Sie sind auf Seite 1von 17

Journal of Urban Economics 69 (2011) 165–181

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

Journal of Urban Economics


www.elsevier.com/locate/jue

Supersizing supercenters? The impact of Walmart Supercenters on body mass


index and obesity
Charles Courtemanche a,⇑, Art Carden b,1
a
Department of Economics, University of North Carolina at Greensboro, P.O. Box 26165, Greensboro, NC 27402, United States
b
Department of Economics and Business, Rhodes College, 2000 N. Parkway, Memphis, TN 38112, United States

a r t i c l e i n f o a b s t r a c t

Article history: Researchers have linked the rise in obesity to technological progress reducing the opportunity cost of
Received 11 January 2010 food consumption and increasing the opportunity cost of physical activity. We examine this hypothesis
Revised 11 September 2010 in the context of Walmart Supercenters, whose advancements in retail logistics have translated to sub-
Available online 20 October 2010
stantial reductions in the prices of food and other consumer goods. Using data from the Behavioral Risk
Factor Surveillance System matched with Walmart Supercenter entry dates and locations, we examine
JEL classification: the effects of Supercenters on body mass index (BMI) and obesity. We account for the endogeneity of
I10
Walmart Supercenter locations with an instrumental variables approach that exploits the unique geo-
R10
I1
graphical pattern of Supercenter expansion around Walmart’s headquarters in Bentonville, Arkansas.
R1 An additional Supercenter per 100,000 residents increases average BMI by 0.24 units and the obesity rate
by 2.3% points. These results imply that the proliferation of Walmart Supercenters explains 10.5% of the
Keywords: rise in obesity since the late 1980s, but the resulting increase in medical expenditures offsets only a small
Walmart portion of consumers’ savings from shopping at Supercenters.
Wal-Mart Ó 2010 Elsevier Inc. All rights reserved.
Supercenter
Obesity
Body weight
Body mass index

1. Introduction and background stroke (Strum, 2002). The consequences of obesity include an esti-
mated 112,000 deaths and $117 billion in medical expenditures
Rising obesity is both a public health and public finance con- per year, with about half of these expenditures paid for by Medicare
cern. Lower prices for food and higher opportunity costs of physical and Medicaid (Flegal et al., 2005; US Department of Health and
activity are plausible explanations for rising obesity, and the rise of Human Services, 2001; Finkelstein et al., 2003).
‘‘Big Box” chains is one of the most important retail trends of the Obesity is particularly amenable to economic analysis because it
post-World War II era. We present evidence that Walmart Super- is the direct result of individual choices in the face of changing
centers’ Every Day Low Prices help explain shoppers’ larger waist- incentives (Philipson and Posner, 2003). Weight gain is caused by
lines since they first appeared in the late 1980s, but that the cost of an imbalance between ‘‘calories in” and ‘‘calories out,” making it
the increase in obesity attributable to Supercenters is small rela- the function of economic variables such as the price of calories
tive to the savings from Walmart-induced lower prices. and the opportunity cost of exercise. The emerging consensus is that
Between 1960 and 2006, the percentage of the population con- technological progress has altered these variables in ways leading
sidered overweight rose from 43% to 67%, while the obesity rate to weight gain.3 For instance, Philipson and Posner (2003) and
grew from 13% to 34% (Flegal et al., 1998; National Center of Health Lakdawalla and Philipson (2002) suggest that rising obesity in the
Statistics, 2008).2 Obesity has been linked to higher prevalence of United States is the result of falling real food prices due to increased
diseases such as high blood pressure, diabetes, heart disease, and agricultural productivity and a movement from jobs requiring physi-
cal activity to more sedentary employment. Cutler et al. (2003) argue
that rising obesity can be attributed to technological innovations that
⇑ Corresponding author. Fax: +1 336 334 4089.
have reduced the time cost of food preparation. Chou et al. (2004)
E-mail addresses: cjcourte@uncg.edu (C. Courtemanche), cardena@rhodes.edu
link several factors reflective of technological progress – including
(A. Carden).
1
Fax: +1 901 843 3736.
2
Someone is considered ‘‘overweight” if her body mass index (BMI = weight in
3
kilograms divided by height in meters squared) is greater than or equal to 25 and The literature on the economic causes of obesity is too extensive to fully survey
obese if her BMI is greater than or equal to 30. here. See Rosin (2008) for a more comprehensive review.

0094-1190/$ - see front matter Ó 2010 Elsevier Inc. All rights reserved.
doi:10.1016/j.jue.2010.09.005
166 C. Courtemanche, A. Carden / Journal of Urban Economics 69 (2011) 165–181

the falling price of grocery food, the falling price of restaurant food, This paper contributes to the Walmart literature by introducing
and the rising number of restaurants – to the increasing obesity rate. another possible consequence of Walmart entry: Supercenters’ low
We contribute to the obesity literature by suggesting an addi- prices for food and products that contribute to a sedentary lifestyle
tional mechanism through which technological progress may have may have increased the incidence of obesity. We examine the im-
contributed to the rise in obesity. While the literature has empha- pact of Supercenters on body mass index (BMI) and obesity using
sized the role of advancements in food production technology in data on the county-level prevalence of these stores matched with
lowering food prices and increasing obesity, by studying Walmart individual survey responses from the Behavioral Risk Factor Sur-
Supercenters we examine the role of advancements in distribution veillance System (BRFSS). We address the endogeneity of Super-
technology that lower the prices of food and other consumer center entry with an instrumental variables approach that
goods. The Walmart revolution is fundamentally a revolution in re- exploits the geographic pattern of Supercenter expansion around
tail logistics; as Karjanen (2006, p. 152) characterizes it, ‘‘Walmart Walmart’s headquarters in Bentonville, Arkansas in the 1990s
does not manufacture or source locally, but merely acts as a global and 2000s. We also perform a number of robustness checks that
commodity supply chain, distributing globally sourced goods to account for potential confounders such as Sam’s Clubs, Walmart
local markets.” The company’s major innovations have been in its discount stores, and differential trends in weight on the basis of
distribution channels, with store locations, warehouse locations, population, economic development, and geographic location.
and logistics practices planned in such a way as to minimize The evidence suggests that the entry of an additional Supercen-
wasted motion. These innovations translate to lower prices – ter per 100,000 residents increases average BMI by 0.24 units and
prices so much lower that Hausman and Leibtag (2007, 2009) individuals’ probability of being obese by 2.3% points, or 10.8% of
suggest the Consumer Price Index is mis-measured because of the sample obesity rate. The effects are strongest for women,
not sufficiently accounting for Walmart. low-income married individuals, and those living in the least pop-
Since 1962, Walmart has grown from a single store in Rogers, ulated counties. These estimates imply that the proliferation of
Arkansas into the world’s largest retailer. The discount store, Walmart Supercenters explains 10.5% of the rise in obesity since
Walmart’s original business model, focuses primarily on nonfood the late 1980s. Importantly, though, the resulting increase in med-
goods like clothing and electronics. The Supercenter, which debu- ical expenditures offsets only 5.6% of consumers’ savings from
ted in 1988 in Washington, Missouri, adds a full-service grocery shopping at Walmart. The obesity effect alone is therefore not suf-
store to create ‘‘one-stop shopping.”4 The number of Supercenters ficient to conclude that Walmart entry is bad for communities as
has risen rapidly since the early 1990s, coinciding with an increase our estimates suggest that the costs of additional obesity are out-
in the growth rate of obesity that is particularly evident in the weighed by the benefits of lower prices.
1990s (Fig. 1). As of 2009, Walmart operated 833 discount stores,
2705 Supercenters, 605 members-only Sam’s Club warehouses, and 2. Theory
151 smaller grocery stores called ‘‘Neighborhood Markets” in the
US Together these stores accounted for over $400 billion in annual The most obvious reason for suspecting a causal relationship
sales.5 Thanks to the Supercenter, Walmart has become a leader in between Walmart Supercenters and obesity is simple: Supercen-
the grocery business. Walmart’s grocery market share averaged ters lead to cheap food (Hausman and Leibtag, 2009; Basker and
14.9% in 2004 across 68 metropolitan areas, and its grocery volume Noel, 2009) and cheap food leads to weight gain (Philipson and
was over twice the sales volume of the largest supermarket chain Posner, 2003; Lakdawalla and Philipson, 2002; Chou et al., 2004).
Kroger (Lord, 2006, pp. 55–62). However, Supercenters also lower the prices of a wide range of
Walmart has attracted attention in the scholarly literature and in nonfood items, including inputs to both sedentary lifestyles (i.e.
the popular press.6 The most obvious manifestation of what Fishman televisions, computers, DVDs, and video games) and active life-
(2006) calls The Wal-Mart Effect is the company’s traditional policy of styles (i.e. fitness equipment and sporting goods). In this section
‘‘Every Day Low Prices.” Numerous studies have documented Walm- we show that the overall net effect of Supercenters on weight de-
art’s negative impact on prices (Hausman and Leibtag, 2007, 2009; pends on a complex combination of income and substitution ef-
Basker, 2005b; Basker and Noel, 2009). Hausman and Leibtag (2009) fects, and that the theoretical effect is ambiguous.
cite data from studies showing that, even after accounting for discount
Consider a representative agent who has budgets for both food
cards and sales, Walmart maintains a price advantage of 8–27% on var-
and nonfood goods. She divides her food budget between healthy
ious food items. Basker and Noel (2009) estimate that grocery stores
grocery food such as fresh fruits and vegetables (H), unhealthy gro-
reduce their prices by 1–1.2% after the entry of a Walmart Supercenter
cery food such as processed snacks (U), and restaurant food (R). The
but that Supercenters still hold a price advantage of 10%. Other re-
prices of the three food types are PH, PU, and PR. She divides her non-
search has studied the labor market consequences of Walmart entry,
food budget between inputs to sedentary activities (S) and inputs to
with Basker (2005a) and Hicks (2007) finding positive effects on
active activities (A), which have prices PS and PA. For simplicity as-
employment and/or wages but Neumark et al. (2008) and Dube et al.
(2007) finding negative effects.7 Recent work has also examined sume that she responds to price changes by substituting within but
Walmart’s impact on a diverse set of other outcomes, ranging from not between the food and nonfood categories. In other words, her
economic indicators such as the poverty rate (Goetz and Swaminathan, food and nonfood budgets are both exogenous and fixed. Body mass
2006) and small business activity (Sobel and Dean, 2008) to cultural index (B) is increasing in calorie intake (C) and decreasing in calorie
indicators such as social capital (Goetz and Rupasingha, 2006; Carden expenditure (E). Calorie intake is increasing in each of the three food
et al., 2009a), leisure activities (Carden and Courtemanche, 2009), and types, but assume that unhealthy food and restaurant food increase C
traditional values (Carden et al., 2009b). more strongly than healthy food because of their greater caloric
density.8 E is increasing in A and decreasing in S. Formally,
4
The dates and locations in the preceding sentences were obtained from http://
walmartstores.com/AboutUs/7603.aspx.
5 8
This information was obtained from http://walmartstores.com/AboutUs/ Whether eating at restaurants leads to obesity is the subject of debate. Studies
7606.aspx, http://walmartstores.com/AboutUs/7605.aspx, and http://walmart- show that a higher frequency of eating fast food is associated with increased intake of
stores.com/sites/AnnualReport/2009/financial_highlights.html. calories, fat, and saturated fat consumed (i.e. Satia et al., 2004). Accordingly, Chou
6
More extensive reviews of the literature on Walmart can be found in Basker et al. (2004) and Rashad et al. (2006) find evidence that a drop in prices at either fast-
(2005b), Basker (2007), Hicks (2007), and Carden et al. (2009a). food or full-service restaurants increases obesity. Chou et al. (2004), Dunn (2008), and
7
These different conclusions hinge on a methodological debate that we detail in Currie et al. (2010) estimate a positive effect of restaurant prevalence on obesity, but
Section 3. Anderson and Matsa (2007) find no evidence of an effect.
C. Courtemanche, A. Carden / Journal of Urban Economics 69 (2011) 165–181 167

Fig. 1. Changes over Time in Number of Walmart Supercenters and the Obesity Rate. Notes: Obesity ratesare from Flegal et al. (1998), Ogden et al. (2006), and National Center
of Health Statistics (2008). Total numbers of stores in the United States are computed using our data.

