Sie sind auf Seite 1von 8

Macroeconomics, History of up to 1933

Robert W Dimand, Brock University, St. Catharines, ON, Canada


2015 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.

Abstract

The eld that became known as macroeconomics emerged from long and rich traditions of monetary theory, business cycle
analysis, and discussion of economic growth. Macroeconomics is the analysis of aggregate levels and rates of change of output
and employment, the price level (and its inverse, the purchasing power of money), the interest rate, and the balance of
payments. This eld had a long history before it received its name with Ragnar Frischs (1933) distinction between mac-
rodynamics and microdynamics and before John Maynard Keynes General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money
(1936). This article analyzes the prehistory of the concept the various strands of economic thinking that coalesced in about
1933 to produce modern macroeconomics, i.e., roughly the history of macroeconomics up to Keynes. The subsequent history
is covered in a companion article, Macroeconomics, history of, from 1933 to the present.

Macroeconomics, the analysis of aggregate levels and rates of cycles, oscillations with more or less regularity in amplitude
change of output and employment, the price level (and its and periodicity, producing a vast literature sampled by
inverse, the purchasing power of money), the interest rate, and D.P. OBrien (1999), Harald Hagemann (2001), and
the balance of payments had a long history before the eld Mauro Boianovsky (2005), and leading to the creation in the
received its name with Ragnar Frischs (1933) distinction interwar period of business cycle research institutes such as
between macrodynamics and microdynamics and before John the National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER)
Maynard Keynes General Theory of Employment, Interest and (Mitchell, 1927; Kondratiev, 1997; Glasner, 1997). Histories
Money (1936). of crisis theories, and particularly of theories of periodic
crises, have been published as early as E. von Bergmann
(1895) and Edward D. Jones (1900), with histories of the
Prehistory phenomenon of crises going back to M. Wirth (1858).
Thirdly, Franois Quesnays Physiocratic Tableau conomique,
Three currents of analysis and discussion, overlapping tracing the circular ow of spending and income in the
but distinguishable, emerged on subjects later considered economy as whole, was followed by the magnicent
macroeconomics, coalescing in the 1930s. The theory of dynamics of classical economists such as David Ricardo,
money and prices began with the quantity theory of money Thomas Robert Malthus, and John Stuart Mill, exploring the
as an explanation of the Price Revolution of the sixteenth paths of population, production, and wage and prot rates as
century and of balance of payments adjustment under the a growing economy approached a stationary state (Eltis,
gold standard (Grice-Hutchison, 1952; Locke, 1991; 1984; Davis, 2005; Brewer, 2010), with the beginnings of
Gervaise, 1720; Hume, 1752; Christiernin, 1761; Monroe, formal algebraic models of economic growth sketched by
1923; Hegeland, 1951; Vickers, 1959; Guggenheim, 1989), J.C.L. Simonde de Sismondi and developed in Karl Marxs
was extended to inconvertible paper currency during the schemes of simple and expanded reproduction (Arthur and
French Revolution and Napoleonic Wars (Thornton, 1802; Reuten, 1998) and a false dawn of modern growth theory in
Murphy, 2009; Arnon, 2011), debated Jean-Baptiste Says with Allyn Young (1928) on increasing returns to scale and
law of markets and the possibility of a general glut of economic growth, Frank Ramsey (1928) on optimal capital
commodities at the end of the Napoleonic Wars (Sowell, accumulation, and Grigorii Feldman (1928) on the growth
1972; Link, 1959; Corry, 1962; Green, 1992; Baumol, rate in a planned economy.
1999; Davis, 2005), and achieved analytical sophistication These extensive pre-1933 contributions to what would
during the Banking SchoolCurrency SchoolFree Banking later be called macroeconomics raised issues that resonate in
School debates (Fetter, 1965; OBrien, 2007), culminating in later macroeconomics (as the terms New Classical and New
Walter Bagehots treatment of the lender of last resort in Keynesian indicate, as do Divisia monetary aggregates
Lombard Street (1873) and then in the contributions in the (Franois Divisia, 1925), Ricardian equivalence, Schumpe-
1890s by Alfred Marshall, Irving Fisher, and Knut Wicksell, terian creative destruction). The work of Milton Friedman and
the three theorists appropriately pictured on the cover of his students revived the quantity theory tradition (see
David Laidlers The Golden Age of the Quantity Theory (1991a); Friedman, 1956). Michael Woodfords Interest and Prices
the interwar ourishing of monetary analysis of saving (2003) harks back to the analysis of a pure credit economy in
investment adjustment (Eshag, 1963; Bridel, 1987; Jonung, Knut Wicksells Interest and Prices (1898). Christopher Sims
1991; Laidler, 1999; Dimand, 2003; and sources reprinted vector autoregression (VAR) approach to modeling economic
in Wood and Capie, 2000). A second approach, brought to uctuations without assuming too much a priori knowledge
prominence by Clment Juglar (1862) and W. Stanley Jevons of the underlying model is, with more modern statistical
(1884), viewed that uctuations in production and prices are techniques, in the spirit of Wesley Mitchells NBER statistical

406 International Encyclopedia of the Social & Behavioral Sciences, 2nd edition, Volume 14 http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/B978-0-08-097086-8.03058-0
Macroeconomics, History of up to 1933 407

