Sie sind auf Seite 1von 17

Cambridge Journal of Regions, Economy and Society 2017, 10, 231–247

doi:10.1093/cjres/rsx001
Advance Access publication 18 February, 2017

The sharing economy as the commons


of the 21st century

Karin Bradleya and Daniel Pargmanb


a
Department of Urban Planning and Environment, KTH Royal Institute of Technology,
100 44 Stockholm, Sweden, karin.bradley@abe.kth.se
b
Department of Media Technology and Interaction Design, KTH Royal Institute of
Technology, 100 44 Stockholm, Sweden, pargman@kth.se

Received on November 16, 2015; editorial decision on June 16, 2016; accepted on June 16, 2016

This article aims to make a contribution to the debate on how contemporary collabora-
tive commons, as part of the wider sharing economy, can be understood and supported.
Three cases of contemporary commons are analysed: a DIY bike repair studio, a pop-up
home office concept and Wikipedia. The article shows how the design principles developed
for governing natural resource commons are only partly applicable to these contemporary
commons. It also illustrates the differences in these types of commons in terms of the nature
of the resource being shared, scarcity, barriers to entry and how rules are formulated and
upheld.

Keywords: commons, sharing economy, collaborative economy, digital commons, design principles,
for-benefit sharing platforms
JEL Classifications: P4, O35, O33, Z10

Introduction to the precariatisation of work and further con-


centrate capital and power (Schor, 2014). There
The current dissemination and uptake of shar-
is growing criticism primarily of the effects of
ing economy platforms and services are praised
global for-profit sharing economy platforms
for allowing various under-utilised resources
when these acquire near-monopoly status in
such as homes, tools, clothes and vehicles to
their respective niches—a position from which
be used more effectively for bringing people
they can dictate the rules and conditions for
together, for encouraging the development of
millions of users, hosts or drivers, who do not
more user-centred services and for constitut-
get to share in the growing corporate profits
ing new forms of entrepreneurship (Botsman
(Gansky, 2014; Gorenflo, 2015; Taylor, 2014).
and Rogers, 2011; Gansky, 2010). Others are
However, there is conceptual confusion in
more critical and argue that sharing economy
this debate about the “sharing economy”, and
platforms such as TaskRabbit, Airbnb and
quite differing phenomena are often placed
RelayRides tend to exacerbate homophily, lead

© The Author 2017. Published by Oxford University Press on behalf of the Cambridge Political Economy Society.
This is an Open Access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution Non-Commercial License
(http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc/4.0/), which permits non-commercial re-use, distribution, and reproduction in any
medium, provided the original work is properly cited. For commercial re-use, please contact journals.permissions@oup.com
Bradley and Pargman

under this umbrella term. Sharing economy easier to create new types of commons that
platforms can be organised in different ways: as would previously either have been much more
for-profit corporations, as for-benefit organisa- complicated and costly or even practically
tions, as foundations, cooperatives, community impossible to organise (Shirky, 2008). This in
groups or through looser informal networks. turn has enabled commentators like Rifkin
Some operate on a global scale, others are (2014) and Mason (2015) to argue that we are
small and local, having different embedded- entering a postcapitalist era.
ness in place. Hence, understanding and assess- Despite grand visions of the effects of cur-
ment of sharing economy ‘performance’ may rent and future collaborative commons, in
indeed vary depending on the particular forms reality these face a number of challenges and
of the sharing economy analysed. Meelen and are often reliant on a small number of highly
Frenken (2015) define the sharing economy as engaged individuals. This and other factors
the interactions of people temporarily letting make it difficult to scale up and gain critical
other people use their under-utilised resources, mass and access to the resources necessary to
with or without monetary exchange. Services compete with mainstream market alternatives.
such as Uber or TaskRabbit thus do not qualify What factors then are crucial for understanding
as part of the sharing economy according to the dynamics of contemporary collaborative
Meelen and Frenken (2015), but should rather commons? In order to investigate this ques-
be considered part of the ‘on-demand econ- tion, here we revisit Ostrom’s (1990) institu-
omy’ or the ‘gig economy’. tional design principles for the governance of
There is a long history of studying phenom- long-enduring natural resource commons and
ena such as sharing, reciprocity, bartering and explore whether these principles are relevant
gift-giving that can be of use when studying for understanding contemporary collaborative
the sharing economy (Kolm, 2000; Mauss, 2002 commons, which are situated in a globalised,
[1924]; Polanyi, 2001 [1944]; Sahlins, 1972). For urbanised and digitalised societal context. The
example, Russell Belk has written prolifically aim of the analysis is to make a contribution to
about the practice of sharing (Belk, 2010) and the debate on how the contemporary collabo-
about the relationship between sharing and the rative commons, as part of the wider sharing
sharing economy (Belk, 2014). In order to con- economy, can be understood theoretically and
tribute to the debate on how sharing economy how they may be supported.
practices can be governed in more democratic Ostrom’s design principles are based on
and resource-efficient ways, we believe that extensive empirical studies of natural resource
theorisation and research on the governing commons situated in localised contexts and
of the commons can be of use, most notably where users are reliant on each other and on
the research by Ostrom (1990). Kostakis and these commons for their livelihood. In this arti-
Bauwens (2014) and others have previously cle, we instead analyse three different cases of
pointed out that parts of the sharing/collabo- what we will refer to as “21st century commons”:
rative economy can indeed be understood as the Bike Kitchen, Hoffice and Wikipedia. These
commons. are examples of types of commons that have
Rifkin (2014) uses the term “collaborative grown in recent years, being set in a more glo-
commons” to denote networked commons balised, urbanised and digitalised world, and
like open-source software and hardware, and representing different degrees of place specific-
argues that these commons democratise access ity, use of digital technologies and social bonds
not only to information, but also to material amongst their users. Natural resource commons
resources. The spread of digital technologies have a much longer history and will of course
and online platforms has made it considerably continue to be of crucial importance also in the

