buyer (e.g., sellers
Conceptualization of participating in a live reverse auction at a prespecified date
the Electronic Marketplace and time in response to a call for bids posted by a buyer).
Such variations can occur in the physical marketplace as
The Intemet, a rapidly expanding global computer and well, but they can be scaled much more readily in the con-
communications infrastructure, has facilitated the emer- text of the electronic marketplace. A second distinguish-
gence of computer-mediated environments that serve as ing characteristic pertains to the increasingly prominent
electronic marketplaces for buyers and sellers. Bakos (1991) role played by other participants in the electronic market-
defined the electronic marketplace as "an inter-organiza- place--entities other than buyers and sellers who provide
tional information system that allows participating buyers value-added services to buyers and/or sellers. For exam-
and sellers to exchange information about prices and prod- ple, interacting with other marketplace participants may
uct offerings" (p. 296). According to Barrett and involve activities such as a buyer accessing information
298 JOURNALOF THE ACADEMYOF MARKETINGSCIENCE FALL2002

about product quality and price of competing brands com- 1920 that Westinghouse's first commercial radio station
prising his or her consideration set from an entity other went on the air (see Hanson 1998 for an interesting
than a seller (e.g., an informediary) and engaging in a con- account of how the radio industry evolved in its early
versation about product quality and price of competing years). The popular press described the radio as "a fad that
brand offerings with past and prospective buyers in an seemed to come from no where [and grew] with almost
electronic chat room. Again, while such interactions can stunning suddenness" (Douglas 1991:190)----even though
also occur in the physical marketplace, their prevalence radio technology had been evolving for more than two
and scalability are greater in the electronic marketplace. decades. FM technology, developed in 1936, languished
As the electronic marketplace evolves, additional distin- until the 1960s, when it was resuscitated by congressional
guishing characteristics relative to the physical market- legislation (the 1967 Public Broadcasting Act) that ush-
place may emerge and thus deserve close attention. How ered in the era of public broadcasting in the United States.
this evolution is likely to occur is the focus of the next Finally, in the interpersonal domain, the telephone market
section. remained quite restricted until the key patents expired in
1895 and allowed independent phone companies to enter
Evolution of the the market.
Electronic Marketplace As the electronic marketplace represents a merging of
different forms of media (which Fidler 1997 referred to as
The concept of interactivity is crucial for understanding mediamorphosis), it is also instructive to study consumer
current buyer-seller activities in the electronic market- adoption of previous generations of similar products and
place and how these activities may evolve over the years. services. VCA (Video Corporation of America), a joint
Hoffman and Novak (1996) distinguished between unme- venture of Knight-Ridder and AT&T, attempted to bring
diated interactivity (e.g., direct face-to-face communica- the document domain to television in 1983 with a service
tion between two individuals) and mediated interactivity called Videotron. Subscribers to this service, which used a
(e.g., communication between two individuals facilitated setup box on their television set, could access financial, lo-
by a device). Steuer (1992), a communication theorist, cal, and national news. It was discontinued in 1986 after
defined mediated interactivity as the "extent to which receiving a disappointing response from the market. Simi-
users can participate in modifying the form and content of lar services met the same fate in England (Prestel) and
a mediated environment in real time" (p. 84). In the context Germany (Bilderschirmtext) but succeeded in France
of a computer-mediated environment, interactivity would (Minitel) (see Mayntz and Hughes 1988 for details related
refer to a user's ability to alter the environment experi- to these early attempts at providing online information ser-
enced via a computer (Hoffman and Novak 1996). Yadav vices). Reviewing such historical evidence, Fidler (1997)
and Varadarajan (2001) reviewed extant work in the area concluded that
and defined interactivity in the electronic marketplace as
"the degree to which computer-mediated communication however society and media may change, we can be
between entities comprising the marketplace is (a) bi- reasonably assured that they will embody and build
directional, (b) timely, (c) mutually controllable, and (d) upon the experiences of the past, as they always
responsive" (p. 6). With technological advances currently have. By letting history be our guide, we will see that
occurring in the realm of connectivity (i.e., how consumers the forces shaping our future are essentially the
same that have shaped our past. (P. 7)
and firms connect with and participate in computer-medi-
ated environments), even higher levels of interactivity can
Recognizing the potential relevance of extant literature
be envisioned in the future (Cairncross 1997).
and perspectives, the next section provides a broad over-
According to Fidler (1997), understanding the evolu-
view of competitive strategy and the drivers and outcomes
tion of different forms of media technologies can provide
of competitive strategy. In a subsequent section, we build
clues about how buyers and sellers may embrace (or resist)
on this foundation and delineate additional characteristics
higher levels of interactivity in the electronic marketplace.
and considerations that merit attention in the context of the
Fidler described the evolution of three types of media tech-
evolving marketplace.
nologies: document domain (print), interpersonal domain
(telephone), and broadcast (radio, television). Fidler noted
that media technologies seem to incubate for many years DRIVERS AND OUTCOMES
(even decades or centuries in some cases) before they have OF COMPETITIVE STRATEGY
a widespread impact on the marketplace. In the document
domain, it took almost 300 years before the steam press Strategy exists at multiple levels--corporate, business,
brought automation to the Gutenberg press and facilitated and functional---of an organization. Corporate strategy
its rapid expansion. In the broadcast domain, the first ama- refers to a firm's choice of businesses to be in. Business or
teur radio broadcast occurred in 1906, but it was not until competitive strategy refers to how a particular business in a
Varadarajan, Y a d a v / S T R A T E G Y A N D T H E I N T E R N E T 299

FIGURE 1
Competitive Strategy: Drivers and Outcomes

2. Industry Structure
4. Product Characteristics Number of Competitors
9Goods vs. Services Size of Compehtors
Industry Concentration
9Search vs. Experience
Market Growth Rate
vs. Credence Goods Entry & Exit Barriers
9Tangibles Dominant vs.
Intangibles Dominant Products
8.

9
Macro
Environment
L
1. Competitive Strategy 6. Marketplace
7. Financial
-Social Performance Performance
9Generic Competttive Strategy
,Legal 9Market Share & Growth *ROI
*Product Strategy 9Earnings Growth
,Regulatory "Promotton Strategy 9Sales & Growth 9Shareholder Wealth
*Pricing Strategy
9Customer Satisfaction

l
9 *Distribution Strategy
9Customer Loyalty
.Infrastructure
.Technological
5. Buyer and Buying
Environment Characteristics
3. Firm Characteristics,
9Individual vs. Organizattonal Skills & Resources
9Non-trivial Information Search Costs
9 Size
9Non-trivial Information 9 Brand, Customer & Channel
Asymmetry VlS-~t-vls Seller Equity
9 Positioning Skills
9Low Cost Transparency
9 Segmentation Skills
9One-to-Many Communicauon Model

N O T E : Ellipses ( . . . . . . ) d e n o t e that the d r i v e r s / o u t c o m e s are i n t e n d e d to be illustrative r a t h e r than c o m p r e h e n s i v e . R O I = return on i n v e s t m e n t .

firm's portfolio of businesses chooses to compete in the industry structure, firm, product, buyer, and buying envi-
marketplace. At the functional level, marketing strategy ronment related variables that are particularly relevant
(or competitive marketing strategy) refers to how a busi- considerations in regard to competing in the electronic
ness chooses to deploy marketing resources at its disposal marketplace.
to facilitate the achievement of competitive positional Building on extant research in marketing, strategic
advantage(s) in the marketplace. The centrality of pattern management, and industrial organization economics fo-
of resource allocation to competitive strategy is evident in cusing on understanding, explaining, and predicting busi-
a number of conceptualizations and definitions of strategy. ness performance, we present a framework delineating the
For instance, Hofer and Schendel (1978) defined strategy relationship between the following (see Figure 1):
as the "fundamental pattern of present and planned
resource deployments and environmental interactions that 1. competitive strategy pursued by the business,
indicates how the organization will achieve its objectives" 2. structural characteristics of the industry in
which the business competes,
(p. 25). Barney (1996) defined strategy as "a pattern of
3. distinctive skills and resources of the firm,
resource allocation that enables firms to maintain or
4. characteristics of the product offerings of the
improve their performance" (p. 27). business,
Building on the extant literature, this section provides 5. characteristics of buyers and the buying envi-
an overview of the embeddedness of the competitive ronment,
strategy of a business in the industry structure, firm, prod- 6. marketplace performance,
uct, buyer, and buying environment. In the next section, 7. financial performance, and
we present an exposition of how competitive strategy in 8. macro environment.
an electronic marketplace can also be viewed as embed-
ded in these same factors. However, while the factors The proposed framework constitutes an attempt to de-
remain the same, we draw attention to certain additional lineate certain key linkages between competitive strategy
300 JOURNALOF THE ACADEMYOF MARKETINGSCIENCE FALL2002

