Sie sind auf Seite 1von 60

Ecology & the Accumulation of Capital, 1

Ecology & the Accumulation of Capital slums, the traffic jams, and not these only as physical objects
but as ourselves in them and in relation to them… The
process… has to be seen as a whole, but not in abstract or sin-
A Brief Environmental History of Neoliberalism gular ways. We have to look at all our products and activities,
good and bad, and to see the relationships between them which
Jason W. Moore 1 are our own real relationships (Williams, 1980: 83-84, empha-
Department of Human Geography, Lund University sis added).

The developing tendencies of history constitute a higher Too often in environmental studies, we are riveted to the con-
reality than the empirical ‘facts’ (Lukács, 1971: 181). sequences issuing from society‘s footprint on nature. And this is
the way that many would put it (York, Rosa, Dietz, 2003; Jorgen-
―We have mixed our labour with the earth, our forces with its son, 2003; Wackernagel and Rees, 1996; Wackernagel, et al.,
forces too deeply to be able to draw back and separate either out,‖ 2002; Altvater, 2007). Debt leads to deforestation. Neoliberal pro-
Raymond Williams first argued in 1971 (1980: 83). In an extraor- grams drive cash-crop monocultures. Industrialization causes CO2
dinary essay, Williams directs his critique towards those ―singular emissions. Are these not reasonable causal statements?
abstractions‖ – society and nature – that confuse and obscure the The short answer is yes and no at the same time. All social re-
historical relations between humans and the rest of nature. But this search must explain change over time, necessarily implicating
is only part of what makes Williams‘ argument so extraord inary. some mix of cause and effect. But the nature of the story changes,
While we may perceive (or fail to perceive) the ―products‖ of hu- according to the ingredients of each moment. One‘s point of de-
manity‘s ―complex dealings with the physical world,‖ Williams parture – nature? society? the relation between them? – shapes the
outlines an approach that would demolish the fictions inscribed in range of possible destinations. What I wish to highlight in this es-
these singular abstractions, and deliver ―not only a more sophisti- say is an uneasy fracture within a broadly conceived left ecology.
cated but a more radically honest accounting.‖ This alternative ac- On the one hand we find a set of sophisticated arguments that na-
counting is one premised on relations rather than ―products‖: ture and society make a dialectical whole. On the other, a set of
empirically rigorous arguments that social causes (capitalism, in-
We ourselves are products: the pollution of industrial society is dustrialization, globalization) drive biophysical consequences (de-
to be found not only in the water and in the air, but in the forestation, CO 2 emissions, pollution). A relational ontology in the
realm of social theory rubs elbows with a mechanical ontology in
the realm of social history. (Although ―social‖ may no longer be
1
Prepared for the workshop, Food, Energy, Environment: Crisis of the Modern the way to put it!) The problem does not lay with the attention to
World-System, Fernand Braudel Center, Binghamton University, 9-10 October
―social‖ drivers or to ―environmental‖ consequences, nor with
2009. Very special thanks to Diana C. Gildea, Benjamin D. Brewer, Henry
Bernstein, Richard A. Walker, and Andreas Malm fo r sustained commentary on causal statements as such. Rather, a difficulty emerges with the
previous incarnations of this essay, and to MacKenzie Moore, Brett Clark, Erik elevation of these ―singular abstractions‖ to the status of actor and
Jönsson, Cheryl Sjöström, Harriet Fried mann, and Dale Tomich for discussions. acted-upon, foot and footprint, as the conventional metaphor
Co mments and critique welco me: Jason W. Moore, Research Fello w, Hu man would have it. In this metaphor, we see a symbolic enclosure (and
Geography, Lund University. Email: jasonwsmoore@g mail.co m. This draft 5
alienation) at work, which effects a separation of producer and
October 2009.
Ecology & the Accumulation of Capital, 2

produced, manifest in a purified social repertoire of agents and a mined in advance. ―The rise of monopoly capitalism,‖ in this
purified bundle of environmental effects. It is an eminently Carte- scheme of things, caused changes in the relation between nature
sian way of seeing. It is, in other words, an ontology that produces and society. But is it not more reasonable to say that ―the rise of
a critique of the social domination of nature while (paradoxically) monopoly capitalism‖ is a means of symbolizing (and explaining)
valorising its inner logic. This line of critique reproduces the very a vast web of nature-society relations, as they unfolded through
alienation of nature and society – an intellectual no less than ma- the crises of the British global market forged in mid-century?
terial movement – that it seeks to weave together. After a certain point, the social cause-biophysical consequence
If not the singular abstractions of society and environment, approach didn‘t say anything that most of us didn‘t know to begin
what? The shortest answer, as Williams suggests, is to adopt a re- with: Capitalism is bad news for the birds and bees, the water, the
lational ontology. Here is a method premised on the dialectical soil, and pretty much all living creatures on the planet. (This has
movement and interpenetration of the (so-called) social and the prompted environmental historians disquiet over ―declensionism‖
(so-called) natural. There is nothing new itself in this answer, so – isn‘t there something more to the story? 2 ) Empirical evidence
long as one remains with the spheres of social theory and the study might be amassed to verify this or that ―environmental‖ impact,
of regional transformation. But what about our stories of the mod- but within the limits of the Cartesian scheme, the socio-ecological
ern world? Translating this relational method from social theory to constitution of capitalism itself remains unexplored. In an expan-
world history has been an enduring challenge. That is to say, sive sense, the big question here is not so much about the centrali-
―green‖ social theory has not (yet) given rise to a ―green‖ history ty of capitalism as it is about the way we think capitalism, or if you
of capitalism. Now, it is certainly true that today we enjoy a vast prefer, modernity, industrialisation, and the many other possible
and enormously rich literature on ―environmental history.‖ But a n ―master processes‖ of world-historical change. 3 The alternative is
inspection of this literature, especially its world-historical compo- between differing ―ways of seeing‖ – between, say, a capitalism
nent, reveals a series of narratives whose motive forces are irre- (or modernity, or industrial society) that acts upon nature, and one
ducibly social – the great thrusts of European colonialism, of that develops through nature. We have, I believe, arrived at a po-
commercialising imperatives, of civilising projects large and small werful eductive moment – one that allows us to erase old bounda-
(e.g. Ponting, 1991; McNeill, 2000; Richards, 2003). ries and open new vistas, and one where we can reconstitute each
This sort of social determinism was indeed my own point of of these processes on the historical basis of the nature-society rela-
departure. Nearly a decade ago, I argued that ―environmental cris- tion. 4
es‖ and long ―systemic cycles‖ of environmental transformation Easier said than done! From this perspective, the call for ―inte-
complemented capitalism‘s phases of development (Moore, 2000). grating‖ human and natural history is very much to be welcomed
It was clear, for instance, that the rise of monopoly capitalism in (Costanza, et al., 2007a, 2007b; Beddoes, et al., 2009). I worry,
the later 19th century entailed a set of far-reaching agro-ecological
transformations, from the wheatfields of the American Midwest to 2
See Steinberg, 2004.
the copper mines of Chile and the rubber plantations of southeast 3
Tilly, 1984.
Asia. But I soon found that one could travel only so far with such a 4
Thus my argument counterposes ideal-type conceptions of capitalism – fro m
model. It was an approach that proceeded from a set of a priori the left and the right – in favor an methodological and theoretical approach that
constructions ontologically prior to the relations I wanted to dis- enables the construction of historical capitalism over large space and the longue
duree (Hopkins, 1978, 1982; McMichael, 1990; Wallerstein, 1974; Moore,
cern. In other words, the game was rigged, the outcome deter-
2007).
Ecology & the Accumulation of Capital, 3

however, that in the absence of synthesis – relative to integration – evident, the hegemony of Snow‘s ―two cultures‖ (1964) persists
we are left with models that cobble together multiple observed still in obscuring the nature-society relations constituting capital-
trends without explaining their interrelations. The ―interplay‖ of ism as a whole.
factors is recognized as decisive, but the specifiable relations, un- The alternative I will pursue is one that privileges the totality
derpinning the descriptive trends, remains in a black box. Costanza of nature-society relations. For this reason I shall borrow from the
and his colleagues, for instance, characterize the twentieth century Greek root oikos (home or house) and speak in terms of ecological
as a ―Great Acceleration… [whose] engine… is an interlinked sys- regimes, revolutions, and crises. And while the Greeks of antiquity
tem that consists of population increase, rising consumption, ab- did not have a word for ecology, the philosopher-botanist Theoph-
undant cheap energy, and liberalizing political economies‖ (2007b: rastus deployed the term oikeios in a way very close to our own:
525). As such, the argument for causation in global environmental ―to indicate the relationship between a plant species and the envi-
change tends to fall back on social drivers – rather than socio- ronment‖ (Hughes, 1994: 4, emphasis added). The shorthand
ecological relations – in a manner very close to world environmen- ―ecological‖ therefore speaks to a holistic perspective on the or-
tal history‘s black boxing of commercialisation, population ganism-environment/society-environment relation. Each dialectical
growth, and industrialisation. 5 movement is actively constructed by (and through) the other. If
And yet, everything need not be ―deep history.‖ There is much organism and environment constitute the parts, ecology signifies
to be learned from an examination of the interplay of distinct long the whole that emerges through these relations (Levins and Le-
waves (and distinct temporal logics) framing the rise and fall of wontin, 1985).
world hegemonies, financial complexes, and yes, ―environmental‖ I have therefore refrained from the language of environmental
change in the modern world. But I will suggest that the relations of crisis, and embraced that of ecological transformation. Ecology
whole cannot be reduced to the sum of these interactions. A mass and ecological, then, signify the relations of the whole, mediated
of evidence indicting capitalism (or modernity, or industrial soc ie- through the partial totalities of capital accumulation and the shift-
ty) for its manifold environmental stressors and stresses does not ing mosaic of nature-society relations. Such a perspective implies
explain how these stresses are generated (and how they are genera- and indeed necessitates a much different set of questions from the
tive), how they turn into crises, and what kinds of crises they im- Cartesian model. Rather than write a history of capitalism‘s im-
plicate. pact on the environment, then, we might posit a generative relation
From where I sit, to say that every phase of capitalist develop- between ―endless accumulation‖ and the ―endless conquest of na-
ment is ―complemented by‖ a specific mode of environmental ture.‖ Instead of a method that identifies ―society‘s‖ footprint on
transformation makes about as much sense as saying that every the rest of nature, we might well ask how the provisionally stab i-
phase of capitalism are complemented by new bourgeoisies, new lized relations between these two end-points creates, simultaneous-
imperialisms, new socio-technical innovations. But where the ge- ly, a ―footprint‖ on society no less than upon the so-called ―envi-
nerative capacities of new bourgeoisies, imperialisms, and innova- ronment.‖ The accumulation of capital and the production of na-
tions in the making of successive capitalist orders have been self- ture are, then, distinct rather more than discrete categories, so in-
tertwined as to make the one unthinkable without the other.
If these are distinctive moments within a dialectical unity, we
5
For example, McNeill, 2000; Richards, 2003; Ponting, 2003. For a engage- might ask, just what are the methodological frames and conceptual
ment of the problem o f explanation in world environmental h istory, see Moore,
premises necessary to illuminate these relations?
2003b.
Ecology & the Accumulation of Capital, 4

constituted through a succession of ecological regimes that crys-


tallize a qualitative transformation of capital accumulation – for
instance the transition from manufacture to large-scale industry –
Wall Street is a Way of Organising Nature within a provisionally stabilized structuring of nature-society rela-
tions. Ontologically speaking, historical capitalism emerges
My response builds out from a simple proposition: Just as a through the dialectic of the accumulation process and nature-
farm is a way of organising nature, so is a market, an empire, a society relations. I am making a deliberately provocative argument
factory. There are distinctions to be made, of course. Let us be here for a simple reason. So long as we continue to view class
clear, at the outset, that the ―production of nature‖ is no act of structures, state- machineries, geopolitics, industrialisation, cultural
Promethean constructivism; it signifies a coevolutionary process. production (and many more besides) as complemented by a specif-
The production of nature qua the production of capital expresses a ic socio- institutional mode of governing ―first‖ natures and prima-
definite relation with (not to) nature. Our putatively ―social‖ for- ry production, we find ourselves in a Cartesian trap. 6 To put it
mations make history, but not within biophysical relations and de- straight, there is not a social ―context‖ for ecological change; there
terminations of their own choosing; ―society‖ is as much biophysi- is not an ecological ―context‖ for social change. There is no con-
cally constructed as nature is socially constituted, even as these text… at all! The socio-cultural, the political, the economic –
constructions and constitutions reveal distinctive modes of opera- merely to take the 19th century‘s tripartite vivisection of social
tion. science – do not now need to be ―integrated‖ with a deeper under-
The problem of language here is inescapable. The approach on standing of biophysical process; the vivisected body itself today
offer eschews a voluntarist approach – we cannot simply invent calls for internment, a higher synthesis birthed.
new categories to talk about the relations between nature and so- Nevertheless, to leave the argument at this level of abstra ction
ciety. We can, however, shift the terms of the discussion from a would miss a magic opportunity. Let us begin with a broad and
reductive focus on the end points (nature, society) to an eductive multilayered conception of ecological regimes as those repertoires
method, one capable of drawing out the relations through which of nature-society relations specific to successive phases of world
nature and society take shape, as material formations and intellec- accumulation (Arrighi and Moore, 2001; Moore, 2000). Recall our
tual constructs alike. Benton I think grasps the nettle of the issue: operative distinction, that regime, in this sense, opens a new angle
of vision on capitalism‘s ontogenesis: capitalism as ecological re-
To transcend dualism is not to abandon the making of dis- gime. Rather than engage in a certain rush to ―premature rigor‖ 7 –
tinctions between and within the domains conventionally surely amongst the great temptations of value-theoretics – I wish
assigned to one side or other of a dichotomy [nature, socie- to encourage a certain productive slippage between capitalism as
ty]. Indeed, part of the strategy may be to proliferate dis-
tinctions, to undermine the forced unity ascribed by dualis-
6
tic ways of thinking to each term… To do this is not onto- This conception stands, therefore, in dialect ic counterpoint to the technocratic
logically dualist (2001: 311, emphasis added). contrivance of ―socio-ecological regimes‖ and ―energy regimes,‖ absent the
social relations of production and reproduction! One can read, for instance, of
―agrarian sociometabolic reg imes‖ with nary a word of peasant-landlord rela-
Let me risk a blunt statement. Capitalism does not have an eco- tions. For recent examples, see, inter alia, Beddoe, et al. (2009); Krausmann, et
logical regime; it is an ecological regime. Or rather, capitalism is al. (2008); and McNeill‘s (2000, 2008) otherwise exemp lary work.
7
To borrow Fried mann‘s nicely turned phrase (1994).
Ecology & the Accumulation of Capital, 5

ecological regime, and the environmental regime of historical ca- and set in motion new (and contradictory) demands upon the rest
pitalism. Here I think we may find a means of relating metabolic of nature. That is to say, the town-country antagonism – overlap-
rift approaches (Foster, 1999; Foster, Clark, and York, 2008a, b), ping, but not be confused, with the core-periphery divide – is the
agro- food regime theory (Friedmann and McMichael, 1989; decisive geographical relation. Ecological regimes, constitute a
McMichael, 2009a; Weis, 2007), resource regime studies (Bunker matrix of relations governing ―town‖ (consuming surpluses) as
and Ciccantell, 2005), energy regime analyses (Podobnik, 2006), well as ―countryside‖ (producing surpluses). Foster‘s ―metabolic
and many more besides, with the ―deep structure‖ of capitalism as rift‖ is, then, not merely a particular output of capitalism, but con-
ecological regime. stitutive of the capitalist mode of production (1999). Every phase
By ecological regime, I highlight those relatively durable pat- of capitalism emerges through a revolution in nature-society rela-
terns of governance (formal and informal), technological innova- tions that create new possibilities for the expanded accumulation
tions, class structures, and organisational forms that have sustained of capital. What constitutes these possibilities? At base, every
and propelled successive phases of world accumulation since the great wave of capital accumulation has unfolded through and upon
long sixteenth century (c. 1450-1640). Ecological regime, from a greatly expanded ecological surplus, which finds its phenomenal
this standpoint, signifies the historically stabilized process and expression in cheap food, cheap energy, and cheap inputs. To the
conditions of extended accumulation; ecological revolutions mark extent that new labor surpluses can be mobilized through derurali-
the turbulent emergence of these provisionally stabilized processes zation, labor costs can be driven down as well – through cheap
and conditions. The focus is not on the interaction of social and food (driving down the minimum wage necessary for social repro-
biophysical essences – these are ―coupled‖ only in the sense that duction) and cheap energy (central to rising productivity). 10
the fish in a pond are ―coupled‖ with the pond itself 8 – but on the But just what does ―cheap‖ really mean? The vernacular may
socio-ecological constitution of modernity‘s strategic relations. be translated to more precise analytical language. Long waves
This constitutive dialectic extends far beyond the manifold emerge only when these ecological surpluses can be produced sig-
―changes in the land‖ commonly associated with environmental nificantly below systemwide production costs, those in primary
history: property relations, commodity-centered resource extrac- production above all. Britain‘s mid-19th century efflorescence as
tion, cash-crop agriculture, energy complexes, and so forth. 9 The the ―workshop of the world,‖ for instance, was nicely linked up
production of nature-society relations has been every bit as much with the agricultural revolution of the American Midwest. North
about factories as forests, stock exchanges, shopping centers, American grain replaced, on a extended scale, the relative exhaus-
slums, and suburban sprawls as soil exhaustion and species extinc- tion of England‘s ―agricultural district‖ in Ireland (c. 1780-1840),
tion. and would in time be complemented by new granaries in Russia,
These ecological regimes comprise, at a minimum, those mar- India, and elsewhere. Between the 1846 repeal of the Corn Laws
ket and institutional mechanisms necessary to ensure adequate and the downturn of the 1870s, Britain‘s grain imports increased
flows of energy, food, raw material, and labor surpluses to the or- 254 percent. Grain arriving from the United States, however, in-
ganizing centers of world accumulation – but we should also at- creased forty- fold, from 25,000 tons to over a million, providing
tend to the production complexes that consume these surpluses, more than half of Britain‘s total grain imports by the end of the

8
Pace Berkes, Cold ing, and Folke (2003), Liu, et al. (2007).
9 10
The phrase is fro m Cronon‘s classic study of colonial New Eng land (1983). On energy and labor productivity, see Jorgenson, 1981, 1984.
Ecology & the Accumulation of Capital, 6

period (calculated from Atkin, 1992: 17-18). 11 It is true that grain geographical expansion have opened vast opportunities for
prices fell only modestly in this golden age of British capitalism channeling a growing share of biospheric wealth into the apparatus
(Barnes, 1930: 290), but this is surely a major accomplishment in of capital accumulation. It has been the genius of capitalism to
light of England‘s rapid population growth (16-23 million) and take advantage of these opportunities in a manner no other civilisa-
rapid industrialisation (one-third of world manufacturing). Prices tion was able to do – composing a succession of socio-technical
would tumble sharply downwards in the generation after 1873, innovations that maximized biophysical throughput relative to la-
even as England came to consume 80 percent of its daily bread bor, and which continually revolutionized the very ―nature‖ of the
from external sources (Mulhall, 1892: 444; Thomas, 1982: 336; biophysical throughput itself. Simply put, modernity gave rise not
O‘Rourke, 1997) simply to more efficient iron smelters, but to new steam engines;
Long waves of economic growth (accumulation) therefore take not simply to more efficient steam engines, but to internal combus-
shape when and where the conditions for profitability are re- tion engines.
established after a downturn. But it is not easy to establish these This succession represents a profoundly more discontinuous
conditions. They depend not only upon socio-technical ingenuity, story than is often recognized. The transition to coal was punc-
but also upon vast rivers of biophysical wealth without which the tuated by the Atlantic social revolutions and the Napoleonic wars;
new innovations are useless. Think, for instance, of the puddling the transition to oil, by two great world wars and a mighty world
techniques that allowed for the fertile marriage of mass produced depression. One could, I think, quite reasonably read the long his-
coal and iron in late 18th century England. 12 The Industrial Revolu- tory of agricultural and industrial revolutions in the modern world
tion, to stick with our example, unfolded through the unprecedent- as a succession of globalizing ecological revolutions that have li-
ed collection of cotton, iron, and coal surpluses whose value co m- berated accumulation from the socio-ecological fetters of the old
position (the average social labor inscribed in the commodity) was regime. What is so often missed, however, is that the rise and de-
very low – relative to, say, shipbuilding or watchmaking. 13 To be mise of successive ecological regimes does not turn on new phases
sure, there were variable reasons for such low value composition – of biophysical exploitation and thence exhaustion as self-evident
favorable geology and canal infrastructure (Welsh coal), the a l- facts. 14 Rather, new agricultural and industrial revolutions
luvial soils of the Mississippi Delta (cotton), the deployment of emerged in response to the relative exhaustion of those ecological
serf labor and simple manufacture in the Urals (iron). spaces not only occupied by – but indeed produced by – the old
In other words, inputs and labor power had to be mobilized ecological regime. 15 The ecological crises of historical capitalism
cheaply, ―cheap‖ precisely because they were abundant relative to are, in other words, crises of the nature-society relations that ena-
the conditions of commodity production and exchange on the eve ble (or fetter) the endless accumulation of capital. They are crises
of a renewed long wave. Historically, we have seen two key mo- of the actually existing relation of socialised nature through the
ments in the formation, and successive decomposition, of this rela- law of value, not of an abstract nature of ―wilderness‖ one, twice
tive ecological surplus. In the first instance, recurrent waves of (or even thrice!) removed.

