Sie sind auf Seite 1von 17

746012

research-article2017
JTRXXX10.1177/0047287517746012Journal of Travel Researchde la Peña et al.

Empirical Research Article

Journal of Travel Research

A New Tool for the Analysis of the


1­–17
© The Author(s) 2017
Reprints and permissions:
International Competitiveness of Tourist sagepub.com/journalsPermissions.nav
DOI: 10.1177/0047287517746012
https://doi.org/10.1177/0047287517746012

Destinations Based on Performance journals.sagepub.com/home/jtr

Mario Raúl de la Peña1, Juan A. Núñez-Serrano2,3,


Jaime Turrión2,3, and Francisco J. Velázquez3,4

Abstract
This article presents a new tool for the analysis of the international competitiveness of tourist destinations based on the
evolution of tourist inflows. For this purpose, an adaptation of the conditional β-convergence to the tourist sector is
proposed. Beyond the analysis of the growth rate of tourist flows, which is not comparable among countries, some of the
specificities of this sector are considered in the competitive analysis, such as the different sizes of the markets and the
maturity of the destinations, the business cycle, and so on. UNWTO data for international tourist arrivals and tourism
receipts for up to 214 destinations and the period 1995 to 2016 are used to analyze the evolution of the competitiveness of
major international tourist regions and some of the world’s leading tourist destinations. The results show the potential of the
proposed tool for analyzing tourism competitiveness by offering a diagnosis in the short, medium and long terms.

Keywords
tourism competitiveness, tourist flows, tourism performance, tourism area life cycle, conditional β-convergence

Theoretical and methodological aspects along with empirical consumer needs to be moved to the place of production.
applications that focus on the analysis of the competitiveness Thus, the impact of consumption and production happens in
of tourist destinations have become important in recent the same place, so that the impact of tourism on the destina-
decades as a result of the rise of tourism as an increasingly tion becomes, in turn, a determining factor for the future
important sector on a global and strategic level for many (Garau 2007; Seyoum 2007). As a consequence, to make an
countries (Hong 2008). Still, there are many authors who adequate diagnosis of competitiveness in this sector, it is
claim that this is an issue of great complexity, as it involves important in the analysis to take into consideration the period
a broad and complex set of aspects which are difficult to inte- in which impacts occur. In addition, the size of the tourism
grate theoretically and gather in objective specific measure- sector in each destination (country) depends on both the
ments to be considered (Waheeduzzan and Ryans 1996; physical size of the country itself and its attractiveness,
Jiménez and Aquino 2012; Gooroochurn and Sugiyarto 2005 which has made performance-based competitive diagnosis
and Claver-Cortés, Molina-Azorín, and Pereira-Moliner focus on the analysis of the evolution of its flows (growth
2007). Thus, Hong (2008), reviewing an important part of rates) rather than its levels.
the literature on the subject, indicates that there is still no But it is common for these analyses not to take into consid-
commonly accepted and standardized definition of tourism eration the product cycle of each destination or tourism
competitiveness. In this sense, the vision that has greater model. Novel or renewed attractive destinations have higher
practical acceptance is derived from the analysis of perfor- growth rates than those that have been in the international
mance in the sector (tourist arrivals, tourism receipts, etc.),
as well as from its similarity to the flows of goods (exports), 1
Universidad de Holguín, Holguin, Cuba
2
despite being of less theoretical appeal (Bolaky 2008). Universidad Autónoma de Madrid, Madrid, Spain
3
From this perspective, the international competitiveness Group for Research on Productivity, Innovation and Competitiveness
(GRIPICO), Spain
of a tourist destination could be defined as its ability to attract 4
Universidad Complutense de Madrid, Madrid, Spain
nonresident tourists (d’Hauteserre 2000; Ritchie and Crouch
2000; Enright and Newton 2004; Hong 2008; Dupeyras and Corresponding Author:
Juan A. Núñez-Serrano, Department of Applied Economics, Faculty of
MacCallum 2013). However, this definition cannot be Economics and Business, Universidad Autónoma de Madrid, Francisco
applied without further analysis to traditional tourism perfor- Tomás y Valiente, 5-28049, Madrid, Spain.
mance indicators since this activity is a service where the Email: juanandres.nunnez@uam.es
2 Journal of Travel Research 00(0)

tourist market for a long time without changes (Butler 1980, incorporate a broad set of cultural, physical, socioeconomic,
2011; Buhalis 2000). Similarly, each specific tourism product and environmental determinants and impacts, but does not
has its own maturation cycle. Thus, a specific destination may consider any indicator of performance of the analyzed tour-
change its position in the product cycle if it is able to change ism sector. Some of these articles are focused on the weight-
its product mix, discontinuing those more mature products ing system or the statistical or econometric procedure with
and incorporating the newest (Bolaky 2008). Indeed, as which all these variables can be condensed into an index or
Crouch (2011) notes, diagnostic difficulties have prompted ranking of competitiveness (Cvelbar et al. 2016; Martín,
the analysis of the competitiveness of international tourism to Mendoza, and Román 2017; World Economic Forum 2017).
focus on its determinants (structural conditions, tourist attrac- That is why this article focuses on presenting a proposal
tions, tourism policy, etc.). However, while the advantages for an additional competitiveness diagnosis from the per-
and sophistication of these approaches must be recognized, spective of tourism sector performance, where there is a lack
they suffer from some unrealism when considering, on almost of analytical tools. In this sense, the little interest in the anal-
the same level or with an unsupported weighting structure, ysis of the indicators of tourist performance shown by aca-
aspects of the overall economic structure of the country and demics contrasts with the interest both politicians and the
the specific tourist attractions of the destinations (Enright and media have in the performance of tourist flows, with no spe-
Newton 2004). At any rate, this approach based on determi- cific methodological analysis to assess whether a particular
nants must be interpreted from the perspective of the potential volume of tourist flow or growth rate is showing good com-
and not from the effective competitiveness of the tourist des- petitive behavior. Precisely, we propose here a simple meth-
tinations (Bolaky 2009). Finally, Krugman (1994) believes odology that is based on a modification of the measures of
that the analysis of competitiveness should not be limited to economic convergence, which allows for a counterfactual
the ability to produce goods and services that are consumed in that takes into consideration the size, maturity, and evolution
the international market, but should also build sustainable of the international tourism market with which to compare
improvement of the living standards of citizens. the actual behavior of a specific destination.
In the absence of analytical explanatory models, generic For the abovementioned purpose, the next section shows
concepts of competitiveness have given way to conceptual a brief review of the main approaches and models of com-
models developed specifically for the tourism sector. Ritchie petitiveness on the basis of the trilogy: determining factors,
and Crouch (2000) have probably been the most influential performance and impacts where the absence of specific lit-
authors on this issue and their merit is being pioneers in inte- erature focused on the analysis of the performance indicators
grating the international trade and Porterian theories related is verified, although all the agents in the sector point out their
to business competitiveness. As a result, they provide a most relevance. Then, the third section presents our methodologi-
comprehensive definition of tourism competitiveness: the cal proposal based on the estimation of a conditional conver-
ability of a destination to create and to stably and sustainably gence equation where the foundation and implications of the
increase national welfare by managing benefits, attractive proposal and its suitability for the analysis of the main indi-
prices, trustfulness, and proximity within a certain economic cators of international tourism performance are also
and social model. explained. The fourth section presents the main results of
However, in this context, it is important to have not only applying this methodology to aggregated UNWTO data on
a complete definition of tourism competitiveness, but also international tourist arrivals for 214 countries and interna-
adequate and specific measures that capture both the com- tional tourism receipts for 203 countries during the period
plexity and the particular aspects to be considered in its mea- 1995 to 2016. This article ends with its main conclusions and
surement. Thus, reviewing the literature of the last two final considerations.
decades shows evidence that the competitiveness analyses
have focused on indirect measurement, especially through
Literature Review
their determinants. Sometimes, the selected variables are
weakly linked to the competitiveness of this sector and a The approaches and models of tourism competitiveness con-
clear methodology for selecting indicators is not always sider three distinct elements to establish a diagnosis on the
offered (Enright and Newton 2004), although there are some competitive situation of a destination: determinants, perfor-
attempts to build an explanatory structural model of the com- mance, and impacts. The determinants of tourism competi-
petitiveness of tourist destinations (Mazanec, Wöber, and tiveness refer to those elements that have a direct influence on
Zins 2007; Assaker el al. 2013). On the contrary, articles the tourist attraction or those that are not necessarily confined
focused on the analysis of the performance (Craigwell 2007; to the tourist sector but have an influence upon performance
Bolaky 2009) and impacts of tourism are rather scarce, espe- and impact (Crouch and Ritchie 1999; Ritchie and Crouch
cially those with regard to its sustainability (Hassan 2000; 2000; Dwyer and Kim 2003; Enright and Newton 2004).
Lundie, Dwyer, and Forsyth 2007). Performance refers to the evolution of the tourist sector out-
In fact, the most recent analysis of tourism competitive- puts that can be seen in physical (e.g., number of tourists),
ness considers conceptual or simply empirical models that monetary (e.g., tourism receipts), or qualitative (e.g., average
de la Peña et al. 3

