Outcomes
Author(s): Margaret A. Neale and Max H. Bazerman
Source: The Academy of Management Journal, Vol. 28, No. 1 (Mar., 1985), pp. 34-49
Published by: Academy of Management
Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/256060
Accessed: 12-10-2017 05:11 UTC
REFERENCES
Linked references are available on JSTOR for this article:
http://www.jstor.org/stable/256060?seq=1&cid=pdf-reference#references_tab_contents
You may need to log in to JSTOR to access the linked references.
JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide
range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and
facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.
Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at
http://about.jstor.org/terms
Academy of Management is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access
to The Academy of Management Journal
This content downloaded from 111.68.103.3 on Thu, 12 Oct 2017 05:11:23 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
OAcademy of Management Journal
1985, Vol. 28, No. 1, 34-49.
This research was supported by Grant SS-45-82-05 from the Social Science
The authors are indebted to Don Kleinmuntz, Gerrit Wolf, Beber Helburn, H
Greg Northcraft for their contributions and helpful comments on previou
version of this paper won the Best Dissertation Paper - 1983 award in
Behavior Division at the national meeting of the Academy of Management
34
This content downloaded from 111.68.103.3 on Thu, 12 Oct 2017 05:11:23 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
1985 Neale and Bazerman 35
This content downloaded from 111.68.103.3 on Thu, 12 Oct 2017 05:11:23 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
36 Academy of Management Journal March
pect of gains. Further, Kahneman and Tversky's (1979) prospect theory states
that potential gains and losses are evaluated relative to their effect on current
wealth. Choice is explained by an S-shaped value function-a value function
that is convex, indicating a risk-averse orientation, for gains and concave,
indicating a risk-seeking orientation, for losses. This figure shows that the
value placed on saving 200 lives is more than one-third of the value placed
on saving 600 lives. In contrast, the value loss suffered by losing 600 lives is
not three times as great as losing 200 lives.
Consider a hypothetical labor-management situation. The union claims
they need a raise to $12/hour, and that anything less would represent a loss
to employees given the current inflationary environment. In contrast, man-
agement claims that they cannot pay more than $10/hour, and that anything
FIGURE 1
Hypothetical Value Function Accounting for Framing
VALUE UNITS
LOSSES I GAINS
I
LIVES
-600 -400 -200 200 400 600
I
!
I
This content downloaded from 111.68.103.3 on Thu, 12 Oct 2017 05:11:23 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
1985 Neale and Bazerman 37
Negotiator Overconfidence
Negotiator overconfidence represents a second bias that reduces conces-
sionary behavior and negotiator success in reaching agreement. While resear
This content downloaded from 111.68.103.3 on Thu, 12 Oct 2017 05:11:23 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
38 Academy of Management Journal March
This content downloaded from 111.68.103.3 on Thu, 12 Oct 2017 05:11:23 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
1985 Neale and Bazerman 39
METHODS
Subjects
This content downloaded from 111.68.103.3 on Thu, 12 Oct 2017 05:11:23 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
40 Academy of Management Journal March
This content downloaded from 111.68.103.3 on Thu, 12 Oct 2017 05:11:23 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
1985 Neale and Bazerman 41
This content downloaded from 111.68.103.3 on Thu, 12 Oct 2017 05:11:23 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
42 Academy of Management Journal March
Measures
RESULTS
This content downloaded from 111.68.103.3 on Thu, 12 Oct 2017 05:11:23 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
1985 Neale and Bazerman 43
TABLE 1
Correlation Matrix of All Variables
2 3 4 5 6 7 8
1. FRAME 1.0
2. TRAIN -.400 1.0
3. COMPETE -.292 -.153 1.0
4. CONCEDE .196 .258 .270 1.0
5. NRSLVD .280 .206 -.744 .839 1.0
6. RESLN .295 .177 -.769 .771 .900 1.0
7. CONTRACT .407 .157 -.461 .553 .600 .563 1.0
8. FAIRCNT .317 .045 -.452 .501 .531 .528 .490 1.0
This content downloaded from 111.68.103.3 on Thu, 12 Oct 2017 05:11:23 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
44 Academy of Management Journal March
further clarification, the means of the original dependent variables are pre-
sented in Table 3. In general, this table illustrates that the components of
both the process and outcome constructs are all in the predicted direction;
that is, amount of concession, number of issues resolved, value of the final
contract, perceived fairness of the contract, and percentage of negotiated
agreements were all greater under the positively framed and realistically
confident conditions. Further, as predicted, the perceived level of competi-
tion was greater under the negatively framed and overconfident conditions.