11
Russian wheat, too, was important, for similiar reasons – but still ranked a
clear second to the U.S. (Atkin, 1992: 18).
12 14
Gordon, 2001: 133-34. As with a longstanding literature on soil exhaustion and civilisation (Mon t-
13
Lloyd-Jones (1990) offers a perceptive and co mplementary accounting of this gomery, 2007; Hyams, 1952; Whitney, 1925).
15
process from a Schu mpeterian perspective. With a nod to Lefebvre (1991).
Ecology & the Accumulation of Capital, 7

I have pitched the tent quite broadly for a deliberate reason. mental history momentarily.) The question could be multiplied
Capitalism does not move through its successive phases of deve l- with ease.
opment by organising new ecological regimes that govern the ex- To be sure, here is a dizzying array of relational webs. The
panded reproduction of food, energy, and materials surpluses. (Al- bounding choices are not easy. Let us be clear about the implica-
though these latter are in fact pillars of every ecological regime, tions of our paradigmatic choices. A Cartesian optic leads in one
and can be fruitfully analyzed through the specification of regime direction (social forces in one box, biophysical change in another),
concepts for each of these mediations.) Rather, every epochal refa- a dialectical optic, in another (all social relations are ecologically
shioning of the circuit of capital – from money to production to constituted).
commodities and back again – is enabled by, represents, and
creates, a new ensemble of nature-society relations. Capitalism
emerges as this accumulation process mobilises through (and re-
shapes) the uneven conditions of possibility and constraint drawn Value Theory & the Great Frontier: Capitalism,
by the ecological regime, which finds its geographical limit in the Ecology, and the World-Historical Method
socially necessary division of labor of the system as a whole.
What this means is that transitions from one phase of world If everything is ecological because ecology is everything, nev-
development to another are about cascading bifurcations in the de- ertheless we cannot do everything at once. My procedure in this
cisive bundles of nature-society relations – commodity production essay moves strongly against the received wisdom, even within
and exchange, state machineries and geopolitics, class relations. left ecology. 16 In what follows, I take Marx‘s lead and begin from
This is, I think, widely seen, but not recognized. If we look at the the expanded reproduction of surplus value (1976). The emergent
transition from postwar Keynesianism to neoliberalism that began contradictions of the accumulation process constitute the point of
in the 1970s, for instance, we can see that all the moments of this departure. But these offer only a necessary, not sufficient, explana-
transition represented new weaves of nature and society: the end of tion of historical change. 17 The decision stems not from any theo-
Bretton Woods and the resurgence of finance capital, energy and logical adherence to value theory, but rather from a reading of a
food price shocks, the fearsome imperial valences of the ―shock
doctrine‖ in Latin America and elsewhere, the globalisation of 16
Classic points of reference in this tradition would include Altvater, 1993;
agribusiness, a savage employers‘ offensive against core working
Benton, 1989; Blaikie and Brookfield, 1987; Braun and Castree, 1998; Bunker,
classes from Stockholm to Detroit, the biophysical disasters of the 1984, 1985; Bu rkett, 1999; Enzensberger, 1974; Foster, 1999, 2000; Harvey,
third world debt regime, de-peasantisation and mega-urbanisation, 1974, 1993, 1996; Levins and Lewontin, 1985; Martinez-Alier, 1987;
the de- industrialisation of the North and (re)industrialisation of the O‘Connor, 1998; Peet and Watts, 1996; Peluso, 1992; Peluso and Watts, 2001;
South, just to offer a sampling of the transition‘s salient move- Perelman, 1975; Schnaiberg, 1980; Smith, 1984; Watts, 1983; Worster, 1990.
17
―Marx himself pointed out that the abstract scheme of capital develop ment
ments. Some of these are palpably biophysical, while others ap-
was not enough to provide any predictions about the actual world. A ll crises in
pear as emphatically social. But is it really possible to explain ei- capitalis m must be explained out of the given empirical cond itions, ―out of the
ther moment in the absence of the other? Was the financial expan- real movement of cap italist production, competition, and credit‘ [Marx, 1905, II:
sion set in motion during the 1970s really independent of export- 286]. The value analysis of capital develop ment postulates ―the possibility of
driven agriculture and industry, with their manifold tales of toxic crises by a mere consideration of the general nature of capital, without regard to
the additional and real relations that form the conditions of the real production
work and dirty water? (We will return to neoliberalism‘s environ-
process‘ [Marx, op. cit., 264] (Mattick, 1969: 61).‖
Ecology & the Accumulation of Capital, 8

double lacuna in left ecology. On the one hand, social construc- mulation, but equally a subjective project of world power; and 3) a
tionists have been reluctant to ground their relational ontologies of world- historical process and project of reordering of the totality of
Swyngedouw‘s ―socionature‖ in an interpretation of capitalism as the nature-society dialectic, such that one ecological moment is
world- historical process (1999). 18 Environmental historians, on the internalised qua human labor power (reclassified as ―social‖) and
other hand, have been (quite reasonably) focused on landscape another is externalised through the progressive subsumption of the
change, energy consumption, pollution, and so forth – the surficial rest of nature as a ―free gift,‖ to use Marx‘s well- turned (and em-
expressions of modern nature-society relations – but have been phatically critical) phrase (1967, III: 745). The production of na-
wary to move from ―environment‖ to oikeios and back again. 19 A ture, in other words, does not represent a phenomenal form, but is
world- historical working of value theory offers, I believe, a fruitful rather constitutive of capitalism‘s inner logic – the contradiction
way forward without abandoning the insights of either camp. With between monetary value and use-value, between nature as labor
Marx, I shall move from the analysis of what makes capital to power and nature as resource, between competition for endless
what capital makes, from the logic of capital to the history of capi- gain and cooperation for necessary survival.
talism. Why Marx‘s value theory? Is this not an anti-ecological formu-
Value theories are of course hotly contested, Marxist, green, lation that explicitly denies nature‘s contribution to capitalist de-
and otherwise (Harvey, 1996; Daly and Townsend, 1993). My ap- velopment? 20 Allow me to interweave two responses, one from the
propriation of Marx‘s theory is to look at value as a means of un- perspective of capital, another from the history of capitalism. We
derstanding how such an extraordinary circulation of wealth has can begin by clarifying that value, in Marx‘s hands, represents a
come to move about with such relative autonomy from the practic- historically- specific form of wealth – whose ―original sources‖ are
es and utilities of everyday life, human no less than extra-human land and labor (Marx, 1976: 638). Taking shape during the long
nature. There is an ever-present danger to see one‘s theory of value transition to capitalism, here was a form of wealth that pivoted on
as a sort of Rosetta Stone, relieving oneself of the thorny tasks of endless commodification. During this era, a most peculiar valua-
historical explanation. tion emerged, one centered on the activity of that ―value forming
In my reading, the crystallization of value as abstract social substance,‖ human labor power (Marx, 1976: 129). This crystalli-
labor in the capitalist era represents: 1) a fundamental contradic- zation of value as socially necessary labour time – the average so-
tion between value and use-value, whose inner contradiction finds cial labour time embodied in any given commodity – illuminates a
(temporary) resolution in the secular trend towards the commodifi- crucial, ever-widening disjuncture in the history of the modern
cation of everything; 2) not merely an objective process of accu- world, between value and the use-value, the ―physical body‖ of the
commodity itself (Marx, 1976: 126). In a system such as capital-
ism, driven towards endless accumulation through the surreal
18
Smith takes pains to distinguish his ―production-of-nature thesis‖ from social compulsions of ceaseless competition, there unfolds a widening
constructionism, and persuasively so (2007). For my purposes, I wish to bracket
gap between the accumulation of value and the socio-ecological
this debate as one unfolding with a broader camp of non -Cartesian left ecology
(e.g. Braun and Castree, 1998; Harvey, 1993, 1996; Levins and Lewontin, 1986; relations that enable such accumulation.
Smith, 1984; W illiams, 1980).
19
Pivots of discussion in environ mental h istory include Cronon, 1983, 1991,
1996; Crosby, 1972, 1985; Dean, 1995; Gadgil and Guha, 1992; Grove, 1995;
20
McNeill, 2000; Merchant, 1980, 1989; Nash, 1967; White, 1996; Worster, 1985, See, inter alia, Bunker‘s classic crit ique (1985). A useful review of the ―value
1989, 1990. A good survey may found in McNeill, 2003. problem‖ in eco logical economics is found in Burkett, 2003b.
Ecology & the Accumulation of Capital, 9

If ―land productivity‖ was given primacy in pre-capitalist civi- basis of abstract social labor on the one hand, and the ―physical
lisations, ―labor productivity‖ became the chosen metric of wealth body‖ of the growing mass of commodities on the other – that ex-
in the capitalist era. It is a simple, and simplifying, logic. More and plains an extraordinary shift in the production of nature after 1450.
more extra-human nature attaches to every quantum of socially Civilisations before capitalism transformed landscapes on a
necessary labor time. Fewer people produce more stuff. Land is large scale: feudal Europe, the Greek city-states, the Romans, suc-
sacrificed on the altar of labor productivity. Indeed, a centerpiece cessive Chinese empires, the Sumerians, and many more. In every
of green consciousness since the 1970s is the recognition of (so- instance, there were vital clusters of commercial activity and
called) ―industrial‖ agriculture‘s colossal energy and nutritional commodity production that were often quite important in such ep i-
inefficiency; a recognition amplified by recent research on ethanol sodes of transformation. What changed after 1450 were the rele-
(Pimentel, et al., 1973, 2009; Perelman, 1977; Nellemann, et al., vant units of time and space. Premodern civilisations transformed
2009; Tilman, et al., 2002; Fargione, et al., 2007). A single kilo- regions over the span of centuries. Capitalism transformed region-
gram of asparagus consumes 73 kilograms of energy in making the al landscapes in mere decades, and through the capacities of mone-
trip from Chile to New York (Friedmann, 2004: 8). But the flip tary capital to command and indeed to produce space, there
side of energy inefficiency was a greater than eight fold increase in emerged a fundamentally globalising mode of producing wealth,
the labor productivity of advanced capitalist agriculture between nature, and power centered on the commodity form. Sugar produc-
1945 and the mid-1980s (Bairoch, 1989). What the more-or- less tion moved, in roughly half-century cycles, across the Atlantic
conventional green critique is unable to illuminate is how this co- world after 1450, from Madeira to São Tomé, enclosing in succes-
lossal inefficiency is not merely an output of the system, but co n- sive turns Pernambuco, Bahia, Barbados, and thence the wider Ca-
stitutive of it. For this peculiar valuation of wealth as abstract so- ribbean. Silver mining flowered in central Europe, moving res-
cial labor – labor productivity – favors socio-ecological develop- tlessly from one site to another (Freiberg to Jáchymov), then relo-
ments that reward the rapid exhaustion of nature (including human cated through the alchemies of imperial power and finance capital
nature), so long as external supplies can be secured. to Potosí, half a world away, only to give way in turn to the great
We can glimpse the emergence of this peculiar valuation from silver mines Zacatecas and Guanajuato in the eighteenth century.
the earliest moments of the transition to capitalism, during Brau- Commodity frontiers premised on forest products, on fish, on iron
del‘s ―long‖ sixteenth century (1450-1648). The genius of early and copper, on cereals and flax, moved with the same socio-spatial
capitalism‘s ―commodity frontier‖ strategy was to raise labor rhythm (although as dance, not lockstep), occupying, producing,
productivity by treating uncapitalised nature as a substitute for and exhausting in serialised fashion the ecological formations of
machinery. 21 At every turn, land (forests, silver veins, fertile soils) the North Atlantic, from the shores of Newfoundland to southern
was organized by empires, planters, seigneurs, yeoman farmers Norway to the banks of the Vistula and the foothills of the Urals
and many others, as a force of production in servitude to the com- (Moore, forthcoming a, b). And far from the facile representation
modity form, as a mechanism for maximizing the productivity of of early capitalism as technologically or socially inert, every
labor. It was precisely the emergence of this value relation – driv- movement of global occupation and transformation signaled a new
ing a growing disjuncture between monetary accumulation on the phase of social organisation, technical deployment, and landscape
discipline. Never before had any ecological regime qua mode of
21
production moved so fast, so far. Something decisive had changed.
The ―natural fertility of the soil can act like an increase of fixed capital‖
(Marx, 1973: 748).
Ecology & the Accumulation of Capital, 10

To call that ―something‖ nature-society relations would merely relations interconnecting the accumulation of value and the socio-
restate the very problem we seek to answer. This is the problem ecological relations that variously enable and limit the endless ac-
that confronts recent Marxist approaches to peak oil. It is excee- cumulation of capital. Most fundamental, the historical conditions
dingly difficult to argue convincingly for the world-historical cen- through which a series of ecological revolutions have been realised
trality of an energy source in the capitalist era without locating the – each yielding a quantum leap in the mass of ―physical bodies‖
production of energy within the central dynamics of accumulation. available for commodity production – may be understood as essen-
One does not need historical materialism to understand that coal, tially non-substitutable, or at best, substitutable only within very
then oil, enhanced the productivity of labor and the mobility of definite limits. Capitalism has moved from peat and charcoal to
capital. 22 But if we can accept, even provisionally, that value coal to oil, from the breadbaskets of the Vistula, southern England,
theory identifies a ―deep structure‖ of historical capitalism that the American Midwest, from labor frontiers in Europe and Africa,
gives priority to labor productivity and mobilizes extra- human na- Latin America, and South and East Asia. These are not repeatable
ture without regard for the socio-ecological conditions of its re- events. Substitutability does not unfold through infinite time and
production, we have more than a simple restatement of the prob- space.
lem. We have an interpretation of capitalism premised on a fun- Here is a decisive methodological choice indeed. Marx‘s con-
damental disequilibrium in the (value) relation of nature and socie- ception of value seems to offer a useful way to cut through the
ty that makes the system. If we, moreover, follow Marx and identi- mass of appearances and to discern not merely the patterned
fy the external vent (the frontier) as central – recall how he moves movement of nature-society relations, but the logic animating the
in successive chapters at the end of Capital, from the ―conquest‖ emergence and evolution of those patterns. I have called this me-
of the national ―home market‖ to the ―commercial wars… which thod eductive because we are locating value as a ―gravitational
[have] the globe as its battlefield,‖ to the ―growth of the interna- center,‖ to borrow Shaikh‘s nicely turned phrase (2004). The pat-
tional character of the capitalist regime‖ and its mounting systemic terns themselves move at once in quasi- linear and contingent fa-
contradictions (1976: 913, 915, 929) – then we may begin to see shion. Premised on the dialectical antagonism of monetary accu-
the successive resolutions of the disequilibrating tendency as es- mulation (―into which all commodities dissolve themselves‖) and
sentially finite. And yet, let us be clear, such a formulation material transformation in commodity production (where money
―impl[ies] the possibility of crises, though no more than the possi- ―dissolves itself into all commodities‖), 23 and a recognition of cap-
bility‖ (Marx, 1976: 209). To realise this possibility, one must ital accumulation as both objective process and subjective project,
move from the logic of capital to the history of capitalism. Marx‘s value theory offers a most promising point of departure for
It would be mystifying to say that the limits of capitalism are comprehending the inner connections between accumulation, bio-
ultimately determined by the biosphere itself, although in an ab- physical change, and modernity as a whole.
stract sense this is true. More to the point, the possibilities for Upon this analytical terrain – between the theory of capital and
overcoming the socio-ecological antagonism inscribed in the value the history of capitalism – we find an extraordinarily productive
form itself are determined by capitalism as a system, that web of tension. It is a tension that we can explore by building upon, and
pushing the limits of, the theory of metabolic rift, arguably the
most dynamic perspective in critical environmental studies today.
22
See Huber, 2008; Altvater, 2007 for the Marxist interpretation; see Burke,
2008; McNeill, 2008 for the non-Marxist perspective. Aside fro m an explicit
23
critique of capitalism, I am unable to see the difference between the two groups. Quotations from Marx, 1973: 142.
Ecology & the Accumulation of Capital, 11

