Sie sind auf Seite 1von 14

World Development Vol. 40, No. 1, pp.

96–109, 2012
Ó 2011 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved
0305-750X/$ - see front matter
www.elsevier.com/locate/worlddev
doi:10.1016/j.worlddev.2011.05.017

Can Public–Private Partnerships Leverage Private Investment


in Agricultural Value Chains in Africa? A Preliminary Review
COLIN POULTON
School of Oriental and African Studies (SOAS), UK

and

JON MACARTNEY *
Independent Consultant
Summary. — Public–private partnerships (PPPs) may be one way of increasing the level of private sector investment into poorly per-
forming agricultural value chains. This paper considers a range of PPP mechanisms that respond to different market failures affecting
such chains and draws on principal–agent theory to illustrate the challenges. It reviews emerging experience with a number of these
mechanisms along with experience from other sectors that may shed light on “generic” problems of implementing PPPs in Africa. While
finding some positive impacts on investment, it notes that state failures can also undermine PPP effectiveness. As the evidence base is still
limited, it calls on organizations promoting innovative PPPs to disclose available information for critical examination.
Ó 2011 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.

Key words — market failure, state failure, public private partnerships (PPP), agriculture, Africa

1. INTRODUCTION sibility for design and execution”. All these definitions


emphasize new investment facilitated by a cooperative ap-
Many parts of African agriculture may be thought of as proach and risk sharing.
struggling between market and state failure. There has been Through PPPs the state (or other “public” actor, such as a
some disappointment with the private sector response to donor or nonprofit foundation) seeks to align the incentives
agricultural market liberalization, which is perhaps best facing private sector actors with public policy goals, for exam-
described as “uneven”. Thus after a period when the major ple the provision of public goods or of services to poor groups.
policy emphasis was on getting the state out of agricultural In this paper we focus on cases where the mechanism formally
marketing activity in Africa, over the past decade or so there used to seek this alignment is some type of contract.
has been a search for a more active role for the state that goes In recent years there has been growing interest in possible
beyond the creation of a basic enabling environment toward PPP mechanisms to improve the performance of poorly func-
encouraging market development. Simultaneously, there is tioning agricultural value chains in Africa and elsewhere. Thus,
ongoing disappointment with the performance of public sector World Bank (2007) notes that PPPs “offer much potential” for
service delivery, including in—but not restricted to—the stimulating innovation, highlighting biotechnology research
agricultural sector. This has prompted a search for ways to and value chains for high value agricultural products as two
bring the private sector into provision of services that were areas of particular promise. Langyintuo et al. (2010) argue that
traditionally considered to be the preserve of state agencies. seed systems in southern and eastern Africa would benefit from
This paper reviews a variety of so-called public–private support from PPP interventions. However, in practice there has
partnerships designed to leverage private investment both been rather less action: many interventions are still at proof-of-
where existing participation in value chains is considered too concept stage. Perhaps understandably, there have been even
limited and into the provision of services traditionally fewer formal evaluations. Nevertheless, it is noteworthy how
provided by the public sector. The scope of the term little information on innovative PPPs for agricultural value
“public–private partnership” (PPP) is subject to considerable chains is readily available. This paper does not provide an
debate (Hodge & Greve, 2007). Hodge and Greve (2007) cite exhaustive review of available evidence, but it does set out what
a definition from Van Ham and Koppenjan (2001, p. 598) of the authors believe to be important general lessons for Africa
“cooperation of some sort of durability between public and from experience so far. One objective is to stimulate deeper
private actors in which they jointly develop products and ser-
vices and share risks, costs, and resources which are connected
with these products”. Narrod et al. (2009, p. 10) define a PPP * A longer version of this paper was commissioned by the Trade and
as “a cooperative venture between the public and private Markets Division of FAO under the EU-funded All ACP Agricultural
sectors built on the expertise of each partner that best meets Commodities Programme. The authors are grateful for comments on
clearly defined goals through the appropriate allocation of re- the paper from participants at a workshop at FAO, Rome in June
sources, risks and rewards”. According to the World Eco- 2010. Sections of the paper also benefited from research assistance from
nomic Forum definition, cited by Warner, Kahan, and Lehel Elena Baglioni and from discussions with Mark Thomas (manager of
(2008, p. 9), PPPs entail “reciprocal obligations and mutual DFID’s Food Retail Industry Challenge Fund), Brinda Ganguly
accountability, voluntary or contractual relationships, the (Rockefeller Foundation, New York) and Akin Adesina (AGRA,
sharing of investment and reputational risks, and joint respon- Nairobi). Final revision accepted: April 12, 2011.
96
PUBLIC–PRIVATE PARTNERSHIPS LEVERAGE PRIVATE INVESTMENTIN AGRICULTURAL VALUE CHAINS IN AFRICA 97

debate on the potential of PPPs in the hope of bringing infor- production and marketing activity in many parts of rural
mation currently buried in gray literature out into the full pub- Africa. Meanwhile, in important export markets, consumers,
lic arena. retailers, and legislators are demanding greater assurances
In this paper some reference is made to PPPs in agricul- about produce quality and safety. This makes it difficult for
tural value chains in other continents, but experience with African supply chains, especially those relying on large num-
PPPs in agricultural value chains in Africa is also compared bers of smallholder producers, to stay competitive (Henson &
with experience within nonagricultural sectors in Africa. Reardon, 2005; Otsuki, Wilson, & Sewadeh, 2001), thus
Much of the literature here is quite critical of PPPs in prac- discouraging investment.
tice and sometimes also as a concept (foisted by donors on As greater emphasis has been placed on the role of transac-
unconvinced governments for ideological reasons where priv- tion costs and the associated risks in constraining private sec-
atization of state activities was not considered a viable op- tor activity in African agricultural markets, so there has been a
tion). Nonagricultural examples are considered relevant search for ways in which public agencies might share some of
here because the low capacity of many African states and of- these costs and risks. Many of the interventions discussed in
ten ambiguous attitudes toward private sector-led develop- this paper have this objective. However, high transaction costs
ment among political elites can be expected to affect public are not the only constraint to greater private sector investment
engagement with the private sector irrespective of sectoral in African agricultural markets, nor even necessarily the bind-
boundaries. ing constraint. PPPs will only encourage greater private invest-
The paper proceeds as follows: In Section 2 reasons for the ment where they tackle the binding constraint to such
poor functioning of agricultural value chains are briefly dis- investment. While a sharing of transactions costs and risks
cussed, leading to an understanding of the types of market could partly compensate for high costs due to an unstable
(and associated state) failures that PPP mechanisms may be macro-economic environment or inadequate physical infra-
designed to address. Section 3 presents a typology of PPP structure, it is unlikely to stimulate greater private investment
mechanisms that is used to structure later sections. Section 4 where unpredictable state policies are what currently discour-
draws on principal–agent theory to highlight the major design age such investment.
challenges facing PPP mechanisms. Sections 5–8 review expe- Table 1 summarizes a range of market failures affecting
rience with different mechanisms both in nonagricultural and African agricultural markets and indicates where some form
agricultural contexts to address the following questions: of PPP might stimulate greater private involvement. Note that
 Can PPPs remove or alleviate binding constraints on pri- there may also be other public interventions that can stimulate
vate investment? greater private sector participation. For example, publicly-
 Can contractual arrangements between state and private funded marketing information or business development ser-
sector actors incentivize the latter to provide supply chain vices may reduce barriers to entry in agricultural markets.
services in ways that meet public policy objectives? However, it is only interventions where a state agency enters
Finally, Section 9 concludes. into some form of contractual relationship with a private sec-
tor partner(s) that are defined as PPPs and reviewed in this pa-
per.
2. REASONS FOR POOR FUNCTIONING OF AGRI- Meanwhile, some PPPs attempt to stimulate private involve-
CULTURAL VALUE CHAINS ment in the provision of services traditionally provided by the
public sector (row 2). Often, the original rationale for public
Following agricultural market liberalization in Africa pri- sector provision was market failure, emanating from the pub-
vate traders have taken up many opportunities to purchase lic or merit good attributes of the services in question. How-
output from producers, although levels of entry and compe- ever, where state provision is also perceived to have failed,
tition vary across geographic space. In general, private sector innovative ways are being sought to bring the private sector
participation in the provision of pre-harvest services has been in after all.
more limited than participation in output marketing. How-
ever, there are significant differences across crop groups, with
the incentives for investment in service provision for tradi- 3. PUBLIC–PRIVATE PARTNERSHIPS: A TYPOLOGY
tional export cash crops generally much stronger than for
food crops (Poulton, Dorward, & Kydd, 2010). Private Table 2 categorizes PPPs according to the type of investment
investment in crop storage has been another “disappointing” that they seek to stimulate or other role that they might play.
area, contributing to increased price volatility post-liberaliza- While in practice the boundaries between categories can be
tion. blurred, the rows in Table 2 are intended to correspond to
The reasons for these outcomes remain contested. Jayne, those in Table 1. Thus, for example, PPPs to develop new prod-
Govereh, Mwanaumo, Nyoro, and Chapoto (2002) argue ucts and services principally tackle problems of barriers to en-
that states have not fully withdrawn from many input and try (row 3 in both tables). Table 2 identifies sectors outside
output markets; their continued presence—and/or the contin- agriculture where the relevant mechanisms have been used, as
ued threat of state intervention—discourages private invest- well as applications related to agricultural supply chains.
ment. Commission for Africa (2005) and Jayne, Govereh, Two details of Table 2 may require more explanation at this
Wanzala, and Demeke (2003) emphasize the impact of low point. Firstly, row 2 distinguishes (a) contracts for delivery of
public investment in basic infrastructure on private invest- services where public sector financing is expected to be re-
ment opportunities in agricultural marketing. Kherallah, quired for the foreseeable future, from (b) good or services
Delgado, Gabre-Madhin, Minot, and Johnson (2000) and where, after a period of improved access (hence greater famil-
Fafchamps (2004) argue that important institutions required iarity), consumers’ willingness to pay might be sufficient to
to support efficient private markets have not been established. sustain a commercial service. In the latter case, public funds
Finally, according to Poulton, Kydd, and Dorward (2006), may be used to stimulate demand in the short-medium term.
important coordination issues have to be tackled to overcome This, then, represents an intermediate case between contract-
“low level equilibrium traps” constraining agricultural ing out of a public service and support for the development
98 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