approach to business cycles, starting with time series analysis analyze the automatic restoration of international payment
of uctuations rather than with theoretical models (an equilibrium and critique the mercantilist obsession with
approach that produces the concept of leading indicators). a balance of trade surplus, holding that in the long run a change
Irving Fisher, although spectacularly mistaken about whether in the quantity of money will cause prices and money wages to
stock prices had reached a permanently high plateau in change in the same proportion, and the money supply will be
October 1929, shaped macroeconomic analysis and practice distributed across countries in proportion to the demand for
through the Fisher equation relating real and nominal real money balances in each country. In Humes pricespecie
interest, the Fisher diagram for intertemporal consumption ow mechanism, mercantilist interventions, using tariffs and
smoothing, indexed bonds, distributed lags, the Fisher ideal quotas on imports, regulations, bounties on exports, and
index number (the geometric mean of the Paasche and Las- monopolies on colonial trade to increase the quantity of
peyres indexes), and, especially since the credit crunches of money in a country through a trade surplus would, in the long
2007 and 2008, his debt deation theory of depressions (see run, just raise prices in the home country and lower prices in its
e.g., Korinek and Mendoza, 2013), with Ralph G. Hawtreys trading partners, reducing net exports until equilibrium was
concept of a credit deadlock and the MisesHayek Austrian restored. In the short run, an increase in the quantity of money
trade cycle theory also attracting renewed attention. Central would give a temporary stimulus to economic activity until
bank responses to the credit crunch were informed by the fact prices and wages fully adjusted (see Filippo Cesarano, 2007;
that Ben Bernanke of the Federal Reserve, in his doctoral Arie Arnon, 2011; Dimand, 2013). The specie (gold and silver)
dissertation, and Mervyn King of the Bank of England, in his that owed into Spain from its empire in the New World
European Economic Association presidential address, had owed out again in trade. In Adam Smiths critique of
studied the US debt deation of the early 1930s, with close mercantilism, closer than Humes of the twentieth century
attention to Fisher (1933), just as monetary policy decisions monetary approach to the balance of payments, the terms of
at the Bundesbank and then at the European Central Bank trade would not change for a country that, like Scotland, was
were informed by acquaintance with the literature small enough to be a price taker in world markets (Humphrey,
surrounding the German hyperination of the early 1920s 1993; Laidler, 2003: Chapter 1; Arnon, 2011). If mercantilist
(including Keynes, 1923). Macroeconomics did not begin in interventions articially increased the quantity of money in
1933 or 1936, although certainly Keynes (1936) provided a country, the resulting excess supply of money would be spent
a transformative focus on the equilibrium level of aggregate on imports and on exportable goods (and on foreign lending),
output and employment rather than on prices and cycles. causing the gold and silver to ow out of the country again,
until the world money supply was distributed in proportion to
demand for real money balances, with money supply equal to
The Theory of Money and Prices money demand in each country.
Although John Law had experimented with inconvertible
European prices roughly quadrupled from 1530 to 1600, as paper currency in France until the collapse of Laws system in
was documented for English prices by Bishop William 1720, David Hume, Adam Smith, and their contemporaries
Fleetwood (1707), pioneer of price history and of quantica- analyzed price and payments adjustment under a metallic
tion of changes in the purchasing power of money (but because standard, with gold and silver coin and bullion circulating
the commodity prices examined by Fleetwood all changed in (see Murphy, 2009, on Law). Following a bank run sparked by
roughly the same proportion, he did not have to consider reports of a French invasion, conversion on demand of Bank
appropriate weights in a price index). This Price Revolution of England notes into specie was suspended from 1797 to
occasioned the emergence of the quantity theory of money, 1821. Henry Thornton, the Bullion Committee of the House
described by Mark Blaug (in Blaug et al., 1995) as the oldest of Commons, and David Ricardo extended the quantity
surviving theory in economics and by David Laidler (1991b) theory of money to inconvertible paper, conclusively estab-
as always and everywhere controversial. Martin Navarro de lishing that the rise in British prices during the Napoleonic
Azpilcueta of the University of Salamanca, writing in Latin in Wars and the high price of bullion on the Hamburg market
1556, and the French political theorist Jean Bodin in 1568 (when purchased with Bank of England notes) resulted from
attributed the rise in European prices to the rise in the same the increase in the Bank of Englands note issue, an analysis
proportion of the quantity of money circulating in Europe, due that failed to convince either the Banks directors or the
to the inow of gold and especially silver to Spain from Mexico majority in the House of Commons (Thornton, 1802; Hayek,
and Upper Peru (now Bolivia) and to increased output of [1931]1991; Viner, 1937; de Boyer des Roches, 2003; Davis,
European silver mines (see Marjorie Grice-Hutchison, 1952 on 2005; Arnon, 2011). The Bank directors insisted that they
the Salamanca School, and Arthur E. Monroe, 1923 and Hugo could not overissue notes as long as they only discounted real
Hegeland, 1951 on Bodin). Azpilcueta and the other Sala- bills of exchange to accommodate the needs of trade, forget-
manca writers were the last phase of a medieval scholastic ting that the nominal volume of trade would grow as prices
tradition that included Nicole Oresmes analysis around 1360 increased. The directors invoked the authority of Adam Smith
of how the princes seigniorage from debasement of the for this real bills doctrine, even though Smiths analysis had
coinage took purchasing power away from the public (Oresme dealt with bank notes that were convertible into coin on
et al., 1989), a discussion that drew in turn on Aristotles demand. Similarly, John Law had argued in 1705 that a land
remarks on the functions of money. Isaac Gervaise (1720), bank could not overissue notes as long as the notes were
Richard Cantillon, P.N. Christiernin (1761), and, above all, created by lending with land as security, overlooking the
David Hume (1752) used the quantity theory of money to endogeneity of the price of land.
408 Macroeconomics, History of up to 1933