In Foster‘s original formulation (1999, 2000), capitalism is dialec- throughput relative to labor – there is no capitalist metabolic rift
tically bound to an epochal shift in the town-country division of without agricultural revolution; 2) the subsequent generalization of
labor – Marx‘s ―urbanisation of the countryside‖ (1973: 479). In value relations, implying a powerful contradiction between the
this reading, the separation of the direct producers from the means ―natural distinctiveness‖ of commodities and their ―economic
of production – and the progressive liquidation of seigneurial equivalence,‖ 24 presupposes and indeed necessitates the progres-
power in the countryside – implies a new geography of wealth and sive urbanisation of the countryside; and 3) the tension between
power. The emergent disciplines of the law of value directed all the country and the city is therefore central, not simply as empiri-
manner of biophysical wealth – laboring bodies and the cheap food cal fact, but as the geographical pivot, of value accumulation, me-
to nourish them, above all – towards urban spaces. In the transition diating biophysical flows from farm to factory through the built
to capitalism, the rift appeared as these ―original sources‖ of environments of the circuit of capital. In this view, ―town and
wealth were largely produced in agrarian spaces, but increasingly country,‖ no less than ―bourgeois and proletarian,‖ emerges as a
consumed in urban spaces. Absent a systemic mechanism to en- relational expression of the underlying contradiction between val-
courage the recycling of urban- industrial wastes to the countryside ue and use-value in historical capitalism.
– as was the case, for instance, with the ―night soil‖ traffic of Late My objection is not that the theory of metabolic rift has gone
Imperial China or Tokugawa Japan (Xue, 2005) – historical capi- too far, but rather that it has not gone far enough. There is, it
talism produces a specifiable tendency towards nutrient depletion seems to me, a rift within the metabolic rift perspective, one
in the countryside, and pollution in the cities. The secular trend movement holding fast to a nature-society divide, another seeking
towards escalating biophysical exhaustion and pollution – Foster‘s to transcend the underlying Cartesianism of modern social
―absolute general law of environmental degradation‖ (1992) – has thought. In the first place, we can identify a tendency to move
been punctuated by a ―series of successive, historical breaks in nu- away from the centrality of the town-country dialectic in Marx and
trient cycling‖(1999: 399; also Moore, 2000). Highlighting the rise Engels‘ understanding of capitalism (esp. 1970), and in Marx‘s
of ―industrial agriculture‖ after World War II, followed by the thinking about the emergence of an ―irreparable rift in the interde-
emergence of large-scale feedlots and the global feedstock sourc- pendent process of social metabolism‖ (1981: 949). Thus do we
ing in recent decades, Foster and his colleagues have illuminated see the metabolic rift as a description of how capitalism ―disrupts
the constitutive relations between capitalism, its geographical pat- the exchange between social systems and natural systems‖ (York,
terns (the metabolic rift), and the system‘s immanent tendency to- 2007; also Mancus, 2007: 277; Clausen and Clark, 2005; Clark
wards biophysical degradation (Foster and Magdoff, 1998). and York, 2005a). In Clark and York‘s hands, the town-country
In my reading, the central contribution of the metabolic rift dialectic appears as a ―particular geographical manifestation of the
perspective is to locate socio-ecological contradictions internal to metabolic rift,‖ which may be dissolved into the latter‘s ―general
the development of capitalism. But the conceptualisation follows a properties‖ (2005a: 400, 391, emphasis added). From these con-
different road than O‘Connor‘s theory of the second contradiction, ceptions, capitalism becomes a socially-constituted ―subject,‖ that
which we will consider momentarily (1998). The distinctive ex- creates an exogenous ―crisis of ecological sustainability‖ through
planatory power of the metabolic rift rests on three crucial connec- the ―disruption‖ of ―natural cycles‖ (Foster, 2001: 473; Clark and
tions: 1) primitive accumulation imposes value relations on the York, 2005a: 406; Clark and York, 2005b). The social logic of this
countryside, compelling rising labor productivity in primary pro-
duction, and establishing the conditions for geometrically rising 24
Marx, 1973: 141.
Ecology & the Accumulation of Capital, 12

ecological crisis tendency is found in an uneasy pastiche of Marx- ticular distillation of the metabolic rift into ―general properties‖
ist and neoclassical political economy, with pride of place given to loses sight of the whole as a ―rich totality of many determinations
the neoclassical logic of the ―Jevons Paradox‖: technological in- and relations‖ (Marx, 1973: 100). For Clark and York, in their
novation drives down unit prices for inputs, thereby widening the groundbreaking exploration of capitalism‘s enclosure of the at-
sphere input consumption and amplifying resource exhaustion mosphere (2005a), the town-country dialectic becomes a particu-
(Foster, 2000; Jevons, 1865, 2001; Clark and York, 2008). It is a larity dissolved into a general whole. This marks a retreat from the
perspective that locates accumulation crisis in one sphere and the geographical promise of the metabolic rift perspective. In substi-
―crisis of the earth‖ in another (Foster, 2009, 1997; Burkett, 1999, tuting a contradiction between ―society‖ and ―nature‖ exogenous
2003a, 2005; Foster and Magdoff, 2009). There is a relation be- to the spatiality of society and nature (town and country), they
tween the two, but one that strikes me as rather more Cartesian produce a crisis theory that is, quite literally, ―lost in space.‖
than dialectical. 25 Where Clark and York see the relations of town and country as
Such Cartesianism is, however, only one tendency. Indeed, the empirical facts, would it not be more fruitful to see town and coun-
dialectic method has been central to the metabolic rift project. try as one of several decisive internal relations ―directly given in
While I am less convinced than Clark and York in their certitude the concept of capital itself‖?
that such a thing as ―society‖ exists, they are assuredly correct in So when I argue that the metabolic rift has not gone far
arguing that, ―while social history cannot be reduced to natural enough, I am suggesting that the ecological contradiction (as oi-
history, it is a part of it‖ (2005b: 21). The crucial question posed keios) goes much deeper than even Foster, Clark, and York have
by our shared commitment to a dialectical method is this: How is acknowledged. For instance, Clark and York argue that the ―value
the metabolic rift ―directly given in the concept of capital itself‖ of oil has nothing to do with nature or natural cycles‖ (2005a:
(Marx, 1973, 408)? 408). If we look deeper, however, we can see that such a view
Surely part of the answer is directly given in Foster‘s reading rests on the (Cartesian) re-coding of human labor power as ―so-
of Marx himself. In this interpretation, Marx‘s critique of capital- cial.‖ But is not human labor power eminently socio-ecological
ism emphasized how ―bourgeois society‘s. . . domination of hu- (Harvey, 1998)? The intergenerational (re)production of labor
manity‖ rested on its ―domination of the earth,‖ especially in the power is itself a ―natural cycle‖ whose socialised flows are regis-
form of large-scale landed property (2000: 74). The endless accu- tered in the determination of socially necessary labor time (Sec-
mulation of capital is, in other words, the endless conquest of the combe, 1982). From biorhythms to bioaccumulation, on closer in-
earth. But rather than corral accumulation crisis in one pen, and spection we find it challenging indeed to determine the boundaries
biospheric crisis in another, might we instead begin from the rela- of the allegedly social and the seemingly natural.
tions the connect the two? I am therefore concerned that the par- Within the metabolic rift perspective, Burkett has gone farthest
rooting the analysis in the theory of value (1999). Demonstrating
25 that Marx‘s theory of value is unthinkable in the absence of the
Clark and York, for instance, argue for a Cartesian feedback-loop approach:
―the metabolic approach [addresses] both sides of the dialectic between society contradiction between the ―natural distinctiveness‖ and ―economic
and nature, considering the processes that take place in each realm, as well as equivalence‖ that constitutes the commodity form, Burkett points
examining how these positions interact and transform each other‖ (2005: 396, strongly towards a new synthesis of the metabolic rift. The stum-
emphases added). Notice the emphasis on the interaction of positions rather than bling block in moving towards such a synthesis appears, however,
upon the generative qualities of a contradictory relation, that gives rise to these
in an overemphasis on the theory of capital, at the expense of the
positions.
Ecology & the Accumulation of Capital, 13

history of capitalism. Burkett therefore inverts Clark and York‘s The classic debate over this temporal deferment (it has contin-
overemphasis on the historical approach to capitalism, at the ex- ued ever since) was sparked by Luxemburg‘s famous argument
pense of the logic of capital. Just as it unclear how the circuit of that capitalism could not survive on the basis of internal consump-
capital links up with actually existing technological and enviro n- tion alone. (Let us be mindful, that in her scheme even much of the
mental change in Clark and York‘s account, it is unclear how Bur- early 20th century German market was ―external.‖) Whatever diffi-
kett‘s now-classic ―red-green‖ accounting of Marx‘s theory of cap- culties may arise in her treatment of expanded reproduction and
ital translates into the history of capitalism. The challenges co n- the realisation of values, my sense is that Luxemburg‘s enduring
fronting the theory of metabolic rift therefore represent a particular contribution lies in her historical account of capital‘s incessant
instanciation of the broader problem of translating ―green‖ social drive to expand frontiers for a much different kind of consumption
theory into a ―green‖ theory of social change. – not consumer goods, but producer inputs, not least labor power
Extending the key insights of the metabolic rift perspective, we (1968: 361-362). Within mature capitalism, ―the natural propaga-
might posit the accumulation of capital, in its manifold relations tion of the workers and the requirements of accumulating capital‖
with actually existing socio-ecological complexes, as an ecological invariably entered into a dynamic contradiction that propelled the
crisis-generating, and crisis-attenuating, formation. If there are ―incessant transition to capitalism‖ towards non- and semi-
many possible forms of ―ecological crisis‖ in the modern world, capitalist zones, including those within early 20th century Europe
the relations underpinning these forms are found in a many- (Luxemburg, 1968: 361-362). On the matter of natural resources,
layered process through which the dynamics of accumulation link Luxemburg is even more emphatic. Cost-cutting in the extraction
up with the nature-society relations that are value‘s point of depar- and production of the ―elements of constant capital‖ has compelled
ture, and point of return. Here the essential limits of expansion are the ―unrestricted utilisation of all substances and facilities afforded
―external‖ only in a highly abstract sense. Rather, the guiding by nature‖ (1968: 347). If capitalist production (strictly defined)
thread on offer opens up an analysis of these limits as internally were somehow to be rendered:
constituted by the contradictions of nature and society that capital-
ism makes, propelled by the inner contradiction of the value form, dependent exclusively on elements of production obtaina-
between value and use- value, between the commodity in ―general‖ ble with [the] narrow limits [of the temperate zones], its
and the commodity in ―particular‖ (Marx, 1973: 141). Whereas the present level and indeed its development in general would
former moment (in general) presumes limitless expansion, the lat- have been impossible. From the very beginning, the forms
ter (―in reality‖) drives the contradiction to a series of crises on an and laws of capitalist production aim to comprise the entire
ever-―higher scale,‖ combining the ―highest development of pro- globe as a store of productive forces. Capital, impelled to
ductive power‖ with the ―most straitened exhaustion‖ of human appropriate productive forces for purposes of exploitation,
and extra-human nature (Marx, 1973: 750). From this standpoint, ransacks the whole globe, it procures its means of produc-
we may begin to puncture the myths of substitutability, and pose tion from all corners of the earth, seizing them, if necessary
new questions about how the accumulation of capital over the lon- by force, from all levels of civilization and from all forms
gue durée has been a spectacular moment of temporal deferment, of society. The problem of the material elements of capital-
one realised through the widening and deepening of capital‘s he- ist accumulation, far from being solved by the material
gemony. form of the surplus value that has been produced, takes on
quite a different aspect. It becomes necessary for capital
Ecology & the Accumulation of Capital, 14

progressively to dispose ever more fully of the whole riod of turbulence and conflict. Oil, for instance, emerged as the
globe, to acquire an unlimited choice of means of produc- fossilized pivot of the system‘s energy regime only after two world
tion, with regard to both quality and quantity, so as to find wars and a mighty world depression.
productive employment for the surplus value it has rea- How we periodize capitalism has everything to do with how
lised... The process of accumulation, elastic and spasmodic we understand the system, and shapes how we analyze the present
as it is, requires inevitably free access to ever new areas of conjuncture of possibilities and constraints. Of these latter, surely
raw materials (1968: 358, emphasis added). the apparent ecological moment looms large, as we confront a se-
ries of challenges that reads like a page torn from the Book of Re-
What, then, of ecological crisis? Let me offer a simple state- velations: global warming (Monbiot, 2006), species extinction
ment that I will take as my guiding thread. Historical capitalism (Leakey and Lewin, 1995), peak oil (Heinberg, 2003; Foster,
does not create ecological crises so much as it has been created 2008), water scarcity (Barlow, 2008; Pearce, 2006), unpredictable
through them. It is the relation between social power and biophys- new disease vectors (D. Davis, 2007; M. Davis, 2006), and so
ical process that has given rise to such crises. (Keeping in mind forth. But the relations that underpin these trajectories are not at all
that the symbolic distinction itself becomes possible only through apparent in this list; the construction of an ―ecological crisis‖ dri-
the forcible separation of the direct producers from the means of ven by, but not constitutive of, capital accumulation hardly makes
production; that the ―two cultures‖ devoted to the study of nature things better. Identifying a ―crisis of the earth‖ may be reasonable
and society drip with blood and dirt neither less nor more than our point of departure, but it begs the question. If endless accumula-
language of bourgeois and proletarian.) tion is the strategic mediating relation of humans and the rest of
Of these ecological crises, two great forms can be readily ob- nature, how do we know the crisis of the earth except through this
served – epochal and developmental ecological crises. We may relation?
briefly consider these in turn. First, capitalism, from its origins in The problem, for left ecology, is that our constructs of capital-
the ―long‖ sixteenth century, emerged out of an epochal ecological ism as a historical- geographical formation, and of its phases of de-
crisis (Moore, 2007). This was the crisis of the long fourteenth velopment, are scarcely rooted in the relations between social
century, which marked the end of European feudalism. Far from power and biophysical process. Instead, we tend to view today‘s
an ecological crisis narrowly conceived, the late medieval transi- biospheric challenges as consequences of capitalism – rather than
tion was a multivariate crisis in which the nature-society relation constitutive of the capitalist mode of production. This has not been
played a pivotal role. Ecological crisis, in this formulation, was not the result of some ―Promethean‖ blindness, as some critics of
so much a cluster of consequences (demographic collapse, soil ex- Marx would have it (Kolakowski, 1978, I: 412-414; Giddens,
haustion) as constitutive of the era‘s manifold crises – of states, of 1981: 59-60). Rather, capitalism has been premised on a frag-
class structures, of markets. mented relation of nature, pivotal to its expanded reproduction: the
Second, since the long sixteenth century, capitalism has devel- internalization of nature qua human labor power (reclassified as
oped through successive developmental ecological crises. That is ―social‖) and the externalization of nature as ―free gift,‖ to use
to say, the world capitalist system has developed through the cyc- Marx‘s well- turned (and emphatically critical) phrase. A periodi-
lical emergence of ecological crises, not in spite of them. Every zation of capitalism premised on just one of these moments is ma-
great wave of capitalist development has emerged through a new nifestly insufficient to the tasks of the present conjuncture. The
crystallization of nature-society relations, stabilized after some pe- crucial question, as I see it, is this: How does the history of capital-
Ecology & the Accumulation of Capital, 15

ism look different from the standpoint of the nature-society dialec- the supply-side, reinforcing difficulties the system already faces in
tic? In what ways might these differences lead us to (re)think capi- the realisation of surplus value through the sale of commodities.
talism in ways that inform our analysis of, and our political res- That is to say, O‘Connor sought to uncover the nature-society rela-
ponses to, the present crisis? tions inscribed in both movements – overproduction and under-
production – and to unearth the conditions through which the latter
What on Earth is an Ecological Crisis? crisis tendency would assume primacy, at some point in the (not-
too-distant) future. What I wish to underscore is the effort to bring
If we are indeed living through the midst of profound turning point biophysical transformation into the theory of accumulation crisis.
in human affairs, then our central question becomes, What kind of Whatever the pitfalls of O‘Connor‘s innovation, the act of bringing
turning point is this? An epochal ecological crisis? A developmen- ―political ecology‖ and ―political economy‖ together into a holistic
tal ecological crisis? Perhaps, even, a crisis of human civilisation theory of accumulation crisis is exactly the kind of theoretical in-
as we have known it since the Neolithic Revolution? novation needed, if we are to come to grips with the specificities
In posing such questions, my intention is push the broadly con- of ecological crisis today.
structionist perspective on nature-society relations onto the terrain In this respect, I think we may re-read the great divide between
of actually existing capitalism. The task immediately calls for a accumulation crisis theory and ecological crisis theory in two of
grasping of the deep structures connecting accumulation crisis and our greatest political economists – John Bellamy Foster and David
ecological crisis. If the alienation of nature and society has been Harvey – who are also amongst our leading theorists of nature-
de-stabilized in social theory (e.g. Braun and Castree, 1998; Dick- society relations (inter alia, Foster, 1992, 1999, 2000, 2001, 2002,
ens, 1992; Redclift and Benton, 1994; Barry, 1999; Foster, 1999), 2009; Foster and Magdoff, 2009; Harvey, 1982, 1993, 1996, 2000,
social reductionism remains secure in its hegemony over the 2003, 2005). Foster, perhaps best-known for the theory of meta-
theory of social change. Here I refer to the categories bounding, bolic rift (1999), is also heir to Baran and Sweezy‘s monopoly
and the analytical narratives emerging from, modernity‘s ―master capital theory. Baran and Sweezy‘s great innovation was to argue
processes‖ (Tilly, 1984) – commercialization, industrialization, that the increasingly centralization of capitals had qualitatively
demographic movements, social revolutions, development, colo- transformed the conditions of competition, such that the ―tendency
nialism, financial expansions, geopolitics, the accumulation of of the surplus to rise‖ had displaced the tendency of the rate of
capital. 26 profit to decline (1966). Foster has so far refrained, however, from
Perhaps most fruitful has been O‘Connor‘s notion of a ―second explaining how the production of nature matters to this scheme. 27
contradiction‖ (1998). O‘Connor‘s innovation was to attempt a Harvey‘s enduring contribution is the theory of spatial fix
synthesis of the capital- labor antagonism (a ―first contradiction‖ of (1982), highlighting the irreducibly geographical character of cri-
overproduction) and the capital- nature antagonism (a ―second con- sis formation and crisis resolution in metropolitan accumulation.
tradiction‖ of underproduction). For O‘Connor, rising costs issuing And yet, the theory of spatial fix remains at some distance from
from the degradation of the conditions of production has, since the the elegant simplicity of his argument that all social projects are
1970s, set in motion a dynamic that will fetter accumulation from 27
But see Dowd, 1989. Clark and Yo rk, writ ing fro m a monopoly capital pers-
pective, emphasize the centrality of waste frontiers in capitalist development,
26
A representative sampling of this literature includes: Anderson, 1974a, b; B. without however specifying the specific contribution of monopoly capitalism
Moore, 1966; Skocpol, 1979; Wolf, 1982; Wallerstein, 1974; Tilly, 1990. (2005).
Ecology & the Accumulation of Capital, 16

ecological projects and vice- versa (1993, 1996). 28 What is the po- centuries of early capitalism (Moore, 2007) – then one would ex-
litical ecology of the spatial fix, of time-space compression (1989), pect the accumulation crises emerging from the second contradic-
of the body as accumulation strategy (1998)? tion to be slow in building, rapid and explosive in their detonation.
How do we bring together these two mighty contributions, A theory of capitalism today that identifies the convergence of
such that accumulation becomes a bundle of socio-ecological rela- rapidly moving and explosive contradictions need not succumb to
tions? Such that, to paraphrase Williams, we have mixed these two catastrophism. (A word that runs like red thread though Foster‘s
moments so deeply that the relation between them is always vis i- work.) Harvey rightly observes that any perspective premised on
ble? ―the view that environmental catastrophe is imminent is a sign of
The landscape of crisis theory is treacherous ground. Crisis weakness‖ (1998). But invoking catastrophe and theorizing crisis
theories are fundamentally predictive enterprises. They build up are distinct. Harvey is surely among our most powerful exponents
and out from the analysis and experience of previous crises. At of a relational ontology of nature-society relations and a
their best, they seek to discern the underlying forces that have not groundbreaking theorist of accumulation crisis. And yet, in his re-
generated crisis, but will do so if they continue, all things being cent accounts of neoliberalism the connection between the two is
equal. O‘Connor has seen the day of reckoning coming, but the unclear (2003, 2005). We are treated to a social reductionist narra-
second contradiction cannot tell us just when that day might arrive. tive that, however brilliant, leaves behind nature-society relations
Foster criticizes O‘Connor on these grounds, acknowled ging that as an organizing principle. My point here is to underscore the
rising costs from ecological degradation may have some purchase enormity of the larger challenge, that of translating relational on-
on regional developments, but that in itself, the theory of the tologies into narratives of modern world history. As I suggest in
second contradiction cannot account for the stagnation of the the conclusion to this essay, Harvey provides a big part of what is
world-economy since the 1970s (2002). The global ecological cri- needed to meet this larger challenge. For in Harvey‘s theory of
sis threatens humanity but is not, Foster seems to be arguing, im- spatial fix (1982), the initial flexibility, and acceleration, of turno-
plicated in the ripening of accumulation crisis. There are two log- ver time achieved through a ―built environment‖ favorable to cap i-
ics, related for sure, but largely in mechanical ways. If, however, tal in one era, becomes a fetter upon accumulation in the next. In
accumulation crises unfold through the production of nature, Fos- this way, the remaking of nature-society relations, in successive
ter‘s critique may generate more heat than light. Foster rightly ob- eras, liberates accumulation only to imprison its ―future paths‖
jects to any excessively narrow conception of biophysical crisis (1991).
that derives its motive power from a narrow conception of accu- If we can agree that civilisation is indeed living through an era
mulation crisis. But this objection goes only so far. Deconstruction of transition that will compel fundamental revisions in the organi-
calls for reconstruction. What unifies the ―rich totality‖ of accumu- zation of economic life, biophysical process, and social power,
lation crisis and biophysical tipping points? If O‘Connor‘s second amongst the most pressing tasks is this. In order to understand the
contradiction tracks the emergence of a new crisis tendency within crisis today we need to understand the origins of these crisis te n-
late capitalism – or possibly, the reassertion of an older, underpro- dencies in their historical and geographical specificities. And I
ductionist crisis tendency that ruled the roost during the formative would say this is what is missing from these signal contributions to
the political ecology of capitalism – O‘Connor, Foster, Harvey,
28
and many others. While we have an ecologised theory of accumu-
It is however clear that this is the direction in which he moving, albeit cau-
lation crisis from O‘Connor, there remains a lacuna, located in the
tiously (Harvey, 2006).
Ecology & the Accumulation of Capital, 17

