Sie sind auf Seite 1von 4

Social Capital and the Collective Management of Resources

Author(s): Jules Pretty


Source: Science, New Series, Vol. 302, No. 5652 (Dec. 12, 2003), pp. 1912-1914
Published by: American Association for the Advancement of Science
Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/3835714 .
Accessed: 11/01/2011 20:01

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use, available at .
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp. JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use provides, in part, that unless
you have obtained prior permission, you may not download an entire issue of a journal or multiple copies of articles, and you
may use content in the JSTOR archive only for your personal, non-commercial use.

Please contact the publisher regarding any further use of this work. Publisher contact information may be obtained at .
http://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=aaas. .

Each copy of any part of a JSTOR transmission must contain the same copyright notice that appears on the screen or printed
page of such transmission.

JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of
content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms
of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.

American Association for the Advancement of Science is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and
extend access to Science.

http://www.jstor.org
TRAGEDY OF THE COMMONS?

115. J. A. Aragon-Correa,S. Sharma,Acad. Manage. Rev. Sri Lankaand the Food and AgricultureOrganisa- 152. R. Costanza, B. S. Low, E. Ostrom, J. Wilson, Eds.,
28, 71 (2003). tion, Rome, 1995). Institutions, Ecosystems, and Sustainability (Lewis
116. A. Randall,in New Tools for EnvironmentalProtec- 133. C. E. Morrow, R. W. Hull, World Dev. 24, 1641 Publishers,New York,Z001).
tion: Education, Information and VoluntaryMea- (1996). 153. Committee on the Human Dimensions of Global
sures, T. Dietz, P. C. Stern, Eds. (National Academy 134. T. Nilsson, thesis, Royal Institute of Technology, Change, National ResearchCouncil,Global Environ-
Press,Washington, DC, 2002), pp. 311-318. Stockholm, Sweden (2001). mental Change: Understandingthe Human Dimen-
117. G. T. Gardner,P. C. Stern, EnvironmentalProblems 135. N. Polman, L. Slangen, in EnvironmentalCo-opera- sions, P. C. Stern, O. R. Young, D. Druckman,Eds.
and Human Behavior (Allyn and Bacon, Needham tion and InstitutionalChange, K. Hagedorn,Ed. (El- (National Academy Press, Washington, DC, 1992).
Heights, MA, 1996). gar, Northampton, MA,2002). 154. C. Hess, A ComprehensiveBibliographyof Common-
118. P. C. Stern,J. Consum. Policy 22, 461 (1999). 136. A. Sarker, T. Itoh, Agric. Water Manage. 48, 89 Pool Resources(CD-Rom,Workshopin PoliticalThe-
119. S. Hanna, C. Folke, K.-G. Maler, Rights to Nature (2001). ory and Policy Analysis,IndianaUniv., Bloomington,
I (IslandPress,Washington, DC, 1996). 137. C. Tucker,Praxis15, 47 (1999). 1 999).
120. E. Weiss, H. Jacobson, Eds., Engaging Countries: 138. R. Costanza et al., Science Z81, 198 (1998). 155. Ground fish data were compiled by D. Gilbert
StrengtheningCompliancewith InternationalEnviron- 139. T. Dietz, P. C. Stern, Bioscience 48, 441 (1998). (Maine Department of MarineResources)with data
mentalAgreements(MITPress,Cambridge,MA,1998). 140. E. Rosa,A. M. McWright,O. Renn,"Therisksociety: from the National MarineFisheriesService. Lobster
121. A. Underdal, The Politics of InternationalEnviron- Theoreticalframes and state management challeng- data were compiled by C. Wilson (Maine Depart-