232
The sharing economy as the commons of the 21st century

21st century, but here we have opted to ana- upheld. Our contribution is hence a structured
lyse the 21st-century commons, exemplified by understanding of these differences, which can
these three cases. The first, the Bike Kitchen, is serve as a basis for future work on developing
an open non-profit Do-It-Yourself (DIY) bike more tailored support structures for contem-
repair studio that exemplifies a locally anchored porary commons. The 21st century commons
analogue form of commons, but with a set of are a vital part of the for-benefit collabora-
general principles, developed through an inter- tive sharing economy and finding ways to sup-
national network, which has made the concept port them responds to calls by Gansky (2014),
easy to copy and spread across the world. The Gorenflo (2015), Kostakis and Bauwens (2014),
Bike Kitchen can be seen as an example of a and Scholz (2016) to democratise the sharing
form of localised physical commons, often set economy.
in an urban context and similar to e.g. maker
spaces or community gardens. The second case,
Hoffice, is an open concept for arranging tem-
From natural resource commons to
porary “home offices”, i.e. a set of principles for digital commons
how to offer and transform a private kitchen During the past few decades there has been
table into a one-day shared office space for a surge of interest in the notion of the com-
community members. Hoffice is an example mons, relating the concept to contemporary
of temporary, pop-up commons, similar to the struggles over natural resources in the cases
“home restaurants” or peer-to-peer ride shar- of land grabbing and the privatisation of
ing services that have gained ground with the water resources (Ross, 2014; Shiva, 1998) and
spread of digital technologies. The third case to debates about urban and digital commons
is Wikipedia, an entirely digital commons with (Bollier and Selfrich, 2012; Walljasper, 2010).
a global reach, although it should be said that Discussions over what material and imma-
some languages are better represented than terial resources and socio-environmental
others. relations are, or should be, part of the mar-
In this article, we build a typology that can be ket system, under state control and/or self-
used as a framework for analysing 21st century governed as commons (outside the state and
commons by using the three cases described market) have historically been, and continue
above and contrasting them with Ostrom’s to be, both a central political concern and
natural resource commons (1990). The typol- the subject of heated scholarly debate (e.g.
ogy is structured around questions such as what De Angelis, 2007; Hardt and Negri, 2009;
is being shared, who can access the resource in Klein, 2001; Linebaugh, 2008; Neeson, 1993;
question and to what extent the commoners Thompson, 1991). An important milestone in
are dependent on the resource. Based on this the literature on the commons was Garrett
typology, we then comment on Ostrom’s design Hardin’s heavily cited essay “The tragedy of
principles and outline factors that are relevant the commons” (1968). Hardin proposed that
for understanding and supporting the 21st cen- for any common resource, individuals who act
tury commons. independently and rationally, e.g. according
The findings of this article illustrate how the to their self­interest, will invariably try to max-
21st century commons differ from traditional imise their own personal benefit. It is thus in
natural resource commons in several ways—in the interest of each individual (for example,
terms of the character of the resource being a herder) to overuse the common resource in
shared, in terms of what exactly is “scarce”, question (for example, grazing land). Since
barriers to entry and exit, reliance on the each individual will tend to act according to
resource, and how rules are formulated and their self-interest, this will invariably lead to

233
Bradley and Pargman

the long-term carrying capacity of the land for successful common-pool resource institu-
being exceeded and subsequently to a sub- tions (Ostrom, 1990, p. 90):
optimal outcome for the whole group and
for each individual. While acting in accord- 1. Define clear group boundaries.
ance with individual short-term self-interest, 2. Match rules governing use of common goods
that same individual (and each of their neigh- to local needs and conditions.
bours) will simultaneously act against the long 3. Ensure that those affected by the rules can
term interests of the whole group. Hardin’s participate in modifying the rules.
conclusion in relation to this dilemma was 4. Make sure the rule­ making rights of com-
that the commons should either be privatised munity members are respected by outside
into parcels of land, or ownership should be authorities.
transferred to the government, which would 5. Develop a system, implemented by com-
then bear the responsibility for regulating use munity members, for monitoring members’
of the land. behaviour.
Another milestone in the literature about 6. Use graduated sanctions for rule violators.
the commons was Ostrom’s book Governing 7. Provide accessible, low-cost means for dis-
the Commons: The Evolution of Institutions pute resolution.
for Collective Action (1990). Where Hardin’s
bleak view was based on extrapolation and David Bollier (2012, p.  212) succinctly sum-
theoretical speculations about the (mis-)use marises the difference between Hardin’s and
of the commons, Ostrom instead based her Ostrom’s perspectives on the commons: “Outer
book on extensive empirical studies of natu- space, the oceans and the Internet are com-
ral resource commons situated in localised mon-pool resources. They don’t belong to any-
contexts and where users were dependent on body individually or to any state individually.
the continued quality of their grazing lands, But they are not commons. Commons require
fisheries, forests and irrigation systems for the active participation of the people in for-
their livelihood. Ostrom drew on a number of mulating and enforcing the rules that govern
studies of communities around the world that them”. A key to understanding what constitutes
in fact had successfully managed their com- commons is hence that they include some form
mons for decades and sometimes even for of self-governing beyond the market and the
centuries. These communities had, over time, state (Bollier and Helfrich, 2012). What Hardin
developed appropriate institutions (norms discussed was not so much the commons as
and rules) for the safeguarding and manage- common-pool resources with an open-access
ment of these common-pool resources. An regime that lacks norms and rules for how to
example is Swiss villages, which have private manage and utilise the resources in question.
plots that are planted and harvested commu- With the growth of the internet and online
nal summer meadows for grazing cows. A rule communities, Ostrom’s theorisation has been
dating back to 1517 states that “no citizen may extended and discussed in relation to the digi-
send more cows to the alp than he could feed tal sphere (Benkler, 2006; de Rosnay and Le
during the winter”. Since wintering a cow is Crosnier, 2012; Hess and Ostrom, 2003; Kollock
costly, this rule effectively rations access to and Smith, 1996; Kollock, 1996; Lev-On, 2013).
the commons by tying them to private prop- Certain characteristics of digital resources dif-
erty rights in a way that averts overexploi- fer fundamentally from the real-world finite and
tation of the communal summer meadows. rival local natural resources that served as a back-
Based on her empirical research, Ostrom for- drop to Ostrom’s design principles. Intellectual
mulated the following set of design principles and digital resources can rather be regarded as

234
The sharing economy as the commons of the 21st century

infinitely reproducible and non-rival (Madison democratise access to resources, be it infor-


