Sie sind auf Seite 1von 8

Health Policy 68 (2004) 4754

The effect of generic competition on the price


of brand-name drugs
Joel Lexchin a,b,c,
a Emergency Department, University Health Network, Toronto, Ont., Canada
bSchool of Health Policy and Management, York University, Toronto, Ont., Canada
c Department of Family and Community Medicine, University of Toronto, Toronto, Ont., Canada

Received 22 January 2003; accepted 27 July 2003

Abstract

Background: Literature from the US has shown that brand-name manufacturers do not compete on price once generic com-
petitors become available. This study was undertaken to investigate if this is also true in Canada. Methods: Editions of the
Ontario Drug Benefit Formulary were used to identify brand-name drugs that lacked generic competition in July 1990 but had
acquired one or more generic competitors by December 1998. Prices of the brand-name drugs were compared before generic
competition, at the point when generic competition started and subsequent to the initiation of competition. Results: Price changes
for 81 different products in 144 separate presentations were analysed. There was no statistically significant change in brand-name
prices when generic competition started. The movement of brand-name prices was not influenced by whether the generic was
made by the company producing the brand-name product or price freezes imposed by the Ontario government. When generics
first became available having four or more generics was associated with a rise in the price of the brand-name drugs compared
to having one, two or three generic competitor(s). Interpretation: The lack of price competition may lead to increased costs in
the private market. Private insurance companies generally do not require generic substitution and some provinces do not require
generic substitution for cash-paying customers. Maintaining higher prices on brand-name drugs impacts on the prices of new
patented medications coming onto the Canadian market under the current pricing guidelines of the Patented Medicine Prices
Review Board.
2003 Elsevier Ireland Ltd. All rights reserved.

Keywords: Brand-name drugs; Drug prices; Generic competition; Prescription drugs; Ontario

1. Introduction Products Directorate (TPD) of Health, Canada is


charged with approving generics on the basis of bioe-
Generic drugs enter the Canadian marketplace fol- quivalence and manufacturing quality. The decision
lowing the expiration of the 20-year patent period to list generics on formularies and to pay for them
granted to brand-name products. The Therapeutic out of public funds is a provincial matter with each
of Canadas 10 provinces having its own set of rules
Present address: 121 Walmer Road, Toronto, Ont., Canada for listing and negotiating its own prices with phar-
M5R 2X8. Tel.: +1-416-964-7186; fax: +1-416-923-9515. maceutical companies. TPD approves approximately
E-mail address: joel.lexchin@utoronto.ca (J. Lexchin). 5070 new generic products per year and over the

0168-8510/$ see front matter 2003 Elsevier Ireland Ltd. All rights reserved.
doi:10.1016/j.healthpol.2003.07.007
48 J. Lexchin / Health Policy 68 (2004) 4754