mental Management (KluwerAcademic Publishers, es" (Dept. of Sociology, Washington State Univ., ment of MarineResources).J. Wilson (Universityof
Dordrecht,Netherlands, 1998). Pullman,WA, 2003). Maine) worked with the authors in the preparation
122. A. Krell, The Devil's Rope: A Cultural History of 141. S. Levin,FragileDominion:Complexityand the Com- of this figure.
BarbedWire(Reaktion,London,2002). mons (Perseus Books, Reading,MA, 1999). 156. United Nations Environment Programme, Produc-
123. S. Singleton, ConstructingCooperation:The Evolu- 142. B. Low,E.Ostrom, C. Simon,J. Wilson, in Navigating tion and Consumptionof Ozone Depleting Substanc-
tion of Institutions of Comanagement (Univ. of Social-Ecological Systems: Building Resilience for es, 1986-1998 (United Nations EnvironmentPro-
MichiganPress,Ann Arbor,1998). Complexity and Change, F. Berkes, J. Colding, C. gramme Ozone Secretariat,Nairobi, Kenya, 1999).
124. E. Moran, Ed., The EcosystemApproach in Anthro- Folke,Eds.(CambridgeUniv.Press,New York,2003), 157. World Resources Institute, WorldResources 2002-
pology: FromConcept to Practice(Univ.of Michigan pp. 83-114. 2004: EarthErendsData CD ( World Resources Insti-
Press, Ann Arbor,1990). 143. J. Liuet al., Science 292, 98 (2001). tute, Washington, DC, 2003).
125. M.Janssen,J. M.Anderies,E.Ostrom, paperpresent- 144. R.York,E.A. Rosa,T. Dietz,Am. Sociol. Rev. 68, 279 158. P. C. Stern, T. Dietz, E.Ostrom, Environ.Pract. 4, 61
ed at the Workshop on Resiliency and Change in (2003). (2002).
Ecological Systems, Santa Fe Institute, Santa Fe, 145. G. Hardin,Science 280, 682 (1998). 159. We thank R. Andrews,G. Daily,J. Hoehn, K. Lee, S.
NM, 25 to 27 October 2003. 146. G. W. Barrett, K. E. Mabry, Bioscience 52, 282 Levin,G. Libecap,V. Ruttan,T. Tietenberg,J. Wilson,
126. T. Princen,Global Environ.Polit. 3, 33 (2003). (2002). and O. Young for their comments on earlier drafts;
127. K.Lee,Compassand Gyroscope(IslandPress,Wash- 147. C. Hess, The Comprehensive Bibliographyof the and G. Laasby,P. Lezotte, C. Liang,and L.Wisen for
ington, DC, 1993). Commons, database available online at www. providing assistance. Supported in part by NSF
128. C. L.Abernathy,H. Sally,J.Appl. Irrig.Stud. 35, 177 indiana.edu/ iascp/lforms/searchcpr.html. grants BCS-9906253 and SBR-9521918, NASAgrant
(2000). 148. V. Ostrom, The Meaning of Democracy and the NASW-01008, the Ford Foundation, and the
129. A. Agrawal,in The Drama of the Commons, Com- Vulnerabilityof Democracies (Univ. of Michigan MacArthurFoundation.
mittee on the HumanDimensionsof GlobalChange, Press,Ann Arbor,1997).
Supporting Online Material
National Research Council, E. Ostrom et al., Eds. 149. M. McGinnis,Ed., Polycentric Governanceand De-
www.sciencemag.org/cgi/content/full/302/5652/1 907/
(National Academy Press, Washington, DC, 2002), velopment: Readingsfrom the Workshopin Political
DC1
pp. 41-85. Theoryand PolicyAnalysis(Univ. of MichiganPress,
SOM Text
130. P. Coop, D. Brunckhorst,Aust.J. Environ.Manage. 6, Ann Arbor,1999).
Fig. S1 to S5
48 (1999)- 150. M. McGinnis,Ed.,PolycentricGamesand Institutions:
Table S1
131. D. S. Crook,A. M.Jones, Mt. Res. Dev. 19, 79 (1999). Readingsfrom the Workshopin Political Theoryand
132. D.J. Merrey,in IrrigationManagementTransfer,S. H. Policy Analysis(Univ. of MichiganPress,Ann Arbor, Web Resources
Johnson, D. L.Vermillion,J. A. Sagardoy,Eds.(Inter- 2000). www.sciencemag.org/cgi/content/full/302/5652/1 907/
national IrrigationManagement Institute, Colombo, 151. T. Dietz, Hum. Ecol. Rev. 10, 60 (2003). DC2