B ¼ BðC; EÞ ð1Þ being that additional income allows individuals to switch from
C ¼ CðH; U; RÞ ð2Þ cheap processed food to more expensive but healthier fresh food
(Basiotis and Lino, 2002; Ranney and McNamara, 2002; Drewnow-
E ¼ EðA; SÞ ð3Þ
ski and Specter, 2004). As shown in Table 1, the overall effects of
H ¼ HðPH ; PU ; PR Þ ð4Þ PH, PU, and PR on H, U, and R are
U ¼ UðPH ; PU ; PR Þ ð5Þ
R ¼ RðPH ; PU ; PR Þ ð6Þ dH dU dR dH dU
< 0; ?0; ?0; ?0; ?0;
A ¼ AðPA ; PS Þ ð7Þ dP H dPH dPH dPU dP U
dR dH dU dR
S ¼ SðPA ; PS Þ ð8Þ ?0; ?0; ?0; < 0: ð10Þ
dPU dPR dP R dPR
where
Assume the two types of nonfood goods A and S are substitutes
and are both normal. When PA (PS) increases, A (S) decreases
dB dB dC dC dC
> 0; < 0; > 0; > 0; > 0; through both the substitution and income effects, while S (A) in-
dC dE dU dH dR
creases through the substitution effect and decreases through the
dC dE dE
> 0; > 0; < 0: ð9Þ income effect. Therefore,
dH dA dS
Assume the three types of foods are substitutes, H and R are dA dS dA dS
< 0; ?0; ?0; < 0: ð11Þ
normal goods, and U could be either normal or inferior. We allow dPA dP A dPS dPS
for the possibility that junk food is an inferior good because re-
search documents a negative relationship between income and Walmart Supercenters (W) lower the prices of healthy and un-
weight throughout most of the US income distribution (i.e. Lakda- healthy food– but presumably not restaurant food – and both kinds
walla and Philipson, 2002; Chou et al., 2004), with one explanation of nonfood goods.9 Therefore,

dPH dPU dPR dPS


< 0; < 0; ¼ 0; < 0: ð12Þ
Table 1 dW dW dW dW
Theoretical effects of healthy, unhealthy, and restaurant food prices on healthy,
unhealthy, and restaurant food consumption. BMI can be expressed as
Price change Food type Substitution effect Income effect Total effect  
C½HðPH ðWÞ; P U ðWÞ; PR Þ; UðP H ðWÞ; PU ðWÞ; P R Þ; RðP H ðWÞ; PU ðWÞ; P R Þ
PH " H ; ; ; B¼B
E½AðP A ðWÞ; PS ðWÞÞ; SðP A ðWÞ; P S ðWÞÞ
PH " U " ? ?
PH " R " ; ? ð13Þ
PU " H " ; ?
PU " U ; ? ? and the overall effect of Supercenters on BMI is
PU " R " ; ?
PR " H " ; ? 9
PR " U " ? ? Some Supercenters do contain restaurants like McDonald’s and Subway, but it
PR " R ; ; ; seems hard to imagine that this would meaningfully impact the market price of
restaurant food. We revisit this issue in Section 3.7.
168 C. Courtemanche, A. Carden / Journal of Urban Economics 69 (2011) 165–181

 
dB @B @C @H @PH @H @PU @B regressions. We use Walmart Supercenter and discount store entry
¼ þ þ
dW @C @H @PH @W @PU @W @C dates and locations generously made available online by Thomas J.
  Holmes.13 Sam’s Club locations through May of 2003 were collected
@C @U @P H @U @PU @B
 þ þ by Austan Goolsbee and Chad Syverson and were generously pro-
@U @PH @W @PU @W @C
  vided by Chad Syverson. We updated the Sam’s Club data using
@C @R @PH @R @PU @B
 þ þ information on store opening dates since 2003 provided by Walmart
@R @PH @W @P U @W @E Stores, Inc. In our main regressions we adjust for market size by cal-
 
@E @A @PA @A @PS @B culating the number of stores per 100,000 residents in the county,
 þ þ
@A @PA @W @PS @W @E using population data from the US Census Bureau. Scaling by popu-
  lation is common in the Walmart literature since presumably the ef-
@E @S @PA @S @PS
 þ ð14Þ fect of an additional Walmart store should be stronger in smaller
@S @PA @W @PS @W
counties with fewer shopping alternatives than larger counties.14
Since the magnitudes of the partial effects are ambiguous, the over- To construct the set of instruments discussed in Section 3.2, we
all effect is ambiguous and depends on the agent’s sensitivity to the utilize distance from the center of each county to the location of
prices of the different types of goods, Walmart’s effect on relative Walmart’s headquarters in Bentonville, Arkansas, computed using
prices, and the strength and direction of the income effects. A rela- the great circle distance formula. As a robustness check, we also
tive price effect of particular interest is that of healthy versus un- use distance from Walmart’s nearest food distribution center. Food
healthy foods. On one hand, Walmart’s efficiency along the supply distribution center locations and entry dates were obtained from
chain is especially important for rapidly-depreciating perishable Holmes’ website.
items like fresh fruits and vegetables. Also, Walmart’s advances in Our individual-level data come from the 1996 to 2005 waves of
transportation logistics and forecasting may have made it profitable the restricted version of the Behavioral Risk Factor Surveillance
for retailers to stock a wider range of fresh fruits and vegetables System (BRFSS), a telephone survey of health conditions and risky
than was previously available locally, and the relative prices of health behaviors conducted by state health departments and the
goods that were previously unavailable necessarily fall. On the Center for Disease Control. The BRFSS consists of repeated annual
other hand, a business model built around a global distribution net- cross sections of randomly-selected individuals starting in 1984.
work and extended warehouse storage may be more amenable to In 1984, only 15 states participated, but this number grew rapidly
processed foods than fresh produce.10 and all states were participating by 1996. The number of respon-
Though food and consumer good prices are the most obvious dents also grew rapidly, from 12,258 in 1984 to 355,710 in 2006.
mechanisms through which Supercenters could affect weight, We utilize the restricted version of the BRFSS, which at the time
there are other less obvious possible mechanisms that reinforce of this paper included only the years 1994–2005, because this ver-
the theoretical ambiguity. For instance, cheap cigarettes and alco- sion includes the county identifiers for all individuals.15 We use
hol from Walmart could theoretically affect weight, as nicotine only the years starting in 1996 because, as noted by Neumark
stimulates the metabolism and curbs appetite while alcohol con- et al. (2008), distance from Bentonville predicted discount store
tains empty calories.11 Additionally, evidence suggests that big entry until 1995, after which point Walmart spanned the entire
box retailers such as Walmart displace local mom-and-pop stores country and ‘‘there was only filling in of stores in areas that already
(Haltiwanger and Jarmin, 2010). Walmart may therefore reduce cal- had them” (p. 412). By focusing only on years after 1995, we help
orie expenditure by changing the nature of shopping from a walk be- to ensure that our distance-based instruments predict only Super-
tween corner stores to a one-stop drive to the suburbs.12 Given the center entry and not discount store entry as well.
theoretical complexities involved with analyzing Walmart’s effect on We utilize the following BRFSS variables. The BRFSS includes
body weight, we next turn to empirical analysis. self-reported height and weight, which allows us to construct our
dependent variables: BMI and an indicator variable for whether or
3. Empirical analysis not the respondent is obese (BMI P 30).16 We also construct a set
of individual-level controls containing the following variables. The
3.1. Data data include household income categories; we calculate continu-
ous measures of real incomes (in 2005 dollars) by assigning indi-
While we focus on the effect of Walmart Supercenters, we also viduals incomes equal to the midpoint of their category and then
utilize data on Walmart discount stores and Sam’s Clubs in some adjusting for inflation using the consumer price index for all urban
consumers from the Bureau of Labor Statistics. We convert infor-
10
mation on educational attainment to a set of dummy variables
The empirical literature does not reveal a clear relationship between the health
quality of foods and the extent to which Walmart affects their prices. Hausman and
Leibtag (2009) find that the effects of ‘‘SMCs” (supercenters, mass merchandisers, and
13
club stores) on the prices of apples, apple juice, and bananas are smaller than the http://www.econ.umn.edu/~holmes/data/WalMart/index.html. The data were
effects on cookies, eggs, ham, and ice cream, but some of the largest effects they used in Holmes (2008).
14
estimate are on the prices of lettuce and tomatoes. Basker and Noel (2009) estimate For examples, see Basker (2005a), Goetz and Rupasingha (2006), Goetz and
Walmart’s effect on a number of food prices. The largest price effect is for margarine, Swaminathan (2006), Sobel and Dean (2008), and Carden et al. (2009a), Carden et al.
but the second-largest is for lettuce and the smallest price decreases are for soda, (2009b).
15
shortening, ground beef, sugar, and eggs. The effects on the prices of milk and We thank the Center for Disease Control for making the restricted data available.
parmesan cheese are actually positive. The publically available data contains some county identifiers in all years after 1988,
11
The causal effect of cigarette prices on body weight is the subject of debate in the but they are hidden for many states.
16
literature; see Chou et al. (2004), Gruber and Frakes (2006), Chou et al. (2006), Baum Self-reported weight and height may be problematic since people tend to
(2008), Nonnemaker et al. (2008), and Courtemanche (2009). underreport their weight and, to a lesser extent, exaggerate their height. Some
12
Recent studies have attempted to link obesity to sprawl, as the spreading out of a economists have employed a correction for self-reported BMI developed by Cawley
city to suburban areas reduces the viability of walking, bicycling, and mass transit as (1999). This correction the National Health and Nutrition Examination Survey, which
transportation options. Ewing et al. (2003, Giles-Corti and Donovan, 2003, and Frank includes both actual and self-reported weight and height, to estimate actual BMI as a
et al. (2004) show that increases in automobile-oriented infrastructure are associated function of self-reported BMI and a variety of demographic characteristics. Research-
with higher obesity, while Eid et al. (2008) and Plantinga and Bernell (2007) find that ers have generally found that the correlation between actual and self-reported BMI is
at least some of this association can be attributed to reverse causality. Zhao and very high, and that correcting for measurement error does not substantially alter the
Kaestner (2010) find that sprawl leads to obesity using an instrumental variable coefficient estimates in regressions (Cawley, 1999 and Lakdawalla and Philipson,
analysis. 2002). We therefore elect not to employ the correction in this paper.
C. Courtemanche, A. Carden / Journal of Urban Economics 69 (2011) 165–181 169

Table 2
Summary statistics.