overemphasis on accumulation itself. For Marx, we may recall, the City as constituted by, and constitutive of, the cash crop fro n-
thinking capitalism consisted of two dialectical movements. The tier expansions of the 19th century (Cronon, 1991; Brockway,
first is the theory of capital, as we see in most of the first volume 1978); Wall Street as inseparable from the Green Revolution – in
of Capital. The second is the history of capitalism, such as we see, both core and periphery (Perkins, 1997). Whereas a social reduc-
quite early, in The German Ideology (Marx and Engels, 1970). It is tionist approach would view the financial centers as causal; and an
no mere happenstance that Marx reordered the ―general law of ca- ecological reductionist approach would begin from the conse-
pitalist accumulation‖ (theory of capital) and the discussion of quences of these financial webs, we might use both premises and
―primitive accumulation‖ (history of capitalism) into a single co n- look for a higher synthesis. This would reconstitute the history of
cluding part of Capital, in the last edition (the French, 1882) he capitalism, in this instance, as the crystallization of successive fi-
prepared before his death (Dunayevskaya, 1982). This dialectic, nancial-ecological complexes, through which one or another mo-
between an ecologised theory of accumulation crisis and a histori- ment enters into a determinative position in the lifecourse of these
cal account of capitalism‘s political ecology, has been scarcely ex- complexes. Would it be possible to do the same, we might ask, for
plored in left ecology. the grander movements of world accumulation over the past six
From this standpoint, what is needed is a theory that views the centuries?
increasing centrality of value relations over the past five centuries
as an ecological project. (That is, a project that transcends its so-
cial and biophysical moments.) Such a reconstruction of ecological Ecology & Accumulation Crisis: The Dialectic of
crisis qua accumulation crisis would lay emphasis on the irreduci-
bly ecological constitution of ―value‖ itself (as process and Underproduction and Overproduction
project) – its internalization of nature through labor power, and its
externalization of nature through the treatment of nature as a ―free We have become accustomed to thinking that crises in histori-
gift.‖ Value emerges in and through Braudel‘s ―market economy‖ cal capitalism are overproduction crises. David Harvey, for in-
(1982), weaving together the ethereal valences of finance capital stance, identifies the 1840s as the occasion of the ―first‖ capitalist
and the prosaic routines of everyday life in new world-historical crisis (2003: 42). If this is so, overproduction crises are a very re-
crystallizations of power and profit, pivoting on the commodity. In cent development in the history of capitalism. In fact, the long his-
this light, the surficially external relations of capitalism to nature tory of capitalist transition, from the 1450s to the early 19th cen-
are revealed as constitutive of new, profoundly restless, socio- tury, was one of recurrent underproduction crises – that it is to say,
ecological configurations. the insufficient flow of food, energy, and materials relative to the
To illustrate, let us take the most powerful instanciation of ca- demands of value production. Indeed, this is why Marx views the
pitalism‘s Cartesian logic, the quantifying logic of finance capital. whole era as one of successive bursts of primitive accumulation
In ecohistorical perspective, the emergence of successive financial (1976: Part 8), and why Byres, in the same spirit, views the Global
centers in the history of capitalism – from the Amsterdam Bourse South of the 1960s as wracked by ―under-accumulation…, an in-
to the City of London to Wall Street – becomes legible as the sufficiency of the means of production‖ (2005: 86).
emergence of new modes of ecological transformation. The Ams- It is often forgotten that Marx offered a theory of underproduc-
terdam Bourse as shaped and shaped by the transformation of the tion alongside one of overproduction. So powerful is the sense that
Vistula Basin and southern Norway (Moore, forthcoming, a, b); capitalism‘s fundamental crisis tendency is overproduction, that
Ecology & the Accumulation of Capital, 18

the decisive passage in the Penguin translation of the third volume are perhaps most evident in the great energy transitions from peat
of Capital (1981) reads ―overproduction‖ when it should read and charcoal (1450-1830), to coal (1750s-1950s), to oil and natural
―underproduction.‖29 What I wish to suggest is that capitalism may gas (1870-present). These energy sources did not make capitalism
well be headed towards the reassertion of underproduction crises so much as capitalism remade itself through their incorporation.
as the dominant crisis tendency. Let us, at any rate, hold this pos- To paraphrase Marx, coal is coal. It becomes fossil fuel ―only in
sibility as an open question. certain relations‖ (1971: 28, emphasis added).
Marx‘s theory of underproduction crisis – he calls it a ―general Now, it has been such an enduring challenge to drive down the
law‖ of accumulation – argues that ―the rate of profit is inversely cost of inputs because capitalism is not only a spatial system but
proportional to the value of the raw materials‖ (1967, III: 111). also a temporal one – the production of space and time are bound
(All things being equal.) And yet, the very dynamism of capitalist together. Capitalism not only accelerates the extraction of energy
production leads the ―portion of constant capital that consists of beyond the capacity of biophysical nature to regenerate. Through
fixed capital… [to] run significantly ahead of the portion consist- the escalation of control efforts, capitalism accelerates the evolu-
ing of organic raw materials, so that the demand for these raw ma- tion of biophysical nature itself – pesticide resistance is in this re-
terials grows more rapidly than their supply‖ (ibid: 118-119). For spect merely the tip of the proverbial iceberg. Over the long run,
Marx, the crucial dialectic consists of ―the ―overproduction‖ of the tendency of market competition and geopolitical rivalry has
machinery‖ on the one hand, and the ―underproduction‖ of raw increased the geographical reach of commodity-centered extrac-
materials on the other (Marx, 1967, III: 119). 30 Thus, an enduring tion. Sometimes this global reach has extended horizontally, across
priority of capitalism has been to drive down the cost of inputs space, and at other times it has stretched vertically, to grasp the
while simultaneously expanding, in geometrical fashion, the ma- wealth of coal veins, oil fields, and aquifers. The same competitive
terial volume of commodity production. Hence the centrality of the logic that compels such ―widening‖ of commodity relations also
frontier. Not only has capital sustained itself on the basis on cheap compels a powerful moment of ―deepening.‖ This movement re-
inputs (the quantitative moment), but by revolutionizing the eco- veals itself in rising capital intensity – Marx‘s rising organic com-
logical relations of production on a systemwide level (the qualita- position of capital (1976, 1981) – and this accelerates the extrac-
tive moment), it has mobilized a succession of ―great leaps for- tion of ecological wealth beyond the capacity of nature to regene-
ward‖ in the relative ecological surplus. These great leaps forward rate. 31 More free gifts from nature could be absorbed into the body
of capital only through the acceleration of this capital- metabolism
29
―The more capitalist production is developed, bringing with it g reater means itself. This was evident from the ―first‖ sixteenth century (c. 1452-
for a sudden and uninterrupted increase in the portion of constant capital that 1557), as the sugar planting and silver mining commodity frontiers
consists of mach inery, etc., the greater is the relative overproduction of mach i- in the Atlantic Islands and Central Europe were exhausted, only to
nery and other fixed capital, the more frequent the overproduction [sic] of plant give rise to the Brazilian sugar and Andean silver revolutions of
and animal raw materials, and the more marked the previously described rise in
their price and the corresponding reaction‖ (Marx, 1981: 214, emphasis added).
30
In this instance, I have stuck to convention and spoken of material inputs to
production as ―raw materials.‖ The category itself is part of the problem I am
31
addressing. Young (1985) states the issue quite well: ―‗Raw materials‘ is a eu- Perelman (1996: 73) goes so far as to argue that Marx deployed ―the organic
phemis m, because in the world of human beings no materials are truly raw. composition of capital as a code for scarcity, and that, in the back of Marx‘s
They are all ‗cooked‘ in some degree. There is simp ly no such thing for humans mind, scarcity was responsible for the falling rate of profit.‖ Or perhaps it is
as ‗nature in the raw‘‖ (1985). better to say, partially responsible.
Ecology & the Accumulation of Capital, 19

the ―second‖ sixteenth, century (c. 1545-1648) (Moore, 2003a, linear movement of ―time-space appropriation,‖ the reworking of
2003b, 2007).32 external spaces through the imposition of capitalist time. 33
Re-reading Marx in this fashion may help us take one step fur- At the level of the social economy, rising capital intensity –
ther Wallerstein‘s longstanding argument about rising costs and Marx‘s rising organic composition of capital – places downward
accumulation crisis (2004). For Wallerstein, three movements in pressure on the general rate of profit. The operative assumption
the history of capitalism have propelled a secular rise in the sys- here is that aggregate profit, on balance, flows from aggregate sur-
temwide costs of production: 1) the rising costs of labor power plus value, with is generated and distributed unevenly (Marx,
apace with proletarianization, as a growing share of world house- 1976, 1981). Walker nutshells the underlying tendency with typi-
holds come to depend on wage, relative to non-wage, remunera- cal verve (1998):
tion; 2) the rising costs of taxation, as democratization compels
rising expenditures on education, health care, and other social pro- Why [do] profit rates fall? The argument is simple. It is be-
grams; and 3) the rising costs of inputs, as the infinite expansion of cause the numerator in the profit equation, surplus value, is
capitalist production outstrips the finite qualities of biophysical outrun by the denominator, capital stock (both measured in
nature (2004). How have these tendencies been constrained, even annual terms)…That is, too much capital stock builds up in
at times temporarily reversed, in the history of capitalism? Surely factories and equipment around the world, pitting compa-
we can identify a series of interlinked responses in the most recent nies against each other in an ever-fiercer competitive brawl
phases of capitalist development – the reassertion of coercive- for markets. This holds prices down, leads commodity out-
intensive income redistribution from poor to rich (Klein, 2007; put to outrun demand at prevailing prices, and/or lowers
Duménil and Lévy, 2004; Harvey, 2005), the industrialization of capacity utilization rates – thereby lowering profit margins,
the Global South (Amsden, 1990; Arrighi, Silver and Brewer, leaving goods unsold, and running equipment at less effi-
2003), the temporal deferments of financialization. cient levels. 34
These responses, I want to suggest, are implicated in an under-
lying crisis tendency. On the one hand, competition drives capital- If expansion across space (global conquest) represents one fix to
ism to expand geographically, enabling capital to drive down the the falling rate of profit; innovation through time (capital intensifi-
cost of inputs, and in so doing, to increase the rate of profit. On the cation) represents the second. 35 The first moment extends the net
other hand, competition compels individual capitals to innovate of energy-resource consumption ever more widely, driving down
through rising capital intensity, such that relatively less labor and the costs of circulating capital (inputs); the second accomplishes
relatively more nature is embedded in every commodity. This ac- the production of more commodities with fewer workers in less
celerates the uptake of first natures into a geometrically expansive time, driving down the costs of variable capital (labor power). Nei-
production process, which intensifies the drive towards geographi- ther can be amplified endlessly. Global space is not only relational,
cal expansion. In this fashion, the quasi- linear movement of ―time-
space compression‖ finds its dialectical counterpoint in the quasi- 33
Hornborg, 2006: Harvey, 1989.
34
A rather more rigorously exp licated, if less streamlined, version is on offer in
Walker, 1999.
35
In the capitalist era, rising productivity is simply another way of saying that a
rising material volu me (in commodity form) is moving through the hands and
32
The notion of a ―first‖ and ―second‖ sixteenth century is Braudel‘s (1953). minds of workers in the same span of time.
Ecology & the Accumulation of Capital, 20

but asymptotic and finite from the standpoint of endless accumula- be attenuated – especially if ―capital saving‖ innovations run
tion. And although in theory, ―constant capital‘s material volume‖ strongly alongside labor saving movements 38 – and the tendency
may be augmented without limit (Marx, 1981: 317), the rate of towards a falling rate of profit, not only checked but (for a time)
exploitation operates within a much stickier field of power. reversed. 39
How does profitability revive? Marxists usually respond by The same logic applies to variable capital. If a sufficient vo-
emphasizing the role of crises in propelling creative destruction, lume of cheap food can be supplied to workers – and cheap food‘s
through: 1) devaluing fixed capital (such as factory shutdowns), biophysical costs externalised, for the time being – the rate of sur-
over the short-run; 2) increasing the rate of exploitation through plus value may be augmented in a manner roughly analogous to
technical innovation; and 3) increasing surplus value through wage wage freezes and technical innovations. The most spectacular
freezes or reductions (Walker, 1999; Harvey, 1982). booms in the capitalist era have woven these two moments togeth-
There is, of course, enormous debate over the relation between er – think of English industrialization with its heavy reliance on
accumulation crisis and the falling rate of profit. 36 For the present cheap energy (Welsh coal) and cheap calories (Jamaican sugar).
argument, I would prefer to bracket these, and simply point to a While focusing on the first moment, in what follows, I will treat
fourth moment. This turns on circulating capital (inputs), but with Marx‘s ―progressive tendency‖ towards a ―gradual fall in the gen-
important implications for variable capital as well. What I wish to eral rate of profit‖ (1981: 318-319) as a historical proposition on
underscore is that Marx‘s ―most important law‖ (1973: 748) can be the long-run relation between the overproduction of machinery and
more fully grasped – and its explanatory power radically extended the underproduction of inputs. I am less concerned with a precise
– by taking as a whole the contradictions between ―first‖ and operationalization of this proposition at a sectoral or national level,
―second‖ nature (machinery relative to inputs) as well as those and rather more with its utility for illuminating a decisive point of
within second nature (constant relative to variable capital). Indeed, fracture in the longue durée movement of historical capitalism. My
I am tempted to say that the crucial weakness in falling rate of sense is that this latter approach will allow for a broader conceptu-
profit arguments has not been the theory itself, but rather an over- alization of cyclical crises in the modern world-ecology – and a
emphasis on the ―wrong‖ moment of constant capital – on fixed serious questioning of the possibly epochal character of the present
rather than circulating capital. Could it be that since the 1830s, ca- crisis.
pitalism‘s technological dynamism has forged agro-extractive One may well object that underproductionist tendencies have
complexes capable of outrunning the tendency towards the under- been recurrently checked since the 1830s, that underproductionist
production of inputs? 37 If a sufficient mass of cheap energy and crises have been swept into the dustbin of history by the competi-
raw materials can be mobilised, the rising organic composition can tive-technical logic of capitalism. 40 There‘s a kernel of truth here.
The ―great depression‖ of the late 19th century is arguably the pa-
36
Useful surveys can be found in Mandel (1981) and Choonara (2009). See the
38
recent debate between Harman (2007) and Kincaid (2008). Between 1980 and 2005, ―relative price of capital goods has declined by be-
37
In the United States during the neoliberal era, energy expenditures declined tween 25 and 40%‖ in the U.S. and Japan (BIS, 2006: 24).
39
fro m 13.7 to 7.2 percent of GDP between 1981 and 2000 (WUTA, 2004); the Harvey, as if to prove the general point, views the ―release‖ of cheap raw ma-
composite industrial mineral price index fro m about 130 to 100 between 1975 terials as ―just as important‖ as other strategies in reviving accumulation, but
and 2000 (Su llivan, et al., 2000); and generally (if unevenly) declining food proceeds to give short-shrift to the subject in his recent analyses of neoliberal
expenditures as share of household income between 1980 and 2000 (Elit zak, ism (2003: 150, 139; 2005).
40
1999). See, inter alia, Buck, 2007; Burkett, 2005; Vlachou, 2002.
Ecology & the Accumulation of Capital, 21

radigmatic example. World prices for raw materials imported by dawn of the long 20th century, Malaysian rubber and tin, Chilean
Britain began to rise sharply during the 1860s and ‗70s, at the very nitrates, Australian copper and gold, Canadian nickel, all entered
moment of its peak industrial supremacy (Hobsbawm, 1975; Ros- the world- historical stage as key moments in an ecological revolu-
tow, 1938; Mandel, 1975). The inflationary moment was, as we tion that was ―far quicker, far more prodigious in its results, far
know, quickly turned inside-out, as world market prices generally more revolutionary in its effects on people‘s lives and outlooks‖
declined quite sharply (Landes, 1969). At the same time, an infla- than anything known before in the history of capitalism (Barrac-
tionary undercurrent was at play. The late 19th century was indeed lough, 1967: 44). What I wish to underscore is that the delivery of
characterized by the episodic and uneven moments of underpro- crucial ecological surpluses was achieved through the combined
duction in such key raw materials sectors as cotton, indigo, rubber, movement of capital- intensive and labor- intensive processes.
palm oil, copper, nickel, lead, tin, jute, and sisal (Headrick, 1996; State-of-the-art Canadian nickel smelters were of a piece with Ma-
Mandel, 1975; Brockway, 1979; Barraclough, 1967; Bukharin, laysia‘s tin sector, where nearly a quarter-million Chinese miners
1915; Magdoff, 1969: 30-40). These inflationary undercurrents ―equipped with little more than shovels and simple pumps‖ fed the
were set in motion by the rise of new industrial powers, Germany growing appetites of the new industrializers (Huff, 2007 : i131.).
and the United States above all. They were amplified further still One needn‘t take a resource-determinist view of the ―new impe-
by the qualitative shifts inscribed in the ―second‖ industrial revolu- rialism‖ of the 19th century to understand that the reorganization of
tion, premised on oil and petrochemicals, the auto, steel, and elec- world-ecology – at times coercive- intensive, at times capital-
trical industries, and the first synthetic plastics (Barraclough, 1967: intensive – was central to the trajectory of power and progress in
45-63). the long century that followed.
The underproductionist tendency was therefore checked but From the standpoint of world accumulation, the challenge has
not abolished by the second industrial revolution. The tendency been to strike the right balance between regularizing supply
within the inner contradiction between value accumulation and the (which is always rising) and making those supplies cheap enough
production of inputs was intensified, insofar as we restrict our at- to permit expanded accumulation. Rising capital intensity tends to
tention to the new industrializers. The contradiction was resolved regularize supply but does so by accelerating the place-specific
through the dialectic of productivity and plunder characteristic of exhaustion of profitability (see Figure I). 42 Capitalism has been
capitalism‘s successive global ecological fixes: 1) the radical en- remarkably adept at finding ways to overcome the basic tendency.
largement of the geographical arena; and 2) the ―massive penetra- Through capital intensification and innovation, capitalist agencies
tion of capital into the production of raw materials‖ (Mandel, have found ways to make more out of less in the short- to middle-
1975: 61). There is no question that steam power augmented the run. More out of less, however, is not something for nothing. The
capacities of capitalist agencies to transform space – as a relatively counter movement to the underlying tendency of input underpro-
modest amount of capital mobilised a relatively vast energy sur- duction has therefore been a frontier movement. From the 16th cen-
plus – and therefore extended the hegemony of capital to new tury, the appropriation of biophysically rich frontiers combined
frontiers faster than the overproduction of machinery could ex-
haust extant reservoirs of resources and labor power. 41 At the
42
The exhaustion of these conditions of profitablity in any one place emerges,
we should say, at the intersection of biophysical depletion and the broader co n-
41
This is much different fro m saying that ―coal transformed the world‖ tradictions of production and power that enter the register of market competi-
(McNeill, 2008; fro m a Marxist optic, Huber 2008). tiveness.
Ecology & the Accumulation of Capital, 22

