Sie sind auf Seite 1von 5

Journal of Urban Economics 98 (2017) 15

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

Journal of Urban Economics


journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/jue

Urban economics for the developing World: An introduction


Edward Glaeser a, J. Vernon Henderson b,
a
Fred and Eleanor Glimp Professor of Economics, Harvard University, USA
b
School Professor of Economic Geography, Houghton Street, London School of Economics and Political Science, WC2A2AE, UK

a r t i c l e i n f o a b s t r a c t

Article history: This is an introduction to the special issue of the Journal of Urban Economics on Urbanization in De-
Received 29 July 2016 veloping Countries: Past and Present. We argue that the rapid urbanization and the rise of cities in the
Revised 15 January 2017
developing world demand new avenues of research and much more research to deal with the urban is-
Available online 27 January 2017
sues facing billions of people across the world that current work barely covers. This issue contains papers
JEL classication: which move in that direction and signals a commitment by the journal to pursue this agenda.
O 2017 Elsevier Inc. All rights reserved.
R
H7
O18
P3

Keywords:
Urban economics
Development economics

1. Introduction do not mean to minimize the contributions of early authors who


focused on urban issues in developing countries like Harris and To-
From the dawn of humanity to 1950, the worlds urban popu- daro (1970), Malpezzi (1999) or many others.1 But no one can deny
lation grew by less than 750 million people. According to the U.N., the overwhelming orientation of our eld towards western cities.
the worlds urban population will increase by more than 750 mil- The focus of urban economists on wealthy world cities has cre-
lion between 2010 and 2020. In 1899, Adna Weber wrote that the ated a knowledge gap. We know a great deal about rich urban
most remarkable phenomenon of the present century is the con- areas but far too little about poor urban areas, where the policy
centration of people in cities. This claim seems even more appli- problems can be far more severe. We do not want this journal to
cable to the 21st century than for the 19th century. publish papers that are targeted only at the one-fth of the worlds
Yet 21st century urbanization is different, most obviously be- urbanites who live in Europe and the U.S. This special issue on
cause of the accelerated growth of cities in the worlds poorer ar- cities in the developing world signals a commitment of this journal
eas. Between 20 0 0 and 2020, the United Nations projects a total to publish research on urban issues worldwide. We note with plea-
increase in urban population of 1.48 billion, and of that 1.35 billion sure that we were able to assemble 13 very high quality papers on
will come from less developed regions. In 1950, Europe and the Urbanization in Developing Countries: Past and Present. We em-
U.S. together accounted for 51.4% per of the worlds urban popula- phasize that all of the papers were refereed and went through the
tion. By 2010, Europe and the U.S. account for 22% of the worlds same evaluation process as other papers appearing in the journal.
urban population.
Yet the pages of this journal, which reect the interests of the 2. Whats different about developing world cities?
wider community of urban economists, have been overwhelmingly
dedicated to the cities of Europe and especially the United States The need for developing world urban economics is signicantly
for more than 40 years. In a sense, the geographic focus of ur- reduced if we believe that models and facts established in the
ban economics has been profoundly backward-looking focusing on developed world also hold in poorer places, and in many cases,
the cities that were dominant at the end of World War II, rather we think that is likely to be true. For example, the Alonso-Muth-
than the cities the will come to dominate the 21st century. We

1
http://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S01660462980 0 0210. Glaeser

Corresponding author. also wishes to emphasize that his co-author was a particularly early advocate and
E-mail address: j.v.henderson@lse.ac.uk (J.V. Henderson). practitioner of urban economics in the developing world (e.g. Henderson, 1988).

http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jue.2017.01.003
0094-1190/ 2017 Elsevier Inc. All rights reserved.
2 E. Glaeser, J.V. Henderson / Journal of Urban Economics 98 (2017) 15

Share of Countries over 1/3 Urbanized, by GDP per Capita (2012 $)


1960 and 2010

1
.8
.6
.4
.2
0

$0-1000 $1000-2000 $2000-3000 $3000-4000 $4000-5000


1960 2010
Source: World Bank

Fig. 1. Share of Countries by Income over 1/3 Urbanized in 1960 and 2010.