stay or average expenditure per overnight spent at destina- Porter (1980, 1985, 1990), collecting some of these ideas
tion) terms. Finally, impact focuses on the benefits—or and others from industrial organization and management and
harm—for society as a whole like income growth, job cre- strategy literature, also determines a number of elements to
ation, environmental degradation or sustainability, and so on be considered at country and sector levels for competitive
as a result of tourism (Lundie, Dwyer, and Forsyth 2007). analysis. His basic contribution lies in considering the ability
It is evident that better determinants allow for greater per- of different economies or firms to manage the factor endow-
formance in the sector, but society as a whole also gains a ments in the most efficient possible way. Moreover, estab-
greater benefit through promoting economic growth and lishing policies of regeneration and incrementing comparative
development (Sinclair 1998; Balaguer and Cantavella-Jordá factors are key elements in competitive development as well
2002). Similarly, better performance pushes entrepreneurs as the ability to create new ones, especially intangibles. This
and governments to improve determinants (e.g., human capi- aspect of competitive advantage is not linked to an initial
tal, transport infrastructure, etc.) either through investments factor endowment (factor conditions) and is determined by
or structural changes (Khadaroo and Seetanah 2007). Finally, demand conditions, related and supporting industry, firm
a greater and better impact of tourism on society will lead to strategy and structure and rivalry. It finally introduces an
a greater willingness for public investment to improve the opportunity element that can positively or negatively con-
determinants. In this sense, the perception of population hos- tribute to a country’s competitiveness, which will constitute
pitality constitutes a crucial element for future performance its environmental conditions.
(Andereck and Vogt 2000), and ultimately, this will mean This set of theories from trade in goods and business com-
better performance. But it is also true that better tourism per- petitiveness, simply outlined here, has been emerging
formance can lead to a worsening of living and environmen- throughout in the tourist sector since the 1990s and has pro-
tal conditions in those destinations where the base of the duced a significant dispersion of ideas and concepts that
tourist model has not taken social context into account. Crouch and Ritchie (1999) and Ritchie and Crouch (2000)
While the classification of all elements influencing tourism try to arrange in the case of a given tourist destination in its
competitiveness in these three aspects is not standard in the conceptual model, as they themselves describe it. These arti-
literature on the subject, it indeed seems appropriate for a cles are considered seminal in the analysis of tourist destina-
critical review of the conceptual theories regarding tourism tion competitiveness and, despite making reference to the
(Table 1). need to incorporate performance and impact in tourist com-
The initial and main aspects of tourism competitiveness petitiveness diagnosis, it continues to have a strong bias
analysis have been developed from the theories of interna- toward determinants.
tional trade (Hong 2008) and Porter’s approach to business In their conceptualization, they differentiate two types
competitiveness (Porter 1980, 1985). Based on these theo- of “lawyers” who may be external and internal to the sec-
ries, considering the peculiarities of the tourism sector, today tor. Among the former, they consider comparative and
there is a conceptual framework for analyzing tourism com- competitive advantages of the economy as a whole that
petitiveness. The seminal article on this topic is attributed to will affect both tourist sectors and other activities, although
Crouch and Richie (1999), who basically have the merit of they might do so differently. However, their greatest con-
having articulated a comprehensive set of determinants as a tribution focuses on grouping internal elements, determi-
kind of eclectic theory of tourism competitiveness. The main nants of tourism basically, into five major aspects: (1)
shortcoming in this regard, as the authors themselves recog- supporting factors and resources, (2) core resources and
nize, is probably the absence of an articulated analytical attractors, (3) destination management, (4) destination pol-
model that would establish concrete relationships among icy, planning, and development, and (5) qualifying and
variables. This deficiency also persists, although to a lesser amplifying determinants. Ultimately, part of the first
extent, in the analysis of the competitiveness of goods trade. (infrastructure and accessibility), second, and fifth ele-
The determinants of competitiveness (which constitute ments (location) refers to specific comparative advantages
the potential competitiveness of a destination) could be in the tourist sector, while the third, fourth, and part of the
grouped, in turn, into three types: comparative advantages first and fifth correspond to competitive advantages. It is
(Ricardian advantages), competitive advantages (Porterian true that, according to these authors, the ultimate goal of
advantages), and environmental conditions. Comparative competitiveness is to increase prosperity of tourist destina-
advantages come from the classical and neoclassical theo- tions with a minimal negative impact, but it is also true that
ries of international trade. Basically, they refer to factor their conceptual model has an evaluative weakness in this
endowments. In turn, they could have two natures: exoge- aspect and therefore prevents the possibility of making
nous or inherited (such as factor endowments and natural comparable studies (Garau 2007).
conditions—Ricardo 1817 and Heckser and Olhin) and This is precisely the fundamental contribution of Dwyer
endogenous or created (knowledge, technology—Lucas and Kim’s (2003) model. Their approach, perhaps less
1988; Romer 1990; Schumpeter 1912; and human capital— complex than the previous one, really revolves around the
Arrow 1962). same aspects, grouping exogenous comparative advantages
4
Table 1.  Main Contributions to Competitiveness in the Tourism Sector.
Competitiveness general theories Competitiveness tourism-specific theories Firm perspective

  Pre-Porter contributions Porter contribution Crouch and Ritchie (1999) Dwyer and Kim ( 2003) Artto (1987) Resource-based

Competitiveness Comparative Exogenous: factor Factor conditions Core resources and Heritage resources Price and nonprice Tangible and intangible
factors or advantages endowments and natural attractors, qualifying and competitiveness resources controlled by
determinants (Ricardian) conditions (Ricardo, and amplifying determinants firms: assets, organizational
Heckser and Olhin) processes, firm attributes,
Endogenous: knowledge Supporting factors and Created resources information and knowledge
(Lucas 1988), technology resources, qualifying and (Barney 1991; Peteraf 1993;
(Romer 1990) and human amplifying determinants Prahalad and Hamel 1990;
capital (Arrow 1962) Wernerfelt 1984)
Competitive Demand conditions, Destination management, Supporting factors,
advantages related and destination policy destination
(Porterian) supporting industry, planning and management, demand
firm strategy and development, qualifying conditions
structure and rivalry and amplifying
determinants
Environmental Chance  
conditions
Performance Tourist performance Tourist performance  
Impacts Development Economic prosperity,  
sustainability
de la Peña et al. 5