and its drivers and outcomes. The intent here is to parsimo- cost. The resource-based view ofthefirm suggests that the
niously organize extant works and perspectives focusing sustainability of the competitive advantage of the busi-
on these linkages. After briefly reviewing this framework, nesses in a firm's portfolio is a function of the core compe-
we use it as a foundation for our subsequent discussion of tencies of the firm (Barney 1991; Hunt 2000; Prahalad and
competitive strategy, drivers of competitive strategy, and Hame11990). A firm's core competencies are based on the
outcomes in the context of the electronic marketplace (see collective learning in the organization and built around re-
Figure 2). sources that are valuable, rare, difficult to imitate, and not
easily substitutable (Barney 1991). As noted by Prahalad
Competitive strategy and performance (Links 1 ~ 6 and Hamel (1990), "The real sources of advantage are to
and 6 ~ 7). As noted previously, the purpose of competi- be found in management's ability to consolidate corporate-
tive strategy is to achieve a competitive positional advan- wide technologies and production skills into competencies
tage (differentiation and/or cost advantage) in the that empower individual businesses to adapt quickly to
marketplace. Achieving competitive differentiation and changing opportunities" (p. 81).
cost advantage entails performing activities comprising
the value chain in ways that lead to differentiation of a Product characteristics and competitive strategy
business's offerings from its competitors' offerings and at (Link 4 ---) 1). There is a long history of research in mar-
a lower cost relative to competitors, respectively. The keting and economics focusing on the competitive strat-
sustainability of competitive positional advantages is a egy implications of the characteristics of a product. The
function of the characteristics of the firm's skills and re- vast body of literature in marketing on product and brand
sources underlying the strategy (i.e., the extent to which management, as well as on innovation and new products,
the underlying skills and resources are rare, valuable, provides valuable insights into the linkage between prod-
nonimitable, and/or characterized by the absence of equiv- uct characteristics and marketing strategy. Seminal
alent substitutes) (see Barney 1991). A business's compet- works highlighting the differences between goods and
itive positional advantages, in turn, affect its marketplace services (Shostack 1977), tangible and intangible prod-
performance (e.g., market share, market share growth rate, uct attributes (Levitt 1981), and search, experience, and
sales, sales growth rate, customer satisfaction, customer credence attributes of products (Darby and Karni 1973;
loyalty) and financial performance (e.g., return on invest- Nelson 1970) also provide valuable insights into the link-
ment, earnings growth rate, shareholder wealth). age between product characteristics and the competitive
strategies of businesses.
Industry structure characteristics and competitive
strategy (Link 2 ~ 1). Industry structure refers to the eco- Buyer and buying environment characteristics and
nomic and technical characteristics of an industry that de- competitive strategy (Link 5 ---) 1). The literature in mar-
fine the context in which competition takes place. keting focusing on the role of buyer characteristics and
Research in industrial organizational economics, strategic buying environment characteristics on competitive strat-
management, and marketing lends support for the link be- egy is also vast and extensive. Starting with Webster and
tween the structural characteristics of the market in which Wind's (1972) call for studying the differences related to
a business competes and the competitive strategy pur- individual and organizational buying processes, a large
sued by the business. For instance, the structure-conduct- body of research has emerged over the years that seeks to
performance (SCP) model (Bain 1956) views industry provide insights into the competitive dynamics of business-
structure as determining the behavior (conduct/strategy) to-business environments (see Keep, Hollander, and
of businesses in an industry, and conduct as determining Dickinson 1998 for a historical overview). Research fo-
industry performance. Conduct/strategy, in effect, is cusing on the interconnectedness of the information envi-
viewed as merely reflecting the industry environment in ronment prevalent in a marketplace and the competitive
which a business operates. For example, to the extent that strategies of businesses can be traced to the early work of
concentrated market structures are conducive to facilitating Stigler (1961) and Ackerlof (1970). Stigler's analysis of
oligopolistic coordination among competitors, it could re- markets, characterized by nontrivial search costs, contin-
sult in lower output, higher prices, and higher rates of retum. ues to inspire research efforts in the area (e.g., Dickson and
Sawyer 1990; Urbany 1986). Ackerlof's notion of infor-
Firm-specifc skills and resources and competitive mation asymmetry in the marketplace (which gives an in-
strategy (Link 3 --~ 1). A firm's unique skills and resources formation advantage to sellers over buyers) also has served
are a major determinant of its choice of competitive strat- as a foundation for a large body of subsequent work (e.g.,
egy at the level of individual business units. Competitive Rao and Bergen 1992; Urbany, Dickson, and Wilkie
business strategy entails leveraging the firm's unique 1989). Building on the drivers of competitive strategy de-
skills and resources to perform the various activities in lineated in Figure 1, in the next section, we focus on the
the value chain in ways that differentiate a business's of- drivers of competitive strategy in the physical and elec-
ferings from its competitors' offerings and/or at a lower tronic marketplace.
Varadarajan,Yadav/ STRATEGYAND THE INTERNET 301

INTEGRATING THE INTERNET . Deployment of resources in an attempt to lever-


INTO COMPETITIVE STRATEGY: age the potential of the Internet to pursue new
A CONCEPTUAL FRAMEWORK business models and competitive strategies. "~

Integrating the Internet into a business's competitive The potential of the Internet can be leveraged for en-
strategy and competitive marketing strategy is increas- hancing the effectiveness of a business's competitive strat-
ingly becoming an imperative, with the market environ- egy as well as the efficiency of its operations. The absolute
ment evolving to encompass both the physical and the amount of marketing resources a business chooses to allo-
electronic marketplaces. Figure 2 provides an overview of cate toward competing in the electronic marketplace, as
selected industry structure, firm, product, buyer, and buy- well as the allocation relative to the resources allocated to
ing environment characteristics that assume added rele- competing in the physical marketplace, will therefore be
vance in the context of competing in the evolving hybrid affected by both efficiency and effectiveness consider-
marketplace. It should, however, be noted that the factors ations. Complementing Box 1 in Figure 2, Table 1 pro-
delineated in Figure 1 continue to be relevant consider- vides an overview of how businesses might leverage the
ations from the standpoint of competing in the electronic potential of the Internet to enhance the effectiveness of
marketplace in and of itself, as well as in the broader mar- their marketing strategy and the efficiency of their market-
ketplace encompassing both the physical and the elec- ing operations in the evolving hybrid marketplace. As in-
tronic marketplaces. In Figure 2, Links 8 ---) 2, 8 ~ 3, 8 dicated in this table, with the exception of the actual
4, and 8 ---) 5 are shown as dotted lines. These linkages distribution of nondigital/nondigitizable products, effec-
serve to highlight technological developments that have tive and/or efficient deployment of all other marketing mix
necessitated the need to revisit extant perspectives relating elements can be enhanced by leveraging the potential of
to Links 2 ~ 1, 3 ---) 1, 4 ~ 1, and 5 ~ 1. A more detailed the Internet.
discussion of these linkages follows. We next focus on selected linkages (drivers of competi-
In response to the change in the frame of reference for tive strategy) delineated in Figure 2. While we recognize
competitive strategy from "How to compete in the physi- that a business's competitive strategy decisions will realis-
cal marketplace?" to "How to compete in the physical and tically be based on a multiplicity of considerations, in this
the electronic marketplace?" businesses have instituted a initial exposition, we limit our discussion to linkages
number of changes in their competitive marketing strate- between specific drivers of competitive strategy delin-
gies (i.e., their pattern of deployment of marketing re- eated in Boxes 2, 3, 4, and 5 and competitive strategy (Box
sources). Illustrative of such changes are the following 1). Our goal is to develop the logic underlying these link-
(see Box 1 in Figure 2): ages generally rather than describe all possible relation-
ships between pairs of variables depicted in Figure 2.
1. Changes in resource deployments manifesting
as relative emphasis on traditional channels ver- Industry Structure Characteristics
sus electronic channels (i.e., the Internet) for and Competitive Strategy
9 providing product-related information to
customers, Market thinness, customer dispersion, and relative em-
9 communicating with customers, phasis on competing in the physical versus the electronic
9 promoting to customers, marketplace. Among the structural characteristics of a
9 transacting with customers,
market that favor placing greater emphasis on competing
9 distributing digital/digitizable products, and
in the electronic marketplace vis-~t-vis the physical mar-
9 customer trial/sampling of digital/digitizable
products. ketplace are market thinness and customer dispersion
2. Changes in resource deployments manifesting (Gupta and Chatterjee 1997). Thin markets, such as the
as greater emphasis on market for antique cars, tend to have undesirable proper-
9 marketing directly to customers in the electronic ties for both buyers (e.g., lack of choice) and sellers (e.g.,
marketplace versus through intermediaries (tradi- inability to locate buyers). The electronic marketplace,
tional, electronic, and/or hybrid intermediaries), due to its effectiveness in bringing potential buyers and
9 market pioneering (first to market), and sellers together, is conducive to improving the working of
9 strategic alliances. thin markets. Dispersion of customers over a wide geo-
3. Deployment of resources in an attempt to lever- graphical area, as opposed to concentration in one geo-
age the potential of the Internet for innovations, graphical area, results in a market that is thin on the buyer
customization, and augmentation in the realms
side at the local level. A business focused on a local market
of product, price, promotion, and distribution
(e.g., product innovations, customization, and may not be viable due to the small number of potential
augmentation). buyers in that market. However, by leveraging the poten-
tial of the Internet, a seller, by aggregating buyers dis-
302 JOURNAL OF THE ACADEMY OF MARKETING SCIENCE FALL 2002

