Sie sind auf Seite 1von 9

Redistribution in Aegean Palatial Societies.

Redistribution and the Political Economy: The


Evolution of an Idea
Author(s): TIMOTHY EARLE
Source: American Journal of Archaeology, Vol. 115, No. 2 (April 2011), pp. 237-244
Published by: Archaeological Institute of America
Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/10.3764/aja.115.2.0237 .
Accessed: 31/03/2013 14:48

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at .
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp

.
JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of
content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms
of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.

Archaeological Institute of America is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to
American Journal of Archaeology.

http://www.jstor.org

This content downloaded from 128.197.27.9 on Sun, 31 Mar 2013 14:48:56 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
FORUM

Redistribution in Aegean Palatial Societies


Redistribution and the Political Economy:
The Evolution of an Idea
TIMOTHY EARLE

Abstract ist, I would be unreasonable to try to judge the quality


Whether the Bronze Age Aegean economies can be of the evidence and give a new synthesis of the Aegean
described as “redistributive” depends on how one defines economy; rather, I simply ask what is gained by calling
the term. The concept of redistribution itself has under- (or not calling) the economy “redistribution”?
gone several decades of critical archaeological analysis, Systems of classification have lost favor in anthro-
much of it stemming from my early work in Polynesia. I
consider here how Polanyi’s ideas about redistributive pology and archaeology. To classify an economy, its
economies have been expanded since the 1970s. My review specialization, or its broader social formations accord-
complements the article in this Forum by Nakassis et al. ing to specific types appears to be a rather mindless
and the contribution by Halstead, who discusses why and exercise that does injustice to the observed variety in
how the concept of redistribution still matters in studies human societies. Classification can also have unintend-
of the Minoans and Mycenaeans. To some degree, we
all agree: chiefs, and later kings, who sought power in ed consequences, offending people with societies or
archaic societies did so through many highly variable, histories measuring up “poorly” in such classification
contingent, and changing means, all designed to support exercises. I, however, believe in the usefulness of the
political-economic strategies based on multiple systems ideal (Weber-like) types, as long as we realize that they
of finance. The Bronze Age Aegean societies provide ex- are not real categories but act as models to capture
cellent examples of this process, as demonstrated by the
contributors to this Forum. distinctive patterns of economic, social, and political
interconnections. Thus, I advocate using ideal types,
like redistribution, to define a broad category of pro-
introduction cesses. Our purpose in using such types is not to clas-
In their introduction to this Forum, Nakassis et al. sify societies or economies but to recognize cases with
admirably summarize the history of the concept of re- similar processes and structures that we can compare
distribution and ask whether the Bronze Age economy in order to identify and explain the observed variation.
of the Aegean world should be classified as redistribu- Employing this framework, we would want to ask how
tive.1 They believe that it should not. In support of this and why the redistributive economies of Mesopotamia
conclusion, the articles in this Forum call for a descrip- and the Aegean differed and not assume that calling
tion of the economy from the bottom up. The Aegean both redistributive means they are the same. Rather,
regional economy was made up of rather ad hoc con- variation within types and macroregional formations
nections between specific segments of local communi- should focus our attention. Although the Aegean
ties, palaces, and sanctuaries. The real economy of the Bronze Age world represented common historical
Bronze Age Aegean was a changing, checkered mosaic themes, to understand it requires us to focus on re-
of elements, for which the single term “redistribution” gional and temporal differences. The ideal type of
is inadequate. Although in fundamental agreement redistribution points to specific variables of interests
with Nakassis et al., Halstead emphasizes that the con- and strategies for our investigation.
cept of redistribution continues to have utility for the Redistribution encompasses the political economies
Bronze Age Aegean, and he stresses the centrality and of archaic societies, broadly grouped as chiefdoms and
asymmetry of economic relationships.2 As a nonspecial- early states. Surpluses in staples and wealth objects

1 2
Nakassis et al. 2011. Halstead 2011.
237
American Journal of Archaeology 115 (2011) 237–44