Table 1. Sources of failure in agricultural markets


Source of market failure: What is the constraint to private sector involvement? Agricultural examples Possible PPP solutions
1. Lack of enabling Unstable macro-economic environment; – –
environment
Inadequate physical infrastructure; Rural roads, irrigation Provision and/or
infrastructure maintenance of infrastructure
Weak property rights and/or contract enforcement; – –
State as problem (crowding out, unpredictable policies) – –
2. Public or Merit Market under-provides due to:
goods
-Nonexcludability, nonsubtractability OPV seed research Contracting out service
delivery
-Social benefits exceed private benefits Fertilizer (e.g., if food price falls) Voucher schemes
-Lack of effective demand Extension
3. Barriers to entry Lack of access to:
Capital Stockists, Seed companies Loan guarantees
-Technical knowledge – –
-Market information – –
High fixed costs/risks Biotechnology research, credit, Risk sharing schemes
smallholder engagement in high
value commodity chains
4. Coordination failures Asymmetric information, no mechanism to Complementary investments in Deliberative fora
enforce commitments; lack of trust service provision to smallholders
or along value chain

Table 2. A typology of PPPs for leveraging private sector investment


Category Sub-type Nonagriculture Agriculture
1. Capital Investment Roads Rural roads
(and Maintenance) Prisons Irrigation
Schools Market Places
Hospitals Rural ICT
2. Service Delivery a) Service Contracts Water Extension contracting
(ongoing) Solid waste
Primary health care
b) Demand stimulation Bednet distribution Fertilizer vouchers
Extension vouchers
3. New Products and a) Investment Funds Neglected health research Smallholder inclusion in high value
Services (“bottom of the chains
pyramid”) b) IPR deals Seed varietal research
c) Loan Guarantee Funds – Guarantees to banks for loans to
stockists, seed companies, farmers
4. Coordination Health investment funds Stakeholders’ fora (whole value chain)
(Deliberative fora)

of new products and services by the private sector (row 3). 4. THEORETICAL CONSIDERATIONS
Distinguishing service delivery and new products development
in this way highlights the importance of considering exit strat- Principal–agent (P–A) theory can shed light on the chal-
egies for the public sector from PPPs. lenges inherent in devising and managing PPPs. Assume that
Secondly, deliberative fora (the final row of Table 2) are a the state (or other “public” actor) is the principal, while the
bit different in nature from the other mechanisms discussed agent is the private company, partnership, or consortium
in this paper. Such fora bring together stakeholders from pub- that the state contracts with. Formally, the state wishes to
lic and private sectors for dialog that, it is hoped, will generate harness the capacity (human and investment), entrepreneur-
mutual understanding and trust and thereby lead to joint ac- ship and innovation of the private sector “agent” to achieve
tion to strengthen value chains. This joint action could include public policy goals. However, it has to recognize that private
the types of contractual arrangements discussed elsewhere in sector “agents” (1) have their own objectives and (2) will
the paper. However, it could also include coordinated actions only enter into PPP agreements that will further these objec-
by private players, where the role of the state is limited to that tives. Specifically, their expected “utility” from PPP agree-
of discussion facilitator, or private investments that are ments should exceed the opportunity cost of the resources
encouraged by changes made within the policy or institutional that they will have to contribute. (This is the agent’s reserva-
environment as a result of the forum deliberations. tion position).
PUBLIC–PRIVATE PARTNERSHIPS LEVERAGE PRIVATE INVESTMENTIN AGRICULTURAL VALUE CHAINS IN AFRICA 99

To illustrate the divergence in objectives, assume that the market. However, where PPP agreements are designed to
private sector ultimately seeks to maximize profits. This can leverage greater private sector involvement in poorly function-
encourage firms to cut costs (raise efficiency), innovate, or ex- ing value chains, the number of potential partners will often be
pand service coverage (in such a way that the total size of the small. This gives the agent more active bargaining power. Fur-
market increases). PPP agreements aim to harness such entre- thermore, one way of avoiding adverse selection is to work
preneurial energy in pursuit of public goals. However, firms with “established” players. However, narrowing the choice
only act like this if external conditions (market competi- in this way increases the chances that the agent will exercise
tion—or, failing that, the incentives provided by a contract) power in contractual negotiations. Indeed, given the disparity
demand it. Alternatively, they might seek profit through in resources between African state agencies (or their person-
increasing margins, reducing quality, or displacing competi- nel) and some large private companies, private sector agents
tors. A contract with a public agency could assist them to may not just exert power in contract negotiations, but may
do any of these things. even “capture” the agency or personnel that are supposedly
As a result some observers are wary of PPP agreements, acting as principal.
which could simply squander public resources on the enlarge- This leads to the fourth and perhaps most fundamental point.
ment of private profit, with no improvement in service deliv- While a state might have an agreed set of public policy objec-
ery. From the perspective of P–A theory, however, the tives (summarized, for example, in a national development plan
challenge facing the state is to: or Poverty Reduction Strategy Paper), individual agents within
Identify appropriate private sector players to contract with. the state—including the most senior ones—might pursue quite
Through the terms of the contract, structure incentives to different private objectives (van de Walle, 2001). Thus, the insti-
encourage the private “agent” to act in line with the “public tutional set-up for devising and implementing PPP agreements
interest”. should include provision for holding the “principals” account-
Achieve all this at reasonable cost. able for their actions. Asymmetric information again comes
The problem is asymmetric information in the presence of into play. In some contexts public officials—or consultants
risk. If the state had perfect information on the capability hired by such officials—who truly understand private sector
and motives of potential private sector partners prior to business models and operations are scarce. If they defend PPP
signing a contract and on their actions and motivations dur- agreements as the best deal that the public sector could obtain,
ing its implementation, contracting would be straightfor- it may be costly for those holding them accountable to discern
ward. Unfortunately, these things are at least partly the truth or otherwise of such claims.
hidden from everybody except the senior management of
the firm itself.
Hart and Holmstrom (1987) distinguish three types of P–A 5. PPPS FOR CAPITAL INVESTMENT
models. Under adverse selection the main challenge facing the
principal is to choose an agent with the capability and motiva- To date these are more common in OECD countries and La-
tion to do what the principal wants. Under moral hazard (hid- tin America than in Africa.
den action), the principal cannot observe the actions of the
agent, although it can observe the outcomes. Under moral (a) Nonagricultural infrastructure
hazard (hidden information), the principal observes the ac-
tions of the agent, but cannot observe the contingencies under OECD experience with infrastructure PPPs is reviewed by
which they were taken. Hodge and Greve(2007, 2009). They note positive assessments
In all cases risk factors beyond the agent’s control affect the from both individual studies and reviews, but argue that
relationship between the agent’s action and the observed out- equally authoritative studies and reviews reach skeptical or
come. Hence, the principal cannot be sure whether an undesir- negative conclusions. Two main arguments are advanced for
able outcome results from opportunistic actions or decisions PPPs in infrastructure investment: (i) that they can relieve
by the agent or from adverse circumstances. The combination pressure on the public budget, because private firms assume
of the asymmetric information constraint and the risk factors responsibility for raising finance necessary for infrastructure
restricts the principal’s choice of indicators for inclusion in the investment; (ii) that by involving the private sector in this
contract: what is observable and, therefore, measurable? How- way, the state can achieve better value-for-money in infra-
ever, use of “second-best” indicators can distort the incentives structure provision. On the first claim, Hodge and Greve
faced by the agent, so considerable care has to be taken in con- (2007) observe that there is little evidence that money “saved”
tract design. Implementation could produce poor outcomes through resort to infrastructure PPPs is diverted to other
(i.e., not contributing to public policy goals) simply because pressing uses. Moreover, it is only the need for lump sum pay-
the contract was poorly specified. ments that is saved by PPPs: states still have to remunerate
Four additional issues are worthy of note. Firstly, P–A the private partners eventually, unless some of the investment
models generally assume that principals have a reasonable can be recouped through user fees. Evidence on the second
understanding of the “utility functions” and “reservation posi- claim is mixed. A methodological challenge is to establish
tions” of the population of agents with whom they might do the appropriate public-sector-only counterfactual against
business. 1 Indeed, the principal maximizes his/her expected which costs of a PPP project can be compared. Assessment
profit by providing a set of incentives that will allow the agent is further complicated by the complex remuneration formulae
to just achieve his/her reservation position. While some public embodied in some long-term infrastructure maintenance con-
agencies may employ personnel with this level of understand- tracts.
ing of large private sector operations, the analytical capacity Warner et al. (2008, p. 45–46), commenting on PPPs for
of many African state agencies with respect to private sector water, health, and education infrastructure in developing
business models is arguably rather more limited. countries, observe that private operators frequently complain
Secondly, it is assumed that the principal can push the agent of insufficient government commitment to agreements, espe-
down to his/her reservation position because the agent is a cially after political change-overs. Politicians may view PPPs
price (or contractual term) “taker” within a competitive as ways of getting more for less or as opportunities for
100 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