At the end of the Napoleonic Wars, the sharp reduction in presentation of the quantity theory of money and the price
military spending, availability of cheaper grain imports from specie ow mechanism, Currency School writers such as J.R.
Continental Europe and the United States, and the contraction McCulloch, G.W. Norman, and Lord Overstone urged that
of the note issue as the Bank of England moved toward resto- the Bank of England should act so that a mixed paper and
ration of convertibility at the prewar parity combined to metallic currency would behave like a metallic currency (for
produce industrial and agricultural depression in Britain. The instance, a 100% marginal reserve requirement on note
classical theory of rent and of comparative advantage emerged issue), and should manage the volume of currency to prevent
from the classical critique of the Corn Laws, the protectionist gold outows. The Currency School, whose ideas shaped Sir
reaction to the agricultural depression. Thomas Robert Malthus Robert Peels Bank of 1844, attributed banking crises to
and J.C.L. Simonde de Sismondi attributed the industrial mismanagement by the Bank of England. Banking School
depression to a general glut of commodities, an insufciency of writers such as Thomas Tooke and John Fullarton
effective demand. David Ricardo, James Mill, and Jean-Baptiste emphasized the endogeneity of credit, with the volume of
Say held that such a general glut was impossible, because credit more likely to react to changes in prices than to cause
people only supply goods, services, and assets because they them, and with the quantity of banknotes demand-
wish to acquire other goods, services, and assets, so that the determined. Rather than expecting the Bank of England to be
industrial depression was a transitional problem, as wage and able to prevent gold drains by varying the discount rate, the
price signals shifted factors of production from producing Banking School wished the Bank to hold a large enough
commodities in demand during wartime to producing bullion reserve to accommodate temporary balance of
commodities in demand during peacetime (Link, 1959; Corry, payments uctuations without unsettling credit markets.
1962; Patinkin, 1965; Sowell, 1972; Green, 1992; Hollander, These debates in monetary theory culminated in Walter
1997; Davis, 2005). The problem of transition was not Bagehots Lombard Street (1873), the classic account of how
considered by the classical economists as something to be the central bank should act as lender of last resort to preserve
ignored Say endorsed public works to provide employment the liquidity of the banking system, rather than acting as an
during the transition, whereas Ricardo wished to restore ordinary bank to maximize the prots of its shareholders.
convertibility at the depreciated value of notes rather than the
prewar parity but it was a temporary, short-run issue, resulting
from a change in the mix of commodities demanded, not from 1886 and All That
a shortfall of demand in general. Following a tradition going
back to Aristotles invocation of the myth of King Midas, The Royal Commission on the Depression of Trade and
Ricardo, Say, and James and John Stuart Mill held that people Industry (Northcote, 1886: p. x) reported that the trade and
sell commodities for money intending to use the money as industry of the country are in a condition that may be fairly
a medium of exchange, not with the hoarding of money as the described as depressed; that by this depression is meant
ultimate goal. In the debate over what Keynes was to call Says a diminution, and in some cases, an absence of prot, with
law of markets (see Baumol, 1999), (aggregate) supply creates a corresponding diminution of employment for the laboring
its own (aggregate) demand, the classical economists (in classes; that neither the volume of trade nor the amount of
Keynes sense of classical as accepting some form of Says Law) capital invested therein has materially fallen off, though the
tried to say something stronger than what Oskar Lange (1942) latter has in many cases depreciated in value; that the depres-
later termed Says Equality (the value of excess demand sums to sion above referred to dates from about the year 1875, and that,
zero in equilibrium over all markets other than money that is, with the exception of a short period of prosperity enjoyed by
the truism that the value of aggregate excess demand is zero if certain branches of trade in the years 1880 to 1883, it has
excess demand is zero in each market), but weaker than what proceeded with tolerable uniformity. The same year, the rst
Lange termed Says Identity (the value of excess demand sums annual report of the US Commissioner of Labor was on
to zero over all markets except money, at any set of prices, Industrial Depressions (Wright, 1886; Barnett, 1941). Lecturing in
market clearing, or otherwise which, together with Walras Scotland on Irregularity of Employment and Fluctuations of Prices
Law, implies that the money market always clears for any set of (Foxwell, 1886: pp. 48, 96), Herbert S. Foxwell, professor of
prices). Keynes (1933a, 1936) drew inspiration from Malthus political economy at University College, London (where Knut
emphasis on the concept of effective demand (demand allow- Wicksell attended some of his lectures that year) and a fellow
ing for quantity constraints: if the labor market is in excess and lecturer of St. Johns College, Cambridge, lamented the
supply, unemployed workers cannot spend on goods the wages most serious effect of falling prices. They depress industry and
they would have earned if employed), even though Malthus trade leading to what is of all the many claims of labor, the
failure to distinguish a decision to save from a decision to invest most grave, the most pressing, and the most just, . the claim I
undermined his response to Ricardos analysis. have brought before you to-night, the claim for more regular
The Bank Act of 1844 and the British banking crises of 1825, employment. The literature on depression and
1832, 183637, 1847, and 1857 occasioned the debate unemployment grew until a bibliography on unemployment
between the Currency School and Banking School over the published by the London School of Economics in 1909
appropriate structure and policy of the Bank of England extended to 71 pages (not counting Sidney Webbs
(Viner, 1937; Fetter, 1965; Skaggs, 1999; Laidler, 2003; Introduction). Many shared Foxwells conviction that
OBrien, 2007; Arnon, 2011), with the Free Banking School uctuations in the purchasing power of money caused
denying the need for any legally privileged bank of issue uctuations in employment (although formal economic
acting as a central bank (Smith, 1936). Drawing on Ricardos theory, like Foxwell, was vague on the mechanism connecting
Macroeconomics, History of up to 1933 409