This content downloaded from 128.197.27.9 on Sun, 31 Mar 2013 14:48:56 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
238 TIMOTHY EARLE [AJA 115

were mobilized and distributed centrally to finance in- rized in my book Bronze Age Economics,4 my questions
stitutional apparatuses of power (e.g., warriors, manag- concentrated on redistribution as a means to mobilize
ers, and craftsmen of wealth items and weapons) with and direct surplus to finance emergent institutions of
the goal to expand political reach. The economy of power and management. The new political economies
any archaic society can best be thought of as divided were based on what I now call bottlenecks, restrictions
into various intertwined sectors, including its political to flows in resources that allowed would-be leaders to
economy, religious economy, community economy, channel flows for their institutional purposes. But I
and trading economy. Each sector has some degree am getting ahead of myself.
of independence in terms of logic and motivation, When I entered graduate school, economic anthro-
and all are interconnected within constantly changing pology was healing from a heated debate between for-
resource flows. The concept of redistribution focuses malists seeking to apply cross-culturally formal theories
attention on the processes of political power and fi- of economics and substantivists looking to Polanyi’s
nance that girded emergent political structures to defining publications. Sahlins and other followers of
organize populations in the thousands, tens of thou- Polanyi argued that human economies involved the
sands, and hundreds of thousands and eventually to production and distribution of goods to meet the
form the basis for the first complex imperial systems material wants of a society; economies were first and
of the ancient worlds. foremost “substantive,” built for the substance of life.
In this brief article, I summarize the history of my Furthermore, economies were organized, that is, “in-
views on redistribution, archaic political economies, stituted,” as part of the varying structures of those so-
and the role of centrally managed economies in the cieties. Provisioning was thus socially embedded, and
evolution of stratified and politically centralized soci- the range of different economic organizations tracked
eties. This is little more than a narrative of an idea. the range of human social formations. Reciprocity
The ultimate question is: how do chiefs, and eventu- reflected egalitarian relationships, redistribution re-
ally kings and emperors, try to control local and re- flected centralized relationships, and market exchange
gional resource flows to finance their apparatuses of reflected the particular relationships of modern capi-
power? The answer shows the highly variable, contin- talism.5 All exchange relationships (reciprocity, redis-
gent, and changing means used to develop political tribution, or market exchange) were thought to be
economies, and I seek to encapsulate this political functionally the same, meeting material wants and
strategy into a model of redistribution as an archaic reinforcing existing social formations.
system of finance. The American neo-evolutionists Service and Sahlins
took the next logical step. They argued that the devel-
the narrative of an idea: redistribution opment of complex (hierarchically organized) societies
and the political economy was linked to redistribution. Service wrote a popular
In the early 1970s, as a graduate student at the Uni- book, Primitive Social Organization: An Evolutionary Per-
versity of Michigan, I hoped to unravel how complex spective, which was oriented to a general, largely under-
societies emerged with strong leaders, elaborate in- graduate audience.6 In the book, he defined chiefdoms
stitutional structures and public displays of artwork, as redistributive societies in which chiefs distributed
and economic differentiation. My endeavor was part goods among locally specialized communities to meet
of what was then a central anthropological objective their populations’ needs. Following Polanyi, Service
with roots extending back to the beginnings of the viewed redistribution as a system of exchange (an al-
discipline. In the spring of my first year, I took Sahl- ternative to reciprocity or market exchange) in which
ins’ course in economic anthropology (his engaging chiefs provided central management to assure the
lectures presented Polanyi’s substantivist econom- transfer of goods from each according to his ability to
ics), which he later published as Stone Age Economics.3 each according to his need. Although helpful heuristi-
A world of hunter-gatherers and horticulturalists, cally to organize undergraduate classes, Service’s short,
the Stone Age was a time when social relationships introductory book created three problems. First, a gen-
dominated economic relationships. Later, working eration of processualist scholars started the sterile en-
with Sahlins in Hawaii, I came to focus more on how deavor to classify individual societies into generalized,
social economies were transformed by the political evolutionary types. For example, chiefdoms became a
economies of chiefdoms and archaic states. Summa- checklist of traits, including redistribution. Second,

3 5
Sahlins 1972. Polanyi 1957.
4 6
Earle 2002. Service 1962.