TABLE 1
Leveraging the Potential of the Internet for Enhancing Marketing
Strategy Effectiveness and Marketing Operations Efficiency
Product Class
Digital and Dtgitizable Intangibles-Dominant Tangibles-Dominant
Productsa Productsb'd Productsc'd
Leveraging the potential of the Internet for the following:
Information provision to prospective buyers Y Y Y
Communicating with prospective buyers
(prepurchase and/or postpurchase) Y Y Y
Customer service and customer relationship managemente Y Y Y
Market research Y Y Y
Product innovations Y Y Y
Product customizationf Y Y Y
Promotion renovations Y Y Y
Promotion customizationf Y Y Y
Pricing innovations Y Y Y
Price customizationf Y Y Y
Distribution innovations Y Y Y
Distribution customizationf Y Y Y
Transaction processing Y Y Y
Product distribution y Ng Ng

NOTE: Y = yes; N = no. As indicated in the table, while the Internet is not a viable channel for the actual product distribution (i.e., physical transportation)
of nondigitizable products (whether intangibles-dominant or tangibles-dominant products), it is a viable medium for, and/or a facilitator of, every other
marketing-related activity delineated in the table.
a. Software, music, videos, books, newspapers, magazines, financial information, etc. Although digitizable, in some instances, customers' preference
may be for the product in a nondigital format (e.g., books).
b. Air travel, car rental, hotel accommodations, etc.
c. Automobiles, appliances, computers, entertainment electronics products, real estate, etc.
d. Finer distinctions within intangibles-dominant and tangibles-dominant products can provide further insights into the viability of the Internet as a me-
dium for, and/or facilitator of, the marketing-related activities delineated in the table. For instance, tangibles-dominant products can be further distin-
guished as products that are light (weight) and/or compact (volume) versus those that are heavy and bulky. All else equal, lower fulfillment costs associated
with high value, light weight, and compact products make them more conducive to being bought and sold in the electronic marketplace.
e. As in ECRM (electronic customer relationship management).
f. Although customization at the level of an individual buyer may be feasible, the economics of customization and the buyer's level of interest in custom-
ized products (e.g., for products such as toothpaste, soap, detergent, etc.) are factors that should be borne in mind.
g. Based on a broader construal of a product as an "augmented product," it could be argued that certain elements of an augmented product can be digitized
(e.g., reviews of books, virtual tours of real estate properties) and distributed through the Internet. We include them here under "distribution innovations."
Product distribution here refers to the actual distribution of the core product.

persed over several local markets, m a y be able to create a with each other and with individuals) (see Tapscott 1996),
viable c u s t o m e r base and cater to their needs in the elec- can increase substantially a product's functionality. The
tronic marketplace. greater the order of m a g n i t u d e of n e t w o r k effects, the
greater the importance of market p i o n e e r i n g as a source of
Network externalities, tippy markets, and market pio- c o m p e t i t i v e a d v a n t a g e for digital p r o d u c t s v i s - a - v i s
neering. Network externalities (or effects) refers to the nondigital products.
p h e n o m e n o n of a product b e c o m i n g increasingly valuable Network effects exist at multiple levels:
to its present and potential users as the n u m b e r of others
who adopt, own, or use the product (i.e., the size of the net- 9 market exchange level (e.g., e B a y . c o m vs. A m a z o n .
work) increases. For instance, as the installed base of fax c o m and Yahoo.com auction sites),
machines increases, so does the usefulness of the device to 9 industry standards level (e.g., W i n d o w s vs. Mac Op-
each individual with access to the service. For markets erating System; V H S vs. B e t a m a x format VCRs),
characterized by n e t w o r k effects, the market pioneer, b y 9 b r a n d level (Word vs. WordPerfect word-processing
cultivating a large user base for its product offering prior to software).
the entry of competitors, can achieve a competitive advan-
tage. Such effects are often observed in the case of m a n y Consider network effects as a source o f first-mover advan-
c o m m u n i c a t i o n technologies (e.g., telephones, fax ma- tage at the electronic market exchange level. All else
chines, e-mail). Product digitizability, by facilitating net- equal, sellers will be more predisposed to list to sell their
worked intelligence (i.e., products being able to interact products at electronic market exchanges with the most
Varadarajan, Y a d a v / S T R A T E G Y A N D T H E I N T E R N E T 303

FIGURE 2
Integrating the Internet Into Competitive Strategy: A Conceptual Framework

12. Industry Structure

i 4. Product Characteristics .MarketThinness


9Customer Dispersion
i -i~roduct Digitizabdtty | .Network Externalities
9Market Tippiness
:-................ P -Dtsaggregatability [
.Channel Structure
-Aggregatablhty /
9 Cost structure
9 Primary-Complementary Space 1. Competitive Strategy
8. Macro 9Product Tangibility
Environment 9Relative Emphasts on Traditional
-Remote Information Provision and Electronic Channels for: 6. Marketplace
.Pohttcal 9 Volume-Weight-Value -Providing Information to Customers
Performance
9Product Perishability -Communicating with Customers 7. Financial

t
.Social
-Transacting 9Market Share & Growth
Performance
9 -Distributing 9Sales & Growth 9
-Trial/Sampling 9Earnings Growth
9 9Customer Satisfaction
9Relative Emphasis on: 9Shareholder Wealth
.Economic -Marketing Direct vs Intermediaries 9Customer Loyalty 9Other indicators
-Market Pioneenng & Alliances
9 V
9Leveraglng Electronic Channels for: 9Other Indicators
-Product Innovation/Customization
.Technological 5. Buyer and Buying -Pricmg Innovation/Customization
.Other~ Environment Characteristics -Promotion lnnovatton/Customization
-Dlstrtbunon Innovation/Customization
9Competing in Fundamentally New Ways
9Dlrnlmshmg Informanon Search Costs
i .................. 9D~rnmlshmgInformanon Asymmetry
9IncreasingCostTransparency 3. Firm Characteristics,
9Many-to-Many Commumcatlon Model
Skills & Resources
9 Resources
..................................................................................... ..... 9IT Resources and Information
Processing Slolls

N O T E : Ellipses ( . . . . . . ) d e n o t e characteristics d e l i n e a t e d in Boxes 1 to 5 in F i g u r e 1. R O I = return on i n v e s t m e n t ; I T = i n f o r m a t i o n technology.

buyers, and buyers will be more predisposed to look to buy to describe such markets (Frank and Cook 1995), this is
at electronic market exchanges with the most sellers. The somewhat of a misnomer as a number of (albeit, very
above behavior of sellers and buyers can be mutually rein- small) competitors can in fact coexist with a dominant firm
forcing. Network effects at the industry level for digital in such markets (Economides and Flyer 1998). Shapiro
products are attributable to systems tending to evolve and Varian (1999) suggested that a market's likelihood of
around (competing) standards. The associated high tipping depends on two factors: (1) consumer demand for
switching costs can lead to the market pioneer enjoying a variety and (2) economies of scale. While consumer
competitive advantage (see Shapiro and Varian 1999). demand for variety can be high for certain types of digital
Farrell and Saloner (1985) showed that a standard, once products (e.g., entertainment software such as computer
established, exhibits "inertia" (i.e., it is difficult for the and video games), it can also be low (e.g., for productivity
market to adopt another standard). When some users do tools such as word-processing software). When consumer
move from one dominant (but inferior) standard to another demand for variety is low, users tend to develop loyalty
emerging (but superior) standard, they experience "tran- toward familiar products that get the job done. Digital
sient incompatibility" (Farrell and Saloner 1986)--that is, products are generally characterized by considerable
they are temporarily part of a smaller network that lacks economies of scale as the reproduction of product compo-
the network externalities of the dominant standard. Net- nents with a high level of digitization is associated with
work externalities at the brand level are also driven by sim- relatively low incremental costs. Furthermore, due to sup-
ilar considerations in that a network of users of one brand ply-side effects of network externalities (Katz and Shapiro
competes, in effect, with networks represented by users of 1985), the total cost of serving an installed base of users
other brands. may in fact decline as the installed base expands (largely
Tippy markets refer to markets that tend to tip in favor of because the expanding installed base attracts additional
just one firm. While the term winner-take-all is often used firms that produce spare parts, supplies, and other value-
304 JOURNALOF THE ACADEMYOF MARKETINGSCIENCE FALL2002