rent-seeking. Thus, if the real constraint to investment is lack Lack of capacity (on both sides, but particularly within
of political commitment to public service delivery, PPPs may public agencies) to structure and negotiate deals that deli-
not solve the problem. Warner et al. (2008) recommend: ver value for money for the state and its citizens, while still
More transparent procurement and bidding processes. providing a sufficient return on investment to be attractive
Mechanisms, such as multi-stakeholder fora, to give infra- to private investors.
structure beneficiaries a voice regarding service delivery Competitive bidding processes to ensure transparency in
options. contract allocation have high fixed costs. Relatively large
That private operators build strong relationships with cus- projects are required to make these costs worthwhile.
tomers, who “may then be a source of support in disputes Equally, the set-up costs of a PPP, which also include the
with political leaders” (p. 46). costs of negotiating a final contract with the selected
bidder, have to be offset against any efficiency gains from
(b) PPPs for construction and maintenance of agricultural private sector involvement.
infrastructure In the absence of a suitable regulatory framework, private
investors may pursue pricing policies that exclude poor
Improved infrastructure is vital to increase competitiveness groups, thereby undermining the “public” nature of bene-
in many African agricultural value chains (World Bank, fits from the infrastructure investment.
2009), but government and donor investments in rural
infrastructure projects fell during the 1980s and 1990s.
Volumes of business in much of rural Africa remain too low 6. CONTRACTING THE PRIVATE SECTOR FOR
to directly recover investment costs in infrastructure, while SERVICE DELIVERY
revenue streams that depend on rainfed smallholder agricul-
tural production are considered too risky by many private As with PPPs for infrastructural investment, experience with
investors. contracting out of service delivery 2 in water, waste manage-
Nevertheless, there may be advantages to private sector par- ment, and health sectors in developing countries shows that
ticipation in infrastructure investment, including the private this rarely avoids the problems of state failure that previously
sector’s ability to source investment capital (easing immediate afflicted public service delivery, while the fundamental
constraints on infrastructure investment imposed by limited challenges of service delivery remain.
state development budgets, albeit at the cost of higher recur- PPP water contracts in Africa have struggled in the face of
rent budgets in future) and its project management skills. Un- high costs of constructing new distribution (pipe) networks
der a conventional construction contract, a public agency on the one hand and low willingness to pay for public water
might pay a private contractor to construct the asset in ques- supplies (due to low incomes and popular beliefs that access
tion, with subsequent management and maintenance of that to water should be a right) on the other (Kayaga, 2008). How-
asset handled (often by the public agency) through separate ever, both Kayaga (2008) and Tati (2005) also highlight limi-
arrangements. A PPP agreement can engage the same private tations in contract design and the contractor selection
firm both in construction and subsequent management, with processes. Where services have traditionally been provided
the firm contributing investment capital that is recouped by the public sector, one should not expect strong domestic
through revenue linked to asset management, utilization, or private sector capacity to exist.
performance. This can reduce the incentives to cut construc- Awortwi (2004) assesses the contracting out of solid waste
tion costs in ways that undermine future performance of the collection services by municipal governments in Ghana. Many
asset, while also sharing the risks from cost overruns or lower of the fundamental rules of P–A theory were ignored in prac-
than expected utilization of the asset. tice. As a result, the volume of solid waste that was collected
Key questions concern the revenue stream for the private increased (this was the basis on which the companies were
company. Potential for user fees varies by type of rural infra- paid), but so too did the cost per ton of solid waste collected.
structure (compare irrigation with feeder roads). Shadow tar- Two of the major contracts were not competitively tendered,
iffs, whereby the sum paid by the public partner to the private which discouraged efficiency savings. Instead, “politics and
operator depends on utilization rates or other dimensions of patronage became a factor in awarding contracts” (Awortwi,
performance, are a way of encouraging risk sharing. Warner 2004, p. 218). Meanwhile, inflexible civil service regulations
et al. (2008) argue that infrastructure investment can be made meant that few jobs were saved by contracting services out,
more attractive to the private sector through “bundling” con- but few resources were made available for monitoring contrac-
tracts for complementary investments—for example, feeder tual performance. However, 10 years of contracting out had
roads + agro-processing or irrigation + power generation— stimulated capacity for service delivery among community-
which have different revenue and risk profiles. based organizations, which could stimulate future competition
In practice, Warner et al. (2008, p. 10–11) cite World Bank and performance.
figures showing that only 1% of private investment in Palmer and Mills (2005) examine three contracts for pri-
infrastructure during 2003–05 was in investments directly or mary health care services in South Africa and Lesotho. Pri-
indirectly related to agriculture (i.e., including rural electrifica- mary health care is complex, involving a broad range of
tion and telecommunications). Based on a review of 18 PPPs services. This makes it difficult to specify complete contracts,
for rural infrastructure (seven of which are in Africa), they con- documenting all services to be rendered and under what
clude that PPPs can have a number of advantages and that con- terms. This is particularly the case in rural locations where
ditions are in many ways right for their use to be expanded. it is rare for more than one service provider to operate in
However, they are “by no means a panacea” (p. 6) for problems a given area. Similarly, the known pool of potential provid-
of rural infrastructural investment. Potential pitfalls include: ers is often low, so rural contracts may be managed relation-
Lack of real political will—politicians can have various ally. Palmer and Mills (2005) note that, if problems were
motives for seeking to leverage private investment and identified, contractor and provider generally talked them
may renege on agreements that turn out to be politically over, as contract termination was considered problematic.
unpopular, for example due to high user fees charged. Monitoring was also problematic: the resources within the
PUBLIC–PRIVATE PARTNERSHIPS LEVERAGE PRIVATE INVESTMENTIN AGRICULTURAL VALUE CHAINS IN AFRICA 101

contracting agency for visiting rural care centers were lim- in NAADS sub-counties than in their matched control group
ited. of nonNAADS sub-counties. However, adoption rates of new
Within the agricultural sector, Hubbard (2003, p. 148–157) technologies were insufficient to generate higher yield growth
reviews four cases where state agencies (two African and in NAADS sub-counties than others. Benin et al. (2007) also
two South Asian) contracted private providers for diverse ser- found that NAADS service providers were more effective at
vices (crop storage or export, rural road maintenance). He promoting the adoption of new crop varieties and yield
concludes that the agencies could generally handle basic con- enhancing technologies than at promoting improved soil fertil-
tracting tasks, but that unwillingness of state agencies to ity management, while Bahiigwa, Rigby, and Woodhouse
reconfigure themselves as regulators, rather than service pro- (2005) found that NAADS focused primarily on commercial
viders, constitutes a significant obstacle to the expansion of producers and crops. Advice on new crop varieties and yield
contracting. enhancing technologies is fairly readily time-bound, with
adoption relatively easily linked to the advice received (hence
(a) Agricultural extension services well suited to a contracting approach), whereas soil fertility
management is more complex and the impacts longer term.
Anderson and Feder (2007) quote estimates that “80% of the In this sense, these findings are consistent with the predictions
world’s extension services are publicly funded and delivered by of theory.
civil servants” (p. 2345), while only 5% are private. Except Wider lessons from these two cases include the following.
where supply chains are characterized by strong vertical coor- Firstly, given the pre-reform history of public extension provi-
dination between farmers and buyers, two over-riding con- sion in both Chile and Uganda, most of the “private” provid-
straints discourage private investment in extension service ers post-reform are agents who have come out of the public
delivery: much extension information has public or common system. In extension there are no international specialist ser-
pool good attributes, while variable weather and/or market vice providers ready to enter national markets to compete
prices render the valuation of advice, and thus ability of ser- for contracts. Thus, reform programs should build in an ele-
vice providers to appropriate a suitable user charge, difficult ment of capacity building for commercial extension providers.
(Hanson & Just, 2001). The attributes of the extension process Secondly, effective farmer voice in contract allocation and
also pose formidable challenges for management of effective monitoring requires functioning decentralized administrative
delivery, irrespective of the agent (public, private, NGO). systems and strong farmer organizations. These two elements
Attributing positive agricultural outcomes to particular exten- are missing in much of eastern and southern Africa. While
sion input or disappointing agricultural performance to poor NAADS shows that the latter can be developed as part of
extension services is often not possible (Israel, 1987). The effort an extension reform program, assuming sufficient (donor?)
of front-line extension staff is also difficult to monitor, espe- funding, the former is a broader political issue. This leads to
cially in quality terms, given the dispersed locations that they arguably the most fundamental point: extension reform in
visit. Only farmers can really say what quality of support they both Chile and Uganda has benefited from clear local “owner-
have received. ship” and political support (see Bebbington & Sotomayor,
However, public extension services are often centralized, 1998 for the Chile case 3). Where public sector “principals”
hierarchical, and unresponsive to the diverse needs of farmers. are incentivized to deliver on stated public policy objectives,
Contracting private extension service providers could increase interactions with private sector agents can be reviewed and re-
responsiveness, if there is a mechanism through which farmers fined over time to ensure that those objectives are met.
can express their preferences across competing providers. Finally, although it does not directly contract commercial
Given that willingness to pay for extension is likely to be private sector operators, the Maendeleo Agricultural Technol-
low, this could happen through distribution of vouchers or ogy Fund (MATF) is worthy of note. It aims to promote dis-
alternatively through farmers’ representation on the bodies semination of “proven” technologies to farming communities
that allocate contracts in a given area. in East Africa by facilitating multi-stakeholder partnerships
Chile and Uganda provide useful lessons on involving pri- for technology transfer and its main tool for identifying prom-
vate service providers in national extension systems. In Chile, ising technologies and partnerships is a system of competitive
a subsidized voucher system was introduced in 1978 in the grants (i.e., a challenge fund). MATF’s expectation is that pro-
hope of quickly transitioning to a commercial extension mod- vision of the new products or services becomes self-sustaining
el. As the value of the subsidy was progressively reduced, how- by the end of the grant period, which in practice has proven
ever, farmers proved reluctant to pay increasing fees, resulting extremely challenging (Poulton, Mangheni, Okwadi, & Kilewe,
in declines in service quality. In addition, monitoring was 2006). If smallholder farmers are to adopt new technologies,
inadequate and Bebbington and Sotomayor (1998) found evi- they require access to a range of support services, including
dence of collusion between farmers and providers to share credit, efficient supply of the technology itself, access to remu-
voucher values. From 1983, therefore, vouchers were aban- nerative output markets—and perhaps some ongoing techni-
doned. Instead, providers bid for service contracts in a given cal advice as well. Finessing demand and supply for these
geographic area, based on specified work plans. This model services within a 2–3 year project, such that by the end of
has remained, with farmer representatives playing an increas- the project volumes of business are attractive to commercial
ing role in contract allocation and monitoring, though their service providers, is a daunting task. Organizing provision of
control over these processes remains inadequate (Cox & credit has proven particularly problematic.
Ortega, 2004). Nevertheless, MATF can provide valuable lessons. The
In Uganda the extension service was reformed starting in “advisory panel”, which selected projects for approval,
2001 and renamed National Agricultural Advisory Service worked hard and in an objective manner. Being part of a
(NAADS). Under the new approach, farmer groups con- donor-funded, NGO-managed project perhaps helped to insu-
tracted service providers, including both commercial private late them from rent-seeking or other external interference. The
sector and NGOs, to provide advice through short-term panel played an active role in monitoring, including making a
contracts. Benin et al. (2007) found that the quantity and pre-contract visit to check out the capabilities of the partners
(perhaps) quality of advice services in Uganda were greater against the claims made in the bid. The time that they and
102 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