the two phenomena). As Foxwell (1886: p. 52 n) noted, So between spot and forward exchange rates to the difference
long ago as 1856, Mr. William Cross ably advocated between nominal interest rates in two currencies, was added
a monetary standard corrected by means of an index number. by Keynes (1923) (see Flanders, 1989 on developments in
See his Standard Pound v. the Pound Sterling (Aberdeen, 1856). open-economy monetary economics). Modeling expected
Another method for securing the same object has recently ination with a distributed lag of past price level changes,
been proposed by M. Walras (see Lon Walras Thorie de la Fisher (1911: Chapter IV, 1926) attributed uctuations in real
Monnaie, 1886, and Bridel, 1997). Alfred Marshall (1887), economic activity and employment to slow and incomplete
also of St. Johns College, Cambridge, and one of the adjustment of ination expectations to monetary shocks,
witnesses before the Royal Commission, tentatively a phenomenon that in a 1928 book title Fisher termed the
suggested, as a rst step toward stabilizing the purchasing money illusion. Inuenced by Fisher (the only economist he
power of an index number, symmetallism, a monetary unit had read at the time of writing Hawtrey, 1913), Ralph
of a certain amount of gold plus a certain amount of silver, Hawtrey of the British Treasury also advanced a monetary
rather than just one metal, but backed away after Sir Robert theory of the trade cycle (Hawtrey, 1913, 1919, 1932;
Giffen blasted fancy monetary standards that would tamper Deutscher, 1990). From the concluding chapter of Fisher
with the trusted, impersonal, and automatic gold standard (1911) onward, Fisher advocated a compensated dollar,
(Laidler, 1991a; see also Marshall, 1923, 1926). The seeking to stabilize the real economy by stabilizing the
possibility of using monetary policy to target a price index purchasing power of money as measured by a price index. To
(rather than an exchange rate or the price of gold), in the try to make this proposal operational, Fisher identied the
interest of stabilizing output and employment, was a thought geometric mean of the Paasche and Laspeyres indexes as the
that occurred to economists before the twentieth century ideal index number, published a weekly price index, and
and although William Cross is a forgotten gure who was pioneered the issue of indexed bonds.
never part of the mainstream of economics, the same cannot While Fisher and Hawtrey stressed monetary shocks and
be said of Walras or Marshall. advocated price level stabilization, Joseph Schumpeter
([1912]1934) and Dennis Robertson (1915) saw clusters of
entrepreneurial innovations, introducing new products or
Monetary Theorists and Economic Stabilization techniques, as the real shocks driving economic uctuations
(see Presley, 1979 and Fletcher, 2000 on Robertson, and
Bimetallists, such as William Jennings Bryan in his Cross of Swedbergs introduction to Schumpeter, 1991). Pigou
Gold speech accepting the Democratic nomination for Presi- (1927) argued that waves of optimism and pessimism
dent of the United States in 1896, saw gradually declining caused uctuations in investment. The Stockholm School
prices as a burden on debtors (especially farmers with mort- (Karin Kock, 1929; Erik Lindahl, 1939; Erik Lundberg, 1937;
gages), and proposed to increase the quantity of money and Gunnar Myrdal, 1939) followed Knut Wicksell (1898, 1907,
thus raise prices by coining both gold and silver at a xed price 1915) in emphasizing the distinction between the market
ratio (so that the monetary authority would have the daunting rate of interest, set by the banking system, and the natural
task of xing the relative price between two metals, a problem rate of interest, variously dened as the interest rate at which
that Marshalls symmetallism avoided). J. Laurence Laughlin, the price level would be constant, or at which investment
a hard-money opponent of bimetallism and an important equals saving, or which reects the marginal productivity of
inuence on the design of the Federal Reserve System, capital. Monetary shocks shift the market rate of interest,
responded by rejecting the quantity theory of money, while innovations and other real productivity shocks change
emphasizing the cost of production of gold rather than the the natural rate. As long as the market rate was less than the
quantity of money (Skaggs, 1995). Irving Fisher (1896, 1911) natural rate, entrepreneurs would borrow for new invest-
offered a theoretical and statistical defense of the quantity ment, causing prices to rise, and the converse occurred when
theory (see also Kemmerer, 1907), with changes in the the market rate was above the natural rate. Monetary policy
quantity of money determining the price level and short-run could stabilize the economy by varying the market rate to
real uctuations, but, contrary to the bimetallists, with match changes in the natural rate (which was not directly
money neutral in the long run (Dimand, 2013). Fisher observable). The process analysis of the Swedish economists,
(1896), equating the difference between interest rates in any of Robertson (1926), and of Keynes Treatise on Money
two standards (gold and silver, money and commodities, two (1930), while motivated by concern with uctuations in
national currencies) to the exchange rate of appreciation of output and employment, formally modeled price level
one standard against the other, showed that the price movements and interest rates, with no explicit theory of
deation (appreciation of the purchasing power of money) unemployment or aggregate income (Patinkin, 1982;
only burdened debtors if the deation was unexpected. If the Jonung, 1991). Beginning with the rst German edition of
deation was expected, it would be reected in lower interest Mises (1935) in 1912, the Austrian monetary malinvestment
rates. With acknowledgment to Marshalls evidence before theory of the trade cycle drew on the Currency School
ofcial inquiries (later collected by Keynes as Marshall, tradition and on Wicksell to interpret depressions as the
1926), Fisher (1896) introduced the Fisher equation necessary corrections of unsound speculative investment
(nominal interest equal to real interest plus expected resulting from expansionary monetary disturbances, and to
ination), the expectations theory of the term structure of reject price level stabilization as interfering with and pro-
interest rates, and uncovered interest parity between longing necessary deationary adjustments (Mises, 1935;
currencies. Covered interest parity, equating the spread Hayek, 1931, 1933; Ellis, 1934).