with cheap labor and sufficiently mobile capital has periodically moment the unusual expansiveness of neoliberalism‘s appropria-
resolved, for a time, the underlying contradiction. tions, captured in a long series of phrases now part of the everyday
These periodic resolutions, underpinning successive waves of parlance of critical scholars: ―accumulation by dispossession‖
world accumulation, have been realised through varying combina- (Harvey, 2003), ―biopiracy‖ and the new ―enclosures‖ (Shiva),
tions of the global ecological fix – 1) the coercive- intensive impo- ―disaster capitalism‖ (Klein, 2007), a new ―scramble for Africa‖
sition of territorial systems and property-relations that either ap- (Watts, 2006), resurgent ―resource wars‖ (Klare, 2001), and many
propriates directly ecological surpluses (in their human and extra- more. By this we understand neoliberalism as a phase of capital-
human dimensions), or indirectly, by compelling producers to ―sell ism premised on taking, first, and making, second. My suggestion
to survive‖ under conditions of competition in the world mark et; is that this is an epochal shift in the history of capitalism that e x-
and 2) the capital- intensive restructuring of agricultural and extrac- presses the (asymptotic) exhaustion of frontiers, and the promise
tive sectors on the basis of the rising organic composition of cap i- of renewed accumulation offered – and delivered – over the past
tal. If one part of this twin-process falters, the whole edifice five centuries.
erodes, calling forth the need for additional stimuli.
Capital‘s great need is for low-cost energy, food, and raw ma-
Figure I, Capitalising Nature: The Temporal Logic terials. The response to this imperative has been endless geograph-
ical expansion and endless innovation. They are not independent, I
wish to argue. They are in fact so closely connected that the tech-
nical fixes of capitalism have always been intertwined with move-
ments of global expansion. This is what I have called the pairing of
plunder and productivity in world accumulation. The pattern that
we can observe can be reduced to a two phase process: 1) skim-
ming the most easily-won surpluses, such as Amazonian rubber
tapping prior to Malaysia‘s plantation revolution in the early 20 th
century (Brockway, 1979; Tucker, 2000); and 2) reorganizing a
widening sphere of world nature on an increasingly capitalist ba-
sis, such as the progressive rationalization of forest-product indus-
tries worldwide since end of the 19th century (Rajala, 1998; Pelu-
so, 1992). But it would be a mistake to see this simply as a logical-
historical succession. The capitalisation of nature that characteriz-
es this second phase issues short-run windfalls, to be sure. It is an
Source: Gowdy & Juliá (2007). eminently modern variant of the ―yield honeymoon‖ that early
modern planters enjoyed when their slaves planted Eurasian cane
This outward movement looms large today. Where will the on New World soils. The concert of favorable biophysical cond i-
next phase of capitalism find comparable reservoirs of uncapita- tions with cutting edge agronomy issues yield bursts that invaria-
lised nature? In the next section, we will chart neoliberalism‘s as- bly turn bust over the course of 50-75 years. (Perhaps more quick-
cent and unfolding crisis from this standpoint. Let us note for the ly in late capitalism.) Thus, the very ecological innovations that
Ecology & the Accumulation of Capital, 23

create yield booms invariably undermine supply conditions over tal intensity), the system has historically extended the sphere of
the middle-run. From the standpoint of the oikeios, the contradic- capitalised nature in recurrent, great bursts of global expansion –
tions are unified, while their expressions diverge, comprising ―so- hence, every great era of capitalist development seems to be ac-
cial‖ transformations in, say, the agro-food regime no less than companied by a ―new‖ imperialism. There is, then, a tension be-
―biophysical‖ feedbacks in weed control. As these contradictions tween that quantum of socio-ecological relations dependent on the
unfold in ways that limit accumulation, the search for new fro n- circulation of capital, and that which remains within the gravita-
tiers reappears with savage power. If frontiers are unavailable, fe- tional pull of accumulation, but whose reproduction is not yet
rocious acts of redistribution are visited upon those populations capital-dependent.
least able to offer effective resistance – from poor to rich, or from There is a clear homology with Marx‘s relation of the active
agriculture to industry (as in Soviet collectivisation). Indeed, the and latent strata of the reserve army of labor. It is, in my reading, a
long environmental history of capitalism may be read as a cease- theory of capital‘s tendency to drive human nature beyond its lim-
less effort to move back to the first (skimming) phase whenever its – to turn ―blood into capital‖ (1976: 382) – that is based on the
possible. system‘s capacity to continually draw in uncapitalised (but ex-
The implication of Marx‘s underproduction crisis theory is ploitable) reservoirs of labor power. ―It would seem,‖ Marx ob-
this. The rising organic composition of capital, as we have seen, served (1976: 377), ―that the interest of capital itself points in the
drives a contradiction between the overproduction of machinery direction of a normal working day.‖ A longer and more intensive
and the underproduction of inputs. But rising capital intensity in working day ―shortens the life of the… worker,‖ which would
the technical division of labor enters into dialectical tension with a seem a costly venture of capital, as ―the forces used up have to be
distinctive, if broadly homologous, process within the social divi- replaced more rapidly, and it will be more expensive to reproduce
sion of labor. This process is the rising capitalised composition of labour-power.‖ But there is a crucial geographical caveat to this
world nature. Capital is compelled to capitalise an ever-growing surficial logic. Enter the frontier. If such labor power can be ―sup-
share of world nature, whose ―free gifts‖ can only be enjoyed to plied from foreign preserves,‖ where the reproduction of labor
the extent that they remain uncommodified. The ―coercive laws of power does not pivot on the accumulation of capital
competition‖ drive capital to remake the rest of nature according to
the temporal logic of ―socially- necessary turnover time,‖ a far cry the duration of [the worker‘s] life becomes a matter of less
from the reproduction time of forests and fields, not to mention moment than its productiveness while it lasts. It is accordingly
mines, oilfields, and aquifers. 43 In order to keep this ecological a maxim of slave management, in slave-importing countries,
face of socially- necessary turnover time from getting out of con- that the most effective economy is that which takes out of the
trol, and radically undermining the conditions of production (e.g. human chattel in the shortest space of time the utmost of exer-
resource exhaustion) or the conditions of profitability (rising capi- tion that it is capable of putting forth. It is in tropical culture,
where annual profits often exceed the whole capital of planta-
43
Marx, 1976: 44; Harvey, 2001: 327. ―Marx was not necessarily wrong to pri- tions, that negro life is most recklessly sacrificed… Mutato
oritize t ime over space. The aim and objective of those engaged in the circula- nomine te fabula narratur [The name is changed but the tale is
tion of capital must be, after all, to command surplus labour time and convert it told of you!]. For slave trade, read labour- market, for Ken-
into profit within the socially-necessary turnover time. Fro m the standpoint of tucky and Virginia [in the slave trade], Ireland and the agricul-
the circulation of cap ital therefo re, space appears in the first instance as a mere
inconvenience, a barrier to be overcome‘ (Harvey, 2001: 327).
Ecology & the Accumulation of Capital, 24

tural districts of England, Scotland, and Wales, for Africa, the case in the long sixteenth century, and at the beginning of the
Germany (Marx, 1976: 377-378). long twentieth century, in the classic instanciation of the ―new im-
perialism.‖
For labor power, read nature. Mutato nomine te fabula narra- The extension of capitalist power into new frontiers works to
tur! propel world accumulation so long as two conditions hold: 1) the
Far from an artifact of the Industrial Revolution, this tendency newly incorporated formations reproduce themselves relatively
was in motion from the earliest moments of capitalism. The envi- independently of capital, but are capable of delivering sizeable
ronmental history of the rise of capitalism turned decisively on the contributions to the relative ecological surplus; and 2) the mass of
centralisation of economic power combined with ―economies of use- values taken up is sufficiently large, relative to value accumu-
speed.‖44 While economic growth was sustained through geo- lation, so as to reduce the capitalised share of the ecological sur-
graphical expansion and therefore the era‘s ecological regime is plus in general. As geographical expansion slows, relative to the
rightly called extensive, the uneven synergies of generally rising rising organic composition of capital, the quantum of socialised
demand translated to agro-extractive strategies of hit-and-run. Hit nature dependent on the cash nexus increases. At some point (and
where the ecological wealth was most accessible (cheapest), ex- as capital drives the acceleration of turnover time ever closer to the
tract it as fast as possible, then move as quickly as possible once speed of light, this point in the horizon approaches ever more
declining ecological returns (and therefore rising capitalisation) quickly), the quantitative advance of commodification reaches a
registered a significant contraction of profitability (Moore, 2007). tipping point within any given socio-ecological formation. At this
The contradiction between the overproduction of machinery point, socialised natures give way to capitalised natures,
and the underproduction of inputs can, therefore, be overcome to representing the moment of capitalist transformation at which ne i-
the extent that the inner contradiction finds an outer vent. (Thus, ther governing structures nor production systems nor the (newly
the dialectic of productivity and plunder.) The rising organic com- transformed) forests, fields, and other ecosystems can reproduce
position of capital, quite independently of the appearance of unde- themselves except through the deepening participation in the cir-
raccumulation crises, instanciates an immanent tendency towards cuits of capital on a world-scale. The circuit of capital becomes
socio-ecological disequilibrium, whose systemic expression is the every bit as much a ―life support system‖ as the circulation of air,
rising capitalised composition of world nature. To the extent that water, and nutrients (pace, inter alia, Costanza and Patten,
the rising capitalist composition of nature is not offset by succes- 1995).45 Thus, the rising capitalised composition of world nature.
sive special stimuli derived from uncapitalised social ecologies The more that social ecologies – fields, forests, fisheries, and
(about which more, presently), there is a clear ecological crisis so forth – become capitalised ecologies, the more their reproduc-
tendency: the tendency of the ecological surplus to fall. This can tion is entrained within the reproduction of capital. (There is, then,
be counteracted, as we‘ve noted, through geographical expansion. an important distinction between anthropogenic residues – for in-
But take note of the relational process. It is not simply that a large stance, lead particulates found in Arctic ice – and socialised condi-
mass of use-values is now easily skimmed, once geographical ex- tions of ecological reproduction that are the hallmark of, for e x-
pansion reaches critical mass. More to the point, the quantum of
45
socialised nature dependent on the cash nexus declines. This was That is to say, the circulations of air, water, and nutrients are not so much a
―life support system‖ for cap italism, as the circuit of capital is the socio-
ecological basis for the actually existing mosaic of ecological flows , including
44
To borrow a nice turn of phrase fro m Chandler (1977). those now characterised as ―rifts.‖
Ecology & the Accumulation of Capital, 25

ample, agriculture.) Rising capitalisation tends to produce short-


and medium-run windfalls, but over time, undermines profitability.
This issues, first, from rising capital intensity itself (independently
of soil exhaustion, deforestation, etc.), and second, from the pro-
gressive exhaustion of the ecological regime as its reservoirs of
uncapitalised land and labor become dependent on the accumula-
tion process. The rising organic composition of capital and the ris- Figure II, Capitalising Nature: The Metabolic Rift
ing capitalised composition of world nature are therefore dialecti- Nutrients Air

cally bound – the one operating in the technical division of labor, Nutrient Recycling
Low
Waste Land
the other, in the social division of labor. In the first instance, co m-
Country Metabolic Rift City
petition compels capital to increase the productivity of labor Water
through the installation of new machinery; to the extent that it is Geographical Expansion
unable to increase the rate of exploitation faster than the rising Nutrients Capitalisation
Nutrient Recycling Air
composition of dead labor (a more daunting challenge), there is a of Nature
strong tendency towards a declining rate of profit. At the same Waste Land

time, competition compels capital to find ways to drive down the


Country Metabolic Rift
City
costs of circulating capital (such as energy and other raw mate- Water

rials); to the extent that sufficiently cheap energy sources and other Geographical Expansion
Nutrients
inputs are secured, this favors a rising rate of profit. But the o nly
Nutrient Recycling Air
way to drive down the costs of circulating capital is to develop
new technologies that mobilize ―resources‖ more efficiently, or to Waste Land
extend to the geographical field such that new low-cost resources
Metabolic Rift
are secure (see Figure II). Country City
Water
High

Limit of
Global Expansion :

Extended 16th century 21st century


Local Global

Both moments, but especially the second, are vitally dependent


on state machineries. (Enter the question of primitive accumula-
tion and imperialism.) In either case, the relative price of inputs
falls, but only temporarily, since the very decline in the value-
composition of the resources in question favors their relative e x-
haustion (skimming the easy surpluses of the first phase), followed
a rising value-composition (phase two). Thus relative ecological
exhaustion sets in, driving the relative prices of inputs upwards.
Ecology & the Accumulation of Capital, 26

Meanwhile, rising capital intensity tends to accelerate relative e x- world value production. (A terminal crisis still awaits.) 46 Even af-
haustion in its own right, and enters also into ―social‖ contradic- ter the moment of signal crisis, the absolute mass of the ecological
tions with variable capital (labor power), as workers (and other surplus may increase even as the relative ecological surplus falls –
subaltern strata) organise against employer- initiatives to ratchet just as a country‘s population may grow as its reserve army of la-
upwards the rate of exploitation (Silver, 2003), or ratchet down- bor declines.
wards the wage-bill (Harvey, 2005). What becomes clear is that, at In what follows, I take as my temporal frame 1973-2008, a pe-
the very moment when capital most needs a less capitalised eco- riod bookended by the two great commodity booms – both cen-
logical regime, we are witnessing rising capitalisation and there- tered in oil and agriculture – of the end of this long, 20th century
fore rising costs (witness the rising costs of oil extraction today (World Bank, 2009: 51-93; Hone 1973). We shall examine these
[IEA, 2008: 37-49]), in the process diminishing the possibilities two great primary sectors from the standpoint of a central ques-
for counteracting the tendency of the rate of profit to fall. The two tion: To what extent has the underproductionist tendency of cap i-
movements, productivity- maximizing and cost-minimizing, are talism begun to reassert itself? Two tantalizing observations can be
therefore dialectically bound. At some point, these two pressures made about these two sectors, oil (the energy regime) and agricul-
(which are really one) reach a tipping point – and at this tipping ture (the agro- food system), in their respective turns:
point, the logic of value accumulation gives rise to logic of primi-
tive accumulation. 1) the oil commodity boom failed to produce new large-
scale investment, as it had in the 1970s (Kolko, 1988:
A Brief Environmental History of Neoliberalism: 163-164). The shortfall is now amplified by the unfold-
ing depression. The International Energy Agency is po-
Fossils, Finance, Factories, & Food
sitively hysterical about declining investment, fearing
that any recovery from the present muck will be scut-
Neoliberalism is now rightly viewed as a specifiable phase of tled by skyrocketing energy prices (IEA, 2008; IEA,
capitalist development (Klein, 2007; Harvey, 2005; Saad-Filho 2009; Mouwad, 2009, 19.5: Werdigier, 2009). The ac-
and Johnston, 2005). And whatever the fine points of the debate, it cumulation of capital and the production of a rising
is increasingly clear that neoliberalism has reached the limits of its ecological surplus appear to be moving in opposite di-
developmental possibilities – even if, as Harvey reminds us, as rections.
―class project‖ it lives on (2009). As ecological project and eco-
logical regime, however, neoliberalism survives as the walking 2) the agro-food system has been the site of massive capi-
dead. Drained of its vital forces, the body survives, its days num- tal investment, but with a dramatic slowdown in yield
bered. growth, and a systemwide decline in the relative food
The interconnected food, energy, and financial crises of 2008 surplus. Investment in the agro- food system – most
marked the signal crisis of the neoliberal ecological regime. By spectacularly, GMOs, whose proliferation moved in
signal crisis, I refer to the moment at which the ecological regime lockstep with the financial expansion between 1995
has reached its tipping point in the production of the relative eco- and 2008 – has squeezed the direct producers but failed
logical surplus, the mass of use-values relative to the demands of
46
For the language of signal and terminal crises, see Arrighi and Moore, 2001.
Ecology & the Accumulation of Capital, 27

to deliver a rising ecological surplus. Once again, ex- rich states, but also from East Asia. This is what GRAIN calls the
change- value and use- value appear to be moving along worldwide ―land grab ‖ – farmland across the Global South, upon
divergent paths. which could be cultivated foodstuffs equal to 15 percent of world
cereal trade (GRAIN, 2008; The Economist, 2009). Highlighting a
Whether or not capitalist agencies can restore the historical shift in the investment calculus, The Economist recently offered
relation of value accumulation, coercive- intensive appropriation, this perceptive bit of reportage:
and the expansion of the ecological surplus remains to be seen.
Neil Smith sees the production of nature as entering a new phase, In the past, foreign farming investment was usually private:
one characterised by ―capitalisation all the way down‖ – to the ge- private investors bought land from private owners… But the
netic relations of all life (2007). And I think this is true as far as it majority of the new deals have been government-to-
goes. But the implication is that such capitalisation pro mises a new government… That makes the current round of land acquisi-
wave of accumulation, and I am not at all certain that this fo llows. tions different in kind, as well as scale. When private investors
Capitalism‘s great problem is not too little capitalisation of ―so- put money into cash crops, they tended to boost world trade
cionature,‖ but too much. While pockets of highly capitalised pri- and international economic activity. At least in theory, they
mary production have always thrived in the modern world-system, encourage farmers to switch from growing subsistence rice to
the decline (not increase) of the ecological surplus has always is- harvesting rubber for cash; from growing rubber to working in
sued from the rising systemwide capitalisation of world nature – a tyre factory; and from making tyres to making cars. But now,
that is, the quantum of the capitalist oikeios whose reproduction governments are investing in staple crops in a protectionist
crucially turns on the circuit of capital. Hence, every great wave of impulse to circumvent world markets (The Economist, 2009).
accumulation has found its point of departure in the radical en-
largement of the geographical arena for commodity production and The sands are still shifting rapidly, and so it would be impru-
exchange – extending the realm of socialised nature appropriated dent to take this notion of a rupture too far. Clearly, the expanded
(but not yet subsumed) by capital. reproduction of capital has been hit hard, but not (yet) broken
It may well be that the absence of really significant frontiers down. But it would be hazardous to deny the punctuated character
today is implicated in a world-historical rupture of the relation be- of late capitalist history. There is good reason to look closely at the
tween ―normal‖ investment and a rising ecological surplus. The fissures appearing in the investment logics responsible for feeding
International Energy Agency counts on state hydrocarbon firms to and fueling the system. Indeed, it is in the very temporal logic of
supply 80 percent of incremental production over the next two capitalism that its technological dynamism may serve to conceal
decades, but notes that such firms may not follow the prevailing (for a time) the ongoing contraction of the relative ecological sur-
investment logic, preferring instead ―slower depletion‖ strategies plus. The secular slowdown of major oilfield discoveries, for in-
―in support of national goals‖ (2008: 44; also IEA, 2009). Mean- stance, may be compensated by new techniques that extract the
while, the neoliberal project of forging a ―world agriculture, pre- same (or an even greater) volume of oil extracted from mature
mised on the elimination of extant agricultures and agro-ecologies zones. While this works for a time, the middle-run consequence is
through the privatization of knowledge,… [and] subordinated to a punctuated rather than gradual decline – in this instance, not only
capital‖ (McMichael, 2005) has precipitated a curious counter- in the volume of oil produced but also in a dramatic upward shift
movement from a cluster of state machineries, not only from oil- in the systemwide organic composition of capital. It is a lo gic that
Ecology & the Accumulation of Capital, 28