Mills model seems no less relevant in a mono-centric Latin Amer- during daylight hours and Cato the Elder could effectively protect
ican city than in a mono-centric North American city and the the public water supply. One can visit a more typical city of the
Fujita and Ogawa (1982) model of multi-centered cities and dis- Roman Empire at its height, Pompeii, and see the imposed regu-
persed work places may have special relevance in certain devel- larity of city layout, infrastructure provision, and trac ows. It is
oping country cities with transport infrastructure. And for national hard to imagine Kinshasas rulers being so effective today, and they
economies, transportation-cost based models of urban agglomer- also have to deal with much larger populations.
ation (e.g. Krugman, 1991) seem more relevant in sub-Saharan The great challenge of 21st century poor mega-cities is that
Africa than in the U.S., because transportation costs are so much they must fulll the requirements of connectivity in production
higher. for businesses and address the negative externalities for consumers
Yet there are many reasons to believe that the new urbaniza- of density with extremely limited nancial resources and public
tion is different from the old urbanization, primarily because of the capacity. Cities may be dense but employment can be dispersed
related problems of extreme poverty and poor governance. Fig. 1 with insucient clustering. Congestion can be so extreme with no
illustrates how different 21st century urbanization is from urban- public transport, that walking is the dominant mode of consumer
ization in the past. trips, over 70% in Dar Es Salaam for example (IAPT, 2010). While
Each bar captures the share of countries that is more than one- this may in part reect the problem of urbanization under such
third urbanized within each income bracket, where incomes have limited nancial resources, there are other problems. Corruption is
been corrected for ination. The one-third mark was chosen as endemic. In some countries, both in Africa and in Latin America,
a rough indicator of whether the nation has moved signicantly the state does not enjoy a monopoly on violence. And urban in-
down the urbanization path. The wealthier countries in this group stitutions are weak: property rights are often unclear and poorly
have shown little change over this time period. For example, ap- established. In the key slums in Nairobi, the majority of housing
proximately 80 percent of countries with per capita incomes be- is controlled by landlords who have no legal claim to the land but
tween four and ve thousand dollars were more than one-third ur- are major political gures. Not only do they earn high economic
ban both in 1960 and 2010. The large gap occurs in countries with rents, but they block redevelopment and formalization of the land
per capita incomes that are less than $20 0 0. One-fth of countries to which they have no legitimate claim (Henderson et al., 2016).
with incomes between one and two thousand dollars were more Yet amidst these challenges, key leaders in certain developing
than one third urbanized in 1960 but more than one-half are sig- world mega-cities are trying to address congestion, contagious dis-
nicantly urbanized today. Today, more than 40 percent of coun- ease, crime and high housing costs. In many cases, the experience
tries with per capita incomes below $10 0 0 are one-third urban- of the modern west may be irrelevant and even misleading for
ized. In 1960, no country that poor was signicantly urban. Indeed, them. Some experts argue that exporting western institutions to
throughout all of history, poor countries were predominantly rural. the poorer world has caused great harm. For example, Bold, Collier
Today, great metropolises, like Kinshasa or Nairobi, have grown up and Zeitlin (2009) argue that embracing the post-war European
in places of desperate poverty. model of direct state provision of services was a mistake in sub-
Moreover, the few historic mega-cities of their time that existed Saharan Africa. Brueckner and Lall (2015) remind us that extremely
in nations with low per capita incomes were all capitals of large large minimum lot sizes in parts of sub-Saharan Africa are of-
empires, such as Rome, Abbasid Baghdad, and Kaifeng. These cities ten an overhang of colonial planning, notably the 1947 British
may not have been rich by modern standards, but they were the Town and Country Planning Act, despite the fact that African per
seats of great empires precisely because their governments were capita incomes are less than ve percent of British incomes. Over
the most effective of their era. Consequently, Julius Caesar could 90% of dwelling units in Dar Es Salaam fall below the minimum
address trac congestion by banning wheeled vehicles from Rome footprint regulation. While that might suggest that sometimes bad
E. Glaeser, J.V. Henderson / Journal of Urban Economics 98 (2017) 15 3