project staff spent in the field generated impressive organiza- recurring themes. The nature of rural services also poses chal-
tional learning, with regard to both the requirements for suc- lenges for contract design, as illustrated by the complexity of
cessful technology adoption and the capabilities necessary rural health care and the difficulties of specifying or monitor-
within a partnership for this to occur. However, MATF’s ing extension quality. The PPP approaches that we review in
pro-active management approach, when combined with the the remainder of the paper have been pioneered by interna-
small size of individual projects, came at a cost: total adminis- tional organizations, so the capacity and incentive issues are
trative “overheads” came to 40% of funds disbursed (Poulton, more readily dealt with, albeit at the same time raising ques-
Mangheni et al., 2006). tions of replicability. Meanwhile, challenges for contract de-
sign remain.
(b) Demand stimulation

Table 2 distinguishes ongoing service delivery contracts 7. PPPS FOR NEW PRODUCTS AND SERVICES
from public efforts to stimulate demand for private services
in the hope that a self-sustaining private market could develop Margins on new products and services for so-called “bottom
once clients become familiarized with the product or service in of the pyramid” consumers are typically low, so firms have to
question. Jones, Quigley, and Foster (2006) discuss an exam- achieve scale if their investment is to be worthwhile. This
ple of the latter—the Tanzania National Voucher System makes the investment very risky. PPPs, therefore, aim to share
(TNVS) that distributed vouchers to women in remote rural costs and/or risks at critical stages of the product development
areas to subsidize the purchase of insecticide-treated bednets process. Once the viability of the product or service is estab-
for malaria control. The vouchers could be exchanged at par- lished, however, the private sector partner is expected to make
ticipating local traders upon payment of a small transaction the necessary investment to scale up delivery.
fee. According to Jones et al. (2006), use of vouchers and nets
were both high. In addition, the extra demand created by (a) Investment funds
TNVS encouraged the expansion of distributor networks in
the study area, where sales of unsubsidized nets rose 30%. Classic challenge funds disburse grants on the basis of a
Are there agricultural services for which public and private periodic, competitive bidding process. Other funds are man-
sectors could share the costs and risks of stimulating demand aged with greater flexibility or discretion, even if the manager
for commercial service delivery? Returning to extension, Cox ultimately has to seek approval from an oversight board to
and Ortega (2004) report that, after 25 years of promoting pri- fund a particular proposal. Thus proposals might be funded
vate involvement in extension provision, the state in Chile still on a first-come-first-served basis, providing that certain basic
pays 80% of the cost of extension delivery. While vouchers criteria are fulfilled, or managers may pro-actively seek pro-
were abandoned in 1983 and full privatization has apparently posals from particular groups, seeing capacity building of po-
fallen off the policy agenda, it is perhaps surprising that a fully tential bidders as part of their role.
private “top end” service has not emerged for better-off pro- Advocates of the competitive bidding approach highlight
ducers. This suggests that, if other states embark on service several advantages. Only the best proposals received in any gi-
contracts for extension provision, they should do so in the ven period are backed—not all that cross a minimum thresh-
expectation that they will be funding these contracts for some old. Transparency of decision making is maximized as
time to come. proposals are explicitly assessed against each other. If African
Donors are also keen to ask similar questions of fertilizer states establish investment funds to support their local private
voucher (subsidy) schemes, such as that in operation in Mala- sectors, the governance advantage of a competitive (challenge)
wi since 2005/06. However, there are important differences be- fund should be a compelling argument. Finally, it is believed
tween bednets and fertilizer. Firstly, bednets were a genuinely that open competition allows the best ideas to reveal them-
new technology to many rural Tanzanian households, whereas selves. By contrast, a more pro-active approach by fund man-
Malawian farm households have long had (intermittent) ac- agers can look like an attempt to “pick winners”—something
cess to fertilizer. The issue for Malawian farm households is that can be done well, but which is difficult to achieve, with the
affordability, while some of the most important benefits from danger of large, wasted subsidies when done badly. On the
the subsidy scheme are indirect, that is, increased demand for other hand, competitive bidding processes can be time-con-
casual labor combined with lower food prices (Dorward & suming and may not fit the investment timetable of key private
Chirwa, 2011). Secondly, the challenges of operating at scale sector actors. If private sector capacity is limited, so too will be
make it difficult for the fertilizer subsidy program to facilitate the numbers bidding in open competition and hence the ben-
experimentation with fertilizer use, 4 such that farmers might efits of competitive bidding.
improve fertilizer use efficiency and thereby be willing to pay
more for fertilizer. Thirdly, fertilizer vouchers are a potent tool (i) Health investment funds
of political patronage, whereas distribution of vouchers for Moran, Ropars, Guzman, Diaz, and Garrison (2005) ex-
bednets is not so easily transformed into political gain, espe- plain how a series of investment funds has helped to transform
cially when linked to attendance at ante-natal clinics. Perhaps the landscape of research into so-called “neglected” diseases
partly for this reason, private stockists have been excluded (including HIV/AIDS, malaria and tuberculosis). 5 Where dis-
from distribution of subsidized fertilizer (though not seed). eases are prevalent in low income countries, the ability of most
Continuing political interference in the fertilizer market can potential consumers to pay for treatment is low, yet drug
be expected, thereby increasing the risks of private sector development costs are large, with large risks associated with
investment in fertilizer distribution. the development of any particular treatment. Hence, while
In Sections 5 and 6 we have reviewed experience with con- drug development was driven by the value of patent rights
tracting the private sector to construct infrastructure and to alone, diseases of the poor were neglected by major pharma-
deliver a range of services. The capacity of state agencies ceutical companies. In recent years increasing political and
and the incentives facing state agents to administer contracts civil society pressure has led to companies to seek new models
in a way that achieves stated public objectives have been of drug development that combine social responsibility and
PUBLIC–PRIVATE PARTNERSHIPS LEVERAGE PRIVATE INVESTMENTIN AGRICULTURAL VALUE CHAINS IN AFRICA 103

