Sie sind auf Seite 1von 9

Transport Policy 25 (2013) 169–177

Contents lists available at SciVerse ScienceDirect

Transport Policy
journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/tranpol

The economic effects of government regulation: Evidence from the New York
taxicab market
- etin a,n, Kadir Yasin Eryigit b,1
Tamer C
a
Department of Economics, Yildiz Technical University, Yildiz Kampusu, 34349 Yildiz-Besiktas, Turkey
b
Department of Econometrics, Uludag University, Gorukle Kampsu, 16059 Bursa, Turkey

a r t i c l e i n f o abstract

Available online 24 January 2013 This paper empirically investigates the economic effects of government regulation in a regulated
Keywords: taxicab market. We use a cointegration model with structural breaks to test the hypothesis that
Taxicabs government regulation increases the price of the regulated good and/or causes the monopoly price.
Entry regulation We examine the New York taxicab market and argue that regulation brings about artificial rents by
Price controls increasing medallion prices, and an increase in medallion prices gives rises to upward pressure on taxi
Elasticity fares. The evidence presented shows that regulation of the New York taxicab market increases
Cointegration medallion prices, and this increase in medallion prices pressures on taxi fares.
Structural breaks & 2012 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.

1. Introduction price stability and the efficient production of goods. A monopoly is


characterized by the presence of a single firm in a market rather than
Until the present, considerable attention has been paid to under- several and some type of economic regulation is required to avoid the
stand the economic effects of government regulation2 on the market- monopoly exploit (Ogus, 1994; p. 30).
place. The relevant economic literature on government regulation has The public interest theory has been criticized and rebutted
introduced theoretically and empirically substantial contributions over last 40 years by empirical and theoretical studies (Demsetz,
and evidence for understanding the nature of government regulation 1968; Stigler, 1971; Posner, 1975; Ippolito, 1979; Baumol, 1977,
in the economy. The theoretical contributions include normative 1982). Currently, academic works accept that the public interest
analysis. The normative analysis of regulation attempts to understand theory of regulation does not accurately account for market
how markets fail, when regulation is needed and what the optimal failure phenomena (Domas, 2003; p. 166). The public interest
form of regulation is. The public interest theory of regulation as a theory of regulation is at least insufficient to explain why
normative approach justifies the necessity of regulation. The public government regulation exists. Instead, as a positive analysis of
interest approach argues that government intervention ameliorates government regulation, the economic theory of regulation has
market failures such as natural monopolies, externalities, public argued that government regulation either has been manipulated
goods, and information asymmetries (Joskow and Rose, 1989)3. In by private interest groups for the markets in which they operate
this context, from the perspective of public interest theory, the (Stigler, 1971), or that it has caused society to incur substantial
principal reason for price and entry regulations is the existence of social costs (Posner, 1975). Regulators, like other private agents of
markets characterized by natural monopolies (Noll, 1989; economic activity, also maximize their own self-interest. Hence,
Braeutigam, 1989). An unregulated market system, because of the special interest groups can manipulate regulatory outcomes by
undesirable consequences of natural monopolies, cannot provide pressuring regulators. In other words, as a rule, government
regulation is not implemented because it is needed, but because
it is demanded by the regulated industry and is operated
n
Corresponding author. Tel.: þ90 212 383 25 26; fax: þ 90 212 259 42 02. primarily in favor of the regulated industry (Stigler, 1971;
1
Tel.: þ90 0224 2941000; fax: þ 90 0224 2941199. Posner, 1975; Peltzman, 1976, 1993).
E-mail addresses: tcetin@yildiz.edu.tr, tamer.cetin@yahoo.com (T. C - etin),
kyeryigit@uludag.edu.tr (K. Yasin Eryigit).
Also, regulation produces adverse effects for the regulated
2
By ‘‘government regulation’’ we refer to economic regulations such as entry industries. It leads to long-term rents for interest groups and
restrictions and price controls. Additionally, by ‘‘the economic effects’’, we mean deviations from competitive outcomes. Resources are wasted in
the effects of regulation on prices and fares. In that sense, the analysis in the paper this process (Parker, 2002). In the literature, the effects of
does not include social regulations regarding service quality, safety, and security
regulation on prices, costs, technological change, product quality,
and their effects on taxi markets.
3
For a detailed discussion of the rationales for or theories of economic and the distribution of income and rents have empirically been
regulation, see Noll (1989) and Joskow and Rose (1989). investigated by the students of regulatory economics (Joskow and

0967-070X/$ - see front matter & 2012 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.tranpol.2012.11.011
170 - etin, K. Yasin Eryigit / Transport Policy 25 (2013) 169–177
T. C