et  al., 2010), and internet-based information mation, tools, space or social support, i.e.
resources are global in their scope, yet unevenly making these resources more widely accessi-
distributed, as their availability is reliant on ble to people by not requiring monetary con-
access to necessary hardware, software and digi- tributions or direct exchange (Benkler, 2006;
tal literacies. Hess and Ostrom (2003) suggest Rifkin, 2014). The overall goal of these com-
that the term “subtractability” is more suitable mons is to make it easy for people to cooper-
than the term “rivalry”. The latter term implies ate and solve common problems, empowering
a more binary characteristic of the resource in and making people less dependent on cor-
question and a more antagonistic relationship porate and/or state power. This ethos differs
between commoners, while the term “subtracta- slightly from Ostrom’s (1990) analysis, which
bility” does not exclude the possibility of com- was centered around how natural resource
moners sharing the resource in question more or commons can be long-enduring in order to
less equitably. Many of the contemporary digital continue to sustain the communities that are
commons are—just like knowledge—neither dependent on them.
rival nor subtractable but to varying degrees Another difference is that many contem-
infinitely shareable. The information resources porary commons are situated in more urban
themselves can thus not be regarded as scarce, contexts—like community gardens, cultural
but there will still be a need to sustain and econ- urban spaces, maker spaces etc.—where the
omise with other types of more “ephemeral” users are not a tight-knit community that
resources such as conversational floor, attention, is reliant on the resource for their subsist-
enthusiasm, sense of commitment and responsi- ence in the same way as in Ostrom’s natural
bility to the community etc. (Pargman, 2005). It resource commons. Moreover, the growth of
should be pointed out, however, that the crea- digital platforms has also enabled coordi-
tion of infinitely shareable digital resources still nation of temporary physical “pop-up com-
requires the use of finite natural resources such mons”, i.e. resources that are privately owned
as minerals, metals, plastics for building the nec- but are temporarily transformed into a
essary hardware, as well as fossil-fuelled cooling commons, like parking places that are tem-
systems for maintaining server rooms etc (Cubitt porarily transformed into parks for a day,
et al., 2011; Hilty and Aebischer, 2015), as well ride sharing platforms turning private vehi-
as complex sociotechnical assemblages to create cles into temporary commons etc. (Bradley,
software and digital content. There is hence an 2015). Given these shifting characteristics of
indispensable subtractable sociomaterial base in contemporary commons, there is a need to
place to support the creation and dissemination develop theorisation and design principles
of endlessly shareable knowledge resources. to support them.
In the early years of the internet, Kollock
(1996) commented on Ostrom’s principles in
relation to online communities, specifically the
Three cases of contemporary
graphical virtual community WorldsAway. He commons: the Bike Kitchen, Hoffice
argued that the first principle of defining clear and Wikipedia
group boundaries is difficult to apply to the dig- In contrast to Ostrom’s natural resource com-
ital sphere, but that the third principle, i.e. that mons, here illustrated with the case of grazing
users should be able to participate in modifying land for cows, we chose three cases of what we
the rules, is relevant for online communities. call 21st century commons. These have been
The study object in this article is contem- chosen so that they illustrate commons rang-
porary commons that are driven by a will to ing from the analogue localised resource to

235
Bradley and Pargman

the urban digitally enabled commons and the help each other, thus building a spirit of collec-
entirely digital global non-rival commons. tive learning and culture of sharing of space,
Our first example of a 21st century commons tools and knowledge (Johnson, 2014). The
is the Bike Kitchen, a non-profit DIY bike Bike Kitchens also serve as recycling centers
repair studio concept. Our analysis is based for abandoned bikes. Citizens, the police, hous-
on four interviews with initiators and users at ing associations or local businesses donate old
the Bike Kitchens in Malmö and Gothenburg bikes or spare parts which people can use free
during 2014 and 2015 and on-site observations of charge.
on three occasions. These Bike Kitchens are Bike Kitchens are run on a non-profit basis,
part of a larger international network of bicy- generally by volunteers, and focus on spreading
cle kitchens, or community bike repair shops/ bike repair skills to citizens. A central idea of the
bicycle collectives. Bike Kitchens appeared in Bike Kitchen is that it is accessible and welcom-
the late 1990s in Europe as well as in California, ing to all, particularly people with little finan-
and have since spread across the world, and cial means (Johnson, 2014; Luna, 2012). The
can now be found in cities as Buenos Aires, Malmö Bike Kitchen is managed by volunteers
Toronto, Tasmania, Minsk, Madrid, Dortmund and a couple of part-time paid workers funded
etc.1 The initiators of the Malmö Bike Kitchen, by a non-profit foundation. The Gothenburg
which was the first in Sweden when it opened in Bike Kitchen is entirely run by volunteers,
2011, were inspired by the Los Angeles Bicycle who alternate responsibility for managing the
Kitchen, and Malmö has since become a source facility every month. The Bike Kitchens in
of inspiration for other Swedish cities wishing Gothenburg and Malmö are managed as mem-
to open their own Bike Kitchens. bership organisations, but they charge a very
The Bike Kitchen is an open DIY repair low annual fee of 5 and 10 Euros respectively,
workshop, where anyone can come to fix their per year. Non-members may use the facilities as
bike or build a bike from recycled spare parts. well, but are encouraged to become members
Tools are available, as are volunteers that can if they make frequent use of the facilities. The
help, but the idea is that ordinary users should Gothenburg Bike Kitchen receives funding for

Figure 1.  The outdoor premises of the Malmö Bike Kitchen. Photo by Karin Bradley.

236
The sharing economy as the commons of the 21st century

its premises and is run in cooperation with an joining the Hoffice Facebook group can offer
educational non-profit foundation.2 The Malmö up their kitchen table as a gift in the shape of
Bike Kitchen (Figure  1) has received funding a free “pop-up” temporary office (commons)
from a non-profit foundation and some limited for a day (by providing information about the
financial support from the municipality.3 The number of available seats, address etc.). Other
idea is to keep rules simple and easily readable Hoffice members can then book a seat in that
on walls at the sites: this is a DIY repair/build temporary office-for-a-day. While Hoffice was
workspace, give help to others and feel free to restricted to purely being a Stockholm phe-
borrow tools and use spare parts. nomenon during 2014, the simple structure and
The Bike Kitchen is an open concept ease of replication, combined with increased
that can be copied and taken up by anyone. media coverage, led to an explosive spread in
Experiences from managing bike kitchens the concept during 2015. There are currently
and tips for people who want to set up a new Hoffice groups on five different continents,
one are exchanged via forums such as the and in 50 European cities. Hoffice events are
Bike Collectives Network, regional network- easily set up and coordinated with the help of
ing projects (Cykelköket, 2013), online articles low-cost digital technologies—each Hoffice
(Johnson, 2014) and Wikis.4 The Bike Kitchen group is currently organised through a separate
serves here as an example of a localised physi- Facebook group.
cal commons, often situated in urban areas, but Hoffice is more than a scheme for efficient
formulated as a concept with certain principles use of under-utilised “office spaces”, however.
(not-for-profit, DIY, reuse, sharing of spaces, It was founded with inspiration from Gandhian
tools and skills, volunteer-run, community thought, Buddhist philosophy, the secular Sri
building around bike transportation), which Lankan Sarvodaya6 movement’s ideas about
can be adapted to fit local circumstances, access gift economies and more modern ideas about
to spaces and funding. Thus it bears a resem- “collective intelligence” (Lévy, 1997). Offering
blance to other physical commons like maker up one’s home as a temporary workspace for
spaces, tool libraries or community gardens. others can be seen as a pure gift; the host can-
Our second example is Hoffice, an open con- not expect to get anything back except friend-
cept for arranging temporary “home offices”, ship and company. Correspondingly, the guest
i.e. a set of principles for transforming a pri- cannot set any particular demands on the host
vate kitchen table into a one-day shared office or the workspace. A number of principles pro-
space.5 Hoffice was started in 2014 by a small vide a structure for organising the day, in order
group of Stockholm-based friends who were to ensure that a sizable amount of work is per-
self-employed social entrepreneurs and who formed at a Hoffice event while still providing
both enjoyed and suffered from the fact that an appealing and supportive social environ-
their work lives were characterised by much ment. Work shifts (usually 45 minutes of man-
freedom and little structure. While loving dated silence) are followed by 5–10 minutes
their work, many social entrepreneurs who of recuperation and a social/physical exercise
work from home or a coffee shop miss out (stretching, dancing, breathing exercise, cof-
on important aspects of work life, e.g. lack of fee break etc.). Work shifts are also preceded
workmates, lack of a separate workspace and, by participants stating what they will work on
not least, a lack of self-discipline. Hoffice aims and are followed up by reporting back on work
to solve these problems by creating shared performed. This constitutes a pledge of sorts
values out of under-utilised resources, most and the group can thus also provide social
notably someone’s kitchen table, thereby creat- and emotional support, as well as a structure
ing a type of commons out of thin air. Anyone to ensure that the time is used productively.