into heritage resources and the endogenous comparative A New Tool for Diagnosis of
resources into created resources. Again, the Porterian com- Competitiveness of Tourist
petitive advantages are now grouped into supporting fac-
Destinations Based on International
tors, destination management, and demand conditions, and
this scheme explicitly includes performance and impacts Performance Indicators
(economic prosperity and sustainability). Enright and Despite the limited academic interest, it is common for both
Newton (2004, 2005) are the true architects of the develop- politicians and the media to make a diagnosis of the competi-
ment of specific indicators for evaluating most of the tive situation of a tourist destination based on the evolution
aspects considered in these models. The well-known of some international inbound flow: international tourist
“Travel and Tourism Competitiveness Report” (World arrivals, international tourism receipts, and so on. In any
Economic Forum 2017) is ultimately the result of such case, the analysis of the indicators of performance is comple-
approaches where determinants and impacts are considered mentary to that of the determinants and impacts.
in the analysis of tourism competitiveness, although the However, these level indicators show the size acquired
sector’s performance is ignored. over time by the tourism sector of a specific destination
Some approaches, from the business perspective, have rather than its current competitiveness (Bolaky 2008). Their
offered some ideas about the determinants of competitive- growth rates are more approximate to the concept of com-
ness at the company level but, ultimately, they are incorpo- petitiveness because they indicate the change in time of those
rated in some of the previous conceptualizations. The acquired levels; however, they have the disadvantage of
resource-based view as a basis for the competitive advantage being affected by economic situations that impact interna-
of a firm expresses that competitiveness of enterprises is tional tourism markets. In this regard, a higher-than-average
determined by the tangible and above all intangible resources rate could be considered a gain of competitiveness because it
they control, including assets, organizational processes, firm involves an increase in market share (Dupeyras and
attributes, information, and knowledge (Barney 1991; MacCallum 2013). In fact, a feature of measuring competi-
Peteraf 1993; Prahalad and Hamel 1990; Wernerfelt 1984). tiveness in any destination should be carried out in compari-
Except for assets, other aspects correspond to Porterian com- son with other destinations. That is why many argue that it is
petitive advantages. the differential evolution of market share—measured in
A comprehensive set of authors, taking a widely used terms of some of the variables mentioned above—which
classification in trade on the determinants of competitive- would be a good indicator of tourism competitiveness based
ness, introduced a differentiation price and nonprice com- on performance. However, the evolution of market shares
petitive variant (Artto 1987; Oral 1986, 1993; Oral and also suffers from two problems: differences in physical size
Reisman 1988; Li 2000; Hong 2008; Azzoni and Menezes of the destination (in terms of tourism) and maturity or stage
2009). This is not a new conceptual proposal, but a form of of the product life cycle in which the destination is situated
classification of determinants based on the mechanism by (Butler 2011 and Economic Commission for Latin America
which they act. Price competitiveness is understood as and the Caribbean 2010). It is expected that major destina-
those factors that enable a firm or tourist destination to tions (by area), with greater tourist attractions and a long his-
produce tourist services at lower costs, subsequently tory in this market, have larger market shares. On the other
reflected in lower prices, which should lead to a gain in hand, more mature destinations will have lower-than-aver-
market share (Dwyer, Forsyth, and Rao 1999, 2000, 2002). age growth rates, thus gradually reducing their share in the
The factors operating behind this mechanism are many: international market, but it should not be considered a loss of
from a factor endowment that accommodates the needs of competitiveness. Therefore, competitiveness through tour-
this sector to the implementation of organizational tech- ism performance should analyze whether the development of
niques involving the reduction of costs or prices. tourist flow has separated from the path it should have fol-
Meanwhile, nonprice competitiveness refers to items that lowed depending on the size and maturity that a particular
enable companies to gain a market share in a competitive destination has. Thus, if a destination performs equal or bet-
way other than by price reductions: quality, differentiation ter than expected, then a positive competitiveness diagnosis
of production, distribution channels of production, and so would be established, and the opposite if the flow evolved
on (Tsounta 2008). worse. The main problem for this diagnosis is the difficulty
As can be seen, the debate on tourism competitiveness, of obtaining this alternative or counterfactual path.
although it should have tourism performance as a principle, Now then, this idea of competitiveness resembles the eco-
has focused primarily on its determinants, and recently on its nomic convergence concept: first, because there is a path of
impacts, especially on the environment and its contribution evolution leading to a situation of zero or constant flow
to growth and reducing inequalities. The lack of studies on growth (what is often called steady state); second, because
performance is due to the absence of analytical tools. It is declining growth rates are expected to reach the steady state
precisely this question that arises in the following section unless a structural change occurs or, in our context, the tour-
and gives rise to our contribution. ism model is modified, starting a new path of convergence
6 Journal of Travel Research 00(0)

toward that new steady state. This is the basic assumption However, the prediction made in (2) is obtained from the
that is found in the theory of the tourism area life cycle, value of the tourist inflow in the previous period, so that if it
applied here to the case of the tourist model of each country had presented a worse behavior, away from the path, for the
and not a specific resort or tourist place. Ultimately, there- next period, the model would have predicted higher rates so it
fore, the tourism life cycle area theory implies that the growth would tend to take the estimated trajectory. Now then, a sharp
possibilities of a tourism model are exhausted in the long drop in tourist inflow affecting a specific destination in a
run. However, changes in the model of tourism development period as a result of some exceptional phenomenon or a change
through a reorientation in the markets of origin, the introduc- in the tourism model would not be perceived in the diagnosis
tion of new attractions, changes in the basic structures that of two years later since the model memory is limited to one
support the tourist model (physical and institutional), and period.1 Therefore, there is a possibility that the diagnosis will
changes in tourism promotion policies, including the exter- vary greatly. To avoid these problems in the competitiveness
nal image, can contribute to the emergence of a new cycle of diagnosing and to obtain more structural conclusions on tour-
growth in the tourism sector of a specific destination. ism competitiveness based on performance, some variants that
The third and final reason is because some concrete con- consider different time spans are proposed below. Also, a com-
vergence measures allow control of the global economic petitiveness index based on performance for international
cycle. In addition, the concept of conditional convergence tourism can be obtained for comparison between actual per-
would take into account the structural differences between formance and counterfactual scenarios.
economies (size, tourism model, etc.). The empirical transla-
tion of a conditional convergence equation to the evolution
of tourist inflows would come by the expression:
Short-Term Competitiveness Based on
Performance
lnFit − lnFit −1 = α i + δ t + β lnFit −1 (1) In this case, the tourist inflow is predicted as in equation (2)
and the short-term international tourism competitiveness
On the left side of the equation, there is the logarithmic indicator based on performance for year t and country i (ST_
difference in levels of tourist inflow (proxy for the growth ITCIit) is calculated by comparing the actual and counterfac-
rate). β reflects the relationship between levels of tourist tual flows of the form:
inflow in the previous period and growth rate, which is
expected to be negative because of depletion of the destina- Fit − Fit
ST _ ITCI it = x100 (3)
tion or evolution of its life cycle. On the other hand, αi takes Fit
up the idea of the existence of a different size of the tourism
where Fit is the actual tourist inflow for year t for country i
sector in each destination as well as a different tourism model
and Fit is the counterfactual inflow obtained in equation (2).
(country effect). It can also pick up the attraction of every
destination. δt reflects the conjunctural and cyclical influ-
ences affecting the international tourism market (year effect). Medium-Term Competitiveness Based on
Consequently, the estimation of equation (1) would pro- Performance
vide predictions of growth rates, so that it becomes a bench-
mark with which to compare actual behavior. This prediction To make the diagnosis of competitiveness based on perfor-
could also therefore be obtained for tourist inflow on the mance in the medium term, its counterfactual is calculated
basis of the value in t-1, using equation (1), to obtain: for each year using equation (2) but iteratively chained from
five periods before and always considering the three-year
Fit = e
α +δ ( )
 i t + 1+β lnFit −1
(2) totally right decentered moving average instead of annual
inflows. Thus, to calculate the counterfactual value for year
Therefore, once tourist inflow information is available for t, the calculation must be started from t-5 as follows:
period t, the model can be reestimated and predictions can be
it −5 = Fit −7 + Fit −6 + Fit −5
t-5: F
compared with actual data, thus establishing a diagnosis of
3
tourist competitiveness for that period. Accordingly, the pro-
cedure compares the projected path for a destination, esti- (δ +δt −5 +δt − 4 ) + 1+β F
( )
t −6

mated from the average evolution of all destinations in the t-4:  α +i it −5

Fit −4 = e 3
world, compared to the observed flow for that destination,
taking into account structural conditions, maturity, size,
(δ +δt − 4 +δt −3 ) + 1+β F
t-3: ( )
t −5
development, the tourism model, and so on, expressed in the i
it −3 = eα + it − 4

country effect and cyclical effect through the year effect. On F 3

the other hand, the analysis is comparative, as the counter- ..


