Sie sind auf Seite 1von 7

Optimal Auction Design and Equilibrium Selection in

Sponsored Search Auctions


By Benjamin Edelman and Michael Schwarz∗

In analyses of sponsored search auctions for search advertisements. We also consider a cor-
online advertising, it is customary to model the responding static game of complete information.
dynamic game of incomplete information by con- We analyze the underlying dynamic game of in-
sidering a static games of complete information. complete information, and we establish an upper
This approach is used in Edelman, Ostrovsky bound on the revenue of any equilibrium of any
and Schwarz (2007) (EOS), Varian (2007), and dynamic game in this environment. We then ex-
the subsequent literature. clude equilibria of the corresponding static game
Modeling complex interactions in uncertain with revenue that exceeds this upper bound. See
environments as games of complete information Section D.
has a long history. For example, the Bertrand We use this equilibrium selection criteria to
model of oligopolistic competition posits that assess optimal design of search engine advertis-
companies know their competitors’ costs based ing platforms. We characterize optimal reserve
on their experience from prior interactions. prices and show that the optimal reserve price is
The use of a static game of complete informa- independent of the number of bidders and inde-
tion often offers important benefits. For one, it is pendent of the rate at which click-through rate
tractable – avoiding complex multi-period infor- declines over positions. See Section E.
mation sets in a dynamic game. Furthermore, a Our analysis of reserve prices also lets us as-
suitably-chosen static game can capture impor- sess their welfare effects. We separate the effects
tant characteristics of the underlying dynamic of reserve price increases into direct effects (caus-
game. When a game is repeated over an ex- ing the lowest value bidder to face a higher pay-
tended period, there is good reason to think par- ment) and indirect effects (inducing other bid-
ticipants will learn many characteristics of their ders to increase their bids, thereby increasing
counterparts – supporting the use of a complete others’ payments). We show that most of in-
information model. cremental revenue from setting reserve price op-
Yet the use of a static game of complete in- timally comes not from the low bidder’s direct
formation is also unsatisfying. There is no clear effect, and not from indirect effects on other low
way to identify which (if any) equilibria of the bidders, but rather from the indirect effects on
static game of complete information are a rele- high bidders. This result may appear counter-
vant approximation of the equilibria of the dy- intuitive because top bidders’ large valuations
namic game of incomplete information. place them, in an important sense, “furthest
In this paper, we consider a dynamic game from” the reserve price. See Section II.
of incomplete information used to sell sponsored
I. Environment and Mechanisms
∗ Edelman: Harvard Business School, Boston,
MA 02163 (e-mail: bedelman@hbs.edu). Schwarz: A. Environment
Yahoo! Labs, 2397 Shattuck Ave, Berkeley, CA
94704 (e-mail: mschwarz@yahoo-inc.com). We
Our model for the sponsored search environ-
thank Susan Athey, Brendan Daley, Scott Komin-
ers, Robin Lee, Preston McAfee, Michael Ostrovsky, ment follows EOS. We consider a market for ad-
Al Roth, and Adam Szeidl. A draft of this paper was vertisements triggered by searches for a single
circulated under the title “Optimal Auction Design keyword. Each period, a slate of ads is shown to
in a Multi-Unit Environment: The Case of Spon- users, and the world lasts for 𝑇 periods. Each
sored Search Auctions.” position has a commonly-known click-through
1
2 DRAFT MAY 2010