Variable name Description Mean (std. dev.)


BRFSS variables
BMI Respondent’s body mass index 26.612 (5.358)
Obese 1 if BMI P 30 and 0 otherwise 0.212 (0.409)
Height Height in inches 67.217 (4.095)
Married 1 if married 0.600 (0.490)
Some high school 1 if attended some high school but did not graduate 0.075 (0.264)
High school 1 if graduated high school but obtained no further education 0.308 (0.462)
Some college 1 if attended some college but did not graduate 0.277 (0.448)
College 1 if graduated from college 0.301 (0.459)
Female 1 if female 0.496 (0.500)
Race: black 1 if race is black 0.096 (0.295)
Race: other 1 if race is neither white nor black 0.161 (0.367)
Real income Household income in 2005 dollars 52,236 (27918)
Age Age in years 44.774 (16.888)
Matched county-level variables
Supercenters Walmart Supercenters per 100,000 residents 0.333 (0.793)
Distance Distance from Bentonville, AR 852.242 (392.532)
Distance from FDC Distance from nearest Walmart food distribution center 337.962 (353.921)
Discount stores Walmart discount stores ever entered per 100,000 0.918 (1.146)
Sam’s Clubs Sams Clubsper 100,000 0.190 (0.268)
Population Population in units of 100,000 9.376 (18.763)
Density Population density (100,000s of people per 100 square miles) 1.691 (5.219)
Unemployment Unemployment rate 5.126 (2.011)
Grocery Grocery stores per 100,000 residents 55.689 (27.139)
General General merchandise stores (besides Supercenters) per 100,000 14.601 (9.081)
McDonald’s McDonald’s restaurants per 100,000 residents 46.293 (15.670)

Note: Observations are weighted using the BRFSS sampling weights.

for some high school, high school graduate, some college, and col- 3.2. Identification strategy
lege graduate. Wealso include age and binary variables for whether
or not the individual is married, female, black, and a race other A widely acknowledged problem with identifying the causal ef-
than black or white. fects of Walmart is endogeneity bias from the non-random nature
We match these individual-level data to the number of Super- of Walmart’s locations. Neumark et al. (2008) offer a detailed dis-
centers, discount stores, and Sam’s Clubs in the county at the end cussion of Walmart’s expansion strategy using quotes from Sam’s
of the year preceding the respondent’s interview.17 This allows Walton’s autobiography and maps of store locations and openings
some time for changes in store presence to affect eating habits, over time. To summarize, Walmart slowly expanded outward from
and for changes in eating habits to affect weight. In unreported Benton County, Arkansas, saturating a market before moving onto
regressions, we also estimated models using average store pres- a new market further away. This process continued from 1962 to
ence over the 12 months preceding the respondent’s interview, 1995, at which point Walmart stores had reached all corners of
and the results were similar. the US Walmart’s store location decisions until 1995 can therefore
We also adda number of other county-level characteristics as loosely be summarized as the result of a two-step process. First,
controls in some of the robustness checks. First, we include county the company decided on the distance ring (i.e. less than 100 miles
unemployment rates from the Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS). from Bentonville, 500–600 miles from Bentonville, etc.) at which to
Additionally, we use number of general merchandise stores, gro- focus its attention in a given year. Then, within that distance ring it
cery stores, and restaurants from the Economic Census. These vari- chose locations that maximized the expected sum of future profits.
ables are only available every 5 years; we use the 1992, 1997, and This process creates the potential for endogeneity bias in studies
2002 censuses and impute the other years using linear interpola- examining Walmart’s effects. In particular, the areas with the high-
tions and extrapolations.18 Since general merchandise stores in- est expected future profits – presumably those where economic
clude Walmart Supercenters, we subtract them out to obtain the development is projected to occur the fastest, those which offer
number of other general merchandise stores in the county. We the most generous tax advantages, and those which are the most
again calculate the number of stores per 100,000 residents. Finally, receptive to Walmart entry – are likely trending differently than
we utilize number of McDonald’s restaurants in the county per other areas along numerous unobservable dimensions.
100,000 residents, graciously made available by Richard Dunn Different methods of addressing this endogeneity concern have
and used in Dunn (2008). This variable is only available in 2005, been used in the literature, but an increasingly popular approach is
so for regressions with McDonald’s locations we use only that year. to instrument for Walmart presence with interactions of year fixed
Our matched sample consists of 1,644,094 observations from effects and variables representing distance from Walmart’s head-
1996 to 2005. We report variable names, sources, descriptions, quarters in Benton County. Recent papers by three different groups
and summary statistics in Table 2. The sample obesity rate is of authors have utilized variations of this approach to identify
21%. The average respondent has a BMI of 26.6 and lives in a Walmart’s impacts: Neumark et al. (2008) found a negative effect
county with 0.33 Supercenters per 100,000 residents. on retail employment, Dube et al. (2007) found negative effects
on retail earnings and health benefits, and Carden et al. (2009a)
found no effect on social capital. Identifying Walmart’s effect using
17
For instance, if a respondent is interviewed in 2000, we match her individual the interaction of time and distance from Benton County is appeal-
information to the number of stores in her county at the end of December, 1999.
18 ing for several reasons. First, it is a natural approach given
The 2007 Economic Census was not publically available at the time of this paper,
so we use only 1992, 1997, and 2002. In 1992, both variables are available in the Walmart’s aforementioned expansion path, meaning that the
Economic Census’ Census of Retail Trade. In 1997 and 2002, they are in Retail Trade. instruments are sufficiently powerful predictors of Walmart
170 C. Courtemanche, A. Carden / Journal of Urban Economics 69 (2011) 165–181

Fig. 2. Walmart Supercenters, 1990.

presence. Second, distance from Bentonville is plausibly exogenous where WTict is a measure of weight – either BMI or an indicator for
since it was determined long before Walmart’s founding. Addition- obesity status – for individual i living in county c in year t.19 Scy is
ally, by identifying off the interaction of time and distance as op- the number of Supercenters per 100,000 residents in the county. Xjict,
posed to simply distance, these papers retain the ability to where j = 1, . . . , J, represents the individual-level control variables
account for time-invariant confounders using fixed effects or discussed in Section 3.1. The next two summation terms reflect year
differences. and county fixed effects. The last summation term represents inter-
This approach, however, is not without controversy. Replying to actions of county population density (PDct) with the year fixed ef-
an early version of Neumark et al. (2008), Basker (2006) argues that fects. We add these interactions to address Basker’s (2006) concern
the distance  year interactions are correlated with unobserved about differential trends on the basis of population.20 Approximately
determinants of employment, making them invalid instruments. two-thirds of entering Supercenters during the sample period were
Specifically, she claims that large population centers – which may conversions from discount stores, while the other third were entirely
experience different labor market shocks than other areas – are new stores. The parameter of interest – b1 – should therefore be
located disproportionately near the coasts, making them relatively interpreted as the weighted average effect of new and converted
far from Bentonville. She shows that Neumark et al.’s approach pre- Supercenters. We compute heteroskedasticity-robust standard er-
dicts an implausibly large effect of Walmart entry on local manu- rors clustered by county.21
facturing employment. Neumark et al. claim, though, that even if The identifying assumption for b1 is that Supercenter presence
a distance-based identification strategy is inappropriate to examine is uncorrelated with the error term. Formally,
the impacts of Walmart on employment in geographically-concen-
trated industries such as manufacturing, this does not necessarily Cov ðeict ; Sct Þ ¼ 0: ð16Þ
mean it is inappropriate to examine impacts on employment in less
There is little reason to suspect unobserved individual characteris-
geographically-concentrated industries such as retail. They also
tics to be correlated with county-level Supercenter presence condi-
show that the implausible effect on manufacturing employment
tional on unobserved county characteristics. Therefore, the
disappears when linear distance ring-specific trends are added to
identifying assumption is effectively that changes over time in
the model. To summarize, the literature suggests that identifying
Supercenter presence are uncorrelated with changes over time in
Walmart’s impacts using the interactions of time and distance from
unobservable county characteristics that impact body weight. If
Walmart’s headquarters is an intuitively appealing strategy that is
Supercenter locations are the result of a two-part process in which
likely appropriate in some contexts but not in others.
Walmart selects first a distance ring and then a county within the
Our paper uses a variation of the distance  time interactions
distance ring, there are two reasons for concern with this assump-
identification strategy to estimate the effect of Walmart Supercen-
tion. Most obviously, the choice of store locations within a distance
ters – as opposed to Walmart stores in general – on body weight.
ring is endogenous. If Walmart chooses counties trending upward
Our strategy is based on the observation that the proliferation of
in income and economic activity, b ^1 could be biased downward
Supercenters beginning in 1988 follows a similar expansion path
as the aforementioned proliferation of Walmart discount stores
19
that began in 1962. As Neumark et al. (2008) note, the expansion Because of the large sample size, we estimate linear probability models for these
binary dependent variables. Results are robust to the use of probit models. For all
of Walmart discount stores occured in essentially concentric circles
years, we scale the number of Supercenters by county population in 1997 obtained
around Bentonville, Arkansas for a large part of the company’s his- from the US Census Bureau. We fix county population so that the variation over time
tory. Figs. 2–10 show that Walmart Supercenters follow a similar comes entirely from variation in the number of Supercenters. Our results are very
pattern of expansion. similar using county population from the survey year.
20
We begin with a naïve fixed effects specification: Our estimated impacts of Supercenters are not sensitive to the exclusion of the
density  year interactions.
21
X
J X
Y X
S Our data do not allow for an analysis at a finer level of geographic detail than the
WT ict ¼ b0 þ b1 Sct þ b2j X jict þ sy YRyt þ as CY sc county. However, we feel that a narrower analysis – such as at the zip-code level –
j¼1 y¼1 s¼1 would be inappropriate in this context because of the large number of Walmart
shoppers who cross zip code lines to shop there. To illustrate, in 2005 84% of
X
y
Americans shopped at Walmart at least once a year (Pew Research Center, 2005) even
þ qy ðPDct  YRyt Þ þ eict ð15Þ
though only 26% of the US population lived in a zip code with a Walmart discount
y¼1
store or Supercenter (authors’ calculation).
C. Courtemanche, A. Carden / Journal of Urban Economics 69 (2011) 165–181 171

Fig. 3. Walmart Supercenters, 1993.

Fig. 4. Walmart Supercenters, 1994.