This content downloaded from 128.197.27.9 on Sun, 31 Mar 2013 14:48:56 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
2011] REDISTRIBUTION AND THE POLITICAL ECONOMY 239

the significance of redistribution was reduced to its Within the Hawaiian chiefdoms, redistribution did
adaptive function, ignoring the political significance not distribute subsistence goods among specialized
of economies. And third, a subsequent generation of communities.12 Rather, the redistributive economy
postmodernist scholars found in the book a caricature mobilized and distributed “surplus” for institutional
of neo-evolutionists as unilinear and progressive, al- finance. The hierarchy of Hawaiian chiefs channeled
lowing them to ignore the substantive case materials the flow of mobilized staples to finance specific opera-
analyzed by many processualists. If they had looked tions and personnel in control. Surpluses were used
instead, for example, to Sahlins’ Social Stratification in (1) to build and maintain irrigation systems, fishponds,
Polynesia,7 they would have seen a systematic attempt to and dry-field complexes; (2) to support an enforcing
understand the highly variable scale and integration of and expansive warrior elite; and (3) to support priests,
Polynesian chiefdoms, characteristics that were tied to their elaborate ceremonies, and monument construc-
historical differences (eastern vs. western Polynesia), tion.13 Additionally, exchanges in desired specialty
island size, and gross island productivity. products existed outside redistribution within family
In 1971, I accompanied Sahlins back to Polynesia, and trading networks.
seeking to understand the nature of Hawaiian polities, Although redistribution, as defined by centralized
which had been at the very apex of the evolutionary flows, could be applied to many economic systems,
spectrum of chiefdoms in that region. While Sahlins it appears to have had a much narrower and more
was transforming his approaches to become increas- specific use as a means of mobilization and central
ingly structural, I remained focused on the ideas put allocation.14 The Hawaiian case was based almost ex-
forth by the younger Sahlins. My dissertation research clusively on the mobilization of staples from intensive
evaluated three then-popular theories of social evolu- agricultural fields, over which chiefs exerted owner-
tion: Wittfogel on irrigation, Service on redistribution, ship rights. The important point was that redistribu-
and Carneiro on warfare.8 Each emphasized that chief- tion was not a different social mechanism to organize
doms evolved to solve emergent problems in society; I exchange;15 it was a new tributary mode of produc-
found these theories to be substantially wrong for the tion,16 an archaic form of political economy.
Hawaiian case.9 My model for the evolution of Hawai- Redistribution is thus best seen as a system of con-
ian complex chiefdoms emphasized the same variables trolled mobilization of surplus for institutional fi-
but organized them into a model of the growth-orient- nance. It was never a total economy. As I investigated
ed political economies responsible for the emergence redistribution, I could see that central control over the
and elaboration of chiefdoms. Let me explain. economy was always contingent, never complete, and
The emerging organization of chiefdoms in Poly- that control could be exercised in many different con-
nesia depended on generating and allocating (i.e., texts and with different degrees of exclusiveness. In the
redistributing) surplus to finance governing institu- Hawaiian case, mobilization was based on ownership
tions. The generation of surplus depended on con- of highly productive resources, especially irrigation,
trol over highly productive staple farming. Although and I suspect that many (if not most) chiefdoms used
the irrigation systems of the Hawaiian Islands were land ownership to mobilize surplus. Interestingly, in
small-scale and required no central management,10 many archaic states, of which the Inca empire became
they were highly productive and concentrated in the my main example, mobilized staples also formed the
limited valley bottomlands. The concentration of farm- primary means for finance.17
land created the bottleneck in subsistence production An alternative way to control flows to support the
that permitted chiefs to mobilize surplus.11 New power emergence of complex political systems was through
specialists—the warrior elite and land managers—mo- the manufacture and distribution of primitive valu-
bilized a percentage of the resources in each commu- ables or highly valued raw materials. For example,
nity. In return for subsistence rights to irrigated and the increased volume and decreasing variation in
other productive lands, commoners provided corvée long-distance exchange of obsidian was identified as
labor and specified goods to their chiefs. a characteristic of redistribution.18 Of particular im-

7 13
Sahlins 1958. Kolb 1994.
8 14
Wittfogel 1957; Service 1962; Carneiro 1970. Earle 1977.
9 15
Earle 1978. Contra Polanyi 1957.
10 16
Contra Wittfogel 1957. Wolf 1982.
11 17
Earle 1980. D’Altroy and Earle 1985.
12 18
Contra Service 1962. Flannery 1976, 291–92.