rate (CTR), and higher positions have higher Advertisers can change their bids at any time.
CTR. In expectation, an ad in position 𝑖 receives Each period, advertisers observe positions of
𝛼𝑖 clicks per period, and the number of clicks de- their competitors. By seeing other advertis-
pends on position only. In a given period, each ers’ positions, each advertiser updates its beliefs
ad can appear in at most one position. about others’ valuations, influencing bids in fu-
There are 𝑁 advertisers. Advertiser 𝑘 values ture periods. When choosing a bid, an advertiser
a click at 𝑠𝑘 , which is 𝑘’s private information, may consider how its action will influence future
does not change over time, and does not depend play of other advertisers. Historic bid informa-
on the position where the ad appears. Bidder tion is relevant in equilibrium because an adver-
values are i.i.d. drawn from a commonly-known tiser’s best response depends on its expectation
distribution with support [0, 𝑠], pdf 𝑓 (.), and cdf of bidding behavior of other advertisers. This in-
𝐹 (.) satisfying the regularity condition from My- formation structure creates a complex dynamic
erson (1981). In particular, we assume virtual game of incomplete information.
valuation 𝜓(𝑠) = 𝑠 − 1−𝐹 (𝑠)
𝑓 (𝑠)
is decreasing in 𝑠. Our key observation is that we can establish
The per-period payoff of advertiser 𝑘 in posi- an upper bound on revenue in any equilibrium
tion 𝑖 is 𝛼𝑖 (𝑠𝑘 − 𝑝𝑘 ), where 𝑝𝑘 denotes the pay- of any dynamic game in this environment with-
ment per-click made by advertiser 𝑘 in that pe- out characterizing the equilibrium of a dynamic
riod. The total payoff of advertiser 𝑘 is the sum game. Importantly, the environment is fairly
∑𝑇
of 𝑘’s period payoffs, i.e. 𝑡=1 𝛼𝑘(𝑡) (𝑠𝑘 − 𝑝𝑘 (𝑡))
simple – letting us characterize an optimal mech-
where 𝑘(𝑡) denotes the position of advertiser 𝑘 anism for this environment, thereby bounding
in period 𝑡 and 𝑝𝑘 (𝑡) denotes the payment made revenue in any dynamic mechanism in this en-
by advertiser 𝑘 in period 𝑡. vironment without solving for an equilibrium of
a dynamic game. An optimal mechanism is pre-
B. The Dynamic Game of Incomplete sented in Section D.
Information
C. Approximation with a One-Shot Game
We begin with a stylized model that captures of Complete Information
the dynamic aspects of the mechanism used in
practice. Search engines sell advertisements us- The dynamic mechanism described above is
ing real-time generalized second price (GSP) sufficiently complex that it is difficult or per-
auctions. As each search occurs, an auction is haps impossible to solve analytically for an equi-
conducted to determine which ads should be dis- librium strategy. The literature on sponsored
played to the corresponding user. Advertisers search auctions sidesteps the complexity of the
are ranked based on bids: all else equal, the dynamic game of incomplete information by
higher the bid, the higher the position assigned modeling it as a one shot game of complete in-
to the corresponding advertiser, and hence the formation. The complete information game cor-
more clicks the advertiser receives. If there are responding to the incomplete information game
more positions than advertisers, a position is al- retains payoffs and the actions exactly as in the
located to all advertisers whose bid exceeds the previous section. However, there are two impor-
reserve price. The per-click payment of the ad- tant differences: the complete information game
vertiser in the bottom position equals the re- lasts only one period, and the per-click values of
serve price. For each other advertiser, the per- all bidders are common knowledge. The justi-
click payment equals the bid of an advertiser fication for considering a complete information
who is ranked one position lower. (For exam- model is that in a dynamic game of incomplete
ple, the advertiser in the third position pays an information, players learn each others’ values,
amount equal to the fourth-largest bid.) The making complete information plausible in the
mechanisms used by Google, Yahoo!, and Mi- long-run. This justification follows longstand-
crosoft adCenter build on this GSP approach ing practice in the industrial organization liter-
– though they add variations such as adjusting ature, modeling price competition among firms
prices based on ad quality. See e.g. Abrams and as a one-shot game with common knowledge of
Schwarz (2008). each firm’s production costs.
VOL. 100 NO. 2 OPTIMAL AUCTION DESIGN IN SPONSORED SEARCH 3