237
Bradley and Pargman

The possibility to meet new people and extend more than 12.5 billion page views per month.
personal networks is attractive to many par- There are currently official Wikipedias in 290
ticipants (not least to self-employed freelanc- different languages and while the majority of
ers and social entrepreneurs). There is much these are relatively limited (e.g. containing
experimentation going on with the Hoffice 10,000 or fewer articles), together they contain
format itself (outdoor meetings, meetings on more than 35 million articles.7 There are twelve
a boat or with specific themes, e.g. web devel- different languages with more than one million
opment, creative writing etc.). The analysis articles each.
of Hoffice in this article is based on having One of the greatest strengths and weak-
attended Hoffice meetings in Stockholm dur- nesses of Wikipedia is that anyone can
ing 2014 and 2015 (Figure  2), hosting a few become an editor,8 and there are currently
Hoffice events and holding lengthy conversa- more than 70,000 contributors who regu-
tions with the founder of the Hoffice concept larly edit Wikipedia. With such a large editor
in 2014. base, there are also a number of higher levels
Hoffice serves here as an example of tem- of authority, e.g. “editors in good standing”
porary, pop-up commons, similarly to the “res- who have more privileges than ordinary edi-
taurants at home” or peer-to-peer ride sharing tors, “administrators” who can delete articles
concepts, where a private space is temporarily or edit protected articles, “bureaucrats” who
turned into a commons, a process which has can add or remove administrative rights, an
become more easy to organise with the spread “Arbitration Committee” that deals with con-
of digital technologies. flicts and “stewards” with complete access to
The third example is Wikipedia, serving as an the wiki and the ability to change all other
example of an entirely digital commons with a users’ rights. A  2008 article (Butler et  al.,
global reach. The basic service that Wikipedia 2008) that examines and compares different
provides is well known; it is the largest and perspectives on the role of policies and rules
most popular encyclopaedia in the world, with in Wikipedia bears the telling name “Don’t

Figure 2.  A Hoffice in Stockholm, 2016. Photo by Daniel Pargman.

238
The sharing economy as the commons of the 21st century

look now, but we’ve created a bureaucracy”. Towards a typology of commons


While Wikipedia strives to be egalitarian,
What are then the similarities and differences
open and transparent (and of course above
between Ostrom’s natural resource commons,
all to present correct information in its arti-
e.g. grazing land, and the three cases of 21st
cles), the sheer size of the project is a chal-
century commons described above? In Table 1,
lenge to the governance structure and there
we present a typology that characterises these
is thus “continuing experimentation with different types of commons by responding to
approaches to community-self-regulation” questions in terms of the nature of the com-
(Bruns, 2008, p.  140). Some argue that “ad mon resource and how it is being managed and
hoc meritocracies” like Wikipedia “are at risk governed.
of transforming themselves into more inflex- The first question concerns what resource
ible hierarchies” (Kostakis, 2010). Others is being shared. This varies from grazing land,
propose that it is more or less inevitable that i.e. a subtractable natural resource, to shared
peer production projects such as Wikipedia premises, tools, spare parts and skills in the case
will become increasingly oligarchic as they of the Bike Kitchen and a temporary work-
grow (Shaw and Hill, 2014). Our analysis of space in the case of Hoffice, i.e. a kitchen table
Wikipedia is based on several years of fre- in somebody’s home and the social structures
quent use and of occasionally editing arti- and atmosphere created around co-working.
cles, but primarily on published research on The latter two include human-made physi-
Wikipedia, e.g. the above-mentioned sources. cal resources and human-made non-physical
Our three cases of 21st century commons resources such as skills and social support.
can be interpreted as representing different In the case of Wikipedia, the resource being
categories of commons: a localised physical shared is information, i.e. a human-made, non-
urban commons that is part of a wider inter- physical and infinitely sharable resource. All
national network, a temporary pop-up com- the resources being shared have, however, been
mons enabled by digital technologies, and built up by innumerable hours of work, inter-
an entirely digital and global commons. The personal relations and trust-building, together
initiators of The Bike Kitchen and Hoffice with the physical resources needed to enable
have not themselves theorised these enti- the commons, such as the metals and hardware
ties as commons, whereas Wikipedia is often of the computers used to build Wikipedia, the
referred to as an example of a digital com- materiality of the tools and physical space of
mons (Bollier, 2007). Given their fundamen- the Bike Kitchen and the rent-paying and
tal differences, our ambition is not to develop home-making of the Hoffice events.
design principles that could be relevant for The second question deals with who can
all of these (and other) cases, but rather to access the resource and barriers to entry and
use these cases to deepen understanding of exit for accessing the resource in question. In
the diverse nature and organisational struc- the case of the grazing land, local villagers and
ture of contemporary commons. We do this their cows can access the resource. The barriers
through constructing a typology of the differ- to entry are intentionally kept high, i.e. users
ent commons (Table  1) and comparing them need to become part of the community, which
against Ostrom’s design principles (Table  2). traditionally would be through kinship. Barriers
Our article can thus serve as a basis for future to exit are also high as opportunities for leav-
work on developing support structures for ing the community and creating a new life else-
contemporary commons, as part of the wider where could be limited. The Bike Kitchen is very
sharing economy. different, as anyone can access the resources in

239
240
Table 1.  Typology of commons ranging from natural resources to entirely digital resources
Bradley and Pargman

Grazing land (Ostrom) Bike kitchen Hoffice Wikipedia

1. What resource Natural resource Shared premises, tools, spare Temporary co-working Information
parts and skills space, i.e. physical and social
space
2. Who can access Community Anyone Group access Anyone
(barriers to entry/exit) (high barriers to entry/low (easy entry, keep from exit) (easy entry, easy exit) (unnoticeable entry/exit)
to exit)
3. Degree of subtractability High Low for physical resources; High for seats but low for Non-existent or negative,
negative for collaborative number of events
learning
4. Dependence on the High Low but varying Medium but varying Medium but varying
resource
5. What rules No more grazing cows in DIY and helping others Abide by Hoffice/host local Open to all, but requiring
summer than can be kept in rules digital access
winter
6. Control of compliance Monitoring system, graduated Informal social control Informal social control Norms, rules and sophisticated
with rules sanctions, means for dispute software tools
resolution
7. Who sets or changes the The local community Open concept with general Part of an umbrella concept, Board of the Wikimedia
rules for governing? members principles, local initiators or but hosts decide local rules Foundation
volunteers decide local rules
The sharing economy as the commons of the 21st century