This content downloaded from 128.197.27.9 on Sun, 31 Mar 2013 14:48:56 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
240 TIMOTHY EARLE [AJA 115

portance were primitive valuables, objects of symbolic ers for use as bride wealth payments and other social
and intersubjective value used to mark status within exchanges. In this way, the chiefs controlled the so-
emergent stratification. Examples of primitive valu- cial life of their followers. An ability to control the
ables include specialty ceramic serving vessels, fine movement of the valuables was apparently based on
cloth and bird-feather paraphernalia, unusual stone, the relative isolation of the Trobriand Islands, which
amber and shell ornaments, metal jewelry and weap- required the use of large sailing canoes in the trade.
ons, and much else. The fine feather cloaks, helmets, Reflecting their exclusive sponsorship of canoe manu-
and accoutrements of the Hawaiian chiefs were ob- facture, Trobriand chiefs were the exclusive owners
jects that marked the chiefs as gods on earth.19 With of the elaborate trading canoes. Controlled trade and
many wealth objects produced and moving through local distribution of primitive valuables thus provided
many conduits, and with objects valued so differently an alternative mechanism for chiefly finance of politi-
in one social context or another, control over primi- cal institutions.
tive valuables would seem always to have been prob- As my analysis fell into place, three alternative
lematic. But, as I came to argue, these valuables were bottlenecks appeared to exist in the supply chain for
critically important in chiefly redistribution, when con- valuables: attached specialization, resource owner-
trol could be exercised through spheres of exchange, ship, and/or specialized transport. Attached special-
expensive transport technologies (esp. ships), and at- ization appeared initially to be the easiest means for
tached specialized production. elites to control production and distribution of socially
Bohannan, a leading substantivist, coined the significant objects.22 As in the Hawaiian case, staples
phrase “spheres of exchange” to differentiate tradi- mobilized from the chiefs’ fields supported skilled
tional economies from modern market ones.20 Essen- crafters, who made the specialty feathered regalia of
tially, traditional economies were thought to have been chiefly status. The development of such highly crafted
organized differently, not because of their function, display objects using special materials generally ac-
but because of the different structuring characteris- companied the emergence of centralized economies.
tics of traditional societies. With spheres of exchange, Most often, they were linked directly to control over
valuables were convertible only for other valuables and staple production.
not for subsistence goods; this lack of convertibility was The complexity and difficulty of control over the
in sharp contrast to the integrating distribution of all production of wealth are well illustrated by the Dan-
commodities within market systems. When I looked ish example.23 With the beginnings of the Bronze
at the ethnographic record for primitive valuables Age, metal became a major import into Scandinavia
in the western Pacific, however, I saw quite a differ- and was linked to the general emergence of social
ent pattern for traditional economies. In some cases, stratification. New bronze weapons and elaborate
valuables were exchanged freely for subsistence items, dress with bronze accoutrements marked the regional
while in others, they moved in distinct spheres of ex- chiefs and their warriors. Control was rather compli-
change. This variation in exchange (isolated in sepa- cated, involving the procurement, manufacture, and
rate spheres vs. open and interchangeable) proved redistribution of the new and dramatic metal objects.
to be highly political and can be linked to our under- First was the need to control local exports used to ob-
standing of redistribution.21 tain foreign metal. I believe that the rapid construc-
Spheres of exchange reflected emergent social strat- tion of chiefly burial monuments in Scandinavia and
ification linked to an ability to control the exchange elsewhere asserted chiefly ownership over grazing
and redistribution of socially and symbolically charged lands that allowed for chiefly control over secondary
objects. In the kula exchange of chiefdoms in the animal products (such as hides), which were traded
Trobriand Islands, the valuables were shell necklaces internationally.24 A limited number of highly gifted
(soulava) and armbands (mwali), which circulated in metallurgists were apparently also attached to chiefly
opposing directions and were largely exchangeable households, where metal production debris was con-
only for each other. On the Trobriand Islands, chiefs centrated early in the Bronze Age. The chiefs, who
controlled the interisland movement of the kula ob- sponsored the gifted craftsmen, then would use the
jects and then “redistributed” them to their support- special metal objects themselves and distribute them

19 23
Earle 1987. Kristiansen 1987; Earle 2002, 2004; Earle and Kristiansen
20
Bohannan 1955. 2010.
21 24
Earle 1982. Earle 2002.
22
Earle 1981, 1987.