factual scenario is constructed using information from all ..
tourist destinations. ..
de la Peña et al. 7

( δ t −12 +δ t −11 +δ t −10 +δ t −9 +δ t −8 ) + 1+β F


t-8:  α + i ( ) it −9

Fit −8 = e 5

..
..
..
(δ +δt −3 +δt − 2 +δt −1 +δt ) + 1+β F
( ) (6)
t −4
i
itLT = eα + it −1

F 5

thus, defining the indicator of long-term tourism competi-


tiveness based on performance for country i and year t (LT_
ITCIit) in the form:
Fit5TRDMA − FitLT
LT _ ITCI it = x100 (7)
itLT
F

5TRDMA Fit −4 + Fit −3 + Fit −2 + Fit −1 + Fit


where: Fit =
5
On the other hand, according to De la Fuente (1998),
equation (1) implies the existence of a “steady state” or equi-
librium level in the tourist inflow as long as the tourism
Figure 1.  Calculation of the counterfactural in the case of
model remains unchanged. Assuming that β is negative,
medium-term diagnosis of international tourism competitiveness
based on performance. TRDMA = totally right decentered equation (1) indicates a certain level of tourist inflow from
moving average. which the growth rate is zero; this would be its steady-state
situation. To calculate such a level, it is sufficient to set the
right side of the equation (1) equal to zero, that is, to assume
(δ +δt −1 +δt ) + 1+β F that the growth rate is zero,
( ) (4)
t −2
α + i
t:  MT it −1

Fit = e 3

α i + δ t + β lnFit −1 = 0 (8)
To obtain the medium-term international tourist competi-
tiveness indicator based on performance for year t and coun- so that:
try i (MT_ITCIit), the counterfactual obtained is thus
−α i −δ t
compared with the three-year totally right decentered mov- (9)
β
ing average of actual flow (see Figure 1): Fi e = e

it MT This expresses the maximum expected level of tourist


Fit3TRDMA − F
MT _ ITCI it = MT
x100 (5) flow for country i under current conditions that would only
it
F oscillate under certain circumstances. Therefore, once this
state is calculated for all countries, their potential growth can
Fit −2 + Fit −1 + Fit be obtained by comparing this level of inflow with the cur-
where: Fit3TRDMA =
3 rent level. Likewise, if you get that αi is different among
countries, then it would indicate, as expected, that the size of
Long-Term Competitiveness Based on the tourism sector also tends to be different among them.
Performance
The calculation procedure for long-term analysis is similar to Results
that used for the medium term, except that a wider period of
The analysis of international tourism competitiveness based
ten years for the iterative process and wider moving averages
on performance is to be carried out on the information of the
(five years) are used; that is, the procedure begins ten periods
two main performance indicators: international tourist arriv-
earlier and chain-estimated to find the counterfactual for
als (ITAs) and international tourism receipts (ITRs). An
each year, namely:
international tourist is a nonresident visitor who stays at least
 Fit −14 + Fit −13 + Fit −12 + Fit −11 + Fit −10 overnight at a destination (UNWTO 2017).2 Data for ITAs
t-10: Fit −10 =
5 have been obtained from the World Tourism Organization
(UNWTO) and cover the period 1995 to 2016. Initially, there
( δ + δ t −12 + δ t −11 + δ t −10 + δ t −9 ) + 1+β F is information for 219 countries or territories, although those
( )
t −13
iα+
t-9: F it −9 = e
it −10
5
destinations for which there are fewer than 10 temporal
8 Journal of Travel Research 00(0)

original observations have been excluded. The final sample functions shown in Figure 2 can be displayed. From those
consists of 214 countries, from 16 subregions belonging to figures, average reference values for growth rates of tourist
four regions of the world.3 The selected variable is the one flow can be obtained according to the level reached by each
we consider most relevant, within the physical indicators, to destination. Specifically, for those destinations that have
conduct this analysis. Otherwise, the total arrivals variable fewer than 10 million tourists, growth rates above 6.5 per-
could have been used; it is broader than the previous one cent are expected. From this level up to 20 million tourists, a
since it includes day visitors. This flow is relevant to the des- decrease occurs so that from this figure to 65 million, the
tinations where important day tourist arrivals are produced expected rate should be around 3 percent. Again, between 65
from neighboring territories or cruise routes nearby. On the and 70 million, a new decrease up to 2 percent occurs, which
contrary, the variable could have been more restricted, con- is the expected rate above 70 million. In the case of interna-
sidering only tourists staying in tourist establishments. The tional receipts, the form of the stylized function is very simi-
selected variable is the one that contains the most complete lar. Thus, up to 30 billion 2016 US dollars, growth rates of
information among all of them and which we believe more about 5.5 percent are expected. From this level up to 50 bil-
reliably reflects the tourist inflow. lion, a decrease occurs. Again, a rate of 3 percent is set for
However, it should be advisable to complete the competi- large-sized destinations, up to 200 billion. From this point it
tive diagnostic by analyzing other monetary variables. The collapses, and is even capable of presenting negative values.
ITRs data have also been obtained from the UNWTO and, In any case, it is clear that for small destinations (fewer than
for consistency with the previous variable, cover the same 10 million tourists and with incomes lower than 30 billion,
period. However, the primary source of this information is growth rates in the region of 6 percent are expected). For
the IMF Balance of Payments Database and includes the large destinations (with between 25 and 65 million tourists
value recorded in credits under the item “Travel” plus and incomes between 50 and 200 billion), growth rates of 3
“International passenger transport.” The same criterion for percent are expected. Medium-sized destinations represent a
inclusion of countries in the sample is used. The final sample transition in these rates and the very large ones will show
consists of 203 countries. The lower number of countries is growth rates far below 3 percent. Clearly, these are only ref-
due to the fact that the balance of payments are usually erence figures that may change significantly among destina-
offered at the country level, so some territories dependent on tions. Therefore, it is appropriate to use the procedure
other countries included separately in the UNWTO statistics described in the previous section for specific destinations.
do not have this type of information. The difference between In Figure 3, we present the aggregate competitive indica-
the trajectory the two variables follow, in addition to the tors based on performance for short, medium and long terms
exchange rate, is due to tourist spending, which is influenced for the main regions of the world, aggregated from the results
by both the daily expenditure per tourist and the length of the obtained at a country level.
stay. To eliminate the evolution of the increase in prices, the As can be seen, at least at this level of aggregation, when
series have been deflated and are presented in 2016 constant the analysis is done with a higher reference period (from short
US dollars. to long term), the diagnosis is clear and forceful. The short-
In Table 2, we present the estimation of equation (1) for term analysis (first column) is oscillating, alternating very
ITAs and ITRs. In columns 1 to 4 and 9 to 12, results by OLS short periods where the competitive situation changes. This
are offered, while the following columns (5 to 8 and 13 to 16) behavior ceases to be observed in the medium (second col-
are made by WLS, using as weights the share average repre- umn) and long term (third column). Diagnoses for the medium
sented by each country in the international tourism market and long terms, even with nuances, are quite similar in the
for the period 1995 to 2016. These weights are calculated years of coincidence (for the medium term, indicators can be
from the number of tourists in the case of ITAs and total obtained since 2002, but only since 2009 for long-term indi-
receipts in the case of ITRs. The results show a negative and cators). There is also a great similarity between the evolution
statistically significant relationship in all cases between the followed by the ITA and ITR indicators, especially in the long
size of the tourism sector and its growth rate, confirming the term. Precisely for this reason, we are going to use preferably
existence of depletion in the evolution of this sector in each long-term and medium-term indicators for the analysis of the
destination as a result of maturation. The F tests presented, tourist performance in different regions and subregions.
contrasting the equality of the country and year effects, reject Figures 4 and 5 show the results obtained for the medium
these hypotheses at 99 percent, which reveals the existence (gray) and long-run (black) indicators, for both ITAs (con-
of different structural factors among countries. We also find tinuous line) and ITRs (dotted line). Although there is still a
evidence of the influence of the economic cycle on the world high degree of similarity between the results with both vari-
evolution of the sector. ables, it is also true that in some cases there are nuances that
Now establishing a relationship using a local polynomial point to different competitive tendencies, specific behavior
smooth estimation among the predicted values of the equa- of prices or the exchange rate of currencies.
tions above (8 and 16) for the growth rates of ITAs and ITRs The first result to note is that regions follow different
and the level of these variables, including country effects, the paths corresponding to different competitive contexts.
Table 2.  Results of the Conditional Convergence-Competitiveness Equation for ITAs and ITRs, 1995-2016 (Estimated on ITAs).
OLS WLS OLS WLS