The one-shot game of complete information librium of the complete information game, one
has multiple equilibria. Some of these equilibria can view a complete information game as a
can be ruled out by the envy-free restriction in- valid approximation of the incomplete informa-
troduced in EOS and Varian (2007). The envy- tion game. This suggests an equilibrium selec-
free condition requires that no bidder wishes to tion criteria: An equilibrium of complete infor-
exchange positions with a bidder ranked above mation game can be ruled out if there does not
him. Note that the payment of the advertiser exist an equilibrium of the corresponding game
in position 𝑖 − 1 equals the bid of advertiser 𝑖, of incomplete information that converges to the
so envy freeness means that for each advertiser, same outcome. As a result, expected revenue
𝛼𝑖 (𝑠𝑘 −𝑝𝑘 ) ≥ 𝛼𝑖−1 (𝑠𝑘 −𝑏𝑘 ) where 𝑝𝑘 is advertiser in a “plausible” equilibrium of complete infor-
𝑘’s payment per click in his current position, and mation game integrated over all possible real-
𝑏𝑘 is 𝑘’s current bid. EOS and Varian (2007) izations of bidder values cannot exceed the ex-
show that the equilibrium with VCG-equivalent pected revenues in some equilibrium of the in-
payoffs yields the lowest revenues of all envy-free complete information game. We call this the
equilibria. Both EOS and Varian identify the Non-Contradiction Criteria (NCC).
lowest-revenue envy-free (LREF) equilibrium as Let us define NCC precisely. Denote by 𝑅(𝑇 )
the most plausible. Varian offers an informal the expected revenue in the highest revenue per-
argument for the LREF equilibrium, while the fect Bayesian equilibrium of the incomplete in-
main result of EOS shows that in a generalized formation game that lasts for T periods. Let 𝑅
English auction, the LREF equilibrium is the denote the (largest possible) expected per period
unique outcome. Cary et al. (2007) show that equilibrium revenues in an incomplete informa-
if bidders play myopic strategies in a repeated tion game 𝑅 = 𝑇1 lim𝑇 →∞ 𝑅(𝑇 ). Consider equi-
GSP auction, the system converges to the LREF librium per-period revenues in an equilibrium 𝜇
equilibrium. A number of subsequent papers use of the complete information game. Denote by
the LREF equilibrium as the solution concept 𝑟𝜇 (s) the expected revenues in Nash equilibrium
for sponsored search auctions. 𝜇 of a complete information GSP auction where
It remains uncertain whether the LREF equi- values of bidders are given by vector s.
librium is the “right” equilibrium to select in
GSP auctions. Athey and Nikopolev (2010) use DEFINITION 1: A NE 𝜇 of a complete in-
noise in estimates of bidders’ click-through-rate formation game fails NCC if it generates
to pin down the equilibrium. Thompson and greater expected revenues than any equilib-
Leyton-Brown (2009) computationally explore rium of the corresponding incomplete infor-
the set of all equilibria in complete informa- mation
tion GSP. This approach would be unnecessary if ∫ ∫ game. That is, 𝜇 fails NCC if
𝑠1
... 𝑠
𝑟 𝜇 (s)𝑓 (𝑠1 )...𝑓 (𝑠𝑁 )𝑑𝑠1 ...𝑑𝑠𝑁 >𝑅.
a convincing equilibrium selection criteria were 𝑁

available. Borgers et al. (2007) consider var-


ious Nash equilibria of the complete informa- The idea behind NCC differs from the logic of
tion game and suggest that a profit-maximizing most equilibrium refinements. Refinements such
search engine should be able to coordinate bid- as subgame perfection, perfect Bayesian equilib-
ders on an equilibrium with revenue greater than ria, and intuitive criteria result from ruling out
LREF. However, our Proposition 4 shows that strategies that are consistent with NE yet im-
when a reserve price is chosen optimally, a search plausible in the actual game. In contrast, NCC
engine cannot coordinate bidders on an equilib- calls for comparing two distinct games, say 𝐺
rium with revenues higher than in the LREF and Γ. Γ is a game of complete information
equilibrium. that is believed to approximate the behavior of
players in a corresponding game of incomplete
information 𝐺. Some equilibria of Γ may cor-
D. The Non-Contradiction Criteria rectly capture behavior in 𝐺 while others may
(NCC) not. If we can establish some fact that is true in
any equilibrium of 𝐺 (e.g. the upper bound on
As long as the outcome of the incomplete in- equilibrium revenues), this fact can be used to
formation game quickly converges to an equi- narrow the set of relevant equilibria of Γ. Note
4 DRAFT MAY 2010

that NCC is not a restriction on the set of equi- son framework to the case of multiple heteroge-
libria in Γ; NCC says nothing about reasonable neous objects when bidders’ private information
equilibria in Γ. Rather, NCC restricts equilibria is one-dimensional.1
of Γ when Γ is meant to capture behavior in 𝐺. Obtaining an optimal mechanism is a key
We use NCC to analyze sponsored search ad- intermediate result in our analysis. Simi-
vertising. But the underlying idea is general. larly, Roughgarden and Sundararajan (2007)
Many models of complete information games are and Athey and Elison (2009) also obtain an
simplified representations of complex dynamic optimal mechanism as an intermediate result,
games of incomplete information. In these cases, but for entirely different purposes. Iyengar and
the set of plausible equilibria of a static game Kumar (2006) consider computational methods
should be considered in the context of the cor- to estimate optimal auctions when clickthrough
responding incomplete information game. Our rates are arbitrary. In contrast, the structure of
insight is that even if the incomplete informa- clickthrough rates assumed in our model allows
tion game is very complex, it may be possible us to obtain an analytic result.
to bound the set of equilibria of the incomplete The following proposition characterizes the
information game. optimal mechanism2 :

