Sie sind auf Seite 1von 26

The

hte
OVERVIEW _ Model: Fi e
This chapter combine~ the theory of income and
output and the theory of money and interest in a
two-market equilibrium model that shows how the
Price Lev
goods and money markets interact to determine
the level of output and the rate of interest. The
price level is not a variable in this model because
the model retains the assumptions of Part 2: The
aggregate supply curve is perfectly elastic up to
the full employment level of output and does not
shift; and the economy's level of output varies
along the range belOw the full employment level. The next part of the chapter analyzes the sep-
Therefore, changes in aggregate spending can arate and combined effects of increases in invest-
affeCt only the output level; the price level is fixed. ment and the money supply on the income level
The first part of the chapter explains the deri- and the interest rate. The conclusions reached
vation of the IS and LM functions on which the through the use of the I5-LM tool differ from
model is built. At the particular combination of those reached when the goods and monetary
income level and interest rate at which IS equals aspects of the analysis were considered sepa-
LId. there is eqUilibrium in both the goods and the rately. For example, the simple Keynesian multi-
money markets. The IS and LM functions have pliers developed for the two-sector economy In
long been the most basic tools of macroecon- Chapter 5 are now seen to apply only when
omics. The balance of the chapter uses them to events in the monetary sector are such that the
examine questions that could not be handled interest rate remains constant as aggregate
adequately with the tools at hand in earlier chap- spending for goods and services changes.
ters. Following the derivation of the IS and LM The same sort of general analysis is carried
functions is the derivation of the aggregate out in the next part of the chapter for changes in
demand function or curve. This is found from the government spending and taxation. Here again
intersection formed by the IS and LM functions. the simple government spending and tax multi-
To simplify in this chapter, the assumptions are pliers presented in Chapter 6 are found to apply
such as to produce a perfectly inelastic aggregate only when the monetary authority acts to maintain
demand curve. a constant interest rate.

234------~----...::...-----------
The last part of the chapter turns to the ques- theory-which argues that only fiscal policy can
tic1nof the elasticities of the IS and LM functions, be effective. On the basis of this analysis, the LM
and to the closely related Question of the effec- function, if it is assumed to vary from perfect ine-
tiveness of monetary and fiscal policies. The elas- lasticity at one extreme to perfect elasticity at the
ticities of the two functions are analyzed to clarify other, can be divided into a segment consistent
the difference between the extreme version of the with classical theory, a segment consistent with
classical theory-which argues that only mone- Keynesian theory, and an intermediate segment
tary policy can be effective in raising the income lying between the extreme versions of the two the-
level-and the extreme version of the Keynesian ories.

nprevious chapters, we developed sepa- that the interest rate and the level at Income are

I rately the theories of income determination


and money and interest. Although this pro-
cedure provided an orderly introduction to the
linked in a complicated manner. In this and the
following two chapters, we will construct and
employ an extended model that can accommo-
relevant theory, it must now be recognized as date this and other complications.1
highly simplistic. The two parts are actually so
related that what happens in one depends on
what happens ioJhe other. In developing the sim- The Goods Market
ple Keynesian theory of income determination in and the
Chapters 4-7, we found that a rise in investment
spending would raise the equilibrium level of
Money Market _
income by an q.mount equal to the multiplier
Our model consists of two parts: The first draws
times the rise in investment spending. However,
together the determinants of equilibrium in the
we implicitly assumed that the interest rate was
market for goods, and the second draws together
given. If we now admit the interest rate as a var-
the determinants of equilibrium-in the market for
iable in the system, the rise in investment spend-
money. For a two-sector economy, we found in
ing will, by raising the level of income, also force
Chapter 4 that goods market equilibrium is found
up the interest rate. This in turn will discourage
at that level of Y at which the sum of C + I is just
investment, and the actual rise in the equilibrium
equal to that level of Y.Goods market equilibrium
level of income will be less than it would other-
is also defined by an equality between saving
wise be. Similarly, in developing the theory of
money and interest in Chapter 11, we saw that
an increase in the money supply would reduce
the interest rate, as shown by the movement 'The construction here will be almost entirely graphic.
For an algebraic formulation of the same elementary
down the given demand curve for money. How-
model covered in this chapter, see the Appendix to Chap-
ever, this curve assumed a given level of income. ter 12 of E Shapiro, Macroeconomic Analysis-A Student
If we nQw admit the income level as a variable in Workbook, 5th ed .. Harcourt Brace Jovanovich, 1982. A
the system, the increase in the money supply will, concise algebraic treatment of a less elementary IS-LM
by lowering the interest rate, stimulate investment model is provided in WL. Smith and R.L. Teigen, Readings
in Money, National Income, and Stabilization Policy,
spending and raise the level of income. This will
4th ed., Irwin, 1978, pp 1-22 The model, Including a var-
~ncrease the transactions demand for money, iable price level, is developed in R.S. Holbrook, "The Inter-
and the actual fall in the interest rate will be less est Rate, Price Level, and Aggregate Output," in the same
than it would otherwise be. Therefore, it appears .volume, pp. 38-54.
236
and investment. At the level of Y at which S = I,
the leakage from the income stream into S is
exactly offset by I. Money market equilibrium is
defined by an equality between the supply of and
the demand for money-m s = m d-the condition
that gave us the equilibrium interest rate. In other
words, at the interest rate at which ms = md• there
is money market equilibrium.2
The particular level of income at which there
is goods market equilibrium depends in part on
conditions in the money market. The particular
interest rate at which there is money market equi-
librium depends in part on conditions in the
goods market. For a preliminary look at what is
involved, let us briefly review the simplest pos-
sible Keynesian model as shown in Figure 12-1 .
Given the C + I, curve in Part A and the Sand
I, curves in Part B, the equilibrium level of Y is Y,.
If investment depends at all on the interest rate,
the C + I, curve in Part A and the I, curve in
Part B must have been drawn on the assumption
of some particular interest rate. Other things
being equal, a lower interest rate would indicate
a different position for the C + I curve-say C
~
+ 12instead of C + I,-and a different position
for the I curve-say /2 instead of I,. This, in turn,
would indicate a different equilibrium income
level, Y2 instead of Y,. Figure 12-1, however, does
not reveal what the interest rate may be-it
assumes some rate and proceeds from there.

FIGURE 1~·1
2 A more complete general equilibrium model will also Equilibrium Levels of Income
include the market for factors of production. which,
because of the short-run assumption 01 a fixed capital
stock, becomes the marKet lor labor. Equilibrium in this
market requires equality between the supply of and the Figure 12-2 shows the determination of the
demand for labor. From a Keynesian viewpoint. disequi- equilibrium interest rate. Given the ms and md\
librium in this market in the form of an excess supply of
curves, the equilibrium rate is (" at which the
labor-that is. unemployment-can be corrected by pol-
icies designed to raise the level of output-that is, to shift demand for and the supply of money are equal,
the equilibrium In the goods market to a higher level of or mIl + msp, = md, = ms' However, the demand
goods output whose production in turn calls for employ- for money is composed in part of the transactions
ment of more labor. From a classical viewpoint. the same demand which depends on the level of income.
disequilibrium would be removed automatically by falling
Therefore, the md1 curve must have been drawn
wages and prices in a system characterized by such flex-
ibility. Following the development '')1 the basic model, on the basis of some assumed income level that
which is limited to the goods and mo,1eymarkets, attention defined mil' Other things being equal. a higher
will be given to these other questions in Chapter 13. income level would indicate a different position
EquDibrium
in the Goods
Market
Because equilibrium in the goods market requires
that Y = C + I and S = I, all the factors that
cause the consumption function and therefore
mlZ
the saving function to shift and all the factors that
rz r----
cause the investment function to shift influence
I
r, '-"--- the determination of this equilibrium. Although
m'l other factors may be introduced once the basic
model is developed, we assume here that invest-
Tn ment is a function of the interest rate alone and
that consumption and therefore saving is a func-
FIGURE 1.1·~ tion of income alone. From the C + 1 approach,
we then have, in general terms, the following
Equilibriwn Levels of the
three equations to cover the g00ds market:
Interest Rate
Consumptfon function: C = C(Y)

for the curve-say md2 instead of md . This would


Investment function: 1 = I(r)

indicate a different equilibrium rate ~f interest , r.2'


Equilibrium condition: Y = C(Y) + I(r)
at which mt2 + m~ = md2 = m2. Figure 12-2,
however, does not reveal what the level of income From the S, 1 approach, we have, in general
may be-it assumes some income level and pro- terms, the following three equations to cover the
ce~ds from there:' goods market:
It appears that we cannot determine the equi-
librium income level without first knowing the
Saving function: S = S(Y)

interest rate and that we cannot determine the Investment function: I = I(r)

equilibrium interest rate without first knowing the Equilibrium condition: S(Y) = I(r)

income level. Somehow Y and r must be deter-


mined simUltaneously. Although this cannot be One may develop the diagrammatic an~lysis that
done through Figures 12-1 and 12-2, there are follows on the basis of either or both of the
nonetheless a particular income level and inter- approaches. tlut attention here will be limited to
E'st rate that simultaneously provide equilibrium that based on the S, I approach.
in the goods market behind Figure 12-1 and in The set of equations for that approach may
lhe money market behind Figure 12-2. The model be shown graphically as in Figure 12-3. Part A
to be developed in this chapter provides this gives the investment spending schedule. show-
simultaneous solution of the two equilibrium ing that investment spending varies inversely with
values and clarifies some other important prob- the interest rate. The straight line in Part B is
I~s and policy questions. 3 ,
drawn at a 45° angle from the origin. Whatever

J
. .
the amount of planned investment measured

3This model was originally developed by J.R. Hicks in


hiI article MMr. Keynes and the 'Classics': A ~gest~ See also F. Modigliani, "Liquidity Preference and the The-
Interpretation,· in Econometrica. April 1937, pp. 147-59. ory of Interest and Morley," in FA. Lutz and L.w. Mints,
reprinted in W. Fellner and B,F. Haley, eds., Readings'iJJ \ ,005 .• Reaoings in Monetary Theory, Irwin, 1951, partlcu-
the Theory of Income Distribution, Irwin, 1946.pp:- 461-76. lcirlypp. 190-206.
S
I
100 -

____ 1_
o 40

C Saving Function B Saving Inv8strnenl Equality


S = S(Y) 5 c- I

I
I
I
I
IS I
I
I
I IE
---------- -1--------
I
----------:r-
F I I
I I
I I
I I I

'l
I I
I I
I I
I I
! ,I ! -- 1 1 __
40 80 120 160 200 Y o 20 40 60

D Goods Market Equilibrium A Investment Function


S(Y) =
I(r) I= I(r)

FIGURE 12·~
Goods Market ~quilibrium
5, ~
along the horizontal axis of Part B. equilibrium means a low I. A low t is the resuJt of a high r.
requires that planned saving measured along the Although the 15 function indicates that equilib-
vertical axis of Part B be the same. Therefore. all rium in the goods market will be found 'at a lower
points along the 45° line in Part B indicate equal- level of income for a higher interest rate, it alone
ity of saving and investment. Part C brings in the does not reveal what particular combination of Y
saving function. showing that saving varies directly and r will be found in any specific time period. All
with income. combinations on the 15 function are equally pos-
The 15 curve in Part 0 is derived from the sible equilibrium combinations of Y and r in the
other parts of the figure. For example, assume goods market.
an interest rate of 6 percent in Part A, indicating Identifying all equilibrium combinations does
that investment is $20 per time periOd:4 In Part B not. however, mean that the actual combination
to satisfy the equality between 5 and I, saving in each time period will be one of them. There
must also be $20, as shown on the vertical axis. may be disequilibrium in the goods market. Sup-
In Part C. saving will be $20 only at an income pose that tile actual combination is the disequi-
level of $120.5 Finally. bringing together Yof $120 librium combination of Y = $140 and r =
from Part C and r of 6 percent from Part A yields 6 percent indicated as point E in Part 0 of Figure
one combination of Y and r at which 5 = I (and 12-3. At the income level of $140. 5 will equal I
Y = C + I). If we assume the lower interest rate only if the interest rate is 5 percent. Therefore,
of 5 percent, Part A indicates that investment will given this $140 income level and an interest rate
be $30, which yields an income level of $140 in of 6 percent. 5 must exceed t because I will be
Part C. Therefore. Y of $140 and r of 5 percent is smaller at a rate higher than 5 per£ent, but 5 will
another combinatidn of Y and r at which 5 = f. be unchanged. 5 depends only on the level of
Other combinations could be found in the same income, which is here unchanged at $140. The
way. Connecting th~se combinations gives us the combination of Y = $140 and r = 6 percent is
15 ctJrve in Part 0.6' also a disequilibrium from a second point of view.
There is no longer a single level of income at At the interest rate of 6 percent, 5 will equalf only
which 5 = t, but a different level for each different if the income level is $120. Therefore. given the
interest rate. The higher the interest rate, the combimition of this 6 percent interest rate and an
lower will be the level of income at which 5 = I. income level of $140 as at point~, 5 must exceed
Viewed in one way. this follows from the fact that I because 5 will be larger at an income level
a high r means a low f. A low I, through the mul- above $120. but iwill be unchanged. t depends
tiplier.means a low Y. Viewed in another way, it only on the interes~ rate, which is here unchanged
follows from the fact that a low Y means a low 5. at 6 percen.t. It follows that for any combination
Because equilibrium requires that 5 = f, a low 5 of Y and r located anywhere in the space to the
right of the 15 curve. the same conclusion may
be drawn that was drawn for point E: There is a
disequilibrium in which 5 exceeds I and Y
4AII dollar amounts are in billions.
sThe saving function S = Sa + sY is here S = -$40
exceeds (C + I).
By the same line of reasoning, the combina-
+ 'I2Y.
6 A!ternatively, the combinations of Y and , at which S tion of Y = $120 and r = 5 percent indicated as
= 1could just as well be determined graphically by start- point F is a disequilibrium of the opposite kind:
ing with assumed levels of Y.Assuming Y of $120, Part C
Here f must exceed 5. Generalizing as before,
shows ~hat S will be $20. Moving from Part·C through
P".,I B to, Part A. 1of $20 is consistent with" pf 6 Pf;rcent. f~r, any combination of Y and r anywhere in the
Therefore, in-Part D. Yof $120 and, of 6 percent identify space to the left of the f5 curve, there is a dise-
one combination at which S = ,. qui!ibrium in which I exceeds 5 and (C + I)
240----------------------rC~H~APTED:mR;-:lWE~iVCLVE

exceeds Y. In other words. the aggregate spend- Assume in Part A an interest rate of 6 percent,
ing on goods exceeds the aggregate output of at which the public will want to hold $40 in spec-
goods. ulative balances. In Part B, subtracting the $40
of speculative balances from a total money sup-
ply of $100 leaves $60 of transactions balances,
Equilibrium an amount consistent with an income level of
in the Money $120 as shown in Part C. Finally, in Part D, bring-
ing together y of $120 from Part C and r of
Market 6 percent from Part A yields one combination of
Equilibrium in the money market requires an
equa1ity between the supply of and the demand
Yand r at which md =ms or at which there is
equilibrium in the money market. If we assume
for money. The Keynesian theory of the demand
the lower interest rate of 5 percent, Part A indi-
for money makes the transactions demand (here
cates that speculative balances will be $50,
combined with the precautionary demand) a
Part B indicates that transactions balances will
direct function of the income level alone. orm,
be $50. and Part C indicates the income level of
= k(Y) . .It makes the speculative demand an $100 as that consistent with transactions bal-
inverse function of the interest rate alone. or msp
ances of $50. This yields another combination of
= h(r). Total demand for money is md = mr + Y and r~100 and 5 percent-at which md =
ms = k(Y) + h(r). The supply of money ms is
ms' Other such combinations can be determi~ed
determined outside the model--it is exogenous.
in the same way. In Part D, th~ function labeled
This may be written ms = mar in which m8 is sim-
LM results when these combinations are con-
ply the am0unt of money that exists, an amount
nected.7
determined by the monetary authorities. (The
Although particular characteristics of the LM
monetary authorities determine only the nominal
function will call for attention later, in general the
stock of money, Ms. but with P assumed to be
function slopes upward to the right. With a given
stable. determination of Ms also determines ms')
stock of money. money market equilibrium is
This .gives us three equations to cover the money
found at combinations of high interest rates and
market:
high income levels or low interest rates and low
income levels. Viewed in one way, this follows
Demand for money: md = k(Y) + h(r)
from the fact that a high level of income calls for
Supply of money: ms = mil relatively large transactions balances, which,
Equilibrium condition: md = ms
with a given money supply, can be drawn out of
speculative balances only by pushing up the
This set of equations is shown graphically in interest rate. Viewed in another way, it follows
Figure 12-4. Part A shows the speculative demand from the fact that at a high interest rate specu-
for money as a function of r. Part B is drawn to lative balances will be low; this releases more of
show a total money supply of $100. all of which
must be held in either transactions or speculative 7 As with the IS curve. the combinations of Y and r at
balances. The points along the line indicate all which md = m. could just as well be determined graphi-
the possible ways in which the given money sup- cally by starting with assumed levels of Y. Therefore,
ply may be divided between m, and map' Part C assuming Yof $120, Part C ShONSthat m, will be $60.
Subtracting S60 from the total money supply of $100
shows the amount of money required for trans-
leaves $40. As Part A shoNs. this is an amount the public
actions purposes at each level of income on the will be willing to hold in speculative balances, msp. at r of
assumption that k = 1/2. The LM curve of Part 0 6 percent. In Part D. Yof $120 and r of 6 percent therefore
is derived from the other parts as follows, . identify one combination of Yand r at which md = m.,
m,
I

100 I
1

60 ------
i ms = $100
---------1-
I
I
I
! !
I
I
I I
I
I I
_j J..
80

C Transactions Demand 8 Supply of Money


mt = k(Y) m. = mr + msp

;
I
10 ~-
! I
I
I
I
I
I
Fi
6 ---------t-
I I
-1-----------
I E
I I
I I
I I
I I
I I
I I
I

o Money Market Equilibrium A Speculative Demand


m, == k(Y) -;- h(r) m.p = h(r)

FIGURE 1;1..4
Money Market EquWbrium
the money supply for transactions balances. This Two ..Market
money wil! be held in such balances only at a
correspondingly high level of income. Although
EquilibriUni-
the LM function indicates why equilibrium in The Goods and Money
the money market wil! occur at a higher interest Markets
rate for a higher level of income, it alone cannot
reveal what particular combination of Y and (-" Equilibrium between Hie supply of and demand
will be f0und in any given time period. All combi- for goods is possible at all combinations of Yand
nations on the LM function are equally possible r iridicated by the IS curve; similarly, equilibrium .
equilibrium combinations in the money market. between the supply of and demand for money is
As with the IS curve. identifying all combi- possible at ail combinations of Y and r indicated
nations at which md = ms does not mean that the by the LM curve. However, there is only one com-
actual combination in each time period will be bination of Y and ( at which the supply of goods
one of them. The actual combination may involve
equals the demand for goods and the supply.of
a disequilibrium in the money market. For exam- money equals the demand for money This com-
ple. consider the disequilibrium combination bination is defined by the intersection of the IS
indicated by poin,t E in Part D of Fig!Jre 12-4. At
and LM curves derived in Figures 12-3 and 12-4
the income level of $120, md will equal ms only if and brought together in Figure 12-5. in this dlus-
( is 6 percent. Therefore. if we combine this $120
tration, equilibrium in both markets occurs with
income level with an interest rate of 5 percent. Y = $120 and ( =-= 6 percent.
md must exceed ms because md will be larger at
( = 5 percent. The quantity of money demanded
for speculative purposes rises with a lower inter-
est rate. but the total supply of money is fixed.
Alternatively. if we start with the interes1 rate of
5 percent, md will equal ms only -if the income I
level is $100. Therefore. if we combine this
5 percent interest rate with an income level of "Ir ~
/
$120 shown as point E, md must exceed ms 10

because md WIll. be larger at an income level


i "-
'&i>ove $100 than it will be at $100. The quantity 81- "-
of money demanded for transactions rises with
a higher income. but the total money suppiy is. I
I IV
q-----------
as before. fixed. What has been concluded for
the combination indicated by point E holds true I
for any combination located in the space to the III
right of the LM curve; any combination of Y and I

( in this space is necessarily a disequilibrium ) I- :


combi[1ation in which md exceeds ms' I
1 1. .1
: _-L- , __
By the same reasoning. the combination of I
,

v
Y = $100 and r = 6 percent indicated as point o 1 4L: 80 1 ~c: 1CJ 200 ;l4q 1

__ I ._. . _
F is a disequilibrium of the opposite kind: ms must
here exceed md. Generalizing as before. there is FIG1JP..J: 12 5 9

a disequilibrium in which ms exceeds mCI for any Equilibrium in 'the Goods and
combination of Y and ( located in the space to Money Markets
tr-18 ieTt of the L:'v1 curve.
From Disequilibrium to for goods and the direction in which the interest
Equilibrium rate tends to move in response to an excess sup-
Every possible combination of Y and r in Figure ply or excess demand for money, we can trace
12-5 other than that given by the intersection of out in a nonrigorous fashion a possible path that
the IS and LM curves is one at which there is the income level and the interest rate may follow
disequilibrium in the goods market, the money in response to any given disequilibrium situation.
if) Figure 12-6 we assume the economy is
market, or both. All those combinations that do
not lie on either the IS or the LM curve fall into located at the disequilibrium combination of Y
this last category. Because all such combinations and r indicated by A, which is in Space IiI. Here
do not lie on a line, they necessarily jie in one of there is an excess demand for goods and an
the four areas identified by the Roman numerals excess demand for money. The excess demand
I through IV As we saw earlier, any combination for goods tends to raise the income level. as
of Y andr that lies anywhere to the right of the IS indicated by the horizontal arrow originating at A.
curve is a combination at which S > I and Y > The excess demand for money tends to push up
(C + I). The opposite is true for any combination the interest rate, as indicated by the vertical
of Y and r anywhere to the left of the IS curve. arrow originating at A. With these forces at work,
Similarly, any combination of Y and r anywhere it is not unreasonable to expect the economy to
to the right of the LM curve is a combination at move along the path designated by the arrow
which md > ms' The opposite is true for any com- from A~to B. Next, with the economy at B, the
bination to the left of the LM curve. Accordingly, supply of and demand for goods are equal,
each of the four spa~s may be distinguished
from the other three in terms of the relationships
between the supply of and demand for goods
and between·the supply of and demand for
money for any-'combination of Y and r that falls
within that space:

Money
Goods Market Market
In Space I: f < S, (C + I) < Y md < ms
In Space II: 1< S, (C + I) < Y md> ms
In Space III: I> S, (C + I) > Y md> ms
In Space IV: I> S, (C + I) > Y md < ms

From the analysis of the goods market con-


sidered in isolation, we know that a situation in
which' I > S or (C + I) :> Y will lead to a rise in
income and vice versa. From the analysis of the
money market considered in isolation, we know
that a situation in which m d > m s will lead to a rise
in the interest rate and vice versa. What we now
have in the four spaces laid out in Figure 12-5 FIGURE 12-6
are various combinations of IS and LM disequi- Possible Paths of Movement to
.Iibrium situations. Because we know the direction Equilibrium in the Goods an4
in which the income .level tends to move in Money Markets
. response to an excess supply or excess demand
because we are on the IS curve. But we are still D. As was shown for themovement-from-A.t6 the
at a point to the right of the LM curve, so the intersection, the continuous;pa.th-th_at;t~~ ~
demand for money exceeds the supply of money. omy might follow fro~ E to H and then to the
Therefore, a force is at work to push up the inter- intersection is indicated by a dashed line. Once
est rate and the next movement may be along at the intersection. the combination of Y and ,
the arrowfrom B to C. At C there is still an excess provides equilibrium in both markets; the income
demand for money, which again tends to push level and the interest rate will remain unchanged
up the inlerest rate as indicated by the vertical until the existing equilibrium is upset by a shift in
arrow originating at C. However, at C there is an the IS or LM curve. or in both.8
excess supply of goods, "thich tends to reduc€
the income level as shown by the horizontal arrow
originating at C. These forces may on balance E5-LM Equilibrium and the
cause the economy to move along the path Aggregate Demand Curve
described by the arrow running from C to D. At In th~simple classical theory of Chapter 9, the
0, the forces are the same as at C; the result is aggregate demand curve was derived from the
a movelTocnt of the same kind. The combination quantity of money and appeared graphically as
of income level and interest rate may change in a downward sloping curve (rectangular hyper-
this way over time until finally the system reaches bola). Given the classical theory's conclusion
that one combination of Y and r at which both that the aggregate supply curve is a perfectly
markets clear. Although the several discrete inelastic line situated at the full employment level
steps traced out here help reveal the-underlying of output, the intersection of the AD curve with
process at work, the actual process would be a the AS curve did no more than determine the
continuous one in which Y and r might move price level of the full employment output.
..
along a path like that indicated by the dashed
line running from A to 0 and then to the intersec-
The model being constructed in this chapter
includes the opposite extreme for the AS curve-
tion of the two curves. that is. one that is perfectly elastic up to the full
Instead of starting at A, we could start at any employment level of output but perfectly inelastic
other disequilibrium point in Figure 12-6 and at that level. This kind of AS curve is shown in
trace the movement of Y and r toward the single Part B of Figure 12-7. The present model also
pair of equilibrium values in the same way. No assumes that the economy operates below the
matter what disequilibrium point one starts with, full employment level of output-that is, along the
all one need do is (1) identify whether I > S, 1< perfectly elastic portion of the AS curve. Some
S, or I = S, or in terms of aggregate spending
whether (C + !) > Y, (C + I) < Y, or (C + I) =
Y, which te!ls whether Y will tend to rise, fall, or 8 Although it is quite illuminating to trace the path fol-