holds, with appropriate modifications, across the board of capita l- become quite familiar with this tendency in the recent subprime
ism as world-ecology. And notwithstanding the facile arguments crisis – the securitization of mortgages facilitated a rapid expan-
of ―dematerialization‖ – premised on the spurious correlations of sion of claims on the future income of would-be property owners;
GDP and energy- and metal- intensity47 – the history of neoliberal- insofar as the expansion of the real economy failed to keep pace, a
ism shows us, as Michael Watts and his colleagues opine, ―just default crisis was destined to materialize (Blackburn, 2008). Al-
how vital to this dream of the future remains the control of a few though distinct in its mode of operation, the same logic has worked
strategic commodities. They are the motors of production, the ul- its magic in the production of global nature. The geometric expan-
timate hard currency of exchange… [And] for that very reason sion of, for example, ―asset-backed securities‖ – just $108 billion
they are subject to the deepest and most complete mystification‖ in 1995, but $1.2 trillion in 2006 (Phillips, 2008: 62) – represented
(Retort, 2005: 39). a quantum leap in the world-economy‘s claims on the future eco-
Let us see if we might begin to unravel these mystifications. I logical surplus. Is it coincidence that GMO field trials show the
would begin with the ecological crisis-tendencies that emerged in same trend over the same period (Pechlaner and Otero, 2008;
response to the overaccumulation crises of 1967-74 – one crisis FAO, 2004: 34)? Looking back over the past three decades or so, it
tendency centered in the financial expansion that took shape out of is safe to say that the financial expansion centered in the U.S. was
the Washington-OPEC condominium to recycle petrodollars, the possible only through a radical extension in the gravitational pull
other centered in the rapid industrialization of the Global South. of finance capital on world ecological process. And yet, in contrast
From the early 1970s, the flowering of a new systemwide fi- to previous movements of financialisation – I am thinking espe-
nancial expansion and the rapid industrialization of the Global cially of the Edwardian belle époque (1896-1914) – we are not
South entrained a radical enlargement of claims on the rest of na- witnessing an expansion of the real economy‘s capacity to deliver
ture (Arrighi, 1994: 299-324; Arrighi, Silver, and Brewer, 2003; a rising ecological surplus.
Amsden, 1990). It was a double movement. In the first instance, The breakneck industrialization of the Global South since the
consider that all financial instruments represent a deferred, and 1960s has issued its own distinctive bundle of radically enlarged
expanded, claim on ecological process, whether labor power, the claims on the rest of nature. This leads to our second crisis-
built environment, or the manifold forms of primary production. tendency, the industrialization of the Global South. By 1980 the
Insofar as this holds true, there is a general tendency for the e x- South had closed the industrialization gap with the North. ―Be-
pansion of finance capital to outrun the expansion of the relative tween 1960 and 1980 the proportion of GDP in manufacturing for
ecological surplus. 48 (This is especially true of fictitious capital, as the First World as a whole decreased from 28.9 percent to 24.5
the subprime crisis suggests.) To paraphrase Marx, it is in the na- percent, while the same proportion for the Third World as a whole
ture of capitalism that it accumulates money-capital more rapidly increased from 21.6 percent to 24.3 percent‖ (Arrighi, Silver, and
than it develops primary production (1971a, II: 300-301). We have Brewer, 2003: 11). By century‘s end, the South was more indu-
strialized. It goes without saying that this has been an extraordina-
47
World Ban k, 2009: 65; for a critique of dematerialization, see Bunker, 19 89. rily uneven process, one vitally dependent on ―internal‖ frontiers.
For an empirical accounting, see IEA, 2000: 73-74. The ―rise‖ of the so-called BRIC countries – Brazil, Russia, India,
48
Thus, at the heart of the world-system, the relative weight of finance within and (above all) China – has been located in precisely those states
the U.S. economy expanded by nearly fifty percent (14 to 20.4 percent) b etween with labor- and resource- frontiers sufficient to check the rising
1970 and 2005, while manufacturing‘s share of GDP contracted by nearly half
(23.8 to 12 percent) (Ph illips, 2008: 31).
Ecology & the Accumulation of Capital, 29

capitalisation of global nature. 49 If the industrialisation gap global industrialization‘s acceleration and expansion of demands
closed, the income gap persisted. The rising capitalisation of pro- on the present ecological surplus.
duction of a world-scale could proceed in an era dominated by ef- The most obvious villain in the price rise of 2003-08 was the
fective closure of the Great Frontier only through a sustained effort speculator (Altvater, 2007; Roberts, 2008; Chaudhuri, 2008; Auth-
to increase the exploitation of labor, and to drive down input costs, ers, 2008; Soros, 2008). But this may confuse a particular tree with
above all through the coercive-intensive strategies of the ―shock the entire forest. To be sure, the movement of institutional inves-
doctrine‖ and capital‘s newfound capacities for geographical mo- tors into world commodity markets is expected during such a pe-
bility realised through the marriage of financialisation and the in- riod, but it seems to have been a secondary factor (IMF, 2008;
formation technologies. Mouwad, 2008 [June 25]). Indeed, the strongest argument for the
These crisis-tendencies, emerging through the financial expan- vitality of the neoliberal ecological regime would be one that em-
sion and the latest phase of world industrialisation, underpinned phasized the role of speculation, relative to the erosion of the re-
the signal crisis of the neoliberal ecological regime in 2008. Its gime‘s capacity to deliver a rising ecological surplus. But it was
surficial expression was a sharp rise in prices for food, energy, and precisely the erosion of this capacity that underpinned the 2008
metals (IMF, 2006, 2008; World Bank, 2009). These price move- crisis. (Keeping in mind that crisis is an irreducibly plural reality.)
ments cannot be regarded as the straightforward expression of The crisis was, in a broad sense, at once revealed through, and de-
peak oil, or other resource scarcities, narrowly conceived. The tonated by, the oil- food price spikes. 50
World Bank therefore rightly points out that commodity booms Rising oil prices precipitated a massive turn towards ethanol
favor speculation (as it were) about impending resource scarcity production, a shift that constituted a large share (perhaps as much
(2009: 89). In this sense, peak oil arguments (e.g. Heinberg, 2003) as 75 percent, according to an internal World Bank memo) of the
– and various incarnations of ―limits to growth‖ thinking from the doubling of world food prices between January 2006 and the
1970s on (e.g. Meadows, et al., 1972) – are rightly viewed as neo- summer of 2008 (Chakrabortty, 2008; Morelli, 2008; Angus,
Malthusian (Retort, 2005). We cannot read off a signal crisis in the 2008). It was a spectacular reversal. To the extent that neoliberal-
ecological regime from price movements alone. At the same time, ism as a class project revived accumulation after the 1970s, it did
the crisis itself cannot be explained without reference to the double so by driving down food commodity prices, after 1980, to the low-
movement we‘ve identified: 1) the financial expansion as a geo- est levels of the 20th century (FAO, 2009; see Figure IV). By
metric expansion of claims on future ecological surplus; 2) and 2008, food prices were the highest in real terms since 1845, or so
The Economist reported (Buntrock, 2007).
If speculation was but one tree, we might ask, where is the for-
est? From the standpoint of the financial expansion, a crucial fac-
49
The BRIC group produced 30 percent of world energy, and contained 43 per- tor behind the oil price rise must have been the gravitational pull
cent of world population, in 2005 (Armijo, 2007: 20). A large population by
of the financial expansion itself, above and beyond the futures
itself, no mo re than a large mass of coal in the ground, does not represent a
commodity frontier, in these terms. Rather, we can speak of commodity fron- markets. By 2008, the global oil sector had experienced more than
tiers, to the extent that there exist minimally-capitalised human and extra-
50
human natures in given geographical zone that can be mob ilized by capital and Although let us not forget that metals were also centrally implicated in the
the capitalist state for a new phase of commodity-centered development. The overall price rise mo ment (World Bank, 2009: 69-71). It was the first time in
human and extra-hu man natures must be explo itable, but not yet exploited. This the twentieth century that metals, oil, and agriculture together were at the center
is by no means a given in the history of capitalism (Moore, 2007). of a co mmodity boom (1915-17; 1950-57; 1973-74; 2003-08) (ibid : 55).
Ecology & the Accumulation of Capital, 30

two decades of ―investment famine‖ (The Times, 2008). The top


five supermajors (BP, Chevron, ConocoPhillips Company, Ex-
xonMobil, and Royal Dutch Shell) spent just one percent of total
expenditures on stock buybacks in 1993, and nearly 14 percent on
exploration. By 2006, they were spending 37 percent on equity
repurchases, and just 5.8 percent on exploration (Jaffe and Soligo,
2007: 21). Between 2004 and 2005, stock buybacks by the six
largest firms jumped 60 percent (Mouwad, 2005). Far from limited
to the private sector, the same logic underpinned a 75 percent de-
cline in OPEC‘s spare capacity in the quarter-century after 1979 Figure III
(Jaffe, 2004). The Oil Frontier: Stable Prices, Neoliberal Expansion
The ongoing crisis of the neoliberal ecological regime and its
energy regime in particular cannot be explained through invest-
ment alone. While the financial expansion tended to favor a reo-
rientation of capital from the real economy to finance, this
represents only a partial explanation, one crisis tendency in the
terms we have outlined. The second crisis-tendency stemmed from
production, at two levels: 1) the demands of global industrializa-
tion set in motion since the 1970s; and 2) the opening, and then
progressive exhaustion, of the oil frontier, opened in three succes-
sive phases, first in the United States before the Second World
War, in the Middle East after the War, and then in the North Sea,
Mexico, West Africa, and Alaska in the 1970s (Tanzer and Zorn,
1985). Indeed, the success of this latter moment can hardly be un-
deremphasized, as world oil consumption rose 35 percent, from
about 58 million to 79 million barrels a day between 1983 and
2003 without spiking oil prices (BP, 2009; Brown, et al., 2008 ; see
Figure III).

Source: Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas (Brown, et al., 2008)

Global industrialization, the dialectic that Marx identified, be-


tween the overproduction of machinery and underproduction of
inputs, exerted rising pressure on the world energy regime after the
Ecology & the Accumulation of Capital, 31

end of the last millennium. Simply put, oil exporters were (and are transition from underproduction to overproduction crises in the
still) consuming more energy. Sooner or later, this would impact first half of the 19th century. The ensuing steam-transport revolu-
prices. The ―rise of China‖ is of course the most spectacular e x- tions – railroadization above all – opened vast new frontiers
ample, moving from an oil exporter, to a prodigious importer in through which one could skim vast ecological surpluses from mi-
the 1990s, its consumption surging 85 percent in the ten years after nimally capitalised production, driving down the capitalised co m-
1998 (Li, 2005; Mouwad, 2008 [October 28, 2008]). Secondly, position of global nature.
industrialization has been wrapped up with a spectrum of resis- The exhaustion of these skimming opportunities on a world-
tance to U.S. hegemony, perhaps most spectacularly evinced by scale may help us understand why oil prices have fallen dramati-
Chavez‘s geopolitical and alter-developmental initiatives in Latin cally but not collapsed. Falling from a positively stratospheric
America. ―Peak oil‖ is therefore as much a question of the geo- $147/barrel in July 2008, oil has been hovering around $50-60 for
graphical distribution of oil as it is one of geological exhaustion. much of the spring and summer. So oil is cheaper, but not cheap,
Nor should we underestimate the political ecology of this ex- and this constitutes a barrier to the recovery of expanded accumu-
haustion. The world is not running out of oil. This much is true. lation. Real prices for oil for the period 1983-2003 were about fifty
But the modern world-system is. Oil is, in some sense, beside the percent higher than during the postwar expansion – around
point. Capitalism‘s great strength, at same time its greatest weak- $30/barrel compared to $15/barrel between the 1940s and 1973
ness, has been its capacity to reproduce itself through a ―complex, (BP, 2009: 16). At this writing (July 2009), oil has been hovering
self-contained world of money equivalents‖ (Retort, 2005: 38). It around $60/barrel, which is not a good sign for a system dependent
is an illusion of course, one whose continuing vitality owes every- on cheap energy, as the IEA has been reminding us for several
thing to cheap energy, and this depends on checking the tendency years now (IEA, 2009; Birol, 2004).
towards the rising capitalisation of global nature. When advocates The present conjuncture, then, is something of a mirage. The
of peak oil illuminate the declining energy return on energy in- ongoing depression will produce the first back-to-back annual de-
vested (EROEI) since the 1970s, therefore, they get it partly right clines in world oil consumption since the early 1980s (Mouwad,
and partly wrong at the same time. From the standpoint of capital, 2009, 27.3). At the same time, world demand – whose increase
a low energy return on energy invested is not necessarily a prob- will originate almost entirely (87 percent) from outside the OECD
lem. Capital is, after all, premised on the externalization of energy (IEA, 2008: 38) – will at some point resume its upward curve, pre-
efficiencies as a metric of value. So long as the energy surplus suming that still deeper crises do not occur over the next few
yielded by capital investment is sufficient to maintain cheap ener- years. (Chinese demand for oil and other commodities has already
gy for generalized value production (thereby checking the rising revived, at least for the moment [Roubini, 2009, 14.5; Johnson,
organic composition of capital), a high or low EROEI remains an 2009]).The upshot is that falling investment (21 percent this year,
abstraction, albeit a powerful one. Early capitalism, after all, according to the IEA) 51 promises another price shock that may
thrived on a very low EROEI. What capitalism can never tolerate, reinforce the ongoing breakdown of historical capitalism‘s ―nor-
however, is a low energy return on capital invested – EROCI not mal‖ investment patterns in fuel and food.
EROEI. The contradiction may be specified in these terms. On the one
But, as we know, capitalism not only develops; it ages. Let us hand, the inner logic of value accumulation – embedding less labor
recall that the hegemony of a ―self-contained world of money
equivalents‖ was achieved on the historical foundations of the 51
Vandore, 2009, AP, 22.5.09.
Ecology & the Accumulation of Capital, 32

and more extra- human energy in each commodity – points towards vernance; and 3) vigorous moves by the same powers to enclose
a strong resumption of oil demand. (That is, once we have passed spaces previously external to (or relatively untouched by) the
through the roughest waters of the ongoing depression.) On the world-economy‘s division of labor, what I have called the strategy
other hand, to the extent that a capitalist logic organizes world oil of the ―commodity frontier.‖ The second moment represents a cri-
production, the very dynamism that enabled the long era of cheap sis- intensification strategy; the first and third have together charac-
oil (c. 1870-2003) is now creating the conditions of relative ex- terized the ecological spatial fix to recurrent energy and resource
haustion. Under favorable market conditions, new technologies crises in the modern world – great waves of technological innova-
can be (have been) deployed to allow for a maintenance, even a tion in the modern world have always been dialectically joined to
modest expansion, of output. The result? An acceleration of deple- great waves of geographical expansion. What is striking is that the
tion (IEA, 2008: 43; Heinberg, 2003; Mouwad, 2008 [November third movement – the extension of the geographical arena of re-
19]). This reveals a secular trend of rising production costs. Oper- source extraction – has been folded into (and obscured by) discus-
ating costs in the world oil sector have ―more than doubled‖ over sions of ―energy imperialism‖ (Foster, 2008; Klare, 2001, 2003).
the past decade, exploration costs have quadrupled, and we have But this is unduly partial: too much Lenin (geopolitical conflicts),
seen a whopping ten- fold increase in the marginal cost of produc- not enough Luxemburg (the incorporation of new frontiers). We
ing a barrel of oil between 1991 and 2007 (World Bank, 2009: 60; have been focusing on established production zones in the Middle
Simpkins, 2009; IMF, 2008: 95). These marginal costs – that is, East and Africa, at the expense of an engagement with the double
the cost of producing on the worst fields (in the U.S., as luck movement of states and capitals (often as not fused, as in the case
would have it) – are strongly linked to world price beyond the very StatoilHydro and Gazprom) into the vast oil and gas fro ntiers of
short-run (Bina, 1990). Nor is this the least of it. While investment the extended Arctic (Shoumatoff, 2008).
started to tick upwards in 2006 and 2007 – and some firms, such as If the energy regime looks to be faltering in its capacity to gen-
Norway‘s Statoil and French Total are banking on an earlier, ra- erate not only low-cost energy, but a significant expansion of
ther than later, onset of ―peak oil‖ – the prolonged period of low cheap energy, what then of the agricultural regime? In the wake of
investment entails a dramatically longer ―delivery time‖ for new skyrocketing food prices and worldwide food riots in 2008 – fol-
equipment, and not least of all, the training of new engineers lowed in 2009 by rising world hunger (now at least one billion
(Mouwad, 2005; World Bank, 2009: 60-61; Hoyos [Feb. 15), people) in the midst of modestly falling food commodity prices
2009). In other words, a significant temporal lag in the political (still markedly higher than in 2004) – the question of agriculture
ecology of oil investment is manifesting at the very moment when occupies a central place in our thinking about the present crisis,
an acceleration is most needed, to drive down oil prices and renew and the future of capitalism. The world agriculture constituted by
systemic conditions of profitability. neoliberalism, helped in no small measure by the broadly ―Fordist‖
If we are indeed in the midst of a major energy transition, what sensibilities of the Green Revolution era that preceded and over-
we should expect to see (and I believe, what we are seeing), are lapped with it, was tremendously successful. World food prices
three major responses by the world‘s leading territorialist and capi- dropped 39 percent between 1975 and 1989, and still further in the
talist agencies: 1) technological innovations to offset rising costs decade that followed (McMichael, 2005: 278; FAO, 2009).
from exhaustion; 2) an intensification of conflict between the lead-
ing world powers for access to the contracting energy surplus
within the established modes of socio-technical extraction and go-
Ecology & the Accumulation of Capital, 33

is the analogous process for today‘s workshop of the world? From


where, we might ask, will China‘s hundred million-plus industrial
workers be fed?
I am not at all sure that the old answers to this question apply.
The sixteenth-century Dutch grew rich thanks to cheap grain from
Poland‘s Vistula; the nineteenth-century English had Ireland, the
Caribbean, and the American Midwest. When the United States
came to world power, they still had the Midwest, plus the Ameri-
Figure IV can South now fully integrated after 1945, and California, and Lat-
Cheap Food & the Neoliberal Ecological Regime in America. The neoliberal agro-export regime has fed off the
light-speed appropriation of peasant holdings from Mexico to Chi-
na. Decisive food surpluses were won in all cases from untapped
frontier zones, coupled (increasingly), with the productivity-
maximizing genius of capitalism. And while biotechnology and
biopiracy through the ―new‖ enclosures have succeeded in greas-
ing the wheels of world accumulation over the past two decades,
they have done little to achieve what all previous agricultural revo-
lutions had done: expand the surplus and drive down food prices.
Yes, we can look at GMO soybeans in places such as Brazil and
see that yields are higher, 52 but the return of Brazil to the center of
world agriculture — echoes of the seventeenth-century sugar
Source: FAO, 2009. boom — now promises only to postpone the contraction, rather
than drive the expansion, of the relative food surplus. The Green
These days are now over. Not only ―cheap oil,‖ but also Revolution accomplished this in the 1960s and 1970s, but it too
―cheap food,‖ may be consigned to the dustbin of history. For its was not simply a technological marvel. The Green Revolution de-
part, the OECD forecasts real price increases of 10-35 percent over pended on the same frontier processes that have underwritten ac-
the next decade for a basket of key food commodities – a forecast cumulation from the sixteenth century—enclosure and the exploi-
premised on the dubious expectation that yield growth will follow tation of nature as free gift. Taking the best lands and slurping wa-
the ―historical trend‖ (OECD, 2008; OECD/FAO, 2008: 47). This ter at unprecedented speed, the Green Revolution was a self-
is bad news for a world-economy in the grips of the most serious propelling and self- limiting enterprise, one that was progressively
depression since the late 19th century (this, not the 1930s, is I think exhausted after the 1980s.
the relevant comparison). In the ―great depression‖ of the late 19th The transition from British to American hegemony was of
century, cereal prices declined by nearly 27 percent between 1870 course a bumpy one, but, almost unbelievably, now seems consi-
and 1914 (O‘Rourke, 1997: 789), underwriting the rapid shift in derably more tranquil than what lies ahead. Reading through the
the global center of gravity from Britain as the workshop of the
world, to the United States as the world‘s assembly line. But what 52
Tony Smith, New York Times, 14 October, 2003.
Ecology & the Accumulation of Capital, 34