E. Optimal Mechanism for the Incomplete PROPOSITION 2: The generalized English


Information Environment auction with reserve price 𝑟∗ is an optimal
mechanism∗ with reserve price 𝑟∗ that solves
Even though the sponsored search environ- 𝑟∗ − 1−𝐹 (𝑟 )
𝑓 (𝑟 ∗ )
= 0.
ment allows for multistate dynamic mechanisms,
we will show that a one-shot generalized English PROOF:
auction is an optimal mechanism. The optimal direct revelation mechanism can
To apply NCC, we must find an upper bound be characterized using the same technique as
on revenue in the dynamic mechanism. In this in a single object case, except that the prob-
section, we describe the optimal mechanism for ability of receiving an object is replaced with
the incomplete information environment. the expected number of clicks that a bidder re-
Consider the generalized English auction for ceives. Denote 𝑥𝑘 (r) the expected number of
the incomplete information environment. The clicks received by bidder 𝑘 when the realized vec-
auction is run once, and positions are allocated tor of bidder values is given by r = (r1 ...rN ),
for the entire game. Following EOS, imagine and let 𝑓 (r) denote the pdf of vector r and
a clock showing the current price, and contin- 𝑡𝑘 (0) the expected payment of bidder k when his
uously increasing over time. The price begins value is zero. With this modification, formula
at the reserve price, and all advertisers willing 5.12 from Krishna (2002) gives seller ∑𝑁 revenues
to pay at least the reserve price participate in in a direct revelation mechanism: 𝑘=1 𝑡𝑘 (0) +
∫ ∑𝑁
the auction. As the clock ticks upwards, adver- ( 𝑘=1 𝜓(𝑟 𝑘 )𝑥𝑘 (r))𝑓 (r)𝑑r. Thus, only bidders
r
tisers can drop out. The auction is over when with positive virtual valuations are allocated a
the next-to-last advertiser drops out. The last positive expected number of clicks, and bidders
remaining advertiser is placed in the best (high- with higher virtual (and actual) valuations are
est) position. allocated higher positions. Thus, the generalized
In general, optimal auction design for the English auction achieves the same allocation and
sale of multiple heterogeneous objects remains revenue as the optimal direct revelation mecha-
an open problem. However, the structure of nism.
sponsored search makes it possible to extend
the single-object results of Myerson (1981) to
cover multiple items. Although the equilibrium 1 Thus, even if bidders differ in exogenous quality,
price per click is higher in top positions, each an optimal mechanism can be constructed.
advertiser’s value for each position can be de- 2 We thank Michael Ostrovsky for suggesting a
rived from a single variable – the advertiser’s dramatic simplification of the version of this proof
value per click. Ulku (2009) extends the Myer- that appeared in the 2006 draft of this paper.
VOL. 100 NO. 2 OPTIMAL AUCTION DESIGN IN SPONSORED SEARCH 5

COROLLARY 3: The optimal reserve price in are more slots than advertisers, that 𝑛 bidders
the generalized English auction is independent of had values greater than r𝑜𝑙𝑑 , and that 𝑗 bidders
the number of bidders, number of slots being auc- drop out as a result of the increase in reserve.
tioned, and the rate of decline in click-through In the following proposition, we compare the
rate from position to position. revenues resulting from a change in reserve price.

F. Applying NCC PROPOSITION 5: When reserve price in-


creases, the total payment of every advertiser
Consider application of NCC to a complete who remains (except the last) increass by an
information GSP auction with reserve price 𝑟∗ . identical amount.