remain unchanged; (2) identify whether md > ms' lowed by Y and' as we have done here. the IS-LM model
md < ms' or md = ms' which tells whether r will , now before us does not in itself reveal that Y and , will
follow the path here described or any other particular path
tend to rise, tall, or remain unchanged; and (3)
from an initial disequilibrium position like A or E. As briefly
establish the direction of movement at the Y, r explained in Chapter 3. to trace the process of change in
combination indicated by the forces found to be the values of a model's variables from one period to
at work in (1) and (2). For example, starting with another can be done only with a dynamic model. The
any point in Space I such as E, forces tend to IS-LM model isnot dynamic, but completely static. It iden-
tifies the values the variables must exhibit in order that
reduce both the income level and the interest
there be equilibrium. but it does not show the sequence
rate. The reader may trace the discr€te steps - of changes by which these values will be reached if we
from E thrOi !gh H, which are different In direction start off with any values eltler than Ihese equilibrium
but exactly symmetrical with those from A through values.
ular IS and LM curves, and it is from the inter-
section of this pair of curves that the AD curve is
i derived in the present model. To derive the AD
12 r-
curve, we make one final assumption-that nei-
ther the IS nor the LM curve shifts with changes
in the price level. This assumption enables us to
postpone dealing with some major complications
until Chapter 13.
With this 3ssumption, whatever the price level
might be-1, 2, 3, 4, or any other level in Part B
of Figure 12-7-the IS and LM curves remain in
the position shown in Part A. Therefore, corre-
4,
sponding to each possible price level on the ver-
tical axis of Part B, we have the same pair of IS
2 ,-
and LM curves and the same equilibrium figure
IS
of 120 for the output level found in Part A. The
'- - ... -' . AD curve shows the toial amount of goods
0 40 80 160 200 240 Y
demanded at various price levels, but on the
A
present assumption that amount is a constant
P 120. Therefore, the aggregate AD c.urve is per-
AD AS fectly inelastic at the output level of 120, as
4 shown in Part B. Throughout the balance of this
3 chapter we will assume that the IS andLM curves
2 do not shift with the price level; therefore all of
"'~ 1 the AD curves will be perfectly inelastic. How-
i. ......... - ever, these AD curves can shift :to the right or the
0 40 80 120 160 200 240 Y left, and we next look at some of the factors· that
~ will produce such shifts.

FIGURE 12·7
The IS-LM Curves and the q,.;mges in Aggregate
Aggregate Demand Curve
Demand_· _' _
,...--- .,-
//

:other assumptions finally yield the conclusion The eqUilibrium combination of Yand r identified
that the level of output is determined entirely-p¥' by the intersection of the IS and LMfunct~ons will,
aggregate-demand. In this case, aggregate'sup- of course, change in response to any.$hift in
1,~ly only determines the' price level at which that those functions, and the AD curve will s~ift to the
'output will sell. level of Y identified by the new infers~ctiof) ...Shifts
.:. ,:.J,n this model, the derivation of the AD curve .in the IS function are caused by shifts· in the
is more complicated than in the simple classical investment or the saving function (parts A"and . .c
model in which it only depends on the supply of of Figure 12-3); ,shifts in the LM, -function ar~
money Here it depends on all the factors that caused by shifts in the, money supply, transac-·
determine the positions of the IS and LM curves. tions demand, or speculative demand functions
The supply of money is only one of these factors. (Parts B, C, and A, respectively, of Figure 12-4).
At any time, these factors will determine partic~ Finally, a shift in any of the functions on which the
Is and LM curves are based may result from a age point) as shown by the intersection of IS2 and
change in the factors that determine the positions LM in Part D. As the increase ,
in investment.
of the-se functions. This givBs us a method of ana- spending starts an upward movement in income,
lyzing the effects of a change in any of these the rising income level increases the money bal-
underlying factors. We can trace a change in any ances needed for transactions purposes. This
factor through the system to its final effect on the leads to a rising interest rate, which in turn feeds
income level and interest rate-assuming, of back to make the increase in investment spend-
course, that all other factors remain unchanged. ing less than the $20 and the increase in income
Given the assumed shape of the aggregate sup- less than the $40 they would have been with no
ply curve, none of these changes will affect the rise in the interest rate. In the present illustration,
price .Ievel. with the LM curve as given, the shift in the IS
curve caused by a rightward shift of $20 in the
investment curve raises Y by $20 and r by one
A Change in Investment percentage point. The $20 rise in Y means an
Among the various possibilities, a shift in the increase of $10 in required transactions bal-
investment curve is one of the most important. ances, given k = 0.5. The rise in r of one pe~-
Suppose a change in an underlying factor-for centage point is just sufficient to reduce th~
-example, an improvement in business expecta- amount of money the public wishes to hold in
tions-causes this'curve to shift $20 to the right speculative balances by $10, thereby supplying
at each rate~of interest. In Part A of Figure 12-8, the additional $10 needed for transactions bak
the original curve is labeled I, and the new one ances. Therefore, with ~ Y = $20 and ~r of one
12, In Figure 12-3, an IS curve was derived graph- percentage point, the supply of and demand for
ically from the investment and saving curves money will again be in balance.
given there. Similarly, in Figure 12-8, a separate The same one percentage point rise in r will
IS curve may be derived from each of the invest- decrease investment from $20 to $10. As may be -
ment curves in combination with the given saving seen in Part A of Figure 12-8, investment-which
curve. In Part D, the IS, and IS2 curves are based would have risen from its original $20 at r -of
on the I, and 12 curves, respectively. At each 6 percent (point E) to $40 with no change in r
interest rate, IS2 lies $40 to the right of IS,. In (Point F)-only rises from $20 to $30 (point G)
other words, at each interest rate the level of because one half of what would have been the
income at which S = I is now $40 greater than larger increase is choked off by the rise in r from
it was before the shift in the investment schedule. 6 to 7 percent. The final increase in investment
This follows from the fact that, with an increase of $10 turns out to be the same amount as the
of $20 in investment, income must rise by $40 to increase in saving that occurs with a rise in
induce an increase of $20 in saving, given that income of $20. From ~S = s(~Y), we here have
the MPS is 1/2. This is nothing more than the $1g- = 0.5($20). With ~ Y = $20 and ~r of one
simple multiplier in action, ~ Y(1 /MPS~/, which percentage point, S will again equal I and Y will
gives us $40 = 2'· $20. again equal C + '- No other combination of
, The original equilibrium was earlier -found at changes in Y and r will be consistent with equi-
Y pf $120 and r of 6 percent. Here it is shown librium in both the goods and money rn'arkets,
a@ain by the intersection of IS, and L,M in Part D assuming the indicated rightward shift in the
of Fig'Jre 12-8. As before, this gives us the AD, investment schedule with all else as given.
curve positioned at Y of $120 in Part E. The LM For a leftward shift in the investment sched-
curve here is the sa\Tle as the one derived in Fig- ule, the results will be the opposite. If the invest-
ure 12-4. The new equilibrium that results from - ment schedule of Part A were to shift to the left
the shift in the investment curve is at Y of $140 by $20 or from " to '3' the new equilibrium in
and r of 7 percent (an 'increase of one percent- Part D wQuld show Yof $100 and r of 5 percent.
S s
!
100 l- S- 100 ~

I
80 I 80 \-

I
6d-
I
:: ~
I
40
I

!

20 r- 1
,---------- --

l~_l.-__ ..J _l.

120
I I
--1..--_1 _...L __
160
..l...--.
200
----
_
Y
.....L..-..__...L
60 80
__..._L..
100
__

C B

2 ~.

I[ ~ ~ G
..__ •• .....L..-. •• _ .••L_ _.L_ ..._L
.. .__
L.-..._. ...
__.
o 20 40 60 80 100 I

_ ..