period 19992002 the mean approval time has been In Canada, the public sector controls a much larger
between 500600 days [1]. The time taken to be listed segment of the market than in the US, owing to the
on a provincial formulary varies from an average of existence of the provincial drug plans [16]. The loss
84 days in British Columbia to 466 days in Ontario of the public share of the market when generic com-
[2]. petitors are listed on provincial drug formularies may
In 2001, 39.6% of all prescriptions in Canada were prompt brand-name companies to behave differently
dispensed generically representing 14.6% of retail in Canada as compared to the US. Therefore, pricing
sales for a value of about Can$ 1.02 billion [3,4]. Apo- behaviour in Canada cannot be assumed to be the same
tex and Novopharm are the two largest generic com- as in the US. The object of this study is to examine the
panies in Canada with sales of Can$ 458 million and effects of the entry of generic competitors on the price
248 million in 2000, respectively [5]. Some generics of brand-name products in the province of Ontario.
are made by firms controlled by brand-name compa-
nies, so-called pseudogenerics or ultragenerics.
Ultragenerics are introduced to pre-empt competition 2. Methods
from independent generic companies and are made
and marketed by another division of the same com- The Ontario Drug Benefit Plan is a publicly run
pany or are distributed by another company under programme that pays for drugs in the ambulatory care
license [6]. setting for seniors (65 years of age) and those on
When generic drugs enter the market in Ontario, social assistance. Drugs covered by the plan are listed
they are priced substantially below brand-name prod- in the Ontario Drug Benefit Formulary. The sample
ucts. In the early 1990s, there was a 25% discount of drugs was derived by comparing formulary no. 29,
when a single generic competitor was available, rising issued July 1990 [17], and formulary no. 36, issued
to a 50% or greater price reduction when there are four 31 December 1998 [18]. All drugs in any presentation
to five generic competitors [7]. Since 1999, the ini- (tablets, capsules, oral liquids, suppositories, injec-
tial generic approved for listing on the Ontario Drug tions, topicals, drops) without generic competitors in
Benefit Formulary must be priced at 70% of the com- formulary no. 29 were identified. Formulary no. 36
parable brand-name product and subsequent generics was then searched for the same drugs in the same
must be at least 10% lower than the first [8]. presentations and those that were still listed and had
Nearly all Canadian provincial plans have either generic competitors were selected. Prices of the drugs
mandatory generic substitution or only cover the cost in formulary no. 29 were recorded and then all sub-
of the generic product [9] and very few prescrip- sequent formularies up to and including no. 36 were
tions do not allow generic substitution [10], so it is searched and the following items were recorded: name
largely irrelevant to provincial payers whether or not of brand-name drug, number of different presentations
brand-name manufacturers lower the prices of their of brand-name drug, price of brand-name drug, man-
products in response to generic competition. ufacturer of brand-name drug, the formulary edition
The situation in the private market in Canada may be in which a generic competitor was first listed, price
different. Few private insurance plans require manda- of generic competitor(s), number of generic competi-
tory generic substitution [11], cash-paying customers tors, manufacturer(s) of generic competitors. Prices in
may not request generic drugs and provincial legis- the Drug Benefit Formulary are calculated per gram,
lation may not make it mandatory for pharmacists to millilitre, tablet, capsule or other appropriate unit.
offer generic equivalents to this group. Therefore, in Prior to formulary no. 35, prices were for the lowest
the private market, drug costs may be substantially af- amount for which the drug could be purchased in
fected if brand-name manufacturers decline to com- Canada minus any price reduction granted by the man-
pete on the basis of price. Work in the US has tended ufacturer or wholesaler to their representatives in the
to show that the entry of generic drugs does not affect form of rebates, discounts, refunds, free goods or any
the price of brand-name products [1214] although other benefits of a like nature. Prices in formularies
one study found that generic entry did slow the in- nos. 35 and 36 are those agreed to by the Ontario Min-
crease in brand-name prices [15]. istry of Health in negotiation with the manufacturer.
J. Lexchin / Health Policy 68 (2004) 4754 49

The price of the brand-name drug in the edition Results from a study based on the Ontario formu-
of the formulary immediately prior to the listing of a lary may not be applicable to other provinces. To over-
generic competitor was taken as the base price. Prices come this problem, a random subset of 15 brand-name
in subsequent editions of the formulary were com- drugs was chosen and prices for these drugs were
puted as a ratio of this base price. Therefore, if a compared in formularies from Alberta [19], Manitoba
drug had price of Can$ 1.50 in the edition of the for- [20], Newfoundland and Labrador [21], Ontario [22],
mulary before the introduction of generic competition Quebec [23], and Saskatchewan [24]. Other provincial
and a price of Can$ 1.65 when generic competition formularies do not list prices.
started its price ratio would be 1.1 (1.65/1.50). All Comparisons between brand-name prices were
comparisons were made on the basis of price ratios of made using Students t-test. The effect of the initial
brand-name drugs. number of generic competitors was analysed using
When brand-name drugs face competition only analysis of variance and two-factor analysis of vari-
from ultragenerics, pricing behaviour may be differ- ance was used to assess the effect of the number of
ent than when competition comes from generics made generics over time. Statistical analysis was done us-
by independent manufacturers. The Canadian Generic ing StatView 5.0.1 for Macintosh [25]. P values of
Pharmaceutical Association provided a list of indepen- <0.05 were considered statistically significant.
dent generic and ultrageneric companies. Price ratios All prices are reported in Canadian dollars un-
for brand-name drugs were compared when generic adjusted for inflation. Adjusting prices for inflation
competition was initially only from ultragenerics and would have been appropriate had companies been
only from generics made by independent companies. free to either raise or lower prices. However, after
One American study [15] found an association 1993, they were unable to increase prices without
between the number of generic competitors and sub- losing formulary listing and therefore their remaining
sequent declines over time in the rate of rise of choice, aside from lowering prices, was to maintain
brand-name prices. This question was investigated by existing prices. In this situation, adjusting for inflation
looking at price ratios for brand-name drugs as a func- would make it seem that companies were voluntarily
tion of the number of generic competitors both at the lowering prices which was clearly not the case.
time when generic competition began and subsequent
to the initiation of generic competition.
In 1993, the Ontario government instituted a price 3. Results
freeze for products listed on its formulary. This freeze
may have affected brand-name companies decisions A total of 81 different products, with 144 different
about whether or not to alter prices when generic com- presentations (14 presentations per drug) were iden-
petition began. Therefore, price ratios of brand-name tified that lacked a generic competitor in July 1990 but
drugs with generic competition before 1993 were com- had acquired one or more by December 1998.
pared to those with competition that began in 1993 or For nine products (16 different preparations) com-
later. panies lowered prices when a generic competitor
Time periods are reported in terms of editions of the first appeared with an average price decrease of 30%
Ontario Drug Benefit Formulary rather than in months (S.D. 15%); in 12 cases (21 different preparations)
or years. The formulary was issued on an irregular prices rose by an average of 9% (S.D. 15%). For
basis (Issue 29July 1990, Issue 30February 1991, the remaining 60 drugs (107 preparations) prices did
Issue 31April 1992, Issue 32July 1992, Issue not change. For all 144 presentations, the price ra-
331993 (no month given), Issue 34December tio of brand-name products at the time of generic
1994, Issue 35May 1996, Issue 36December competition was 0.98 (S.D. 0.128) which was not
1998) and therefore periods of time, for example, significantly different from 1 (P > 0.05).
between the edition of the formulary immediately Of the 12 cases where prices rose, 11 occurred be-
preceding generic competition and the edition when fore the government imposed price freeze in 1993.
a generic competitor was first available, were not Conversely, all nine instances where prices dropped
comparable from product to product. occurred after 1993 (Table 1). Prices rose for three
50
Table 1
Products with prices raised and lowered upon entry of generic competitors
Products with prices raised Products with prices lowered

Drug and presentation Therapeutic class Manufacturer Date of formulary Drug and presentation Therapeutic Manufacturer Date of formulary
when first generic class when first generic
competitor competitor
appeared appeared
Betamethasone dipropionate Topical Schering April 1992 Acetaminophen Analgesic SmithKline December 1994
ointment in base containing corticosteroid suppository 325 mg Beecham
propylene glycol 0.05%
Clonidine tablet 0.1 mg Antihypertensive Boehringer February 1991 Acetaminophen Analgesic SmithKline December 1994
Ingelheim suppository 650 mg Beecham
Clonidine tablet 0.2 mg Antihypertensive Boehringer February 1991 Cyproterone tablet 50 mg Antiandrogen Berlex December 1998