Fig. 5. Walmart Supercenters, 1995.

because of the aforementioned negative association between in- than other areas for reasons aside from Walmart. Southern states
come and weight. Alternatively, rapid economic development may do on average have higher obesity rates than other states (Cen-
^1 could be
increase availability of restaurant food, in which case b ters for Disease Control and Prevention, 2009).Of course, some of
biased upward. this difference could be the causal effect of Walmart, while
A second, though less obvious, concern is that Walmart’s tar- much of the remaining regional variation should be captured
geted distance ring(s) may be trending differently in obesity by the county fixed effects, controls for potential confounders
172 C. Courtemanche, A. Carden / Journal of Urban Economics 69 (2011) 165–181

Fig. 6. Walmart Supercenters, 1998.

Fig. 7. Walmart Supercenters, 2000.

Fig. 8. Walmart Supercenters, 2003.

such as income and education, and density  year interactions. and Saint Louis, MO as well as Knoxville, TN and Madison, WI
Also, while Bentonville is technically in the south, its location (Carden et al., 2009a). Nonetheless, the possibility for bias
in the northwest corner of Arkansas is less than 500 miles from remains.
the geographic center of the US Columbus, GA and Denver, CO We next eliminate the first of these two concerns by estimating
are nearly equidistant from Bentonville, as are Shreveport, LA an instrumental variables model using interactions of distance
C. Courtemanche, A. Carden / Journal of Urban Economics 69 (2011) 165–181 173

Fig. 9. Walmart Supercenters, 2005.

Fig. 10. Walmart Supercenters, July 2009.

from Bentonville with each of the year fixed effects as instruments The instrumental variables model is valid under two assump-
for Supercenter presence. The first stage estimates tions. First, the distance  year interactions must impact Supercen-
ter presence conditional on the controls, fixed effects, and
X
J X
Y X
S X
y density  year interactions. This assumption is empirically testable
Sct ¼ c0 þ cj X jict þ ry YRyt þ hs CY sc þ xy ðPDct  YRyt Þ and seems likely to hold given the pattern of Supercenter expan-
j¼1 y¼1 s¼1 y¼1 sion displayed in Figs. 2–10. The second – and more controversial
X
y
– assumption is that the distance  year interactions can be ex-
þ uy ðDIST c  YRyt Þ þ lict ð17Þ cluded from the second-stage model. In other words, they do not
y¼1
affect weight other than though their impact on Supercenter pres-
ence. The instrumental variables model therefore improves on the
while the second stage estimates Eq. (15) using predicted instead of fixed effects model in that it does not rely on the strong assump-
actual Supercenter presence.22 DISTc is county c’s distance in miles tion that Supercenter locations within distance rings are exoge-
from Walmart’s headquarters in Bentonville, AR. Different specifica- nous. It does, however, still rely on the assumption that the
tions for distance have been used in the literature. Neumark et al. different layers of distance have a common trend in unobservable
(2008) constructed a set of dummy variables reflecting 100 mile characteristics that affect body weight. We examine the validity of
distance increments (i.e. less than 100 miles from Benton County, this assumption in Section 3.4 with a series of robustness checks..
100 to 200 miles, etc.). Dube et al. (2007) used dummy variables
for 10 distance rings in their baseline model, though they obtained
similar results with a variety of alternative specifications. Carden 3.3. Results
et al. (2009a) used linear and quadratic distance specifications.
Our results remain very similar regardless of the functional form Table 3 reports the coefficient estimates for the distance  year
for distance, so we use the simplest specification – linear distance instruments from the first-stage regression, along with the F statis-
– in our baseline model and experiment with alternatives in the tic from a test of joint significance of these variables. The
robustness check section. distance  1996 interaction is omitted to prevent perfect collinear-
ity; the coefficient estimates can therefore be interpreted as the
22
We estimate the model using the Stata module xtivreg2 by Schaffer (2005). difference between the effect of distance in the given year and
174 C. Courtemanche, A. Carden / Journal of Urban Economics 69 (2011) 165–181

Table 3 Walmart Supercenter opened – can be attributed to Supercenters


Effect of distance–year interactions on Wal-mart Super- and (2) How much of consumers’ savings from shopping at Super-
centers per 100,000 residents (first stage).
centers is offset by additional medical expenses from the increased
Supercenters obesity rate? For the first question, define DO as the change in the
Distance  1997 0.00007 BRFSS obesity rate between 1988 and 2005, 14.3% points. S is the
(0.00001)*** sample mean for Supercenters per 100,000 residents in 2005, and
Distance  1998 0.00011 dO
is the estimated effect of Supercenters on obesity from the base-
dS
(0.00002)***
Distance  1999 0.00018
line IV regression. The percentage of the rise in obesity that can be
(0.00002)*** attributed to Supercenters is
Distance  2000 0.00028
(0.00003)*** S  dO
dS 0:651  0:023
Distance  2001
PS ¼  100% ¼  100% ¼ 10:5% ð18Þ
0.00036 DO 0:143
(0.00003)***
Distance  2002 0.00041 Our results therefore imply that the existence of Walmart Super-
(0.00004)*** centers accounts for 10.5% of the rise in obesity since the late 1980s.
Distance  2003 0.00051 The percentage of savings from Walmart Supercenters offset by
(0.00004)***
Distance  2004 0.00060
the increased medical expenditures is
(0.00005)***
Distance  2005 0.00073 S  dO
dS
 MED
POFFSET ¼  100% ð19Þ
(0.00006)*** H  SAV
F statistic 19.49
Observations 1,644,094 S  dO
dS
represents the percentage increase in obesity from Supercen-
ters. MED represents the total annual medical expenditures in the
Notes: Standard errors are in parentheses. Standard
US from obesity, estimated at $117 billion (US Department of
errors are heteroskedasticity-robust and clustered by
county. County and year fixed effects are included, as Health and Human Services, 2001). The total annual savings from
well as the individual-level control variables and Walmart is equal to the number of households H times the average
county population density  year interactions. Obser- savings per household SAV. For H, we use the number of households
vations are weighted using the BRFSS sampling
in the US according to the 2000 census, 105,480,101.24 In Appendix
weights.
*
Indicates statistically significant at the 10% level.
A, we calculate SAV = $177 based on estimates of Walmart’s price
**
Indicates statistically significant at the 5% level. effects from the literature and information from the 2002 Census
***
Indicates statistically significant at the 1% level. of Retail Trade and Walmart’s annual reports. Since this estimate
is based on 2002 information, we also use 2002 levels of Supercen-
ter prevalence for S. Ultimately,
the effect of distance in 1996. Each distance  year interaction is
significant at the 1% level. The coefficient estimates are all negative 0:390  0:023  $117; 000; 000; 000
POFFSET ¼ ¼ 5:6% ð20Þ
and become increasingly negative each year, meaning that distance 105; 480; 101  $177
from Bentonville became a stronger predictor of Supercenter pres-
Our estimates therefore suggest that medical expenditures from the
ence over time during our sample period. The F statistic for joint
increase in obesity offset approximately 5.6% of consumers’ savings
significance of the instruments is 19.49, safely over commonly-ac-
from shopping at Walmart Supercenters. While our calculations are
cepted levels at which a weak instrument problem can be ruled
admittedly crude, they are sufficient to illustrate the point that,
out.
while Walmart Supercenters appear to have been an important con-
Table 4 reports the coefficient estimate of interest from the two
tributor to the rise in obesity, the obesity effect only offsets a small
second-stage regressions, along with the corresponding OLS esti-
portion of the savings from their lower prices.
mates. We also report results from a Hausman test of the consis-
tency of the OLS estimator, as well as the p-value from the test
3.4. Robustness checks
of the over identifying restrictions. The OLS estimates suggest that
Supercenters have little to no effect on BMI or obesity. The IV esti-
In this section, we evaluate the sensitivity of our baseline IV
mates, however, are both statistically significant at the 1% level and
estimates to a number of alternative specifications. Our robustness
much larger than the OLS estimates. An additional Supercenter per
checks fall into four categories: (1) alternate functional forms for
100,000 residents increases BMI by an average of 0.237 units,
the Supercenter variable, (2) alternate functional forms for the dis-
which represents 1.5 lb at the sample mean height. The effect on
tance  year instruments, (3) checking whether the estimates are
P(Obese) is 2.3% points, or 10.8% of the sample obesity rate.23 These
confounded by Walmart discount store entry or Sam’s Club entry,
estimates imply that a 100% increase in Supercenter presence rel-
and (4) evaluating the potential for bias from differential trends in
ative to the sample mean of 0.333 stores increases average weight
weight on the basis of distance from Bentonville.
by half a pound and the obesity rate by 0.8% points. Both Hausman
While our scaling of the number of Supercenters in the county
tests strongly reject the consistency of the OLS estimator, while the
by population follows much of the Walmart literature, papers in
overidentification tests fail to reject the null hypothesis that the set
the literature have also used the raw number of stores (Basker
of instruments is valid. (Admittedly, the results from the overiden-
and Noel, 2009) and a binary variable reflecting whether there
tification test are of limited usefulness since all instruments are
is at least one store in the county (Basker, 2005b). In Panel A of
constructed using the same distance variable.)
Table 5, we report the results using these two functional forms
We next evaluate the economic significance of these results by
for Supercenters, as well as another specification that scales the
using the estimated effect on obesity to answer two questions: (1)
number of Supercenters by land area in hundreds of square miles.
What portion of the rise in obesity since in 1988 – when the first
The effects of Supercenters on BMI and P(Obese) remain positive
in all regressions, and are statistically significant in five of the six.
23
Note that a new Supercenter per 100,000 residents is a large change in The magnitudes are not comparable across specifications because
Supercenter presence relative to the sample mean of 0.333. A 100% increase in
Supercenters therefore increases weight by half a pound and obesity by 0.8
24
percentage points. See http://quickfacts.census.gov/qfd/states/00000.html.
C. Courtemanche, A. Carden / Journal of Urban Economics 69 (2011) 165–181 175