PROPOSITION 4: In a complete information SKETCH OF PROOF:


GSP auction with a reserve price of 𝑟∗ , from For the full proof, see the online appendix.
among all envy-free equilibria only the lowest Advertiser 𝑛 receives slot 𝑛 and pays reserve
revenue equilibrium survives NCC. Furthermore, price 𝑟. Changing the reserve price by Δ𝑟 =
this equilibrium is unique. 𝑟1 − 𝑟0 changes 𝑛’s total payment 𝛼𝑛 Δ𝑟.
Advertiser 𝑛 − 1 pays a per-click fee 𝑝𝑛−1 =
PROOF: 𝑏𝑛 . With reserve price 𝑟, advertiser 𝑛 bids 𝑏𝑛 =
According to EOS Theorem 1, all envy-free 𝑠𝑛 − 𝛼𝛼𝑛−1
𝑛
(𝑠𝑛 − 𝑟). (See Theorem 2 of EOS.) So
equilibria of the GSP auction yield revenues that the change in reserve price causes 𝑛 − 1’s per-
are at least as large as revenue in the correspond- click payment to change by
ing VCG auction. Yet Proposition 2 shows that
these revenues equal the optimal revenue in the Δ𝑝𝑛−1 = Δ𝑏𝑛 = 𝑏1𝑛 − 𝑏0𝑛
incomplete information environment. All but 𝛼𝑛
= (𝑠𝑛 − (𝑠𝑛 − 𝑟1 ))
one envy-free equilibria of the complete infor- 𝛼𝑛−1
mation GSP auction yield higher revenues than 𝛼𝑛
− (𝑠𝑛 − (𝑠𝑛 − 𝑟0 ))
𝑅 (optimal revenue for incomplete information 𝛼𝑛−1
environment) and hence are ruled out by NCC. 𝛼𝑛
= Δ𝑟
𝛼𝑛−1
II. Reserve Prices and Individual
Advertiser 𝑛 − 1 receives 𝛼𝑛−1 clicks, so
Bidder Payoffs
his total payment changes by 𝛼𝑛−1 Δ𝑝𝑛−1 =
𝛼𝑛−1 ( 𝛼𝛼𝑛−1
𝑛
Δ𝑟) = 𝛼𝑛 Δ𝑟.
In this section, we explore the impact of re-
Recursing upwards yields an identical cancel-
serve prices in an equilibrium of the generalized
lation of terms at each step – hence the same to-
English auction where strategies are continuous
tal payment change, 𝛼𝑛 Δ𝑟, for each advertiser.
in player types.
Now consider the case in which the changed
reserve 𝑟1 exceeds the valuations of the lowest 𝑗
A. Bidders’ Cost Increases advertisers. Unable to achieve a positive profit,
these advertisers exit. Advertiser 𝑛 − 𝑗 takes the
In this section, we will show that raising the role of 𝑛 in the preceding analysis. 𝑛 − 𝑗’s per-
reserve price creates an indirect effect far larger click payment change is irregular, but each other
than the direct effect. advertiser’s total payment changes by 𝛼𝑛−𝑗 Δ𝑟.
The reserve price directly affcts the lowest
bidder. As long as there are more positions The following corollary shows that indirect
than bidders, the lowest bidder pays the re- effects are in some sense larger than direct ef-
serve price.) The reserve price may also indi- fects: The higher the position, the greater the
rectly affect other bidders because change in re- expected incremental revenue from reserve price.
serve price may impact equilibrium behavior of
all players. COROLLARY 6: As reserve price increases,
Consider an increase in a reserve price by an the expected increase in revenue from position
amount Δ𝑟 = 𝑟𝑛𝑒𝑤 − 𝑟𝑜𝑙𝑑 . Suppose that there 𝑘 exceeds the expected increase from 𝑘 + 1.
6 DRAFT MAY 2010