410 Macroeconomics, History of up to 1933

Fluctuations as Cycles and Fishers critique of the so-called business cycle as


a dance of the dollar, turned the attention of economists
Although they were not the rst to detect some more or less to oscillatory responses to external shocks (real or
regular periodicity in the pattern of crises and booms (Jevons, monetary), rather than underlying cycles (see Andvig, 1981
1884: p. 129, cited publications by Hyde Clarke in 1847), the on Frisch and V. Barnett, 2011 on Slutsky). The Moscow
idea that trade and prices follow a cycle gained force in the Conjuncture Institute led by Nikolai Kondratiev, whose long
1860s with the empirical work of Clment Juglar (1862) and wave theory implied that capitalism would experience
W. Stanley Jevons (1884) (a collection of his articles from another upswing after the Depression, was destroyed in
1862 to 1882 edited after Jevons death by Herbert S. Foxwell, Stalins purges, with Slutsky retreating from economic topics
his successor at University College), with later writers from to meteorology and statistics ironically including research
London School of Economics (LSE) director Sir William Bev- on sunspots (Kondratiev, 1997; V. Barnett, 1998, 2011).
eridge to NBER founder Wesley Mitchell (1927) and Joseph Other business cycle institutes survived but, as in the case of
Schumpeter (1939) going beyond a single cycle to interpret Mitchells NBER, evolved into general economic research
time series as several superimposed cycles of differing ampli- centers, with seasonality and leading indicators as the most
tude and periodicity. The literature was immense (OBrien specic lasting contributions of business cycle analysis.
(1999), Hagemann (2001), Boianovsky (2005) offer 11 More generally, Christopher Sims VAR approach to
volumes of selections from the primary sources) and, macroeconomics, starting with time series analysis without
following the establishment of Wesley Mitchells NBER in the assuming much knowledge of the true underlying
United States and the London and Cambridge Economic theoretical model, is in the spirit of the statistical approach
Service and the National Institute of Economic and Social to business cycle analysis undertaken by Juglar, Mitchell,
Research in Britain, conjuncture or business cycle research Beveridge, and others.
institutes ourished in Vienna, Berlin, Kiel, Soa, Warsaw,
Moscow, and other European centers in the 1920s (the Aus-
trian Institute for Business Cycle Research became the Austrian Dynamics and Growth
Institute for Economic Research after World War II).
Jevons attribution of the 11-year trade cycle to the 11-year David Ricardo, Thomas Robert Malthus, and John Stuart Mill
sunspot cycle, the periodic oscillation of solar activity, was analyzed the movement of prot rate, real wages, rent, and
responsible for economics being allowed to remain in the output as economies moved toward a stationary state in
British Association for the Advancement of Science, by which the wage would equal the natural price of labor and
offering an apparently objective, scientic physical explana- both population and the capital stock would be constant until
tion for economic uctuations, but in modern macroeco- the next innovation changed agricultural productivity
nomics, the term sunspots refers to any intrinsically (Hoselitz, 1960; Eltis, 1984; Hollander, 1997; Brewer, 2010).
irrelevant variable. Jevons hypothesis, while mistaken, was More formal algebraic modeling of economic growth began
not unreasonable: meteorologists of the time believed that tentatively with Sismondi and then, drawing inspiration from
sunspots affected the weather: cycles in rainfall and temper- Quesnays Tableau conomique, more systematically with Karl
ature would cause cycles in agricultural harvests, and agri- Marxs schemes of simple and expanded reproduction in
culture accounted for a larger share of the world economy in Volume II of Capital (Arthur and Reuten, 1998), which were
the 1860s than it does now. When sunspots were believed to developed further in debates between Rosa Luxemburg
follow a cycle of 11.1 years, Jevons founds an 11-year cycle in ([1913]1951) and Otto Bauer about whether the capitalist
prices, and when the sun-spot cycle was revised to mode of production would inevitably break down after
10.45 years he was able to make the average interval a certain number of periods because of insufcient purchasing
between English crises 10.466 years (Mitchell, 1927: power and sectoral imbalances (see Kalecki, 1967 and
p. 384). Jevons assumed that a cyclical effect must have Joan Robinsons introduction to the 1951 translation of
a cyclical cause, but Frisch (1933) drew attention to Luxemburg).
Wicksells remark that when a rocking horse is struck with In his presidential address to Section F of the British
a stick, the motion of the rocking horse does not resemble Association, Allyn Young (1928), recently transplanted from
the motion of the stock. Seasonality, Jevons other discovery Harvard to a chair at LSE, directed attention to Adam Smiths
of an economic cycle with a cyclical physical cause (also in linkage of economic growth to increasing returns to scale
Jevons, 1884), has fared better, and is the progenitor of (the division of labour is limited by the extent of the
seasonally adjusted time series. market), ironically just 2 years after Piero Sraffa had, in the
With enough cycles, any time series could be explained as same journal, shown that increasing returns are problematic
the summation of cycles: using the periodogram (an early for modeling equilibrium of the Marshallian rm. In the same
version of spectral analysis), Beveridge found 19 cycles in journal issue as Young (1928), the Cambridge mathematician
wheat prices with periods varying from 2.735 to 68 years and philosopher Frank Ramsey (1928) analyzed optimal
(Dimand, 1999). In a paper rst published in Russian in 1927 capital accumulation (with the rst use of calculus of varia-
with an English summary, Eugen (or Evgenii) Slutsky (1937) tions in an economics journal) in the rst step toward what is
used a moving average of the last three digits of the winning now taught as the RamseyCassKoopmans model, and the
Moscow lottery numbers to demonstrate that summation and same year G.A. Feldman (1928) attempted a formal model
averaging of random series would produce apparent cycles of capital intensity and output growth rates for Soviet
where none existed. Slutsky (1937) and Ragnar Frisch (1933), central planning. But by 1930, Young and Ramsey were
Macroeconomics, History of up to 1933 411

dead (Ramsey at the age of 26), and Feldman had 1999). Drawing on the multiplier analysis of his student
disappeared in Stalins purges, and the lines of research they Richard Kahn (1931), who together with Giblin (1930),
indicated were not pursued until much later. Hawtrey (1932), and others had related changes in
equilibrium income to changes in autonomous investment
or exports (see Davis, 1980; Patinkin, 1982; Clarke, 1988;
From Cycles and Price Dynamics to Analysis Dimand, 1988), Keynes (1933b, 1936) offered a theory of
of Aggregate Output and Employment the equilibrium level of national income as the level of
income at which desired investment equals desired saving.
Although both monetary theorists and business cycle analysts Noting that nominal wages had fallen by 30% in the
were motivated by concern over periods of high unemploy- United States in the early 1930s without reducing
ment (as well as by the social costs of rapid ination, with unemployment or real wages, Keynes (1936: Chapter 19)
Keynes Tract on Monetary Reform and Fisher stressing the invoked dynamic arguments to deny that wage and price
collapse of monetary exchange in the German hyperination exibility would guarantee restoration of full employment
of the early 1920s), they lacked a macroeconomic analysis of after a demand shock sticky wages were his
unemployment. Pigou (1913) talked about effective demand recommendation, not his assumption (see also Minsky,
in an early short book for the general public about unem- 1975; Tobin, 1980). Not only did Keynes have a message
ployment, but his more formal and systematic Theory of welcomed by policy makers and the public, but, combined
Unemployment (1933) offered only a one-market analysis in with the creation of national income accounts and
which unemployment just meant that the wage rate was advances in econometric technique, his theory of the
above the market clearing level. The implication of Pigous determination of aggregate income and employment
analysis, which Pigou steadfastly refused to draw in his provided an agenda for macroeconomists, drawing together
advice and writings on policy, was that wage cuts would the traditions of monetary theory and empirical studies of
eliminate unemployment even in the Great Depression. But economic uctuations. Regardless of later serious doubts by
Edwin Cannan did draw that conclusion in his 1932 macroeconomists about the shift of emphasis from
presidential address to the Royal Economic Society ination to unemployment, or the eclipse of search-
(reprinted in Dimand, 2002: vol. III). Beveridges theoretic analysis of unemployment, or Keynes sanguine
Unemployment, a Problem of Industry (1909 and 1930) (1930), view of the motivation of policy makers, the theory of
an expansion of his 1909 book, saw unemployment in equilibrium aggregate income and employment sketched in
search-theoretic terms, with labor exchanges as the means to Keynes (1933b) and in his 1933 lectures (in Rymes 1989)
more efcient matching of workers and jobs. Fisher (1933) and pamphlet and presented in the General Theory marked
presented a debt deation theory of depressions, stressing a transformation of a eld that had a long and rich history
the scramble for liquidity because of fears of default on by the time it acquired the name macroeconomics.
inside debts with xed money values, which later inuenced
Hyman Minsky (1975), James Tobin (1980), Ben Bernanke See also: Economics, History of; Financial Crises, History of;
(2000), and Mervyn King, but at that time he had lost his Fisher, Irving (18671947); Hume, David (171176); Keynes,
audience by being so memorably wrong about the stock John Maynard (18831946); Keynesianism and the Question
market. The mass unemployment of the early 1930s turned of State Interventionism; Macroeconomics, History of From
public attention from such academic authorities to 1933 to Present; Malthus, Thomas Robert (17661834);
underconsumptionists outside the mainstream (see Bleaney, Marshall, Alfred (18421924); Marx, Karl (181883); Mill,
1976) or to Marxist claims that depressions and mass John Stuart (180673); Myrdal, Gunnar (18981987);
unemployment were inherent in capitalism. Schumpeter Ricardo, David (17721823); Robinson, Joan (190383);
held that the Great Depression was just the regrettable Schumpeter, Joseph A. (18831950); von Hayek, Friedrich A.
coincidence of the troughs of three cycles of different lengths. (18991992).
John Maynard Keynes, in his pamphlet The Means to
Prosperity (1933b) and his 1933 Cambridge lectures (recon-
structed in Rymes, 1989), and then more fully and formally
in The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money Bibliography
(1936), offered a solution to this impasse. Contrary to the
Andvig, J.C., 1981. Ragnar Frisch and business cycle research during the Interwar
Marxists, depressions and unemployment could be tamed years. History of Political Economy 13, 695725.
without revolution or abolition of capitalism, by appropriate Arnon, A., 2011. Monetary Theory and Policy from Hume and Smith to
management of aggregate demand to offset uctuations Wicksell: Money, Credit and the Economy. Cambridge University Press,
in expectations of the long-period protability of new Cambridge, UK.
Arthur, C.J., Reuten, G. (Eds.), 1998. The Circulation of Capital: Essays on Volume II
investment, uctuations resulting from fundamental
of Marxs Capital. Macmillan, London.
uncertainty about the future. Unlike John Hobson or other Bagehot, W., 1873. Lombard Street, a Description of the Money Market. John
underconsumptionists, or Michal Kalecki writing in Polish Murray, London. Reprinted in: Stevas, N.St.J. (Ed.), The Collected Works of
within a Marxian tradition (Kalecki, 1967; translations of Walter Bagehot, The Economist 19741986, London.
essays written in the 1930s), Keynes was a well-established Barnett, P., 1941. Business-Cycle Theory in the United States, 18601900.
University of Chicago Press, Chicago.
gure within the profession, steeped in the Cambridge Barnett, V., 1998. Kondratiev and the Dynamics of Economic Development:
heritage of Marshallian monetary theory and saving- Long Cycles and Industrial Growth in Historical Context. Macmillan,
investment analysis (Eshag, 1963; Bridel, 1987; Laidler, Basingstoke.
412 Macroeconomics, History of up to 1933