adding services). Shapiro and Varian noted that pioneering Information technology resources and information-
advantage is more likely to be sustained in product-markets processing skills involve the ability of the firm to use
characterized by relatively low demand for consumer vari- information technology (IT) resources and informa-
ety and high economies of scale. tion-processing skills to gain insights about individ-
ual customers and use this knowledge to customize
Channel structure characteristics and marketing di-
its future interactions with these customers.
rectly to customers. An inverse relationship can be ex-
pected to exist between concentration at the intermediary
A firm's skills and resources in the above two catego-
level and the propensity of producers to transact directly
with customers in the electronic marketplace (i.e., resort to ries are key strategy enablers in that they determine the abil-
disintermediation). An indicator of concentration at the in- ity (or lack thereof) of a business to pursue certain compet-
termediary level is the percentage of industry sales ac- itive strategies in the electronic marketplace. Glazer
counted for by the largest intermediaries. In the United (1991), in his analysis of information- and technology-
States, the airline industry is characterized by low concen- driven changes in the marketplace, discussed the increas-
tration (high fragmentation) at the intermediary level (i.e., ing strategic significance of information as an organiza-
several thousand travel agencies that are small in size, rela- tional asset. He argued that information (often originating
tive to the size of commercial passenger airlines). In such as transaction-related data that firms can capture) could be
industries, producer firms face fewer deterrents to shifting used to reduce costs and increase revenue. Information-
an increasingly larger proportion of their marketing re- intensive firms, in Glazer's conceptualization, acquire and
sources to marketing directly to customers in the elec- use information toward this end to a greater extent than
tronic marketplace. Illustrative of an industry that is their competitors. Porter and Millar (1985) discussed the
characterized by high concentration at the intermediary implications of information-intensive value chains that are
level is the small electrical home appliances industry (e.g., characterized by a large number of "value activities" in-
electric irons, toasters, and blenders). Here, a few large re- volving the processing of information (relative to the pro-
tailers in the United States (e.g., Wal-Mart, Target, Home cessing of physical inputs). They also documented the
Depot, and Lowe's) account for a significant percentage of increasing prevalence of information-intensive products
the producer industry's sales. In such industries, there is a (i.e., products that require a large amount of "information
lower likelihood of firms in the producer industry commit- content" to facilitate their purchase and use).
ting substantial resources to transacting directly with cus- A firm's information assets and information-process-
tomers in the electronic marketplace. High concentration ing skills and resources critically affect its ability to pursue
at the traditional intermediary level, as well as their atten- certain marketing strategies as well as make better deci-
dant ability to retaliate, is conceivably a deterrent to firms sions in the realm of various marketing mix variables. For
in the producer industry pursuing a direct-to-consumer instance, a firm's ability to engage in suggestive selling
strategy in the electronic marketplace. Established pro- (recommending products to an individual customer based
ducers in industries characterized by high concentration at on perceived similarity with the purchase patterns of
the traditional intermediary level are likely to be more se- other customers) depends on its information assets and
lective in their choice of a direct-to-consumer strategy in information-processing skills and resources. Similarly, in
the electronic marketplace. For instance, a producer that the area of pricing, the information assets and information-
implements a direct-to-consumer strategy involving a lim- processing assets of a firm determine the extent to which it
ited product line (e.g., refurbished products, niche prod-
would be able to engage in more fine-tuned price discrimi-
ucts, replacements parts, etc.) is less likely to encounter
nation (e.g., inferring buyers' price sensitivity from their
retaliatory actions from traditional intermediaries.
Web navigation and purchase behavior and offering prod-
ucts at prices customized to the level of individual buyers).
Firm-Specific Skills and Resources A firm's IT assets and capabilities are also a critical deter-
and Competitive Strategy
minant of its ability to pursue other strategies in the realm
of pricing such as dynamic pricing (e.g., changing the
As shown in Figure 2, the development and nurturing of
two firm-specific skills and resources assume consider- price at which a product is offered on the basis of prevail-
able importance in the context of competing in the elec- ing supply and demand conditions).
tronic marketplace: Firms with superior information assets and information-
processing assets may eventually be able to pursue market
Information resources involve the nature and segmentation to its logical limits--segment size of one.
amount of information possessed by the firm about Not surprisingly, firms are being advised to diagnose their
individual customers. one-to-one capabilities by assessing their ability to
Varadarajan, Yadav/ STRATEGYAND THE INTERNET 305

identify, differentiate, and interact with individual custom- (e.g., a dictionary and thesaurus being subsumed within
ers and to develop customized product offerings (Peppers, a word-processing software) and disaggregation (e.g., a
Rogers, and Doff 1999). Increasing interest in managing chapter of a textbook or a song in a CD collection).
customer relationships and measuring customer lifetime Products created through disaggregation can be mar-
value (Berger and Nasr 1998), besides reflecting a shift keted as micro products as well as reaggregated to create
in focus from groups of consumers to individual con- other macro products (e.g., a customized CD that is a
sumers, also highlights the imperative for firms to focus compilation of songs from different CDs). Product
on developing superior information assets and information- disaggregatabitity, while presenting opportunities for
processing assets. firms to generate new revenue streams, also presents asso-
Finally, as information-intensive environments are ciated challenges such as pricing of micro products, cost-
characterized by frequent and unpredictable changes effective mode of distribution of micro products, and
(D'Aveni 1999), it is important to emphasize the need for guarding against the threat of cannibalization of macro
constantly renewing a firm's set of skills and resources. products from which the micro products are derived.
Specifically, a finn's dynamic capabilities (Eisenhardt and Abell's (1980) schema for defining the scope of a busi-
Martin 2000; Teece, Pisano, and Shuen 1997) that result in ness in terms of customer functions served, customer
the creation of new skills and resources pertaining to the groups served, and technologies used is relevant to under-
management of information-based assets need careful standing the implications of product digitizability for
scrutiny when competing in the electronic marketplace. competitive strategy. In some instances, alternative analog
While extant work has highlighted the significance of cre- and digital technological solutions for satisfying a specific
ating such information-based assets (e.g., Glazer 199 I), it customer need may coexist (e.g., e-books and printed
remains unclear how these assets can be created and nur- books; a roll of film being processed and delivered to the
tured most effectively. Eisenhardt and Martin's (2000) customer as pictures on paper, on a CD as digitized pic-
observation regarding the equifinality of dynamic capa- tures, or digitized and stored at a Web site for the customer
bilities (i.e., different paths may lead to similar out- to access and selectively print or electronically forward).
comes) implies that each firm must seek out best prac- In other instances, the analog technological solution to
tices but also leave room for experimentation with satisfying a customer need may eventually be displaced
alternative approaches. by a superior and/or cost-efficient digital technological
alternative (e.g., the print version of an encyclopedia
Product Characteristics being displaced by a Web site and/or a CD version). Such
and Competitive Strategy dynamics, in turn, can be expected to affect a business's
relative emphasis on the physical versus the electronic
Product digitizability and relative emphasis on compet- marketplace.
ing in the electronic versus the physical marketplace. As a result of increasing product digitization, the primary-
Product digitizability has important implications for com- complementary product space has broadened well beyond
petitive strategy due to the potential for augmentation of a analog primary--analog complementary products (e.g., razor
product that conversion into digital hardware or software and blade cartridge) to encompass the foUowing:
offers (see Balasubramanian et al. 2000 for an extended
discussion). For instance, products amenable to being dig- 9 analog primary-digital complementary products
itized offer considerable potential for (e.g., car telematics and digital music services),
9 digital primary-analog complementary products
9 product customization (e.g., developing a custom- (e.g., digital navigation services and alternative ac-
ized readings packet for a course comprising book cess devices such as cell phones and personal digital
chapters from different textbooks, made available assistants), and
either in print or digital version), ~ digital primary-digital complementary products
9 product innovation (e.g., creating new services such (e.g., e-mail and stock alert services packaged for
as audio and video on demand), and wireless delivery).
~ product enhancement (e.g., offering to subscribers of
the print version of a business magazine privileged The insights that extant literature provides into the market-
access to certain sections of the publication's Web ing strategy implications of complementary products
site that are not accessible to the general public). (e.g., price bundling, joint sales promotion, marketing alli-
ances) were, for the most part, developed in the context of
Digital products and products amenable to being digi- analog primary-analog complementary products. The rel-
tized also offer considerable potential for aggregation evance of these insights in the context of other pairings of
306 JOURNAL OF THE ACADEMY OF MARKETING SCIENCE FALL 2002