Table 4 deviations. Nonetheless, the results from Panel A show that the
Effects of Wal-mart Supercenters on BMI and P(Obese) (second stage). conclusion that Supercenters increase BMI and obesity does not
BMI Obese depend on the functional form used for Supercenters. We therefore
return to the per capita Supercenter measure for all subsequent
OLS IV OLS IV
regressions.
Supercenters 0.024 0.237 0.001 0.023
We next examine the sensitivity of the results to the different
(0.014)* (0.090)*** (0.001) (0.006)***
specifications for the distance  year interactions used in the
Hausman test – 0.213 – 0.022
Walmart literature. As discussed in Section 3.2, these include a
(0.089)*** (0.006)***
quadratic functional form for distance (Carden et al., 2009a), dis-
Overidentification test – 0.180 – 0.582
tance rings of 100 miles (Neumark et al., 2008), and 10 distance
Observations 1,644,094 1,644,094 1,644,094 1,644,094 rings (Dube et al., 2007). We construct distance rings of 100 miles
See notes for Table 3. by creating a dummy variable equal to one if the county is less than
100 miles from Bentonville, another if the county is 100 or more
miles away but less than 200, etc., up to the last ring of 1600 miles
Table 5 or more.25 We then create the set of instruments by interacting
Robustness checks. each of the distance ring dummies with each of the year fixed ef-
BMI Obese fects. In the models with 10 distance rings, each ring represents
170.31 miles, reflecting the maximum distance from Bentonville
Panel A: alternate Supercenter variable 0.585 0.057
functional form for scaled by land area (0.227)*** (0.017)***
in the sample divided by 10. As shown in Panel B of Table 5, the
Supercenter variable Unscaled Supercenter 0.082 0.008 estimates are virtually identical to the baseline estimates from
variable (0.042)** (0.004)** Table 4. The results are therefore not sensitive to different func-
Binary Supercenter 0.199 0.034 tional forms for distance from Bentonville, and we return to the
variable (0.269) (0.019)*
linear specification in subsequent regressions unless otherwise
Panel B: alternate Quadratic distance 0.232 0.023 indicated.
functional form for (0.090)*** (0.006)***
Next, we consider the possibility that our estimates are con-
instruments 10 distance rings 0.215 0.020
(Dube et al.) (0.090)*** (0.005)*** founded by Walmart discount store or Sam’s Club entry. Since
Distance rings for 100 0.233 0.022 these two chains are also operated by Wal-Mart Stores, Inc., their
miles (Neumark et al.) (0.082)*** (0.005)*** expansion patterns were likely influenced by distance from Ben-
Panel C: Sam’s Clubs and Control for Sam’s 0.246 0.024 tonville. If these stores impact body weight, our IV estimator of
discount stores Clubs (0.091)*** (0.006)*** the effect of Supercenters could potentially be biased. However,
Control for discount 0.247 0.025
it seems unlikely that bias from discount stores or Sam’s Clubs is
stores (0.102)*** (0.006)***
Drop if Sam’s Club 0.380 0.029
driving our results for two reasons. First, we restricted the sample
entry (n = 1,371,068) (0.087)*** (0.006)*** to the years 1996 and later because, as documented by Neumark
Drop if discount store 0.406 0.036 et al. (2008), Walmart discount stores had spread to all corners
entry (n = 1,247,730) (0.147)*** (0.011)*** of the US by 1995, after which point new discount stores entered
Panel D: additional Unemployment 0.263 0.025 to fill gaps instead of expand the chain to new territory. Distance
robustness checks rate  year (0.084)*** (0.005)*** from Bentonville therefore predicts discount store entry much
Grocery stores  year 0.216 0.023
more weakly in the post-1995 period than in the pre-1995 period.
(0.092)** (0.006)***
General merchandise 0.193 0.017 Similarly, Sam’s Clubs had also spread to all corners of the US by
stores  year (0.106)* (0.007)** 1995. Second, even if distance from Bentonville did strongly pre-
Restaurants  year 0.227 0.023 dict discount store and Sam’s Club entry during the sample period,
(0.088)*** (0.006)***
it is not clear that these stores would meaningfully impact body
Drop closest 10% of 0.208 0.023
counties (0.099)** (0.006)***
weight. Discount stores sell primarily nonfood items, while
(n = 1,510,081) Sam’s Clubs primarily served small businesses during the sample
Drop furthest 10% of 0.344 0.035 period, as evidenced by their slogan ‘‘We are in business for small
counties (0.197)* (0.014)** business.”26
(n = 1,205,578)
Nonetheless, we conduct robustness checks to test whether dis-
Drop if 0.265 0.024
population > 1,000,000 (0.090)*** (0.007)*** count stores and Sam’s Clubs confound our estimates for Supercen-
(n = 1,499,433) ters. We control for the per capita number of discount stores and
Ring-specific trends 0.104 0.024 Sam’s Clubs opened in the county, and we also estimate models
(0.374) (0.023)
dropping counties that experienced discount store or Sam’s Club
Census-division  year 0.292 0.028
(0.146)** (0.009)***
entry during the sample period. As shown in Panel C of Table 5,
Distance from FDC 0.246 0.013 controlling for these stores has essentially no effect on the esti-
(0.152) (0.009) mated effects of Supercenters, while dropping counties that expe-
Distances from 0.266 0.020 rienced their entry actually increases the estimates somewhat.27
Bentonville and FDC (0.103)*** (0.007)***
[0.160] [0.569]

Notes: Sample size is 1,644,094 unless otherwise indicated. p-value from the
25
overidentification test is in brackets. See other notes for Table 3. The maximum distance from Bentonville in the sample is 1703.1 miles; we
combine the few observations for whom distance is greater than 1700 miles with the
1600–1700 mile category.
26
See http://www.fundinguniverse.com/company-histories/Sams-Club-Company-
a one unit increase in the Supercenter variable represents a dif- History.html for a brief history of Sam’s Club that discusses its focus on small
businesses beginning in 1994.
ferent shock to the market depending on which functional form 27
Our coefficient estimates for Sam’s Clubs in the BMI and obesity regressions are
is used. For instance, an additional Supercenter per 100,000 resi- 0.138 (standard error 0.106) and 0.009 (standard error 0.009), respectively. Our
dents is an increase of 1.26 standard deviations, while an addi- coefficient estimates for discount stores in the BMI and obesity regressions are 0.031
tional (unscaled) Supercenter is an increase of 0.74 standard (standard error 0.068) and 0.005 (standard error 0.005), respectively.
176 C. Courtemanche, A. Carden / Journal of Urban Economics 69 (2011) 165–181

We therefore find no evidence that neglecting to account for dis- 3.5. Heterogeneity
count stores or Sam’s Clubs led to the estimation of a spurious po-
sitive effect of Supercenters on weight in the baseline regression.28 We next return to the baseline IV model and evaluate the po-
Finally, we estimate a number of additional models to examine tential for heterogeneity on the bases of gender, income, and
the validity of the assumption that underlying trends in body county population. Stratifying by gender is common in the obesity
weight do not vary systematically on the basis of distance from literature. We stratify by income and population as well since
Bentonville. We first test for differential trends on the basis of eco- Walmart’s shoppers are disproportionately low-income individu-
nomic activity by estimating models including interactions of the als living in rural areas or small towns. For income and population,
year fixed effects with unemployment rate, grocery stores per ca- we divide the sample into those below the 25th percentile, be-
pita, general merchandise stores per capita, and restaurants per ca- tween the 25th and 75th percentiles, and above the 75th percen-
pita.29 We also run regressions dropping the furthest 10% of tile. When splitting the sample by income, we also stratify by
counties from Bentonville (those beyond 1119.74 miles), the clos- marital status since household income depends largely on the
est 10% of counties to Bentonville (those within 264.06 miles), and number of adults in the family.
counties with a population of over 1,000,000. This helps to ensure Table 6 reports the results. The effect of Supercenters on BMI is
that our results are not driven by large coastal population centers stronger for women than men, but the effect on P(Obese) is stron-
and/or rural areas close to Bentonville. Next, we estimate two ger for men. This suggests that the impact on men is skewed more
models that account for differential trends more generally: one heavily toward the right tail of the BMI distribution. Supercenters
including linear 100 mile distance ring-specific time trends, and have the strongest effect on the weights of low-income married
another including interactions of the year fixed effects with dum- individuals, while there is no clear connection between the income
my variables reflecting the nine US Census Bureau census divi- of single individuals and the strength of the effect. The most strik-
sions.30 Ring-specific time trends and census division-by-year ing result shown in the table, however, is the strong impact on the
effects eliminate much of the variation in the instruments, so to in- weight of people living in the least populated areas. An additional
crease power we use the most flexible of the distance specifica- Supercenter per 100,000 residents increases average BMI by 0.634
tions – 100 mile distance rings – for the instruments in these units (4 lb at the sample mean height) and P(Obese) by 5.9% points
regressions. Finally, we consider a different identification strategy among individuals below the 25th percentile in county population.
altogether: we use interactions of the year effects with distance These large effects may reflect the relative lack of shopping alter-
from the nearest Walmart food distribution center as the instru- natives in rural areas.
ments. This approach is less susceptible to concern about differen-
tial trends between coastal and inland areas because Walmart food 3.6. Falsification tests
distribution centers are scattered throughout the country. How-
ever, food distribution center locations and Supercenter locations In this subsection we consider two falsification tests. First, we
may be jointly determined. We also estimate a model using both estimate the baseline IV regression given by Eqs. (15) and (17)
the distance from Bentonville  year interactions and the distance but use height (in inches) as the second-stage dependent variable.
from the nearest food distribution center  year interactions as BMI is a measure of weight scaled by height, raising the question
instruments. of whether Supercenters’ positive effect on BMI could actually re-
Panel D of Table 5 displays the results from these additional flect a decrease in height as opposed to an increase in weight. Such
robustness checks. Supercenters are statistically significant in 18 an effect would be implausible and call into question the validity of
of the 22 regressions, and the estimates are generally similar across the identification strategy. The first column of Table 7 reports the
the different specifications. An additional Supercenter increases results. The relationship between Supercenters and height is statis-
BMI by 0.1–0.34 units and P(Obese) by 1.3–3.5% points. The 95% tically insignificant and extremely small. An additional Supercenter
confidence intervals include the point estimate from the baseline
IV regression in all 22 regressions, so there is no evidence that
the baseline estimator is inconsistent.31 We only report the over- Table 6
identification test p-value for the regression with the distances Heterogeneity.

from both Bentonville and the nearest food distribution center as BMI P(Obese)
instruments, as this is the only model with a plausible over identi- Gender Women 0.320 0.018
fying restriction. For both BMI and obesity status, the overidentifi- (0.112)*** (0.007)**
cation test fails to reject the null hypothesis that the set of Men 0.181 0.029
instruments is valid. (0.121) (0.008)***
Income: married Lowest 25% 0.375 0.019
(0.200)* (0.016)
Middle 50% 0.203 0.014
(0.139) (0.013)
28 Highest 25% 0.198 0.015
In other unreported regressions (available upon request), we dropped counties
(0.149) (0.013)
with Supercenters and estimated our baseline IV model using per capita discount
stores as the endogenous variable. The set of distance  year instruments only weakly Income: single Lowest 25% 0.133 0.027
predicted discount store presence, with a first stage F statistic of 3.97. We also (0.249) (0.017)
performed the same analysis for Sam’s Clubs, and the first stage was an even smaller Middle 50% 0.185 0.027
0.91. Accordingly, in both cases the estimated effects on BMI and obesity from the (0.200) (0.016)*
second stage were noisy and insignificant. Highest 25% 0.183 0.019
29
Ruhm (2000, 2005) documents a negative relationship between unemployment (0.275) (0.023)
rate and obesity. Population Smallest 25% 0.634 0.059
30
Census division classifications are available at http://www.census.gov/geo/www/ (0.363)* (0.030)**
us_regdiv.pdf. Middle 50% 0.273 0.022
31
Note that adding distance ring-specific time trends (row 8 in Panel D) creates (0.121)** (0.009)**
severe multicollinearity and inflates the standard errors to the point where the results Largest 25% 0.189 0.023
are not particularly informative. However, the distance-ring-specific trends are both (0.255) (0.016)
individually and jointly insignificant in both the BMI and obesity regressions, so the
evidence suggests that they do not belong in the model. See notes for Table 3.
C. Courtemanche, A. Carden / Journal of Urban Economics 69 (2011) 165–181 177