Table 2.  Applicability of Ostrom’s design principles to the 21st century commons


Ostrom’s design principles for natural resource Applicability to our three cases of 21st century commons
commons

1. Define clear group boundaries Not particularly relevant, more important to keep barriers to entry low
2. Match rules governing use of common goods Relevant for the Bike Kitchen and Hoffice, but not very relevant for
to local needs and conditions Wikipedia
3. Ensure that those affected by the rules can Relevant for the Bike Kitchen and Hoffice, but less relevant for
participate in modifying the rules Wikipedia given the distance between ordinary users, different levels of
editors and the board
4. M
 ake sure the rule­making rights of community Currently unproblematic and taken for granted for the Bike Kitchen,
members are respected by outside authorities Hoffice and Wikipedia
5. Develop a system, implemented by community Not (yet) relevant for the Bike Kitchen and Hoffice. Relevant for
members, for monitoring members’ behaviour Wikipedia editors, but not users
6. Use graduated sanctions for rule violators Not (yet) relevant for the Bike Kitchen and Hoffice, perhaps relevant for
Wikipedia editors
7. Provide accessible, low­cost means for dispute Not (yet) relevant for the Bike Kitchen and Hoffice. Relevant for
resolution Wikipedia editors

question: locals and visitors, members and non- and for each cow that grazes the land, there will
members. The barriers to entry are designed to be a little less left for the next cow. The com-
be low, since the whole idea of the Bike Kitchen mon resources of The Bike Kitchen are less
is based on disseminating know-how and tools subtractable. Spare parts are indeed highly sub-
for bicycling widely. The barriers to exit are tractable, but the shared space and the tools
higher, however, as users are actively encour- will not diminish with others’ use. The social
aged to return, but also to become members resources in terms of skills sharing and col-
and/or volunteers, since the common resource laborative learning are, however, “negatively
is highly reliant on people contributing to main- subtractable”, as they constitute resources that
taining it. Hoffice is restricted to group access increase in value when many users are present at
(membership in a Facebook group) and users the same time. At some point, the space and the
need to book one of the limited number of tools can become less valuable if too many want
available seats at any specific Hoffice event. to use them simultaneously, creating crowding
The number of events and seats can easily be and waiting. It is then however possible to cre-
multiplied, however, as anyone is free to host a ate another Bike Kitchen, although this requires
Hoffice event around their own kitchen table. considerable physical and social resources.
The barriers to entry and exit are intention- Hoffice has both a high and low degree of
ally kept low, as users can easily host or join a subtractability; there is a limited number of seats
Hoffice event, but can also easily exit—there is available at each event, but new Hoffice events
no membership or commitment to be a repeat can easily be created out of innumerable small or
user or host. In the case of Wikipedia, any- large homes without the corresponding invest-
one with internet access can freely access the ments needed to create a more permanent com-
resource, and entry and exit is frictionless (oth- mon resource like a Bike Kitchen. It should be
ers do not notice a user’s entry and exit). noted that a potential bottleneck (“resource”)
The third question concerns degree of sub- is having the key individuals necessary to create
tractability. Grazing land is highly subtractable and maintain these commons, e.g. Hoffice hosts

241
Bradley and Pargman

and Bike Kitchen initiators and volunteers. The summer meadows as they can keep indoors dur-
creation of these types of human-made resources ing the winter. Being a DIY repair studio, the
partly differ from natural resources like grazing basic rule of the Bike Kitchen is that users can
land, which self-reproduces with enough time, borrow tools to work on a bike but are expected
sun and rain. It should however be noted that to help others when present. There are also
the longevity of many natural resources require other implicit rules, like putting the tools back
human caretakers as well; grazing land might be in order, leaving when the space closes etc. If
overgrown if no humans see that cattle graze it. a user becomes a volunteer, they also need to
For a digital resource like Wikipedia, the sub- follow a schedule and do certain tasks, such as
tractability is non-existent or even negative; maintaining the spaces in order, opening and
the resource does not diminish with more users, closing the space. Users at a Hoffice event need
but rather increases in value (Hess and Ostrom, to follow the working rules (45-minute silent
2005). Specific knowledge increases in value work shifts etc.) as well as the host’s local rules
the more widely it is circulated. The more peo- on how the space may be used (as a guest in
ple that use Wikipedia, the higher the chances their home). Wikipedia has no rules set up for
that some users will become editors. With more usage, but has a set of (over time progressively
editors, the knowledge resource expands and, at more specific) guidelines and rules for editors
least in theory, improves. However, it should be on how to make or edit an entry (many formal-
acknowledged that there are also problems with ised in the Wikipedia Manual of Style9), how
the open collaborative production (errors, poor to provide sources, how to write from a neutral
editing, vandalism, disputes etc.), and therefore point of view etc.
various structures have been set up to handle The sixth question concerns the control
such problems (version and revision controls, of rules being followed. In Ostrom’s natu-
internal discussion forums, dispute resolution ral resource commons, the design principles
processes etc.). include a system of monitoring that is car-
The fourth question deals with the degree to ried out by the community members, gradu-
which the users are dependent on the resource. ated sanctions for rule violations and low-cost
In the case of grazing land, the commoners are means for dispute resolution. In the cases of the
highly dependent on the resource for their sub- Bike Kitchen and Hoffice, the rules are upheld
sistence. In the case of the Bike Kitchen, the through informal social control and anyone
users are less dependent on the resource. For who does not follow the rules is instructed by
some it can be socially important and/or for oth- others, but there are currently no sanctions for
ers a way of serving transportation needs in a rule violators (see further below). In the case of
low-cost way. The dependence on Hoffice varies. Wikipedia there is no need to control ordinary
It can perform an important role for some regu- users, but there are norms and rules for editors
lar users as a way of getting work done in a much and for discussion forums, and sophisticated
more socially agreeable and effective manner. software tools to keep track of changes.
For others it can simply be more of a fun expe- The seventh and last question concerns who
rience. The dependence on Wikipedia varies sets and changes the rules for governing the
between users. Some use it every day in their job resource. For grazing land, it is the community
or education and others use it occasionally, but members of the village who set and change
few are entirely reliant on it for their subsistence. the rules collectively. A  core principle of suc-
The fifth question concerns the rules for using cessfully governing common-pool resources
the resource. In the example of grazing land, is that those affected by the rules are part of
the core rule is that the commoners are only the decision-making process. In the case of the
allowed to have as many cows grazing on the Bike Kitchen, the specific local rules are set and