  1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16

lnFit-1 −0.007*** −0.007*** −0.092*** −0.146*** −0.016*** −0.015*** −0.076*** −0.120*** −0.009*** −0.008*** −0.134*** −0.193*** −0.013*** −0.012*** −0.070*** −0.103***
(0.001) (0.001) (0.005) (0.007) (0.001) (0.001) (0.005) (0.006) (0.002) (0.002) (0.007) (0.009) (0.001) (0.001) (0.005) (0.07)
Constant 0.104*** 0.139*** — — 0.196*** 0.215*** — — 0.106*** 0.140*** — — 0.159*** 0.179*** — —
(0.010) (0.017) (0.012) (0.013) (0.013) (0.023) (0.014) (0.015)
Year dummies No Yes No Yes No Yes No Yes No Yes No Yes No Yes No Yes
Country No No Yes Yes No No Yes Yes No No Yes Yes No No Yes Yes
dummies
Fyear — F(20, 4472) — F(20, 4259) — F(20, 4472) — F(20, 4259) — F(20, 4241) — F(20, 4039) — F(20, 4241) — F(20, 4039)
6.10*** 14.11*** 18.00*** 23.59*** 7.67*** 13.72*** 46.81*** 50.26***
Fcountry — — F(214, 4279) F(214, 4259) — — F(214, 4279) F(214, 4259) — — F(203, 4059) F(203, 4039) — — F(203, 4059) F(203, 4039)
3.07*** 3.71*** 3.33*** 3.88*** 2.67*** 3.19*** 2.17*** 2.72***
Observations 4,494 4,494 4,494 4,494 4,494 4,494 4,494 4,494 4,263 4,263 4,263 4,263 4,263 4,263 4,263 4,263
Adj-R2 .005 .027 .136 .186 .035 .103 .19 .267 .005 .035 .090 .143 .019 .193 .095 .272

Note: Significance levels are denoted as follows: 99% (***), 95% (**), and 90%(*)

9
10 Journal of Travel Research 00(0)

Figure 2.  Relationship between the size of tourist destination and its growth rate. Local polynominal smooth estimation of predicted
growth rate in conditional convergence equation.

Figure 3.  International tourism performance indicators, main world regions.

Europe is, without doubt, the worst performing region, The Americas also present a clear improvement, although
with a downward trajectory and a poor competitive posi- they have a negative indicator of competitiveness through
tion. Central and Eastern Europe and Western Europe the entire period of analysis except for the last year. North
show a downward trend more intense in receipts than in America presents indicators of a certain improvement in its
tourists. Northern Europe maintains a balanced position in performance, although much more marked from the receipts
terms of tourists and a remarkable improvement from the than the tourist perspective. The Caribbean presents a model
receipts perspective. Meanwhile, as of 2010, Southern in certain decline, although it seems to reinvent itself in the
Europe shows a remarkable improvement (probably an last two years, especially from the receipts perspective.
effect derived from the Arab Spring) that is not reflected Something similar happens with Central America and, to a
in income, which in some way reflects a strategy based on lesser extent, with South America, where the improvement in
low-cost tourism. tourists is not reflected in the receipts indicator.
de la Peña et al. 11

Figure 4.  International tourism performance indicators, European and American subregions.

Figure 5.  International tourism performance indicators, Asian, Pacific, African, and Middle East subregions.

Asia and the Pacific is the region which shows the best per- of the four subregions in this area has a particular problem,
formance, with a prolonged upward trajectory over time. In this although all of them are affected by political instability, ter-
sense, this path is the result mainly of what Southeast Asia and rorism and wars, along with situations of health emergency
South Asia show, since Northeast Asia, despite an upward tra- (for example, the Ebola crisis from 2014 to 2016). Thus,
jectory, shows a slope that is lower than average for the region. North Africa has shown an unstoppable deterioration since
On the contrary, Oceania presents a downward trend, espe- the Arab Spring. Sub-Saharan Africa also suffers a small
cially in the case of receipts, where it seems that has improved drop in the indicator made from the ITAs;, though this indi-
in the last five years. In both Oceania and Northeast Asia, there cator recovers slightly after 2014. On the contrary, the behav-
is a significant difference in some years between the diagnosis ior of the ITRs indicator is especially bad, possibly because
provided by ITAs and ITRs. This is a consequence of the evolu- of the decrease in tourists with higher purchasing power and
tion of local currency exchange rates against the dollar. some adjustment in prices. Central and South Africa, after a
Africa, which had an unbeatable situation earlier in this particularly volatile behavior in the last decade, presents a
decade, has seen its competitiveness gradually weaken, espe- significant drop that leads to negative indicators. Finally, the
cially as of 2012 (Arab Spring and Islamic terrorism). Each Middle East suffers a fall in terms of the indicator of tourists,
12 Journal of Travel Research 00(0)

Figure 6.  International tourism performance indicators, top six destinations.

although this fall is not followed by the revenue indicator. •• Spain: Continued and fast deterioration of its tourist
This latter behavior could be explained by the commitment competitiveness (plummeting of long-term indicator).
of the Gulf countries to luxury tourism. This trend seemed to reverse at the end of the period,
Like the information used to calculate the regional indicators especially as of 2012 (trend change of long-term indi-
derived from those obtained at the country level, in Figure 6, the cator and rebound of the medium term for ITAs).
evolution of competitiveness indicators based on performance Exhaustion of model that improves because of
in the medium and long term for the six biggest tourist destina- changes in the rest of its competitors in North Africa.
tions is presented, merely to present some results at the country The situation turns more slowly in the case of receipts.
level. As can be seen, the long-term indicator accordingly pro- •• China: Continued and fast deterioration of its tourism
vides a more structural diagnosis, complemented with the competitiveness after the peak in the middle of last
medium-term indicator, which advances the possible changes in decade (fast fall of medium and long-term indicators).
the long-term indicator. Hence, the combination of the two is •• Italy: Exhausted tourist model. No downward trend
important in making an accurate diagnosis. in terms of tourist arrivals in the long and medium
Each destination has a peculiar behavior with many term, but it is stuck in a negative value. On the con-
nuances, which would be too complex to analyze here. trary, the fall has continued in the case of the receipts
However, in a brief way to show the potential of these indica- indicator.
tors, it could be noted that: •• UK: Continued deterioration of its competitive posi-
tion (steady fall in long-term indicator) with glimmers
•• France: Continued deterioration of its tourism perfor- of stoppage of the fall (midterm indicator with some
mance (long-term indicator with a continuously recovery at the end of period). The performance indi-
decreasing trend) that shows no sign of recovery cator related to tourism revenues improved notably in
(medium-term indicator also decreasing). Exhausted the medium term.
tourism model.
•• United States: Continued improvement after the tour- The proposed methodology permits us to estimate the
ism crisis resulting from the September 11th attacks steady state or equilibrium of this market as long as the con-
(upward trend of long-term indicator). Some evidence ditions are not altered (tourism model and international envi-
of model depletion (slow evolution of medium-term ronment). Using expression (9) with the country effects, the
indicator) is presented, although this is not observed equilibrium situation for each destination is obtained. Results
from the ITRs perspective. for the increase from actual situation to steady state are
de la Peña et al. 13