Frame
TABLE 2
Means and Standard Deviations of Standardized Dependent Va
TABLE 3
Means of Unstandardized Dependent Variables
Process Outcomes
Con-
Level of cessionary Number Com- Value of Perceived
Framea Confidenceb Processes Resolved petitiveness Resolution Contract Fairness
N 0 $30,180 3.28 15.96 36.0% $ 200 24.3
N R 33,903 4.08 13.42 61.5% $1,404 25.4
P 0 33,231 4.27 12.00 73.1% $2,981 28.2
P R 35,456 4.65 10.96 82.6% $4,043 28.6
aN = negative, P = positive
bO = overconfident, R = realistically
This content downloaded from 111.68.103.3 on Thu, 12 Oct 2017 05:11:23 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
1985 Neale and Bazerman 45
Confidence
ANOVA results showed that the training of negotiators about the tendenc
towards overconfidence significantly influenced the process of negotiation:
F1,97 = 6.3, p<.01; w2 = .046. That is, individuals who were overly confident
in their judgments showed less concessionary behavior in the negotiati
process than did realistically confident negotiators; the respective mea
were -.614 (s.d. - 3.00) versus .644 (s.d. = 1.95). Further, the realistical
confident negotiators (those who received training) were able to obtain out
comes that were superior to those of individuals who were overconfiden
F1,97 = 3.4,p<.07;w2 = .019;therespectivemeanswere.433(s.d. = 2.22)vers
-.387 (s.d. = 2.37). In both analyses, only a small portion of the varianc
was accounted for.
DISCUSSION
This content downloaded from 111.68.103.3 on Thu, 12 Oct 2017 05:11:23 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
46 Academy of Management Journal March
This content downloaded from 111.68.103.3 on Thu, 12 Oct 2017 05:11:23 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
1985 Neale and Bazerman 47
REFERENCES
This content downloaded from 111.68.103.3 on Thu, 12 Oct 2017 05:11:23 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
48 Academy of Management Journal March
Einhorn, H. J., & Hogarth, R. M. 1978. Confidence in judgment: Persistence of the illusio
validity. Psychological Review, 85 (11): 395-416.
Einhorn, H. J., & Hogarth, R. M. 1981. Behavioral decision theory: Processes of judgment
choice. Annual Review of Psychology, 32: 53-88.
Esser, J. K., & Komorita, S. S. 1975. Reciprocity and concession making in bargaining. Journ
Personality and Social Psychology, 31: 864-872.
Farber, H. S., & Katz, H. C. 1979. Interest arbitration, outcomes, and the incentive to bar
Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 33: 55-63.
Feuille, P. 1977. Final offer arbitration and negotiating incentives. Arbitration Journal, 32:
203-220.
Fisher, R., & Ury, W. 1981. Getting to yes. New York: Houghton-Mifflin.
Grigsby, D. W., & Bigoness, W. J. 1982. The effects of third party intervention on preintervention
bargaining behavior. Journal of Applied Psychology, 67: 549-554.
Hartnett, D. L., & Cummings L. L. 1980. Bargaining behavior: An international study. Houston,
Tex.: Dame Publications.
Kahneman, D., Slovic, P., & Tversky, A. 1982. Judgment under uncertainty: Heuristics
biases. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Kahneman, D., & Tversky, A. 1979. Prospect theory: An analysis of decisions under
Econometrica, 47: 263-291.
Nisbett, R. E., & Ross, L. B. 1980. Human inference: Strategies and shor
judgment. Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice-Hall.
This content downloaded from 111.68.103.3 on Thu, 12 Oct 2017 05:11:23 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
1985 Neale and Bazerman 49
Phelps, R. H., & Shanteau, J. 1978 Livestock judges: How much information can an
Organizational Behavior and Human Performance, 21: 209-219.
Pitts, G. F., & Sachs, N. J. Judgment and decision: Theory and application. Annua
Psychology, 1984, 35: 139-163.
Raiffa, H. 1982. The art and science of negotiation. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard Pr
Rubin, J. Z. 1980. Experimental research on third party intervention in conflict: Tow
generalizations. Psychological Bulletin, 87: 379-391.
Rubin, J. Z., & Brown, B. R. 1975. The social psychology of bargaining and negoti
York: Academic Press.
Slovic, P. 1969. Analyzing the expert judge: a descriptive study of a stock broker's d
processes. Journal of Applied Psychology, 53: 255-263.
Thaler, R. H. 1980. Toward a positive theory of consumer choice. Journal of Economic
ior and Organization, 1: 39-60.
Tversky, A., & Kahneman, D. 1981. The framing of decisions and the psychology of
Science, 211: 453-463.
Tversky, A., & Kahneman, D. 1974. Judgment under uncertainty: Heuristics and biases. Scien
185: 1124-1131.
This content downloaded from 111.68.103.3 on Thu, 12 Oct 2017 05:11:23 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms