Sie sind auf Seite 1von 17

Party Government in Presidential Democracies: Extending Cartel Theory beyond the U.S.

Congress
Author(s): Mark P. Jones and Wonjae Hwang
Source: American Journal of Political Science, Vol. 49, No. 2 (Apr., 2005), pp. 267-282
Published by: Midwest Political Science Association
Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/3647676 .
Accessed: 10/09/2013 18:32

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at .
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp

.
JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of
content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms
of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.

Midwest Political Science Association is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to
American Journal of Political Science.

http://www.jstor.org

This content downloaded from 136.145.174.50 on Tue, 10 Sep 2013 18:32:49 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Party Government in Presidential Democracies:
Extending Cartel Theory Beyond the U.S. Congress

MarkP.Jones RiceUniversity
WonjaeHwang Rice University

CartelTheory(andpartisantheorymoregenerally)expertlyexplainsthefunctioningof the U.S.Congress. However,as a


to a
theoryoriginallydeveloped study singlelegislature where the institutionalcontext differsgreatlyfrom thatfound in
otherpresidential its
democracies, applicability to thesedemocracies has beenquestioned. Betweenoneextremerepresented
by the UnitedStates control
(wherelegislators their own politicalfuture)and the other represented by centralized
party
systems(where thenationalpartyleadership controls an
exists
legislators'future) intermediate groupof democracies where
subpartybossesarethekeyactors,controllingthefutureofsubsetsof a party'slegislativedelegation.Weanalyzeoneof these
intermediatedemocracies,
Argentina, anddemonstrate thegeneralapplicabilityof CartelTheorytoan institutionalcontext
thatdiffersnotablyfromthatfoundin the UnitedStates.Wehighlighthowthetheorycanbeadaptedto a politicalsystem
wheresubpartybosses,not individuallegislators,
arethemostrelevantpoliticalactors.

Congressional Studies is arguablythe most Venezuela), where the national party leadership controls
US. theoretically and methodologically advanced legislators' political careers (Crisp 2000). This control is
0 subfield in Political Science. However, while primarily the product of the use of closed party lists in
this subfield has dramaticallyimproved our understand- multimember districts and the centralization of the can-
ing of the U.S. Congress, its contribution to the develop- didate nomination process in the hands of the national
ment of general legislative theory has been more limited party.
(Gamm and Huber 2002). Between the extremes represented by the United
United States-basedtheories of congressional behav- Statesand the centralizedparty systems exists an interme-
ior, for instance Cartel Theory and Conditional Party diate group of democracies. In these democracies multi-
Government (CPG) Theory, were developed within an ple subparty (state-level or intrapartyfaction) bosses, not
institutional context that differs dramatically from that the individual legislators or the national party leadership,
found in virtually all other presidential democracies. U.S. control the legislators'political future. Within these inter-
legislators are unique in the level of control they exer- mediate democracies the electoral laws, candidate nom-
cise over their political career, in large part the prod- ination rules, and structure of political career pathways
uct of the use of single-member districts, use of open provide these state/faction bosses with considerable in-
nomination rules, and lack of term limits (Mayhew 1974; fluence over the legislators'political careers(Morgenstern
Morgenstern2003). In an overwhelming majorityof pres- 2003).
idential democracies, party leaders, not the individual This intermediate arrangement is found in several
legislators, control the legislators' political destiny. At federal democracies, where the state-level party lead-
the opposite extreme from the United States are central- ers, not the national party leadership, dominate state-
ized party systems (e.g., El Salvador,Honduras, pre-1993 level politics, and, by extension, the political careers of

MarkP.Jonesis AssociateProfessorof PoliticalScience,Rice University,Houston, TX 77251-1892 (mpjones@rice.edu).WonjaeHwang is


Post-DoctoralFellowof political science, Rice University,Houston, TX 77251-1892 (wonjae@rice.edu).
Researchfor thisarticlewassupportedby the NationalScienceFoundation(SBR9709695),the Centrode Estudiosparael Desarrollo
WethankEduardo
(CEDI),andthe PoliticalInstitutionsandPublicChoice(PIPC)Programat MichiganStateUniversity.
Institucional
Alemain,RubenBambaci,NoraBarraza, PalomaBauerde la Isla,JohnCarey,JamieCarson,MatthewCleary,BrianCrisp,SilvinaDanesi,
ScottDesposato,MarcelaDurrieu,CharlesFinocchiaro, AlbertoF6hrig,ArielGodoy,JimGranato,SimonJackman, EricMagar,Scott
Mainwaring, BryanMarshall, SergioMassa,WilliamReed,Baldomero DavidRohde,Sebastian
Rodriguez, Saiegh,MatthewShugart,and
RossanaSurballeforanswering questionsandprovidinghelpfulassistance, andcomments.
suggestions,
AmericanJournal of Political Science,Vol. 49, No. 2, April2005, Pp. 267-282

?2005 by the MidwestPoliticalScienceAssociation ISSN0092-5853

267

This content downloaded from 136.145.174.50 on Tue, 10 Sep 2013 18:32:49 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
268 MARKP.JONESAND WONJAEHWANG

copartisan deputies from their state. Examples include veloped to explain U.S. congressional organization can be
such prominent countries as Argentina (De Luca, Jones, utilized to explain legislative organization and the func-
and Tula 2002), Mexico since 2000 (Langston 2004), and, tioning of legislative politics in one of these intermediate
to a somewhat lesser extent, Brazil (Samuels 2003). This cases: Argentina.
intermediate arrangement however is not restricted to The contemporary literature on Argentine politics
these federal systems and also can be found in unitary sys- underscores the vital importance of provincial-level fac-
tems where relativelyinstitutionalized intrapartyfactions tors for the functioning of the country's political sys-
exist, and hence where intraparty faction bosses exercise tem. It highlights the provincial-based nature of congres-
considerable influence over the political future of legisla- sional careerpaths as well as Chamber deputies' generally
tors belonging to their faction. Examplesinclude Paraguay strong dependence on provincial party bosses. Based on
(Hernandez Sanchez 2001), Taiwan(Winckler 1999), and this literature we would expect a legislature dominated
Uruguay (Morgenstern 2003). Nonetheless, given the by provincial party bosses, with the legislativebehavior of
greater institutional structure and resources present in deputies determined by the preferencesof their provincial
the federal systems (i.e., autonomous state governments) bosses.
and the more permanent nature of stateboundaries (com- However,when Argentine Chamber deputy behavior
pared to factional boundaries), the power exercised by is examined through roll-call vote analysis, no provin-
state-level party bosses over legislators' careers is likely cial (or regional) effects are uncovered. To the contrary,
to be greater than that exercised by intraparty faction this analysis points to the powerful role in the legislative
bosses. process played by the majority party in the Chamber of
The most promising route by which to improve gen- Deputies. Based on this roll-call analysis, the Argentine
eral theory of legislative institutions is to apply the- Chamber appears to be dominated by the national party,
ories and methodologies developed to study the U.S. with provincial party bosses and their preferencesof scant
Congress to legislatures in other countries (Gamm and relevance for the functioning of legislative politics in
Huber 2002). However, Cartel (and CPG) Theory was Argentina.
not originally designed to explain the functioning of po- The Argentine institutional context bearslittle resem-
litical systems with the characteristics of the "interme- blance to that in the United States (see the next section).
diate" democracies described above.' Cartel Theory is Thus, at first glance, Cartel Theory (Cox and McCubbins
grounded on the assumption that the political parties 1993) would appear to be inapplicable to Argentina,
have virtually no direct impact on whether a legislator since contrary to the case in the United States, provincial
is elected and hence possess little leverage with which to party bosses, not the individual legislators, control the
influence the legislators (Finocchiaro and Rohde 2002). legislators' political destiny. Nevertheless, we are able to
In the United States, the individual representative, not explain this apparentdisjuncturebetween the extant liter-
the party leadership, controls the representative'spoliti- ature and the results obtained from roll-call vote analysis
cal future, in particularthe ability to successfully run for through the application of a modified version of Cartel
reelection (Cox and McCubbins 1993; Rohde 1991), an Theory. Informed by CartelTheory, it becomes clear that
assumption that is invalid in almost all other presidential there actually exists no disjuncture between the literature
democracies. and the roll-call results. Provincial bosses do in fact exer-
Giventhe noteworthy differencesbetween the institu- cise a great deal of influence over the Argentine legislative
tional context found in the United States and that found process, but this influence is not observed in roll-call vote
in other presidential democracies, some scholars argue behavior due to the powerful agenda control possessed by
theories developed to study the U.S. Congress, such as the majority party in the Chamber,which functions as an
Cartel Theory, are of little use in explaining the func- effective cartel.
tioning of legislatures in other presidential democracies The origins of the cartels in the Argentine Chamber
(e.g., Weyland2002). We however contend the theoretical are nonetheless distinct from those in the U.S. House. In
foundations of Cartel Theory are sufficiently robust and the United States, the representativesare the crucial ac-
flexible that they can be adapted to institutional contexts tors who delegate power to the party leadership, while in
that arequite distinct from that found in the United States. Argentina the provincial party bosses are the key players
In this article we demonstrate how a theory originally de- who engage in this delegation, but the end effect on the
functioning of the legislature is quite similar. The ma-
jority party leadership uses its majority status (especially
'FollowingFinocchiaroand Rohde (2002), Carteland CPGTheory
are consideredcomplementary.For stylisticreasonswe thus refer negative and positive agenda control) to dominate the
primarilyto CartelTheoryin this article. legislative process.