Rose, 1989). This empirical contribution constructs the positive performs in favor of medallion owners as producers of this
analysis of government regulation. In this context, many studies market.
have estimated the effects of regulation on prices (Stigler and As pointed out by Viscusi et al. (1998), this appears to be a
Friedl, 1962; Kitch et al., 1971; Jarrell, 1978; Ippolito, 1979). It is classic example of the economic theory of regulation. Whereas
generally accepted that regulation that is subject to political medallion owners gain an artificial rent from regulation of entry
influence is rarely implemented to improve economic efficiency. and taxi fares, consumers take a loss from it. In the presence of
On the contrary, entry and price regulations give rise to an such regulatory process, because medallion owners are more
increase in prices and/or an artificial rent for the private pressure effective in getting regulation put in place than are consumers
groups in the industry by creating a monopolistic structure in the in preventing regulation, we can expect that medallion owners as
regulated industry (Stigler, 1971; Posner, 1975; Peltzman, 1976; private interest groups in the market would manipulate the
Becker, 1983; Kahn, 1998; Guasch and Hahn 1999)4 . As a result, regulation of taxi fares (Frankena and Paulter, 1984; Svorny,
insightful theoretical and empirical approaches have been intro- 1999). Since, the cost of organizing political support for regulation
duced both for and against government regulation (Stigler, 1971; is much lower for medallion owners, fares will be also manipu-
Becker, 1983; Braeutigam, 1989; Laffont and Tirole, 1991). lated by regulation. Generally, the economic theory of regulation
Taxicab markets are excellent examples to analyze the shows that prices (fares) are regulated on inflation rates in the
economic effects of government regulation in the marketplace. recovery period, they are determined under inflation rates in the
The rationale for economic regulation in taxicab markets is the recession terms (Viscusi et al., 1998). Accordingly, in our model,
presence of negative externalities such as congestion and pollu- we expect that fares regulated in the New York Taxicab Market
tion, the public good characteristics of taxis, and information exceed inflation rates during the recovery periods, while they fall
asymmetries5. Due to these rationales, taxicab markets are below inflation rates during the economic downturn periods.
subject to quantity restrictions, fare controls, and social regula- The effects of governmental regulation on medallion prices
tions as the primary regulatory tools (C - etin and Eryigit, 2011; and taxi fares in taxicab markets have been investigated for
Heyes and Heyes, 2007; Seibert, 2006; Teal and Berglund, 1987; decades. Many studies have found a relationship between
Frankena and Pautler, 1984; Shreiber, 1975). The taxicab market economic regulation and high medallion prices in taxicab mar-
is not a natural monopoly. It is potentially a competitive industry. kets. It has been argued that restricting the number of taxicabs
Entry restrictions and price controls in taxicab markets have can only serve to increase the prices of medallions by restricting
negative effects (Eckert, 1970; Beesley and Glaister, 1983; the supply of taxicabs compared to the number that would
Frankena and Pautler, 1984; Moore and Balaker, 2006). Because otherwise be provided (C - etin and Oğuz, 2010; Cumming, 2009;
regulation in relatively competitive industries such as taxicab OECD, 2007; Moore and Balaker, 2006; Koehler, 2005; Barrett,
markets gives rise to increase in prices and above-normal profit 2003; Frankena and Pautler, 1984; Tullock, 1975; Kitch et al.
(Viscusi et al., 1998), barriers to entry will result in an artificial 1971; Turvey, 1961). However, there is no empirical evidence
rent that is greater than the prices of medallions6 by creating a showing that government regulation influences medallion prices
monopolistic market structure (Tullock, 1975). Rents occur and thus the increase in medallion prices affects taxi fares, except
because the entry barrier enables prices to be high and medal- for the work of C- etin and Eryigit (2011). In our earlier paper, we
lions can be traded in the market (Turvey, 1961). Accordingly, introduced a model to estimate the direct (on medallion prices)
economic regulation in taxicab markets triggers a rent seeking and indirect (on inflation) effects of entry restrictions in the
process and causes government failure (C - etin and Oğuz, 2010; Istanbul taxicab market. In this paper, we progress our model to
Moore and Balaker, 2006; Frankena and Pautler, 1984). estimate the effect of regulation on medallion prices and taxi
The value of medallions to their owners is a monopoly rent fares, but not inflation rates. Since, the real effect of government
that is artificially produced by restricting the number of taxicabs. regulation in taxicab markets is on medallion prices and taxi
This artificial rent captured by medallion owners is greater than fares. Another difference in this paper is that the paper includes
the economic profits in comparable industries (Schaller, 2006). the analysis of regulation in the New York taxicab market that is
Thus, an unofficial market for medallions occurs (Friedman, taught as an interesting case in microeconomics textbooks. This
2008). In this regulatory environment, medallion owners will be paper analyses in more detail the effects of regulation in another
in favor of regulation of entry and fares, but not deregulation. taxicab market. In that sense, the current paper differentiates
Because an increase in the number of taxis in conjunction with a from our previous paper on the Istanbul taxicab market. The
probable deregulation will depress individual license values, paper consists of four main sections including an introduction.
medallion owners and cab drivers are unanimous in opposing Section two describes the regulatory process in the New York
any increase in the number of medallions (Orr, 1969; Friedman, taxicab market. Section three empirically analyzes the economic
2008). The empirical evidence seems that regulation in taxicab effects of government regulation in the New York taxicab market.
markets supports prices above cost and prevents entry from The paper ends with the forth section that includes conclusions.
dissipating rents (Viscusi et al., 1998). Regulation inherently

4
Peltzman (1976) and Becker (1983) of these studies develop a model on the
political influence of interest groups and the role of politicians as regulator in the
2. Regulatory history of the New York taxicab market
regulatory process.
5
In the literature, it has been argued that there are further reasons for By Local Law No. 12 of 1971, the New York City Taxi and
regulating taxicab markets. Economies of scale, declining marginal costs, Limousine Commission (TLC) was established as the regulator
predatory pricing, and excessive competition arguments are sometimes used to
responsible for regulating the New York taxicab market. The aim
justify government regulation of taxicabs. However, these rationales are weaker
than aforementioned arguments and their theoretical structures are contested of the TLC is to ensure ‘‘the development and improvement of taxi
vigorously because it is not possible to empirically show economies of scale in y service in New York City y, and to establish certain rates and
taxicab markets (Pagano and McKnight, 1983), and technological innovations have standards’’. Currently, to this end, the TLC sets taxi fares and
made these arguments outdated for cities like New York, where corporations determines how many medallions will be issued. Moreover, it
control most of the market (Harris, 2002).
6
In this paper, we focus on medallions and their prices, because entry
licenses those seeking to become taxi drivers and operate a
regulation influences directly medallions and they can be traded in the secondary vehicle in the market, adopts rules that drivers and cab owners
market. must obey, adjudicates rule infractions and consumer complaints,
- etin, K. Yasin Eryigit / Transport Policy 25 (2013) 169–177
T. C 171