commercial viability. The willingness of PPP investment ute at least 50% of total project costs. Given the assumption
funds to share costs and risks at later (higher cost) stages of that private sector capacity, entrepreneurship and spirit of
the drug development process—for example, large-scale innovation that are relevant to the sector(s) concerned already
clinical trials—was critical for the emergence of what has exist, one can ask why challenge funds are needed to stimulate
been called a “no profit—no loss” model (Moran et al., private sector investment. Irwin and Porteous (2005) explain
2005, p. 12). their rationale in terms of the risk-return relationship of so-
The investment funds in question are pro-actively managed cially beneficial projects and hence the chances of these pro-
funds that also seek to network players working on particular jects being prioritized in the internal competition for
problems. Nwaka (2005) concludes that the Medicines for investment funding within firms that may otherwise target
Malaria Venture (MMV), established in 1999, “radically chan- higher income or less risky markets.
ged the antimalarial R&D landscape” (pS20). Given the large This, however, raises the so-called “additionality” question
sums of money involved in medical research projects, high (an adverse selection issue): is/was the public contribution
quality fund management, including the ability to manage from the challenge fund really necessary for the innovation
relationships, structure contracts, and negotiate IP agree- to proceed? Outsiders can glean at best partial information
ments, was critical. Some of the MMV-funded projects did about the internal processes of competition for investment
fail, but overall the portfolio performed well. Chataway and funds within firms, while project proposals have to argue that
Smith (2006) note the achievements of the International AIDS the public contribution is essential if they are to stand a chance
Vaccine Initiative (IAVI) but also note the importance of insti- of being funded.
tutional learning. In its early years IAVI was accused of being Moving away from the “classical” challenge fund model can
a rather arrogant organization, insensitive to local cultures help here. Initial concept notes typically provide little insight
and needs, but, according to both Chataway and Smith into the additionality question. However, many private sector
(2006) and Rosiello and Smith (2008), it has since invested players have limited experience in putting funding proposals
in more genuine partnerships in many of the countries in together, while fund managers have an interest in receiving
which it works. A similar learning process is documented for the best possible proposals, so there is then a case for personal
the African Comprehensive HIV/AIDS Partnership, involving interaction between bidders and managers. This can provide
Merck, Government of Botswana and Bill and Melinda Gates managers with useful insights into how the project is seen
Foundation (BMGF). Initial criticisms focused on Merck’s within the firm, which in turn they can feed into the decision
apparent desire to achieve quick public relations gains from making process if requested by the panel or board.
the venture, rather than to form genuine partnerships, but For external evaluators, however, the problem is still not
these tensions have now been at least partly addressed. The solved. Irwin and Porteous (2005) classify projects funded by
experience highlights the useful role that a “third party”, FDCF in terms of whether the fund was a “catalyst” for the
BMGF, could play in the process of building trust between project (i.e., essential to it going ahead), an “accelerator”
Merck and GoB (Clark & O’Brien, 2003; Ramiah & Reich, (i.e., it probably would eventually have gone ahead anyway,
2006). but later and/or more slowly) or where the public funding
Buse and Harmer (2007) take a critical look at 23 health probably made little difference to the process and speed of
PPPs, arguing that these funds have distorted national health innovation. The difficulty of assessing additionality is high-
priorities in countries in which they work, while imposing lighted by a mobile banking scheme in Kenya, which Irwin
uncoordinated reporting requirements on national partners and Porteous (2005, p. 24) place in the “would have gone
(as a result of their proliferation and silo-based approaches). ahead anyway” category, but Enterplan (2004, footnote 10),
Buse and Harmer (2007) also criticize the internal governance citing a CGAP report, hailed as a clear case of additionality.
of (many) health PPPs for over-representation of the private Experience with the DFID challenge funds highlights the
sector in decision making compared with its financial contri- following practical lessons if a fund is to leverage private sec-
bution, a lack of measurable objectives, and poor transpar- tor investment in a cost-effective manner:
ency. Nevertheless, they also recognize their “impressive The “challenge” and associated outcome indicators against
contributions to efforts to tackle neglected diseases” (p. 261). which projects will be assessed need to be clearly defined,
but should neither be so narrow and specific that innovative
(ii) DFID challenge funds new ideas are excluded, nor so broad that the projects col-
DFID has so far established at least eight challenge funds lectively fail to trigger any systemic change in their (sub-)
(some in collaboration with other donors), with most of these sector. 7
supporting some projects directly relevant to the agricultural There should be a clear understanding of why a challenge
sector. 6 Thus, for example, the Financial Deepening Chal- fund might leverage private investment that would other-
lenge Fund (FDCF) supported roll-out costs for the now-fa- wise not be forthcoming, given that successful investments
mous M-PESA mobile phone-based money transfer system are expected to achieve both sustainability and replicability
in Kenya; the Africa Enterprise Challenge Fund runs a win- within short periods of time.
dow to encourage businesses commercialize technologies If a fund is too large, large sums of public money may be
developed within public agricultural research systems, and squandered if the management is poor. If it is too small,
the Food Retail Industry Challenge Fund assists agribusiness the overhead rate (administrative costs as a share of fund
to link smallholders into agricultural export supply chains. As size) will be high, given the fixed costs associated with man-
is now widely recognized, there are significant fixed costs asso- agement both of individual projects and of a challenge fund
ciated with sourcing from smallholders—for example, group as a whole. 8 This overhead rate has to be set against the
mobilization and training—that can be sufficient to prevent social benefits derived from PPP implementation.
smallholder inclusion (Boselie, Henson, & Weatherspoon, Enterplan (2004) and Irwin and Porteous (2005), both high-
2003; Poulton et al., 2010; Raynolds, 2004), but which could light that, without active and ongoing efforts to market a
be partially met through such a fund. fund, it runs the danger of servicing a small number of pri-
All the DFID funds have sought (or seek) to attract “expe- vate actors, whose motives for engagement could readily
rienced” private sector investors who are required to contrib- slip from help for innovation to rent-seeking.
104 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

Active monitoring—and swift action on the information it (c) Loan guarantee funds
provides—are also important. Monitoring and evaluation
may not resolve the additionality problem, but are necessary Loan guarantee funds encourage commercial lending to
for demonstrating the eventual impact of a fund’s investment, players within agricultural value chains who otherwise suffer
can shed light on the types of projects and organizations from sub-optimal access to capital. Two scenarios may be
likely to make good use of funds and also help to minimize considered. In the simplest case, the risk of lending to the
shirking (a form of moral hazard) by successful bidders. new borrowers is perceived differently by the lender and the
Where a project is not performing, the grant should be can- third party willing to offer the guarantee. For example, the
celed quickly, so as to maintain incentives for future bidders new borrowers may be unknown to the lender, but known
and protect the overall performance of the fund portfolio. and trusted by the third party. The guarantee provides the len-
However, to do this, managers and their boards must be der with sufficient assurance to lend to the new groups for an
shielded from political pressures by the institutional arrange- exploratory period. If the borrowers repay all their loans, the
ments of the fund. Being donor-funded may be a considerable lender should then be willing to advance loans without guar-
benefit here. 9 antee, based on his/her own acquired knowledge of the bor-
rowers. The best case scenario is that new lender–borrower
(b) The CGIAR and PPPs relationships are established without any recourse to the loan
guarantee fund.
In the field of agricultural research there has been interest Where the third party has no direct knowledge of the poten-
in PPPs for at least a decade. Publicly funded national and tial new borrowers, the rationale may be as follows: The third
international agricultural research centers engage with party believes that increased lending is in the public interest,
private sector partners in a number of ways. Spielman, Hart- but recognizes that successful lending to the new groups will
wich, and von Grebmer (2007) review 75 PPPs (loosely de- require a period of learning about the new borrower popula-
fined) that involved centers within the CGIAR system. 10 tions. Given that perceived lending risks during the learning
They noted two distinct patterns of interaction, depending phase are sufficient to discourage “uninsured” experimenta-
on the nature of the private sector partners. Center relation- tion, the guarantee provides the lender with a degree of insur-
ships with local private sector enterprises were typically in- ance against expected losses during this phase. The best case
tended to encourage commercialization of technologies scenario is that, by the end of the guarantee period, the lender
developed within the centers by the private sector partners will develop suitable new loan products and modes of delivery
(e.g., local seed companies). By contrast, through relation- and will know enough about the new groups to be able to
ships with multi-national crop science firms, centers often identify creditworthy individuals. Nevertheless, some recourse
aimed to access proprietary technologies or other re- to the loan guarantee fund is expected.
sources—recognition of the huge investment made by such
firms in crop biotechnology and the resultant ownership of (i) Guarantees for supplier credit to agro-dealers
intellectual property rights (Pingali & Traxler, 2002). On This model was pioneered by CARE in Zimbabwe and
their part, crop science firms may be willing to grant access Kenya in the 1990s (Rusike & Gandanhamo, 1999) and has
to proprietary technology as part of their corporate social subsequently been promoted by projects funded by Rockefel-
responsibility, recognizing that markets in countries where ler Foundation and AGRA. In these projects, access to credit
CGIAR centers are based currently offer them few commer- is one component of a capacity building program for agro-
cial opportunities. dealers, alongside training in business management skills
Nevertheless, Spielman et al. (2007) conclude that “the po- and/or technical knowledge regarding agro-inputs. 11 Through
tential benefits of PPPs have yet to be fully realized in the the training programs the implementers get to know which
CGIAR” (p. 3), a view echoed by World Bank (2007). They agro-dealers are competent and diligent. They then offer guar-
observe that it has proven difficult to bridge the cultural gulf antees to input wholesalers to stimulate supplier’s credit for
between public and private sector organizations, and that these individuals.
negotiations over intellectual property rights are difficult World Bank (2006) reports briefly on experience in Mala-
(partly because public organizations have much less informa- wi. Over 300 trained agro-dealers were enabled to acquire
tion on the technologies available from private partners than stock on 30–60 day credit from input supply companies.
vice versa)—even though private companies conduct such The volumes of sold inputs rose impressively as a result. In
negotiations with each other all the time. Systematic compar- 3 years the default rate on this suppliers’ credit was below
ison of this experience with that of the health investment 1%. The authors understand that default rates have been sim-
funds discussed above could prove insightful. Here we note ilarly low within the parallel program in Kenya, where over
that there are few examples of what Spielman et al. (2007) 200 agro-dealers were trained in the west of the country by
call “frontier” agricultural research, that is, collaborative ef- 2007.
forts to develop new technologies, between public and private However, as noted earlier, the agro-dealer network in Mala-
sectors, unlike the efforts catalyzed by the health investment wi has also had to contend with the introduction of the major
funds. The lack of investment funds to catalyze this within fertilizer subsidy program. If they were allowed to distribute
the field of agricultural research may be a contributory fac- the subsidized fertilizer and reclaim the value of the vouchers
tor, but CGIAR centers do have their own funding streams from the state, the scheme would benefit private agro-dealers.
to draw upon. We hypothesize that another factor differenti- Instead, the Malawi government has channeled all sales of
ating the two sectors is the much stronger political and civil subsidized fertilizer through two parastatal organizations,
society pressure upon life science companies to demonstrate thereby crowding out the emerging agro-dealer network (Fu-
positive impact upon poor populations than exists for crop ture Agricultures Consortium, 2009). While access to capital
science firms, whose proprietary technologies are viewed by and training were undoubtedly constraints on agro-dealer
many civil society groups as undesirable for smallholder expansion, the nature of ongoing state intervention could be-
producers. come the more binding constraint.
PUBLIC–PRIVATE PARTNERSHIPS LEVERAGE PRIVATE INVESTMENTIN AGRICULTURAL VALUE CHAINS IN AFRICA 105