242
The sharing economy as the commons of the 21st century

changed by the initiators/key individuals or by barriers to entry are hence made low and new-
volunteers. However, the general principles of comers are welcome and encouraged to join
Bike Kitchens, i.e. being non-profit, built on and to contribute at various levels. A  crucial
DIY and collaborative learning, are not rules factor is how to recruit and motivate enough
but rather a tradition and an international con- people to create and maintain the resource in
text in which the specific local Bike Kitchen question. The 21st century commons also have
operates. In a similar way, Hoffice has general intentionally low barriers to entry because of
principles that can be modified and adapted their low (or even negative) subtractability.
to local conditions by the host. The rules for Another important challenge is therefore to
Wikipedia are set, and changed, by the board of “convert” at least some of the users into active
its governing body, the Wikimedia Foundation. contributors (hosts, volunteers, editors etc.).
Taken together, it is clear that the charac- Unlike Ostrom’s natural resource commons,
teristics and rules of these commons differ in contributing to our cases of 21st century com-
several respects, implying that Ostrom’s set of mons means less of a life-long commitment.
design principles for successful common-pool However, a certain degree of commitment is
resource institutions needs to be rethought and necessary for a facility to work; for example,
adapted with these differences in mind. in the case of the Bike Kitchen, if volunteers
do not keep their commitment to open up the
facility according to a schedule, the resource
Design principles of 21st century will deteriorate. It is therefore important that
commons? there are welcoming, simple and clear contribu-
We return here to Ostrom’s (1990) design prin- tor interfaces for volunteers, hosts and editors.
ciples and discuss how they relate to our three The digital interfaces of Wikipedia and Hoffice
cases of 21st century commons. One important play an important role in this, whereas the spe-
difference between natural resource commons cific local volunteer Bike Kitchen system needs
and 21st century commons is that the latter often to be simple to join and attractive enough to
have two distinct groups of members; contribu- encourage users to remain. An important fac-
tors (or “managers”, e.g. volunteers, hosts, edi- tor for disseminating a concept is that it is
tors) and ordinary users (guests, visitors). In the clearly communicated and easy to replicate and
case of natural resource commons, it is instead adapted to local conditions. This is the case for
often the case that users (members) also man- Hoffice and Wikipedia, e.g. the process of start-
age and monitor the commons and vice versa. ing a Wikipedia in a new language.
In Table 2, Ostrom’s seven principles are com- The three 21st century commons we describe
mented upon. It can be seen that some of them here are all mission driven but were founded on
are not directly applicable to our cases and that three different ideas: to democratise access to
other principles apply to managers, but not to low-cost bicycling and repair, to use under-uti-
ordinary users. It would be desirable to develop lised assets while simultaneously building a cul-
modified sets of design principles for successful ture of trust and generosity, and to democratise
21st century institutions, but here we can only access to information beyond the money-based
contribute reflections on factors relevant to economy. In line with Benkler’s (2006) analysis
consider when formulating such principles. of commons-based peer production in the digi-
The commons are all reliant on human care- tal sphere, these three contemporary collabora-
takers, however, the 21st century commons tive commons can be viewed as embodying a
analysed here are particularly dependent on postcapitalist ethic, i.e. the resources in question
key persons—initiators, hosts and contributors. are produced for use, rather than for exchange
In the three cases of 21st century commons, the value, are produced by peers, rather than in

243
Bradley and Pargman

hierarchical command structures, and are based participants took the lessons to heart and
on an ethic of sharing and common ownership, developed new BBS systems “…with perhaps
rather than competition and private property. less visionary character but [that] allowed mon-
In Ostrom’s examples of natural resource itoring and disconnection of “troublesome”
commons, the commoners are invariably highly participants” (Stone, 1995, p. 117).
reliant on the resource in question for their More mature commons such as Wikipedia
subsistence and their very livelihood, whereas and long-enduring natural resource commons
the contributors and users of the 21st century (where whole livelihoods are at stake) will
commons are not nearly as dependent on these have successfully survived series of disrup-
commons. The 21st century commoners are not tions and crises and will to a higher extent be
forced to get along with each other no matter characterised by rules that include an “...or else”
what and people who do not like the way that statement, e.g. that specifies punishments for
Hoffice, the Bike Kitchen or Wikipedia is gov- rule-breakers (Conway, 2014). Anthropologist
erned will find that it relatively easy to simply Victor Turner argues that the relations between
leave, rather than to conform or struggle to members in spontaneous counter-movements
change the rules (Hirschman, 1970). (“communitas”) “can seldom be maintained
It is notable (see Table  2) that neither the for very long. […] and it is the fate of all spon-
Bike Kitchen nor Hoffice—unlike Wikipedia taneous communitas in history to undergo
and Ostrom’s natural resource commons—have what most people see as a ‘decline and fall’ into
systems for monitoring members’ behaviour, structure and law” (Turner, 1996 [1969], p. 132).
graduated sanctions for rule violators or low- While idealism and a sense of community is
cost means for dispute resolution. One explana- essential to the development of new commons,
tion is that these organisations are still “young” the true success of such human-made resource
commons that have not yet encountered many commons may only be proven after they have
crises. They are also still relatively small, there been in existence for some time and have sur-
is a high degree of trust between members vived and evolved beyond the goodwill that
and they are to a high extent still governed by often fuels the initial enthusiasm. Both natural
benevolent norms that dictate suitable behav- and human-made resource commons can be
iour and assume well-behaved participants. It degraded and a balance must be found over
may be the case that these commons efforts time that weighs the positive and spontane-
experience future crises from which they will ous forces that create or renew the resources
evolve or to which they will succumb. Stone in question against the need to protect these
(1995) tells the story of CommuniTree, the first resources from abuse.
(1978) online bulletin board system (BBS) that
aimed to foster (technical) discussions but also
to create an online community. An idealistic
Conclusions
ethos that assumed the best of each participant This article shows that contemporary com-
was an intrinsic part of the very software code mons, situated in a globalised, urbanised and
at the heart of the system. Unfortunately, this digitalised context, differ from traditional natu-
made it impossible to reprogramme (“defend”) ral resource commons in several ways: in terms
the system a few years later, when high school of the character of the resource being shared,
students started to use new school comput- what exactly is ‘scarce’, barriers to entry and
ers and modems to connect to, sabotage and exit, reliance on the resource and how rules are
desecrate CommuniTree. After a few months formulated and upheld.
of being assaulted by “the barbarian hordes”, Some of Ostrom’s design principles for long-
CommuniTree was closed down, but some enduring governance of commons are still