This content downloaded from 136.145.174.50 on Tue, 10 Sep 2013 18:32:49 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
IN PRESIDENTIAL
PARTYGOVERNMENT DEMOCRACIES 269

Thestructureof the articleis asfollows.First,we pro- Third,the locus of partisanpoliticsis the province
vide an overviewof Argentinepartypoliticsthat under- (Calvoand Murillo2003;De Luca,Jones,and Tula2002;
scoresits provincial-centricnature.Second,we identify Eaton2002;GibsonandCalvo2000;RemmerandWibbels
the numberof dimensionspresentin Argentineroll-call 2000;SpillerandTommasiN.d.). Politicalcareersarenor-
votes.Third,we examinetheeffectof thepowerof provin- mally provincial-based(with even positions in the na-
cialpartybosseson deputyroll-callvotebehavior.Fourth, tional governmentoften determinedby provincialfac-
of CartelTheoryto Argentina.
we discussthe applicability tors),andthe baseof politicalsupportfor politiciansand
Fifth,we respectivelyprovidetestsof the applicabilityof partiesis concentratedat the provinciallevel.
CartelTheoryto the ArgentineChambervia an analysis Fourth,a singlepersonor smallgroupof leadersgen-
of the internalChamberrulesandof floorandcommittee erallydominatespoliticalpartiesat the provinciallevel
roll rates.We concludewith a discussionof the article's (De Luca,Jones,and Tula 2002; Joneset al. 2002). In
principalfindingsand of avenuesfor futureresearchin provinceswherethepartycontrolsthegovernorship, with
this area. rareexceptionsthe governoris the undisputed(or atleast
dominant)bossof theprovincialparty.Inotherprovinces
wherethe governorshipis not heldby the party,theparty
is nonethelessoften dominatedin a comparablemanner
Party Politics and the Argentine (witha greateramountof spaceforintrapartyopponents)
Chamber of Deputies by a singleindividual.Finally,in the remainingprovinces
wherethe partydoes not controlthe governorshipand
Thisarticleexaminesthe 1989-2003period.It coversthe there is not a dominantboss, there is a small group of
two termsof PresidentCarlosMenem (1989-95, 1995- leaderswho predominatein partylife.
(PJ),the abbreviated
99) of thePartidoJusticialista tenure Fifth,this dominanceof the provincialpartyis based
of President Fernandode la Rfia(1999-2001) of theUni6n principallyon patronage,porkbarrelpolitics,and clien-
CivicaRadical(UCR),whichformeda governmentalal- telism(CalvoandMurillo2003;De Luca,Jones,andTula
liance with the FrentePais Solidario(FREPASO),and 2002; Remmerand Wibbels2000). Dominanceof the
the tenureof interimPresidentEduardoDuhalde(2002- provincialpartyrequiresa bossbe ableto defeatanyrival
2003) of the PJ. In this section we providea series of in a partyprimary.Patronage,porkbarrelactivities,and
generalconclusionsfrom the extant literatureon con- clientelismareimportantfor successin generalelections,
temporaryArgentinepolitics. but areindispensablefor successin primaryelections.In
First, Argentinais a presidentialdemocracy.The addition,patronage,pork barrel,and clientelistic-based
presidentis endowed with considerableconstitutional supportoftenhas the sameanticipatedreactioneffecton
powers, including a strong veto and decree authority. potentialintrapartychallengersthata largecampaignwar
It has a bicamerallegislatureand a federalsystem of chesthasin theUnitedStates;it causesthemto desistfrom
governmentin whichprovincialgovernorsexercisesub- anyattemptto defeatthe partyboss.3
stantial autonomy (Eaton 2002; Spiller and Tommasi The electoratefor primariesis partymembersalone
N.d.). The 24 provincesreceivea number of deputies or partymembersand independents.4When a primary
(minimumof five)proportionalto their1980population. is held, successdependsalmost entirelyon materialre-
TheArgentineCongress,whilemorea reactivebluntveto sources.As former (1999-2003) ChubutgovernorJose
playerthanproactiveagendasetter,is neverthelessan im- Lizurumerecentlystated,"lainternaesaparatopuro"[the
portantactorin thepolicyprocess(Eaton2002;Joneset al. primaryis puremachine](DiarioEl Chubut,7/18/03).
2002). Sixth,Chamberdeputiesareelectedfromclosedparty
Second, during the 1989-2003 period two political lists in multimember districts, lists that are created at the
parties (the PJ and UCR) dominated the political arena.
For instance, in the Chamber the PJ occupied nearly half 1991-95: PJ(14), UCR (4), Others(5); 1995-99: PJ(14), UCR (6),
of the seats (median of 45%, range of 38-51%), and the Others (4); 1999-2003: PJ (14), UCR (7), Others (3).
UCR nearly one-third (32%, 25-45%/o).The remaining 3Challengingthe party boss is always an option. It is however a
seats were held by a multitude of minor parties, with the decision that is taken with great care, since failure often entails
serious negativeconsequencesfor the challenger.
third largestdelegation (a status held by four parties) only
accounting for a median of 5% of the seats.2 4Between 1987 and 2003, in PJ provincial-levelChamberdeputy
primariesrestrictedto party members and open to independents
respectively,the median percentageof registeredvoters who par-
of governors
2Thedistribution (electedforfouryearterms)byparty ticipatedwas 7% and 14%.The comparableUCR figureswere 3%
forthe 1987-2003periodis:1987-91:PJ(17),UCR(2),Others(3); and 5%.

This content downloaded from 136.145.174.50 on Tue, 10 Sep 2013 18:32:49 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
270 MARKP.JONESAND WONJAEHWANG

provincial level through elite arrangement or party pri- suggests that, in addition to a partisan dimension, a simi-
mary (primaries are held using closed lists) (De Luca, lar,regional, dimension may also be present in Argentina.
Jones, and Tula 2002). In most instances the reelection In particular, several authors (Calvo and Murillo 2003;
decision for deputies (as well as their political future) lies Eaton 2002; Gibson 1997; Gibson and Calvo 2000; Sawers
primarily with the provincial party boss(es), not with the 1996) contrast the starkdifferencesbetween the populous
individual deputy. Furthermore,these bosses practice ro- advanced industrial (metropolitan) provinces (Buenos
tation, with the consequence being very low reelection Aires, Capital Federal, C6rdoba, Santa Fe) and their
rates for deputies. Between 1989 and 2003 only a median less populous and developed counterparts in the interior
of 19% (20% and 12% for the PJ and UCR, respectively) (periphery). They underscore the salient metropolitan-
of deputies achieved immediate reelection, with an over- periphery cleavage that exists among the Argentine
whelming majority returning to political posts in their provinces, suggesting its potential to serve as a second,
province, or going to national level posts, often in "rep- regional, dimension comparable to that observed in the
resentation" of their province (Jones et al. 2002). Once United States.5
a deputy obtained a position on the party list however, We examine roll-call votes held between July 8, 1989
his/her probability of reelection skyrocketed to a median and May 24, 2003.6 These data represent six full two-
of 73% (92% and 69% for the PJ and UCR), illustrating year legislative periods, corresponding to the Chamber's
the importance of the influence exercised by the party biennial partialrenovations (1989-91, 1991-93, 1993-95,
boss over the list creation process. In sum, deputies are 1995-97, 1997-99, 1999-2001), and two partial periods
in most cases dependent on the provincial party boss and (July 8 to December 9, 1989 and December 10, 2001 to
hence possess limited political autonomy. May 24, 2003).
The above description suggests we should expect To evaluate the dimensionality of Chamber roll-call
provincial factors to have a powerful effect on deputy votes we use the Bayesianestimation procedure developed
behavior in the Chamber. Provincial party bosses gener- by Jackman and his colleagues (Clinton, Jackman, and
ally exercise a profound amount of influence over both Rivers 2004; Jackman 2001).7 With a one-dimensional
who is elected as a deputy as well as what the political model, the roll-call vote analysis is expressed as:
future of a deputy will be. The following two sections test
for a "provincial"influence in two ways. First, an analysis = Ui( = XijP - ij (1)
Yi* j) - Ui(t j)
of the number of issue dimensions present in Chamber where yj is a choice between a "Yes"position, ?j, and
roll-call voting is conducted. Second, the influence of a "No" position, ij, for each deputy i on each bill j. In
provincial party bosses (especially governors) on the be- this one-dimensional context, Equation (1) for the util-
havior of their provincial copartisans in the Chamber is ity differential y*j can be expressed as a linear regres-
examined. sion with the unobserved ideal points Xi and unknown
parameters pj and otj. We assume Eij - N(O, 1). Xi is
a (n x 1) matrix of ideal points, Pj is a (1 x m) ma-
trix of discrimination parameters, and ou1is a m-vector
Roll-CallVotingDimensions of intercepts. By the assumption of utility maximization,
in the ArgentineChamber > 0, Yij = 0 otherwise. Using a hierarchical
Yij = 1 if
y;* estimated by a Bayesian simulation, we ob-
probit model
Poole and Rosenthal'sseminal work identifies two dimen- tain the parameters.We utilize truncatednormal sampling
sions to roll-call voting in the U.S. House. The dominant to operationalize the probit model (positive and negative
first dimension "almost alwayspicks up the fundamental
economic issues that separate the two major parties of
5Thefour metropolitanprovincesaccountfor 51%of the Chamber
the time" (1997, 27). This dimension "can be thought of deputies.During the 1987-2003 period the PJoccupied the gover-
as ranging from strong loyalty to one party (Jeffersonian norship in a medianof 67%(rangeof 50-75%) of the metropolitan
Republicans or the Democrats) to weak loyalty to either provincesand 60%(55-79%) of the peripheryprovinces.The UCR
occupied the governorshipin a median of 33% (0-50%) and 20%
party and to strong loyalty to the second, opposing party (5-35%), respectively.
(Federalists, Whigs, or Republicans)" (46). The second,
6Only 39 valid roll-call votes were held between December 10,
regional, dimension "divides the parties internally over 1983 and July 7, 1989. For more information on roll-call votes
regional issues" (27). in Argentina,see AppendixA.
The above discussion of the prominent role of the 7Foradditionalinformationon this proceduresee the cited authors
provinces and provincial actors in Argentine politics and AppendixB.