primary and complementary products delineated above is Product volume-weight-value characteristics and po-
somewhat limited. Contrast, for instance, complementary tential of the electronic marketplace. The volume-weight-
digital products consumed in the virtual marketspace with value characteristics of a product can affect a firm's rela-
analog complementary products consumed in the physical tive emphasis on the physical versus the electronic market-
marketplace. Compared to stand-alone analog comple- place. As pointed out in Table 1, the economics of
mentary products that tend to retain their distinct identity, fulfillment of transactions that occur in the electronic mar-
a number of digital and digitizable complementary prod- ketplace favors products that are less bulky and command
ucts tend to be subsumed and seamlessly integrated into a high price relative to transportation costs, but it may be
more aggregate digital products (e.g., products such as inefficient for bulky products that have a low value/weight
free e-mail service, Web search engine, and an information ratio. Niche e-retailers such as Ashford.com (which spe-
portal and a shopping portal being integrated in a Web cializes in high-end watches and jewelry) capitalize on the
browser). Such considerations suggest that exploration of economics of performing fulfillment activities in the elec-
the feasibility of acquiring providers of complementary tronic marketplace for certain types of products.
products and/or forging alliances with a larger network of
Product perishability and relative emphasis on compet-
providers of complementary products (e.g., an Internet ac-
ing in the electronic versus the physical marketplace.
cess provider forging alliances with a large number of pro-
Product perishability refers to the degree to which product
viders of content and marketers of goods and services)
value declines due to the mismatch between when the
assumes added importance for businesses competing pri-
product is produced and when it is consumed. The decline
marily in the virtual marketspace vis-h-vis the physical
in product value can be viewed from the perspective of a
marketplace. 3
buyer (in that the product suffers a loss in utility) and a
Product tangibility, remote information provision, and seller (in that the seller is unable to recover this loss in
relative emphasis on competing in the electronic versus product utility). While practically every product has some
the physical marketplace. Product tangibility refers to the degree of perishability, the value of some products (e.g.,
relative dominance of tangible attributes relative to intan- fashion and seasonal merchandise, financial information)
gible attributes in a product. In general, tangible attributes is more likely to decline as the time between production
that require tactile feedback may be difficult to communi- and consumption increases. In the case of many services
cate in electronic settings (e.g., a fabric's texture). How- where production and consumption must occur simulta-
ever, tangible attributes that have some degree of neously (e.g., airline seats, hotel rooms), product
standardization (e.g., neck size of men's shirts) can be perishability is very high. Naturally, the key to operating
evaluated with relative ease. Also, in a repurchase situa- effectively in a perishable product category is to develop
tion, buyers may feel comfortable evaluating attributes mechanisms that will enable the seller to (a) anticipate
that do require tactile feedback (Alba et al. 1997). For when product supply is likely to exceed demand and (b)
some products, physical proximity may be essential for implement promotional mechanisms (such as discounts)
providing the information needed. Nevertheless, even that will clear the market when available supply exceeds
products for which buyers need large amounts of informa- prevailing demand. The electronic marketplace, by virtue
tion to facilitate evaluation, acquisition, and use are likely of inexpensive and highly scalable communication link-
to benefit more from the information search capability of ages between buyers and sellers, is ideally suited for devel-
the electronic marketplace. For example, by undertaking a oping such mechanisms.
virtual real estate tour, a prospective buyer may be able to
reduce the consideration set to a smaller and manageable Buyer and Buying
number. The electronic marketplace also facilitates trial Environment Characteristics
and/or sampling of digital/digitizable products (e.g., the and Competitive Strategy
first chapter of a book, the basic version of a video game,
or selected clips from a soon-to-be-released CD/DVD) at Significant changes are occurring in buyers and the
a considerably lower cost to the firm vis-?~-vis the physi- buying environment as a result of the increasing reliance of
cal marketplace. In certain instances, facilitating product buyers and sellers on the emerging electronic marketplace.
trial in the electronic marketplace may allow a firm to of- For instance, Haubl and Trifts (2000) noted that the avail-
fer to prospective buyers the option of trying its complete ability of sophisticated interactive decision aids in online
product offering prior to making a purchase decision buying environments is likely to alter how consumers
(e.g., free trial of software for preparation of personal in- search for product information and make purchase deci-
come tax returns and seeking payment only when the user sions. Research by Lynch and Ariely (2000) shows that
is ready to print or electronically file a copy of the com- lowering buyers' search cost for information on product
pleted tax return). quality is conducive to lowering buyers' price sensitivity
Varadarajan, Yadav/ STRATEGYAND THE INTERNET 307

TABLE 2
The Evolving Hybrid Marketplace and Associated Changes in the Buying Environment
Characteristic of the Buying Environment Physical Marketplace Physical and Electronic Marketplace
Principal sourcesof information Traditionalwordof mouth(WOM)and ElectronicWOM and new mediaa
mass media
Sourcesof credible/neutralinformation Few Many
Amountof informationavailableto buyersabout
price and nonpriceattributesof competingproductofferings Limited Extensive
Informationasymmetrybetweensellerand buyer Considerable Diminishing
Buyerrelianceon proxies(e.g., brand name) in the absence
of objectiveinformationon productquality Considerable Diminishing
Ease of informationsearch Greaterb
Qualityof information Better
Organizationand structuringof information Better
Ease of comparingand evaluatingalternativesin the
buyer's considerationset Greater
a. In additionto traditionalwordof mouthand mass media.
b. Relativeto the physicalmarketplace,an informationsearchcanbe donewithgreatereasein thehybridphysicalandelectronicmarketplace.Otheritems
that followshouldbe interpretedsimilarly.

when products are differentiated. Such efforts serve to characterized by heterogeneous buyer preferences and
highlight sellers' need to adapt to changes in buyers' infor- product characteristics. Hotelling's (1929) work modeling
mation search and buying behavior as a consequence of choice in differentiated markets suggests that sellers are
changes occurring in the buying environment. Table 2 pro- able to increase prices when (1) consumers' search costs
vides an overview of changes in the buying environment as increase and/or (2) consumers' perceived costs associated
the competitive landscape shifts from a predominantly with not selecting the "ideal" product increase.
physical marketplace to a physical and electronic market- Using the broad framework of information economics,
place. As indicated in this table, every stage of buyers' Bakos (1991, 1997) examined the implications of dimin-
decision-making process--search, simplification of the ishing search costs in the electronic marketplace. The gen-
choice set, evaluation, and final choice--is likely to be eral finding is that reduced search costs lead to increased
affected as the role played by the Internet increases. The price competition between sellers and, consequently,
nature of these changes and their implications for competi- lower average prices. Bakos (1997) made a distinction
tive strategy are discussed next. between search costs associated with price information
and nonprice information (e.g., product attributes related
Diminishing information search costs. Beginning with to product quality). While declining search costs associ-
Stigler's (1961) seminal analysis, search costs have been ated with price information increase pricing pressures on
recognized as an important determinant of buyers' decision- sellers, declining search costs associated with nonprice
making process in the marketplace. Information econom- information dampen pricing pressures on sellers.
ics, which examines consumer behavior under conditions Surviving and prospering in an environment character-
of incomplete price knowledge in imperfectly competitive ized by declining search costs will require considerable
markets, assumes that consumers are aware of price dis- skill and new thinking on part of the firms. As noted above,
persion in the marketplace and that they engage in price it appears likely that there will be increased industry-level
search as they seek a lower asking price. This search pro- pricing pressures. However, even in this environment,
cess is subject to diminishing returns, and an optimal ter- there will be opportunities to preserve (and perhaps even
mination of the search is determined by equating marginal increase) profit margins. Profit margins may be preserved
search costs with marginal returns of search. by cutting costs, segmenting the market more astutely and
It has been shown that in commodity markets (at equi- precisely, and implementing price discrimination and
librium), sellers charge the same price---one that would dynamic pricing that more effectively capture consumers'
have been charged by a monopolist (Salop and Stiglitz surplus. The analysis presented by Bakos (1997) suggests
1977). In such markets, even a modest increase in search that facilitating consumers' access to the type and amount
costs enables sellers to increase prices and profits. When of nonprice information disseminated in the marketplace
buyers' search costs vary in commodity markets, a mixed- can reduce pricing pressures. Of course, the effectiveness
price equilibrium may result (i.e., both low-price and high- of this approach is likely to vary considerably across firms
price sellers emerge). Differentiated markets are (depending on the specifics of nonprice information that is
308 JOURNALOF THE ACADEMYOF MARKETINGSCIENCE FALL2002

disseminated by an individual firm). Firms that can make increased participation in the electronic marketplace cre-
credible claims regarding the superiority of their nonprice ates cost transparency--that is, it enables buyers to infer
attributes will be able to combat pricing pressures more (among other things) sellers' cost-related information. In-
effectively than other firms. creased participation in the electronic marketplace leads to
more exposure to price information, which, in turn, may
Diminishing information asymmetry. An exchange is
provide clues about costs. As discussed above, informa-
viewed as characterized by information asymmetry when
tion asymmetry regarding quality enables sellers to offer
the parties participating in the exchange are unequally in-
branded products that seek to reduce buyers' uncertainty.
formed about pertinent details regarding the exchange. For
Buyers may be willing to pay a premium for this reduction
example, while a buyer may learn about the quality of a
in uncertainty, but the magnitude of this premium cannot
product after it is purchased, the seller may have access to
be judged fully unless buyers have access to firms' cost-
this information prior to the exchange. Markets character-
related information. Once the magnitude of this premium
ized by information asymmetry facilitate the emergence of
is ascertained, it can serve as a basis for making assess-
branded products offered at premium prices, ensuring a
ments about price fairness. Access to cost information also
certain level of predetermined quality to buyers. Sellers of
enables buyers to evaluate the plausibility of a competi-
branded products charge premium prices that reflect the
tor's claim that its lower priced product is comparable in
higher production costs (if any) and also "yield a normal
quality to an incumbent's offering. Thus, by facilitating
rate of return on the foregone gains from exploiting con-
the entry of credible lower priced competitors, increased
sumers' ignorance" (Klein and Leffler 1981:624). Infor-
cost transparency can spur price competition in the mar-
mation asymmetry also leads to more concentrated
ketplace. Some pricing strategies (e.g., price bundling) can
markets with higher prices because it is difficult for new
partly disguise price (and thus cost) information regarding
entrants (that seek entry by offering lower prices) to make
individual products. However, in the long run, firms must
credible claims pertaining to the quality of their products.
accept the reality of increasing cost transparency. As in the
The likelihood of market concentration increases in product-
case of information asymmetry regarding quality, devel-
markets where experience and credence attributes domi-
oping and offering a superior value proposition to buyers
nate search attributes.
through sustained innovation is perhaps the only effective
To a large extent, information asymmetry results from
strategic response to increasing cost transparency in the
buyers' (a) inability to evaluate a product prior to purchase
marketplace.
and/or (b) inability to access appropriate information due
to high search costs. The emergence of the electronic mar- Changing communication model. Finally, many
ketplace can affect both factors. Buyers not only can learn changes occurring in the buying environment can be
how to evaluate a product (e.g., which attributes are more traced to changes occurring in the underlying communica-
diagnostic of overall quality), but they can also access the tion model. Hoffman and Novak (1996) suggested that the
evaluation of other buyers who may already have pur- traditional one-to-many model of communication (one
chased and used the product (through electronic word of firm transmitting standardized content to segmented buy-
mouth). As a result, information asymmetry can be ers) is being replaced by a many-to-many communication
expected to decline significantly as buyers and sellers model (firms and buyers transmitting customized content
increase their reliance on the electronic marketplace. to each other). One important implication of this change is
Sellers of branded products will be under pressure to jus- that buyers are abandoning the relatively passive role that
tify the price premiums they have traditionally charged in has been traditionally assigned to them in the communica-
the physical marketplace. Justifying and maintaining price tion process. Moving away from being mere recipients of
premiums can be accomplished by making a renewed firm-generated content, buyers are demonstrating a keen
commitment to continuous innovation and by educating interest in developing and exercising greater control over
existing and prospective buyers about the superiority of a the communication they receive and generate.
given product. In segmented markets, firms can explore
According to Hoffman and Novak (1997), this commu-
opportunities to develop a value proposition that justifies a
nication-related shift has profound strategic implications.
premium pricing approach in selected market segments.
Consider increasing electronic word of mouth, for exam-
However, one consequence of declining information
ple, which is just one manifestation of how communica-
asymmetry is that firms wilt have to work considerably
tion patterns are changing in the marketplace. The ease
harder to develop and pursue such premium pricing
with which buyers can spread the word about a firm (both
opportunities.
favorable and unfavorable) has spurred a new type of
Increasing cost transparency. The emergence of the buyer activism. Buyers are sharing experiences with one
electronic marketplace is also affecting information asym- another and, increasingly, expect that firms will pay atten-
metry regarding costs. Sinha (2000) suggested that buyers' tion and respond appropriately. The well-publicized
Varadarajan, Yadav/ STRATEGYAND THE INTERNET 309

design and/or quality problems in Intel's original Pentium the buying environment (e.g., high vs. low informa-
chip (the so-called "floating point" problem, which could tion search costs), and
result in erroneous answers to division problems) were the macro environment in which the firm operates
first revealed in a seemingly innocuous posting on a com- (e.g., legal, political, regulatory, social, cultural,
puter bulletin board. Intel's initial response was to assure economic, and technological factors).
computer buyers that the likelihood of this specific error
was so small that a broad product recall was not warranted. Building on the extant strategy literature and the
Eventually, with negative publicity spiraling out of hand emerging literature on e-commerce, this article advances a
largely due to electronic word of mouth, Intel announced a conceptual framework highlighting the role of the Internet
broad product recall to address this problem. as an enabler and driver of competitive marketing strategy.
Buyers' increasing involvement in the communication As shown in Figure 2 (Box 1), competing in the evolving
process also has implications for how firms conduct need hybrid market environment calls for a broader construal of
assessment studies in the marketplace, design and test new the scope of marketing strategy. Key to such a broader
products, and make marketing mix decisions. Buyer activ- construal is recognizing the potential of the Internet as an
ism can either be a threat (when ignored by an unrespon- enabler of marketing strategy, a strategic tool whose po-
sive firm) or an opportunity (when a responsive firm har- tential is gainfully leveraged to enhance the effectiveness
nesses buyers' ideas and sentiments to address existing of a business's competitive marketing strategy. The link-
problems and develop new initiatives). Indeed, the market- ages from Box 8 (specifically, the information technology
ing concept--a philosophy of putting customers at the dimension of the macro environment) to Box 1 (competi-
center of all of the firm's activities---can be (and should tive strategy) through Boxes 2, 3, 4, and 5 (industry struc-
be) embraced more fully in a communication environment ture, firm-specific skills and resources, product
where a meaningful, more interactive conversation with characteristics, and buyer characteristics and buying envi-
customers becomes possible (Hoffman and Novak 1997). ronment) delineated in Figure 2 serve to highlight the role
Insights gleaned from these conversations can then serve of the Internet as a driver of competitive strategy.
as a basis for determining unmet needs in the marketplace,
obtaining rapid feedback on new product concepts, and Future Research Directions
developing and implementing a more customized market-
ing mix. Further refinement of the proposed conceptual frame-
work and empirical research building on the proposed
framework constitute promising avenues for future re-
CONCLUSION AND FUTURE search. For instance, the change in the competitive land-
RESEARCH DIRECTIONS scape (from a physical marketplace to one encompassing
both the physical and the electronic marketplace) can be
Marketing strategy as a field of study is primarily con- expected to evoke a multiplicity of responses from buyers
cerned with understanding, explaining, and predicting the and sellers. Broadly, these responses can be characterized
marketplace behavior of businesses in the realm of deploy- as follows:
ing marketing resources at their disposal to facilitate the
achievement of competitive advantage and their contex- 1. First-order effects
tual underpinnings. Regardless of whether a business is A. Supply-side effects: Changes in seller behavior
competing in the physical marketplace, electronic market- B. Demand-side effects: Changes in buyer
behavior
place, or both, certain fundamental tenets are likely to en-
2. Second-order effects
dure. Among other factors, businesses are likely to A. Demand-side effects: Effects of changes in
continue to base their competitive strategy decisions on an seller behavior on buyer behavior
analysis and understanding of factors such as the of the B. Supply-side effects: Effects of changes in
following: buyer behavior on seller behavior

9 the industry in which the business competes (e.g., The scope of the article in its present form is largely limited
concentrated vs. fragmented markets), to first-order effects and points to the need for future re-
9 the unique skills and resources of the firm (e.g., su- search focusing on second-order supply-side and demand-
perior alliance management skills and a large cus- side effects. Both cross-sectional and longitudinal investi-
tomer base), gations are needed to empirically examine the relation-
9 the company's product offerings (e.g., goods vs. ships depicted in the proposed conceptual framework. The
services), proposed conceptual framework also serves to highlight
9 the buyers (e.g., businesses vs. households), future research in the following broad areas:
310 JOURNAL OF THE ACADEMY OF MARKETING SCIENCE FALL 2002