.l- ....1.- __ ..... _


I I
- 160 200 Y

FIGURE 12·8
A Change in Investment and the Change in Aggregate Demapd '(
Relative to the original equilibrium, t'1is would be The original eqUilibrium at Y of $120 and r of
a decrease in Yof $20 and in r of one percentage 6 percent is shown here again by the intersection
point.9 No other combination of changes in Yor of IS and LM1 in Part 0 of Figure 12-9. The IS
r would be consistent with equilibrium in both the curve here is the same as ·the one originally
goods and money markets, assuming the indi- derived in Figure 12-3. The new equilibrium that
cated shift in the investment schedule with all results from the increase in the money supply is ..
else as given. at Y of $140 and r of 5 percent. Although the $20
Just as the intersection of IS1 and LM in increase in ms will shift the LM curve $40 to the
Part D established the AD1 curve in Part E, the right at each interest rate. it will not raise the
intersections of the IS2 and LM curves and of the equilibrium level of Y by $40, because, with-no·
IS3 and LM curves establish the AD2 and AD3 shift in the IS curve, a rise in the equilibrium level
curves, respectively, in Part E. Given the LM of income cannot occur unless r falls. However,
curve in Part D, the shifts in the I curve of. Part A a fall in r will increase the amount of money peo-
which cause the indicated sh:fts in the IS curve ple choose to hold in speculative balances. In
in Part D also produce the shifts here noted in the present illustration, $10 of the $20 increase
the AD curve in Part E. in M will be absorbed in speculative balances as
r falls from 6 to 5 percent (as may be seen from
Part A of Figure 12-9). This same fall in r is also
A Change just sufficient to raise f by $10 (as may be seen
in th'e Money Supply from Part A of Figure 12-8) and, through the mul-
As a second illustration of a shift in the AD curve, tiplier, raise Y by $20. A rise in Yof $20 increase~
assume a $20 increase in the money supply. This required transactions balances by $10, which
shifts the ms curve in Part B of Figure 12-9 from accounts for the balance of the $20 increase in
its original position of mS1 to the new position ms' Nu other possible combination of changes in
ms2. With no change in the speculative demand Y and r but this $20 increase and one percentage
function or the transactions demand function, the point decrease will be consistent with equilib-
$20 increase in ms shifts the LM function right- rium, assuming the indicated increase in the
ward by $40 at each rate of interest, or from LM 1 money supply with all else as given.
to LM2. What lies behind this may be seen as If the change were in the opposite direction-
follows. Equilibrium between md and ms requires a $20 decrease in the money supply that shifts
a rise in Y sufficient to absorb the ms increase of the curve from ms 1 to ms 3-the new equilibrium
$20 in transactions balances, ml, if the interest combination of Y and r would be at $100 and
rate is assumed to be given. Because mt = k(Y), 7 percent, or a decrease in )l of $20 and a rise
we ' .J.veY = m,lk and ~ Y = tun,lk. Accordingly, in r of one percentage point. By the reasoning of
with k given as 0.5, a Y must be $40 to produce the preceding paragraph, no other combination
a new equilibrium between md and ms at each of changes in Y and r will provide a new equilib-
jntere~t rate. rium within the assumptions of the present illus-
tration.
Because the LM 1 and IS curves in Figure
9For simplicity, here we. assume that the LM curve is
linear over the range of interest rates (5 to 7 percent) rel-
12-9 are identical with the LM and IS1 curves in
evant to our illustrations. (This requires that we also Figure 12-8, they intersect at Y = $120 and r =
assume that the underlying speculative demand curve is 6 percent. With the eqUilibrium interest rate set
linear over this same range.) Specifically, the slope of LM at 6 percent, S = I and Y = C + I at Yof $120.
is taken to be 0.05 (r changes by 0.05 percentage point
As in Figure 12-8, this establishes the AD; curve
for each $1 billion change in Yor by 1.00 percp-ntage point
for a $20 billion change in V). Any dE:;J~lrture from linearity
in Part E at Y = $120. An increase from m.l to
would give actual numerical resultsdifferent from the sym- ms2 shifts the • LM curve from LM1 to LM21 lowers
metrical ones found in the illustrations. the equilibrium interest rate, and makes S = J
249

.....J _
I
-1- -+ - - - - - - - - - - - ,
I I 40 t-
I

I I ,
I I
I I
I I
I I
I I I
__ -L __L.L__
L_--.L ..L.._ ..._._ _
40 80 120 160 200 Y

10 I
8~

6~

I
.~ I
I ,
I
2 I 2 ~
I i -
~
, I(
l----l- L. __ l
I
L ......L. . _ L .l-..., .L L _ ... .c. . L. L.
o 40 80 120 160 200 Y o 20 40 60 80 100 120 msp

"
-';

.'
_.,

I I I I

" FIGURE 12-9


A G •• p :Inthe Money Supply and the Change in Aggregate Demand
and Y = C + I at Y of $140. This establishes the
AD2 curve at Y of $140 in Part E. In the same way,
the LM3 curve based on mS3 yields the AD3 curve
at Y of $100 in Part E.
Although the present illustration involv~s
nothing more than a purely monetary change,
one result is still a change in the level of .real
income. In short, given the IS and LM curves as
in Figure 12-9, monetary policy can influence the
economy's level of output. As will be explained
later, the effect on the income level of an increase
in the mqney supply depends on (1) how great
the fall in the interest rate is, which in turn I
depends on the elasticity of the speculative I
I
demand function, and (2) how much investment I
spending rises as a result of any given drop in 2 I
the interest rate, which in turn depends on the
interest elasticity of the investment function. If the
r :
I'- __----.--L-_-----l-..._-L ,I
I

--.L
IS,
----.--L- I

interest rate falls with a rise in the money supply o. 40 80 120 160 200 240 Y
and if investment 'spending rises with a fall in the A
interest rate, the income level will rise. AD, AD2 AS