244
The sharing economy as the commons of the 21st century

relevant, for example, ensuring that the rules not only growth of the myriad of decentralised
that govern use of the commons are matched collaborative commons such as community
with local needs and conditions and that com- gardens, Bike Kitchens, local food coopera-
moners affected by the rules can participate in tives, Time Banks, etc., but also more general
modifying them. However, in these localised and structures that can enable for-benefit collabo-
well-demarcated commons, commoners have rative economies to scale up and seriously
dual roles; they both benefit from and uphold compete with the mainstream market alterna-
(care, manage, monitor) the commons. In con- tives. Wikipedia is in fact one such example of a
trast, with the 21st century commons analysed for-benefit centralised commons that has gone
here, there is a (sometimes relatively stark) dif- from the margins to the mainstream. However,
ference between ordinary “users” and contribu- much needs to happen before a contemporary
tors (volunteers, editors, hosts) who are essential commons like the Bike Kitchen becomes a
for building and taking care of the human-made standard option for fixing users’ main means of
commons. In the latter commons, it is primarily transportation. However, a first step in devel-
human engagement that constitutes the scarce oping scalable for-benefit collaborative struc-
resource and that needs to be cultivated and tures is to understand the characteristics of the
cared for. Therefore it is important to have clear diverse commons they are built upon, which is
contributor-interfaces and simple systems that where our contribution lies.
potential contributors can plug into, yet that
are also possible to adjust, making contributors End Notes
want to continue to develop the collaborative
work. However, in order for a commons regime 1
http://www.bikecollectives.org/wiki/index.
to survive crises and recruit new users and con- php?title=Community_Bicycle_Organisations
tributors, it is important that the commoners [Accessed 11 November 2015].
are closely attached to the commons, that the 2
h tt p : / / w w w. cy ke l ko ke t . o rg / o m cy ke l ko ke t /
commons is not simply a hobby but somehow omcykelkoket.html [Accessed 9 November 2015].
becomes part of the commoners’ lives, or per- 3
The Bike Kitchen has had 3-year project funding
haps even their livelihoods. This feeds into the from Allmänna Arvsfonden, a Swedish foundation
ongoing debate about the future of the shar- gathering the inheritances from people without close
ing economy, with Scholz (2016) and Gorenflo relatives, and set-period financial support from the
(2015) calling for the development of “plat- City of Malmö, which ended in 2015.
form co-operativism”, where sharing platforms 4
See The Bike Collectives website http://www.bike-
are turned into cooperative structures where collectives.org/ and their Wiki http://www.bikecollec-
the former platform ‘users’ also become own- tives.org/wiki/index.php?title=Main_Page [Accessed
ers and decision-makers and gain parts of their 11 November 2015].
livelihood from the platform. This is a reaction 5
http://hoffice.nu/en/ [Accessed 11 November 2015].
against the global contemporary for-profit shar- See http://www.sarvodaya.org/about [Accessed 11
6

ing economy platforms, which build on peer-to- November 2015].


peer production and sharing of resources, whilst 7
See https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Wikipedia:About
the expansion of the platforms primarily benefit [Accessed 11 November 2015].
the corporate shareholders, and to little extent 8
See https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Wikipedia:
the millions of users who in fact “build” the con- A b o u t # S t r e n g t h s. 2 C _ w e a k n e s s e s. 2 C _ a n d _
tent of the platform. article_quality_in_Wikipedia [Accessed 11
Bauwens (2014) has argued for the impor- November 20 15].
tance of development of semi-centralised for- 9
See https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Wikipedia:
benefit forms of collaborative economy, i.e. Manual_of_Style [Accessed 2 November 2015].

245
Bradley and Pargman

Acknowledgements Conway, R. T. (2014) Ideas for change: Making mean-


ing out of economic and institutional diversity. In
The research conducted for this article is part of the D. Bollier and S. Helfrich (eds.) The Wealth of the
project Urban Sharing—The rise of collaborative Commons: A  World Beyond Market and State.
consumption and co-use of spaces, funded by the Amherst, MA: The Commons Strategies Group.
Swedish Research Council Formas, grant number Cubitt, S., Hassan, R., and Volkmer, I. (2011) Does
2012–641. We are thankful for valuable comments cloud computing have a silver lining?, Media,
from two anonymous reviewers as well as the Editors. Culture and Society, 33: 149–158.
Cykelköket (2013) Den enes skrot…” – En inspiration-
sskrift om Cykelköket i Malmö. Malmö: Holmbergs.
Gansky, L. (2010) The Mesh: Why the Future of
References Business is Sharing. New York: Penguin.
Bauwens, M. (2014) “Four Scenarios for the Gansky, L. (2014) Collaborative economy companies
Collaborative Economy”, lecture at OuiShare need to start sharing more value with the people
Fest 2014. https://www.youtube.com/ who make them valuable, FastCoExist, December
watch?v=mgtGCZgTiqc [Accessed 4 May 2015]. 4, 2014. http://www.fastcoexist.com/3038476/
Belk, R. (2010) Sharing, Journal of Consumer collaborative-economy-companies-need-to-
Research, 36: 715–734. start-sharing-more-value-with-the-people-who-
Belk, R. (2014) You are what you can access: sharing make-th [Accessed 2 November 2015].
and collaborative consumption online, Journal of Hardt, M. and Negri, A. (2009) Commonwealth.
Business Research, 67: 1595–1600. Cambridge, MA: Belknap Press of Harvard
Benkler, Y. (2006) The Wealth of Networks: How Social University Press.
Production Transforms Markets and Freedom. New Klein, N. (2001) Reclaiming the commons, New Left
Haven/London: Yale University Press. Review May–June, 81–89
Bollier, D. (2005) The growth of the commons para- Kolm, S.-C. (2000) Introduction: the economics of
digm. In C. Hess and E. Ostrom (eds.) Understanding reciprocity, giving and altruism. In L. A. Gérard-
Knowledge as a Commons: from Theory to Practice. Varet, S-C. Kolm, and J. M. Ythier (eds.) The
Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. pp. 27–40. Economics of Reciprocity, Giving and Altruism.
Bollier, D. and Helfrich, S. (eds.) (2012) The Wealth of Basingstoke: Macmillan Press.
the Commons: A World Beyond Market and State. Gorenflo, N. (2015) How platform coops can beat
Amherst, MA: The Commons Strategies Group. death stars like Uber to create a real sharing econ-
Bollier, D. (2014) Global enclosures in the service omy. Shareable, November 3, 2015. http://www.
of empire. In D. Bollier and S. Helfrich (eds.) The shareable.net/blog/how-platform-coops-can-beat-
Wealth of the Commons: A World Beyond Market death-stars-like-uber-to-create-a-real-sharing-
and State. Amherst, MA: The Commons Strategies economy [Accessed 7 November 2015].
Group. Hardin, G. (1968) The tragedy of the commons,
De Angelis, M. (2007) The Beginning of History: Science, 162: 1243–1248.
Value Struggles and Global Capital. London: Hess, C. and Ostrom, E. (2003) Ideas, artifacts, and
Pluto. facilities: information as a common-pool resource.
Botsman, R. and Rogers, R. (2011) What’s Mine Law and Contemporary Problems, 111–145.
is Yours: How Collaborative Consumption is Hess, C. and Ostrom, E. (eds.) (2005) Understanding
Changing The Way We Live. London: Collins. Knowledge as a Commons: from Theory to
Bradley, K. (2015) Open-source urbanism: creat- Practice. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
ing, multiplying and managing urban commons, Hilty, L. M. and Aebischer, B. (2015) ICT for sus-
Footprint Delft Architecture Theory Journal, 16: tainability: an emerging research field. In L. M.
91–108. Hilty and B. Aebischer (eds.) ICT Innovations for
Bruns, A. (2008) Blogs, Wikipedia, Second Life, and Sustainability (pp. 3–36). Springer International
beyond: From Production to Produsage. New Publishing.
York: Peter Lang. Hirschman, A. (1970) Exit, Voice, and Loyalty:
Butler, B., Joyce, E., and Pike, J. (2008) Don’t look Responses to Decline in Firms, Organizations, and
now, but we’ve created a bureaucracy: the nature States. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
and roles of policies and rules in Wikipedia. In Johnson, C. (2014) How to Start a Bike Kitchen.
Proceedings of the SIGCHI conference on human Shareable, November 18, 2014. http://www.
factors in computing systems, pp. 1101–1110. shareable.net/blog/how-to-start-a-bike-kitchen
ACM. [Accessed 4 January 2015].