1. The impact of the Internet on the drivers of com- ing subsequent time periods to enhance the competitive positional advan-
petitive strategy (i.e., industry structure, firm tages of its present and new product offerings (i.e., Link 3 ~ 1).
characteristics and skills and resources, product It is also conceivable to envision linkages between the drivers of com-
characteristics, and buyer characteristics and the petitive strategy delineated in Figure 1--for instance, heterogeneity of
demand affecting the heterogeneity of supply as a consequence of the
buying environment).
strategic actions of competing businesses in an industry (Link 5 --~ 1 --~4)
2. The performance consequences of changes in
(see Dickson 1992).
the competitive strategies of businesses in re-
In the interest of space, we do not discuss the direct impact of the
sponse to the opportunities afforded by and chal- macro-environmental factors on competitive strategy (Link 8 --4 1).
lenges posed by the evolving hybrid marketplace. However, in a later section, we highlight the impact of macro-environ-
3. A unique and distinctive characteristic of the mental changes (specifically, technological changes related to the emer-
Internet in regard to digital products is its dual gence of the electronic marketplace) on the other drivers of competitive
role as both a distribution channel and a promo- strategy delineated in Figures 1 and 2.
tion channel. In contrast, for the most part, the 2. Resource deployment activities related to Items 1 to 3 can be la-
distribution and promotional channels for mar- beled broadly as sustaining innovations (Christensen and Overdorf 2000)
keting of goods in the physical marketplace are in that they seek improve the effectiveness of existing organizational pro-
distinct. Extant literature focusing on issues re- cesses and strategies. Disruptive innovations refer to developments that
suggest fundamentally new ways of competing, frequently involving
lating to distribution and promotion has also, for
new organizational processes and strategies. A wide variety of initiatives
the most part, evolved as distinct streams. by new entrants in the business-to-consumer sector (e.g., eBay.com,
Against this backdrop, exploration of issues and Pricehne.com) and in the business-to-business sector (e.g., Freemarkets.
questions pertaining to the use of the Internet as com) highlight the disruptive opportunities available in this regard. In-
both a distribution and promotion channel for cumbent firms also have shown a keen interest in developing such initia-
digital products constitutes a promising avenue tives (e.g., Covisint, an ambitious business-to-business [B2B] initiative
for future research. in the automotive sector that is cosponsored by prominent incumbents
4. For legacy businesses in particular, competing in such as Ford, General Motors, and DaimlerChrysler). While we make
the evolving hybrid marketplace implies effec- references to such developments where appropriate, a comprehensive
tive and seamless integration of the business's discussion of disruptive innovations in the context of the electronic mar-
ketplace is beyond the scope of this article.
interface with its customers in the physical and
3. In regard to the discussion pertaining to digital primary~ligital
the electronic marketplace. Although our focus complementary products presented here, we gratefully acknowledge the
here was limited to marketing strategy content- insights shared by Dr. Venkatesh Shankar.
related issues, we nevertheless recognize the The authors are grateful to Dr. Tom Ingram for sharing his insights on
importance of strategy formulation process and this issue.
implementation effectiveness-related issues
from the standpoint of competing in the evolving
hybrid marketplace and the attendant need for REFERENCES
future research.
Abell, Derek E 1980. Defining the Business: The Starting Pointof Strate-
gic Planning. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice Hall.
Ackerlof, George. 1970. "The Market for 'Lemons': Quality Uncertainty
NOTES and the Market Mechanism." QuarterlyJournal of Economics 84 (3):
488-500.
1. In the interest of completeness, the links relating to both drivers Adam, Nabil and Yelena Yesha. 1996. "Strategic Directions in Electronic
and outcomes of competitive strategy are shown in Figure 1. However, Commerce and Digital Libraries: Towards a Digital Agora." ACM
our primary focus here is on the drivers. In Figure 1, with the exception of Computing Surveys 28 (4): 818-835.
firm characteristics (Box 3), all other boxes are shown at the business unit Alba, Joseph, John Lynch, Barton Weitz, Chris Janiszewski, Richard
level. The underlying rationale is that in the case of a multibusiness firm, Lutz, Alan Sawyer, and Stacy Wood. 1997. "Interactive Home Shopping:
the unique skills and resources of a firm deployed to compete in a particu- Consumer, Retailer, and Manufacturer Incentives to Participate in
Electronic Marketplaces." Journal of Marketing 61 (July): 38-53.
lar business arena are also the unique skills and resources of the focal
Bain, Joseph. 1956. Barriers to Competition. Cambridge, MA: Harvard
business. Collectively, the variables enumerated in Boxes 2, 3, and 4 University Press.
denote "supply-side drivers," and those enumerated in Box 5 denote Bakos, J. Yannis. 1991. "A Strategic Analysis of Electronic Market-
"demand-side drivers." places." M1S Quarterly 15 (September): 295-310.
While our primary focus here is on selected drivers of competitive 9 1997. "Reducing Buyer Search Costs: Implications for
strategy (Links 2 ~ l, 3 --* 1,4 ~ 1, and 5 ~ 1), it should be noted that ef- Electronic Marketplaces." Management Science 43 (December):
fects m the opposite direction are also conceivable. For instance, a bus~- 676-692.
ness's competitive strategy can affect the structure of the industry in Balasubramanian, Sridhar, Vish V. Krishnan, and Mohanbir Sawhney.
2000. "New Offering Realization in the Networked Digital Environ-
which it competes (i.e., Link 1 --* 2) when efficiency differences between ment." In Digital Marketing. Eds. Vijay Mahajan and Jerry Wind.
competitors in an industry lead to the exit of marginal competitors, and New York: John Wiley, 310-338.
the number and size of competitors in an industry are affected. Link I --4 3 Barney, Jay B. 1991. "Firm Resources and Sustained Competitive Ad-
is affected when the strategy pursued by a business leads to the firm accu- vantage." Journal of Management 17 (1): 99-120.
mulating certain valuable resources (e.g., brand equity, customer equity, - - . 1996. Gainingand Sustaining CompetitiveAdvantage. Reading,
and channel equity) and skills (e.g., product innovation and brand posi- MA: Addison-Wesley.
tioning skills). These resources are likely to be leveraged by the firm dur- Barrett, S. and B. Konsynski. 1982. "Inter-Organization Information
Sharing Systems?' MIS Quarterly 6:93-105.
Varadarajan, Yadav / STRATEGY AND THE INTERNET 311