pages of the UN‘s recent report on the ―environmental food cri- bourgeois state, propelled a process of dispossession and differen-
sis,‖ the OECD‘s forecast looks impossibly optimistic. Among the tiation whose historical justification was found in rising labor
highlights, we find (Nellemann, et al. 2009): 1) a climate change- productivity in agriculture. Vast reservoirs of labor power took
driven reduction in cropland by 8-20 percent by mid-century; 2) shape to feed the satanic mills, and vast agricultural surpluses were
mounting pressures on aquifers and above all glaciers, signaling mobilized to feed these workers. From the Dutch and English agri-
looming water scarcity for commodity production; 3) the prolifera- cultural revolutions of the early modern era, to the Green Revolu-
tion of invasive species, and rising biological resistance to pesti- tions of the 20th century, the bloody expropriations of capital have
cides and herbicides; 4) the rising cost of fertilisers (driven by ris- justified themselves on the basis of this signal achievement.
ing energy prices), and also the declining effectiveness of fertilis- It is fair to say that this achievement – the cyclical revamping
ers to increase yield; 5) declining yields from fisheries, already on of a rising relative food surplus – is usually considered, even from
the brink of collapse from overexploitation and toxification; 6) es- the left, as a marvel of technological ingenuity. (Although critics
calating competition for arable land from agrofuels (already one- would surely emphasize, as I have done, the violence of the
third of the US maize crop in 2008); and perhaps most ominously, process.) It is on this basis that we encounter all manner of propo-
7) ―an absolute decline in the productive land area (Net Primary sitions concerning some future agricultural revolution – inaugurat-
Productivity) across 12 percent‖ of the planet, the areas most a f- ing a ―biotech century‖ in Business Week‘s breathless pronounce-
fected, home to nearly one- fifth of world population. All of which ment a decade ago (Business Week, 1997; also Rifkin, 1998). But
may be amplified still further by climate change and the profusion this may well be an instance of putting the proverbial cart before
of ―risk of abrupt and major irreversible changes‖ (ibid: quotations the horse. Agricultural revolutions in the modern world have been,
on 40, 43). in the first instance, control revolutions. However much technolo-
In itself, such an empirical survey hardly constitutes a brief for gical innovations may flow from, and precipitate, a variety of
the impossibility of a ―gene revolution‖ that will revive the food emancipatory and oppressive possibilities, the main thrust of tech-
surplus relative to the demands of world accumulation. The key nological development in the modern world-system has been di-
question, it seems to me, pivots on the adequacy of external fro n- rected at realising the successive deepening and widening of cap i-
tiers, sufficiently vast and sufficiently uncapitalised, upon which talist control over the production process.
capitalist agricultural revolutions have always turned. The failure That this extension of the control frontier has unfolded dis-
of biotechnological applications, and all manner of ―new enclo- tinctly in industry relative to agriculture need not distract us from a
sures‖ (Shand, 2003), to expand the ecological surplus suggests shared dynamic (MacLennan and Walker, 1980; Stone, 2007;
that we have reached an epochal moment of crisis in the history of Glenna, 2003). It is certainly true that control projects and control
capitalism. struggles have taken specific forms in the transitions to (and elabo-
But let us not get too far ahead of ourselves. For the greater rations of) the assembly line production systems of the 20 th cen-
part of six centuries, the relation between capitalism and agricul- tury, the cotton plantations of the antebellum American South, the
ture has been a remarkable one. In contrast to all previous histori- capitalist farming of 17th century England, the mining and metal-
cal systems, capitalism slipped the binds of its civilisational fore- lurgy of 16th century Potosí and Saxony. For all their variation,
bears and organized, through successive agricultural revolutions, a however, the socio-technical trend reveals the underlying drive:
series of extraordinary expansions of the agro-food surplus. The the widening and deepening of capitalist control over production,
imposition of private property in land, backed by the power of the in the interests of maximizing surplus value by any means neces-
Ecology & the Accumulation of Capital, 35

sary. 53 While there is a certain bias within Marxism that gives the great integrated field- mill plantations of 17th century Barbados
pride of place to the production of relative surplus value (and rea- (Moore, 2007: chapter six).
sonably so), we would do well to recognize that rising capitalisa- If ―industrial agriculture‖ misleads, however, there may be a
tion (implicating relative surplus value) and control revolutions powerful sense in which the metaphor of global farm qua global
(implicating absolute surplus value) are dialectically bound – that factory makes sense. If ―factory‖ is understood fundamentally as
the restructuring and development of production systems in the an architecture of control rather than the site of a seamless produc-
history of capitalism has often pivoted on new architectures of tion line (or even segmented commodity chain), then it is reasona-
control (literally no less than metaphorically) oriented towards the ble to identify a longue durée alternation of ―Taylorization‖ run-
maximization of absolute surplus value. It is a salient fact – and I ning through the history of agriculture and industry alike. After all,
think one often overlooked – that the ―scientific management‖ before there were factories in the towns, there were factories in the
revolution of early 20th century American capitalism (premised on field! It may well be today that technical innovations, in a fantasti-
the ―separation of conception from execution‖ and the ―rationalisa- cally abstract sense, could deliver rising yields. But to leave it at
tion‖ of the labor process‖54 ) was a systemwide phenomenon, with that brackets far too much. Further innovation in agriculture is cer-
varied expressions in the reworking of primary nature – in forestry tainly possible, but further Improvement (in all its specifiably
(Rajala, 1998; Fernow, 1911), on the North American family farm bourgeois magnificence), bringing together a rising food surplus
(Fitzgerald, 2003); through the rise of agricultural colleges and with the extension of the control frontier in the service of value
new forms of botanical imperialism (Kloppenburg, 1988; Brock- accumulation, seems unlikely. I shall try to elaborate.
way, 1979), in mineral extraction (Hovis and Mouat, 1996). Baldly put, what I wish to suggest is that the proposed homo l-
From this standpoint, the phraseology of ―industrial agricul- ogy of ―global farm‖ and ―global factory‖ signifies a much more
ture,‖ signifying rising capital intensity in agriculture, falls some- fundamental rupture in the history of capitalism than hitherto sup-
what wide of the mark. 55 It is a metaphor that tends to direct our posed.56 Here I think a clue is provided by Bernstein‘s potent ar-
attention to the machine, rather than to the relations that give rise gument that the ―old‖ agrarian questions of capital (the transition
to the machine. And it is a metaphor that tells us the origins of the to capitalism) have, since the 1970s, given way to the ―new‖ agra-
systemic problems mestasizing through the body of world agricul- rian questions of labor (the struggle of capital and labour over the
ture today are found in the mechanized agriculture of the 20th cen- contested forms of a ―generalised living wage‖) (2001, 2002; Ar-
tury rather than the rise of capitalised agriculture in the 16th cen-
tury (Moore, 2003a). If one wishes to find the origins of capital- 56
The reassuringly stable categories of farmer and peasant are in fact progres-
intensive agriculture, one need look no further than the great sugar sively destabilized by progressive advance of capitalisation in its double mov e-
revolutions of the early modern era, systematically combined in ment – the rising organic co mposition of capital and the advance of the control
frontier. Thus Bernstein is assuredly correct in observing that the late 20th cen-
tury has been characterized by capital‘s drive to ―simplify and standardize the
53
―In the same relations in which there is a development of the forces of pro- conditions of agricultural production… [and] to appro ximate the ideal of control
duction, there is also the development of a repressive force‖ (Marx, 1976: in industrial production‖ (2001: 28). And I would add that this ideal of control
799n). emerged in agriculture long before the scientific management revolutions of the
54
Braverman, 1974; Taylo r, 1911. 20th century – the sugar plantation complexes of early capitalism were paradigm
55
Although retaining the shorthand of industrial agriculture, Fried mann‘s fo r- mo ments in the rationalization of land and labor in the interests of maximal
mu lation is well put: ―a deepening of co mmodity relations through industrial commodity production, prefiguring the transitions to large-scale industry in the
technologies and capitalist firms‖ (2005b). 19th century (Mintz, 1985; To mich, 1990).
Ecology & the Accumulation of Capital, 36

righi and Moore, 2001: 75). If plausible (and I think it is), flight from the rising costs of production, but that, historically
Bernstein‘s observation illuminates a second transition. Namely, speaking, the relative closure of frontiers tends to shift the balance
that the very logic of accumulation that gave rise to the global fac- of class forces in favor of the laboring classes by limiting the ca-
tory during the 1970s also precipitated the rise of the global farm. pacity to capital to ―jump scale‖; the ―runaway‖ shop can run, so
(This, McMichael‘s ―world agriculture.‖) In laying emphasis on long as there are frontiers to run to; frontiers are not merely places
this homology of farm and factory, I am not immediately con- ―out there‖ (and out of time) but constituted by the varying logics
cerned with the many- layered restructuring of production chains, of systemic reproduction in its successive developmental phases.
agribusiness, and world-systemic divisions of labour since the Second, rising capitalisation of agriculture at the point of pro-
1970s, whose dynamics have been captured in the work on the duction – now, increasingly reinforced by the rapid centralisation
―world steer,‖ New Agricultural Countries, food regimes, and so of capital in downstream and upstream sectors (Heffernan, 2000;
forth. 57 My immediate concern is, rather, the rise of global farm Nellemannn, et al., 2009: 87-88) – has been realised through suc-
qua global factory as a bundle of relations through which techno l- cessive control revolutions. If the dialectic of productivity and
ogical revolutions (the rising capitalisation of production) are e f- plunder constitutes a law of motion for the political ecology of the
fected and realised through control revolutions in the immediate systemic division of labour, this latter dialectic, of capitalisation
process of production. Simply put, the agro-technical revolutions and control, constitutes a law of motion for the political ecology of
of the modern era have unfolded as control revolutions – above all, technical division of labour. From this standpoint, the two move-
control of the conditions of production and the process of produc- ments of global farm and global factory have been homolo gous
tion. and overlapping, though not identical. There are clearly distinctive
Two observations on this point seem especially relevant. First, geographies, class relations, and productive units between these
the transition from the ―old‖ to the ―new‖ agrarian question during two broad constructs, not to mention the decisive temporal differ-
the 1970s signified, on a world-scale, the end of capitalism‘s agro- ence between industry and agriculture – the age-old disjuncture
ecological frontier, set in motion during the 15th and 16th century. I between labor time and production time (Mann, 1990; Marx, 1967,
do not mean to suggest that there are no forests left to enclose and II). What I wish to highlight is that the ―class project‖ of neolibe-
exploit, or that there are no tracts of ―underutilised‖ land for the ralism, premised as we know on the redistribution of wealth from
taking. There are. My point is that today’s frontiers are but a drop poor to rich, the rollback of democracy, and the coercive- intensive
in the bucket relative to the demands of value accumulation. There extension of commodity production and exchange under the he-
may indeed be a ―new scramble for Africa‖ today, for instance gemony of the ―Washington Consensus,‖ crucially represented a
(Watts, 2006), but this is a struggle for the resources of one of the control revolution – that is to say, an epochal widening and dee-
world-system‘s most transformed regions. Frontiers are frontiers pening of capitalism‘s control capacities, within state and society
because the wealth is there for the taking, where the opportunities for sure, but above all at the point of production. This control revo-
for effective resistance to the rule of capital are limited. This clo- lution has been most conspicuous in manufacturing, with new bu-
sure of the Great Frontier marks an epochal transition in the histo- reaucratic, technical, and surveillance apparatuses instanciating the
ry of capitalism. It is not only that the closure of resource, labor, separation of conception from execution – from the ―team con-
and waste frontiers has cut off a key avenue of escape in capital‘s cept‖ to computerised work flow monitoring to new efforts to dis-
guise the time-honored techniques of speed- up and stretch-out. But
57
See above all, Fried mann‘s decisive contributions (1993, 2005a, b).
Ecology & the Accumulation of Capital, 37

have we not witnessed a homologous control revolution within Thus Shiva, I think, gets it only partially right when she speak of
world agriculture over the past 40 years? biopiracy and invokes the ―old‖ enclosures as historical precedent
My proposition is this. The rising capitalisation of agriculture (1997). Now, there is no question that this tendency within world
at the point of production, and the rising capitalisation of world agriculture has been in motion from the origins of capitalism – the
nature as a whole (extending far beyond agriculture), will prove an ―primitive accumulation of botanical knowledge‖ was materialized
increasingly insuperable barrier to the medium-run revival of ex- by the botanical gardens of the European empires from the earliest
panded accumulation. No revolution in the production of the rela- moment of global expansion, reaching its highest stage of deve l-
tive ecological surplus is on the horizon. opment with the Kew Gardens under British hegemony (Brock-
This barrier emerges from the confluence of economic, social, way, 1979; Canizares-Esguerra, 2004). The transition from large-
and ecological contradictions flowing from the logic of endless scale industry to ―giant‖ industry that occurred with the ascent of
capitalisation. The rising capitalisation of world agriculture – American capitalism in the late 19th century implied, indeed neces-
through which the farm becomes the agro-ecological pivot of sitated, a world-historical shift from the primitive accumulation of
―downstream‖ and ―upstream‖ commodification – not only ampli- botanical knowledge to the expanded reproduction of botanical
fies the tendency towards a declining rate of profit, but in equal knowledge, pioneered by the land-grant agricultural colleges of the
measure amplifies the pressures to escape it, through efforts to ex- United States, and thence globalised through the network of
tend the control frontier. 58 This is what drives Lewontin to speak IARCs (International Area Research Centers) (Berlan and Lewo n-
of the ―farmer as proletarian‖ (1998). What the so-called biotech tin, 1986a, 1986b; Perelman, 1977; Kloppenburg, 1988). In this
―revolution‖ – although I would say it smacks far more of Thermi- light, the Green Revolution, with its recipes for growing (this
dorian reaction than revolutionary event – signifies is a mighty ef- much seed, this much fertilizer, this much water, and so forth),
fort on the part of agribusiness to realise the separation of concep- may be re-read as the agro-ecological moment of the control revo-
tion from execution in the global farm, centralising agricultural lution that enabled the rise of giant industry, and the wholesale
knowledge (in its emphatically bourgeois form) in the hands of displacement of skilled with semi-skilled labor, characteristic of
capital and displacing the older ―craft‖ knowledge of local cond i- the America mass production regime.
tions and best practices of farmers and peasants qua proletarian. Each such control revolution was premised on, but not deter-
mined by, successive leaps forward in the organic composition of
58 capital, can be viewed as a two-phase process. In the first phase,
Recall that there are three main ways to counter-act the tendency towards a
declining rate of profit on a systemwide basis: 1) cheapen the inputs of variable the marriage of capitalisation and control disorganizes the old rela-
capital (labor) and circulating capital (raw materials) by extending the frontier tions of production, and undermine the capacities of the direct
(driv ing down the capitalised composition of world nature); 2) develop new producers to offer effective resistance to the new order. The two
sectors of commodity production with a low organic composition of capital; and movements are centrally connected in the accumulation of capital.
3) intensify the rate of surplus value (explo itation). While all three mov ements
In this first phase, not only does rising capitalisation effect the ris-
are always in play, to the extent that external frontiers can be mob ilized into the
circuit of capital, the first and second strategies will be primary. Thus the rising ing productivity of labor power (more surplus value is created),
power of metropolitan working classes (and petty capitalist farmers) could be but the control revolution enables a rising rate of exploitation
accomodated within a series of more-or-less remunerative ―social compacts‖ for (relatively more value flows into the pockets of Mr. Moneybags).
the long century between 1848 and 1968 – that is to say, from the beginning to There is, then, a sort of ―boom‖ or ―golden age‖ that is characteris-
the end of the ―great frontier‖ opened by industrial capital with the advent of
tic of this first phase. This was true of the sugar-slavery revolu-
railroadization and its successors in the ―annhilation of space by time.‖
Ecology & the Accumulation of Capital, 38

tions of early capitalism. And it was certainly the case with US duction and exchange looms large indeed. The English agricultural
farming in the half-century after the introduction of hybrid corn in revolution of the long 17th century– our classic frame of reference
the 1930s, and with Indian cereal cultivation between the late – was not ―simply‖ the expression of convertible husbandry, new
1960s and mid-1980s. In the second phase, rising productivity drainage systems, and so forth. It was this, to be sure. But the so-
tends to slacken (at the point of production), and the capacity of cio-technical innovation could only proceed on the basis of a
the direct producers to offer effective resistance increases (at the double movement of geographical expansion: 1) an ―inner‖ co n-
level of the social formation), as the latter develop new organiza- version of nitrogen-rich pasture into arable land (therefore opening
tional responses to the control regime. The crisis of early capital- a vast nitrogen frontier) within England (Overton, 1996); and 2) an
ism‘s ecological regime, for instance, was punctuated by a re- ―outer‖ conversion of the English Caribbean into plantation mono-
markably synchronized cluster of agrarian revolts and social revo- cultures, in sugar above all (Dunn, 1972). English, then British,
lutions across the Atlantic world in the half-century after 1776. capitalism thrived on the basis of this double movement. The in-
When the industrial capitalist regime that emerged to take its place dustrial revolution took shape on its basis, the first movement is-
began to stagger, a century later, chief amongst its contradictions suing labor surpluses, the second, capital surpluses (Brenner,
were the agrarian movements set in motion by turbulence of a 1976; Blackburn, 1997).
world market premised on the circuit of industrial capital (Kim- By the second half of the 18th century, however, this ―first‖
mel, 1988; Wolf, 1969). agricultural revolution was showing clear signs of exhaustion.
The contradictions emerging through this dialectic of capitali- Within England, per acre yields were stagnating after mid-century,
sation and control have been resolved through a succession of spe- a stagnation that was by no means confined to England (Clark,
cial (and specifiable) stimuli. The point is crucial. Just as specific 1991; Abel, 1980; Slicher van Bath, 1964). Pomeranz‘s observa-
substances, such as fossil fuels, are not infinitely substitutable tion on this agro-ecological impasse gets us close to the crux of the
within capitalism, neither can capital simply conjure up new problem. Although Pomeranz does not see this is a capitalist crisis,
sources of long term growth. he quite fruitfully posits this impasse in historical-relational rather
Capitalisation is not alchemy. The socio-technical innovations than abstract- materialist term, from the standpoint of socio-
propelling modernity‘s successive agro-ecological revolutions ecological organisation rather than biophysical properties narro wly
were never able to create something out of nothing. Such stimuli defined:
are not infinite; at the some point, the underlying sources of such
stimuli are progressively exhausted relative to the demands of [P]er-acre and total yields from arable land remained flat
world accumulation. Moreover, because these stimuli are not and the threat of decline constant, until Britain began min-
―found‖ so much as they are created (in coevolutionary fashion) by ing, importing, and later synthesizing fertilizer mostly after
the mode of production, the limits to infinite expansion are found 1850…. [A]lthough the English studies continental practic-
in the very socio-ecological matrix that constitutes the mode of es, classical agricultural manuals, and their own experi-
production itself. ments very intently, much of what they learned about how
These special stimuli have pivoted on the relation between the best to maintain soil fertility while increasing yields was
variable forms of bourgeois territorial enclosures and property re- not actually applied in England, because it involved highly
lations, and the availability of un- or under-capitalised nature. labor- intensive methods and English capitalist farmers…
Thus, the extension of the geographical arena for commodity pro- were intent on labor-cost minimization and profit maximi-
Ecology & the Accumulation of Capital, 39