Barnett, V., 2011. E.E. Slutsky as Economist and Mathematician: Crossing the Fisher, I., 1933. The debt-deation theory of great depressions. Econometrica 1,
Limits of Knowledge. Routledge, London and New York. 337357. In: Fisher (1997), vol. 10.
Baumol, W.J., 1999. Retrospectives: says law. Journal of Economic Perspectives Fisher, I., 1997. In: Barber, W.J. (Ed.), assisted by Dimand, R.W., Foster, K.; Tobin, J.
13, 195204. (Consulting Ed. ). The Works of Irving Fisher, 14 vols. Pickering & Chatto, London.
von Bergmann, E., 1895. Die Wirtschaftskrisen: Geschichte der nationalkonomi- Flanders, M.J., 1989. International Monetary Economics 18701960. Cambridge
schen Krisentheorien. W. Kohlhammer, Stuttgart. University Press, Cambridge, UK.
Bernanke, B.S., 2000. Essays on the Great Depression. Princeton University Press, Fleetwood, W., 1707. Chronicon Preciosum. London, second ed. 1745, reprinted.
Princeton, NJ. A.M. Kelley, New York.
Beveridge, W.H., 1930. Unemployment, a Problem of Industry (1909 and 1930). Fletcher, G., 2000. Understanding Dennis Robertson. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham,
Longmans, Green, London. UK; Northampton, MA.
Blaug, M., Eltis, W., OBrien, D.P., Patinkin, D., Skidelsky, R., Wood, G.E., 1995. Foxwell, H.S., 1886. Irregularity of Employment and Fluctuations of Prices.
The Quantity Theory of Money from Locke to Keynes and Friedman. Co-Operative Printing Company, Edinburgh. Reprinted in: Dimand (2002), vol. I.
Edward Elgar, Aldershot, UK; Brookeld, VT. Friedman, M. (Ed.), 1956. Studies in the Quantity Theory of Money. University of
Bleaney, M., 1976. Underconsumption Theories: A History and Critical Analysis. Chicago Press, Chicago.
International Publishers, New York. Frisch, R., 1933. Propagation problems and impulse problems in dynamic
Boianovsky, M. (Ed.), 2005. Business Cycle Theories: Selected Texts 18601939, economics. In: Economic Essays in Honour of Gustav Cassel. George Allen &
vols. 58. Pickering & Chatto, London. Unwin, London.
de Boyer des Roches, J., 2003. La pense montaire: Histoire et analyse. Les Solo, Gervaise, I., 1720. The system or theory of the trade of the world. H. Woodfall,
Paris. London; reprinted. with foreword by J. Viner and introduction by J.M. Letiche.
Brewer, A., 2010. The Making of the Classical Theory of Economic Growth. Johns Hopkins Press, Baltimore. 1954. In: Dimand, R.W. (Ed.), The Origins of
Routledge, London and New York. International Economics, vol. I. Routledge, London and New York, 2004.
Bridel, P., 1987. Cambridge Monetary Thought: The Development of Saving- Giblin, L.F., 1930. Australia, 1930. Melbourne University Press, Melbourne.
Investment Analysis from Marshall to Keynes. Macmillan, Basingstoke. Reprinted in: Dimand (2002), vol. IV.
Bridel, P., 1997. Money and General Equilibrium Theory: From Walras to Pareto Glasner, D. (Ed.), 1997. Business Cycles and Depressions: An Encyclopedia.
(18701923). Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, UK. Garland, New York.
Cesarano, F., 2007. Monetary Theory in Retrospect: The Selected Essays of Filippo Green, R., 1992. Classical Theories of Money, Output and Ination. Macmillan,
Cesarano. Routledge, London and New York. London and Basingstoke.
Christiernin, P.N., 1761. Lectures on the high price of foreign exchange in Sweden Grice-Hutchison, M., 1952. The School of Salamanca: Readings in Spanish
(1967 Trans.). In: Eagly, R.V. (Ed.), The Swedish Bullionist Controversy. Amer- Monetary Theory 15441605. Clarendon Press, Oxford.
ican Philosophical Society, Philadelphia. Guggenheim, T., 1989. Preclassical Monetary Theories. Pinter, London and New York.
Clarke, P., 1988. The Keynesian Revolution in the Making, 19241936. Cambridge Hagemann, H. (Ed.), 2001. Business Cycle Theories: Selected Texts 18601939,
University Press, Cambridge, UK. 4 vols. Pickering & Chatto, London.
Corry, B.A., 1962. Money, Saving and Investment in English Economics Hawtrey, R.G., 1913. Good and Bad Trade. Constable, London. Reprinted
18001850. Macmillan, London. A. M. Kelley, New York, 1970, with 1962 preface by author.
Davis, E.G., 1980. The correspondence between R.G. Hawtrey and J.M. Keynes on Hawtrey, R.G., 1919. Currency and Credit. Longmans, Green, London.
the Treatise: the genesis of output adjustment models. Canadian Journal of Hawtrey, R.G., 1932. The Art of Central Banking. Longmans, Green, London.
Economics 13, 716724. Hayek, F.A., [1931]1991. English monetary policy and the bullion debate. In: Hayek,
Davis, T., 2005. Ricardos Macroeconomics: Money, Trade Cycles and Growth. F.A., The Trend of Economic Thinking. University of Chicago Press, Chicago,
Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK. (Chapters 912).
Deutscher, P., 1990. R.G. Hawtrey and the Rise of Macroeconomics. Macmillan, Hayek, F.A., 1931. Prices and Production, second ed. 1935. Routledge, London.
Basingstoke. Hayek, F.A., 1933. Monetary theory and the trade cycle (N. Kaldor and
Dimand, R.W., 1988. The Origins of the Keynesian Revolution. Edward Elgar, H. M. Croome, Trans.). Routledge, London.
Upleadon, UK. Stanford University Press, Stanford, CA. Hegeland, H., 1951. The Quantity Theory of Money. Goteborg, reprinted 1969.
Dimand, R.W., 1999. Beveridge on unemployment and cycles before. The General A.M. Kelley, New York.
Theory. History of Economic Ideas 7 (3), 3351. Hollander, S., 1997. The Economics of Thomas Robert Malthus. University of
Dimand, R.W. (Ed.), 2002. The Origins of Macroeconomics, 10 vols. Routledge, Toronto Press, Toronto.
London and New York. Hoselitz, B.F. (Ed.), 1960. Theories of Economic Growth. Free Press, New York.
Dimand, R.W., 2003. Interwar monetary and business cycle theory. Research in Humphrey, T.M., 1993. Money, Banking, and Ination: Essays in the History of
History of Economic Thought and Methodology 21-A, 121148. Economic Thought. Edward Elgar, Aldershot, UK; Brookeld, VT.
Dimand, R.W., 2013. David Hume and Irving Fisher on the quantity theory of money Jevons, W.S., 1884. In: Foxwell, H.S. (Ed.), Investigations in Currency and Finance.
in the short run and the long run. European Journal of the History of Economic Macmillan, London.
Thought 20, 284304. Jones, E.D., 1900. Economic Crises. Macmillan, New York.
Divisia, F., 1925. Lindice montaire et la thorie de la monnaie. Revue dconomie Jonung, L. (Ed.), 1991. The Stockholm School of Economics Revisited. Cambridge
Politique 39, 9801009. University Press, Cambridge, UK.
Ellis, H.S., 1934. German Monetary Theory 19051933. Harvard University Press, Juglar, C., 1862. Des crises commerciales et de leur retour priodique en France,
Cambridge, MA. en Angleterre et aux tats-Unis. Guillaumin, Paris.
Eltis, W.A., 1984. The Classical Theory of Economic Growth. Macmillan, London. Kahn, R.F., 1931. The relation of home investment to unemployment. Economic
Eshag, E., 1963. From Marshall to Keynes: An Essay on the Monetary Theory of the Journal 41, 173198.
Cambridge School. Basil Blackwell, Oxford. Kalecki, M., 1967. Studies in the Theory of Business Cycles, 19331939. Basil
Feldman, G.A., 1928. On the theory of the growth rates of national income I and II Blackwell, Oxford.
(1964 Trans.). In: Spulber, N. (Ed.), Foundations of Soviet Strategy for Economic Kemmerer, E.W., 1907. Money and Credit Instruments in Their Relation to General
Growth. Indiana University Press, Bloomington, pp. 174199 and 304331. Prices. Henry Holt, New York.
Reprinted in Dimand (2002), vol. III. Keynes, J.M., 1923. A Tract on Monetary Reform. Macmillan, London. In: Keynes
Fetter, F.W., 1965. The Development of British Monetary Orthodoxy 17971875. (19711989), vol. IV.
Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA. Keynes, J.M., 1930. A Treatise on Money, 2 vols. Macmillan, London. In: Keynes
Fisher, I., 1896. Appreciation and Interest. Macmillan, New York. In: Fisher (1997), (19711989), vols. V and VI.
vol. 1. Keynes, J.M., 1933a. Robert Malthus, the rst of the Cambridge economists. In:
Fisher, I., 1911. The Purchasing Power of Money, with H.G. Brown. Macmillan, Keynes, J.M. (Ed.), Essays in Biography. Macmillan, London. Reprinted in:
New York. In: Fisher (1997), vol. 4. Keynes (19711989), vol. 10.
Fisher, I., 1926. A statistical relationship between unemployment and price level Keynes, J.M., 1933b. The Means to Prosperity, vol. 9. Harcourt Brace, New York.
changes. International Labour Review 13, 785792. Reprinted 1973 as, Lost Reprinted in: Keynes (19711989).
and found: I discovered the Phillips curve Irving Fisher. Journal of Political Keynes, J.M., 1936. The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money.
Economy 81, 496502; Also in: Fisher (1997), vol. 8. Macmillan, London. In: Keynes (19711989), vol. VII.
Macroeconomics, History of up to 1933 413