and subjects each taxicab to an extensive inspection three times a Table 1


year7 (Schaller and Gilbert, 1996b; TLC, 2009). The numbers of taxicabs since 1907.
The New York medallion system has a predetermined ceiling8.
Years The numbers of taxicabs
Accordingly, in New York, the TLC determines the maximum
number of cabs. There is a static restriction on the number of 1907 65
taxis. However, the regulatory structure allows licenses to be 1912 2800
traded within the market (Bekken, 2007). Licenses have also been 1923 15,000
1931 21,000
sold at public auctions. Anyone may bid for a taxicab license in 1933 15,500
the public auction, and the highest bidder who satisfies all of the 1934 14,000
criteria for a taxicab license wins the license and the right to 1937 13,595
transfer it. Although medallions have gradually been released by During WW II 7500
1947 11,414
the public auction, this does not mean that entry into the market
1964 11,787
has been deregulated. May 1996 11,920
Table 1 presents the number of taxicabs in the New York October 1996 12,053
market from 1907 to 2011. Until 1937, entry into the New York September 1997 12,187
taxicab market was free and taxi fares were not regulated, except 2004 12,487
2006 12,779
for a requirement to use meters (Schreiber, 1975; Schaller, 2006). 2007 13,028
Under the Haas Act of 1937, New York City9 limited the number of 2008 13,148
taxis to 13,595. The number of taxicab medallions in New York 2009 13,237
City decreased to 11,787 in 1964 because taxi owners who had 2011 13,296
received licenses during World War II retired and their licenses
Source: Schaller, 2006; TLC, 2007, 2008, 2009, 2010, 2011.
were not reissued. The number of licenses remained constant Note: In some years, because the number of taxicabs
until May 1996 (Schaller and Gilbert, 1996a). Through three sets remained unchanged, the number of taxicabs for these
of auctions that took place under a court order between May 1996 years is not given in the table.
and September 1997, the number of medallions was increased by
400 (Guri, 2005: 157; Frankena and Pautler, 1984; p. 77). As of
September 1997, there were 12,187 licenses in the market. The increase in wait time in November 2006 (Schaller, 2006). This rate
TLC, which had not held any auctions between 1997 and 2004, is the current rate.
auctioned licenses again in 2004. Since then, nine auctions have A crucial component of New York taxicab regulation is medal-
been held, and a total of 1109 new taxi medallions were lion prices. Table 3 shows medallion prices in the market since
distributed. There are currently almost 13,300 medallions, none 1947. As Table 3 shows, entry regulation in the market has
of whom possesses significant market power. They provide increased medallion prices since 1947. Medallions first became
transportation for passengers via street hails. Yellow Medallion valuable after World War II, as demand for taxi service grew
Taxicabs are the official taxis of New York City. while the number of taxies was capped (Schaller, 2006). While the
Taxi fares that are regulated by the TLC have three important medallion price for an individual owner was $5000 in 1950,
components, an initial charge, a mileage charge per-kilometer $28,000 in 1970, and $128,400 in 1990, it reached $601,000 in
rate, and a wait time rate10 . Changes in taxi fares since 1952 are 2010. However, although medallion prices follow a strong upward
shown in Table 2. The 2004 change is one of the most remarkable. trend, significant declines were also experienced during economic
Fares that had not changed dramatically prior to 2004 increased; slowdowns in the late 1960s and the early 1970s and the
the initial fare rose from $2.00 to $2.50 and the price per mile recessions in the early 1980s and early 1990s. Ultimately, medal-
from $1.50 to $2.00. When we analyze this change in detail, we lion prices declined two more times between the spring of 1998
can see that the average fare increased substantially, from $6.85 and mid-2001. However, after 2001, they continued to rise and
to $8.65. However, the initial and per mile fares have not changed remain around $650,000 today.
since May 2004. However, while the unit fare rates have not
changed since 2004, the TLC changed the ‘‘wait time’’ from $0.40
per 120 s to $0.40 per 60 s but did not change the ‘‘wait time 3. The empirical analysis
rate’’. Hence, the effective wait time rate changed to $0.80 per
120 s, and the average fare increased from $8.65 to $9.61 with the Previous studies regarding taxicab regulation have generally
been conducted to show that there is only an anecdotal linkage
between high medallion prices and barriers to entry (C - etin and
Oguz, 2010; OECD, 2007; Moore and Balaker, 2006; Koehler, 2005;
7
The TLC is also responsible for the regulation of commuter vans, paratransit Barrett, 2003; Frankena and Pautler, 1984). We attempt to find a
vehicles, and certain luxury limousines. The commission’s board has nine cointegration between the number of medallions, medallion prices,
members, eight of whom are unsalaried commissioners. The salaried chair/ and taxi fares. We develop an innovative method to estimate the
commissioner presides over regularly scheduled public meetings and is the head
effect of economic regulation on real medallion prices and real taxi
of the agency (TLC, 2009).
8
There are three methods for issuing licenses in taxicab markets: a fares. In doing so, the paper aims to contribute empirical evidence
predetermined ceiling system, objective criteria, and subjective criteria. See to the regulatory economics literature. To investigate this cointe-
Bekken (2007) for a more detailed discussion of this issue. gration, the New York taxicab market is rather characteristic.
9
In most US cities, taxi markets were under the control of municipal or state Market entry and taxi fares are regulated by the TLC, and medallion
regulation by the late 1920s or 1930s (Teal and Berglund, 1987). The reason was
the extremely competitive conditions following the Great Depression. The com-
prices exhibit a positive trend, which is often the case for goods
petitive conditions in the New York taxi market after the Great Depression were a prices in regulated markets.
result of the low cost of entering the taxi industry at a time when other jobs were
hard to find (Guri, 2003; 256). For that reason, New York City introduced the New 3.1. Data
York medallion system in 1937.
10
The fares charged by private hired vehicles are not regulated. In New York,
most companies charge by zone, but when they do use a meter, it must be In this paper, we use annual data spanning the period 1947–
inspected by an approved center at regular intervals (Darbera, 2007). 2010, and the data comes from a variety of sources such as
172 - etin, K. Yasin Eryigit / Transport Policy 25 (2013) 169–177
T. C

Table 2 Table 3
Taxi fares (US Dollars). Medallion prices since 1947 (US Dollars).

Years Initial Charge Wait Average Years Individual Corporate


charge per time fares
mile rate 1947 2500 2500
1950 5000 5000
Before 1952 0.50 0.20 0.05 0.83 1952 7000 7500
July 1952 0.25 0.25 0.05 1.06 1959 19,500 20,000
December 1964 0.35 0.25 0.05 1.16 1960 20,825 19,450
January 1968 0.45 0.30 0.10 1.48 1962 22,000 23,400
March 1971 0.60 0.50 0.10 2.30 1964 26,000 34,145
November 1974 0.65 0.60 0.10 2.71 1965 26,000 30,000
March 1977 0.75 0.70 0.10 3.09 1966 25,000 19,000
July 1979 0.90 0.70 0.10 3.24 1968 27,000 16,000
April 1980 1.00 0.90 0.10 4.06 1969 24,500 N/A
July 1984 1.10 0.90 0.10 4.16 1970 28,000 14,000
May 1987 1.15 1.20 0.15 5.08 1971 25,000 10,000
January 1990 1.50 1.25 0.25 5.70 1972 26,000 12,000
March 1996 2.00 1.50 0.30 6.85 1973 30,000 17,000
May 2004 2.50 2.00 0.40 8.65 1974 30,000 17,000
November 2006 2.50 2.00 0.40 9.61 1975 35,000 22,000
1976 42,000 24,000
Source: Schaller, 2006:p. 18. 1977 55,000 33,000
Note: Because the TLC did not regulate fares in some years, taxi fares for these 1978 63,000 62,000
years are not given in the table. For example, taxi fares have remained constant 1979 67,000 53,000
since November 2006. 1980 60,000 50,000
1981 60,000 50,000
1982 57,500 49,300
1983 68,600 57,900
1984 75,900 66,200
1985 84,900 79,000
Schaller (2006), the TLC’s annual reports, the U.S. Census Bureau 1986 101,600 92,900
and the U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics. The number of taxies, taxi 1987 108,700 94,600
fares, and individual medallion prices prior to 2006 are taken 1988 129,700 121,500
1989 139,100 141,400
from Schaller (2006). The remaining figures concerning these
1990 128,400 135,700
variables are obtained from the TLC’s annual reports (2007, 2008, 1991 126,067 130,360
2009, 2010, and 2011). The data regarding population and infla- 1992 128,577 143,199
tion rates are obtained from the U.S. Census Bureau and U.S. 1993 137,196 17,200
Bureau of Labor Statistics, respectively. 1994 155,633 214,221
1995 169,750 219,958
The variables under consideration are real taxi medallion  
  1996 176,333 207,292
prices prmdl
t , the number of taxies
 per thousand people ntxpt t 1997 199,875 236,500
ravg
and real taxi average fares11 f t . All of the variables are used in 1998 229,000 277,318
logarithmic form. 1999 212,917 269,500
2000 217,125 253,864
2001 188,958 209,458
2002 200,333 232,250
3.2. Methodology 2003 224,958 260,917
2004 277,583 315,636
In this study, we empirically analyze the long-run relation- 2005 335,583 278,556
ships between New York City taxi medallion prices, the number of 2006 375,000 462,500
2007 420,000 560,000
taxies per thousand people in New York City and average taxi
2008 490,000 605,000
fares in New York City within a Johansen et al. (2000) cointegra- 2009 572,000 765,000
tion framework that accounts for structural breaks in the time 2010 601,000 815,000
series. For this purpose, we consider a vector autoregressive (VAR) 2011 637,000 950,000
system containing a group of endogenous variables: taxi medal-
Source: As data for medallion prices until 2006 is obtained from Schaller (2006),
lion prices, the number of taxis per thousand people and fares. the figures between 2007 and 2011 are taken from the TLC’s webpage that
Before proceeding with the cointegration analysis, however, the discloses industry information regarding ‘‘average medallion prices’’ /http://
univariate time series properties of the variables must be exam- www.nyc.gov/html/tlc/html/misc/avg_med_price.shtmlS.
ined. In this context, the introduction of the recent minimum Note: Because there is no sale of medallion in some years, medallion prices for
these years are deemed as the same in the earlier year.