Table 3.  Estimated Increase in International Tourism Arrivals Conclusions


and Expenditure from Actual to Steady State (%).
This article begins by reviewing the various models of inter-
ITAs ITRs national tourist competitiveness. This analysis is developed
Europe 28.3 17.2 on the basis of the following trilogy: determinants, perfor-
  Northern Europe 29.2 18.5 mance, and impacts. It appears that, despite the usefulness of
  Western Europe 16.5 6.0 the analytical approach to tourist competitiveness based on
  Central/Eastern Europe 41.5 33.1 performance, tools for analyzing performance indicators
  Southern/Mediterranean Europe 31.2 23.2 have not been developed to allow a diagnosis of their evolu-
Asia and the Pacific 46.0 44.1 tion, which is related mostly to determinants or potential
  Northeast Asia 45.4 45.0 competitiveness and, more recently, to impacts. That is why
  Southeast Asia 48.8 42.1 this article focuses on providing a diagnostic tool for com-
 Oceania 25.0 30.7 petitiveness based on performance.
  South Asia 57.5 74.0 In particular, the adaptation of the measure of conditional
Americas 22.5 27.5 β-convergence to the study of inflows related to the tourist
  North America 16.9 24.6 sector is proposed. The basic idea is that the proposed equa-
 Caribbean 24.2 26.0 tion, once estimated, allows a counterfactual which is the
  Central America 53.7 80.1 reference value with which the actual data is compared, thus
  South America 37.6 38.1 establishing a competitive diagnosis.
Africa 47.1 45.3
This methodology allows us to consider, in the compara-
  North Africa 33.2 7.3
tive analysis among countries, different sizes of the tourist
  Sub-Saharan Africa 48.1 66.7
sector among destinations and differences in tourist maturity,
  Central and Eastern Africa 42.5 38.2
as well as incorporate the economic cycle in the estimate. In
  Middle East 58.6 67.2
World 32.6 27.7
addition, using these estimates, three indicators of competi-
tiveness are proposed, allowing us to focus the analysis on
different terms: short, medium and long.
reported in aggregated form in Table 3. It shows that the An example of the use of this methodology is imple-
international tourism market could grow to 32.6 percent in mented using UNWTO international tourist arrivals data for
terms of tourist arrivals and 27.7 percent in tourism receipts 214 destinations and international tourism receipts data for
by the current model, reaching half of this growth over the 203 destinations, in both cases for the period 1995 to 2016.
next six to seven years, representing an average cumulative From these estimates, competitive analysis for world tourist
growth rate of 2.4 and 2 percent, respectively, during this regions, the six major tourist destinations (countries) in the
period. However, growth capacity is very different among world, and an estimate of potential growth of the current
different regions and subregions of the world. Asia and the tourism model are obtained. With certain exceptions, the
Pacific and Africa are noted for their potential growth, com- results obtained for both variables are quite coincident, espe-
pared with Europe and the Americas. In the case of Africa, cially in the indicators that consider greater temporal peri-
the model predicts what its potential growth might be in ods. Short-term indicators show a more erratic behavior,
terms of behavior between 1995 and 2016. In this sense, if possibly as a consequence of a certain evidence of reversion
the evolution of the last five years becomes structural, that is, to the mean, whereas this situation disappears in the medium-
it expands over time, then the model would reduce this and long-term indicators, which are perfectly complemented
potential growth. In fact, if the estimates are repeated, elimi- to perform a diagnosis of the competitive situation of each
nating the last five years, and we compare the results, the analyzed territory. The medium-term indicator anticipates
region of the world in which potential growth is most reduced the behavior that could be in the long term, and the latter
is Africa as a result of this change of situation. offers a diagnosis that takes into account not only current
Finally, it should be pointed out that these tools are sensi- behavior, but behavior in recent years, since this indicator, by
tive to changes in economic and political situations, and also construction, has a memory that exceeds the decade, although
changes in all tourist attractions. Those destinations that suf- with a decreasing weight as it moves away in the past.
fer from natural disasters (earthquakes, hurricanes, etc.) or The main utility of this set of indicators and results is to
political problems (armed conflicts, regular terrorist attacks, offer an analysis that allows tourism policy decision makers
etc.) may be punished harshly and model predictions will be to anticipate major structural tourism crises resulting from
clearly affected. The same applies to destinations that are tourism depletions or even plan the reasonable expansion of
benefited by new and exceptional events that cannot be con- the sector, following the path the model indicates.
sidered in this structural model (e.g., major sporting events) Of course, throughout this article, appropriate indications
or destinations that benefit from problems or opportunities in about possible implications that may arise from this model
competing destinations. are made. The model assumes permanence in the tourism
14 Journal of Travel Research 00(0)

model and product mix at each destination. This means that we have tried to use the most complete sample of informa-
changes in this direction will produce a new path leading to tion on tourism at an international level. However, the
a new steady state. That is to say, a change of tourist model increase in the time period that will occur with the passage of
could mean a rejuvenation of the model that, in line with the time will allow for control of structural changes in the tour-
model of the tourism area life cycle, would return to produce ism models. On the other hand, if databases in the future are
higher rates of growth and potential levels of tourists. developed at the level of a tourist site and not by country, the
Similarly, the results are sensitive to the quality of informa- results would gain in precision. Finally, increasing the qual-
tion, the time period used, the sample of countries used in the ity and homogeneity of data, both across countries and over
estimates and the variable selected for analysis. That is why time, will also lead to more accurate analysis.

Appendix 
World Regions, Subregions, and Countries.
Europe Asia and the Pacific The Americas Africa