Keynes, J.M., 19711989. In: Moggridge, D.E. (Ed.), The Collected Writings of John Oresme, N., de Sassoferrato, B., Buridan, J., 1989. In: Dupuy, C. (Ed.), Trait des
Maynard Keynes, 30 vols. Macmillan, London. Cambridge University Press, for monnaies et autres crits montaires du XIVe sicle (F. Chartrain, Trans.).
the Royal Economic Society, New York. La Manufacture, Lyon.
Kock, K., 1929. A Study of Interest Rates, Stockholm Economic Studies No. 1. Patinkin, D., 1965. Money, Interest and Prices, second ed. Harper & Row, New York.
P.S. King, London. Patinkin, D., 1981. Essays on and in the Chicago Tradition. Duke University Press,
Kondratiev, N.D., 1997. In: Samuels, W.J., Makasheva, N. (Eds.), Barnett, V., Durham, NC.
Reijnders, J., Solomou, S., Tylecote, A. (Consulting eds.), The Works of Patinkin, D., 1982. Anticipations of the General Theory? And Other Essays on
Nikolai D. Kondratiev, 4 vols. Pickering & Chatto, London. Keynes. University of Chicago Press, Chicago.
Korinek, A., Mendoza, E., 2013. From Sudden Stops to Fisherian Deation: Quantitative Pigou, A.C., 1913. Unemployment. Williams & Norgate, Home University Library, London.
Theory and Policy Implications. NBER Working Paper 19362, August. Pigou, A.C., 1927. Industrial Fluctuations. Macmillan, London.
Laidler, D.E.W., 1991a. The Golden Age of the Quantity Theory. Phillip Allan, Pigou, A.C., 1933. Theory of Unemployment. Macmillan, London.
London; Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ. Presley, J., 1979. Robertsonian Economics. Holmes & Meier, New York.
Laidler, D.E.W., 1991b. The quantity theory is always and everywhere controversial Ramsey, F.P., 1928. Mathematical theory of saving. Economic Journal 38,
why? Economic Record 67, 289306. 543559.
Laidler, D.E.W., 1999. Fabricating the Keynesian Revolution: Studies of the Inter-war Robertson, D.H., 1915. A Study of Industrial Fluctuation. P.S. King, London.
Literature on Money, the Cycle, and Unemployment. Cambridge University Press, Robertson, D.H., 1926. Banking Policy and the Price Level. P.S. King, London.
Cambridge, UK. Rotwein, E. (Ed.), 1955[1752]. David Humes: Writings on Economics. University of
Laidler, D.E.W., 2003. Macroeconomics in Retrospect: Selected Essays. Edward Wisconsin Press, Madison, WI.
Elgar, Cheltenham, UK; Northampton, MA. Rymes, T.K. (Ed.), 1989. Keyness Lectures, 193235, Notes of a Representative
Lange, O., 1942. Says law: a restatement and critique. In: Lange, O., McIntyre, F., Student. Macmillan, Basingstoke. University of Michigan Press, Ann Arbor.
Yntema, T.O. (Eds.), Studies in Mathematical Economics and Econometrics in Schumpeter, J.A., [1912]1934. The Theory of Economic Development, (R. Opie,
Memory of Henry Schultz. University of Chicago Press, Chicago, pp. 4968. Trans.). Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA.
Reprinted in: Dimand (2002), vol. III. Schumpeter, J.A., 1939. Business Cycles, 2 vols. McGraw Hill, New York.
Lindahl, E., 1939. Studies in the Theory of Money and Capital. George Allen & Schumpeter, J.A., 1991. In: Swedberg, R. (Ed.), The Economics and Sociology of
Unwin, London. Capitalism. Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ.
Link, R., 1959. English Theories of Economic Fluctuations 18151848. Columbia Skaggs, N.T., 1995. The methodological roots of J. Laurence Laughlins anti-quantity
University Press, New York. theory of money and prices. Journal of the History of Economic Thought 17, 120.
Locke, J., 1991. In: Kelley, P.H. (Ed.), Locke on Money, 2 vols. Clarendon Press, Skaggs, N.T., 1999. Changing views: twentieth century opinion on the banking
Oxford. school-currency school controversy. History of Political Economy 31, 361391.
Lundberg, E., 1937. Studies in the Theory of Economic Expansion. P.S. King, Slutsky, E.E., 1937. The summation of random causes as the source of cyclic
London. processes. Econometrica 5, 105146.
Luxemburg, R., [1913]1951. The Accumulation of Capital (A. Schwarzchild, Trans. Smith, V.C., 1936. The Rationale of Central Banking. P.S. King, London.
with introduction by J. Robinson). Routledge & Kegan Paul, London. Sowell, T., 1972. Says Law: A Historical Analysis. Princeton University Press,
Marshall, A., 1887. Remedies for Fluctuations in General Prices. Contemporary Princeton, NJ.
Review. Reprinted in: Pigou, A.C. (Ed.), Memorials of Alfred Marshall. Macmillan, Thornton, H., [1802]1939. An Enquiry into the Nature and Effects of the Papers
London, 1925. Credit of Great Britain, with two 1811 speeches by Thornton, and introduction by
Marshall, A., 1923. Money, Credit and Commerce. Macmillan, London. F.A. Hayek. George Allen & Unwin, London.
Marshall, A., 1926. In: Keynes, J.M. (Ed.), Ofcial Papers. Macmillan, London. Tobin, J., 1980. Asset Accumulation and Economic Activity. Basil Blackwell, Oxford.
Minsky, H.P., 1975. John Maynard Keynes. Columbia University Press, New York. University of Chicago Press, Chicago.
Mises, L. von, 1935. The Theory of Money and Credit (H. Batson, Trans.). Cape, Vickers, D., 1959. Studies in the Theory of Money 16901776. Chilton, New York.
London. Viner, J., 1937. Studies in the Theory of International Trade. Harper & Brothers,
Mitchell, W.C., 1913. Business Cycles. University of California Press, Berkeley. New York.
Mitchell, W.C., 1927. Business Cycles: The Problem and Its Setting. National Bureau Walras, L., 1886. Thorie de la monnaie. Larose et Forcel, Paris. L. Corbaz,
of Economic Research, New York. Lausanne.
Monroe, A.E., 1923. Monetary Theory before Adam Smith. Harvard University Press, Wicksell, K., 1898. Interest and Prices (R. Kahn, 1936, Trans.). Macmillan, London.
Cambridge, MA. Wicksell, K., 1907. The inuence of the rate of interest on prices. Economic Journal
Myrdal, G., 1939. Monetary Equilibrium (R. Bryce and N. Stolper, Trans.). W. Hodge, 17, 213220.
London. Wicksell, K., 1915 (E. Claasen, 1935, Trans.). Lectures on Political Economy, vol. 2.
Murphy, A.E., 2009. The Genesis of Macroeconomics: New Ideas from Sir William Routledge, London.
Petty to Henry Thornton. Oxford University Press, Oxford. Wirth, M., 1858. Geschichte der Handelskrisen. Frankfurt am Main, fourth ed. 1890.
Northcote, S., (Lord Iddlesleigh), Chair, 1886. Depression of Trade and Industry. Wood, G., Capie, F. (Eds.), 2000. The Development of Monetary Theory in the
Final Report of the Royal Commission Appointed to Inquire into the Depression of 1920s and 1930s, 4 vols. Routledge, London and New York.
Trade and Industry; with Minutes of Evidence and Appendices. Parliamentary Woodford, M., 2003. Interest and Prices. Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ.
Papers, Command Paper C. 4893, London. Wright, C.D., 1886. Industrial Depressions: First Annual Report of the United States
OBrien, D.P. (Ed.), 1999. Foundations of Business Cycle Theory, 3 vols. Edward Commissioner of Labor. Government Printing Ofce, Washington, DC. Reprinted
Elgar, Cheltenham, UK; Brookeld, VT. A.M. Kelley, 1968, New York.
OBrien, D.P., 2007. The Development of Monetary Economics. Edward Elgar, Young, A.A., 1928. Increasing returns and economic progress. Economic Journal
Cheltenham, UK; Northampton, MA. 38, 527542.

Das könnte Ihnen auch gefallen