11
Average fares used in this paper are calculated following the methodology
of Schaller (2006). This method of calculating fares is uniform throughout the U.S. Lagrange multipliers (LM) structural break unit root tests pro-
and conforms to federal standards for taxi meters. Accordingly, the cab fare is posed by Lee and Strazicich (2003, 2004) seems to be an appro-
$2.50 for the first 1/5 of a mile and 40 cents per additional unit. A unit is composed priate procedure for investigating the univariate properties of the
of distance (one unit equals 1/5 mile) and/or wait time (one unit equals
variables.
60 seconds). When a cab moves at more than 12 mph, the meter clocks distance.
When a cab is stopped or is moving at less than 12 mph, the meter clocks time. The minimum LM unit root tests with one break and two
There is also a $1 surcharge for trips beginning from 4 p.m. to 8 p.m. and a 50-cent breaks that are proposed by Lee and Strazicich (2003, 2004) are
surcharge for trips starting between 8 p.m. and 6 a.m. Trips between John F. versions of the Schmidt and Phillips (1992) unit root test,
Kennedy International Airport and Manhattan are charged at a flat rate of $45 plus modified by incorporating structural break(s) in mean Model A
any tolls. There is a $15 surcharge for trips to Newark Liberty International Airport
(Schaller, 2006; p. 16). However, the method we use to calculate average fares
(Crash Model) and Model C (Changing Level and Growth Model),
does not include any surcharges. Finally, we produce real average fares by which were identified by Perron (1989). The LM unit root test for
deflating average fares. real medallion prices, for example, can be obtained from the
- etin, K. Yasin Eryigit / Transport Policy 25 (2013) 169–177
T. C 173

following regression: Hl ðpÞ alternative r cointegration relationship Hl ðrÞ hypothesis is:


p
X
p
X  
¼ d DZ t þ fS~ t1 þ gi DS~ ti þ Zt LR Hl ðrÞ9Hl ðpÞ ¼ T lnð1li Þ
0
Dprmdl
t t ¼ 1,2,. . .,T ð1Þ ð4Þ
i¼1 i ¼ r þ1

~ Z t d~ , where li are squared sample canonical correlations and 1 Z l 1 Z


where Z t is vector of the exogenous variables, S~ t ¼ yt c x
. . . Z lp Z 0.
t ¼ 2,. . .,T, d~ are coefficients in the regression of Dprmdl on DZ t , c
t
~
x In a cointegration relationship, there is no linear trend, but if
is given by y1 Z 1 d~ (see Schmidt and Phillips, 1992), and prmdl
1 and only a breaking level exists, the model given in Eq. (3) can be
Z 1 denote the first observations of prmdl
t and Z t , respectively. The transformed as in Johansen et al. (2000) and is denoted Hc ðrÞ. The
lag terms DS~ ti are included to correct for serial correlation. Model critical values for both Hl ðrÞ and Hc ðrÞ models are derived from the
A allows for shifts in level and is described by Z t ¼ ½1,t,D1t ,D2t 0 , G-distribution, as proposed in Johansen et al. (2000).
where, Djt ¼ 1 for t Z T Bj þ 1, j ¼ 1,2, and zero otherwise. The time Given the cointegration rank, further restrictions on the VECM
period when a break occurs is denoted T Bj . Model C includes two can be tested using likelihood ratio (LR) testing. Harris and Sollis
(2003) employed these tests within a standard framework. In our
changes in level and trend and is described by Z t ¼ ½1,t,D1t ,D2t ,
study, LR tests are extended for use in the models proposed by
DT 1t ,DT 2t 0 where DT jt ¼ t for t ZT Bj þ1, j ¼ 1,2 and zero other-
Johansen et al. (2000) as in Dawson and Sanjuan (2005).
wise. The unit root hypothesis is tested via the tratio of f,
Assume that one cointegrating vectorðr ¼ 1Þ and two level and
denoted as t~ in Eq. (1). Denoting the break fractions as lj ¼ TBj =T, h i
ravg
trend breaks ðq ¼ 3Þexist for the system Y 0t ¼ prmdl ntxpt ft
the LM test statistic can be defined as: t t