V I EW P O I N T

Social Capital and the Collective Management


of Resources
Jules Pret

The proposition that natural resources need protection from the destructive actions resources are commonly owned is fur-
of people is widely accepted. Yet communities have shown in the past and increas- ther increasedby suspicions that people
ingly today that they can collaborate for long-term resource management. The term tend to free-ride,both by overusing and
social capital captures the idea that social bonds and norms are critical for sustain- underinvesting in the maintenance of
ability. Where social capital is high in formalized groups, people have the confidence resources. As our global numbers have
to invest in collective activities, knowing that others will do so too. Some 0.4 to 0.5 increased, and as incontrovertibleevi-
million groups have been established since the early 1990s for watershed, forest, dence of harm to water, land, and atmo-
irrigation,pest, wildlife, fishery, and microfinance management. These offer a route spheric resources has emerged, so the
to sustainable management and governance of common resources. choices seem to be starker. Either we
regulate to prevent further harm, in
From Malthus to Hardin and beyond, need to be protected from the destruc- Hardin'swords (1), to engage in mutual
analysts and policy-makershave widely tive, yet apparentlyrational, actions of coercion mutually agreed upon, or we
come to accept that natural resources people. The compelling logic is that press ahead with enclosure and privat-
people inevitably harm naturalresources ization to increasethe likelihoodthat re-
Department of Biological Sciences, University of Es- as they use them, and more people sourceswill be more carefullymanaged.
sex, Colchester C04 3SQ, UK. E-mail:jpretty@essex. thereforedo moreharm.The likelihoodof These concepts have influencedmany
ac.uk this damage being greaterwhere natural policy-makersandpractitioners.Theyhave

1912 12 DECEMBER2003 VOL 302 SCIENCE www.sciencemag.org


TRAGEDY OF THE COMMONS?

Table1. Socialcapitalformationin selectedagricultural


andruralresourcemanagementsectors(sincethe earlyl99Os).Thistablesuggeststhat 455,000
to SZO,OOOgroupshavebeenformed.Additional groupshavebeenformedinfarmers'research,
fishery,andwildlifeprogramsin a widevarietyof countries
(21).
Localgroups
Countriesand programs (thousand)
Watershedand catchment groups
Australia(4500 Landcaregroups containing about one-third of all farmers), Brazil(1S,000 to 17,000 54 to 58
microbaciasgroups), Guatemala, and Honduras(700 to 1100 groups), India (30,000 groups in both state
government and nongovernmentalorganizationprograms),Kenya (3000 to 4500 Ministryof Agriculture
catchment committees) United States (1000 farmer-ledwatershed initiatives)
Irrigationwater users' groups
Sri Lanka,Nepal, India,Philippines,and Pakistan(water users grolips as part of govemment irrigation 58
programs)
Microfnance institutions
Bangladesh(Grameen Bankand Proshika),Nepal, India,Sri Lanka,Vietnam, China, Philippines,Fiji,Tonga, 252 to 295
Solomon Islands,Papua New Guinea, Indonesia,and Malaysia
Joint and participatoryforest management
Indiaand Nepal (joint forest management and forest protection commiKees) 73

Integratedpest management
Indonesia,Vietnam, Bangladesh,Sri Lanka,China, Philippines,and India (farmerstrained in farmer field 18 to 36
schools)