(ii) Guarantees to commercial banks to support agricultural of the guarantee fund could be more to support ongoing ser-
lending vice provision than to stimulate the development of new prod-
In 2005 Rockefeller Foundation provided a loan guarantee ucts or services. In principal–agent terms, the outcome may
fund of US$500,000 to Centenary Rural Development Bank advance the objectives of the agent, but the principal has
(CERUDEB) in Uganda, on the basis of which CERUDEB not incentivized the agent to act in accordance with long-term
lent US$1 million to farmers over the period 2005–08. The public policy objectives for the development of rural financial
agreement specified that the two parties would share the costs markets.
of any loan defaults equally. Over this period the drawdown Of course, African smallholders are not a homogeneous
on the guarantee fund to cover loan default was only group, so both analyses may have some validity for different
US$10,400—less than the guarantee fund accumulated in smallholder types. Moreover, the authors understand that
interest (AGRA, 2009). Subsequently, the agreement was deals may also include a concessional finance package—an
renegotiated for a further 2 years with the same US$0.5 mil- additional cost “dividend” that offers the same opportunities
lion guarantee expected to leverage US$4 million of lending and choices as the loan guarantee. As loan guarantee deals
during this extension period. 12 are still in their infancy, the discussion flags issues to be
The total number of farmers benefitting from the first phase tracked during monitoring of the guarantee agreements. Col-
of the arrangement (some of them through membership of lecting data on geographical spread of borrowers and on loan
farmer groups that received collective loans) was in excess of sizes is a useful first step. However, a further step should be to
2000. To ensure a “small farmer” focus Rockefeller stipulated require that monitoring data distinguish between existing bor-
that borrowers should not be cultivating more than 10 ha. The rowers from the bank in question, existing borrowers from
average loan size was in the range US$500–1000, so these were other financial institutions and genuinely new clients who have
certainly “better off” smallholders. It is assumed that most been able to access a loan for the first time as a result of the
were new borrowers, as most loans were directed to previously loan guarantee agreement.
under-served rural areas and CERUDEB had little history of
lending to smallholders prior to this.
Drawing on this experience, AGRA has negotiated further 8. DISCUSSION
loan guarantee deals, including a US$5 million guarantee to
Equity Bank in Kenya, a guarantee fund of US$10 million Can contractual arrangements between public and private
to Standard Bank expected to leverage US$100 million of sector actors effectively incentivize the latter to provide ser-
new lending to the agricultural sectors in four African coun- vices in ways that meet public policy objectives? The answer
tries 13 and a guarantee fund with National Microfinance Bank to this question is a cautious “yes”, but several important
in Tanzania, expected to leverage US$5 million in loans to caveats are in order.
agro-dealers (AGRA, 2009; AGRA & Millennium Challenge Firstly, as principal–agent theory tells us, detailed mecha-
Account Mozambique, 2009). These are innovative deals de- nism design is important. Table 3 considers three of the PPP
signed to tackle one of the major constraints facing farmers mechanisms reviewed in this paper, which between them illus-
and other players in agricultural value chains in Sub-Saharan trate all three main asymmetric information problems distin-
Africa. However, important questions remain regarding the guished by Hart and Holmstrom (1987).
detailed design of the agreements. Table 3 also indicates mechanisms that can be (and in some
AGRA (2009) emphasize that these deals reduce the interest cases have been) employed to tackle these asymmetric infor-
rates that farmers and other borrowers have to pay for credit. mation problems. However, designing effective mechanisms re-
AGRA’s view is that commercial bank lending to smallholder quires expertize. Similarly, we have argued in this paper that
producers in Africa is impeded by an unjustifiably pessimistic designing a contract to align the incentives of private sector
view of the risks involved. The guarantees reduce the risk in agents with stated public objectives in a cost-effective manner
two ways: by providing partial insurance against losses and requires familiarity with the basic business models of those
indirectly by strengthening the relevant value chains through private agents. What type and level of incentive is required
simultaneously financing players at multiple stages. From this to influence their behavior? As CGIAR experience with PPPs
perspective, the reduced interest rates secured are close to what illustrates, such information can be hard to obtain. However,
“true” market rates should be. Moreover, AGRA hopes that it may be particularly challenging for African state agencies
there will be dynamic benefits as the commercial banks realize that have traditionally been suspicious of the private sector.
the potential of the sector and begin to develop new products In the case of DFID challenge funds, this problem of unfa-
to respond to additional opportunities that they see. miliarity is typically overcome by contracting fund manage-
An alternative view is that, at existing interest rates, lenders ment to people with requisite private sector experience,
are unable to cover the high transaction costs and associated something that can also enhance the credibility of the fund
default risks of lending to poor, dispersed clients engaging in with the private sector agents that it is seeking to engage.
rainfed agricultural production in areas where roads are poor. However, international agencies are more likely than African
Loan guarantees reduce the cost of lending and this “divi- state agencies to be able to pay salaries sufficient to attract
dend” can then be used either to reduce the interest rate or people with the necessary experience. Furthermore, this cre-
to expand service provision to new client groups while retain- ates a “nested” principal–agent problem, where the contracted
ing interest rates at the pre-existing level. The danger with the “principal” enjoys an asymmetric information advantage over
former route is that few genuinely new or poor borrowers are the ultimate principal in regard to the private sector agent—an
reached. Existing clients receive loans on improved terms or advantage that an opportunistic manager could exploit, for
clients may be attracted from other banks without expanding example, through collusion with favored private sector part-
the size of the market (the public policy objective). Further- ners. The factor that minimizes this danger in the context of
more, if guarantees are used to reduce interest rates, rather a typical international agency is the overall framework of per-
than to support the development of new loan products or cost formance incentives. Thus, challenge fund managers are ex-
effective modes of delivery, most “gains” may be reversed once pected to present evidence of the effectiveness and impact of
the loan guarantee is removed. In terms of Table 2, the effect the investments their funds have made. By contrast, the overall
106 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

Table 3. PPP mechanisms as principal–agent models


Extension contracts Challenge fund Guarantee fund
Classification Moral hazard (Hidden action) Adverse selection Moral hazard (Hidden
information)
Desired outcome Technology adoption by farmers New products adopted by Greater access to services for
farmers poor/rural clients; no recourse to
guarantee fund
Agent’s action Delivery of extension advice New product roll-out Services provided to new clients
Major danger Shirking on extension quality Subsidy to poor project or Guarantee used to obtain
project not requiring public competitive advantage in serving
support existing market
Are there risk factors beyond the Yes—weather, farmer Yes—consumer acceptance: high On recourse to fund, yes—major
agent’s control that affect the preferences (poorly understood?), risk in rolling out new product, covariant risks affect both
relationship between the agent’s market prices, availability of especially with low margins, fertilizer sales and agricultural
action and the observed complementary services hence scale needed finance
outcome?
To what extent are agent’s Only farmers can observe Fund manager can track through Loan disbursements can be
actions or effort observable? extension quality; principal may regular reporting requirements tracked with strong M&E system
try to track quantity of visits and follow-up
Incentives to avoid moral hazard Contract renewal; involvement of Threat of grant cancellation Partial loss guarantee
farmers in selection
Mechanisms to avoid adverse Competitive bidding Competitive bidding, Due diligence on commercial
selection independent panel; work with partner; work with established
established players players
Note: in the final two rows we identify means of protecting against both moral hazard and adverse selection for all three cases. However, the classification
in the top row shows which of these problems is considered the dominant one in each case.

framework of performance incentives in many African state Haggblade (2006), lack of trust between public and private ac-
agencies is weak (van de Walle, 2001). On a practical note this tors is often mutual, suggesting a role for institutions that can
paper has highlighted the importance of thinking hard about bring different parties together.
monitoring requirements when designing contracts. This mon-
itoring is important for structuring incentives not just for the (a) Deliberative fora
private sector agents, but also for those responsible for con-
tracting them. Hall and Soskice (2001, p. 10–11) explain the importance of
Assuming there is strong commitment to achieve improve- institutions that facilitate “collaboration and strategic interac-
ments in service delivery—as with reforms to the national exten- tion” within OECD economies (and sectors) by assisting ex-
sion services in Chile and Uganda?—it seems inevitable from change of information, monitoring behavior, sanctioning
the foregoing discussions that there will also be a learning curve defection and facilitating “deliberation”. Deliberation, that
as successive contracts are drawn up. (This is one of the reasons is, the chance to get together and discuss, can build mutual
why more cases are required before firm conclusions can be understanding of the roles of different actors in tackling a par-
reached on the efficacy of PPP arrangements). The notion of a ticular problem or of the long-run development vision of a sec-
learning curve suggests that the “cost effectiveness” of PPP tor. The trust that comes from this mutual understanding
arrangements (from a public perspective) should also improve makes collaboration easier.
over time. However, this is an area on which very little informa- However, where coordinated actions by both state and pri-
tion is yet available. Exactly what cost effectiveness means will vate actors are required, Hall and Soskice (2001) caution that,
depend on the type of mechanism. In PPP contracts for infra- if the state is too strong, “firms are reluctant to share ... infor-
structure investment or service delivery a cost comparison mation with governments whose position as powerful actors
may be done with “conventional” options. There is an inconclu- under a range of unpredictable influences raises the risks that
sive literature on cost-effectiveness in the case of PPP contracts they will defect from any agreement and use the information
for infrastructure investment (Hodge & Greve, 2007). For chal- they have acquired against the firm” (p. 47). The “coordinated
lenge funds the “without fund” scenario is no new products; market economies” of northern Europe overcome this prob-
hence ultimately the cost–benefit analysis should consider the lem because powerful employer associations and trade unions
cost of the public investment (including fund administration) exert influence within political parties, so they can “sanction”
vs. the social and economic impacts of the new products and ser- governments that abuse their power.
vices. This is very difficult to do. Existing assessments focus en- Poulton, Kydd et al. (2006) highlight the need for comple-
tirely on the administrative costs of a challenge fund (as a share mentary investments (by both private and public actors) to
of funds invested) and how this compares with figures reported support service delivery to staple food producers in Africa,
for venture capital funds. The discussion in Irwin and Porteous as incentives rarely exist for a single private investor to provide
(2005) illustrates that even this is not a precise science! multiple services to smallholders through contract farming
Learning within the state sector is one reason why contracts arrangements. A similar argument may hold for investments
may be refined and terms improve over time. Another is that it at different stages of a nascent supply chain. Where the return
might take time for private agents to gain trust in public sector on investment by one player is dependent on the existence of a
partners. Where trust is low, the public partner is likely to complementary investment(s) by another player(s), the situa-
have to offer generous terms to achieve collaboration from tion is analogous to that of asset specific investment as ana-
private sector. As observed by Chitundu, Droppelmann, and lyzed by Williamson (1985), with the same basic problem of
PUBLIC–PRIVATE PARTNERSHIPS LEVERAGE PRIVATE INVESTMENTIN AGRICULTURAL VALUE CHAINS IN AFRICA 107