This content downloaded from 136.145.174.50 on Tue, 10 Sep 2013 18:32:49 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
PARTYGOVERNMENT
IN PRESIDENTIAL
DEMOCRACIES 271

infinity are operationalized as +10 and -10). Using a 1 One-Dimensional Analysis of


TABLE
Gibbs sampler, we generate a large number of samples ChamberRoll Call Vote Data via
from the joint posterior density of the parameters and BayesianSimulation
obtain the summary statistics used for inference. We let
the Gibbs sampler run for a long burn-in period of be-
Rateof Correct
tween 130,000 and 350,000 iterations and then saved the Number Discrimination
of Roll Numberof
Legislative of Roll (Percentage
last 10,000 (or 5,000) iterations for inference.8 The esti-
Period CallVotes CallVotes) Iterations
mation procedure provides us with the deputies' mean
and median ideal points and their 95% posterior confi- 1989 23 95.7% 350,000
dence interval. 1989-1991 110 90.9% 140,000
Uniform (1.0, -1.0) priors are given to the density 1991-1993 54 87.0% 160,000
over the ideal points Xi. These uniform priors result in 1993-1995 79 94.9% 130,000
ideal points located within the intervals of 1.0 and -1.0. 1995-1997 56 94.6% 200,000
For one-dimensional fits we assigned initial values for the 1997-1999 29 86.2% 200,000
ideal points, with the PJat 1.0, and the UCR at - 1.0.9Most 1999-2001 81 98.8% 140,000
other parties were placed at 0.0. Normal priors are given 2001-2003 41 97.6% 210,000
for the discrimination parameters p3j:3j -. N(O, 2).10
After obtaining discrimination parameters for each
period, we can determine how many discrimination pa-
rameters are distinguishable from zero. The discrimina- gle dimension are distinguished from those that did not.
tion parameters P3 show "how change in Xi translates By examining these eight figures (availableupon request),
into support for proposal j" (Jackman2001, 229). If only we can determine if a one-dimensional model is a reason-
a small number of discrimination parameters are distin- able fit to the data (Jackman 2001). Since there are few
guishable from zero in a one-dimensional model, then votes that were close and failed to discriminate among
there may exist higher dimensions in the data. deputies simultaneously, it is very unlikely that a higher-
Table 1 provides information on the extent to which dimensional model would provide a better fit to the
the roll-call votes achieved discrimination on this single data.
dimension for each of the eight legislative periods. The Furthermore, all votes that failed to discriminate on
lowest percentage of votes that achieved discrimination is this dimension were examined in detail (through analysis
86.2% (1997-99), while the highest is 98.8% (1999-01). of parliamentarydebates and newspaper coverage as well
The median percentage of votes that achieved discrimi- as interviews with deputies in office at the time of the
nation with respect to the recoveredpolicy continuum is vote) in search of any common trait shared among any
95%. These results indicate there exists only one dimen- of them. No conceivable second dimension was detected.
sion underlying the observed policy space in the Chamber These votes were on transient topics that do not belong
between 1989 and 2003. to any consistent dimension.
In addition, by plotting discrimination parameters Similarto the United States, roll-call vote behavior in
(posterior means) against the percentage of deputies vot- Argentina occurs along a partisan dimension. One end of
ing "Yes,"we obtained a figure for each period in which that dimension is occupied by the PJ (where the median
the roll-call votes that achieved discrimination on the sin- ideal point of the party'sdeputies for the eight periods was
0.58), and the other by the UCR (with a median ideal point
8Thedecision to save the last 10,000 or 5,000 iterationswas based of -0.63), with a considerable gap (median of 1.14) sep-
on technicalconsiderations,and, especiallygiven the long burn-in arating the two parties. The amount of overlap between
period, has no effect on the results. the PJ and UCR legislators also is extremely low, with a
9Theassignmentof priorsis basedon overa dozen yearsof studyof median of only 4% of the PJand UCR deputy ideal points
Argentinepolitics, including extensivefieldworkin the Chamber. having to be moved to yield complete separation between
The priorsonly providestartingvalues.If a deputy'sprior does not
matchtheirvotebehavior,the latterdeterminesthe resultsobtained. the two parties.
However, unlike in the United States, where a less
'OThevarianceprior of 2.0 (which is not overly informative)was
the highest possible while still allowing us to achieveconvergence salient regional dimension has coexisted with the domi-
in all eight periods (given infinite time and computercapacity,this nant partisan dimension, in Argentina virtually all roll-
problemcould be resolved,althoughthe presentresultssuggestthe call vote behavior occurs along this single partisan di-
benefit would be very modest). For those periods where conver-
mension. In spite of the largeliteraturedemonstrating the
gence was achievedwith higher priors (e.g., 8.0), the resultswere
substantivelysimilarto those obtainedwith a prior of 2.0. importance of provincial politics as well as highlighting a

This content downloaded from 136.145.174.50 on Tue, 10 Sep 2013 18:32:49 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
272 MARKP.JONESAND WONJAEHWANG

prominentmetropolitan-periphery cleavage,no provin- PPDhomogeneityis measuredusingthe deputyideal


cial or regionalbaseddimensionwasdetected. pointsdiscussedearlier.First,the standarddeviation(SD)
of eachPPD (the standarddeviationof its deputies'me-
dianidealpoints)of twodeputiesor moreis calculatedfor
eachof the eightperiods.Second,thegrandmeanof these
Provincial Sources respectivePJand UCRPPDSDs is calculatedfor eachof
of Deputy Behavior the eightperiods.Third,PPDhomogeneityis measuredas
the differencebetweenthe party'sgrandmeanSD forthe
The combinationof the provincial-centric natureof Ar- respectiveperiodand the SD of each PPD.Higher(pos-
gentine politics and the powerful control wielded by itive) valuessignifythe PPD is more homogeneousthan
provincialpartybossesoverthe electionof deputiesand the partydelegation'sgrandmean,whilelower(negative)
theirpoliticalfutureleadsus to expectgovernorsto exer- valuessignifythe PPD is less homogenous.This depen-
ciseanimportantdegreeof influenceoverthebehaviorof dentvariable(PPDHOMOGENEITY) rangesfrom-0.36
their provincialcopartisansin the Chamber(Careyand to 0.25 for the PJand -0.31 to 0.25 for the UCR.
Reinhardt2004; Joneset al. 2002; Spillerand Tommasi Careyand Reinhardt(2004) measuregovernorin-
N.d.). Giventheirsuperiorresourcesandinstitutionalad- fluence using a binaryvariable(1 if the PPD was from
vantages,a provincialboss who is a governorwill on av- a provincegovernedby a copartisan,and 0 if not). We
eragebe morepowerfulandthushavea greaterabilityto employ an identicalvariable(GOVERNOR).The rela-
affectthe politicalfutureof deputiesbelongingto their tionshipbetweenGOVERNOR and the levelof PPD ho-
provincialpartydelegation(PPD),thana boss who does mogeneity is expectedto be positive(CareyandReinhardt
not controlthe governorship. 2004).
In their innovative work on Brazil, Carey and GivenBraziliandatalimitations,CareyandReinhardt
Reinhardt(2004) presenta modelwherethis gubernato- (2004) could not distinguishamong governorsin terms
rialeffectis hypothesizedto influencelegislatorbehavior of theirpower.We,however,are ableto controlfor two
undertwo separateconditions.Wherethe governorand vitalfactorsthatinfluencegubernatorial power.First,the
the nationalparty (i.e., the presidentand/or legislative on
rules the immediate reelection of the governorvary
partyleadership)sharethe same position on the legis- acrossprovincesand withinprovincesovertime. Gover-
lation being voted upon (reinforcingprincipals),when norseligibleto run for reelection(andhencemuchmore
a PPD is from a provincewhere a copartisanis gover- likelyto be ableto continueinfluencingdeputies'careers)
nor,PPDbehavioris morehomogenousthanwhena co- are hypothesizedto havemore homogenousPPDs than
partisanis not governor.The more powerfulthis gov- theirlameduckcounterparts(CareyandReinhardt2004).
ernor is, the greaterthe level of homogeneity.Where GOV.REELECTION is coded 1 if the governorwaseligi-
the governorand the national party do not share the ble to run for immediatereelection,and0 if not. Second,
same position (competingprincipals),there is a curvi- governorsvaryin theirlevel of intrapartyoppositionat
linear relationshipbetween governorpower and PPD the provinciallevel. An excellentmeasureof the extent
homogeneity,with homogeneityinitiallydecreasingas of this oppositionis whetherthe governorfaced a seri-
a governorbecomes more influentialand then, at the ous primarychallengeto obtainthe party'snomination
point of nationalparty-governorpower parity,homo- for governor.Governorswho did not face a significant
geneityincreasing.Givenits curvilinearnature,we can- level of intrapartyoppositionareconsideredmorepow-
not fullytestthe competingprincipalshypothesis,but we erful(resultingin higherlevelsof PPDhomogeneity)than
can test the portion most relevantfor Argentina,where governorswho facedsignificantopposition.In the event
governors possess at least power parity with the national the governor's candidacy was uncontested or he/she won
party. a primaryby a margin of more than 50%of the vote, GOV.
The analysis population consists of the PPDs, of two PARTYCONTROLis coded 1, otherwise it is coded 0 (De
deputies or more, of the PJ and the UCR during each of Luca, Jones, and Tula 2002).
the eight legislative periods. Given the different condi- Because of the data'spooled cross-sectional structure,
tions under which the parties' respective deputies func- two sets of control variablesareincorporated. Binaryvari-
tioned, homogeneity data for the PJ and UCR are not ables (splines) are included for the different PPD sizes
entirely comparable. Since pooling data for the two par- (two, three, four, five, six, seven, eight, and nine mem-
ties obfuscates more than it elucidates, we examine them bers), with delegations of 10 or more the excluded cat-
separately. egory. Splines also are included for seven of the eight