regulation simply doesnt matter, that is incorrect. Such regulations We begin with Demography, urbanization and development:
place these buildings in an illegal or quasi-legal status; and, in dif- rural push, urban pull and urban push? by Remi Jedwab, Luc
ferent developing country contexts, this inhibits public servicing, Christiaensen, and Marina Grindelsky. This paper highlights a par-
investment and redevelopment. ticularly important distinction between rich and poor world urban-
In some cases, the Western past may be more relevant for de- ization. The urbanization of the west was largely driven by rural-
veloping world cities today than the Western present, which is one urban migration, which made up for high urban mortality rates
reason why this issue contains several papers on urban history. and lower fertility rates. Poor world urbanization is often driven by
Western cities were poorer in the past, and hence closer in in- high urban fertility rates. Consequently, poorer world cities are less
come to the modern developing world. Historically, western cities likely to be lled with migrants who chose cities because of high
also suffered from corruption and weak public capacity. Yet while economic returns and their demographics tilt much more strongly
the ght against cholera in mid-19th century New York has par- towards the very young. This tilt makes the humanitarian case for
allels with the ght against cholera in 21st century Lusaka, there improving the quality of urban life particularly strong.
are also important differences. Modern Lusaka has access to an- The second paper in the issue is What is Different About Ur-
tibiotics that did not exist in old New York, but it has signicantly banization in Rich and Poor Countries? Cities in Brazil, China, India
less ubiquitous land titling, which makes it harder to impose re- and the United States by Juan Pablo Chauvin, Edward Glaeser and
quirements, like not connecting to sewers, on land owners (Ashraf, Kristina Tobio. This paper asks whether key stylized facts that are
Glaeser and Ponzetto, 2016). well established in the U.S. and Europe also hold for Brazil, China
We therefore conjecture that developing world urban eco- and India. Some facts, such as the strong correlation between ag-
nomics will be more focused on the downsides of density than glomeration size and incomes or the connection between human
traditional urban economics, both because the problems are so se- capital and local success are, if anything, more robust in the devel-
vere and because the ability to just import knowledge from the oping world. Other facts, such as the connection between income
west is more limited. While the literature on the advantages of ag- and housing costs, appear to be weaker.
glomeration may translate readily to poorer places, we know little Gibrats Law, the independence of population growth rates and
about the details. We expect inter-city transport linkages may well initial population levels, also appears to be much weaker in India
be more important in the developing world. But what about hu- and China than in the modern United States, but the third paper in
man capital externalities? Will these be more or less important? this issue notes that Gibrats Law appears to be a relatively recent
Will the young gravitate towards the mega-city of each country phenomenon in the United States. The Settlement of the United
because these cities offer better learning opportunities (De la Roca States, 1800 to 2000: The Long Transition Towards Gibrats Law by
and Puga, 2016), or simply as a location of last resort? Klaus Desmet and Jordan Rappaport document that before World
One particularly salient feature of developing world urban War II, smaller counties displayed convergence and larger coun-
economies is the prevalence of the informal sector in both produc- ties displayed divergence. Both tendencies have moderated in re-
tion and housing. The prevalence of the informal sector is driven cent decades producing Gibrats Law. If the urban systems of China