such that:
LM ¼ inf t~ ðlÞ ð2Þ " #
l
Y t1 h i0
ravg
¼ prmdl
t ntxpt
t ft tE1t tE2t tE3t , ð5Þ
Critical values for Model A and Model B are given in Lee and tEt
Strazicich (2003, 2004). It should be noted that when there are no
" #0
breaks in the series, the critical values are the same as those in b h i
Schmidt and Phillips (1992). ¼ bprmdl bntxpt bf ravg g1 g2 g3 , ð6Þ
ravg
g
Given the non-stationarity of the variables prmdl
t , ntxpt
t and f t ,
the cointegration framework of Johansen et al. (2000), which is a and:
2
slight modification of the vector error correction model (VECM) aprmdl 3
based cointegration analysis proposed by Johansen (1988), pro-
vides a natural way of estimating the long-run relationship(s)
a¼6 7
4 antxpt 5: ð7Þ
among them.
af ravg
h i
ravg
Let Y 0t ¼ prmdl
t ntxpt
t ft be a vector of endogenous First, we test whether each variable exists in the cointegration
I(1) variables with r cointegrating relationships. The VECM, which space. The hypothesis of individual exclusion of prmdl
t , for example,
was proposed by Johansen et al. (2000), can be written as: is:
" #0 " # " #0
b h i
b Y t1 X
k1
H0 : ¼ 0 bntxpt bf ravg g1 g2 g3 ð8Þ
DY t ¼ a þ mEt þ Gi DY ti g
g tEt i¼1

k X
X q X
d and the likelihood ratio test statistics have a w2 distribution
þ Cj,i Dj,ti þ Fm W m,t þ et ð3Þ (LR  w2 ). Second, we test for weak exogeneity. To test for weak
i¼1j¼2 m¼1 exogeneity of prmdl
t , for example, the null hypothesis is:

where D is the first difference operator; k is lag length; H0 : aprmdl ¼ 0 ð9Þ


h i0
Et ¼ E1t E2t . . . Eqt is a vector of q dummy variables with and LR  w2 . Here, rejection of the null hypothesis, aprmdl ¼ 0 refers
to the notion.
Ej,t ¼ 1for T j1 þk r t rT j ðj ¼ 1,. . .,qÞand zero otherwise and the
Under the expectation that two cointegrating vectors are estab-
first k observation of Ej,t is set to zero; Ej,t is the effective sample
lished in the system, at least two restrictions per cointegrating
of the jth period. The indicator variable Dj,ti is a dummy variable
vector are required for exact identification of the long-run relation-
for the ith observation in the jth period—that is Dj,ti ¼ 1 if ships (Pesaran and Shin, 2002). In this case, linear restrictions can be
t ¼ T j1 þ i ðj ¼ 2,. . .,q, t ¼ . . .,1,0,1,. . .Þand zero otherwise. Inter- employed to identify the long-run relationships in terms of eco-
vention dummies, W m,t ðm ¼ 1,. . .,dÞ, are included to make the nomic expectations. The following describes the long-run coefficient
residuals well-behaved, following Hendry and Mizon (1993). The matrix for r ¼ 2, q ¼ 3 and Hl ðrÞ
vector b is the cointegrating vector and represents the long-run " #0 " #
b b1prmdl b1ntxpt b1f ravg g11 g12 g13
relationship, a is a vector representing the speeds of adjustment
h i g
¼
b2prmdl b2ntxpt b2f ravg g21 g22 g23 : ð10Þ
toward the long-run equilibrium, and g ¼ g1 g2 . . . gq is a
matrix of ðp  qÞ dimensional long-run trend parameters. The By identifying the long-run equations, correctly estimated
short-run parameters are m of order ðp  qÞ, Gi of order ðp  qÞ for parameters can be interpreted as long-run elasticities, as all of
i ¼ 1,. . .,k, Cj,i of order ðq  1Þ for j ¼ 2,. . .,q and i ¼ 1,. . .,k, and Fm the variables are used in logarithmic form (Johansen, 2005).
of order ðq  1Þ for m ¼ 1,. . .,d. The innovations et are assumed to
be independently and identically distributed with zero mean and 3.3. Empirical Results
symmetric and positive definite variance–covariance matrix
O—that is, et  iidð0, OÞ. As mentioned in the data and methodology section, we begin
Eq. (3), which is a linear trend model in which the trend and the empirical analysis by testing for (non)stationarity properties
the level of cointegration relationship changes from period to of the series using Lee and Strazicich (2003, 2004) unit root tests.
period, is represented asHl ðrÞ. The likelihood ratio test against an Before testing the (non)stationarity properties of the series,
174 - etin, K. Yasin Eryigit / Transport Policy 25 (2013) 169–177
T. C

sharp declines in the demand for taxi service in New York City.
A total of 6800 taxi licenses, almost 75% of the taxi fleet in the
city, were sold to individual drivers by their owners. Thus, the
recession led to a structural break in medallion prices in 1967. In
addition to the terrorist attacks in 2001, we also estimate that the
economic slowdown in New York City that began a few months
before the September 11 terrorist attacks to be a structural break
in medallion prices in 200112 . Accordingly, the economic slow-
down reduced medallion prices between the spring of 1998 and
mid-2001 (Schaller, 2006). However, after 1967 and 2001, medal-
lion prices continued to rise. Under these circumstances, we can
infer that medallion prices are sensitive to economic fluctuations
like other investment assets13 , although medallion prices have
showed a very strong upward trend since 1950.
Additionally, 1980 and 2003 are clearly structural breaks in
the number of taxies per thousand people. We estimate that the
reasons for the structural break in 1980 are the decline in the
number of medallions from 1964 to 1996 and the increase in New
York City’s population after 1980. As mentioned above, the
number of medallions declined from 13,566 in 1937 to 11,787
in 1980, and this figure remained constant until 1996. Further-
more, the population declined from 7,894,862 in 1970 to
7,071,639 in 1980 and then rose, reaching 7,322,564 in 1990
and 8,008,278 in 2000. This increase in the population caused a
Fig. 1. Time graphs of the series.
decrease and a structural break in the number of taxies per
thousand people in 1980. After 1980, the number of taxies per
thousand people continued to decline until 2003 because the
population continued to rise, and entry to the market has not
Table 4 been deregulated. Instead, nine auctions have taken place since
Lee and Strazicich (2003, 2004) unit root test results. 2004, and a total of 1109 medallions were gradually released
through these auctions, although 400 new medallions were
Series Model Lag Break times l t-statistics Critical values
issued by auctions in 1996 and 1997. For that reason, we estimate
that this gradual increase in the number of medallions results in a
prmdl
t
C 7 1967 2001 0.3 0.8  4.48  5.65n
structural break in the number of taxies per thousand people
ntxpt
t
C 10 1980 2003 0.5 0.8  5.56  5.73
ravg after 2003.
ff C 0 1970 2003 0.4 0.8  3.75  5.65
The empirical analysis shows that 1970 and 2003 were
n
Critical values at the 5% significance level were obtained from Lee and structural breaks in real average taxi fares. We argue that the
Strazicich (2003, 2004). reason for the structural break in taxi fares in 1970 is the oil crisis
of 1970, which particularly affected the United States. Accord-
ingly, the oil crisis of 1970 caused high taxi fares during the 1970s
however, it is useful to plot the variables individually over time. by triggering inflation, although fares declined after 1970 until
Fig. 1 shows the time plots of real taxi medallion prices, the 2003. The findings show another structural break for taxi fares in
number of taxies per thousand people and real average taxi fares 2003, which shifts the trend in taxi fares. We estimate that the
for New York City. reason for this structural break in taxi fares is the dramatic
As we can see from Fig. 1, real taxi medallion prices have a increase in average taxi fares from $6.85 to $8.65 that took place
positive trend over time. However, the number of taxies per in May 200414.
thousand people had a negative trend in the 1981–2003 period, Fig. 2 represents the time plots of the series with structural
while it had a positive trend for the 1947–1980 and 2004–2010 breaks. The shaded areas in the diagrams cover the inter-
periods. Additionally, the real average taxi fare series was rela- break data.
tively stable until it jumped in 1971. However, the trend of taxi After investigating the (non)stationarity properties of the
fares was negative in 1971–2003 period, while it has been series, cointegration between the variables for the 1967–2001
positive in the post-2004 period. break pair was tested using the Johansen et al. (2000) cointegra-
Before performing the Johanse et al. (2000) cointegration tion procedure. The minimum value of the Akaike Information
procedure, we tested the (non)stationarity properties of the series Criterion (AIC) was adopted to select the optimum lag length, and
in the presence of structural breaks using Lee and Strazicich the lag length was estimated to be k ¼ 3. Table 5 presents the
(2003, 2004) minimum LM unit root tests with one and two results of the Johansen et al. (2000) trace statistics for the 1967–
breaks. The unit root test results are reported in Table 4. 2001 break pair.
From Table 4, we can see that all variables are non-stationary
in their levels. Additionally, Table 4 indicates that 1967 and 2001
were estimated to be structural breaks in real medallion prices,
which can be associated with the slowed economic growth in the 12
Taxi ridership declined by 3% due to the economic downturn in New York
US in 1967 and the September 11 terrorist attacks in 2001. City in 2001 (Schaller, 2006).
13
Accordingly, we estimate that the slowed growth in 1967 and The medallion’s value to its owner can be assessed in a manner similar to
an investment in the stock market. Accordingly, economic fluctuations will affect
the terrorist attacks and the subsequent recession in New York the prices of the medallions (Cumming, 2009).
City in 2001 reduced medallion prices. As noted by Schaller 14
This increase in taxi fares does not include any surcharges. For a more
(2006), the recession in the late 1960s and early 1970s led to detailed discussion of the fare increase in 2004, see Schaller (2006).
- etin, K. Yasin Eryigit / Transport Policy 25 (2013) 169–177
T. C 175