J. Lexchin / Health Policy 68 (2004) 4754


Ingelheim
Clotrimazole vaginal cream Antifungal Miles February 1991 Gentamicin otic solution Antibacterial Schering December 1998
20 mg/g 0.3%
Flurbiprofen tablet 50 mg NSAID Upjohn April 1992 Hydromorphone injection Analgesic Knoll December 1998
10 mg/ml
Flurbiprofen tablet 100 mg NSAID Upjohn April 1992 Loperamide capsule 2 mg Antidiarrheal Janssen May 1996
Gemfibrizol capsule 300 mg Antilipemic Pfizer February 1991 Methotrimeprazine tablet Neuroleptic Rhone-Poulenc December 1998
2 mg Rorer
Hydralazine tablet 10 mg Antihypertensive Ciba-Geigy April 1992 Methotrimeprazine tablet Neuroleptic Rhone-Poulenc May 1996
5 mg Rorer
Ketoprofen enteric coated tablet NSAID Rhone-Poulenc February 1991 Morphine injection Analgesic Abbott May 1996
50 mg Rorer 15 mg/ml
Ketoprofen enteric coated tablet NSAID Rhone-Poulenc February 1991 Naproxen suppository NSAID Syntex December 1994
100 mg Rorer 500 mg
Metronidazole capsule 500 mg Antibacterial/ Rhone-Poulenc February 1991 Prochlorperazine injection Neuroleptic Rhone-Poulenc December 1998
antiprotozoal Rorer 10 mg/2 ml Rorer
Prazosin tablet 1 mg Antihypertensive Pfizer February 1991
Prazosin tablet 2 mg Antihypertensive Pfizer February 1991
Prazosin tablet 5 mg Antihypertensive Pfizer February 1991
Sodium cromoglycate nasal Antiallergic Fisons December 1994
solution 2%
Tiaprofenic acid tablet 200 mg NSAID Roussel April 1992
Tiaprofenic acid tablet 300 mg NSAID Roussel April 1992
Trazodone tablet 50 mg Antidepressant Bristol-Myers May 1996
Squibb
Trazodone tablet 100 mg Antidepressant Bristol-Myers May 1996
Squibb
Trazodone tablet 150 mg Antidepressant Bristol-Myers May 1996
Squibb
J. Lexchin / Health Policy 68 (2004) 4754 51

different nonsteroidal anti-inflammatory agents (flur- 1.4


biprofen, ketoprofen and tiaprofenic acid) and three 1.2
antihypertensives (clonidine, hydralazine and pra- ** * #
1
zosin) and dropped in the case of three analgesics
(acetaminophen, hydromorphone and morphine). .8
Rhone-Poulenc Rorer (now part of Aventis) raised .6
prices on two products (ketoprofen and metronidazole)
.4
and lowered them on two products (methotrimeprazine
and prochlorperazine). The only other company to .2

raise or lower prices on more than a single product 0


Four or more generics
One generic

Two generics

Three generics

was Pfizer.
There were 94 instances (72 different drugs)
where presentations of brand-name products faced
competition from generics made only by indepen-
dent companies (price ratio at the time of generic
competition 0.958 S.D. 0.128) and 11 instances
(nine different drugs) where competition came only
Number of generic competitors
from ultragenerics (price ratio 1.017 S.D. 0.023).
The two price ratios were not statistically different Fig. 1. Effect of number of generic competitors on price of
(P > 0.10), indicating that there was no association brand-name product at time of introduction of generic competition.
between who controlled the companies marketing the Price ratio of brand-name products (price in edition of formulary
when generic competition starts/price in edition of formulary pre-
generics and changes in the price of the brand-name ceding introduction of generic competition). Analysis of variance.
product. P < 0.0001 compared to four or more generics; P = 0.0103

The number of generics available when generic compared to four or more generics; # P = 0.0056 compared to
competition began did not lead to price reductions four or more generics. Bars represent 95% confidence intervals.
in the brand-name drug. Fig. 1 shows the price ratio
for brand-name drugs when they first faced generic
competition as a function of the number of generic
competitors that were initially available. Having four 1.2 ** *

or more generics available was associated with a rise


1 Number of generic
in the price of the brand-name drugs compared to competitors:
the situation where there was a single (P < 0.0001), .8

two (P = 0.0103) or three (P = 0.0056) generic .6


One-three
Four or more
competitor(s). .4
In cases where generic competitors were listed in
.2
six successive formulary editions, brand-name prices
were significantly lower than when generic competi- 0

tion had been in place for only three (P = 0.0241) One Two Three Four Five Six

or four (P = 0.0478) formulary editions. However, Number of formulary editions since


there was no difference in price between generic com- generic competition began

petition for six formulary editions and one or two for- Fig. 2. Effect of time since generic competition began and num-
mulary editions (Fig. 2). Brand-name prices were not ber of generic competitors on price of brand-name products. Price
affected by the interaction between the number of ratio of brand-name products (price in successive editions of for-
generics and the length of time of generic competition. mulary after generic competition started/price in edition of for-
As Fig. 2 shows, even after there had been generic mulary preceding introduction of generic competition). Two factor
analysis of variance. P = 0.037 three editions compared to five
competitors listed in six subsequent editions of the for- and P = 0.0241 compared to six; P = 0.0478 four editions
mulary there was no difference in price ratios if there compared to six. Interaction factor not significant. Bars represent
were 13 generics versus 46 generics. 95% confidence intervals.
52 J. Lexchin / Health Policy 68 (2004) 4754