This content downloaded from 128.197.27.9 on Sun, 31 Mar 2013 14:48:56 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
2011] REDISTRIBUTION AND THE POLITICAL ECONOMY 241

to their warriors. Later, this system of long-distance power, namely, economy, warrior might, and ideologi-
trade changed. Areas with substantial cattle produc- cal right.28 The development of a political economy was
tion and wealth, such as Thy, became socially leveled, based on bottlenecks in resource flows as mobilized
and other areas, such as the island of Fünen, became resources were invested (redistributed) into the three
new centers of power. At this point, the bottleneck sources, supporting the construction and maintenance
in the commodity chain of metal wealth ceased to be of intensive agricultural facilities, an enforcing warrior
the controlled export of hides; chiefly barrows were elite, and the priests, ceremonies, and monuments of
no longer built, and metal production became quite the ruling religion. This model of the emergence of a
widespread. The bottleneck for control appears to political economy emphasizes the highly flexible, adap-
have shifted to ownership of long-distance boats and tive, and changing nature of control, as new opportuni-
specialized warriors to protect their excursions. ties emerged and threats challenged. This is a model of
Control over valuables was frequently part of chiefly a political economy that takes no special form, except
redistribution, but I feel that such control is more dif- the ability to mobilize and direct resources in support
ficult and problematic than control over staple produc- and extension of ruling institutions.
tion based on land ownership. Chiefdoms and states
based on control over wealth production and trade a hypothetical model of political
were probably secondary, arising in broad arcs around economy
agrarian states.25 The increasing demand for luxury Redistribution as an economic type has outlived its
items in the developing states would have created ex- usefulness, but, with 50 years of broad use, it should
tensive systems of trade, with opportunities for control be retained as a way to understand emergent politi-
by bottlenecks in transportation routes, as along the cal economies that mobilize and allocate resources
Danube and other rivers of Europe, and in specialized to support developing political institutions. No total
trading vessels and the naval means to defend them. In economy should be characterized as redistributive,
medieval Europe, the Vikings provide a good example only the sectors that were centrally managed for fi-
of this phenomenon, and, as I will return to, the Ae- nance. Among complex societies, resource channel-
gean Bronze Age was perhaps another example. ing was essential for finance. But it was highly variable
To understand redistribution is to understand ar- from society to society and from microregion to mi-
chaic political economies. When looking at the largely croregion within a society. In the Aegean world of the
agrarian-based Inca empire, D’Altroy and I suggested Late Bronze Age, a system of interconnected political
the notions of staple finance and wealth finance as economies apparently resulted in dynamic emergence
alternative means to support political institutions.26 and decline in the political fortunes of small-scale poli-
Based on ownership of productive facilities, staple fi- ties, and this variation in political fortunes should be
nance involved the mobilization of staples, their stor- the focus of our studies of redistribution.
age, and redistribution to support ruling institutions. I offer an outsider’s overview of the Bronze Age
These systems were difficult to control at any distance, Aegean political economies. Bronze Age Aegean
because heavy staples were impractical to move far. economies can be divided into interlocking sectors:
Based on control over valuables, wealth finance in- the subsistence economy in the local communities,
volved the production and/or procurement of special the trading economy of entrepreneurs, the religious
objects to mark status, which were therefore useful as economy of sanctuaries, and the political economy of
payment. Staple and wealth finance could often be palaces. Each sector had specific objectives and opera-
joined. Staples were used to support attached special- tions, but they were linked together. The overall econ-
ists, who converted the staples into the more easily omy of any region was not managed centrally in any
moved valuables that would allow for a centralized comprehensive way, a conclusion that probably applies
political economy over a greater distance. These ideas to the economies of all chiefdoms and states.
link to Blanton et al.’s distinction between corporate With the summary provided by Halstead, the case
and networked strategies.27 materials from the contributors to this Forum, and,
Synthesized in How Chiefs Come to Power, the devel- especially, remedial help from the editors of this Fo-
opment of chiefdoms and other complex societies was rum, I have constructed a rough model of the Bronze
based on three interlocking and variable sources of Age political economies in the Aegean that may help

25
As argued by Parkinson and Galaty (2007) for the 27
Blanton et al. 1996.
Aegean. 28
Earle 1997.
26
D’Altroy and Earle 1985.