Table 7 (Mc) in our regression analysis. We are not aware of any available
Falsification tests. panel data on county-level McDonald’s prevalence, so we use
Height Trends in counties with no supercenters Dunn’s (2008) cross-sectional McDonald’s data from 2005 and con-
BMI P(Obese) duct a cross-sectional analysis using only that year. We begin with
the following OLS regression:
Supercenters 0.043 – –
(0.041) X
J
Distance  1997 – 0.00018 0.000017 WT ic ¼ b0 þ b1 Sc þ b2 M c þ b3 PDc þ b4j X jic þ eic ð22Þ
(0.00012) (0.000010)* j¼1
Distance  1998 – 0.00018 0.00001
(0.00012) (0.00001) where the standard errors are again heteroskedasticity-robust and
Distance  1999 – 0.00017 0.000003 clustered by county. We also estimate an IV model using distance
(0.00017) (0.000011)
Distance  2000 – 0.00018 0.000012
from Bentonville as the instrument for Supercenters. We are not
(0.00014) (0.000012) aware of any attempts in the literature to specifically instrument
Distance  2001 – 0.00018 0.000014 for McDonald’s prevalence (as opposed to fast-food or full-service
(0.00014) (0.000011) restaurant prevalence more generally), so we do not attempt to
Distance  2002 – 0.00007 0.000010
do so here. Our regressions should therefore be interpreted simply
(0.00014) (0.000011)
Distance  2003 – 0.00004 0.000001 as tests of whether controlling for McDonald’s impacts the coeffi-
(0.00013) (0.000011) cient estimate for Supercenters, rather than as attempts to obtain
Distance  2004 – 0.00005 0.000009 the causal effects of McDonald’s.
(0.00014) (0.000010) The left half of Table 8 reports the results for BMI while the
Distance  2005 – 0.00010 0.000001
right half reports the results for obesity. Each half presents OLS
(0.00013) (0.000009)
Observations 1,644,094 710,856 710,856 and IV results both with and without controlling for McDonald’s.
In all cases adding McDonald’s presence to the regressions makes
See notes for Table 3.
almost no difference in the estimated effect of Supercenters. The
effect of Supercenters on weight is positive and statistically signif-
icant in all regressions; the IV estimates are larger than the OLS
per 100,000 residents is associated with an additional 0.043 inches,
estimates and roughly similar to the full-sample IV estimates
which is only 0.06% of the sample mean height.
from Sections 3.3 and 3.4. An additional McDonald’s increases
Our second falsification exercise directly tests the assumption
weight in all specifications as well. While the estimated effect of
that the distance  year interactions do not affect BMI or obesity
a new McDonald’s is much smaller than the estimated effect of
other than through their effect on Walmart Supercenter presence.
a new Supercenter, note that one new McDonald’s represents a
We drop the counties that had one or more Supercenters by the
much smaller change in the market than one new Supercenter –
end of the sample period (leaving a sample size of 710,856) and
the average individual in the 2005 sample lives in a county with
estimate the reduced-form version of our baseline IV model:
46.293 McDonald’s per 100,000 residents but only 0.646 Super-
X
J X
Y X
S X
y centers per 100,000 residents. A more useful expression of the
W ict ¼ c0 þ cj X jict þ ry YRyt þ hs CY sc þ xy ðPDct  YRy tÞ IV estimates is that a 100% increase in McDonald’s presence at
j¼1 y¼1 s¼1 y¼1 the mean increases BMI by 0.147 units and P(Obese) by 0.008 per-
X
y
centage points, while a 100% increase in Supercenter presence at
þ uy ðDIST c  YRyt Þ þ lict ð21Þ the mean increases BMI by 0.210 units and P(Obese) by 0.017 per-
y¼1
centage points.
We report the estimated impacts of the distance  year interactions
on BMI and P(Obese) in the second and third columns of Table 7. 3.8. A food price effect?
The results show that in counties with no Supercenters there is
no clear evidence of differential trends in BMI and obesity on the We close our empirical analysis by examining whether it is
basis of distance from Bentonville. In the BMI regression, none of plausible that Supercenters’ entire effect on weight occurs through
the interactions are statistically significant and the pattern of signs a simple across-the-board reduction in food prices. We do this by
is mixed (five positive, four negative). In the obesity regression, only computing the food price elasticities of BMI and obesity that would
one interaction is marginally significant and the pattern of signs is be necessary for the entire Supercenter effect to operate through
again mixed (four positive, five negative). food prices and checking whether these estimates are in line with
those from the literature.33
Define these elasticities as
3.7. Walmart and McDonald’s
33
We also considered another approach: testing for differences between the
We next consider the possibility that our estimated effects of impacts of Supercenters that are brand new stores and those that were converted
the world’s largest retailer could be confounded by the effects of from discount stores. The main difference between a Supercenter and a discount
one of the world’s largest fast-food chains. Though we already con- store is the addition of grocery section, so if conversions impact weight differently
trolled for per capita number of restaurants in a robustness check, than brand new stores then grocery prices cannot be responsible for the entire
effect – other mechanisms such as cheaper electronics or income effects must be
McDonald’s deserves special consideration because of the chain’s
contributing. We have thus far been unable to develop an IV estimator that
tendency to locate inside Walmart Supercenters, raising the ques- simultaneously estimates the impacts of both new stores and conversions with
tion of whether Supercenters impact weight primarily by enabling meaningful precision. OLS estimators (Eq. (15) but with Supercenters split into new
McDonald’s entry.32 We investigate this possibility by controlling stores and conversions) find no statistically or economically significant differences
for McDonald’s restaurants per 100,000 residents in the county between the impacts of Supercenters that are new stores and those that are
converted discount stores. In the BMI regression, the coefficient estimates for new
stores and conversions are 0.018 (standard error 0.023) and 0.026 (standard error
32
Recently Subway has overtaken McDonald’s as the most popular fast food chain 0.017). In the obesity regression, the coefficient estimates for new stores and
inside Supercenters and as the largest fast food chain in the world. However, we do conversions are 0.0015 (standard error 0.0019) and 0.0008 (standard error 0.0012).
not examine Subways because they did not begin locating inside Supercenters until In both regressions, the p-value from a t-test of the equality of the coefficients is
2004, toward the end of our sample period (Kung, 2007). 0.8.
178 C. Courtemanche, A. Carden / Journal of Urban Economics 69 (2011) 165–181

Table 8
Walmart and McDonald’s.

BMI P(Obese)
OLS IV OLS IV
(1) (2) (1) (2) (1) (2) (1) (2)
Supercenters 0.109 0.089 0.368 0.325 0.008 0.007 0.028 0.026
(0.025)*** (0.025)*** (0.091)*** (0.101)*** (0.002)*** (0.002)*** (0.007)*** (0.007)***
McDonald’s – 0.006 – 0.003 – 0.0004 – 0.0002
(0.001)*** (0.002)** (0.0001)*** (0.0001)
Observations 229,645 229,645 229,645 229,645 229,645 229,645 229,645 229,645

Notes: Standard errors are in parentheses. Standard errors are heteroskedasticity-robust and clustered by county. County population density and the individual-level control
variables are included. The sample is restricted to 2005 so no county or year fixed effects are included. Observations are weighted using the BRFSS sampling weights.
*
Indicates statistically significant at the 10% level.
**
Indicates statistically significant at the 5% level.
***
Indicates statistically significant at the 1% level.

%DBMI dBMI =BMI %D0 d0 =0 imply that the proliferation of Walmart Supercenters explains
eBMI ¼ ¼ dS and e0 ¼ ¼ dS ð23Þ 10.5% of the rise in obesity since the late 1980s, but that the in-
%D P %D P % D P %D P
crease in medical expenditures offsets only 5.6% of consumers’ sav-
where %DBMI, %DO, and %DP are the percentage changes (divided ings from shopping at Walmart.
by 100) in BMI and obesity when a Walmart Supercenter enters; We contribute to the Walmart literature by providing informa-
dBMI
dS
and dO
dS
are the estimated effects of Supercenters on BMI and tion about one of many factors that communities should consider
P(Obese); and BMI and O are the sample means for BMI and obesity when incentivizing Walmart entry. We also contribute methodo-
status (26.612 and 0.212). In Appendix B we perform a back-of-the- logically by showing that distance from Bentonville predicts Super-
envelope calculation for %DP using estimates of Walmart’s price center entry in the post-1995 period in much the same way that it
advantage and effect on competitors’ prices from the literature. predicted discount store entry in the pre-1995 period. This may
We find that the entry of a Walmart Supercenter lowers the average prove useful in identifying other effects of Supercenters. More gen-
county’s grocery prices by 4.2%. Limited information about the erally, our exhaustive robustness testing contributes to the ongo-
parameter values involved in calculating %DP necessitates the use ing debate about the distance from Bentonville instrument by
of unscaled number of Supercenters (instead of per capita) in this showing that it is likely appropriate in at least some contexts.
calculation. The comparable regression estimates of dBMI dS
and dO
dS We contribute to the obesity literature by identifying another
are therefore those from the ‘‘unscaled Supercenter variable” mechanism – improved efficiency in the distribution of food and
regression in the second row of Panel A of Table 5: 0.082 and other goods – through which technological progress likely contrib-
0.008. uted to the rise in obesity. Our findings epitomize an ongoing de-
Computing the elasticities yields bate about the appropriateness of policy interventions designed
0:082=26:612 0:008=0:212 to reduce obesity. The results are consistent with arguments made
eBMI ¼ ¼ 0:073 and e0 ¼ by Lakdawalla et al. (2005) and others that the rise in obesity can
0:042 0:042
be largely attributed to rational responses to changing incentives
¼ 0:898: ð24Þ
from welfare-enhancing technological change, in which case gov-
For comparison, Chou et al. (2004) used BRFSS data toestimate food- ernment interference would be socially wasteful. However, the po-
at-home price elasticities of BMI and obesity of 0.039 and 0.622. tential exists for institutional failures to lead to sub-optimal
Our elasticities are of the same order of magnitude, though some- weight outcomes. Bhattacharya and Sood (2007) note that govern-
what larger in both cases. We interpret this as preliminary evidence ment and private health insurance subsidizes obesity and pools the
that lower across-the-board food prices can explain a significant risk of both the obese and the non-obese, externalizing the costs of
portion of the impact of Walmart Supercenters on BMI and obesity, obesity-related illness. Consumers therefore receive the benefits
but that there is room for the more complex combination of factors from shopping at Walmart but do not internalize the costs, poten-
described in Section 2 to play a role as well.34 For instance, part of tially leading to distortions. Also, self-control problems likely play
the effect could be due to Supercenters decreasing the relative price a role in obesity (Cutler et al., 2003), and cheap food from Super-
of unhealthy to healthy food or decreasing the price of inputs to a centers may exacerbate these self-control problems.
sedentary lifestyle such as movies or video games. Future research Our findings point to natural avenues for future research. Future
should examine these pathways more directly. work should more directly investigate the roles of eating and exer-
cise in explaining the impact of Walmart Supercenters on body
weight.35 If Supercenters do in fact increase caloric intake, research
4. Conclusion should examine whether this increase is the result of an across-
the-board increase in food consumption or a substitution from
This paper exploits the unique geographic pattern of Walmart healthy to unhealthy foods. The former would mean that Super-
Supercenter expansion to identify the effect of county-level Super- centers improve nutrient intake, potentially offsetting some of
center presence on individual BMI and obesity status. We find evi- the health consequences of the rise in obesity. Research should also
dence that Supercenters increase both BMI and obesity, with consider the health effects of Supercenters’ reduced prices for cig-
effects that are largest for women, low-income married individu- arettes, alcohol, and prescription drugs. Finally, future research
als, and those living in the least populous counties. The estimates should examine the effect of other big box retailers on body