by poor regulation, weak land market institutions, constraints on and India are in a formative stage, much like the 19th century U.S.,
nancing, and perhaps a lack of demand for formality. Informality then perhaps it is unsurprising that they do not display Gibrats
can limit the public sectors ability to inuence the local economy. Law.
In the business sector, informal rms which are heavily located in Political favoritism in Chinas capital markets and its effect on
informal neighborhoods may rely more on trust and face-to-face city sizes by Ying Chen, Vernon Henderson and Wei Cai reminds
interactions which suggests agglomeration economies will be im- us that political power can also drive urban size and growth. Dif-
portant. However the volume of built space and potentially of eco- ferent Chinese cities face different capital costs largely for political
nomic activity in cities like Nairobi is much higher in the formal reasons. This is not simply favoritism of state owned rms but bi-
than informal sector (Henderson et al., 2016) at comparable lo- ases in the allocation of capital to private rms in particular cities.
cations, hinting at insucient clustering overall as a challenge to These biases adjust over time, as national leadership and appoint-
building competitive cities. ment of aliated local leaders change. Those cities with access
A second feature of developing world urban economies is the to cheaper capital have grown more quickly. This provides con-
dominance of the state sector. Many of the developing world crete evidence of the power of political favoritism to shape urban
mega-cities are built around political capitals, perhaps reecting futures, which we suspect generalizes to many other developing
the tendency of rents to cluster around power. The role of the world settings.
public capacity is particularly pronounced in major countries like Breaking into tradables: urban form and urban function in a
China. There, the government dominates input markets; and many developing city by Tony Venables analyzes when a city may move
of the rms involved in use and production of strategic materials, from simply producing services for a local agriculture hinterland to
as well as development of new housing and commercial buildings producing internationally traded manufactures or services. In Sub-
are state owned. Saharan Africa, most secondary and smaller cities are not indus-
trialized and are highly oriented to agricultural hinterlands. With
increasing returns to scale cities potentially face multiple equilib-
3. The papers in this issue ria, where outcomes may be driven by expectations and/or history.
A citys ability to break into international markets is in part depen-
This volume contains thirteen papers. The rst ve address dent on its cost structure as inuenced, for example, by the effec-
the fundamentals of agglomeration. The next three consider trans- tiveness of infrastructure investments and internal organization.
portation linkages and urban networks, reecting the large impor- The sixth, seventh and eighth papers all address transporta-
tance of transportation costs in the developing world. Two papers tion. Yatang Lins Travel Costs and Urban Specialization: Evidence
deal with the disamenities of city life and the last three with hous- from Chinas High Speed Railway documents the impact that high
ing. The sparsity of such papers on the developing world in regu- speed rail has had on urban growth in China. This paper uses a
lar issues of the JUE reects an unfortunate lack of supply of high difference-in-difference methodology to show that places that ex-
quality research in this area, and we hope that the Journal of Ur- perienced signicant increases in market access because of high
ban Economics will publish many more papers in this area in the speed rail also experienced signicant increases in employment
future. and housing prices. The employment growth is concentrated in
4 E. Glaeser, J.V. Henderson / Journal of Urban Economics 98 (2017) 15