This content downloaded from 128.197.27.9 on Sun, 31 Mar 2013 14:48:56 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
242 TIMOTHY EARLE [AJA 115

guide future debate and investigation. My approach tied to trade in specialty materials (esp. metals) and
involves two analytical steps meant to identify both the prestige goods moved throughout the eastern Medi-
bottlenecks in resource flows that created opportuni- terranean and tied ultimately to Middle Eastern and
ties to mobilize surplus and the investments of the re- Egyptian demand. Trade is always difficult to assess,
sources into alternative sources of power. because it produces so few archaeological residues.
In terms of bottlenecks, although the options are Most evident, however, are the Bronze Age shipwrecks
many, three seem most likely for the Bronze Age Aege- that document lively commerce. Other evidence may
an. First is land ownership by an elite.29 Based on inten- include specialty production for export. Mycenae was,
sive, engineered agricultural landscapes of irrigation, for example, involved in the production of export ce-
terracing, and/or drainage, in many chiefdoms and ramics. Pylos, in contrast, has little evidence for export
archaic states, ownership of productive field systems production.
allowed elites to mobilize staple resources in return We need to consider carefully how the palaces could
for access to the land by commoners. While owner- have obtained metal that, as I discuss below, was prob-
ship of land was undeniably important throughout the ably central to the emergent political economy. The
Aegean world, it appears to have played a lesser role high-end prestige goods produced by the specialists
here than in many complex societies. Although the attached to the palaces would have offered one way
land was probably intensified with systems of terraces to obtain valued foreign commodities, including the
and managed grazing areas, the absence of irrigation metal imported from a distance. Probably the primary
and of heavily engineered landscape created a rather bottleneck that allowed the extraction of metal derived
fragmented pattern of ownership. The specifics of land from the fact that all trade would have been carried on
tenure across the Aegean were probably quite variable ships with limited routes of safe travel for such high-
and might be studied archaeologically by investigating value cargo. Palaces could have extracted payments
contrasting patterns in the demarcating features of the from merchants for access to safe harbors and/or for
landscapes, which include walls, monuments, and the the protection of shipping lanes. The beginnings of
like. As a generalization, the local communities (dam- a small-scale navy during the Bronze Age would, for
oi) seem to have owned most of the land, which they example, have given palaces considerable control over
managed for their own subsistence and other objec- the movement of wealth. Trade in wealth items is al-
tives. Sanctuaries held lands, too, which they used to ways a high-risk endeavor, for which chiefdoms and
support their personnel. Land owned directly by the states can guarantee “protection” from piracy.
palaces appears to have been quite small, so the sur- Third, many chiefdoms and archaic states were in-
plus directly controlled by them was probably modest. volved in high-end craft production of items that were
Storage for staples at the palaces, for example, was tiny used both as export products and as local wealth dis-
compared with some complex chiefdoms and archaic tributed by elites to build networks of support. The
states, and the primary use of these staples probably high level of crafting and the specialty materials cre-
supported the immediate palace retinue of guards and ated a bottleneck in the commodity chain for such
attached craft specialists. Although difficult to docu- wealth. For example, in Bronze Age Denmark, the
ment archaeologically, it seems likely that palaces main- largest chiefly residences housed bronzeworkers—
tained an overarching control over their territories that attached specialists who produced bronze swords,
allowed the overlords to mobilize gifts in staples and finery, and specialty items that armed a warrior elite
labor. Feasting, festivals, major building projects, and and distinguished elite status. By supporting and thus
wars would have necessitated substantial demands on controlling the manufacture of weapons and wealth,
communities to contribute to palace activities. an elite could control their distribution to the political
Second, many chiefdoms and trading states gener- system of chiefs and warriors. In the Aegean, craft pro-
ated surplus by taxing traders.30 Although the direct duction of high-end wealth was apparently controlled
evidence for this is lacking for the Bronze Age Aege- in two ways. Staple rations could be used directly to
an, I believe that revenues from trade were probably support gifted attached specialists living at the pal-
significant and could help explain the unusually com- aces, or, alternatively, metal could be distributed to
plex societies that arose here in contrast to elsewhere craftsmen, who were required to return a portion of
in Bronze Age Europe. The geographic position of the wealth items to the palace in the ta-ra-si-ja system.
Aegean societies suggests a maritime source of wealth Part of the control over these dispersed specialists, who

30
29
Earle 2002. Oka and Kusimba 2008.