Whether generic competition started before 1993 At no point in time, did the number of generic com-
or later made no difference in the price ratio of petitors lead to a price decrease for brand-name drugs.
brand-name drugs, although there was a trend to a When there were four or more generic competitors
lower price ratio for drugs with competition start- listed on the Ontario formulary, prices for brand-name
ing in 1993 or later (pre 1993: price ratio of 1.027, products were higher than when there were one to
S.D. 0.022 versus 1993 or later: price ratio of 0.971, three generics. This finding differs from the one re-
S.D. 0.137, P = 0.059). ported by Caves and colleagues. In their study of 30
All of the 15 drugs in the subsample were avail- brand-name drugs that went off patent between 1976
able in all five provinces and had generic competition and 1987, they found that after five generic man-
except for Newfoundland and Labrador and Quebec ufacturers had entered the market, the brand-name
that were each missing three products. Except in one price was 8.5% lower than it would have been with-
instance where the Ontario price was Can$ 0.0001 out generic entry [15]. The difference in the time
higher, the Ontario price was always the lowest. periods may explain the opposite results. In the US
market of the 1970s and 1980s, brand-name products
may have been able to retain market share by com-
4. Discussion peting on price with generics. The smaller number of
drugs in the sample and the limited number of thera-
This study shows that brand-name companies do not peutic classes that Caves et al. analysed may also have
compete on price with generic companies in Ontario accounted for the discrepancy in the results.
regardless of who makes the generic product, how long The finding that brand-name prices decreased with
generic competition has been present and whether or longer periods of generic competition, as measured
not prices are subject to a government imposed freeze. by the number of formulary editions, may have been
In finding no evidence of price reductions, these results a spurious result. If companies do tend to lower
agree with those from most of the American literature prices after prolonged generic competition, then there
[1214]. should have been a difference in brand-name prices
If generic drugs were made by the brand-name after generic competitors had been listed in one or
manufacturers (ultragenerics) themselves they may two successive editions compared to six editions, but
not have felt it necessary to compete on price since such a difference did not exist.
they were getting revenue from sales of their own The percent of the market controlled by provincial
products. On the other hand, if the generics came drug plans will vary considerably depending on the
from independent companies, the brand-name firms particular drug. Drugs used predominantly by people
might have had more incentive to lower their prices 65 and over will be heavily dependent on sales through
to retain some market share. However, whether or not provincial plans, since virtually everyone this age is el-
competition came from ultragenerics or independent igible for coverage. Other drugs, such as those used by
generics did not influence brand-name prices. women in their reproductive years or products heavily
The price freeze imposed on products listed in the prescribed to children, will probably have significant
Ontario formulary in 1993 did not affect prices; if any- sales through the private market. In the latter case, the
thing there was a trend for the average price to be brand-name drug may retain significant market share
higher before the freeze. Before the price freeze, prices and therefore there is no economic rational for com-
rose for a number of products when generic competi- panies to lower prices on these drugs.
tion appeared but the numbers are too small to deter- In the US, drug companies have adopted a pol-
mine if this strategy applied to any particular groups icy of market segmentationretaining product loy-
of drugs or was used by certain companies. Price in- alty in a price-insensitive group and conceding the
creases may have been an attempt to compensate for market in a price-sensitive group [12]. In Canada,
anticipated loss of market share. It is unclear why, af- the private market would constitute the group that is
ter the freeze was imposed, companies chose to drop relatively price insensitive since private drug plans
the prices for some products rather than leave them do not generally require the dispensing of the low-
unchanged. est price generic product. The portion of the market
J. Lexchin / Health Policy 68 (2004) 4754 53