hold-up. Thus, mechanisms for coordinating investments are ble nature of state intervention—and fear of its implications
required if significant private investment is to be forthcoming. for future business development—is more of a binding con-
Spielman et al. (2007) note the efforts of some CGIAR cen- straint on private investment than failures in financial or other
ters to facilitate coordination across value chain actors for markets.
crops that they are working on. Chitundu et al. (2006) report
on the activities of a task-force to bring together stakeholders
within the cassava value chain in Zambia. They note that the 9. CONCLUSIONS
“level of public–private interaction [that the task force repre-
sented] does not come naturally in an economy such as The evidence base regarding the effectiveness of PPPs in
Zambia ... Mutual mistrust between the public and private leveraging private investment in poorly functioning agricul-
sector are [sic] common” (p. 19). The opportunity to bring tural value chains and the impact of such interventions on
“interested players together around a table in search of very smallholder producers is still limited. Many of the mechanisms
concrete solutions to identified opportunities” was positive. reviewed in this paper are “pioneering” examples: the number
However, we also note that there are few mechanisms by of cases to observe is still low. Moreover, many are still suffi-
which most private sector actors (and especially indigenous ciently recent that one cannot expect impact evaluations to
small or medium sized enterprises) can sanction the state if have been conducted. On the other hand, initial evidence on
it acts in a way that is damaging to their interests. Thus, delib- their effectiveness in leveraging private investment should be
erative fora alone may be insufficient to encourage greater pri- available, but can be hard to come by.
vate sector investment, especially in politically high profile Insofar as evidence does exist, some mechanisms do seem to
value chains where politicians and public agencies are more alleviate binding constraints to private investment. For exam-
inclined to intervene. ple, reviews of challenge funds have tended to conclude that
Deliberative multi-stakeholder processes, facilitated by they encourage (or hasten) investment with high social returns,
donor-funded projects, have led to the development of ware- although the additionality question remains unresolved. Loan
house receipt systems in several African countries. These are guarantees to agro-dealers have enabled them to expand the
designed to increase traders’ access to capital for commodity volume of their operations.
purchase and to promote private storage activity. The pres- However, it should be noted that these cases were pioneered
ence of inspection companies at coffee and cotton processing by international organizations. This paper has not reviewed
plants in Tanzania has increased banks’ confidence to lend any cases of successful deployment of PPPs for strengthening
to these processors. However, warehouse receipt systems have agricultural value chains by African state agencies. 14 By con-
had a less durable impact on maize trading, where lack of pri- trast, it has noted cases where the main constraint on greater
vate investment in storage has been one of the factors contrib- private investment in such chains was unpredictable public
uting to increased price volatility post-liberalization. Coulter policy. Even where market failures are present, current state
and Onumah (2002) observe that ad hoc government interven- capacity to design and administer effective PPPs may remain
tions in maize markets can depress prices, causing losses to a constraint to private investment. This paper has argued that
traders (and farmers) who have invested in storage. This the general framework of performance incentives within many
undermines the incentive to invest, even where inventory credit African state agencies is at the root of this capacity problem,
is available to assist this. Such difficulties have befallen the which does mean that political commitment can make a differ-
Zambian scheme that Coulter and Onumah (2002) describe ence. If so, there may be an advocacy role for AGRA, among
[Gideon Onumah, pers.comm.]. Following Hall and Soskice others, in persuading African states to experiment with PPP-
(2001), deliberation alone is insufficient to ensure sustained type arrangements for poorly functioning agricultural value
strategic interaction where private parties are powerless to chains. However, this advocacy role should be accompanied
influence (damaging) state actions. Following Jayne et al. by full disclosure of available information on “pioneering”
(2002), this is a case where the unpredictable and uncontrolla- examples for critical examination.

NOTES

1. As pointed out by one reviewer, the central challenge in hidden 3. In Uganda Joughin and Kjaer (2010) suggest that the nature of
information models is that the principal does not know the utility function NAADS may now be changing as increasing political competition causes a
of individual agents. The literature on mechanism design (see Mas-Colell, search for new sources of patronage.
Whinston, & Green, 1995, chapters 14 and 23) thus explores ways in which
principals can induce agents to truthfully reveal their preferences. Even 4. A limited range of fertilizers is offered and coupons are for 50 kg bags,
these, however, generally assume that the preferences of individual agents rather than small packs. The administrative effort of distributing subsi-
are drawn from a commonly known preference set. In the context of PPPs dized fertilizer reduces time that extension staff have to provide advice on
for agricultural value chains, this would still require that principals have a fertilizer use (Chinsinga & Cabral, 2010).
fair degree of understanding of private agents’ business models, strategies,
and objectives. 5. A more recent survey by Moran et al. (2009) found that in 2007
around US$ 2.5 billion was invested in R&D for new products for
2. Hodge and Greve (2007) argue that short-term service contracts neglected diseases, with 90% of this coming from public (including
should not be considered as PPPs. Rather, PPP contracts should be of philanthropic) sources. About a quarter of donor funding was routed to
sufficient duration to provide incentives for significant investment by the PPPs, such as the International AIDS Vaccine Initiative and the Medicines
private partner in improved service delivery. Whether or not all the for Malaria Venture.
contractual arrangements reviewed here meet this criterion, we argue that
common lessons emerge regarding state capacity and incentives for 6. Information on several of these funds can be accessed through
effective contracting. www.frich.co.uk/html/challengefunds.html. Other funds include the
108 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

Financial Deepening Challenge Fund (1999–2007) and the Business 12. Rockefeller Foundation conducted an evaluation of the initial 2005–
Linkages Challenge Fund (2000–08). 08 loan guarantee prior to negotiating the extension. However, the
resulting report remains an internal document [Brinda Ganguly,
7. Some form of systemic change is the “big win” that all challenge funds pers.comm. 15/07/2009].
would like to trigger [Mark Thomas, pers.comm.]
13. Unlike the CERUDEB agreement described above, this is a “first
8. Irwin and Porteous (2005) judged the overhead rate of around 20% for loss” agreement, whereby AGRA will cover all losses up to 20% of the
Financial Deepening Challenge Fund to be reasonable. This compares portfolio size in the first year, 15% in the second year and 10% in the third
with the 40% overhead rate for MATF, which funds much smaller projects year. This structure clearly assumes that Standard Bank will undergo a
as well as having to engage in more capacity building with (potential) learning process over the period of the guarantee.
bidders.
14. Booth and Golooba-Mutebi (2011) suggest that the Rwanda horti-
9. Khan (2000) argues that the ability of the South Korean state to culture sector may in due course provide positive examples. If so, this may
withdraw rents from companies that were not delivering on national be “the exception that proves the rule” for the arguments advanced in this
development priorities, so as to reallocate them to others, was central to its paper. Booth and Golooba-Mutebi (2011) note the unusually strong
success in stimulating economic growth. However, few other states have discipline and performance incentives within the post-2000 Rwandan
been able to do this so effectively. state. The model for PPPs in horticulture is likely to be the activities of
Tri-Star Investments S.A.R.L. (now registered as Crystal Ventures Ltd),
10. The Consultative Group on International Agricultural Research owned by the ruling Rwandan Patriotic Front party. Tri-Star, inter alia,
(CGIAR) comprises 15 international agricultural research centers located partnered the mobile company MTN, subsidizing its learning costs so as
in Africa, Asia and Latin America. to encourage it to establish operations in Rwanda. Linking to our
discussion in Section 8, Booth and Golooba-Mutebi (2011, p. 13) note that
Tri-Star “has a robustly internationalist approach to filling skill gaps in its
11. Adesina et al. (2011) report that around 10,000 agro-dealers across 13
firms, with business efficiency and the meeting of strategic social objectives
countries have now been trained, enhancing farmers’ access to inputs
taking precedence over commitments to local hiring and capacity
through reduced distances from farmer to stockist and expanded ranges of
development”.
products sold.