The LR-statistics of the VECM restriction tests for the 1967–2001


pair of breaks are reported in Table 6.
Table 6 shows that, for the 1967–2001 break pair, each
variable remains in the cointegration space. This implies that
stationarities come from linear combinations of the variables with
broken level and trend. In addition, the lower panel of Table 6
shows that the number of taxies per thousand people is weakly
exogenous, while the others are endogenous.
Because two cointegrating vectors are established in the
system, at least two restrictions per cointegrating vector are
required for the exact identification of the long-run relationships.
To identify the long-run relationships for the Hl ðrÞmodel, we
employed the restrictions below in terms of our economic
expectations as follows:
" #0 " #
b 1 b1ntxpt 0 g11 g12 g13
¼ ð11Þ
g b2prmdl 0 1 g21 g22 g23

In the restrictions matrix above, the first line of restrictions


implies that real average taxi fares are set equal to zero in the real
medallion prices equation. The second required restriction
isbprmdl ¼ 1, which indicates that the medallion prices are nor-
malized. The second row normalizes real average taxi fares to
negative one, with the number of taxies per thousand constrained
to zero.
Fig. 2. Time graphs of the series with structural breaks.
By identifying the long-run equations correctly, these esti-
mates can be interpreted as long-run elasticities (Johansen, 2005).
Table 7 reports the identified long-run equations and identifica-
Table 5 tion test results17 .
Johansen et al. (2000) trace statistics for pair of breaks 1967–2001.
The upper panel of Table 7 shows that the number of taxies
H 0 ðH 1 Þ Model Hl ðrÞ has a negative effect on real medallion prices, with a 1% decrease
in the number of taxies resulting in a 0.45% increase in medallion
r ¼ 0 ðr Z 1Þ 121.46 (70.96)n prices. In the average taxi fares equation, real medallion prices
r ¼ 1 ðr Z 2 Þ 51.77 (45.52) have a positive effect on taxi fares, with a 1% increase in
r ¼ 2 ðr Z 3 Þ 18.51 (23.57)
medallion prices resulting in a 0.12% increase in fares.
n
Critical values in parentheses at the 95% confidence level can be approxi-
mated by G-distribution, as explained in Johansen et al. (2000).
4. Conclusion

By developing a cointegration model with structural breaks to


Table 6 investigate the effects of government regulation, this paper
VECM-restriction tests statistics for 1967–2001 pair of breaks.
provides a unique empirical support for the regulatory economics
Null hypotheses H0 LR-statistics
literature. We can interpret the findings as follows. First, our
innovative model presents strong evidence suggesting that
regulation induces adverse effects in the case of the New York
Individual exclusion of: taxicab market. Given a negative and inelastic relationship
prmdl
t bprmdl ¼ 0 16.03 (0.00)n between the number of medallions and medallion prices, once
ntxpt
t
bntxpt ¼ 0 10.36 (0.00)
market entry is restricted, there is a positive and inelastic
ravg
ft bf ravg ¼ 0 40.23 (0.00)
relationship between medallion prices and taxi fares. In other
words, regulation causes an increase in medallion prices, and this
Weak exogeneity of: increase in medallion prices drives up taxi fares when the number
prmdl
t
aprmdl ¼ 0 13.89 (0.00) of taxies is restricted by government regulation. In that case, we
ntxpt
t
antxpt ¼ 0 3.72 (0.15) can infer that government regulation in the New York taxicab
ravg
ft af ravg ¼ 0 50.81 (0.00)
market causes an artificial or monopolistic rent through medal-
n
Marginal significance levels are in parentheses. lion prices for medallion owners, who constitute an interest
group, in keeping with the economic theory of regulation.
Additionally, taxi fares are regulated in favor of the regulated
Table 5 shows the two cointegrating vectors ðr ¼ 2Þ for the industry because government regulation gives rise to higher fares
model Hl ðrÞ, implying changes in level and trend in the long- than what would emerge in the absence of such regulation. In this
run.15 Because the residuals obtained from the models are context, we have found empirical evidence that is consistent with
normally distributed, intervention dummies were not required.16

17
Two types of restriction matrices can be tested here. However, the first
15
To select between modelsHl ðrÞ and Hc ðrÞ, the trend polynomial test was restriction matrix, the one implying real medallion prices placed at the right side
applied and Hl ðrÞ was found to be the appropriate model. of the second equation, is not rejected; while the other matrix, in which the real
16
Multivariate normality test statistics for skewness, kurtosis and joint are average prices placed at the right side of the second equation, is. Therefore, only
0.92 (p-value ¼ 0.46), 3.41 (p-value ¼ 0.07) and 7.07 (p-value¼ 0.22), respectively. test results of the first restriction matrix and the identified long-run equations
These results imply that the model is normally distributed. were reported in this study.
176 - etin, K. Yasin Eryigit / Transport Policy 25 (2013) 169–177
T. C

Table 7
Identified long-run and adjustment coefficients matrices and identification test result.