This content downloaded from 136.145.174.50 on Tue, 10 Sep 2013 18:32:49 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
PARTYGOVERNMENT
IN PRESIDENTIAL
DEMOCRACIES 273

legislativeperiods(1989 is the excludedcategory).Since ical system.When, however,Chamberdeputybehavior


theyareemployedsolelyfor controlpurposes,anddue to is analyzedusingroll-callvote data,no provincialeffects
spacelimitations,the resultsfor thesevariablesareomit- are detected.This articleexplainsthis apparentdisjunc-
ted fromTable2. turebetweenthe literatureand the roll-callvote analysis
Table2 provides10 models." Models 1 and 6 (PJ throughthe applicationof a modifiedversionof Cartel
and UCR,respectively)displaythe resultswhen, among Theory.
the influentialvariables,only GOVERNORis included. CartelTheory(CoxandMcCubbins1993)wasdevel-
Models2 and 7 includeall threeinfluentialvariables,but opedto explainthe functioningof theU.S.House.Inspite
excludethe splines. Models 3 and 8 include all of the of the dramaticdifferencesbetweenthe institutionalcon-
variables,while Models 4 and 9 are identicalwith the textsin whichtheUnitedStatesandArgentinelegislatures
exceptionthat a fixed effectsmodel (the crosssectional are located,this studydemonstrateshow CartelTheory
unit is the PPD) is utilized.Models5 and 10 arelimited canbe adaptedto explainthefunctioningof thelegislature
to PPDsfrom provinceswherethe PJand UCRheld the in an "intermediate" democracysuchas Argentina.
governorship.
ThefactthataPPDis fromaprovincewherea coparti-
sanis governorexercisesno influenceon PPDhomogene- LegislatorAutonomy and Delegation
ity.Furthermore, whetheror not the governoris powerful
seek Under CartelTheory,U.S. House membersare consid-
(i.e.,can reelection,facesinsignificantintrapartyop-
eredto be independententrepreneurs, exercisinga great
position)alsohas no effecton PPDhomogeneity.Thisis deal of control over their careers (Finocchiaro
thecasebothwhenexaminingthecompletepopulation,as political
wellaswhenexaminingthe subsetof caseswherethe PPD and Rohde 2002). Aldrichand Rohde (2000) and Cox
and McCubbins(1993) highlightthe mannerin which
wasfroma provincegovernedby a copartisan(Models5
and 10).
individualrepresentatives delegatepowerto the House
partyleadershipto further their own reelectionefforts
These resultsprovideno supportfor the reinforc-
both generally(partyreputation)and specifically(perks
ing principalshypothesis.In a similarvein, supportfor of office,pork)as well as to influencepublicpolicy.This
the competingprincipalshypothesiswouldhaveentailed
delegationto the partyleadershiphelps the representa-
powerfulgovernorshavingPPDs that weresignificantly tivesachievetheircollectivegoals.
morehomogenousthanthoseof lesspowerfulgovernors.
No sucheffectwasdetected.In sum, analysisof PPDho- Argentinedeputiesdo not possessa level of auton-
omy comparableto thatof U.S.representatives, but most
mogeneityuncoversno provincialrelatedeffects.'2 bosses do. Hence, in bothlegis-
Argentineprovincialparty
laturesdelegationoccurs.Butwhereasdelegationis bythe
Cartel Theory and the Argentine representatives to theHousepartyleadershipintheUnited
Chamber States,delegationis by the provincialpartybossesto the
Chamberpartyleadershipin Argentina.Thesebossesdel-
in orderto furthertheircollectivegoalof maintain-
A review of the contemporaryliteratureon Argentine egate
controlof theprovincialpartymachineandmaintain-
politics underscoresthe vital importanceof provincial- ing or in the oppositionat
level factorsfor the functioningof the country'spolit- ing (governors) obtaining(bosses
the provinciallevel) control of the governorship.
"Hausman specificationtests comparingfixed and randomeffects Another difference between the two countriesis the
models indicate the models are not statisticallydistinct. The rela- extentto whichone can separatethe partyleadershipin
tionship between GOVERNORand the two governorpower vari- the legislature from the President. In the United States
ablesalso was treatedas interactive,providingresultssubstantively
similarto those here. Wald tests indicate Models 5 and 10 do not these two institutions are relatively separate political
sufferfrom anybias inducedby selectioneffects (Waldtests reacha entities (although see Rohde 1991), whereas in Argentina
similarconclusion regardingthe other models). Autocorrelationis the majority party leadership in the Chamber is in most
not a concern,with AR1values rangingfrom 0.04 to -0.05. Diag-
instances a faithful servant of the President (e.g., between
nostic exercisesindicateheteroskedasticitydoes not pose a problem
for the substantiveinterpretationof these results (standarderror 1989 and 2003 the Chamber majority party leadership al-
inflation/deflationis very modest). ways was comprised of individuals loyal to the President).
12Theuse of alternativemeasuresof PPD homogeneity,based on As a consequence, and similarto the case in most presiden-
uncorrectedandcorrectedPPDroll-callvote cohesion "Rice"scores tial democracies, the distinction between the President
(Desposato2003), providescomparablefindings on the absenceof and his party's leadership in the Congress is not as clear
provincial-basedPPD voting differences.Analysis by Desposato
and Jones(2003) demonstratesthat the PPDs are not significantly cut in Argentina as is the case in the United States (Cox
more cohesivethan their respectivenationalpartydelegations. and Morgenstern 2001).

This content downloaded from 136.145.174.50 on Tue, 10 Sep 2013 18:32:49 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
TABLE
2 Governors and Provincial Party Delegation (PPD) Homogeneity in the Chamber of Deputies

Independent Variables Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4 Model 5 Model 6 Model 7 Mode
GOVERNOR 0.024 0.025 0.039 0.055 -0.016 0.020 0.0
(0.022) (0.025) (0.028) (0.040) (0.024) (0.040) (0.0
GOV. REELECTION -0.006 -0.022 -0.002 -0.015 0.002 0.0
(0.023) (0.026) (0.035) (0.030) (0.039) (0.0
GOV. PARTY CONTROL -0.005 -0.007 0.006 -0.009 -0.064 -0.07
(0.022) (0.023) (0.027) (0.025) (0.037) (0.0
CONSTANT -0.078 -0.012 -0.084 -0.044 -0.068 -0.037 0.005 -0.03
(0.057) (0.016) (0.058) (0.151) (0.051) (0.037) (0.011) (0.0
R-SQUARED 0.061 0.007 0.066 0.037 0.106 0.060 0.030 0.0
ROOT MEAN SQUARED ERROR 0.125 0.124 0.126 0.127 0.110 0.105 0.1
DELEGATION SIZE SPLINES (8) YES NO YES YES YES YES NO YE
LEGISLATIVEPERIOD SPLINES (7) YES NO YES YES YES YES NO YE
NUMBER OF OBSERVATIONS 176 176 176 176 112 127 127 127
METHOD OLS OLS OLS OLS FE OLS OLS OLS OL
POLITICAL PARTY PJ PJ PJ PJ PJ UCR UCR UCR

*Significantat the .05 level. Standarderrorsare in parentheses.

This content downloaded from 136.145.174.50 on Tue, 10 Sep 2013 18:32:49 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
PARTYGOVERNMENT
IN PRESIDENTIAL
DEMOCRACIES 275