B. Welfare Implications theoretical contribution – equilibrium selection


criteria – also grounds our results. Moreover,
Under realistic assumptions, an optimal re- our counterintuitive revenue finding – an indi-
serve price can yield a notable increase in search rect effect larger than the direct effect – stands
engine revenue. For example, Yahoo CEO Sue at the intersection of theory and application.
Decker stated in a Q3 2008 earnings call that
reserve price was the “most significant” cause of REFERENCES
the 11% increase in Yahoo’s revenue per search.
Ostrovsky and Schwarz (2010) use an experi- Z. Abrams and M. Schwarz. Ad auction design
ment to measure the impact of reserve prices. and user experience. Applied Economics Re-
In simulations, we explored how reserve price search Bulletin, pages 98–105, October 2008.
impacts bidders and the seller. The plot below
S. Athey and G. Ellison. Position auctions with
shows simulations with five advertisers whose
consumer search. NBER WP 15253, 2009.
values are drawn from a log-normal distribution
with mean 1 and standard deviation 0.25. S. Athey and D. Nekipelov. A structural model
of equilibrium and uncertainty in sponsored
search advertising auctions. Mimeo, 2010.
T. Borgers, I. Cox, M. Pesendorfer, and V. Pet-
ricek. Equilibrium bids in sponsored search
auctions. U. Ann Arbor Manuscript, 2007.
M. Cary, A. Das, B. Edelman, I. Giotis,
  K. Heimerl, A. Karlin, C. Mathieu, and
The graph reveals that moving from a zero M. Schwarz. Greedy bidding strategies for key-
reserve price to optimal reserve price leads to a word auctions. Proceedings of ACM EC, 2007.
small decline in total surplus and a significant B. Edelman, M. Ostrovsky, and M. Schwarz.
increase in search engine revenues. Internet advertising and the generalized sec-
ond price auction. American Economic Review,
III. Conclusion pages 242–259, April 2007.
G. Iyengar and A. Kumar. Characterizing op-
Reserve prices may have an important impact
timal adword auctions. CORC Report 2006-04.
on search advertising marketplaces. But the ef-
fect of reserve price can be opaque, particularly V. Krishna. Auction Theory. Academic Press,
because it is not always straightforward to com- 2002.
pare “before” and “after” conditions. Proposi- R. Myerson. Optimal auction design. Mathe-
tion 5 assesses the distributional consequences, matics of Operations Research, 6:58–73, 1981.
revealing the counterintuitive across-the-board M. Ostrovsky and M. Schwarz. Reserve prices
effects of reserve price increases that might have in internet advertising auctions: A field exper-
seemed to target low bidders exclusively. iment. Mimeo, 2010.
Our paper also offers insight on equilibrium T. Roughgarden and M. Sundararajan. Is effi-
selection. By establishing bounds on any equi- ciency expensive? In Third Workshop on Spon-
librium of a complex game, we can reduce the sored Search Auctions, WWW2007.
set of plausible equilibria of a simpler game used
D. Thompson and K. Leyton-Brown. Com-
to understand the more complex game. An ap-
putational analysis of perfect-information po-
proach similar to ours may apply in many con-
sition auctions. In Proceedings of ACM EC,
texts where a one-shot game offers a simplified
2009.
view of repeated interactions, e.g. Cournot and
Bertrand models of industry competition. Levent Ulku. Optimal combinatorial mecha-