Identified equations bprmdl bntxpt bf ravg g1 g2 g3 aprmdl antxpt af ravg w2ð2Þ

Medallion prices 1  0.46 0 0.07 0.03 0.10  0.46 – – 5.58


Average fares 0.12 0 1 –0.02 –0.04 0.11 – – 0.51 p-value ¼0.06

both the approaches and findings of the theoretical and empirical market, and our model could be run to estimate the effects of
literature regarding the effects of government regulation. government regulation in other markets with different regulatory
Second, in the case of the New York taxicab market, we regimes.
estimate that a 1% decrease in the number of taxis in the market
causes a 0.45% increase or artificial rent over real medallion
prices. This result can be interpreted as the long-run elasticity References
of medallion prices. Accordingly, real medallion prices respond
negatively to a change in the number of taxis, real medallion Barrett, S.D., 2003. Regulatory capture, property rights and taxi deregulation: a
case study. Economic Affairs 23, 34–40.
prices decline by approximately 0.45% to a 1% increase in the Baumol, J., 1977. On the proper cost tests for natural monopoly in a multiproduct
number of taxis. This evidence coincides with both the arguments industry. American Economic Review 67, 809–822.
of our model and the literature, which asserts that entry regula- Baumol, J., 1982. Contestable markets: an uprising in the theory of industry
structure. American Economic Review 7, 1–15.
tion increases the regulated good’s (the medallion’s) price. Becker, Gary, 1983. A theory of competition among pressure groups for political
Third, the findings show that the elasticity of taxi fares (the influence. Quarterly Journal of Economics 98, 371–400.
sensitivity of taxi fares) to changes in medallion prices is 0.12. Beesley, M., Glaister, S., 1983. Information for regulating: the case of taxis. The
Economic Journal 93, 594–615.
Accordingly, we estimate that a 1% increase in real medallion Bekken, J.-T., 2007. Experiences with (de)regulation in the european taxi ındustry
prices causes a 0.12% increase in taxi fares. This evidence can also (De)regulation of Taxi Industry. OECD, Paris, pp. 31–58.
be interpreted as the long-run elasticity of taxi fares. Braeutigam, R., 1989. Optimal policies for natural monopolies. In: Schmalensee,
Richard, Willig, D. (Eds.), Handbook of Industrial Organization. . Elsevier
Fourth, an important contribution that our analysis makes to
Science Publishers, Amsterdam, pp. 1289–1346.
the literature is that the model estimates structural breaks in - etin, Tamer, Eryigit, Y., 2011. Estimating the effects of entry regulation in the
C
medallion prices, taxi fares, and the number of taxies per istanbul taxicab market. Transportation Research Part A 45, 476–484.
- etin, Tamer, Oğuz, Fuat, 2010. The effects of economic regulation in the istanbul
C
thousand people. We find structural breaks in real medallion
taxicab market. Economic Affairs 30, 59–64.
prices in 1967 and 2001, in the number of taxies per thousand Cumming, Dan, 2009. Why has the price of taxi medallions increased so
people in 1980 and 2003, and in taxi fares in 1970 and 2003. The dramatically?: an analysis of the taxi medallion market. The Park Place
estimates regarding structural breaks show that medallion prices, Economist 17, 12–17.
Darbera, Richard, 2007. When the regulator acknowledges the existences of two
taxi fares, and the number of taxies per thousand people fluctuate distinct markets for taxi services(De)regulation of Taxi Industry. OECD, Paris,
with changes in economic conditions. The most important of pp. 117–132.
these estimates for the relevant literature are the structural Dawson, P.J., Sanjuan, A.I., 2005. Structural breaks, the export enhancement
program and the relationship between canadian and us hard wheat prices.
breaks in medallion prices. Because structural breaks in medallion Journal of Agricultural Economics 57, 101–116.
prices show that medallion prices are sensitive to economic Demsetz, Harold, 1968. Why regulate utilities. Journal of Law and Economics 11,
fluctuations, medallions are used as market investment tools by 55–65.
Domas, M Hantke, 2003. The public ınterest theory of regulation: non-existence or
their owners. misinterpretation? European Journal of Law and Economics 15, 165–194.
Fifth, if we compare the findings in this paper for the case of Eckert, D., 1970. The los angeles taxi monopoly: an economic inquiry. Southern
New York with the findings of our earlier paper on the Istanbul California Law Review 43, 407–453.
Frankena, W., Pautler, A., 1984. An economic analysis of taxicab regulation. Federal
taxicab market, we understand that the effects of a strict regula- Trade Commission, Washington, D.C.
tion case as in Istanbul differentiate from a partial deregulation Friedman, Milton, 2008. Price Theory. Transaction Publishers, USA.
case as in New York. Whereas the case of Istanbul is a strict Guasch, J., Luis, Hahn, W., 1999. The costs and benefits of regulation: implication
for developing countries. The World Bank Research Observer 14, 137–158.
regulation one due to entry into the market has been hindered
Guri, F., 2003. An economic analysis of regulated taxicab markets. Review of
since 1991, the New York taxicab market is a partial deregulation Industrial Organization 23, 255–266.
case. Accordingly, whereas a 1% decrease in the number of taxis in Guri, F., 2005. Local exclusive cruising regulation and efficiency in taxicab markets.
Istanbul as the case of the strict regulation brings about a 0.71% Journal of Transport Economics and Policy 39, 155–166.
Harris, L., 2002. Taxicab economics: the freedom to contract for a ride. Georgetown
increase in real medallion prices18, a 1% decrease in the number of Journal of Law and Public Policy 1, 195–222.
taxis in New York as the case of the partial deregulation causes a Harris, R., Sollis, R., 2003. Applied Time Series Modeling and Forecasting. John
0.45% increase in real medallion prices. Similarly, a 1% increase in Wiley and Sons, Sussex.
Hendry, D.F., Mizon, G.E., 1993. Evaluating dynamic econometric models by
real medallion prices as a result of government regulation leads to encompassing the VAR. In: Phillips, P.C.P. (Ed.), Models, Methods and Applica-
0.32% and 0.12% increase in taxi fares in Istanbul and New York, tions of Econometrics. Basil Blackwell, Oxford, pp. 272–300.
respectively. The findings show that the regulated taxi fares and Heyes, Anthony, Heyes, L., 2007. Regulation of the taxi ındustry: some economic
background(De)regulation of Taxi Industry. OECD, Paris, pp. 91–113.
medallion prices in the case of the partial deregulation are less Ippolito, A., 1979. The effects of price regulation in the automobile insurance
sensitive to government regulation, while they are more sensitive industry. Journal of Law and Economics 22, 55–89.
to regulatory interventions in the case of the strict regulation. Jarrell, Gregg, 1978. The demand for state regulation of the electric utility industry.
Journal of Law and Economics 21, 269–295.
Finally, all of these findings are not well-known results in the Johansen, Sander, 1988. Statistical analysis of cointegration vectors. Journal of
literature. This means that this evidence is a novel contribution to Economic Dynamics and Control 12, 231–254.
the study of government regulation. For that reason, the findings Johansen, Sander, 2005. The interpretation of cointegrating coefficients in the
cointegrated vector autoregressive model. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and
of the paper can be used to decide a probable policy change
Statistics 67, 93–104.
concerning the regulatory process in the New York taxicab Johansen, Sander, R. Mosconi, and B. Nielsen. 2000. Cointegration analysis in the
presence of structural breaks in the deterministic trend. Econometrics Journal
3:s 216–249.
Joskow, L., Rose, L., 1989. Economic regulation and its effects. In: Schmalensee,
18
- etin and Eryigit (2011) for more detailed information about the case of
See C Richard, Willig, D. (Eds.), Handbook of Industrial Organization. Elsevier Science
Istanbul. Publishers, Amsterdam, pp. 1450–1505.
- etin, K. Yasin Eryigit / Transport Policy 25 (2013) 169–177
T. C 177