services, not manufacturing, which is natural because high speed Zhang examines a major determinant of housing supply, both in
rail is a more ecient means of transporting business people than the west and in the developing world: maximum height regu-
goods over space. lations. They nd that these regulations appear to be outed in
Locomotives of Local Growth: The Short- and Long-Term Im- about one-fth of their data, and that the rules are broken espe-
pact of Railroads in Sweden by Thor Berger and Kerstin Eno per- cially where land is more attractive. They also nd that height re-
forms a similar analysis of railroads in Sweden over a 150 year pe- strictions place heights far below the level that would maximize
riod. They nd that population growth was signicantly higher in land value. While China is also contrasted with India, which has
places that received early access to rail lines. These population in- even more draconian land regulations, this paper reminds us that
creases largely persisted over time, which supports the importance even in China, land regulations may be signicantly reducing the
of path dependence in city sizes. supply of housing.
An even more extreme case of path dependence is examined
by Maarten Bosker and Eltjo Buringh in City Seeds: Geography
and the origins of the European City System. This paper docu- 4. Unanswered questions
ments the importance of rivers, and other examples of rst na-
ture, in driving the location of European cities 10 0 0 years ago. This issue is a collection of papers on developing world cities,
Transportation by water was much less expensive than transporta- but we very much hope that it is only the beginning of a great
tion by land. The fact that these early locational choices continue research push on developing country urbanization. The promise
to shape Europes cities provides an extreme example of the power of these cities is enormous. They should provide pathways out
of historic transportation advantages to drive modern urban loca- of poverty into prosperity for billions of people. The problems of
tion. these cities are also extreme. Economic research that helps dene
The ninth and tenth papers both deal with urban disamenities. and reduce those problems would have enormous social benet.
Malthus living in a slum: Urban concentration, infrastructure and We end this introduction with a series of questions that we be-
economic growth by David Castells-Quintana follows Henderson lieve deserve more attention from researchers in the future.
(2003) and examines the correlation between urban concentration What are the larger costs and benets of limiting city size? De-
and economic growth. While the correlation is weakly positive, the veloping countries have long featured a prejudice against urban
overall relationship is negative in poorer countries, such as those growth, primarily because of the obvious downsides of density and
in Latin America and sub-Saharan Africa. Within these countries, their inability to deal with these. Urban economists have often ar-
when infrastructure provision as typically measured by sanitation gued that agglomeration economies yield both static and dynamic
access is poor, urban concentration has distinct negative effects on benets, including swifter economic growth. We need more re-
growth, while there are positive effects when there is better urban search on the foundations of city growth throughout the urban hi-
infrastructure. This suggests that the quality of urban infrastructure erarchy and on the macroeconomic impact of such growth on na-
may have signicant macroeconomic effects. tional economic growth in the developing world.
Sewers diffusion and the decline of mortality: The case of What national policies strengthen and weaken developing world
Paris, 18801914 by Lionel Kesztenbaum and Jean-Laurent Rosen- cities? Cities can be shaped by national policies, as both the Chen,
thal looks at the impact of sanitation in Paris a century ago. At the Henderson and Cai paper and the two papers on rails in this issue
start of their period, Parisians typically had access to clean drink- demonstrate. We need more knowledge about the ways in which
ing water but sewers did not yet remove urban waste. The stag- national policies, including transportation, nance and taxation im-
gered rollout of the sewerage system enables the authors to esti- pact the growth of urban areas. If fertility is a major determinant
mate the impact of sewers on both mortality and housing costs. of urban population growth in many developing countries, then
They nd that sewers added several years of life to the impacted perhaps policies that impact fertility, including education will have
residents and signicantly increased housing rents. This work re- an outsized impact on urbanization. Social insurance policies may
minds us that urban sanitation was an extremely important part of also encourage urbanization by reducing the risk-sharing advan-
making western cities livable and taken together these two papers tages of staying close to ones family.
suggest that sanitation is likely to help enable developing world What infrastructure investments deliver the largest benets? In-
cities to be both healthier and more economically productive. frastructure, such as sewers, public transport and roads can yield
The nal three papers in the issue all deal with housing. Shel- huge social benets, including health and connectivity improve-
ter from the Storm: Upgrading Housing Infrastructure in Latin ments. Infrastructure can also generate enormous social waste,
American Slums by Sebastian Galiani, Paul Gertler, Ryan Cooper, through both bad decision making and the opportunity for graft.
Sebastian Martinez, Adam Ross, and Raimundo Undurraga exam- Governments are making vast investments in urban infrastructure
ines a large scale experiment providing pre-fabricated housing in across the globe. Economists need to determine which investments
Latin American slums. They nd that housing improvements have are most likely to yield the highest social returns. Should the
large effects on self-reported well-being. In two of their settings, marginal dollar go to roads or public transport? Is human capital a
they also nd signicant effects on childrens health. This work better investment than physical capital?
suggests that investments just in housing quality may signicantly What institutional improvements are most likely to make cities
improve urban lives in the developing world. more livable? Infrastructure, housing and cities more generally, rely
The Demand for Space in China, by Michael Murray and Guo- on public institutions. Corruption can make infrastructure unsafe
qing Sun examines income and price elasticities for housing in the and wasteful. Incentives may be needed to induce adoption of bet-
Peoples Republic of China. In this case, the results do not look so ter infrastructure, but then what is the feasibility of shaping insti-
different from many ndings in the developed world. The income tutions to provide these incentives? In the West, there is the ex-
elasticity of demand for housing space is .3 and the price elastic- perience with private provision of streetcars, non-prot turnpike
ity is -.4. The elasticities of demand for housing services, which trusts, independent public authorities such as the Erie Canal Com-
include neighborhood amenities, are .7 and -.64. Larger elasticities mission and the Triborough Bridge Authority and direct public pro-
for total services than for space are also a well-known feature of vision of urban services. The relative value of these institutions
the U.S. data. will surely differ depending on the quality of government and the
Finally, To build above the limit? Implementation of land use strength of civic society. We need research about which institution
regulations in urban China by Hongbin Cai, Zhi Wang and Qinghua arrangements are most likely to be effective in poor world cities.
E. Glaeser, J.V. Henderson / Journal of Urban Economics 98 (2017) 15 5