Benjamin, Robert and Rolf Wigand. 1995. "Electronic Markets and Vir- Hofer, Charles W. and Dan Schendel. 1978. Strategy Formulation: Ana-
tual Chains on the Information Superhighway?' Sloan Management lytical Concepts. St. Paul, MN: West.
Review 36 (2): 62-72. Hoffman, Donna L. and Thomas P. Novak. 1996. "Marketing in
Berger, Paul D. and Nada I. Nasr. 1998. "Customer Lifetime Value: Mar- Hypermedia Computer-Mediated Environments: Conceptual Foun-
keting Models and Applications." Journal of Interactive Marketing dations." Journal of Marketing 60 (3): 50-68.
12 (1): 17-30. - - and - - - . 1997. "A New Marketing Paradigm for Electromc
Blattberg, Robert C. and John Deighton. 1991. "Interactive Marketing: Commerce." Information Society 13 (1): 43-54.
Exploiting the Age of Addressability." Sloan Management Review 33 Hotelling, Harold. 1929. "Stability in Competition." Economic Journal
(1): 5-14. 39:41-57.
Brynjolfsson, Erik and Abraham Seidmann. 1997. "A Call for Explora- Huber, George P. 1990. "A Theory of the Effects of Advanced Informa-
tion: Introduction to Special Issue on Frontier Research on Informa- tion Technologies on Organizational Design, Intelligence, and Deci-
tion Systems and Economics." Management Science 43 (12): 1605- sion Making?' Academy of Management Review 15:47-71.
1607. Hunt, Shelby D. 2000. A General Theory of Competition. Thousand
Burke, Raymond. 1996. "Virtual Shopping: Breakthrough in Marketing Oaks, CA: Sage.
Research?' Harvard Business Review 74 (March/April): 120-131. Katz, Michael L. and Carl Shapiro. 1985. "Network Externalities, Com-
--. 1997. "Do You See What I See? The Future of Virtual petition, and Compatibility." The American Economic Review 75
Shopping." Journal of the Academy of Marketing Science 25 (Fall): (June): 424-440.
352-360. Keep, William W., Stanley C. Hollander, and Roger Dickson. 1998.
Cairncross, Frances. 1997. The Death of Distance: How the Communica- "Forces Impinging on Long-Term Business-to-Business Relation-
tion Revolution Will Change Our Lives. Boston: Harvard Business ships in the United States: An Historical Perspective" Journal of
School Press. Marketing 62 (2): 31-45.
Christensen, Clayton M. and Michael Overdorf. 2000. "Meeting the Klein, Benjamin and Keith B. Leffler. 1981. "The Role of Market Forces
Challenge of Disruptive Change." Harvard Business Review 78 in Assuring Contractual Performance." Journal of Political Economy
(March-April): 221-230. 89 (4): 615-642.
Clark, David D. 1996. "Adding Service Discrimination to the Internet." Levitt, Theodore. 1981. "Marketing Intangible Products and Product In-
Telecommunications Policy 20 (3): 169-181. tangibles?' Harvard Business Review 59 (3): 94-102.
Darby, Michael R. and Edi Karni. 1973. "Free Competition and the Opti- Lynch, John and Dan Ariely. 2000. "Wine Online: Search Costs and
mal Amount of Fraud?' Journal of Law and Economics 16 (April): Competition on Price, Quality, and Distribution?' Marketing Science
67-88. 19 (1): 83-103.
D'Aveni, Richard A. 1999. "Strategic Supremacy Through Disruption Malone, Thomas W. 1997. "Is Empowerment Just a Fad? Control, Deci-
and Dominance?' Sloan Management Review 40 (3): 127-135. sion Making, and IT." Sloan Management Review 38 (2): 23-35.
Dickson, Peter R. 1992. "Toward a General Theory of Competitive Ratio- - - , JoAnne Yates, and Robert I. Benjamin. 1989. "The Logic of
nality." Journal of Marketing 56 (1): 69-84. Electronic Markets." Harvard Business Review 67 (May/June):
166-172.
- - and Alan G. Sawyer. 1990. "The Price Knowledge and Search of
Supermarket Shoppers." Journal of Consumer Research 54 (July): Mayntz, Renate and Thomas P. Hughes. 1988. The Development of Large
Technical Systems. Boulder, CO: Westview.
42-53.
Nelson, Philip. 1970. "Information and Consumer Behavior." Journal of
Douglas, Susan. 1991. "Broadcasting Begins." In Communications in
Political Economy 78 (March/April): 311-329.
History: Technology, Culture, and Society. Eds. David Crowley and
Oliver, Jim R. 1996. "A Machine-Learning Approach to Automated Ne-
Paul Heyer. New York: Longman, 190-197.
gotiation and Prospects for Electronic Commerce." Journal of Man-
Economides, Nicholas and Frederick Flyer. 1998. "Compatibility and
agement Information Systems 13 (3): 83-112.
Market Structure for Network Goods." Working Paper EC-98-02.
Peppers, Don, Martha Rogers, and Bob Dorf. 1999. "Is Your Company
Stern School of Business, New York University.
Ready for One-to-One Marketing?" Harvard Business Review 77
Eisenhardt, Kathleen M. and Jeffrey A. Martin. 2000. "Dynamic Capa- (January/February): 151-160.
bilities: What Are They?" Strategic Management Journal 21 ( 10-11):
Peterson, Robert A., Sridhar Balasubramanian, and Bart J.
1 1 0 5 - 1 1 2 1 .
Bronnenberg. 1997. "Exploring the Implications of the Internet for
Farrell, Joseph and Garth Saloner. 1985. "Standardization, Compatibil- Consumer Marketing." Journal of the Academy of Marketing Sci-
ity, and Innovation?'Rand Journal of Economics 16 (Spring): 70-83. ence 25 (Fall): 329-346.
- - and . 1986. "Installed Base and Compatibility: Innova- Porter, Michael E. 2001. "Strategy and the Internet?' Harvard Business
tion, Product Preannouncements, and Predation." American Eco- Review 79 (3): 63-78.
nomic Review 76 (December): 940-955. - - and Victor E. Millar. 1985. "How Information Gives You Com-
Fidler, Roger. 1997. Mediamorphosis: Understanding the New Media. petitive Advantage?' Harvard Business Review 63 (July-August):
Thousand Oaks, CA: Pine Forge Press. 149-160.
Frank, Robert H. and Philip J. Cook. 1995. The Winner-Take-All Society. Prahalad, C. K. and Gary Hamel. 1990. "The Core Competence of the
New York: Free Press. Corporation?' Harvard Business Review 68 (May-June): 79-91.
Glazer, Rashi. 1991. "Marketing in an Information-Intensive Environ- Rao, Akshay R. and Mark E. Bergen. 1992. "Price Premium Variations as
ment: Strategic Implications of Knowledge as an Asset." Journal of a Consequence of Buyers' Lack of Information." Journal of Con-
Marketing 55 (October): 1-19. sumer Research 19 (December): 412-423.
Grewal, Raj, James A. Comer, and Raj Mehta. 2001. "An Investigation Rayport, Jeffrey E and John J. Sviokla. 1994. "Managing in the
Into the Antecedents of Organizational Participation in Business-to- Marketspace." Harvard Business Review 72 (November/December):
Business Electronic Markets." Journal of Marketing 65 (July): 17-33. 141-150.
Gupta, Sunil and Rabikar Chatterjee. 1997. "Consumer and Corporate Salop, Steven C. and Joseph Stiglitz. 1977. "Bargains and Ripoffs: A
Adoptton of the World Wide Web as a Commercial Medium." In Model of Monopolitlcally Competitive Price Dispersion?' Review of
Electronic Marketing and the Consumer. Ed. Robert A. Peterson. Economics and Statistics 54 (December): 493-510.
Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage, 123-138. Shapiro, Carl and Hal R. Varian. 1999. Information Rules: A Strategic
Gurbaxani, Vijay and Seungjin Whang. 199 l. "The Impact of Informa- Guide to the Network Economy. Cambridge, MA: Harvard Business
tion Systems on Organizations and Markets." Communications of the School Press.
ACM 34 (January): 59-73. Shostack, G. Lynn. 1977. "Breaking Free From Product Marketing."
Hanson, Ward. 1998. "The Original WWW: Web Lesson From the Early Journal of Marketing 41 (April): 73-80.
Days of Radio." Journal of Interactive Marketing 12 (3): 46-56. Sinha, Indrajit. 2000. "Cost Transparency: The Net's Real Threat to
Haubl, Gerald and Valerie Trifts. 2000. "Consumer Decision Making in Prices and Brands." Harvard Business Review 78 (March-April): 3-8.
Online Shopping Environments: The Effects of Interactive Decision Steuer, Jonathan. 1992. "Defining Virtual Reality: Dimensions Deter-
Aids?' Marketing Science 19 (1): 4-21. mine Telepresence?' Journal of Communication 42 (Autumn): 73-93.
3l2 JOURNAL OF THE ACADEMY OF MARKETING SCIENCE FALL 2002

Stigler, George J. 1961. "The Economics of Information." Journal of Po- related issues has been published in the Journal of Marketing,
litical Economy 69 (June): 213-225. Journal of the Academy of Marketing Science, Academy of Man-
Tapscott, Don. 1996. Digital Economy: Promise and Peril in the Age of
Networked Intelligence. New York: McGraw-Hill. agement Journal, Strategic Management Journal, and other lead-
Teece, David J., Gary Pisano, and Amy Shuen. 1997. "Dynamic Capabil- ing journals. He is coauthor of a textbook titled Contemporar?;
ities and Strategic Management" Strategic ManagementJournal 18 Perspectives on Strategic Market Planning. Dr. Varadarajan
(7): 509-533. served as editor of the Journal of Marketing from 1993 to 1996.
Urbany, Joel. 1986. "An Experimental Examination of the Economics
of Information?' Journal of Consumer Research 13 (September): He currently serves on the Board of Governors of the Academy of
257-271. Marketing Science and as editor of the Journal of the Academy of
, Peter R. Dickson, and William L. Wilkie. 1989. "Buyer Uncer- Marketing Science.
tainty and Information Search." Journal of Consumer Research 16
(September): 208-215. M a n j i t S. Yadav is an associate professor of marketing and
Webster, Frederick E., Jr. and YoramWind. 1972. OrganizationalBuying
Behavior. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice Hall. Mays Faculty Fellow, Department of Marketing, Mays Business
Weill, Peter and Marianne Broadbent. 1998. Leveraging the New Infra- School, Texas A&M University. He obtained his Ph.D. in mar-
structure: How Market Leaders Capitalize on Information Technol- keting from Virginia Tech. His research focuses on electronic
ogy. Boston: Harvard Business School Press. commerce, firms' pricing strategies, and consumers' price per-
Yadav, Manjit S. and Rajan Varadarajan. 2001. "Interactivity in the Elec- ceptions. He has published in a number of journals, including
tronic Marketplace: An Exposition of the Concept and Its Implica-
tions for Product Migration." Working Paper. Department of Journal of Marketing Research, Journal of Consumer Research,
Marketing, Texas A&M University. Journal of the Academy of Marketing Science, and Sloan Man-
agement Review. He is a member of the Editorial Review Board
of the Journal of the Academy of Marketing Science. At Texas
ABOUTTHEAUTHORS A&M, Dr. Yadav developed and currently teaches a graduate
course (Strategic Foundations of E-Commerce) dealing with the
P. Rajah Varadarajan is a distinguished professor of marketing strategic challenges and opportunities in the emerging electronic
and the Ford chair in marketing and e-commerce in the Mays marketplace. He served as cochair of the American Marketing
Business School at Texas A&M University. His research and Association's 2001 Faculty Consortium on Electronic Com-
teaching interests are in the areas of strategy and e-commerce. merce held at Texas A&M University.
His research on corporate, business, and marketing strategy-

Das könnte Ihnen auch gefallen