34
However, it should be noted that if for dBMI
dS
and dO dS
we use one standard error
35
below the regression coefficient estimates, our elasticities are actually smaller than The BRFSS is not the appropriate dataset for a thorough investigation of the
those of Chou et al. We therefore cannot conclusively rule out the possibility that a mechanisms, as during our sample period it contains only limited information on
general food price reduction explains the entire effect. eating habits and its exercise questions are inconsistent.
C. Courtemanche, A. Carden / Journal of Urban Economics 69 (2011) 165–181 179

weight. For instance, Target caters to a somewhat more affluent cli- SAV ¼ C  PW ½CðPWW Þð1  PCT C Þð1  PCT W Þ
entele than Walmart, and income and substitution effects for food þ Cð1  PWW Þð1  PCT C Þ þ Cð1  PW Þ ðA3Þ
and other goods could differ across the income distribution. This
paper therefore provides a first step in understanding the health We perform the calculation for 2002 because estimates for all
consequences of big box retailing, but much is left to learn about the parameters are available in that year. For C, we first compute to-
the subject. tal expenditures on the types of goods Supercenters sell using data
from the 2002 Census of Retail Trade. We consider Supercenters to
sell goods in the following categories: electronics and appliances;
Acknowledgments
lawn and garden; food and beverage (not counting restaurants or
bars); health and personal care; clothing and clothing accessory;
The preparation and presentation of this research was sup-
sporting goods, hobby and musical instrument; book, periodical,
ported by grants from Washington University in Saint Louis,
and music; general merchandise; and office supplies and gifts.
Rhodes College, the Independent Institute, the Institute for Hu-
Expenditures in these categories totaled approximately $1.474 tril-
mane Studies, the Association of Private Enterprise Education,
lion, or 14% of 2002s GDP.36 C is equal to this number divided by the
and the American Institute for Economic Research. We thank Jo-
number of households in the US in 2002 according to the US Census
lene Courtemanche, Russell Craig, Jason Fletcher, Mike Hammock,
Bureau, 109.297 million. C is therefore $13,488.
Stephen Holland, Patrick McAlvanah, Van Pham, Chris Ruhm, Ken
For PW, we use the proportion of people from the 2002 wave of
Snowden, the editor, and two anonymous referees for valuable
the BRFSS who live in a county with at least one Supercenter,
comments and suggestions. Shannon Carden, Dylan Chambers,
which is 0.37. For PWW, we begin by dividing Walmart Supercen-
Diana Cheng, Jolene Courtemanche, Kelly Gillean, Thach Truong,
ters’ domestic sales by $1.474 trillion to determine its approximate
and Sameer Warraich provided excellent research assistance, while
market share. We compute a market share of 5.2%.37 To generate a
Mallory Raffensberger assisted with preparation of an early manu-
market share of 5.2% for the entire US, which includes counties with
script. Andrew Foss-Grant provided indispensable assistance with
no Supercenters where their market share should be 0%, the market
the GIS software used to prepare Figs. 2–10. We are grateful to par-
share must be 14.1% in the counties that do have at least one Super-
ticipants at the 2007 Missouri Valley Economic Association, the
center. We therefore assign PWW = 0.141.
2008 Public Choice Society, and 2008 Association of Private Enter-
For the price reduction parameters, we draw on existing litera-
prise Education conferences and seminar participants at the Re-
ture. Basker and Noel (2009) find the entry of a Walmart Supercen-
search Triangle Institute, the University of Southern Mississippi,
ter in a city reduces competitors’ prices by 1–1.2%. We assign
the University of Memphis, Baylor University, Texas Christian Uni-
PCTC = 0.011, the midpoint of this range. As discussed in Section 2,
versity, the University of Mississippi, the University of Alabama,
studies place Walmart’s price advantage over competitors at
the University of Nevada-Las Vegas, the University of North Caro-
between 8% and 27% (Hausman and Leibtag, 2007). We therefore
lina at Greensboro, and the American Institute for Economic Re-
assign PCTW equal to the midpoint, or 0.175. Eq. (A3) becomes
search for valuable comments and suggestions. (Earlier versions
of this paper were presented with the titles ‘‘Risky Business? SAV ¼ 13488  0:37½13488  ð0:141Þð1  0:011Þð1  0:175Þ
Wal-Mart and Risky Health Behaviors” and ‘‘The Skinny on Big þ 13488  ð1  0:141Þð1  0:011Þ  13488ð1  0:37Þ
Box Retailing: Walmart, Warehouse Clubs, and Obesity.”) We also
¼ $176:68 ðA4Þ
thank Richard Dunn, Austan Goolsbee, Thomas Holmes, and Chad
Syversonfor sharing their data. We therefore conclude that Wal-Mart Supercenters saved house-
holds $177 per year in 2002.38
Appendix A. Savings from Wal-Mart
Appendix B. Impact of Walmart Supercenters on market
In this appendix, we perform a back-of-the-envelope calcula- grocery prices
tion of consumers’ savings from Walmart Supercenters’ lower
prices. These savings (SAV) are equal to what expenditures per In this appendix, we perform a back-of-the-envelope calcula-
household on consumer goods and groceries (the goods Supercen- tion of the percentage change in a market’s grocery prices when
ters sell) would be if there were no Supercenters (C) minus what
they are given that there are Supercenters (CW): 36
Of course, Wal-Mart sells some goods outside of these categories and sells a
SAV ¼ C  C W ðA1Þ limited selection of some of the goods within these categories, so our approach
provides only a rough estimate. According to the web site of the St. Louis Federal
CW is identical to C for the portion of the population that lives in Reserve Bank, nominal GDP from July 1, 2002 was $10527.4 trillion.
37
areas with no Supercenters. People who live in areas with at least Walmart’s 2002 domestic sales at discount stores and Supercenters totaled
$139.131 billion according to its annual report, available at http://walmart-
one Supercenter can further be divided into those who shop there
stores.com/Media/Investors/2002_annualreport.pdf. We approximate the sales at
and those who do not. Those who do not shop at Walmart Super- Supercenters by multiplying $139.131 billion by the proportion of Wal-mart stores
centers still face lower prices if Walmart affects competitors’ prices. that were Supercenters, weighted by the average square footage of discount stores
People who do shop at Walmart experience this reduction, plus an and Supercenters. We obtain the average square footage from page 21 of the
additional one due to Walmart’s price advantage over competitors company’s 2006 Annual Report. Ultimately, we estimate total sales at Supercenters of
$77.297 billion.
that remains even after competitors adjust their prices. Therefore, 38
Experimentation with alternative measures of Super Walmart’s price effects and
price advantages ranged from $105.64 using the lowest estimates of Walmart’s cost
C W ¼ PW ½CðPWW Þð1  PCT C Þð1  PCT W Þ þ Cð1  PWW Þð1  PCT C Þ
advantages and price effects from Hausman and Leibtag (2009) and Basker and Noel
þ Cð1  PW Þ: ðA2Þ (2009) to $247.60 using the highest estimates of Walmart’s cost advantages and price
effects from Hausman and Leibtag (2009) and Basker and Noel (2009). This generates
where PW is the proportion of people who live in a county with at estimates of the savings offset from obesity reported in Eq. (20) ranging from 4% using
least one Walmart Supercenter, PWW is the proportion of people living the high estimates from Hausman and Leibtag (2009) and Basker and Noel (2009) to
in a county with a Supercenter who shop there, PCTC is the percentage 9.4% using the low estimates from Hausman and Leibtag (2009) and Basker and Noel
(2009). Even using the lowest estimates of Super Walmart’s effect on competitors’
reduction in competitor prices after Supercenter entry (divided by prices and the lowest estimates of Walmart’s price advantages over competitors, we
100), and PCTW is the percentage savings from shopping at a Super- estimate that the percentage of Super Walmart-related savings offset by increased
center instead of its competitors. Combining (A1) and (A2) yields obesity-related health costs is lower than 10%.
180 C. Courtemanche, A. Carden / Journal of Urban Economics 69 (2011) 165–181