We see this paper as an example of applied nism design. ITAM Working Paper 0903, 2009.
theory. We address the important applied prob- H. Varian. Position auctions. International
lem of setting an optimal reserve price in a large Journal of Industrial Organization, pages
and growing market, and we analyze mecha- 1163–1178, October 2007.
nisms that are widely used in practice. Yet our
Online Appendix: Proof of 𝑛 − 1’s change in bid is
Proposition 5
Δ𝑏𝑛−1 = 𝑏1𝑛 − 𝑏0𝑛
𝛼𝑛−1
PROPOSITION 5: When reserve price in- = (𝑠𝑛 − (𝑠𝑛 − 𝑏1𝑛 ))
𝛼𝑛−2
creases, the total payment of every advertiser 𝛼𝑛−1
who remains (except the last) increass by an − (𝑠𝑛 − (𝑠𝑛 − 𝑏0𝑛 ))
𝛼𝑛−2
identical amount. 𝛼𝑛−1 1
= (𝑏𝑛 − 𝑏0𝑛 )
𝛼𝑛−2
𝛼𝑛−1
= (Δ𝑏𝑛 )
PROOF: 𝛼𝑛−2
𝛼𝑛−1 𝛼𝑛
Setup. Advertisers are 1..𝑛, and slots are = ( (𝑟1 − 𝑟0 ))
𝛼𝑛−2 𝛼𝑛−1
also 1..𝑛. Initial reserve price 𝑟0 changes to some 𝛼𝑛
new reserve price 𝑟1 . Suppose for now that the = Δ𝑟
𝛼𝑛−2
new reserve price 𝑟1 remains sufficiently low that
no advertiser is priced out of the market, i.e. Advertiser 𝑛 − 2 receives 𝛼𝑛−2 clicks. So ad-
𝑟1 ≤ 𝑠𝑛 . vertiser 𝑛 − 2’s total payment increases by
Advertiser n. Advertiser 𝑛 receives slot 𝑛 𝛼𝑛−2 Δ𝑏𝑛−1 = 𝛼𝑛−2 𝛼𝛼𝑛−2𝑛
Δ𝑟 = 𝛼𝑛 Δ𝑟. Recurs-
and pays the reserve price 𝑟. So when the re- ing upwards to advertiser 1 confirms that each
serve price increases from 𝑟0 to 𝑟1 , advertiser advertiser’s total payment increases by the same
𝑛’s per-click payment increases by Δ𝑟 = 𝑟1 − 𝑟0 . amount, 𝛼𝑛 Δ𝑟.
Advertiser 𝑛 receives 𝛼𝑛 clicks, so advertiser 𝑛’s
total payment increases by 𝛼𝑛 Δ𝑟. Reserve price that excludes one or more
advertisers. We now allow an increase in re-
Advertiser n-1. The per-click fee 𝑝𝑛−1 paid serve price such that one or more advertisers is
by advertiser 𝑛−1 is determined by the per-click priced out of the market (relaxing the assump-
bid 𝑏𝑛 of advertiser 𝑛. With reserve price 𝑟, ad- tion in the first paragraph of the proof).
vertiser 𝑛 bids 𝑏𝑛 = 𝑠𝑛 − 𝛼𝛼𝑛−1𝑛
(𝑠𝑛 − 𝑟). (This Suppose the increased reserve 𝑟1 exceeds ad-
is the base case of Theorem 2 of EOS.) So when vertiser 𝑛’s valuation 𝑠𝑛 . Then advertiser 𝑛 can
the reserve price changes from 𝑟0 to 𝑟1 , adver- never achieve a positive profit by buying ads;
tiser 𝑛 − 1’s change in per-click payment equals 𝑛 would have to pay more than his valuation.
advertiser 𝑛’s change in per-click bid, which is So 𝑛 exits. What about the other advertisers?
Advertiser 𝑛 − 1 now takes on the role of 𝑛 in
Δ𝑝𝑛−1 = Δ𝑏𝑛 = 𝑏1𝑛 − 𝑏0𝑛 the preceding analysis. Δ𝑝𝑛−1 = Δ𝑏𝑛 = 𝑟1 − 𝑏0𝑛
𝛼𝑛 which is irregular and cannot be fully simpli-
= (𝑠𝑛 − (𝑠𝑛 − 𝑟1 ))
𝛼𝑛−1 fied. But advertisers 𝑛 − 2 and above follow the
𝛼𝑛 pattern of the preceding section, and for each
− (𝑠𝑛 − (𝑠𝑛 − 𝑟0 ))
𝛼𝑛−1 of those advertiser, total payment increases by
𝛼𝑛 𝛼𝑛−1 Δ𝑟.
= Δ𝑟
𝛼𝑛−1 More generally, if the increased reserve price
leads 𝑗 advertisers to drop out, then the total
Advertiser 𝑛 − 1 receives 𝛼𝑛−1 clicks. So when increase of advertisers 1 through 𝑛 − 𝑗 − 1 is
the reserve price increases by Δ𝑟, advertiser 𝑛 − 𝛼𝑛−𝑗 Δ𝑟.
1’s total payment increases by 𝛼𝑛−1 Δ𝑝𝑛−1 =
𝛼𝑛−1 ( 𝛼𝛼𝑛−1
𝑛
Δ𝑟) = 𝛼𝑛 Δ𝑟.
Advertiser n-2 and the general case. Ad-
vertiser 𝑛 − 2 pays a per-click fee 𝑝𝑛−2 given by
𝑏𝑛−1 . With reserve price 𝑟, advertiser 𝑛 − 1 bids
𝛼
𝑏𝑛−1 = 𝑠𝑛−1 − 𝛼𝑛−1 𝑛−2
(𝑠𝑛−1 − 𝑏𝑛 ). (This is the
general case of Theorem 2 of EOS.) So when the
reserve price changes from 𝑟0 to 𝑟1 , advertiser

Das könnte Ihnen auch gefallen