A Simultaneous Increase
in Investment and
the Money Supply A

Now suppose that the two increases we have dis-


cussed separately occur simultaneously. The rise
in the investment function moves the IS curve
from IS, to IS2, and the rise in the money supply
moves the LM curve from LM, to LM2, as shown
FIGURE 12-10
in Part A of Figure 12-10. The result is a shift in Effect on Aggregate Demand of a
the equilibrium position from Y of $120 and r of Simultaneous Increase in
6 percent to Y of $160 and r of 6 percent. The AD Investment and the Money
curve of Part B correspondingly shifts from its Supply
position at Y of $120 to a position at Y of $160. A
rise in investment spending, with no change in
the money supply, produces a rise in income that model in Chapter 5. Now we see that this result
is dampened by a rise in the interest rate result- will be realized only if an appropriately expan-
ing from it. If the money supply increases by just sionary monetary policy-here an increase in ms
the amount necessary to prevent this rise in the of $20-is pursued to prevent what otherwise
interest rate, the full i'ncome-expansionary effect would be a rise in the interest rate and conse-
of the rise in investmeAt will be realized. The quently a smaller rise in the income level.
increase in Y from $120 to $160, with an increase The effects of shifts in other functions may be
in investment of $20 and an MPC of 1/2, is just traced in the same way. For example, an increase
the result we found in the simple Keynesian in "thrift," which appears as an upward shift in the
saving function (Part C of Figure 12-3), will shift IS curve $40 to the right. from IS1 to IS2, for the
· the IS curv,eto the left and lower rand Y. An ,same reason that the increase in investment of
· increase in the demand for money to be held in $20 shifted the IS curve to the right by $40 in
idle balances, which appears as a shift to the Figure 12_8.10 Part 0 of Figure 12-11 includes the
right in the speculative demand function (Part A same LM function derived in Figure 12-4.
\ of, Figure 12-4), will shift the LM curve to the left, Other things being eElual, the introduction of
. ,,\raiser, and lower Y. A change in payments prac- deficit-financed government purchases of $20
·)ices that makes it possible for each dollar of moves the Y, r equilibrium in' Part 0 from $120
money to handle a larger volume of transaCtions and 6 percent to $140 and 7 percent and shifts
per time period reduces k,and appears as a less the AD curve in Part E from AD1 to AD2• Again
steeply inclined, transactions demand function .the result shown is the same _as that in Figure
(Part C of Figure 12-4), This will shift'the LM curve 12-8 for a $20 shift in the investment demand
to the right. lower r, and raise Y. schedule. What otherwise would be an expan-
sion in Yof $40, as indicat.ed by the simple mul-
tiplier of 2, becomes the lesser expansion of $20
, Government Spending, due to the effect of the rise in r that accompanies
Taxation, and Aggregate the rise in Y. However, there is a difference: G of
Demand, _ $20 is unaffected by the rise in r it causes, but
the rise in r reduces I by $10, which makes the
Once government spending and taxation have net change in I + G only $10 and the rise in
been added to the model, the equilibrium con- income~:only $20. The full income-expansionary
dition S = I in the goods market foi' a two-sector effect of G,is not realized, because tfie resulting
economy becomes S + T = I + G for a three- rise in r crowds out $10 of private investment
sector economy. This simply means that the spending. Therefore, a fiscal policy designed to
aggregate spending for goods and aggregate raise the income level through a deficit-'financed
output of goods will be equal when the sum of expansion of government spending may not pro-
the diversions, S + T, from the real income duce the maximum possible rise of income unless
stream is just matched by the sum of compen- it is accompanied by an appropriately expansion-
sating injections, I + G, into the real..'income ary monetary policy. 1.1
·stream. Alternatively, the equilibrium condition in Let us now suppo~e that there is a balanced
the goods market may be expressed as Y = budget and that the government collects taxes
C + I + G. The equilibrium condition in the of $20 to match its spending of $20,thefeby
money'market is md = ms' as before.
As in the first fiscal model of Chapter 6. both
government purchases of goods and services 1°lt would be more correct to designate the curve as
and net tax receipts'are assumed to be indepen- IG-ST instead of IS, but the simpler notation will be
dent of the level of income. Part A of Figure 12-11 retained. Note. however. that in Parts A-C the axes pre-
viou_slylabeled I are now I + G. and the axes previously
shows $20 9f :government purchases added.
labeled S are now S + T.
to the investment .schedule- of Figure 12-3. 11 Because government spending in this example is
'Bec.~use these Pwchases are also regarded entirely deficit financed, we are concerned with the
as independent of the interest rate, the I + G method of deficit financing employed, If entirely financed-
curve lies $20 to the right of the I curve at all by the sale oLgovernment securities to the public. there
will be no increase in the money supply; the results are as
interest rates. Whatever the interest rate, the sum
described above. If financed by the appropriate "mix" of
of I -+- G will be $20 greater than I alone. In terms- sales to the public and the banking system, there will be
of its'effecton Y,a dollar of G is no different from ~n incr¢ase in the money :;upply that permits the full $40 ;
, a dollar of I. Adding $20 of G therefore shifts the potentiat expansion in Y. .
S+T
100 L
I
!

,
:: f
I
60 ~

!
40 r 401-··-----
~----
r---
I

20
Ir- _1. _ I
20!-- --
I
I
I ! I I I I
I1.__ .__ I I I I
,
, I I
I I
I
45°.__'-_....L1_L ' __
..1...- . ______
.Ll_L__~____----.L.. _ ..l- ._
----L __.. _
o 40 00 lW 100 200 Y G 20 40 60 80 100 I + G

r
I
10 \--
!

6,
i

4 ~-

i,
I
2 r-
I I+~
IL .....L.
__ i_. ..l- ..l_. .1.__... _
o 20 40 60 80 100

-
f ~ 160
'" :\

120
130 140

fiGURE 12-·1 i
Effect on Aggregate D'emand of Changes in Government Spending
and Taxation
avoiding deficit spending,. In the present model, equal to the expansion in the size of the budget-
. taxes of $20 reduce disposable income by $20. will be dampened by the tendency for the interest
With,the" MPS of 1/2, the reduction in saving is rate to rise with the rise in income. In other words,
one-~alf of this amount. Consequently, at each a fiscal policy designed to produce a rise in
.'- (

level of Y, T of $20 reduces 5 by $10 and C by income while maintaining a balanced bUdget will
$10, which appears in Part C of Figure 12-11 as produ~e the maximum possible income increase
a downward shift of $10 from 51 to 52 in the saving only if it is accompanied by an expansionary
function. To the leakage from income made up monetary policy that prevents what otherwis~
of saving must now be added the leakage of $20 might be a rise in the interest rate and a conse-
for taxes. This gives us the curve 52 + T, the sum quent reduction in private investment spending.
of saving and taxes, or that portion of the income We have seen that a rise in the income level
flow that does not appear as consumption m'ay be expected from an expansion in G with no
spending at each level of income.12 change in T and even from an expansion in G
I of Part A and 51 of Part C gave us 151 of that is matched by T. The third possibility, of
Part 0; I + G of Part A with T of zero gave us 152 course, is a reduction in Twith no reduction in G,
of Part 0; finally, I + G of Part A with 52 + T of a commonly cited example of which was the tax
Part C gives us 153 of Part D. The new equilibrium cut of 1964. This major reduction cut federal tax
position indicated by the intersection of 153 and receipts about 10 percent below what they other~
LM in Part 0 is found at Y of $130 and r of 6.5 wise would have been; in contrast. the more
percent. Corresponding to this is AD3 positioned recent anti-reCE:fssionary Tax Reduction Act' of
at Y of $130 in Part E. In our illustration, adding 1975 reduced receipts about 5 percent below
G of $20 and an equal amount of T raises the what they otherwise would have been. Figure
equilibrium level of Y by one-half the increase in 12-11 may bE?used to illustrate an aspect of the
the size of the b'udget.13 1964 tax cut much discussed at the Jime.-SUp-
With G and T both independent of the level pose the original equilibrium is definedf/by)the
of Y, we have a model similar to the one that gave intersection of 153 and LM at Y otl$)3(j,~'nd r of
us the unit multiplier in Chapter 6. In that model, 6.5' percent; this is the equilibriurl consistent with
the rise in Y was equal to the increase in the size 1 + G of Part A and 52 + T ~f ParVJ. of Figure
of the budget. However, because the interest rate 12-11. With no change in G ~ ~Jax cut of $20,
is now part of the model, we' firiOtha:t the adual the I + G curve remains ~ 1's.' ~crthe 52 + T
multiplier is less than the balanced-budget mul- curve shifts downward to.8,. 't'fis'in turn causes
tiplier of 1 that appears in the simpler model. An the 15 curve to shift from 153 'to 152, But the full
expansion in the size of the budget, with the expansionary effect of the tax cut-a rise in Y
budget'balanced, will raise the income level, but from $130 to $150-is not realized because the
the rise in income-which would otherwise be interest rate rises. Therefore, in judging the pro-
spective effectiveness of the 1964 tax cut, one
consideration was whether or not the expected'
12Forexample, with Y of $140 and T of zero, Yd' or Y increase in aggregate spending would be smaller
- T, would be $140; C would be $110, or $40 + 1/2($140
than otherwise obtainable due to adverse mon-
- 0); and $ would be $30, or - $40 + %($140 - 0), the
last figure as shown on the $, curve of Part C of Figure 12- etary effects, In President Johnson's words, ,''It
11 at.y of.$140. The imposition of T of $20 reduces Yd to would be self-defeating to cancel the,stimulus,of
$120 when Y is $140. This reduces C to $100, or $4.0 + tax reduction by tightening money. Monetary and
%($140 - $20), and $ to $20; or -$40 + %($140.- debt policy should be directed toward maintain-
$20), the latter figure as shown on the $2 curve at Y of
jng interest rates and credit conditions that
$140. Finally, adding T of $20 makes total diversions from
income $40 at Y'of $140, as shown on the $2 + T curve, encourage private investment.,,14 The model In
13Theoriginal budget was one in which both G and T
were zero.
254
Figure 12-11 is far tOb simple.to come to grips characteristics at th~' present stab!e-ptice model
with the questions' involved, but it suggests. in and the general conclusions it suggests. As we
very general terms, that what is called-for is an allow for the elasticities of these functions. we will
incre~~e in the money supply. This' Jncrease. find that some ofthese conclusions must be qual-
should be"sufficient to shift the LM cu~e to the ified and that some must even be abandoneq in
right 'by the amount necessary to s.ecure the the extreme cases' of perfectly elastic or inelastic
greater rise in income-from $130 to $"1~~that functions. For example, an expansionary fiscal
will follow f(om the increase in aggregate spend- .policy may rais,e only the interest rate and leave
ing to be exp~cted at ,a stable interest rate. the income level unchanged; conversely, it may
~Itpough we will not go beyond the simple raise only the income level and leave the interest
model in which both G and T are assumed to be rate unchanged. An expansionary monetary pol-
independent of Y, the- IS-LM analysis of Figure icy may lower only the interest rate and leave the
12-11 may be elaborated by introducing more income level unchanged; or it may change nei-
realistic fiscal assumptions. In Part C, for exam- ther the interest rate nor the level of income. The
ple. T may be treated as a function of Y, and the reverse is possible for contractionary policies.
effects of this more realistic fiscal assumption on
the..Y, r equilibrium combination may readily be
tr~ced. This . model will show how the potential
Elasticity of the IS and LM
income-expansionary effect of, say, a rise in Functions
investment. spending may be restrainec.by both With a fixed money supply, the LM function as
a rise in the interest rate and a rise in tax receipts derived in Figure 12-4 slopes upward to the right.
as income expands. Although it adds something However, at one extreme the function may become
to the simpler model of this section, like any other perfectly elastic, and at the other extreme it may
model of this kind it will again bring out our prin- become perfectly inelastic, with a range of vary-
cipal conclusion: An increase in aggregate ing elasticities in between. In general, the higher
spending-whether it is the result of a shift in the the interest rate, the less elastic the correspond-
investment function. consumption function, or a ing point on the L~ function will be. These three
change in government spending or taxation-will ranges are delineated in Part A of Figure 12-12,
not produce the effect on income ~uggested by in which the perfectly elastic section is the
the crude multipliers in earlier ch~ers. , When "Keynesian range," the perfectly inelastic section
we recognize the r<>leplayed by money and inter- is the "classical range," and the section between
est, we see how an otherwise greater expansion is the "intermediate range."
of income suggested by crude multipliers may Why this particular shape with perfect elas-
be prevented by the rise in the interest rate that ticity at one extreme and perfect inelasticity at
may accompany a rise in income. the other? Remember that at sonie very low inter-
est rate th~ speculative demand for money may
become perfectly elastic due to a consensus by
The :IS and LM wealth-holders that the interest rate will fall no
Elasticities lower and that security prices will rise no higher
Wealth-holders accordingly stand ready to
and MOftetaryiFiscaJ. exchange seGurities for cash at existing security
Policies ' , prices. which produces the liquidity trap on the
speculative demand function. Here,' on the LM" ,
81) far, we have intentionally avoided specific ref- function: it produces what is known as the Keynes-
erence to the elasticities of the IS and LM tunc:' ian range. At the other extreme, at some very
tions so that we might concentrate on the general high int~rest rate, the speculative demand for
-~~-.---
ion? In our simplified version of the classical the-
ory, money is demanded only for transactions
purposes. Therefore, in Figure 12-4, classical
theory assumes that the speculative demand for
money is zero at each inter~st rate. In effect.
Part A of that figure vanishes. If the total money
supply given in Part B is $100. that $100 will be
held in transactions balances or msp = 0 and ms
=: tnr With k of 1/2 in Part C. the LM curve of