led, for example,to the popularwilderness local groupsas an effective optioninstead is easily broken.Whena society is pervad-
myth (2) that many ecosystemsare pris- of strictregulationor enclosure.This"third ed by distrustor conflict, cooperativear-
tine and have emergedindependentof the way"has been shapedby theoreticaldevel- rangementsare unlikely to emerge (20).
actionsof local people,whetherpositiveor opmentsin the governanceof the commons Reciprocityincreases trust, and refers to
negative.Empty,idle, and"natural"envi- and in thinkingon social capital (9, 10). simultaneous exchanges of goods and
ronments need protection from harmful These groups are indicating that, given knowledgeof roughlyequalvalue, or con-
large-scaledevelopers,loggers,andranch- good knowledge about local resources; tinuingrelationsover time (14, 15). Reci-
ers, as well as from farmers,hunters,and appropriateinstitutional,social, and eco- procity contributesto the developmentof
gatherers(3). Since the first nationalpark nomic conditions(11); and processesthat long-term obligations between people,
was set up at Yellowstonein 1872, some encouragecareful deliberation(12), com- which helps in achievingpositive environ-
12,750protectedareasof greaterthan1000 munitiescan worktogethercollectivelyto mentaloutcomes.
hectareshave been establishedworldwide. use naturalresourcessustainablyover the Commonrules,norms,andsanctionsare
Of the 7322 protectedareasin developing long term(13). the mutuallyagreedupon or handed-down
countrieswheremanypeople rely on wild driversof behaviorthatensuregroupinter-
resources for food, fuel, medicine, and Social Capital and Local Resource ests are complementary with those of indi-
feed, 30% covering 6 million km2 are Management Groups viduals. These are sometimes called the
strictlyprotected,permittingno use of re- The term social capital capturesthe idea rules of the game (21), and they give indi-
sources(4). that social bonds and normsare important vidualsthe confidenceto invest in the col-
Theremovalof people,oftenthepoorest for people and communities (14). It lective good. Sanctionsensure that those
and the indigenous(5), from the very re- emergedas a termafterdetailedanalysesof who break the rules know they will be
sourceson whichthey mostrely has a long the effects of social cohesion on regional punished. Three types of connectedness
andtroublinghistoryandhas framedmuch incomes,civil society, and life expectancy (bonding,bridging,and linking)have been
naturalresourcepolicy in both developing (15-17). As social capitallowersthe trans- identified as importantfor the networks
and industrializedcountries(6). Yet com- action costs of workingtogether,it facili- within, between,and beyond communities
mon propertyresourcesremainimmensely tates cooperation.People have the confi- (22). Bonding social capital describesthe
valuable for many people, and exclusion dence to invest in collective activities, links between people with similar objec-
can be costly for them.In India,for exam- knowingthat otherswill also do so. They tives and is manifestedin local groups,
ple, commonresourceshavebeenestimated are also less likely to engage in unfettered such as guilds, mutual-aidsocieties, sports
to contributesome US$5 billion year-l to private actions with negative outcomes, clubs, and mothers'groups. Bridgingde-
the incomeof the ruralpoor (7). suchas resourcedegradation(18, 19). Four scribesthe capacityof suchgroupsto make
An importantquestion is could local featuresare important:relationsof trust; links with others that may have different
peopleplay a positiverole in conservation reciprocityand exchanges;commonrules, views, and linkingdescribesthe ability of
and managementof resources?And if so, norms,andsanctions;andconnectednessin groups to engage with externalagencies,
how best can unfetteredprivateactionsbe networksand groups. eitherto influencetheirpolicies or to draw
mediatedin favor of the common good? Relationsof trustlubricatecooperation, on useful resources.
Thoughsome communitieshave long been and so reduce transactioncosts between But do these ideas work in practice?
knownto managecommonresourcessuch people.Insteadof havingto invest in mon- First, there is evidence that high social
as forests and grazing lands effectively itoringothers,individualsare able to trust capital is associatedwith improvedeco-
overlongperiodswithoutexternalhelp(8), themto act as expected,thussavingmoney nomic and social well being. Households
recent years have seen the emergenceof andtime. But trusttakestime to build and with greater connectednesstend to have

www.sciencemag.org SCIENCE VOL 302 12 DECEMBER2003 1913


TRAGEDY OF THE COMMONS?