246
The sharing economy as the commons of the 21st century

Kollock, P. (1996) Design Principles for Online (eds.) Proceedings of the Second International
Communities., Harvard Conference on the Conference on Communities and Technologies.
Internet and Society. http://mysite.du.edu/~lavita/ Dordrecht: Springer.
edpx_3770_13s/_docs/kollock_design_%20princ_ Polanyi, K. (2001) The Great Transformation: The
for_online_comm%20copy.pdf [Accessed 10 Political and Economic Origins of Our Time, 2nd
November 2015]. ed. Boston, MA: Beacon Press.
Kollock, P. and Smith, M. (1996) Managing the vir- Rifkin, J. (2014) The Zero Marginal Cost Society: The
tual commons. In S. C. Herring (ed.) Computer- Internet of Things, the Collaborative Commons,
mediated Communication: Linguistic, Social, and And The Eclipse of Capitalism. New York:
Cross-Cultural Perspectives. Amsterdam: John Palgrave Macmillan.
Benjamins. de Rosnay, M. D. and Le Crosnier, H. (2012) An intro-
Kostakis, V. and Bauwens, M. (2014) Network Society duction to the digital commons: From common-
and Future Scenarios for a Collaborative Economy. pool resources to community governance. In T.
Basingstoke: Palgrave Pivot. Dedeurwaerdere, (ed.). Building Institutions for
Kostakis, V. (2010) Identifying and understanding the Sustainable Scientific, Cultural and Genetic Resources
problems of Wikipedia’s governance: The case of Commons. Louvain-la-Neuve: International
inclusionists versus deletionists, First Monday, 15. Association for the Study of the Commons. https://
http://journals.uic.edu/ojs/index.php/fm/article/ halshs.archives-ouvertes.fr/halshs-00736920/docu-
view/2613/2479 [Accessed 26 January 2017]. ment [Accessed 26 January 2017].
Lev-On, A. (2013) Communities, crowds and focal Ross, A. R. (ed.) (2014) Grabbing Back: Essays Against
sites: Fine-tuning the theoretical grounding of the Global Land Grab. Edinburgh: AK Press.
cooperation online, The Journal of Community Sahlins, M. (1972) Stone Age Economics. New York:
Informatics, 9(3), ci-journal.net/index.php/ciej/ Aldine de Gruyter.
article/view/712/1020 [Accessed 26 January 2017]. Scholz, T. (2016) Platform Cooperativism:
Lévy, P. (1997) Collective Intelligence: Mankind’s Challenging the Corporate Sharing Economy.
Emerging World in Cyberspace. New York: New York: Rosa Luxemburg Stiftung. http://www.
Plenum Trade. rosalux-nyc.org/wp-content/files_mf/scholz_plat-
Linebaugh, P. (2008) The Magna Carta Manifesto: formcooperativism21.pdf [Accessed 12 July 2016].
The Struggle to Reclaim Liberties and Commons Schor, J. (2014) Debating the sharing economy.
for All. Berkeley, CA: University of California Essay published by the Great Transition Initiative,
Press. Tellus Institute. http://greattransition.org/publica-
Luna, M. (2012) Biketopia Exists! Shareable. tion/debating-the-sharing-economy [Accessed 30
February 14, 2012. http://www.shareable.net/blog/ March 2015].
biketopia-exists [Accessed 4 January 2016]. Shaw, A. and Hill, B. M. (2014) Laboratories of oli-
Madison, M. J., Frischmann, B. M., and Strandburg, garchy? How the iron law extends to peer produc-
K. J. (2010) Constructing commons in the cultural tion, Journal of Communication, 64: 215–238.
environment, Cornell Law Review, 95: 657. Shirky, C. (2008) Here Comes Everybody: The Power
Mason, P. (2015) PostCapitalism: A  Guide to Our of Organizing Without Organizations. New York:
Future. London: Allen Lane. Penguin.
Mauss, M. (2002) The Gift: Forms and Functions of Shiva, V. (1998) Biopiracy: The Plunder of Nature
Exchange in Archaic Societies. London: Routledge. and Knowledge. Totnes: Green Books/The Gaia
Meelen, T. and Frenken, K. (2015) “Stop saying Uber Foundation.
is part of the sharing economy”, Fast Company, 14 Stone, A. R. (1996) The War of Desire and Technology
January 2015. http://www.fastcoexist.com/3040863/ at the Close of the Mechanical Age. Cambridge,
stop-saying-uber-is-part-of-the-sharing-economy MA: MIT press.
[Accessed 15 May 2015] Taylor, A. (2014) The People’s Platform: Taking Back
Neeson, J. M (1993) Commoners: Common Right, Power and Culture in the Digital Age. New York:
Enclosure and Social Change in England 1700– Metropolitan Books.
1820. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Thompson, E. P. (1991) Customs in Common.
Ostrom, E. (1990) Governing the Commons: The London: Merlin.
Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action. Turner, V. (1995) The Ritual Process: Structure and
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Anti-structure. New York: Aldine de Gruyter.
Pargman, D. (2005) Virtual community manage- Walljasper, J. (2010) All That We Share – A  Field
ment as socialization and learning. In P. van der Guide to the Commons. New York/London: The
Besselaar, G. De Michelis, J. Preece and C. Simone New Press.

247

Das könnte Ihnen auch gefallen