Northern Europe Northeast Asia North America North Africa

Denmark DNK China CHN Canada CAN Algeria DZA  


  Finland FIN Hong Kong (China) HKG Mexico MEX Morocco MAR  
  Iceland ISL Japan JPN United States USA Sudan SDN (2)
  Ireland IRL South Korea KOR Caribbean Tunisia TUN  
  Norway NOR Macao (China) MAC Anguilla AIA Egypt EGY  
  Sweden SWE Mongolia MNG Antigua and Barbuda ATG Libya LBY (1)
  United Kingdom GBR Taiwan (pr. of China) TWN Aruba ABW Sub-Saharan Africa  
  Faeroe Islands FRO (1) Southeast Asia Bahamas BHS Benin BEN  
  Western Europe Brunei BRN Barbados BRB Burkina Faso BFA  
  Austria AUT Cambodia KHM Bermuda BMU Cameroon CMR  
  Belgium BEL Indonesia IDN Bonaire BON Cabo Verde CPV  
  France FRA Laos LAO Brit. Virgin Islands VGB Centr. African Rep. CAF  
  Germany DEU Malaysia MYS Cayman Islands CYM Chad TCD  
  Liechtenstein LIE (2) Myanmar MMR Cuba CUB Côte d’Ivoire CIV  
  Luxembourg LUX Philippines PHL Curaçao CUW Djibouti DJI  
  Monaco MCO (2) Singapore SGP Dominica DMA Eritrea ERI  
  Netherlands NLD Thailand THA Dominican Rep. DOM Ethiopia ETH  
  Switzerland CHE Timor-Leste TLS Grenada GRD Gambia GMB  
  Central/Eastern Vietnam VNM Guadeloupe GLP Ghana GHA  
Europe
  Armenia ARM Oceania Haiti HTI Guinea GIN  
  Azerbaijan AZE American Samoa ASM (2) Jamaica JAM Guinea-Bissau GNB  
  Belarus BLR Australia AUS Martinique MTQ Liberia LBR (1)
  Bulgaria BGR Cook Is COK Montserrat MSR Mali MLI  
  Czech Republic CZE Fiji FJI Puerto Rico PRI Mauritania MRT (3)
  Estonia EST French Polynesia PYF Saba SAB (2) Niger NER  
  Georgia GEO Guam GUM (2) Saint Lucia LCA Nigeria NGA  
  Hungary HUN Kiribati KIR St. Eustatius EUX (2) Senegal SEN  
  Kazakhstan KAZ Marshall Is MHL St. Kitts and Nevis KNA Sierra Leone SLE  
  Kyrgyzstan KGZ Micronesia FSM FSM St. Maarten SXM Togo TGO  
  Latvia LVA N. Mariana Is MNP (2) St. Vincent and Gren. VCT Central and  
Eastern Africa
  Lithuania LTU New Caledonia NCL Trinidad and Tobago TTO Angola AGO  
  Poland POL New Zealand NZL Turks and Caicos TCA Botswana BWA  
  Rep. Moldova MDA Niue NIU US Virgin Islands VIR Burundi BDI  
  Romania ROU Palau PLW Central America Comoros COM  
  Russian Federation RUS Papua New Guinea PNG Belize BLZ Congo COG  
  Slovakia SVK Samoa WSM Costa Rica CRI Dem. Rep. Congo COD  
  Tajikistan TJK Solomon SLB El Salvador SLV Equatorial Guinea GNQ (3)
  Turkmenistan TKM (2) Tonga TON Guatemala GTM Gabon GAB  
  Ukraine UKR Tuvalu TUV Honduras HND Kenya KEN  
  Uzbekistan UZB Vanuatu VUT Nicaragua NIC Lesotho LSO (2)
  Southern/Medit. South Asia Panama PAN Madagascar MDG  
Europe
  Albania ALB Afghanistan AFG (3) South America Malawi MWI  
  Andorra AND (2) Bangladesh BGD Argentina ARG Mauritius MUS  
  Bosnia and Herzg. BIH Bhutan BTN Bolivia BOL Mozambique MOZ  
  Croatia HRV India IND Brazil BRA Namibia NAM  

(continued)
de la Peña et al. 15

Appendix (continued)
Europe Asia and the Pacific The Americas Africa

Northern Europe Northeast Asia North America North Africa

  Cyprus CYP Iran IRN Chile CHL Reunion REU  


  FYR Macedonia MKD Maldives MDV (2) Colombia COL Rwanda RWA  
  Greece GRC Nepal NPL Ecuador ECU São Tomé and STP (2)
Príncipe
  Israel ISR Pakistan PAK French Guiana GUF Seychelles SYC  
  Italy ITA Sri Lanka LKA Guyana GUY Somalia SOM (3)
  Malta MLT Paraguay PRY South Africa ZAF  
  Montenegro MNE Peru PER Swaziland SWZ  
  Portugal PRT Suriname SUR Tanzania TZA  
  San Marino SMR (2) Uruguay URY Uganda UGA  
  Serbia SRB Venezuela VEN Zambia ZMB  
  Slovenia SVN Zimbabwe ZWE  
  Spain ESP Middle East  
  Turkey TUR Bahrain BHR  
  Kosovo KOS (1) Iraq IRQ  
  Jordan JOR  
  Kuwait KWT  
  Lebanon LBN  
(1) Country without Libya LBY (2)
information on
ITAs
(2) Country without Oman OMN  
information on
ITRs
(3) Country without Palestine PSE  
information on
ITAs and ITRs
  Qatar QAT  
  Saudi Arabia SAU  
  Syria SYR  
  Utd Arab Emirates ARE  
  Yemen YEM  

Acknowledgments show a positive competitive destination despite the fact that the
flow in this second period is lower than in two previous periods.
We would like to thank the three anonymous referees and the editor
2. In some countries, the data refer to nonnationals instead of
for the comments that substantially improved a previous version of
nonresidents.
this article. We also want to thank UNWTO for providing the data
3. The list of regions and subregions as well as the countries that
used in this article.
compose them and data availability can be found in the appendix.

Declaration of Conflicting Interests References


The author(s) declared no potential conflicts of interest with respect Andereck, K. L., and C. Vogt. 2000. “The Relationship between
to the research, authorship, and/or publication of this article. Residents’ Attitudes toward Tourism and Tourism Development
Options.” Journal of Travel Research 39 (1): 27-36.
Funding Arrow, K. J. 1962. “The Economic Implications of Learning by
The author(s) disclosed receipt of the following financial support Doing.” Review of Economic Studies 29 (3): 155-73.
for the research, authorship, and/or publication of this article: This Artto, E. W. 1987. “Relative Total Costs—An Approach to
research was supported by the Spanish Ministry of Economy and Competitiveness Measurement of Industries.” Management
Competitiveness (Research Project ECO2014-52051-R) and the International Review 27 (2): 47-58.
Autonomous Region of Madrid (Research Project H2015/ Assaker, G., R. Hallak, V. Esposito-Vinci, and P. O’Connor. 2013.
HUM3417), cofinanced by the European Social Fund. “An Empirical Operationalization of Countries’ Destination
Competitiveness Using Partial Least Squares Modeling.”
Journal of Travel Research 53 (1): 26-43.
Notes Azzoni, C. R., and T. A. Menezes. 2009. “Cost Competitiveness
1. Suppose that as a result of an exceptional phenomenon in a des- of International Destinations.” Annals of Tourism Research 36
tination, tourist flows fell by 20 percent in one year. That year (4): 719-22.
the diagnosis would identify a problem of competitiveness. If Balaguer, J. M., and Cantavella-Jordá. 2002. “Tourism as a Long-
the estimated increasing flow rate was 6 percent the following Run Economic Growth Factor: The Spanish Case.” Applied
year and it grows by 7 percent, the diagnosis of that year would Economics 34 (7): 877-84.
16 Journal of Travel Research 00(0)