Part 0 becomes a perfectly vertical line at the


income level of $200. if the public holds, money
only for transactions purposes and if it holds
money balances equal to one-half of a period's
income, money market equiiibrium is found at an
. income level of $200 at all interest rates. 15
With the exception of the perfectly. inelastic
section-the so-called classical range-it would
not be altogether incorrect to include the remain-
der of the LM function in the Keynesian range.
However, because of Keynes' emphasis on the
ineffectiveness of monetary policy, the Iiquidity-
trap section alone has been identified. as the
Keynesian range. Within this range, monetary
! 'I I 1 policy is completely ineffective; therefore .. this
L. t.L_L _ range most closely fits Keynes' emphasis.
The IS function as derived in Figure 12-3
slopes downward to the right. Its elasticity
depends on the responsiver:'ess of investment ./
spending to changes in the interest rate and on
FIGtJRE 1:1·12 the magnitude.of the mUltiplier. If the investment
Effects of Shifts m the is and spending schedule is perfectly inelastic (indi-
LM FWtctions with Various pating that investment sRending is completely
Elasticities of the LM FwtCtiOfi tnsensitive to the interest rate). the IS curve
derived in Part 0 will' be perfectly inelastic.
regardless of the magnitude of the multiplier. If,
money may become zero and perfectly inelastic on the other hand, the investment demand
at interest rates above this if wealth-holders schedule shows some elasticity, as se~ms to be
believe the interest rate will rise no higher and the case, the IS curvewili be- more ela,stic, the
that security prices will fall no lower. At this or any lower the MPS. The lower the MPS, the higher will
higher rate, wealth-holders accordingly prefer to be the mutliplier and the greater will be _the
hold only securities and no idle cash. This per- change in income for any increase in investment
fectly inelastic section of the speculative demand resulting from a fall in the interest rate. Part A of .
function is known as the classical range on the Figure 12-13 shows three pairs of IS curves, each
LM function.
Why are the three sections into which the LM ''''The graphic derivation of a perlect!V inelastic LM
function has be-en diVIded labeled in this fash- curve is shoM1 in Chsptei 13 on p. 268.
output attained, Ys in Part A. Consequently, all of
the changes in AD shown in each figure from Y1
to Ys are accompanied by proportional changes
in y"6

Monetary and Fiscal Policy


Monetary policy is the exercise of the central
bank's control over the money supply as an
instrument for achieving the objectives of general
economic policy. Fiscal policy is the exercise of
the government's control over public spending
·. .._, ..... '- and tax collections for the same purpose. We will
0 Y4
y confine ourselves here to the single policy objec-
A tive of raising the level of real income. The IS-LM
framework then provides a basis for comparing'
P the effect of the two types of policy on the income
AD3 ADs
level and the interest rate and for comparing con-
,
AD, AD2 AD4 AS ditions under which each type of policy will oe

I effective or ineffective in prodt.i'ciftg the; desired


change in income. For this purpose, tHe discus-
sion is conveniently divided into three parts, each
PI
corresponding to a range of the LM function in
Part A of Figure 12-12.
...
.

The Keynesian Range Consider first· the Yl'


r, equilibrium in the Keynesian range. An increase
in the money supply shifts the LM curve to the
right, from LM1 to LM2. This means that for each
possible level of income md = ms only at a lower
FIGURE 12·13 interest rate; the rate must fall by the amount nec-
Effects of Elastic and Inelastic IS essary to make the public willing to hold larger
Functions in Different Ranges of idle cash balances. But this is not true in the
the LM Function
16 Although the present model contains a classical ele-
ment in the form of the perfectly inelastic range of the LM
~ made up of one highly inelastic and one elastic curve, the model is essentially Keynesian because it
shows that the equilibrium level of output may be below
IS curve.
it-Ie level consistent with full employment. Remember from
Parts B of both Figures 12-12 and 12-13 Chapter 9 that the simple classical model with its assump-
show AD curves corresponding to the various tion of perfect wage and price flexibility yields a perfectly
levels of Y set off on the Y axis in Part A of each inelastic AS curve, which is located at the full employment
of those figures. As in previous figures of this ievel of output. This makes the full employment level of
output the only equilibrium level, a result altogether dif-
chapter, the AS curve is assumed to be perfectly
ferent from that found in Figures 12-12 and 12-13. Further
elastic up to the full employment level of output. . comparisons between the classical and Keynesian models"
Also as before, the full employment leve! is in terms of the IS-U.If framework will be presented in the
assumed to be greater than the highest leve! of following chapter.
"liquidity trap." Here the interest rate is already Keynesian range is the range of the liquidity trap,
at an irreducible minimum for the time.being. As one can",now appreciate what Professor Hicks
the monetary authority purchases securities, meant by his observation, made shortly after the
security-holders are willing to exchange them for appearance of Keynes' book, that "the General
cash at the existing prices. Therefore, expansion Theory of Employment is the Economics of
?f the money supply cannot cause the interest Depression.,,18
rate to fall below the rate given by the trap. All
that happens is that the public holds more in
speculative balances and less in securities. Fur-
"
The Classical 'Range Next let us examine the
Y4' r 4 equilibrium defined by the intersection of
ther increases in the money supply would shift
IS3 and LM 1 in Part A of Figure 12-12. Some
the LM curve still farther to the right, but the lower
increase
_ in the money supply will shift the LM 1
end of the curve would remain anchored in the
curVe to LM2. In contrast to the result in the
same liquidity trap. If the economy is already in
Keynesian range, the result is now an increase
the trap, monetary policy is powerless to raise
in the inc.ome level from Y4 to Y5 and a fall in the
the income level. It cannot reduce the interest
interest rate from r 4 to r 3' In the classical range I