This content downloaded from 128.197.27.9 on Sun, 31 Mar 2013 14:48:56 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
2011] REDISTRIBUTION AND THE POLITICAL ECONOMY 243

were involved in metal, ceramic, and other high-end The contingent and changing nature of this system of
production, could have been based on providing the networked polities should be evident; each attempt to
specialists with land for their support. Although the centralize power would be balanced by forces trying to
palace apparently controlled this land only indirectly, dissolve that centrality. The key to success of one local
their political influence may have been strong. lord or another would have rested on control of bot-
Staples and wealth obtained by mobilization would tlenecks in the systems of land tenure, trade in metal
then have been strategically distributed in ways that de- and other wealth, and production by attached special-
veloped palatial sources of power, involving attached ists of high-end weaponry and prestige objects. The
craft specialists, a warrior elite, and an organized re- religious economy of ostentatious ceremonial events
ligion. The use of mobilized staples was apparently would have been linked to the distribution of weapons
quite limited but still should not be underestimated. and wealth that bound warriors to their patrons and
The staples would have supported the palace reti- motivated the warriors to defend flows of staples and
nue of high-end crafters, who produced the items wealth that provided for the needs of the gods. As has
for metal export, internal distribution, and alliance- been discussed many times for the rise of city-states
building gifts. Staples also would have been needed and empires among later Greeks, this was a system of
to support both gifted craftsmen (architects, stone prestige measured by wealth, ceremony, and personal
masons, painters) and workers building the palace exploits. It was, however, ultimately deeply grounded
and its many facilities, which were used to display a in a political economy that mobilized staples from
sumptuous lifestyle and to sponsor ceremonial occa- land and commodities from trade to supply a central-
sions that measured status. Support of a palace guard ized distribution of wealth used to build the dynamic
would have been necessary to protect the palace and political system. This model is not meant to describe
to extract so-called surplus payments from reluctant how the Bronze Age Aegean operated; it simply lays
peasants, crafters, and traders. A primary use of sur- out some likely economic processes that would have
plus from palace lands and from other lands in the made it possible.
territory would have been to support elaborate feasts
and festivals associated with the palace and sanctuar-
ies. These festival occasions would have developed the department of anthropology
lord’s sanctity with reciprocal bonds to the gods who northwestern university
could help guarantee, in the minds of the participants, evanston, illinois 60208
the safety and productivity of the palace region. tke299@northwestern.edu
Distribution of metal and wealth was central to the
redistribution on which the political economies of
palaces depended. Partly controlling metal imports Works Cited
through maritime trade allowed for control over pro-
duction by attached specialists, who were provisioned Blanton, R., G. Feinman, S. Kowalewski, and P. Peregrine.
either directly by mobilized staples or indirectly by the 1996. “A Dual-Processual Theory for the Evolution of
distribution of land for their support. The points of Mesoamerican Civilization.” CurrAnth 37:1–14.
Bohannan, P. 1955. “Some Principles of Exchange and
control in the commodity chains of prestige objects Investment Among the Tiv.” American Anthropologist 57:
and weapons probably varied greatly from place to 60–70.
place and through time. The wealth obtained through Carneiro, R. 1970. “A Theory of the Origin of the State.”
distant trade and transformed by attached specialists Science 169:733–38.
would have served to obtain loyalty of regional war- D’Altroy, T., and T. Earle. 1985. “Staple Finance, Wealth
Finance and Storage in the Inka Political Economy.”
riors and to build alliances with other palaces. The CurrAnthr 26:187–206.
Bronze Age political economy created a networked Earle, T. 1977. “A Reappraisal of Redistribution: Complex
strategy dependent on gift exchanges of wealth, es- Hawaiian Chiefdoms.” In Exchange Systems in Prehistory,
pecially metal objects.31 edited by T. Earle and J. Ericson, 213–32. Studies in Ar-
I envision highly dynamic fields of power stretching cheology. New York: Academic Press.
———. 1978. Economic and Social Organization of a Complex
across the Aegean world that sought both to bind war- Chiefdom: The Halelea District, Kauai, Hawaii. University
riors to the palaces and to create regional confedera- of Michigan Anthropological Papers 63. Ann Arbor:
cies between palaces based on opportunistic alliances. University of Michigan.