Barney, J. B. 1991. “Firm Resources and Sustainable Competitive Enright, M. J., and J. Newton. 2004. “Tourism Destination
Advantages.” Journal of Management 17 (1): 99-120. Competitiveness: A Quantitative Approach.” Tourism
Bolaky, B. 2008. “Tourism Life Cycle, Tourism Competitiveness Management 25 (6): 777-88.
and Upgrading Strategies in the Caribbean.” Santiago: Enright, M. J., and J. Newton. 2005. “Determinants of Tourism
Economic Commission for Latin America and the Caribbean. Destination Competitiveness in Asia Pacific: Comprehensiveness
Bolaky, B. 2009. “An Econometric Study of the Determinants and Universality.” Journal of Travel Research 43 (4): 339-50.
of Tourism Competitiveness in the Caribbean.” Santiago: Garau, J. 2007. “Propuesta de dos indicadores para la medi-
Economic Commission for Latin America and the Caribbean. ación de la competitividad de los destinos de sol y playa del
Buhalis, D. 2000. “Marketing the Competitive Destination of the Mediterráneo: Avance de resultados desde el punto de vista de
Future.” Tourism Management 21:97-116. la demanda” [Proposal of two indicators for the mediation of
Butler, R. W. 1980. “The Concept of Tourist Area Life Cycle the competitiveness of the destinations of sun and beach of the
of Evolution: Implications for Management of Resources.” Mediterranean: Advance of results from the point of view of
Canadian Geographer 24:5-12. the demand]. Revista de Análisis Turístico 4:50-67.
Butler, R. W. 2011. Tourism Area Life Cycle: Contemporary Gooroochurn, N., and G. Sugiyarto. 2005. “Competitiveness
Tourism Reviews. Oxford: Goodfellow. Indicators in the Travel and Tourism Industry.” Tourism
Claver-Cortés, E., J. F. Molina-Azorín, and J. Pereira-Moliner. Economics 11 (1): 25-43.
2007. “Competitiveness in Mass Tourism.” Annals of Tourism Hassan, S. S. 2000. “Determinants of Market Competitiveness in
Research 34 (3): 727-45. an Environmentally Sustainable Tourism Industry.” Journal of
Craigwell, R. 2007. “Tourism Competitiveness in Small Island Travel Research 38 (3): 239-45.
Developing States.” Research Paper No. 2007/19, United Hong, W. C. 2008. Competitiveness in the Tourism Sector: A
Nations University–World Institute for Development Comprehensive Approach from Economic and Management
Economics Research. Points. Amsterdam: Physica-Verlag.
Crouch, G. I. 2011. “Destination Competitiveness: An Analysis of Jiménez, P., and F. K. Aquino. 2012. “Propuesta de un Modelo
Determinant Attributes.” Journal of Travel Research 50 (1): de Competitividad de Destinos Turísticos” [A proposal for a
27-45. competitive destination model]. Estudios y Perspectivas en
Crouch, G. I., and B. J. R. Ritchie. 1999. “Tourism, Competitiveness, Turismo 21:977-95.
and Societal Prosperity.” Journal of Business Research 44 (3): Khadaroo, J., and B. Seetanah. 2007. “Transport Infrastructure and
137-52. Tourism Development.” Annals of Tourism Research 34 (4):
Cvelbar, L. K., L. Dwyer, M. Koman, and T. Mihalic. 2016. 1021-32.
“Drivers of Destination Competitiveness in Tourism. A Global Krugman, P. 1994. “Competitiveness: A Dangerous Obsession.”
Investigation.” Journal of Travel Research 55 (8): 1041-50. Foreign Affairs 73 (2): 28-46.
De la Fuente, A. 1998. “Algunas Técnicas para el Análisis de Li, L. X. 2000. “An Analysis of Sources of Competitiveness and
la Convergencia con una Aplicación para las Regiones Performance of Chinese Manufacturers.” International Journal
Españolas” [Some techniques for the analysis of the conver- of Operations and Production Management 20 (3): 299-315.
gence with an application for the Spanish regions). Secretaría Lucas, R., Jr. 1988. “On the Mechanics of Economic Development.”
de Estado de Presupuestos y Gastos, Ministerio de Hacienda y Journal of Monetary Economics 22 (1): 3-42.
Administraciones Públicas, D-98007. Lundie, S., L. Dwyer, and P. Forsyth. 2007. “Environmental-
d’Hauteserre, A. 2000. “Lessons in Managerial Destination Economic Measures of Tourism Yield.” Journal of Sustainable
Competitiveness in the Case of Foxwoods Casino Resort.” Tourism 15:503-19.
Tourism Management 21 (1): 23-32. Martín, J. C., C. Mendoza, and C. Román. 2017. “A DEA Travel-
Dupeyras, A., and N. MacCallum. 2013. “Indicators for Measuring Tourism Competitiveness Index.” Social Indicators Research
Competitiveness in Tourism: A Guidance Document.” Tourism 130:937-57.
Papers 2013/02, Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Mazanec, J. A., K. Wöber, and A. H. Zins. 2007. “Tourism
Development. Destination Competitiveness: From Definition to Explanation?”
Dwyer, L., P. Forsyth, and P. Rao. 1999. “Tourism Price Journal of Travel Research 46 (1): 86-95.
Competitiveness and Journey Purpose.” Turizam 47 (4): Oral, M. 1986. “An Industrial Competitiveness Model.” IIE
283-99. Transactions 18 (2): 148-57.
Dwyer, L., P. Forsyth, and P. Rao. 2000. “The Price Competitiveness Oral, M. 1993. “A Methodology for Competitiveness Analysis and
of Travel and Tourism: A Comparison of 19 Destinations.” Strategy Formulation in the Glass Industry.” European Journal
Tourism Management 21 (1): 9-22. of Operational Research 68:9-22.
Dwyer, L., P. Forsyth, and P. Rao. 2002. “Destination Price Oral, M., and A. Reisman. 1988. “Measuring Industrial
Competitiveness: Exchange Rate Changes versus Domestic Competitiveness.” Industrial Marketing Management 17 (3):
Inflation.” Journal of Travel Research 40 (3): 328-36. 263-72.
Dwyer, L., and C. Kim. 2003. “Destination Competitiveness: Peteraf, M. A. 1993. “The Cornerstones of Competitive Advantages:
Determinants and Indicators.” Current Issues in Tourism 6 (5): A Resource–Based View.” Strategic Management Journal 14
369-414. (3): 179-91.
Economic Commission for Latin America and the Caribbean. Porter, M. E. 1980. Competitive Strategy: Techniques for Analyzing
2010. “The Tourism Sector and the Global Economic Crisis: Industries and Competitors. New York: Free Press.
Development Implications for the Caribbean.” Economic Porter, M. E. 1985. Competitive Advantages: Creating and
Commission for Latin America and the Caribbean. Sustaining Superior Performance. New York: Free Press.
de la Peña et al. 17

Porter, M. E. 1990. The Competitive Advantages of Nations. New Waheeduzzan, A. N. M., and J. K. Ryans. 1996. “Definition, Perspectives,
York: Free Press. and Understanding of International Competitiveness: A Quest for a
Prahalad, C. K., and G. Hamel. 1990. “The Core Competence of the Common Ground.” Competitiveness Review 6 (2): 7-26.
Corporation.” Harvard Business Review 68:79-91. Wernerfelt, B. 1984. “A Resource-Based View of the Firm.”
Ricardo, D. 1817. On the Principles of Political Economy and Strategic Management Journal 5 (2): 171-80.
Taxation. London: John Murray. World Economic Forum. 2017. “The Travel and Tourism
Ritchie, B. J. R., and G. I. Crouch. 2000. “The Competitive Competitiveness Report 2017.” Geneva: World Economic Forum.
Destination: A Sustainable Tourism Perspective.” Tourism
Management 21 (1): 1-7. Author Biographies
Romer, P. 1990. “Endogenous Technological Change.” Journal of
Mario Raúl de la Peña, MD in Business Administration and
Political Economy 98 (5): S71-102.
Management (Universidad de Holguin, 2011) is an assistant profes-
Schumpeter, J. 1912. The Theory of Economic Development.
sor in Economics (Universidad de Holguín)
Leipzig: Duncker & Humblot.
Seyoum, B. 2007. “Revealed Comparative Advantage and Juan A. Núñez-Serrano PhD in Economics (Universidad
Competitiveness in Services: A Study with Special Emphasis Complutense de Madrid, 2012) is an associate professor in Applied
on Developing Countries.” Journal of Economic Studies 34 Economics (Universidad Autónoma de Madrid).
(5): 376-88.
Sinclair, M. T. 1998. “Tourism and Economic Development: A Jaime Turrión PhD in Economics (Universidad Complutense de
Survey.” Journal of Development Studies 34 (5): 1-51. Madrid, 2008) is an associate professor in Applied Economics
Tsounta, E. 2008. “What Attracts Tourists to Paradise?” IMF (Universidad Autónoma de Madrid)
Working Paper WP/08/277. Francisco J. Velázquez PhD in Economics (Universidad
UNWTO. 2017. “Methodological Notes to the Tourism Statistics Complutense de Madrid, 1997) is a professor in Applied Economics
Database. 2017 Edition.” Madrid: UNWTO. (Universidad Complutense de Madrid)

Das könnte Ihnen auch gefallen