PreferenceCoordination and the Majority The Executiveutilizes severalmethods to learn the bosses'
Leadership'sCarrotsand Sticks preferences and to inform them of the Executive'spref-
erences. The most basic is the ability of most copartisans
The U.S. House majority leadership employs a number of
(especially governors) to contact the President directly
mechanisms to insure it has as complete information as to discuss important issues. On a more day-to-day basis,
possible on the preferences of its rank-and-file members the Executivemaintains fluid relations with the provinces
and at the same time to insure these members are awareof
through the activities of different individuals. While these
the leadership'spositions and strategy.These mechanisms individuals have varied over time (in name, number, and
include the activitiesof the partywhips, the representation the formal position occupied), they share the common
of different party sectors in leadership positions, and the trait of possessing the confidence of, and direct access
holding of regularcaucus meetings (Cox and McCubbins to, the President. Party bosses (especially governors) and
1993;Rohde 1991). The leadershipthen uses this informa- national cabinet ministers also maintain an open dia-
tion to draft legislation that will obtain passage (positive
logue, and in the most important policy areas(e.g., educa-
agenda control), to manipulate the legislative agenda to tion, public works) there exist formal ministerial working
insure legislation is only voted upon when conditions are
groups consisting of all provincial cabinet ministers in
appropriate (negative agenda control), and to determine that area.
to what extent individual, or groups of, representatives The Chamber leadership (often in conjunction with
will have to be pressured or enticed into supporting leg- the Executive) uses the information gleaned from these
islation (Cox and McCubbins 1993; Rohde 1991). The interactions to obtain the legislative passage of the party's
leadership possesses a variety of tools with which to pres- (normally the President's) policy agenda. On legislation
sure and entice representativessuch as its control over the that directly affects the provinces it insures the provincial
distribution of committee assignments and the flow of bosses' interests are incorporated (positive agenda con-
legislation (e.g., its ability to coordinate across policies), trol) either in the specific piece of legislation or through
and its power to influence the amount of pork that flows some type of side-payment.13 For legislation that does
to a representative'sdistrict. not directly affect the provincial bosses' interests, the
The Argentine Chambermajorityleadershipemploys Chamber leadership has the necessary information to
a number of mechanisms to insure it has as complete in- know to what extent (if any) it has to entice or pressurethe
formation as possible on the preferences of the party's
provincial bosses to obtain the support of their deputies
provincial bosses as well as to insure the bosses (and for the legislation. In a similar manner, provincial bosses
deputies) are awareof the leadership'spreferences (which gather information on the extent to which they can em-
are generally also those of the President). These mecha-
ploy the votes of their deputies in the Chamber to extract
nisms areof two types: intralegislativeand extralegislative. benefits on this nonprovincial-oriented legislation. While
The intralegislative mechanisms include guarantee- the bosses generallyleave the Chamber'sday-to-day func-
ing that most provincial bosses have a representativeon tioning to the Chamber leadership, they remain alert for
the party leadership committee. Between 1989 and 2003 instances where the President needs to pass vital or un-
a median of 66% of the majority party's deputies came
popular legislation, and hence may be willing to provide
from a province with a member on the leadership com- additional benefits to the bosses in exchange for their sup-
mittee. Another mechanism is the party caucus meeting
port. The default however is for the deputies, absent in-
held prior to every session, where the leadership explains structions to the contrary from their provincial boss, to
its positions/strategy on upcoming legislation and listens follow the instructions of the Chamberleadership.Finally,
to the deputies' concerns (and indirectly those of their in the event an agreement cannot be reached on legisla-
provincial bosses). Finally, the leadership maintains di- tion, the leadership can insure the legislation does not
rect lines of communication with the provincial bosses, reach the floor (negative agenda control).
though the latter normally interactwith the leadershipvia The Chamber leadership possesses a variety of tools,
their deputies. primarily economic and wielded by the Executive, with
The extralegislative mechanisms stem from the which to pressure and entice provincial bosses. During
prominent role of the President (ExecutiveBranch) in the the 1989-2003 period, the median province obtained
functioning of the majority party in the Chamber. The 72% of its revenue from national government transfers,
Executive thus serves as an additional nexus between
the provincial party bosses and the Chamber leadership,
'3Foranalysisof specific legislationand the manner in which the
and at the same time plays a prominent role in informing PPDs obtained benefits for their respectiveprovinces, see Eaton
the provincial bosses of the Executive'spolicy preferences. (2002) and Sawers(1996).

This content downloaded from 136.145.174.50 on Tue, 10 Sep 2013 18:32:49 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
276 MARKP.JONESAND WONJAEHWANG

overwhichthe Executivepossessesa greatdealof discre- resources they receive), and hence a potential leadership-
tional control(Tommasi,Saiegh,and Sanguinetti2001). constituency conflict between the Chamber leadership
WhiletheExecutiveis legallyobligatedto transferapprox- and the provincial bosses is latent in a more limited per-
imatelyone-halfof thefunds,evenwiththese"guaranteed centage of the roll-call votes (primarilyissues that directly
funds"it possessesconsiderablelatitude.Forinstance,it affect the resourcesreceivedby/interests of the provinces,
can delaytransferfor a few months,whichoften wreaks which representeda median of 34%of the votes during the
havoc on provincialfinances(it also can send less than 1989-2003 period). Finally,since the Chamberleadership
the amount merited).Conversely,it can advancefunds realizesthat maintaining the provincial bosses' support is
by a few months, therebyallowingprovincesto resolve vital to the broader goal of implementing the President's
immediatefinancialcrises.The Executivepossesseseven policy agenda (e.g., the leadershipcoordinates acrosspoli-
greaterdiscretionregardingothertransfersrangingfrom cies), when legislation that directlyconcerns the provinces
the implementationof nationalgovernmentprograms is on the floor, the leadershipattempts to insurethe bosses'
(e.g., targetingspecificprovincesand municipalitiesfor preferences are accounted for (either in the legislation or
disproportional benefits)to thedistributionof purelydis- through side payments).14
cretionaryfunds (Gibson1997;Gibsonand Calvo2000;
Tommasi,Saiegh, and Sanguinetti2001). In addition, The Foundation of MajorityControl
the Executiveregularlyassistsprovincesby implement-
ing programsthat bail out bankruptpension systems, Majority control of the legislature in the United States is
rescueprovincialbonds, etc. (Eaton2002; Sawers1996; based on a ideological, reputational,and, to a lesser extent,
Tommasi,Saiegh,and Sanguinetti2001). Finally,the Ex- distributive logic (Cox and McCubbins 1993;Finocchiaro
ecutiveis continuallycreatingand modifyinga host of and Rohde 2002). In Argentina, majority control of the
programsthat subsidizeagriculture,employment,en- legislatureis based on a similar mix, but with the distribu-
ergy,industry,socialassistance,andtransportationin the tive incentives easily dominating ideology and party rep-
provinces.Provincialpartybosses (especiallygovernors) utation. The goals of the provincial party bosses are best
who supportthemajoritypartyinitiativesin theChamber served by distributive policy, since their hold on power
arerewardedvia the abovemechanismsby the Executive, is based primarily on patronage, pork, and clientelism.
whilethosewho failto supporttheinitiativesreceivefewer However, provincial bosses also are concerned with the
transfersand subsidiesand are less likelyto be included national reputation of their party, since its success at the
in the bail-outprograms. national level affects them in three ways. First,the success
of their party at the national level is vital to its maintain-
ing (or obtaining) control of the presidency, and hence
Institutions and the Incentive to Cultivate the distributive benefits they receive from "their"presi-
a Personal Votevia Roll-CallVoting dent. A similarargument appliesto majoritycontrol of the
In the UnitedStates,the institutionalrulesproviderepre- legislatureand the benefits it provides. Finally,the party's
electoral success in the province is affected by the national
sentativeswith a strongincentiveto cultivatea personal
vote throughtheir roll-callvote behavior(Aldrichand party's reputation (Kellam and Alemain 2004; Remmer
and Gd1ineau2003).
Rohde2000). This often causesthem to vote againstthe
There is considerable variance in the level of control
partyline when it conflictswith the preferencesof their exercised by Argentine provincial party bosses over the
constituencies(geographic,primary),an action often
condonedby the partyleadershipif it believesvotingthe political careersof deputies and other politicians. At one
extreme are situations where there is a single boss who is
partyline will underminethe representative's reelection
governor, is unencumbered by any constraints on his/her
chances. Since the representative'sreelection constituency
immediate reelection, and faces no significant intraparty
is concerned with a wide range of issues, this potential
opposition. At the other extreme are situations where the
leadership-constituency conflict is latent in a majority of
the roll-call votes. party does not control the governorship and no one per-
son exercises dominance over the provincial party. Most
In Argentina, the institutional rules (see our earlier
discussion) provide deputies with a very weak incentive to
cultivatea personal vote through their roll-callvote behav- 14Asa result,Argentinedeputiesareless likelyto registera vote
ior; their careeris determined by the provincialpartyboss, positionon thefloorthantheirU.S.coun-
againsttheleadership's
not the voters. Furthermore, unlike the case for the U.S. terparts.The only principal they normally need to satisfy is the
provincialpartyboss, and thus they lack strongincentivesto pub-
representatives,provincialbosses areprimarilyconcerned licly registera vote againstthe partyline, exceptwhen instructedto
with a limited range of legislation (that affecting the do so by the provincialboss.

This content downloaded from 136.145.174.50 on Tue, 10 Sep 2013 18:32:49 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
IN PRESIDENTIAL
PARTYGOVERNMENT DEMOCRACIES 277