a Walmart Supercenter enters. Similarly to Appendix A, when a Carden, A., Courtemanche, C., Meiners, J., 2009b. Painting the Town Red? Wal-Mart
and Values, Business and Politics 11 (Article 5).
Supercenter enters most consumers will still purchase groceries
Cawley, J., 1999. Rational Addiction, the Consumption of Calories, and Body Weight,
at a traditional grocery store but will experience a slight price PhD Dissertation, University of Chicago.
reduction due to Walmart’s competitive pressure. Define this Centers for Disease Control and Prevention, 2009. Estimated County-level
reduction as PCTW. Other consumers will switch their shopping Prevalence of Diabetes and Obesity—2007, Morbidity and Mortality Weekly
Report 58, pp. 1259–1263.
to the new Supercenter and experience on top of this price reduc- Chou, S., Grossman, M., Saffer, H., 2004. An economic analysis of adult obesity:
tion another larger reduction from the price advantage Walmart results from the behavioral risk factor surveillance system. Journal of Health
retains even after competitors adjust their prices. Define Walmart’s Economics 23, 565–587.
Chou, S., Grossman, M., Saffer, H., 2006. Reply to Jonathan Gruber and Michael
price advantage as PCTC. Assume county-level markets, and let PSW Frakes. Journal of Health Economics 25, 389–393.
be the share of the county’s grocery market captured by the new Courtemanche, C., 2009. Rising cigarette prices and rising obesity: coincidence or
Walmart. The percentage reduction in market grocery prices (di- unintended consequence? Journal of Health Economics 28, 781–798.
Currie, J., DellaVigna, S., Moretti, E., Pathania, V., 2010. The effect of fast food
vided by 100) when a Walmart Supercenter enters is therefore restaurants on obesity and weight gain. American Economic Journal: Economic
Policy 2, 32–63.
%DP ¼ ð1  PSW ÞPCT C þ PSW ðPCT C þ ð1  PCT C ÞPCT W Þ ðA5Þ Cutler, D., Glaeser, E., Shapiro, J., 2003. Why have Americans become more obese?
Journal of Economic Perspectives 17, 93–118.
We calibrate the parameters as follows. As in Appendix A, Drewnowski, A., Specter, S., 2004. Poverty and obesity: the role of energy density
PCTW = 0.011 because of Basker and Noel’s (2009) finding that the and energy costs. American Journal of Clinical Nutrition 79, 6–16.
entry of a new Walmart Supercenter reduces grocery stores’ prices Dube, A., Lester, T., Eidlin, B., 2007. Firm entry and Wages: Impact of Wal-Mart
Growth on Earnings Throughout the Retail Sector. Institute of Industrial
by 1–1.2%. Also following Appendix A, PCTC = 0.175 based on Haus-
Relations Working Paper No. iirwps-126-05.
man and Leibtag’s (2004) finding that estimates of Walmart’s price Dunn, R., 2008. Obesity and the Availability of Fast-food: An Instrumental Variables
advantage range from 8% to 27%. We are not aware of a direct esti- Approach, Working Paper, University of Wisconsin-Madison.
mate of PSW so we approximate it as follows. Lord (2006, pp. 55– Eid, J., Overman, H., Puga, D., Turner, M., 2008. Fat city: questioning the relationship
between urban sprawl and obesity. Journal of Urban Economics 63, 385–
62) estimates that Walmart Supercenters had a 14.9% share in 404.
the US grocery market in 2004. Only 46% of our BRFSS sample lived Ewing, R., Schmid, T., Killingsworth, R., Zlot, A., Raudenbush, S., 2003. Relationship
in counties with a Supercenter in 2004. Walmart’s share of the gro- between urban sprawl and physical activity, obesity, and morbidity. American
Journal of Health Promotion 18, 47–57.
cery market in these counties must have been 32.4% to offset a 0% Finkelstein, E., Fiebelkorn, I., Wang, G., 2003. National Medical Spending
share in the counties with no Supercenters and bring the overall Attributable to Overweight and Obesity: How Much, and Who’s Paying?
national average to 14.9%. This 32.4% is split between the different Health Affairs, Web Exclusives: W219-W226.
Fishman, C., 2006. The Walmart Effect. Penguin Press, New York.
Supercenters in the market. Among those individuals living in a Flegal, K., Carroll, M., Kuczmarski, R., Johnson, C., 1998. Overweight and obesity in
county with a Supercenter in our 2004 BRFSS sample, the average the United States: prevalence and trends, 1960–1994. International Journal of
number of Supercenters in the county was 1.8. A 32.4% overall Obesity 22, 39–47.
Flegal, K., Graubard, B., Williamson, D., Gail, M., 2005. Excess deaths associated with
market share therefore translates to an average market share per underweight, overweight, and obesity. Journal of the American Medical
Supercenter of 18%. We therefore set PSW = 0.18. Association 293, 1861–1867.
Using these parameter values, Frank, L., Andresen, M., Schmid, T., 2004. Obesity relationships with community
design, physical activity, and time spent in cars. American Journal of Preventive
%DP ¼ ð1  0:18Þ0:011 þ 0:18ð0:011 þ ð1  0:0011Þ0:175Þ Medicine 27, 87–96.
Giles-Corti, B., Donovan, R., 2003. Relative influences of individual, social
¼ 0:042 ðA6Þ environmental, and physical environmental correlates of walking. American
Journal of Public Health 93, 1583–1589.
We conclude that the entry of a Walmart Supercenter reduces gro- Goetz, S., Rupasingha, A., 2006. Wal-Mart and social capital. American Journal of
Agricultural Economics 88, 1304–1310.
cery prices in the average market by 4.2%.39
Goetz, S., Swaminathan, H., 2006. Wal-Mart and county-wide poverty. Social
Science Quarterly 87, 211–226.
References Gruber, J., Frakes, M., 2006. Does falling smoking lead to rising obesity? Journal of
Health Economics 25, 183–187.
Haltiwanger, J., Jarmin, R., 2010. Mom-and-Pop meet big-box: complements or
Anderson, M., Matsa, D., forthcoming. Are restaurants really supersizing America?
substitutes? Journal of Urban Economics 67, 116–134.
American Economic Journal: Applied Economics. <http://www.aeaweb.org/
Hausman, J., Leibtag, E., 2009. CPI bias from Supercenters: does the BLS know that
forthcoming/output/accepted_APP.php>.
Wal-Mart exists? In: Erwin Diewert, W., Greenlees, John S., Hulten, Charles R.
Basiotis, P., Lino, M., 2002. Food Insufficiency and Prevalence of Overweight among
(Eds.), Price Index Concepts and Measurement. University of Chicago Press and
Adult Women. United States Department of Agriculture Center for Nutrition
NBER, Chicago, pp. 203–231.
Policy and Promotion Nutrition Insights 26. <http://www.cnpp.usda.gov/
Hausman, J., Leibtag, E., 2007. Consumer benefits from increased competition in
Publications/NutritionInsights/Insight26.pdf>.
shopping outlets: measuring the effect of Wal-Mart. Journal of Applied
Basker, E., 2005a. Job creation or destruction? Labor-market effects of Wal-Mart
Econometrics 22 (7), 1157–1177.
expansion. Review of Economics and Statistics 87, 174–183.
Hicks, M., 2007. Job turnover and wages in the retail sector: the influence of
Basker, E., 2005b. Selling a cheaper mousetrap: Wal-Mart’s effect on retail prices.
Walmart. Journal of Private Enterprise 22, 137–159.
Journal of Urban Economics 58, 203–229.
Holmes, T., 2008. The Diffusion of Wal-Mart and Economies of Density, National
Basker, E., 2006. When Good Instruments Go Bad: A Reply to Neumark, Zhang, and
Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper w13783.
Ciccarella. University of Missouri Department of Economics Working Paper 07-
Karjanen, D., 2006. The Walmart effect and the new face of capitalism: labor market and
06.
community effects of the megaretailer. In: Lichtenstein, N. (Ed.), Wal-Mart: The
Basker, E., 2007. The causes and consequences of Wal-Mart’s growth. Journal of
Face of Twenty-First Century Capitalism. The New Press, New York, pp. 143–162.
Economic Perspectives 21, 177–198.
Kung, M., 2007. Wal-Mart Dumps McDonald’s For Subway as In-Store Restaurateur.
Basker, E., Noel, M., 2009. The evolving food chain: competitive effects of Wal-
The Huffington Post Online. <http://www.huffingtonpost.com/2007/09/13/
Mart’s entry into the supermarket industry. Journal of Economics and
walmart-dumps-mcdonalds-f_n_64322.html>.
Management Strategy 18 (4), 977–1009.
Lakdawalla, D., Philipson, T., 2002. The Growth of Obesity and Technological
Baum, C., 2008. The effects of cigarette costs on BMI and obesity. Health Economics
Change: A Theoretical and Empirical Investigation, National Bureau of Economic
18, 3–19.
Research Working Paper 8965.
Bhattacharya, J., Sood, N., 2007. Health insurance and the obesity externality.
Lakdawalla, D., Philipson, T., Bhattacharya, J., 2005. Welfare-enhancing
Advances in Health Economics and Health Services Research 17, 279–318.
technological change and the growth of obesity. American Economic Review
Carden, A., Courtemanche, C., 2009. Wal-Mart, leisure, and culture. Contemporary
Papers and Proceedings 95, 253–257.
Economic Policy 27, 450–461.
Lord, J., 2006. Walmart Supercenter market share of grocery retailing in US
Carden, A., Courtemanche, C., Meiners, J., 2009a. Does Wal-Mart reduce social
metropolitan areas. In: Brunn, S. (Ed.), Walmart World: The World’s Biggest
capital? Public Choice 138, 109–136.
Corporation in the Global Economy. Routledge, Oxford, pp. 55–62.
National Center of Health Statistics, 2008. Prevalence of Overweight, Obesity and
39
Experimenting with the low and high estimates of the price effects and price Extreme Obesity among Adults: United States, Trends 1976–80 Through 2005–
advantages from Hausman and Leibtag (2009) and Basker and Noel (2009) produced 2006. <http://www.cdc.gov/nchs/data/hestat/overweight/overweight_adult.
pdf>.
estimates ranging from 2.4% using the low estimates to 6% using the high estimates.
C. Courtemanche, A. Carden / Journal of Urban Economics 69 (2011) 165–181 181

Neumark, D., Zhang, J., Ciccarella, S., 2008. The effects of Wal-Mart on local labor Rosin, O., 2008. The economic causes of obesity: a survey. Journal of Economic
markets. Journal of Urban Economics 63, 405–430. Surveys 22, 617–647.
Nonnemaker, J., Finkelstein, E., Engelen, M., Hoerger, T., Farrelly, M., 2008. Have Ruhm, C., 2000. Are recessions good for your health? Quarterly Journal of Economics
efforts to reduce smoking really contributed to the obesity epidemic? Economic 115, 617–650.
Inquiry 47, 366–376. Ruhm, C., 2005. Healthy living in hard times. Journal of Health Economics 24, 341–
Ogden, C., Carroll, M., Curtin, L., McDowell, M., Tabak, C., Felgal, K., 2006. Prevalence 363.
of overweight and obesity in the United States, 1999–2004. Journal of the Satia, J., Galanko, J., Siega-Riz, A., 2004. Eating at fast-food restaurants is associated
American Medical Association 295, 1549–1555. with dietary intake, demographic, psychosocial and behavioural factors among
Pew Research Center for the People and the Press, 2005. Wal-Mart a Good Place to African Americans in North Carolina. Public Health Nutrition 7, 1089–1096.
Shop But Some Critics Too. <http://people-press.org/report/265/wal-mart-a- Schaffer, M., 2005. XTIVREG2: Stata Module to Perform Extended IV/2SLS, GMM and
good-place-to-shop-but-some-critics-too>. AC/HAC, LIML and k-class Regression for Panel Data Models. <http://
Philipson, T., Posner, R., 2003. The long run growth of obesity as a function of ideas.repec.org/c/boc/bocode/s456501.html>.
technological change. Perspectives in Biology and Medicine 46, S87–S108. Sobel, R., Dean, A., 2008. Has Wal-Mart buried mom and pop? The impact of Wal-
Plantinga, A., Bernell, S., 2007. The association between urban sprawl and obesity: is Mart on self employment and small establishments in the United States.
it a two-way street? Journal of Regional Science 47, 857–879. Economic Inquiry 46, 676–695.
Ranney, C., McNamara, P., 2002. Do healthier Diets Cost More? Working Paper Strum, R., 2002. The effects of obesity, smoking, and drinking on medical problems
02-22, Department of Applied Economics and Management, Cornell and costs. Health Affairs 21, 245–253.
University. US Department of Health and Human Services, 2001. The Surgeon General’s Call to
Rashad, I., Grossman, M., Chou, S., 2006. The super size of America: an economic Action to Prevent and Decrease Overweight and Obesity.
estimation of body mass index and obesity in adults. Eastern Economic Journal Zhao, Z., Kaestner, R., 2010. Effects of Urban Sprawl on Obesity. Journal of Health
32, 133–148. Economics 29, 779–787.

Das könnte Ihnen auch gefallen