higher incomes, better health, higher edu- only themselves;in this sense, social capi- 8. E.Ostrom, Governingthe Commons(CambridgeUniv.
Press, New York, 1990).
cational achievements, and more construc- tal can also have its "darkside"(29). 9. E. Ostrom et al., Eds., The Drama of the Commons
tive links with government (4, 9, 15, 16, Social capitalcan help to ensurecom- (National Academy Press, Washington, DC, 2002).
23). What,then,can be doneto developappro- pliancewith rulesandkeep downmonitor- 10. S. Singleton, M. Taylor,J. Theoret. Politics 4, 309
priateformsof social organizationthatstructur- ing costs, provided networks are dense, (1992).
11. T. O'Riordan,S. Stoll-Kleeman,Biodiversity,Sustain-
ally suit naturalresourcemanagement? with frequentcommunicationand recipro- ability and Human Communities(Earthscan,London,
Collective resource management pro- cal arrangements,small group size, and 2002).
grams that seek to build trust, develop new lack of easy exit options for members. 12. J. Dryzek,Deliberative Democracy and Beyond (Ox-
norms, and help form groups have become However, factors relating to the natural ford Univ. Press, Oxford, 2000).
13. N. Uphoff, Ed.,AgroecologicalInnovations(Earthscan,
increasingly common, and such programs resourcesthemselves,particularlywhether London,2002).
are variouslydescribedby the terms commu- they are stationary,have high storageca- 14. J. Coleman,Am. J. Sociol. 94, S95 (1988).
nity-, participatory-,joint-, decentralized-,and pacity (potential for biological growth), 15. R. D. Putnam, Making Democracy Work (Princeton
Univ. Press, Princeton,NJ, 1993).
co-management.They have been effective in and clearboundaries,will also play a crit- 16. R. G. Wilkinson, Ann. N. Y. Acad. Sci. 896, 48
severalsectors,includingwatershed,forest,ir- ical role in affectingwhethersocial groups (1 999).
rigation, pest, wildlife, fishery, farmers' re- can succeed, keep down the costs of en- 17. R. Putnam, Bowling Alone (Simon & Schuster, New
search,and micro-financemanagement(Table forcement, and ensure positive resource York,2000).
18. J. Pretty, H. Ward, World Dev. 29 (no. 2), 209
1). Since the early l990s, some 400,000 to outcomes(30). (2001 ).
500,000 new local groupswere establishedin Communitiesalso do not always have 19. A. Agrawal,in TheDramaof the Commons,E.Ostrom
vaxyingenvironmentalandsocialcontexts(18), the knowledgeto appreciatethatwhatthey et al., Eds.(National Academy Press,Washington,DC,
2002).
mostly evolving to be of similar small size, are doing may be harmful.For instance,it 20. R Wade, Hllage Republics (ICSPress, San Francisco,
typicallywith 20 to 30 activemembers,putting is commonfor fishing communitiesto be- ed. 2, 1994).
total involvement at some 8 to 15 million lieve thatfish stocks are not being eroded, 21. M. Taylor, Community,Anarchy and Liberty (Cam-
households.The majoritycontinue to be suc- even though the scientific evidence indi- bridge Univ. Press, Cambridge,1982).
22. M. Woolcock, Can.J. Policy Res. 2, 11 (2001).
cessful and show the inclusive characteristics catesotherwise.Localgroupsmayneedthe 23. A. Krishna,Active Social Capital (Columbia Univ.
identified as vital for improving community supportof higherlevel authorities,for ex- Press, New York,2002).
well-being (24), and evaluations have con- amplewith legal structuresthat give com- 24. C. B. Flora,J. L.Flora,Am. Acad. PoliticalSoc. Sci. 529,
firmed that there are positive ecological and munitiesclearentitlementto landandother 48 (1993)-
25. K.S. Murali,I. K.Murthy,N. H. Ravindranath,Environ.
economic outcomes, including for water- resourcesas well as insulationfrom the Manage. Health 13, 512 (2002).
sheds (23), forests (25), andpest management pressures of global markets (8, 9). For 26. J. Pontius, R. Dilts, A. Bartlett, From Farmer Field
(26, 27). globalenvironmental problems,suchas cli- Schools to CommunityIPM(FAO,Bangkok,2001).
27. See the following websites for more data and evalua-
mate change, governmentsmay need to tions on the ecological and economic impact of local
Further Challenges regulate, partly because no community groups:(i) Sustainableagricultureprojects analysisof
The formation, persistence, and effects of feels it can have a perceptibleimpacton a 208 projects in developing countries in which social
new groups suggests that new configura- globalproblem.Thus,effectiveinternation- capital formation was critical prerequisiteof success,
see www2.essex.ac.uk/ces/ResearchProgrammes/