PJdeputies have come from provinces with a PJgovernor, There is considerable evidence that in the Argentine
who in all but a few instances was the undisputed party Chamber of Deputies the majority party functions as an
boss. Between 1989 and 2003 a median of 73% of the PJ effective cartel (a la Cox and McCubbins 1993). Given
delegation came from provinces with a PJgovernor (range space limitations however, we restrict our focus to two
of 69-80%). In contrast, only a median of 24%of the UCR key pieces of evidence that provide support for the appli-
delegation came from provinces where the UCR held the cability of Cartel Theory to the Chamber.
governorship (range of 11-38%; 34% for 1999-2001). In
the PJ an overwhelming majority of delegation was by
provincial bosses to the Chamber party leadership, with
CartelTheoryand the Internal
the individual deputies most commonly following orders ChamberRules
from the provinces. In the UCR, there was a broader mix
in the distribution of deputies for whom provincial bosses As would be expected in a legislature where the majority
were delegating power on their behalf and who themselves party functions as an effective cartel (Cox and McCubbins
were the bosses delegating power, although the former 1993), the Chamber rules provide the majority party
easily represented the majority of the UCR delegation. leadership with substantial power and nearly complete
In the United States,the representativesarethe crucial control over the legislative agenda (Danesi 2003; Jones
actorswho delegatepower to the partyleadership,while in 2002). This can be seen in the allocation of the most cov-
Argentina provincial party bosses are the key playerswho eted committee chairs, partisan composition of the key
engage in this delegation (on behalf of their deputies), committees, and construction of the legislative agenda in
but the end effect on the functioning of the legislature is the Rules Committee (Comisi6n de Labor Parlamentaria
quite similar.Justas U.S. representativesdelegatepower to [CLP]).
the House party leadership to achieve collective goals, so Between 1989 (December) and 1999, and 2001 and
too do the Argentine provincial bosses delegate power to 2003, the PJ delegation was the dominant force in the
the Chamberparty leadership (and indirectlyto the Presi- Chamber, enjoying either an absolute majority or near
dent in the case of the majority party). The majority party majority of the seats. The UCR-FREPASOAlianza occu-
leadership uses its majority status (especiallynegative and pied a similar position between 1999 and 2001. While an
positive agenda control) to dominate the legislative pro- absolute majority was rarelyachieved, the majority party
cess, excluding legislation it believes may pass despite its possessed a sufficient number of seats (median of 47%,
objection, as well as implementing legislation it desires. range of 45-51%) such that it was able to exercise major-
The opposition, lacking this agenda control, is left in a ity control of the Chamber, either alone or via the tacit
very reactive position. support of a subset of the numerous minor parties. This
The normal operating procedure in Argentina is for latter ability was enhanced by the fact that the major-
the majority party leadership (generally following pres- ity party was always the party of the President, who was
idential directives) to manage the functioning of the in the unique position of possessing substantial resources
Chamber. In equilibrium, the party leadership, not the with which to influence the behavior of nonmajority party
provincial bosses, exercises the principal day-to-day in- deputies.
fluence over deputy voting behavior. The decisions made While the formal and informal Chamber rules pro-
by the party leadership are though constantly influenced vide for the allocation of some committee chairs to the
by the preferences of the provincial bosses (generally on opposition parties,the majority party generallymaintains
topics that directly affect the provinces), both in terms of control of the most politically important committees (e.g.,
what they place on the legislative agenda and in terms of the Budget Committee alwayshas a majority party chair;
the drafting of the legislation they want to pass. Danesi 2003). The majority party also receives a number
The above realityin large part explains the absence of of chairs far out of proportion to its number of seats.
provincial factorsaffecting the dimensions underlying the During the 1989-2003 period, the majority party occu-
roll-call votes and PPD homogeneity. Of course, provin- pied a median of 77% of the chairs, but only 47% of the
cial bosses reservethe right to dissent (via their deputies), seats. Furthermore, the majority party insures it always
and at times they must be called on by the party leadership possesses a working majority on the politically impor-
to control their deputies. Serious dissent by the provincial tant committees. Finally, the majority party determines
bosses is however relativelyuncommon due to the skill of which committee(s) will review a bill (allowing it to fur-
the majority party leadership (and the President) in in- ther refine the partisan distribution of those reviewing
ternalizing their preferences (i.e., the leadership is a good key legislation) and which will be the lead committee
agent of the provincial bosses). (Danesi 2003). This latter power is very important, since

This content downloaded from 136.145.174.50 on Tue, 10 Sep 2013 18:32:49 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
278 MARKP.JONESAND WONJAEHWANG

the lead committee chair can keep a bill from emerging ogy advocated by Cox and McCubbins (2002) as the ideal
from the committee process, a veto power also held by empirical test for the applicability of Cartel Theory to
the chair of the Budget Committee if it is assigned the a given legislature. Cox and McCubbins (2002) employ
bill. data on majority and minority roll rates, on the floor and
Prior to all legislative sessions, the CLP drafts the in committees, to assess the agenda control exercised by
agenda. While the CLP operates in part based on con- the majority party over the legislative process in the U.S.
sensus, when a disagreement occurs the majority party's House (a party is rolled when a majority of its members
position prevails. When the CLP meets is left to the ma- are on the losing side of a vote that results in legislation
jority party'sdiscretion. The CLP decides which bills will being passed). A complete information model derived
be discussed during the session, who will speak during the from Cartel Theory (Cox and McCubbins 2002) predicts
floor debate, the session hours, etc. The majority leader- the majority party will never be rolled. Through nega-
ship often unilaterally modifies the agenda without con- tive agenda control the majority party leadership keeps
sultation or warning when it considers the modification legislation that divides the party (and which might lead
to be in its best interest (Danesi 2003). Furthermore, the to the party being rolled) off the floor. Through positive
agenda customarily contains more bills than actually can agenda control the majority party leadership obtains the
be discussed, thereby providing additional flexibility to passage of legislation by drafting it (or making alternative
the majority leadership. arrangements) so as to achieve (at least) the minimum
Finally, the majority party leadership possesses sev- threshold of party support necessary.
eral resourceswith which to directly influence deputy be- Neither the PJnor Alianza possessed an absolute ma-
havior. They include committee assignments (especially jority of the seats during most of the 1989-2003 period.
chairs), modest budgetary resources,and control over the However, the combination of the majority party's at least
flow of legislation (Jones 2002). near-majority status in all instances, the fact the oppo-
sition was fragmented among a large number of parties,
and the realitythat the majorityparty was also the party of
Roll Rateson the Chamber the President, turned these near majorities into absolute
Floorand in Committee majorities in terms of negative agenda control and func-
tionally absolute majorities in most instances for positive
The above presentation indicates that in Argentina the agenda control.
majority party functions as an effective cartel. In this sec- Table 3 provides the majority and minority floor
tion we evaluate this premise employing the methodol- roll rates for the 1989-2003 period. Following Cox and

3 ChamberandBudgetCommitteeRollRatesfor the MajorityandMinorityParties:


TABLE
1989-2003
FloorRollRates BudgetCommitteeRollRates
Legislative Majority Minority Total Majority Minority Total Majority Minority
Period RollRate RollRate Votes RollRate RollRate Votes Party Party
1989-1991 1.4 54.9 71 0.0 41.2 34 PJ UCR
1991-1993 0.0 57.1 28 0.0 16.3 49 PJ UCR
1993-1995 0.0 58.3 48 0.0 20.0 75 PJ UCR
1995-1997 2.8 72.2 36 0.0 13.0 77 PJ UCR
1997-1999 0.0 80.0 19 0.0 10.8 74 PJ UCR
1999-2001 0.0 83.3 48 0.0 16.3 80 ALIANZA PJ
2001-2003 0.0 16.7 24 0.0 10.4 48 PJ UCR

Note 1:The 1989 (July8 to December9) period was peculiargiven that the UCR held the majorityof the seats,but due to the earlytransfer
of power agreementbetween PresidentRail Alfonsin (UCR) and President-ElectCarlosMenem, to obtain the latter'searlyassumptionof
office, the UCR delegatedmajoritystatusto the PJ (Jones2002). This period is thereforeexcludedfrom our analysis.
Note 2: Six votes took place during the final six weeks of the De la R6a Administration(1999-2001), at which time a majority of the
FREPASOdeputies had officially (or unofficially) left FREPASOand/or the UCR-FREPASO Alianza,therebyeffectivelyeliminatingthe
Alianza'smajoritystatus.In these six votes, the Alianza"Majority"was rolledtwice while the PJ"Minority"was not rolled at all. These six
votes are not included in this table.
Note 3: The FREPASOfloor roll rate was 86.1% during the 1995-97 period and 80.0% during the 1997-99 period. Due to the small
number of FREPASOBudgetCommitteemembers,comparableroll ratesare unavailablefor the BudgetCommitteeanalysis.

This content downloaded from 136.145.174.50 on Tue, 10 Sep 2013 18:32:49 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
IN PRESIDENTIAL
PARTYGOVERNMENT DEMOCRACIES 279