31
Blanton et al. 1996.

This content downloaded from 128.197.27.9 on Sun, 31 Mar 2013 14:48:56 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
244 T. EARLE, REDISTRIBUTION AND THE POLITICAL ECONOMY

———. 1980. “Prehistoric Irrigation in the Hawaiian Is- Religious Authority in Precontact Hawaii.” CurrAnthr
lands: An Evaluation of Evolutionary Significance.” Ar- 34:1–38.
chaeology and Physical Anthropology in Oceania 15:1–28. Kristiansen, K. 1987. “From Stone to Bronze: The Evolution
———. 1981. “Comment: Evolution of Specialized Pottery of Social Complexity in Northern Europe, 2300–1200
Production: A Trial Model, by P. Rice.” CurrAnthr 26: B.C.” In Specialization, Exchange, and Complex Societies,
230–31. edited by E. Brumfiel and T. Earle, 30–51. New Direc-
———. 1982. “The Ecology and Politics of Primitive Valu- tions in Archaeology. Cambridge: Cambridge Univer-
ables.” In Culture and Ecology: Eclectic Perspectives, ed- sity Press.
ited by J. Kennedy and R. Edgerton, 65–83. A Special Nakassis, D., W.A. Parkinson, and M.L. Galaty. 2011. “Re-
Publication of the American Anthropological Associa- distributive Economies from a Theoretical and Cross-
tion 15. Washington, D.C.: American Anthropological Cultural Perspective.” AJA 115(2):177–84.
Association. Oka, R., and C.M. Kusimba. 2008. “The Archaeology of
———. 1987. “Specialization and the Production of Wealth: Trading Systems, Part 1: Towards a New Trade Synthe-
Hawaiian Chiefdoms and the Inka Empire.” In Special- sis.” Journal of Archaeological Research 16:339–95.
ization, Exchange and Complex Societies, edited by E. Brum- Parkinson, W.A., and M.L. Galaty. 2007. “Primary and Sec-
fiel and T. Earle, 73–81. New Directions in Archaeology. ondary States in Perspective: An Integrated Approach
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. to State Formation in the Prehistoric Aegean.” American
———. 1997. How Chiefs Come to Power: The Political Economy Anthropologist 109:113–29.
in Prehistory. Stanford: Stanford University Press. Polanyi, K. 1957. “The Economy as Instituted Process.” In
———. 2002. Bronze Age Economics: The Beginnings of Politi- Trade and Market in the Early Empires: Economies in History
cal Economies. Boulder, Colo.: Westview Press. and Theory, edited by K. Polanyi, C. Arensberg, and H.
———. 2004. “Culture Matters: The Neolithic Transition Pearson, 243–70. New York: Free Press.
and Emergence of Hierarchy in Thy, Denmark.” Ameri- Sahlins, M. 1958. Social Stratification in Polynesia. American
can Anthropologist 106:111–25. Ethnological Society Monograph 29. Seattle: University
Earle, T., and K. Kristiansen, eds. 2010. Organizing Bronze Age of Washington Press.
Societies: The Mediterranean, Central Europe, and Scandinavia ———. 1972. Stone Age Economics. Chicago: Aldine.
Compared. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Service, E. 1962. Primitive Social Organization: An Evolution-
Flannery, K. 1976. The Early Mesoamerican Village. Studies ary Perspective. Random House Studies in Anthropology.
in Archeology. New York: Academic Press. New York: Random House.
Halstead, P. 2011. “Redistribution in Aegean Palatial Soci- Wittfogel, K. 1957. Oriental Despotism: A Comparative Study
eties: Terminology, Scale, and Significance.” AJA 115(2): of Total Power. New Haven: Yale University Press.
229–35. Wolf, E. 1982. Europe and the People Without History. Berke-
Kolb, M. 1994. “Monumental Grandeur and the Rise of ley: University of California Press.

This content downloaded from 128.197.27.9 on Sun, 31 Mar 2013 14:48:56 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Das könnte Ihnen auch gefallen