tions of social and human relations could al institutionsare needed to complement subheads4foodprodinchtm.See also (32). (ii) Jointfor-
be prerequisites for long-term improve- local ones (31). est managementtFM) projectsin India.Forimpactsin
ments in naturalresources. Regulations and Nonetheless,the ideas of social capital Andhra Pradesh,includingsatellite photographs,see
www.ap.nicin/apforest/jfm.htm.For case studies of
economic incentives play an importantrole andgovernanceof the commons,combined JFM,see www.teriin.org/jfm/cs.htm and www.iifm.org/
in encouraging changes in behavior, but with the recent successes of local groups, databank/jfm/jfm.htmL See also (25, 33). (iii) Forcom-
although these may change practices, there offer routes for constructiveand sustain- munityIPM,see www.communityipm.org/and (26). (iv)
Forimpactson economic success in ruralcommunities,
is no guaranteedpositive effect on personal able outcomes for natural resources in see (34, 35). (v) For Landcareprogram in Australia,
attitudes (28). Without changes in social many of the world's ecosystems.To date, where 4500 groupshave formedsince 1989, see www.
norms, people often revert to old ways however, the triumphsof the commons landcareaustralia.com.au/projectlist.asp and www.
landcareaustralia.com.au/FarmingCaseStudies.asp.
when incentives end or regulations are no havebeen largelyat local to regionallevel, 28. G. T. Gardner, P. C. Stern, EnvironmentalProblems
longer enforced, and so long-term protec- where resourcescan be closed-accessand and Human Behavior (Allyn and Bacon, Needham
tion may be compromised. where institutionalconditionsand market Heights, MA, 1996)
However, there remains a danger of ap- pressuresare supportive.The greaterchal- 29. A. Portes, P. Landolt,Am. Prospect 26, 18 (1996).
30. P. C. Stern,T. Dietz, N. Doscak, E.Ostrom, S. Stonich,
pearing too optimistic about local groups lenge will centeron applyingsome of these in (9), pp. 443-490.
and their capacity to deliver economic and principles to open-access commons and 31. P. M. Haas, R. O. Keohane, M. A. Levy, Eds.,in Insti-
environmental benefits, because divisions worldwideenvironmental threatsand creat- tutions for the Earth,(MITPress, Cambridge,1993).
32. J. Pretty, J. I. L. Morison, R. E. Hine, Agric. Ecosys.
within and between communities can result ingtheconditionsby whichsocialcapitalca Environ.95 (1), 217 (2003).
in environmental damage. Moreover, not workundergrowingeconomicglobalization. 33. K. S. Muraliet al., Int. J. Environ.SustainableDev. 2,
all forms of social relations are necessarily 19 (2003).
good for everyone. A society may have References and Notes 34. D. Narayan,L.Pritchett,Centsand Sociability:House-
1. G. Hardin,Science 162, 1243 (1968). hold Income and Social Capital in Rural Tanzania,
strong institutions and embedded reciprocal 2. R. Nash, Wldemess and the American Mind (Yale World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 1796
mechanisms yet be based on fear and pow- Univ. Press, New Haven, 1973). (World Bank,Washington, DC, 1997). Available at:
er, such as feudal and unjust societies. For- 3. J. B. Callicott, M. P. Nelson, Eds., The Great New hap://poverty.worldbank.org/library/view/6097/.
Wlderness Debate (Univ. of Georgia Press, Athens, 35. P. Donnelly-Roark,X. Ye, Growth, Equityand Social
mal rules and norms can also trap people 1998). Capital:How Local Level InstitutionsReduce Poverty
within harmful social arrangements, and 4. J.Pretty,Agri-Culture:ReconnectingPeople, Landand (World Bank, Washington, DC, 2002). Available at:
the role of men may be enhanced at the Nature (Earthscan,London,2002). http://poverty.worldbank.org/library/view/1 3137.
5. D. Posey, Ed.,Culturaland SpiritualValues of Biodi- 36. I am grateful for helpful comments on an earlier
expense of women. Some associations may versity. (IT Publishing,London,1999). version of this paper by H. Ward and J. Morison,
act as obstacles to the emergence of sus- 6. M. Gadgil,R. Guha, ThisFissuredLand:An Ecological together with those of two anonymous referees.
tainability, encouraging conformity, per- History of India (Oxford Univ. Press, New Delhi,
1992). Web Resources
petuatinginequity,andallowingcertainin- 7. T. Beck,C. Naismith, WorldDevelopment 29 (no. 1), www.sciencemag.org/cgi/content/fulU302/5652/1 912/
dividualsto shapetheir institutionsto suit 119 (2001). DC1

1914 12 DECEMBER
2003 VOL302 SCIENCEwww.sciencemag.org

Das könnte Ihnen auch gefallen