controlled by the provincial drug plans would be the British Columbia and Quebec do not require phar-
price-sensitive group since provincial drug plans only macists to substitute generic products for cash-paying
reimburse pharmacists for the least expensive version customers [29]. Changes in provincial policies about
of the drug included on the formulary. Data on the generic substitution should help keep drugs more af-
public/private market sales of generic and brand-name fordable for cash-paying customers.
drugs included in this study was not available to test Finally, maintaining higher prices on brand-name
the hypothesis that brand-name companies may retain drugs impacts on the prices of new patented medica-
significant market share in the private market. tions coming onto the Canadian market. The Patented
When most of a drugs sales is through the provin- Medicine Prices Review Board (PMPRB), which lim-
cial drug plan, it is difficult to understand the rea- its the maximum introductory price for new patented
sons why companies do not compete on prices. The medicines, currently allows companies to set prices
brand-name industry claims that only 3 in 10 prod- up to the highest amount charged for other medicines
ucts make back their development costs [26], but if in the same therapeutic market [30]. By not lower-
sales have fallen dramatically then maintaining a high ing prices of brand-name drugs, companies thereby
price will not increase revenues. By the time generic enable new entrants into the same therapeutic market
competition occurs, companies have usually stopped to charge higher prices. Patented drugs now account
large-scale promotion of products and therefore there for 65% of total sales of prescription medications, up
is no need to keep prices high to recover marketing from 44% in 1995 [4] and the cost of a prescription
expenses. for a patented medication has been rising between 50
The main limitation of this study is that it only and 500% more rapidly than the cost of a generic pre-
looked at price changes in one of the 10 Canadian scription, depending on when the patented medication
provinces. However, the fact that the price in Ontario came onto the market [31]. The prices for new patented
is almost always lower than that in other provinces medicines is one of the major driving factors in the
lends weight to the assumption that the behaviour of cost of provincial drug plans [32]. The PMPRB is
companies in other provinces, when generic competi- currently reviewing its policies on introductory prices
tion is introduced, is the same across Canada. and should look at the issue of whether to change its
rules in the face of the absence of price reductions of
brand-name medications.
5. Policy recommendations

The report from the Congressional Budget Office 6. Conclusion


in the US notes that the fact that brand-name prices
do not decline following generic competition primar- The lack of price competition by brand-name man-
ily impacts third-party payers that do not manage their ufacturers has economic consequences in the private
outpatient drug benefits and consumers who have no sector and indirectly in the public sector. Drug compa-
insurance [14]. These same groups may also be af- nies cannot be forced to lower their prices when drugs
fected in the Canadian setting. Benefits packages are go off patent and generic competitors appear but both
as high as 7% of an employees total compensation private insurers and government can institute measures
package and companies identify rising drug costs as to compensate for the effects of these continuing high
the number one cost driver in increasing the cost of prices.
health benefits [27,28]. The fact that private insurance
plans generally do not require mandatory generic sub-
stitution may be one of the factors driving up costs. Acknowledgements
Changing this feature of their drug plans may help
employers control costs. Vernon Chiles, Wayne Critchley and Tanya Potash-
Individuals who pay out-of-pocket for prescription nik read an earlier version of this manuscript and
drugs are at a disadvantage due to the continuing gave valuable feedback. Julie Tam provided key
higher prices of brand-name drugs. Currently, Alberta, information about the breakdown of generic drug
54 J. Lexchin / Health Policy 68 (2004) 4754