How will technological change interact with urban life in the de- oping world cities. Urban knowledge is disproportionately focused
veloping world? Cholera is far less deadly today than it was be- on the developed world, but urbanization is proceeding far more
fore antibiotics. Uber-like systems provide a tool for making the quickly in the developing world. It is time for urban economists to
jitneys of Johannesburg more orderly. Cell phones increase connec- know as much about Dar Es Salaam as about Detroit and as much
tivity; they potentially reduce the costs of migration and working as New Delhi as about New York.
remotely. Web scrapping for items such as house and land prices
or satellite and aerial images depicting the detail and layout of the References
built environment which are assembled, processed and sold by lo-
cal IT rms improve information and the working of urban markets Ashraf, N., Glaeser, E.L., Ponzetto, G.A., 2016. Infrastructure and development infras-
tructure, incentives, and institutions. Am. Econ. Rev. 106 (5), 7782.
and provision of services. We do not yet know how urban life will
Bold, T., Collier, P., Zeitlin, A., 2009. The provision of social services in fragile states:
be shaped by new technologies, which have the power to make ag- independent service authorities as a new modality. Centre For the Study of
glomeration economies and human capital externalities both more African Economies. Oxford University.
and less important. Some technologies, like the television, reduce Brueckner, J., Lall, S., 2015. Cities in Developing Countries: Fueled by Rural-Urban
Migration, Lacking in Tenure Security, and Short of Affordable Housing. In: Hen-
the amenity advantages of living in a city. Other technologies, like derson, J.V., Duranton, G., Strange, W.C. (Eds.). Handbook of Regional and Urban
Zipcar, seem to complement urban density. What will future tech- Economics, Vol. 5B. Elsevier.
nologies do to urban economies and urban quality of life? De la Roca, J., Puga, D., 2016. Learning by working in big cities. Rev. Econ. Stud. 84
(January(1)), 106142.
What are the appropriate housing policies for developing world Fujita, M., Ogawa, H., 1982. Multiple equilibria and structural transition of non
cities? Many researchers believe that land use restrictions, bor- monocentric urban congurations. Reg. Sci. Urban Econ. 12 (2), 161196.
rowed from the wealthy west, have helped to make developing Harris, J.R., Todaro, M.P., 1970. Migration, unemployment and development: a two
sector analysis. Am. Econ. Rev. 126142.
world cities dysfunctional. But what are the right urban policies Henderson, J.V., 1988. Urban Development: Theory, Fact, and Illusion. Oxford Uni-
for the developing world? How should slums be regulated? Should versity Press.
land titling be prioritized and is titling essential to urban rede- Henderson, J.V., 2003. The urbanization process and economic growth: the so what
question. J. Econ. Growth 8, 4771.
velopment and building high? Are subsidies for homeownership
Henderson, J.V., Venables, A.J., Regan, T, Samsonov, I., 2016. Building functional
appropriate? How should evictions from rental properties be han- cities. Science 352 (6288), 946947.
dled? The land and housing markets of the developing world are IAPT, 2010. Public transport in Sub-Saharan Africa: major trends and case Studies.
Trans-Africa Consortium http://s3.amazonaws.com/zanran_storage/www.uitp.
very imperfect, and we need more research targeted towards the
org/ContentPages/78551334.pdf.
incremental improvement of these markets. Krugman, P., 1991. Increasing returns and economic geography. J. Polit. Econ. 99 (3),
We end this introduction then with a call for more research and 483499.
a commitment that this journal will, as long as we are aliated Malpezzi, S., 1999. Economic analysis of housing markets in developing and transi-
tion economies. Handbook Reg. Urban Econ. 3, 17911864.
with it, maintain a strong openness to papers written on devel-

Das könnte Ihnen auch gefallen