McCubbins (2002), analysis is restricted to simple ma- (governors) or obtaining (opposition provincial bosses)
jority final passage votes. During this time the PJ was control of the provincial administration, provincialbosses
the majority party, except for 1999-2001 when the UCR- delegate substantial power to their party's leadership in
FREPASOAlianza was in the majority. The principal mi- the Chamber, which for the majority party also can be
nority party was the UCR, except for 1999-2001, when considered delegating to the President, due to the influ-
the PJ occupied this role. ence he wields over the Chamber majority party leader-
In line with Cartel Theory, the majority party is al- ship. As a consequence of this delegation, the majority
most never rolled on the Chamberfloor. The majority roll party leadership controls the day-to-day functioning of
rate ranges from 0% to 2.8%, with a median of 0%. These the Chamber. In sum, provincial factors have a powerful
roll rates are indicative of a majority party with strong effect on deputy behavior in the Chamber. Due however
negative agenda control. With the exception of 2001-03, to the influence wielded by provincial bosses over political
the minority roll rates are very high, ranging from 55% careers in Argentina, and the consequent ability of these
to 83%. bosses to delegatepower to the Chamber partyleadership,
Table3 also provides majority and minority roll rates this provincial effect is unobserved in roll-call analysis of
for legislation involving the Chamber's most prestigious deputy behavior.
and powerful committee: the Budget Committee (Danesi This article highlights the utility of CartelTheory for
2003). The majority party was never rolled on legislation the understanding of legislatures outside of the United
considered by the Budget Committee. In contrast, the mi- States. The U.S. Congress literatureoccupies the pinnacle
nority party roll rate ranged from 10%to 41%. The lower of legislative scholarship, providing the ideal theoretical
minority roll rate for committee votes is due to the fact foundation for those interested in improving general leg-
that while roll calls on the Chamber floor are generally islative theory. While theories developed to explain U.S.
held on only controversial issues, all legislation must be politics cannot be blindly applied to other countries, it is
voted on nominally in committee. possible to adapt these theories and successfully employ
This section provides substantial evidence suggest- them in other contexts (Gamm and Huber 2002). The de-
ing the majority party in the Argentine Chamber func- velopment of general theories of legislative institutions in
tions as an effective cartel. The majority party's control fact requires such extensions and adaptations of existing
over the agenda resultsin it being rolled very infrequently, theory, and given its status as one of the premier theo-
while the minority party suffers rolls on a consistent ba- ries of legislative organization in the United States, Cartel
sis. The majority party provincial bosses delegate a con- Theory represents an ideal candidate for extension and
siderable amount of power to the Chamber party lead- adaptation to other democracies.
ership. The leadership in turn uses its majority power The institutional context in which U.S. congressional
to obtain distributive and reputational benefits for the politics occurs is rather unique: legislators in virtually all
bosses. The minority party often has weak incentives to other presidential democracies possess far less autonomy
support the majorityparty'sagenda, and strong incentives over their political future than their U.S. counterparts. A
to oppose it, given the general lack of distributive bene- fundamental assumption undergirding most U.S. theo-
fits for the minority party and the reputational benefits ries of congressional organization (including Cartel The-
(these legislators are the party'sonly national-level coun- ory) is, however, the existence of autonomous legislators.
terweight to the President) that can be achieved through Therefore, in order for many of these theories to be use-
opposing some legislation. ful for explaining behavior outside of the United States,
they need to be adapted to take account of the different
institutional context present in other democracies.
Conclusion In this article, a modified version of Cartel The-
ory was utilized to help explain why, in spite of the
In spite of a large literature demonstrating the strong provincial-based nature of Argentine politics, no provin-
province-based nature of Argentine politics, analysis of cial effects were observed in analyses of roll-call vote be-
roll-call vote behavior in the Argentine Chamber failed to havior. The article highlights the strong potential for a
uncover any provincial effects. To the contrary, the roll- similar modified version of Cartel Theory to explain leg-
call data highlighted the prominent role played by the islative politics in other presidential democracies where
national party. The solution to this apparent puzzle lies neither the individual legislators nor a single centralized
with the nature of delegation by provincial party bosses. national party leadership control the political future of
In order to further their collective goal of maintaining the members of the party'slegislative delegation. In these
control of the provincial party machine and maintaining intermediate democracies, state-level party bosses (e.g.,

This content downloaded from 136.145.174.50 on Tue, 10 Sep 2013 18:32:49 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
280 MARKP.JONESAND WONJAEHWANG

Argentina, Brazil, Mexico) and intraparty faction bosses to 95% of the floor votes). Similarto the case for the floor
(e.g., Paraguay,Taiwan, Uruguay) exercise considerable votes, the dimension was highly partisan in nature, with
influence over the careers of legislators. Future research the PJ deputies clustering at one end of the continuum
should therefore attempt to analyze legislative politics in (with a median ideal point of 0.72 for this period, com-
these and other intermediatepresidentialdemocracies us- pared to 0.55 for the floor votes) and the UCR deputies
ing a modified version of CartelTheory. In doing so, these clustering at the other (with a median ideal point of - 0.71,
studies will provide invaluable further evidence on the vi- compared to -0.61 for the floor votes). Lastly,in spite of
ability of Cartel Theory to serve as a foundation for the the different legislation being voted upon, and the distinct
development of a generaltheory of legislativeinstitutions. rules governing committee votes (which, ceteris paribus,
result in fewer observable defections from the party line
since it is impossible to determine abstentions and those
present but not voting), the individual Budget Commit-
Appendix A tee members' median floor ideal points during this period
Roll-CallVotes in the Argentine Chamber (0.53 and -0.43 for the PJand UCR committee members,
respectively) were not substantively different from their
Roll-call votes are infrequent and normally taken on con- median committee ideal points.
flictual issues where party leaders (generally of the oppo- For every Chamber session an attendance list is com-
sition) want their vote or that of others (generally of the piled. There are five categories: Present, On Leave, On
majority party) to be on record or, to a much lesser extent, Leave (approval pending), Absent With Notice, and On
where party leaders (generally of the majority) use them An Official Mission. For those voting, there are three cat-
to enforce discipline and enhance legitimacy. In addition,
egories:Yes,No, and Abstain. Deputies who at some point
roll-call votes are mandatory in some instances (e.g., veto were present at the session, but were not on the floor at
overrides).'5 During the eight legislativeperiods, a major- the time of the vote (or chose not to vote) are considered
ity of the roll-call votes were called for by the opposition to be Present But Not Voting.
(median of 57%), followed in frequency by those that Deputies who oppose the position taken by the party
were called for by the majority party (19%), those that
leadership generally will leave the floor at the time of the
were mandatory (15%), ending with those called for by vote or less frequently will abstain. Only on rare occa-
majority party dissenters (0%, mean of 1%). The legisla- sions will deputies vote against the party line. Extensive
tive record does not revealwho called for a median of 4%
qualitative analysis leads to the conclusion that the most
of the votes. common method of opposing the party position on a vote
Despite their infrequent occurrence, an overwhelm- is to be absent from the floor at the time of the vote.
ing majority of the most important legislative initia- There are two principal ways to deal with the reality
tives during the 1989-2003 period were at least partially of Chamber roll-call voting. The first is to only consider
adopted (or rejected)based on a roll-call vote. A review of votes cast as "Yes"or "No," and code all other actions as
legislation upon which roll calls were taken and not taken missing. Such an approach excludes valuableinformation
indicates the former legislation is representative of the on deputy preferences and fails to account for the most
most salient legislation (Molinelli, Palanza,and Sin 1999)
prominent method of expressing dissent with the official
debated in Argentina during the 1989-2003 period.
party position.
Additional evidence of the representativenessof the Another method is that employed by Ames (2001)
roll-call votes is provided by an analysis of Budget Com- and Haspel, Remington, and Smith (1998). This general
mittee votes (where all legislation must be voted on via
approach treats "Yes"and "No"votes in a manner identi-
the signing of committee reports) using the same method- cal to that above. In contrast, deputies who were present
ology described earlier (except with a burn-in period of at the session, but left the floor at the time of the vote or
1,000,000 iterations). The Budget Committee analysis(for abstained (Present But Not Voting, Abstain), are coded
the seven post-1989 periods) provides results comparable as voting contrary to the majority of their party.16All
to those obtained using the floor roll-call votes regarding other deputies are coded as missing (along with the act-
the existence of a single partisan dimension underlying ing Chamber President who only votes in the event of
deputy voting behavior.A median of 88% of the commit- a tie). An alternative way to conceptualize voting under
tee votes discriminated on a single dimension (compared

'5Anonmandatoryroll-callvote is takenwhen a motion for a roll 16The median percentage of deputies who were "Abstain"and
call is supported by at least one-fifth (1989-1996) or one-tenth "PresentBut Not Voting"is 20%. Deputies receive virtually no
(1997-2003) of the deputiesin attendance. public or media censurefor failingto vote.

This content downloaded from 136.145.174.50 on Tue, 10 Sep 2013 18:32:49 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
IN PRESIDENTIAL
PARTYGOVERNMENT DEMOCRACIES 281