rate any further to produce a movement down the


the i~terest rate is so high that speculative bal-
IS1 curve to a higher equilibrium income level.
ances are zero; money is held for transactions
The belief that the economy was in the trap dur-
purposes only. Under these circumstances, if the
ing the early thirties led Keynes to his then unor-
monetary authority enters the market to purchase
thodox fiscal policy' prescriptions. Because gov-
securities, security-holders can be induced to
ernment cannot raise the income level through
exchange securitjes for cash only at higher
monetary policy, it can only try to do so through
prices. As security prices are bid up and the
fiscal policy. If a rise in income cannot be
interest rate is pushed down, investment is stim-
acnieved by producing a movement down the IS 1
ulated (and, in classical theory, saving is dis-
curve through monetary expansion, it can be
couraged). Because nobody chooses to hold
achieved by producing a shift in the IS 1 curve
. idle cash, expansion of the mo"ney supply will
Itself, say from IS1 to IS'l' Fiscal measures such
produce a new equilibrium only by reducing the
as increased government spending or reduced
interest rate by whatever amount is necessary to
taxes .that could shift the IS curve become the
increase the income level sufficiently to absorb
order of the day.
.:0 t~~ extent that monetary policy operates by
raising Investment spending through a reduction
the full increase in the money supply in transac-
tions balances. If in the present case we assume
that ilms = $20 and k = 1/2, equilibrium will be
in t.he cost of money, the impasse of monetary
restored only when Y has risen by $40, or, in gen-
policy for an economy caught in the trap means
eral, when ilY = ilmjk. In the classical range,
that the elasticity or inelasticity of the IS function
the result follows the simple classical quantity
is no longer relevant. In Part A of Figure 12-13, for
theory of money as a theory of aggregate
example, it does not matter Wh~eh r the IS func-
demand. Y rises proportionally with the increase
tion is th~ el.a~ticIS1 or the inelasti IS"1.17
in ms' If V = 2 or k = 1/2, the rise in Y must be
The liqUidity trap is an extre e case that
twice the rise in ms in order to satisfy the equilib-
could occur only during a dee depression, if
rium condition: msV = Y and ms = k(Y).
even then. A prosperous economy and a liquidity
trap do not go hand in hand. Because the pure

18 J.R. Hicks, "Mr. Keynes and the 'Classics': A Sug,

17As we will see, the elasticity of the IS function does gested Interpretation," reprinted in W. Fellner and B.F.
::>ecomerelevaAt elsewhere, but not in the Keynesian Haley, eds., Readings in the Theory of Income Distribution
·ange. Irwin, 1946, p. 472. . '
In contrast to the Keynesian range, in which both classical and Keynesian theory investment
monetary policy is completely ineffective, in the i.s a function of the interest rate, but that in clas-
classical range it appears to be completely effec· a
sical theory saving also is function of the inter-
tive. No part of any increase in the money supply . est rate. Consequently, only if both saving and
disappears into idle cash balances. The increase investment are quite irisensitive to the interest
in the money supply leads to increased spending rate could there be an inelastic curve of the sort
that raises the income !evel to the point at which described by /S" 3 in Part A of Figure 12-13.19 As
the total increase in the money supply is absorbed ..long as one or the other is elastic, the reSUlting
into transactions balances. Because all income IS function will also be elastic; with an elastic IS
changes are real changes in the present model, function, the result of a change in the money sup- .
the increase in the money supply that i>hifts LM 1 ply in the present model is d Y = dmslk.
to LM2 causes an increase horn Y4 to Y5 in output
as well as in income.
Again in contrast to the Keynesian range, in
The Intennediate Range Finally, let us exam-
which fiscal policy alone can be effective, fiscal ine the equilibrium of Y2, r2, as defined by !.he
policy it') the classical range is completely inef- intersection of /S2 and LM1 in Part A of Figu~e
fective. IAn upward shift in the IS function from IS3 12-12. Here again we see that some increase in the
to is' 3 in P?rt A of Figure 12-12 can raise only the money supply will shift the LM1 function to LM2.
interest rate, from r4 to r5; the incdrne level stays In the Keynesian range, this increase in the
unchanged at Y4• Given the increase in spending money supply left both Y and r unchanged
that lies behind the upward shift in the IS function, because that total increase was absorbed in
the interest rate will rise sufficiently to crowd out speculative balances at the existing interest rate. -.
enough spending to leave aggregate spending In the classical range, this increase in the money ,
unchanged. Therefore, if the 'rise in spending supply raised Y by the amount necessarY to
resulted from increased government spending, absorb the full increase in transactions balances.
This worked itself out through the interest rate
-.
the r.ise in the interest rate would crowd out an
amount of private spending equal to the rise in reduction that raised spending by the amount
government spending. The level of income is as needed to produce the required rise in income.
high as the given money supply can support. In In the intermediate range, however, the increase
the classical range, an increase in income is in the money supply is partially absorbed in both
therefore impossible without an increase in the speculative and transactions balances. The level
money supply, and monetary policy becomes an of income rises, but by an amount less than that
all-powerful method of controlling the income which would require the full increase in the
money supply for transactions purposes.
'8"'e~
How does the elasticity of the IS functron affect For example, suppose that the increase in the
the equilibrium positions in the classical range? money suppiy is $20 and k is 1/2. Although the
Let us compare the elastic IS3 function and the resultant shift in the LM function is $40, here the
rise in income (Y3 - Y2) is only ha~fthat amount.
Inelastic IS" 3 function shown in Part A of Figure
12-13. Given the IS" 3 function, no increase in the
money supply and no reduction in the interest
rate is capable of raising the income level from 191nterms of Part C of Figure 12-3, we may show saving
y 4 to Y 5' Monetary policy will raise Y, but not by as a function of both Y and r by drawing in a similar fashion
successively higher saving functions to correspond witl1
the multiple of ms given by 11k. Although this
successively higher interest rates. An inelastic investment
seems to upset the result suggested by classical function in Part A combined with this income-elastic and
theory, classical theorists woutd deny that the IS int8rest-elastic saving function in Part C will still produce
curve could be so inelastic. Remember that in an elastic IS function in Part D.
In reducing the interest rate by the amount that be greater or smaller depending on how high in
produce"s the increase in spending needed to the intermediate range the equilibrium happens
raise the income level by $20, $10 (one-half of to be Although fiscal policy is somewhat effec-
the increase in the money supply) is absorbed in tive anywhere in the intermediat~ range, in gen-
s"peGulative balances. The remaining· $10 is eral it will be more effective the closer equilibrium
exactly the additional amount of money needed is to the Keynesian range and less effective the
for transactions purposes with the income level closer equilibrium is to the classical range.
up by $20. Although both monetary and fiscal policies
In ~he intermediate range, monetary policy have. varying degrees of effectiveness in the
has sume degree of effectiveness but not the intermediate range, the relative effectiveness of
complete effectiveness it has in the classicnl each depends in large part on the elasticity of
range. In general, the closer the equilibrium inter- the IS function. If the IS function is the inelastic
section is to the classical range, the more effec- IS"2 in Part A of Figure 12-13, monetary poli~y
tive monetary policy becomes; the closer the can do very littie to raise the level of income, even
intersection is to the Keynesian range, the less in the intermediate range; fiscal policy alone is
effective it becomes. .effective in such a situation. Furth~rrTlore, an
Within this range, fiscal policy is also effective expansionary fiscal policy need not be con-
to some extent. Fiscal measures that shift the IS cerned with adverse monetary effects in this
function from IS2 to IS' 2' for example, will raise case. A shift in an inelastic IS function will raise
the level of income and the interest rate to the the interest rate, but this higher rate will have little
new equilibrium defined by the intersection of feedback on spending. Keynes maintained that
IS'2 and LM1• If the shift in the IS function stems the investDlent schedule (as well as the saving
from a deficH-financed increase in government schedule) was interest inelastic. If this is the
spending, the interest fate must rise. We are case, the IS schedule must also be inelastic, and
assuming a fixed money supply described by fiscal policy, which is completely effective in the
LM1, so the increased government spending is Keynesian range, must be almost as effective in
being financed by borrowing from the public. Thp. the intermediate range. If the IS sch~dule is
sale of additional securities by the government indeed interest inelastic, tl1en the Keynesian
depresses security prices, raises the interest range becomes, in effect, the complete LM
rate, and chokes off some amount of private curve, more applicable at the lower end than at
spending. The rise in the interest rate following the upper end, but with some applicability
any given increase in government spending will throughout.

Das könnte Ihnen auch gefallen