companies and features of different provincial drug [15] Caves RE, Whinston MD, Hurwitz MA. Patent expiration,
plans. entry, and competition in the US pharmaceutical industry.
Brookings Papers Econ Act Microecon 1991;1991:148.
[16] Jacobzone S. Pharmaceutical policies in OECD countries:
reconciling social and industrial goals. Labour Market and
References Social Policy Occasional Papers No. 40. Paris: OECD; 2000.
[17] Ministry of Health, Ontario. Drug Benefit Formulary No. 29.
[1] Therapeutic Products Directorate. Annual drug submission Toronto: Queens Printer for Ontario; 1990.
performance report, part 1; 2002. Available at http://www.hc- [18] Ministry of Health, Ontario. Drug Benefit Formulary No. 36.
sc.gc.ca/hpfb-dgpsa/tpd-dpt/tpd annual02 e.html. Accessed 5 Toronto: Queens Printer for Ontario; 1998.
June 2003. [19] Alberta Health and Wellness. Drug benefit list. Edmonton;
[2] Anderson M, Parent K. Timely access to generic drugs: 1 October 2002. Available at www.health.gov.ab.ca/Drugs/
issues for health policy in Canada. A research paper prepared index.htm. Accessed 25 November 2002.
for the Canadian Drug Manufacturers Association. Kingston: [20] Manitoba Health. Manitoba drug interchangeability formulary.
Queens University; 2001. 37th ed. Winnipeg; 22 July 2002. Available at http://www.
[3] IMS Health, Canada. Generics share of prescriptions and gov.mb.ca/health/mdbif/. Accessed 25 November 2002.
drugstore purchases 19952001. Available at http://www. [21] Department of Health and Community Services. Newfound-
imshealthcanada.com/htmen/3 2 6.htm. Accessed 5 June land and Labrador drug Formulary. St. Johns; 18 October
2003. 2002. Available at www.gov.nf.ca/health/nlpdp/FORMLARY.
[4] Patented Medicine Prices Review Board. Annual report. PDF. Accessed 25 November 2002.
Ottawa: PMPRB; 2002. [22] Ministry of Health and Long-term Care, Ontario. Drug
[5] IMS Health, Canada. Annual review of prescribing and Benefit Formulary No. 37. Toronto; 7 March 2001. Available
diagnoses trends. Available at http://www.imshealthcanada. at http://www.gov.on.ca/health/english/program/drugs/odbf/
com/htmen/4 2 1 35tables.htm. Accessed 5 June 2003. odbf mn.html. Accessed 25 November 2002.
[6] Hollis A. The anti-competitive effects of brand-controlled [23] Rgie de lassurance maladie. Lise de medicaments. Quebec
pseudo-generics in the Canadian pharmaceutical market. City; October 2002. Available at http://www.ramq.gouv.qc.ca/
Can Public Policy 2003;29:2132. crc/pro/listmed/lm tdmf.shtml. Accessed 25 November 2002.
[7] Lexchin J. The effect of generic competition on the price [24] Saskatchewan Health Formulary. 52nd ed. Regina; October
of prescription drugs in the Province of Ontario. CMAJ 2002. Available at http://formulary.drugplan.health.gov.sk.ca.
1993;148:358. Accessed 25 November 2002.
[8] Tenant L. Dear Prescriber letter. Drug Programs Branch, [25] StatView. SAS Institute Inc.; 1999.
Ministry of Health; 21 December 1998. [26] Grabowski H, Vernon J. A new look at the returns and risks
[9] Currie GR, Nielson NL. Models for funding prescription to pharmaceutical R&D. Manage Sci 1990;36:80421.
drug programs. Institute of Health Economics, Working Paper [27] Fishman R, McLaughlin D. PharmaFocus Canada 1999:
99-5; 1999. looking forward with confidence, Pharma Strategy Group IMS
[10] Gorecki PK. Getting it right: an evaluation of alternative International; 1995.
systems of the organization on the Ontario prescription drugs [28] Canadian Life and Health Insurance Association Inc.
distribution system. Prescriptions for health: report of the Submission to the Standing Senate Committee on Social
pharmaceutical inquiry of Ontario. Appendix 3. Toronto; Affairs, Science and Technology regarding the role of
1990. supplementary health insurance in Canadas health system.
[11] Taylor CL. The corporate response to rising health care costs. November 2001.
Ottawa: Conference Board of Canada; 1996. [29] Provincial Drug Benefit Programs. 23rd ed. Ottawa: Canadian
[12] Grabowski H, Vernon J. Brand loyalty entry and price Pharmacists Association; December 2001.
competition in pharmaceuticals after the 1984 drug act. J Law [30] Patented Medicine Prices Review Board. Compendium of
Econ 1992;35:33150. guidelines, policies and procedures. Ottawa: PMPRB; 1994.
[13] Frank RG, Salkever DS. Generic entry and the pricing of [31] Green Shield Canada. Analysis of drug claim costs
pharmaceuticals. J Econ Manage Strat 1997;6:7590. 19931997. Toronto; 1998.
[14] Congressional Budget Office. How increased competition [32] Federal/Provincial/Territorial Working Group on Drug Prices,
from generic drugs has affected prices and returns in the Cost driver analysis of provincial drug plans: executive
pharmaceutical industry. Washington (DC): US Government summary. Ottawa; April 2000.
Printing Office; July 1998.

Das könnte Ihnen auch gefallen