Kahn, Alfred, 1998. The Economics of Regulation: Principles and Institutions. The Posner, Richard, 1975. The social costs of monopoly and regulation. Journal of
MIT Press, Cambridge. Political Economy 83, 807–828.
Kitch, W., Isaacson, Marc, Kasper, Daniel, 1971. The regulation of taxicabs in Schaller, Bruce, 2006. The New York City Taxicab Fact Book. Schaller Consulting,
chicago. Journal of Law and Economics 14, 285–350. New York.
Koehler, Benedikt, 2005. License values in taxi markets. Economic Affairs 25, Schaller, Bruce, Gilbert, Gorman, 1996a. Villain or Bogeyman? New York’s taxi
52–54. medallion system. Transportation Quarterly 50, 91–103.
Laffont, -J., Tirole, Jean, 1991. The politics of government decision- making: a Schaller, Bruce, Gilbert, Gorman, 1996b. Fixing New York city taxi service.
theory of regulatory capture. Quarterly Journal of Economics 106, 1089–1127. Transportation Quarterly 50, 85–96.
Lee, J., Strazicich, M.C., 2003. Minimum lagrange multiplier unit root test with two Schmidt, P., Phillips, P.C.B., 1992. LM Tests for a unit root in the presence of
structural breaks. Review of Economics and Statistics 85, 1082–1089. deterministic trends. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics 54, 257–287.
Lee, J., Strazicich, M.C. 2004. Minimum LM unit root test with one structural break. Seibert, Christian, 2006. Taxi deregulation and transaction costs. Economic Affairs
Working Paper. 26, 71–73.
Moore, T., Balaker, Ted, 2006. Do economists reach a conclusion on taxi dereg- Shreiber, Chanoch, 1975. The economic reasons for price and entry regulation of
ulation. Economic Journal Watch 3, 109–132.
taxicabs. Journal of Transport Economics and Policy 9, 268–279.
Noll, Roger, 1989. The politics of regulation. In: Schmalensee, Richard, Willig, D.
Stigler, George, 1971. Theory of economic regulation. Bell Journal of Economics
(Eds.), Handbook of Industrial Organization. Elsevier Science Publishers,
and Management Sciences 2, 1–21.
Amsterdam, pp. 1253–1287.
Stigler, George, Friedland, Claire, 1962. What can regulators regulate? the case of
OECD, 2007. (De)regulation of Taxi Industry. OECD, Paris.
electricity. Journal of Law and Economics 5, 1–15.
Ogus, Anthony, 1994. Regulation: Legal Form and Economic Theory. Oxford
Svorny, Shirley, 1999. Licensing, Market Entry Regulation Encyclopedia of Law and
University Press, Oxford.
Orr, Daniel, 1969. The taxicab problem: a proposed solution. The Journal of Economics. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, pp. 296–328.
Political Economy 77, 141–147. Teal, F., Berglund, Mary, 1987. The impacts of taxicab deregulation in the USA.
Pagano, Anthony, McKnight, Claire, 1983. Economies of scale in the taxicab Journal of Transport Economics and Policy 21, 37–56.
industry: some empirical evidence from the united states. Journal of Trans- TLC 2007. Annual Report, TLC, New York, /http://www.nyc.govS.
portation Economics and Policy 17, 299–313. TLC 2008. Annual Report, TLC, New York, /http://www.nyc.govS.
Parker, David, 2002. Economic regulation: a review Issues. Annals of Publics and TLC 2009. Annual Report, TLC, New York, /http://www.nyc.govS.
Cooperative Economics 73, 493–519. TLC 2010. Annual Report, TLC, New York, /http://www.nyc.govS.
Peltzman, Sam, 1976. Toward a more general theory of regulation. Journal of Law TLC 2011. Annual Report, TLC, New York, /http://www.nyc.govS.
and Economics 19, 211–240. Tullock, Gordon, 1975. The transitional gains. The Bell Journal of Economics 6,
Peltzman, Sam, 1993. George Stigler’s contribution to the economic analysis of 671–678.
regulation. Journal of Political Economy 101, 818–832. Turvey, Ralph, 1961. Some economic features of the London cab trade.
Perron, P., 1989. The great crash, the oil price shock, and the unit root hypothesis. The Economic Journal 71, 79–92.
Econometrica 57, 1361–1401. Viscusi, W., Kip, M., Vernon, Harrington, E., 1998. Economics of Regulation and
Pesaran, M.H., Shin, Y., 2002. Long-run structural modeling. Econometric Reviews Antitrust, 4th Ed. M.I.T. Press, USA.
21, 49–87.

Das könnte Ihnen auch gefallen