this coding rule is it measures whether or not the deputy a few exceptions, deputies who did not achieve conver-
supported the party leadership'sposition on the vote. gence did so due to the small percentage of roll calls on
We adopt this latter method. We strongly believe the which they voted. Following the general methodology of
amount of additional information provided (compared to Clinton, Jackman,and Rivers (2004), deputies who failed
the first method) outweighs any errorintroduced through to register a preference on more than 70% of the roll-
the coding of deputies as opposing the party position call votes were excluded from the analysis in which the
when in fact their absence from the floor at the time of Bayesian ideal points are employed.
the vote was due to some other factor. Based on over a Assessing Markov Chain convergence is crucial in
dozen years of study of the Argentine Congress, we are Markov Chain Monte Carlo analysis. One strategyfor in-
confident this methodology provides the most valid mea- suring convergence is to run the chain as long as possible.
sure of deputy preferences on roll-call votes. Under this Another strategy is to use multiple chains with widely
methodology, the median roll call cohesion "Rice"score dispersed starting points (Gelman and Rubin 1992). In
for the PJ is 54%, while that for the UCR is 50%. our analysis we employ the former strategy.However, as
The consequence of this methodology is that we over- a diagnostic we also conducted the analysis using the lat-
state the level of intraparty heterogeneity and understate ter (with two chains) strategy. Our rates of correct dis-
the level of interpartyheterogeneity.Any errorintroduced crimination, estimates of ideal points, goodness of fit
will however be constant, thereby not affecting intertem- results, and discrimination parametersare virtually iden-
poral comparisons. The errorintroduced by this method- tical when employing the one chain and two chain strate-
ology is much less severe than that introduced by limiting gies (Smith 2003).
the analysis to instances of "Yes"and "No" votes (which
severely understates the level of intraparty heterogene-
ity and severely overstates the level of interparty hetero- References
geneity). Analysis using this latter methodology is not
as valid, is less precise, provides reliable information on
Aldrich,John H., and David W. Rohde. 2000. "The Conse-
fewer deputies, and createsconvergencerelatedproblems.
quencesof PartyOrganizationin the House:The Role of
Nevertheless, its use does not lead to substantive conclu- MajorityandMinorityPartiesin ConditionalPartyGovern-
sions that differ from those in this article. ment."In PolarizedPolitics:Congressand the Presidentin a
PartisanEra,ed.JonBondandRichardFleisher.Washington:
CongressionalQuarterlyPress, pp. 31-72.
Ames,Barry.2001. TheDeadlockof Democracyin Brazil.Ann
AppendixB Arbor:Universityof MichiganPress.
BayesianEstimationDiagnostics Calvo,Ernesto,andMariaVictoriaMurillo.2003."WhoDeliv-
Pre-
ers?PartisanClientsin theArgentineElectoralMarket."
Included in the initial population are all valid roll-call sentedat "Rethinking DualTransitions:
Argentine Politicsin
votes held during the eight legislative periods. Follow- the 1990sin ComparativePerspective." HarvardUniversity.
ing Jackman (2001) and Poole and Rosenthal (1997), we Carey,John M., and Gina YannitellReinhardt.2004. "State-
LevelInstitutionalEffectson LegislativeCoalitionUnityin
exclude lopsided votes in which fewer than 2.5% of the StudiesQuarterly29(February):23-47.
Brazil."Legislative
deputies were on the losing side. Clinton, Joshua,Simon Jackman,and Douglas Rivers.2004.
To insure the sample obtained through the Gibbs "TheStatisticalAnalysisof RollCallData."AmericanPoliti-
sampler is representativeof the underlying stationary dis- cal ScienceReview98(May):355-70.
tribution, we employ a combination of convergence di- Cowles,MaryKathryn,and BradleyP. Carlin.1996."Markov
agnostics as well as a visual inspection of the trace plots. ChainMonteCarloConvergenceDiagnostics:A Compara-
tive Review."Journalof theAmericanStatisticalAssociation
To perform convergence diagnostics and statistical and 91(June):883-904.
graphical analysis of Gibbs sampling output we use BOA Cox,GaryW.,andMathewD.McCubbins. 2002."AgendaPower
(BayesianOutput Analysisprogram;Smith 2003). We uti- in the U.S.Houseof Representatives." In Party,Process,and
lize two distinct convergencediagnostics (i.e., Gewekeand PoliticalChangein Congress: on theHistory
NewPerspectives
of Congress,ed. David W. Brady and Mathew D. McCubbins.
Heidelbergen and Welch; Cowles and Carlin 1996; Smith
Stanford:StanfordUniversityPress,pp. 107-45.
2003).
These diagnostics indicate that, in the eight periods, Cox, GaryW., and MathewD. McCubbins.1993. Legislative
Leviathan: PartyGovernment in theHouse.Berkeley:Univer-
the sample output almost perfectly converges to the pos- sity of Press.
California
terior distribution. More than 96% of the parameters (in Cox, GaryW., and ScottMorgenstern.2001. "LatinAmerica's
the case of both votes and deputies) are statistically sig- ReactiveAssembliesandProactivePresidents."Comparative
nificant at the 5% level in the convergence tests. With Politics33(January): 171-89.

This content downloaded from 136.145.174.50 on Tue, 10 Sep 2013 18:32:49 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
282 MARKP.JONESAND WONJAEHWANG

Crisp, BrianE 2000. DemocraticInstitutionalDesign: ThePowers cians: The Consequences of Party-Centered Electoral Rules
and Incentivesof VenezuelanPoliticians and InterestGroups. in a Federal System." American Journal of Political Science
Stanford: Stanford University Press. 46(July):656-69.
Danesi, Silvina. 2003. "A 18 afios de democracia, la gesti6n en Kellam, Marisa, and Eduardo Alemin. 2004. "The National-
la Honorable Caimarade Diputados de la Naci6n" [After ization of Electoral Change in Latin America." Presented
18 Yearsof Democracy, the Management of the Honorable at the Annual Meeting of the Midwest Political Science
National Chamber of Deputies]. Typescript.Universidad de Association.
San Andres. Langston, Joy.2004. "LegislativeRecruitment in Mexico." Pre-
De Luca, Miguel, Mark P. Jones, and Maria Ines Tula. 2002. sented at "Pathways to Power: Political Recruitment and
"BackRooms or Ballot Boxes?Candidate Nomination in Ar- Democracy in Latin America."Wake Forest University.
gentina." ComparativePolitical Studies 35(May):413-36. Mayhew, David R. 1974. Congress:The Electoral Connection.
Desposato, Scott W. 2003. "Comparing Group and Subgroup New Haven: YaleUniversity Press.
Cohesion Scores: A Nonparametric Method with an Appli- Molinelli, N. Guillermo, M. Valeria Palanza, and Gisela Sin.
cation to Brazil."PoliticalAnalysis 11(summer):275-88. 1999. Congreso,PresidenciayJusticia en Argentina [Congress,
Desposato, Scott W., and Mark P. Jones. 2003. "The Impact Presidency,and Judiciaryin Argentina]. Buenos Aires:Temas
of Federalism on Party Systems." Typescript. University of Grupo Editorial.
Arizona.
Morgenstern, Scott. 2003. Patterns of LegislativePolitics: Roll-
Eaton, Kent. 2002. Politicians and Economic Reform in New Call Votingin LatinAmericaand the UnitedStates.New York:
Democracies:Argentinaand the Philippinesin the 1990s. Uni- Cambridge University Press.
versity Park:Pennsylvania State University Press. Poole, Keith T., and Howard Rosenthal. 1997. Congress:A
Finocchiaro, Charles J., and David W. Rohde. 2002. "Warfor Political-EconomicHistory of Roll Call Voting. New York:
the Floor: Agenda Control and the Relationship Between Oxford University Press.
Conditional Party Government and Cartel Theory." PIPC Remmer, Karen L., and Frangois Gd1ineau. 2003. "Subna-
Working Paper 02-02, Michigan State University. tional Electoral Choice: Economic and Referendum Vot-
Gamm, Gerald, and John Huber. 2002. "Legislaturesas Political ing in Argentina, 1983-1999." ComparativePolitical Studies
Institutions: Beyond the Contemporary Congress."In Polit- 36(September):801-2 1.
ical Science:TheState of the Discipline, ed. Ira Katznelson and Remmer, Karen L., and Erik Wibbels. 2000. "The Subnational
Helen V. Milner. New York:W. W. Norton, pp. 313-41. Politics of Economic Adjustment:Provincial Politics and Fis-
Gelman, Andrew, and Donald B. Rubin. 1992. "InferenceFrom cal Performance in Argentina." ComparativePolitical Studies
Iterative Simulation Using Multiple Sequences." Statistical (May):419-51.
Science7(November):457-72. Rohde, David W. 1991. Parties and Leadersin the Postreform
Gibson, EdwardL. 1997. "The Populist Road to MarketReform: House. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Policy and Electoral Coalitions in Mexico and Argentina." Samuels, David. 2003. Ambition, Federalismand LegislativePol-
WorldPolitics 49(April):339-70. itics in Brazil. New York:Cambridge University Press.
Gibson, Edward L., and Ernesto Calvo. 2000. "Federalismand Sawers, Larry.1996. The OtherArgentina: The Interiorand Na-
Low-Maintenance Constituencies: The Territorial Dimen- tional Development. Boulder: Westview Press.
sion of Economic Reform in Argentina." Studiesin Compar-
Smith, Brian J.2003. Bayesian Output AnalysisProgram(BOA),
ative InternationalDevelopment 35(fall):32-55. Version1.0 User'sManual. http://www.public-health.uiowa.
Haspel, Moshe, Thomas E Remington, and Steven S. Smith. edu/boa/boa_user.pdf.
1998. "ElectoralInstitutions and Party Cohesion in the Rus-
Spiller, Pablo T., and Mariano Tommasi. N.d. The Institutional
sian Duma." Journalof Politics 60(May):417-39. Determinants of Public Policy:A TransactionsTheoryand an
Hernandez Sanchez, Ana Isabel. 2001. "Paraguay."In Partidos Application to Argentina. New York:Cambridge University
politicos de America Latina: Cono Sur [Political Parties of Press. Forthcoming.
Latin America: Southern Cone], ed. Manuel Alcintara Saez Tommasi, Mariano, Sebastian Saiegh, and Pablo Sanguinetti.
and Flavia Freidenberg. Salamanca: Ediciones Universidad 2001. "FiscalFederalism in Argentina: Policies, Politics, and
de Salamanca, pp. 355-421. Institutional Reform." Economia 1(spring):147-201.
Jackman, Simon. 2001. "Multidimensional Analysis of Roll Weyland, Kurt. 2002. "Limitations of Rational-Choice Institu-
Call Data via Bayesian Simulation: Identification, Estima- tionalism for the Study of Latin American Politics." Stud-
tion, Inference, and Model Checking." Political Analysis ies in ComparativeInternational Development (spring):57-
9(summer):227-41. 85.
Jones, Mark P. 2002. "Explainingthe High Level of Party Dis- Winckler, Edwin A. 1999. "ElectoralEquilibria in Taiwan."In
cipline in the Argentine Congress." In LegislativePolitics in Electionsin Japan, Korea,and Taiwan Under the Single Non-
LatinAmerica,ed. Scott Morgenstern and Benito Nacif. New TransferableVote: The Comparative Study of an Embedded
York:Cambridge University Press, pp. 147-84. Institution, ed. Bernard Grofman, Sung-Chull Lee, Edwin
Jones, Mark P., Sebastian Saiegh, Pablo T. Spiller, and Mariano A. Winckler, and Brian Woodall. Ann Arbor: University of
Tommasi. 2002. "Amateur-Legislators-ProfessionalPoliti- Michigan Press, pp. 266-86.

This content downloaded from 136.145.174.50 on Tue, 10 Sep 2013 18:32:49 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Das könnte Ihnen auch gefallen