REFERENCES

Adesina, A., Langyintuo, A., Bugo, N., Makinde, K., Bigirwa, G. and Chinsinga, B. and Cabral, L. (2010) The limits of decentralised governance:
Wakiumu, J. (2011) Improving farmers’ access to agricultural inputs and the case of agriculture in Malawi. Policy Brief 033, Future Agricultures
finance: Approaches and lessons from Sub-Saharan Africa. Paper Consortium, Brighton.
presented at the IFAD Conference on “New Directions for Small- Chitundu, M., Droppelmann, K. and Haggblade, S. (2006) A value chain task
holder Agriculture”, January 24–25, 2011, Rome. force approach for managing public–private partnerships: Zambia’s task-
AGRA (2009). Financing growth for Africa’s smallholder farmers, Alliance force on acceleration of cassava utilization. Food Security Research
for a Green Revolution in Africa, Nairobi. Project Working Paper #21, Michigan State University, Lusaka, Zambia.
AGRA, Standard Bank and Millennium Challenge Account Mozam- Clark, P., & O’Brien, K. (2003). Fighting AIDS in Sub-Saharan Africa: Is
bique, (2009) Fact sheet: New loan programme for African agricultural a public–private partnership a viable paradigm?. Medical Science
development, Nairobi. Monitor, 9(9), ET28–ET39.
Anderson, J., & Feder, G. (2007). Agricultural extension. In R. Evenson, Commission for Africa (2005) Our common interest: Report of the
& P. Pingali (Eds.). Handbook of agricultural economics (Vol. 3, Commission for Africa, London.
pp. 2343–2378). Elsevier. Coulter, J., & Onumah, G. (2002). The role of warehouse receipt systems
Awortwi, N. (2004). Getting the fundamentals wrong: Woes of public– in enhanced commodity marketing and rural livelihoods in Africa.
private partnerships in solid waste collection in three Ghanaian cities. Food Policy, 27(4), 319–337.
Public Administration and Development, 24(3), 213–224. Cox, M. and Ortega, H. (2004) Chile: Origin and Evolution of a Privatized
Bahiigwa, G., Rigby, D., & Woodhouse, P. (2005). Right target, wrong Extension System. In: W. Rivera and G. Alex (Eds.). Extension reform
mechanism? Agricultural modernization and poverty reduction in for rural development Volume 2: Privatization of extension systems—
Uganda. World Development, 33(2), 481–496. Case studies of international initiatives. Washington DC, World Bank
Bebbington, A., & Sotomayor, O. (1998). Demand-led and poverty- ARD Discussion Paper No.9: 9–15.
oriented or just sub-contracted and efficient? Learning from (semi-) Dorward, A., & Chirwa, E. (2011). The Malawi agricultural input subsidy
privatised technology transfer programmes in Chile. Journal of programme: 2005–6 to 2008–9. International Journal of Agricultural
International Development, 10(1), 17–34. Sustainability, 9(1), 232–247.
Benin, S., Nkonya, E., Okecho, G., Pender, J., Nahdi, S., Mugarura, S., Enterplan (2004). Discussion document—FDCF: Assessing its achievements
Kato, E. and Kayobyo, G. (2007) Assessing the impact of the National and possible future directions. Report for DFID under contract CNTR
Agricultural Advisory Service (NAADS) in the Uganda rural liveli- 99 7888A.
hoods. IFPRI Discussion Paper 00724, International Food Policy Fafchamps, M. (2004). Market institutions in Sub-Saharan Africa: Theory
Research Institute, Washington DC. and evidence. Mass, MIT Press: Cambridge.
Booth, D. and Golooba-Mutebi, F. (2011) Developmental patrimonialism? Future Agricultures Consortium (2009). Fertiliser subsidies: Lessons from
The case of Rwanda. Africa Power and Politics Programme Working Malawi for Kenya. Future Agricultures Briefing Paper, Institute of
Paper 16, Overseas Development Institute, London. Development Studies, Brighton.
Boselie, D., Henson, S., & Weatherspoon, D. (2003). Supermarket Hall, P., & Soskice, D. (2001). An Introduction to Varieties of Capitalism.
procurement practices in developing countries: Redefining the roles In P. Hall, & D. Soskice (Eds.), Varieties of capitalism: The institutional
of the public and private sectors. American Journal of Agricultural foundations of comparative advantage (pp. 1–68). Oxford: Oxford
Economics, 85(5), 1155–1161. University Press.
Buse, K., & Harmer, A. (2007). Seven habits of highly effective global Hanson, J., & Just, R. (2001). The potential for transition to paid
public–private health partnerships: Practice and potential. Social extension: Some guiding economic principles. American Journal of
Science and Medicine, 64(2), 259–271. Agricultural Economics, 8(3), 777–784.
Chataway, J., & Smith, J. (2006). The International AIDS Vaccine Initia- Hart, O., & Holmstrom, B. (1987). The theory of contracts. In T. Bewley
tive (IAVI): Is it getting new science and technology to the world’s (Ed.), Advances in economic theory: Fifth World Congress (pp. 71–155).
neglected majority?. World Development, 34(1), 16–30. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
PUBLIC–PRIVATE PARTNERSHIPS LEVERAGE PRIVATE INVESTMENTIN AGRICULTURAL VALUE CHAINS IN AFRICA 109

Henson, S., & Reardon, T. (2005). Private agri-food standards: Implications Otsuki, T., Wilson, J., & Sewadeh, M. (2001). Saving two in a billion:
for food policy and the agri-food system. Food policy, 30(3), 241–253. Quantifying the trade effect of european food safety standards on
Hodge, G., & Greve, C. (2007). Public–private partnerships: An international African exports. Food Policy, 26, 495–514.
performance review. Public Administration Review, 67(3), 545–558. Palmer, N., & Mills, A. (2005). Contracts in the real world: Case studies
Hodge, G., & Greve, C. (2009). PPPs: The passage of time permits a sober from Southern Africa. Social Science and Medicine, 60(11), 2505–2514.
reflection. Economic Affairs, 29(1), 33–39. Pingali, P., & Traxler, G. (2002). Changing locus of agricultural research:
Hubbard, M. (2003). Developing agricultural trade: New roles for Will the poor benefit from biotechnology and privatization trends?.
government in poor countries. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan. Food Policy, 27(3), 223–238.
Irwin, D. and Porteous, D. (2005) Financial Deepening Challenge Fund Poulton, C., Dorward, A., & Kydd, J. (2010). The future of small farms:
Strategic Project Review. Report funded by DFID and BMGF, Irwin New directions for services, institutions, and intermediation. World
Grayson Associates, Northumberland. Development, 38(10), 1413–1428.
Israel, A. (1987). Institutional development: Incentives to performance. Poulton, C., Mangheni, M., Okwadi, J., Kilewe, A. (2006) External
Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press. evaluation report for the maendeleo agricultural technology fund. Report
Jayne, T., Govereh, J., Mwanaumo, A., Nyoro, J., & Chapoto, A. (2002). to FARM-Africa, Nairobi.
False promise or false premise? The Experience of food and input Poulton, C., Kydd, J., & Dorward, A. (2006). Overcoming market
market reform in Eastern and Southern Africa. World Development, constraints on pro-poor agricultural growth in Sub-Saharan Africa.
30(11), 1967–1985. Development Policy Review, 24(3), 243–277.
Jayne, T., Govereh, J., Wanzala, M., & Demeke, M. (2003). Fertilizer Ramiah, I., & Reich, M. (2006). Building effective public-private partner-
market development: A comparative analysis of Ethiopia, Kenya, and ships: Experiences and lessons from the African Comprehensive HIV/
Zambia. Food Policy, 28(4), 293–316. AIDS Partnerships (ACHAP). Social Science and Medicine, 63(2),
Jones, L., Quigley, J., & Foster, G. (2006). Vouchers revisited—Can small 397–408.
enterprises save government programmes?. Small Enterprise Develop- Raynolds, L. (2004). The globalization of organic agro-food networks.
ment, 17(4), 43–51. World Development, 32(5), 725–743.
Joughin, J., & Kjaer, A. (2010). The politics of agricultural policy reform: Rosiello, A., & Smith, J. (2008). A sociological economy of HIV/AIDS
The case of Uganda. Forum for Development Studies, 37(1), 61–78. vaccine partnerships: Case studies from Africa and India. International
Kayaga, S. (2008). Public–private delivery of urban water services in Review of Sociology, 18(2), 283–299.
Africa. Proceedings of Institution of Civil Engineers: Management, Rusike, J. and Gandanhamo, T. (1999) The impact of the CARE
Procurement and Law, 161(4), 147–155. Zimbabwe Agribusiness Entrepreneur Network and Training (AGENT)
Khan, M. (2000). Rent-seeking as process. In M. Khan, & K. Jomo (Eds.), programme: A survey of farm input dealers in Makoni North and South
Rents, rent-seeking and economic development: Theory and evidence in Districts. Report produced for DFID project R6720(H) “Linking Seed
Asia (pp. 70–144). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Producers and Consumers: Diagnosing Constraints to Institutional
Kherallah, M., Delgado, C., Gabre-Madhin, E., Minot, N., & Johnson, Performance”.
M. (2000). The Road Half Travelled: Agricultural Market Reform in Spielman, D., Hartwich, F. and von Grebmer, K. (2007) Sharing Science,
Sub-Saharan Africa, Food Policy Report. Washington DC: Interna- Building Bridges, and Enhancing Impact: Public–Private Partnerships in
tional Food Policy Research Institute. the CGIAR. Discussion Paper 00708, International Food Policy
Langyintuo, A., Mwangi, W., Diallo, A., MacRobert, J., Dixon, J., & Research Institute, ISNAR Division, Washington DC.
Bänziger, M. (2010). Challenges of the maize seed industry in eastern Tati, G. (2005). Public—Private partnership (PPP) and water-supply
and southern Africa: A compelling case for private–public intervention provision in urban Africa: The experience of Congo-Brazzaville.
to promote growth. Food Policy, 35(4), 323–331. Development in Practice, 15(3–4), 316–324.
Mas-Colell, A., Whinston, M., & Green, J. (1995). Microeconomic Theory. van de Walle, N. (2001). African Economies and the Politics of Permanent
New York: Oxford University Press. Crisis, 1979–1999. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Moran, M., Ropars, A., Guzman, J., Diaz, J. and Garrison, C. (2005). The Van Ham, H., & Koppenjan, J. (2001). Building public–private partner-
new landscape of neglected disease drug development, Pharmaceutical ships: Assessing and managing risks in port development. Public
R&D Policy Project: George Institute for International Health/ Management Review, 4(1), 593–616.
London School of Economics/Wellcome Trust, London. Warner, M., Kahan, D. and Lehel, S. (2008) Market-oriented agricultural
Moran, M., Guzman, J., Ropars, A.-L., McDonald, A., Jameson, N., infrastructure: Appraisal of public–private partnerships, FAO/ODI,
Omune, B., et al. (2009). Neglected disease research and development: Rome.
How much are we really spending?. PLoS Medicine, 6(2), e1000030. Williamson, O. E. (1985). The economic institutions of capitalism. New
doi:10.1371/journal.pmed.1000030. York: The Free Press.
Narrod, C., Roy, D., Okello, J., Avendano, B., Rich, K., & Thorat, A. World Bank (2007). World Development Report 2008: Agriculture for
(2009). Public–private partnerships and collective action in high value Development, Washington DC.
fruit and vegetable supply chains. Food Policy, 34(1), 8–15. World Bank (2006). Developing rural agricultural input supply systems for
Nwaka, S. (2005). Drug discovery and beyond: The role of public–private farmers in Africa. Case study prepared for Fertilizer Toolkit.
partnerships in improving access to new malaria medicines. Transac- World Bank (2009). Awakening Africa’s sleeping giant: Prospects for
tions of the Royal Society of Tropical Medicine and Hygiene, 99(Suppl. commercial agriculture in the Guinea Savannah Zone and beyond
1), S20–S29. directions in development. Washington DC: World Bank.

Das könnte Ihnen auch gefallen