zation. The methods they adopted instead, which raised la- been the pattern: in California and the American Midwest in the
bor productivity, represented a fundamental break with first half of the 20th century (Walker, 2004; Kloppenburg, 1988),
much of the literature on best farming practices and ac- Europe in the later 19th century (van Zanden, 1991), the American
tually interfered with preserving soil fertility in many cas- Midwest in the mid-19th century (Cronon, 1990), the English and
es; it was in part because of these strategies that increasing Dutch revolutions of the 17th and 16th centuries (Overton, 1996;
amounts of off- farm phosphates and nitrates were needed Brenner, 2001), and let us not forget the multiple plantation revo-
in the 19th century just to keep yields from declining. In lutions of the early modern era (Moore, 2007).
other words, without the new industrial [sic] inputs that Relative to the worldwide ―ecological crisis‖ of peasant socie-
came to its rescue, England might have had a hard time ties in the later 19th century (Wolf, 1969), the ecological revolution
even maintaining its yields without putting far more labor set in motion during the late 1960s represented an epochal leap
into the soil (2000: 216-217, emphasis added). forward in the capitalisation of agro-ecologies worldwide and in
the coercive- intensive apparatus. The late 19th century represented,
The problem was not that ―natural limits‖ has been reached, in contrast to the recent history of neoliberalism, an aggregate de-
but rather that the biophysical impasse was itself a limit of capital- cline in the capitalisation of world nature – the absolute extension
ist relations, a limit of capitalism as oikeios. Until off- farm phos- of commodity production and exchange has so far tended to ob-
phates became available, after the Napoleonic wars, the only way scure the extent to which minimal capital investment met with
to raise land yields in a major way through labor intensity. But this maximal imperial power to realise the epochal appropriation of
was precisely at the moment when such labor supplies were most biophysical surpluses without (yet) capitalising their delivery. Vast
needed, to propel both the industrialization drive and the manpow- new socialised, though not yet capitalised, ecological formations
er demands of the war. were drawn into the matrix of accumulation. This incorporation of
Is it possible that the neoliberal ecological regime has entered a vast new zones into the world-economy was made possible by the
phase of its development – what I have called a developmental most ferocious manifestations of primitive accumulation yet seen –
ecological crisis – that is broadly analogous to the crisis of early this the ―gigantic killing machine‖ of late Victorian capitalism
capitalism‘s ecological regime in the 18th century? Neoliberalism, (Watts, 2001; Davis, 2001.) By compelling peasant producers
as a phase of capitalism, to some extent owed its very existence to throughout the new peripheries to sell ―without regard to price of
the yield windfalls of the Green Revolution – surficially ―technic- production‖ – as Engels observed in the midst of the process (in
al‖ windfalls themselves premised on the disintegrating effects of Marx, 1967, III: 726) – such appropriation relative to capitalisation
market discipline imposed through state power. These windfalls contributed significantly to the ecological surplus.
were famously set in motion in India in the later 1960s, but with The relation was reworked but not fundamentally remade in
important forerunners in Mexico and the U.S. decades earlier the long era of the Green Revolution. It was an era that emerged
(Perkins, 1997; Wright, 1990; Sonnenfeld, 1992; Berlan and Le- first in the North. The 1935 commercial introduction of hybrid
wontin, 1986a, b). Like every agricultural revolution before it, the corn in the U.S. promised not only rising yields per acre, and ris-
Green Revolution of the 1960s and ‗70s increased the relative eco- ing capitalisation through mechanization and skyrocketing fertiliz-
logical surplus, through the judicious (if brutal) reconfiguration of er (and then pesticide) use. Hybrid corn marked an early, pivotal
peasant ecologies, especially in South and Southeast Asia (Ross, moment in capital-oriented biological innovation. By crossing in-
2000; Griffin, 1974; Shiva, 1991; Cleaver, 1972). This had long bred lines of corn whose seed produced high yields but could not
Ecology & the Accumulation of Capital, 40

be reproduced, American seed companies severed the age-old contradiction in historical capitalism has been to simultaneously
connection between seed and grain (Berlan and Lewontin, 1986b; preserve and create – and in the same breathe, to undermine and
Kloppenburg, 1988: 91-129). Hybridization thus married biologi- appropriate – the reproduction of ecologies (as oikeios) relatively
cal control to the coercive dispositions of market competition, autonomous from the circuit of capital. Left ecology has illumi-
chaining metropolitan farmers to the ―vicious cycle… [of a] tec h- nated the ongoing transition from the formal to the real subsump-
nological treadmill‖ and widespread dispossession (Kloppenburg, tion of (extra-human) nature to capital (Boyd, Schurman, and
1988: 119). Prudham, 2001; Smith, 2007). But these discussions, so far, have
The same dispositions played out three decades later in the yet to grasp the ways that the rising capitalisation of nature
South. Far from simply a technological marvel of new seeds and proceeds on the basis of the relative exhaustion of the conditions
new chemicals, the coercive-intensive appropriation of the best of production (e.g. soil exhaustion is ―fixed‖ through rising capita-
ecological spaces (good soil, good water) was necessary for the lisation in the form of fertilizers, while fertilizers themselves work
realization of the socio-technical visions of the Green Revolution. only so far before provoking pest invasions, escalating pesticide
This great leap forward to new frontiers, for the Green Revolution use, which creates new resistances, and so forth). The upshot is
of the 1960s and for its forerunners as well, allowed to extend ca- this. The rising capitalisation of nature – qua the transitions (plur-
pitalisation on socio-ecological terrains that were favorable to the al) from formal to real subsumption, take place in a world-
simultaneous and uneven appropriations of biophysical natures. A historical situation of rising production costs stemming from the
big part of the reason why the Green Revolution was so successful degradation of the conditions of production. Rising exhaustion and
(that is, where and when it actually was successful on its own rising capitalisation are two sides of the same coin.
terms) was that it imposed cutting-edge technology on regions As in the oil sector, rising capitalisation in neoliberalism‘s
where the value of labor and land was very low, driving down sys- world agriculture has set in motion all manner of resistances to the
temwide food prices and therefore, all things being equal, the sys- self-expansion of capital, from antisystemic movements, from eco-
temwide cost of variable capital. (In other words, cheap food re- logical feedbacks, from resurgent national developmentalisms.
lieved pressure on capital‘s wage bill, attenuating the falling rate (All of which points towards the transcendence of a value-
of profit.) At the level of appearances, we are treated, then, to theoretic argument about capitalism‘s inner logic – a profoundly
something of an optical illusion – a new stream of capital inputs heuristic exercise – in favor a history of capitalism, one that moves
leads one to think the Green Revolution in terms of capital- towards an analysis of the ―evolution of society as a whole,‖ in
intensity. But insofar as this ―revolutionary‖ project appropriated, Lukács‘ turn of phrase [1971].) This is the double limit of capital
for free or low-cost, quality land, access to water, and labor power, and capitalism, the inner logic feeds rising costs and declining
the value composition of yields was in fact very low, and therefore profitability, the solution to which is an outer logic that delivers
highly profitable. The revolutionary achievements were made temporary liberation, but only within specifiable limits. Thus, un-
through plunder every bit as much as through productivity. til this moment (and perhaps for a few years more, perhaps even a
The capitalised delivery of ―labor and nature‖ is expensive. decade), the game has been worth the candle because the contra-
Among the secrets of capital accumulations over the longue durée dictions of rising capitalisation could be offset through the dep-
has been the progressive (and always contested) conquest and ab- loyment of socio-technical innovation and brute force to extend
sorption of human and extra-human nature whose reproduction frontiers and stall (or at least, slow-down) the exhaustion of the
was either relatively, or entirely, free from the law of value. The stimuli that have sustained the ecological surplus.
Ecology & the Accumulation of Capital, 41

As world agriculture gets reworked as global factory (an cert, these accomplishments would reduce the wage-bill for capi-
asymptotic process) – its socio-ecological constituents extracted tal, and therefore powerfully counteract the tendency towards de-
and then reintroduced into the body of world-ecology as a macro- clining profitability. In the middle-run of 25-35 years, we would
cosmic face of genetic appropriations and productions – the more expect to see two contradictions come into play, gradually eroding
it becomes subject to the same tendency towards a declining eco- the mechanisms for delivering (or even sustaining) an ecological
logical surplus that we encountered in our survey of the world oil surplus sufficient for expanded accumulation. On the one hand, we
sector. (I shall bracket, for the moment, the ways that contradic- would expect to encounter a rising organic composition of capital
tions within oil shape the contradictions within agriculture, a l- at a systemwide level. This tendency has progressed farthest in the
though these are powerful and significant.) All agricultural revolu- heartland of the so-called ―green revolution,‖ where in the United
tions in the modern world-system have justified their globalising States the rising energy throughput of agriculture precipitated an
expropriations by promising, and until now materializing, a yield avalanche of farm bankruptcies (registering faltering profitability
revolution. Their significance for accumulation rested in the pro- at the ―enterprise‖ level) after the 1970s (MacLellan and Walker,
duction of a rising ecological surplus relative to the demands of 1980). This tendency underpins the high rates of profitability en-
value accumulation – driving down the value composition (price) joyed by agribusiness in recent years (McMichael, 2009b). Lewon-
of food relative to the average value composition of aggregate tin puts his finger on this process:
commodity production. All depended upon successive frontier
movements interlaced with productivity- maximizing innovations. The rise in purchased industrially produced inputs has had
At the heart of the argument advanced here is that the Green two effects. A major increase in yields per acre has driven
Revolution constituted a new phase in the capitalisation of global down the price paid to farmers for their product. Simulta-
nature. As such, we would expect to see an epoch- making expan- neously the farmers' costs of production have risen. There
sion of the relative ecological surplus, at the beginning of any re- has been no escape from this dilemma for an individual
vival of world accumulation. This is true both in terms of extra- farmer. Because the price paid for a farm product is deter-
human nature (for example, grain or energy surpluses available for mined by the aggregate production from all farms, no ind i-
sale at low-cost), and in terms of the mobilization of human nature vidual farmer can push prices up by holding down produc-
qua relative surplus population. Such revolutions would yield a tion. Thus he must increase production when other farmers
double windfall – 1) deploying cheap, extra- human resources to do, but the result of all these individually economically ra-
maximize yields (and minimize their value component), thereby tional acts is mass suicide (2001; also Danaher, 1989; Ken-
driving down food prices relative to industrial goods; and 2) e x- ney, et al., 1989).
panding the reserve army of labor. As we have seen, the period
1980-2000 offered the lowest world market prices for food in On the other hand, the very escalation of rising energy
world history – this was not unrelated to the appropriation of an throughput – declining energy ―efficiency,‖ if this is the right word
extraordinary labor frontier. Freeman thinks nearly 1.5 billion for it (Pimentel, et al., 1973, 2008, 2009) – must be understood as
workers ―from China, India, and the former Soviet Union entered a farm- level response to: 1) the coercion of finance capital, which
the global labor pool‖ in these decades, but my guess is that the demands rising productivity in relation to an the average rate of
overall expansion was not much more than half this (still massive) profit determined in great part by non-agricultural enterprises; and
figure (Freeman, 2005; also Barnet and Cavanagh, 1994). In con- 2) the relative exhaustion of agro-ecology in two main ways, first
Ecology & the Accumulation of Capital, 42

as nutrient depletion, and secondly, as the creative response of e x- version of a vast layer of the world‘s peasantry into
tra-human nature to the disciplines of capitalism. Amongst these (semi)proletarians and commodity-producers (Araghi 1995, 2000).
creative responses we may note the proliferation of herb icide- In contrast to previous waves of primitive accumulation, this form
resistant ―superweeds,‖ resilient in the face of Monsanto‘s famed of agricultural revolution appears as almost entirely redistributio-
RoundUp Ready, GMO soybeans (Brown, 2005; Gurian-Sherman, nary. Thus, for instance, the neoliberal ecological regime brought
2009; Caulcutt, 2009). Considering that GMO soy already consti- to an end the long wave of egalitarian land reform that spanned the
tutes 57 percent of world output, and that the U.S. remains the period 1910-1970 (Bernstein, 2002). In the absence of gigantic
leading soy producer (37 percent), we may soon come to under- ―free gifts‖ on offer from the frontier, it looks as if the neoliberal
stand the rise of the superweed as a world- historical event (Pech- accumulation strategy was rather narrowly focused on redistribut-
laner and Otero, 2008; Masuda and Goldsmith, 2008). ing the fruits of Green Revolution agriculture, a necessarily self-
The accumulation crisis generated by the postwar boom (c. limiting strategy.
1947-1973) was resolved by resurgent financialization and resur- By now there is widespread agreement that the productivity
gent primitive accumulation. (The marriage between these two gains of the Green Revolution have exhausted themselves, even if
moments was much tighter than ever before.) As we know so well there remain possibilities for yield growth on the margins. Per ca-
by the point, the financial expansion – which by its nature pita grain production peaked in the mid-1980s (Tilman, et al.,
represents a multiplication of the systemwide claims on the future 2002; IMF, 2008; Earth Policy Institute, 2006; Scoones, 2001). In
ecological surplus –propelled a radical expansion of property the heartland of the Green Revolution, India, cereal output actually
claims on the genetic diversity of the biosphere. This is not new, declined modestly between 1990 and 2004 (Research Unit for Po-
and in a broad sense this too is a cyclical phenomenon of the litical Economy, 2008). From a long historical perspective, even
world-economy The ―primitive accumulation of botanical know- the Green Revolution appears as a recent reproduction of Euro-
ledge‖ has been with us since the long 16th century (Canizares- pean capitalism‘s land-extensive strategy (Moore, 2003b, 2007;
Esguerra, 2004; Kloppenburg, 1988; Brockway, 1979). What is Weiskell, 1981). These ecological revolutions achieved their gains
new, however, is neither enclosure, nor its latest incarnation qua not only through a geometric increase in off- farm inputs and the
―biopiracy,‖ but the whole spectrum of efforts to rework and con- new techniques they implied, but also by virtue of market and non-
trol nature at a genetic level. What is too often missed is that re- market appropriations of the best land. The Green Revolution
working nature in this way not only implies, but necessitates, the worked wonders where land was great and water abundant – not
rising capitalisation of nature. But far from a productive response, more than 20 percent of arable in the Pakistani Punjab of the late
in the neoliberal era this has been nothing short of a redistributio n- 1960s (Niazi, 2004; Perelman, 1977: 153). As the heartlands of
ist ploy. The neoliberal ecological regime joins rapid financializa- this revolutionary project moved from the windfall phase of socia-
tion with the transition from the ―formal‖ to the ―real subsumption lisation towards capitalisation, land and water offered up increa-
of nature to capital.‖ And so we have moved from Captain Hook singly effective resistance. Water, upon which chemical fertilizers
to Dr. Frankenstein in modernity‘s production of nature. depend so strongly, may prove must intractable of all – and the
In its formative years, neoliberalism succeeded in expanding implementation of yet more capitalisation through better and more
the world food surplus – a pillar of the relative ecological surplus – powerful well-pumps promises a dynamic strikingly similar to
by milking the last of the Green Revolution‘s prodigious increases
in agricultural productivity, making profitable the systematic con-
Ecology & the Accumulation of Capital, 43

oil. 59 The decisive spatial appropriation of the Green Revolution tween the use-value and exchange-value moments of agricultural
was indeed horizontal rather than vertical, depending on oil drill- revolution as we have come to know it. Since the 1930s, beginning
ing and water mining – groundwater withdrawals on the Indian with the hybrid corn revolution in North America, the agricultural
subcontinent accelerated more than 12- fold between the end of the history of this ―short‖ 20th century has been, in crucial respects,
1950s and 2000, with Punjab home to the greatest number of about the concentration of genetic knowledge in the hands of agri-
―overexploited‖ aquifers (World Bank, 2007: 182, 186; Shah, et business in order to bring farmers into the circuit of capital. It is
al., 2003). By the close of the 20th century, cereal harvests, world- not for nothing that Kloppenburg refers to this as a decisive mo-
wide and in the Punjab as well, expanded at just half the rate of ment of ―primitive accumulation‖ within advanced capitalism.
three decades prior (Strauss, 2000: 106; Murgai, Ali, and Byerlee, There is no question that these hybrid initiatives were implicated
2001: 203). (The parallels with the exhaustion of England‘s first in a revolutionary increase in the relative food surplus. (Whether
agricultural revolution, and the developmental crisis of early cap i- or not such revolutionary increases could have been achieved by
talism‘s ecological regime, are not to be missed.) other means remains an open question.) These hybrid revolutions
Whether or not a biotech revolution is in the cards as a mea- were novel in their capacity to privatize genetic knowledge in the
ningful way out of this impasse remains doubtful. Gurian- hands of capital. In contrast to the biotech project today, this earli-
Sherman, in the first comprehensive survey of biotechnology‘s er revolution reproduced the durable relation between use- value
aggregate yield effect, finds almost all gains (such as they are) in (rising food surplus) and exchange-value (reviving accumulation)
operational, not intrinsic, yields (2009). Even if water and land that had persisted for several centuries. But the more recent trans-
constraints could be overcome through new genetic-chemical formations associated with genetically modified crops has yet to
combinations – and the ―water question‖ may well be more serious reproduce this durable relation. Biotech‘s great promise seems to
than commonly recognised (Palaniappan and Gleick, 2008) – the be one of maximizing profitability without maximizing the ecolog-
very basis of late capitalist agriculture, its capital- and energy- ical surplus (Altieri & Rosset, 1999; Gurian-Sherman, 2009). This
intensity, creates an even more serious constraint on late capitalist promise may be read as a key agro-ecological moment of the
agriculture‘s capacity to raise yields. The existing control regime – broader redistribution of income (from poor to rich) characteristic
in this instance, the control of weeds and pests – promises to in- of the neoliberalism (Duménil and Levy, 2004; Harvey, 2005) The
duce the evolution of more resistant pests or pathogen, the very contradiction between use- and exchange- value may as a conse-
superweeds and ―super-pests‖ we encountered earlier (Ruttan, quence be unusually sharp in this latest wave of agro-ecological
2002: 173). transformation.
This suggests a world-historical rupture of the greatest signi- There is, then, a ―feedback‖ contradiction at play here. On the
ficance in the modern history of agriculture. If it persists, the fail- one hand, capital must realise a qualitative expansion of the rela-
ure of biotech to achieve a significant upward revision in the sys- tive ecological surplus – whose chief expression would be massive
tem‘s ecological surplus expresses a fundamental disjuncture be- expansion of food, energy, and materials surpluses available at low
cost. On the other hand, the very (capital- intensifying) strategies
that would enable such a qualitative expansion will e nclose those
59
―Today, India‘s farmers use subsidized energy worth some US $ 4.5– 5 bil- small zones of undercapitalised nature that still exist, a nd will in-
lion/year to pump some 150 km3 of water mostly for irr igation; the country‘s tensify the effort to fragment (and discipline the fragments of) na-
groundwater economy has boomed by bleeding the energy economy‖ (Shah, et
ture. The first movement (frontier expansion) implies an escalation
al., 2003: 138.)
Ecology & the Accumulation of Capital, 44

of class and imperial projects to ―reserve the exclusivity of access & Schurman, 2001). Thus each ecological regime takes less time
to these resources‖ (Amin, 2008), and to an escalation of (costly) than the previous to complete the circle, as it were, reflecting the
social and geopolitical tensions. The second movement (socio- increasing penetration of capital into primary production and its
technical innovation) is already generating a bundle of unpredicta- success in accelerating turnover time.
ble responses. It is, in Wallis‘s apt phrase, a ―taming cycle‖ – the But this success is achieved at a price. This inner logic of cap i-
very strategies that seek to maximize not only the productivity of, tal – which is predicated on the tendency to dissolve socio-
and also control over (predictability), a specific nature- fragment ecological particularities and reconstitute them as fragments (e.g.
undermine the longer-run conditions through which productivity parcelizing land, ―standard‖ slaves or hogs, patented genes and
and predictability can be realised (2000). even organisms) – tends to enable the accumulation of capital for a
For this reason, I am not much concerned with the ecological time, but in the absence of uncapitalised, nature, is unsustainable,
―overshoot‖ preoccupations of much green thinking these days within the logic of value accumulation itself. The rising cost of
(Catton, 1982), including its Marxist incarnation (Foster, Clark, fixed and circulating capital drives upward the organic composi-
and York, 2008a, 2008b). I don‘t mean to suggest that overshoot is tion of capital, which drives down the rate of profit. The temporal
a poor description; merely that it is not much o f an explanation – moment is crucial, for the rising capitalisation of nature works
as with the ecological footprint metaphor (with which it is closely within established boundaries (keeping in mind the constant drive
linked) we have an order of things in which the socio-ecological for new commodity frontiers) by accelerating the extraction of
relations that constitute both ―society‖ and ―nature‖ are beside the ecological wealth. The acceleration of such exploitation poses one
point. For the argument at hand, there is too much emphasis on the set of contradictions through the overproduction of machinery and
acting units and not nearly enough on the relations that form and the underproduction of nature; and another set of contradictions
re-form the agencies of capitalism as oikeios. The crucial issue, through the control efforts that seek to render more predictable the
from the standpoint of the longue durée, is that the ―time-space relation with the rest of nature, but over the middle-run, create
compression‖ central to the accumulation of capital at once de- conditions of spiraling unpredictability. Global warming is a mon-
pends upon, and drives ever faster and forward, the time-space strous case in point!
compression of biophysical nature. But this is no mere capital- The eminently rational kernel in the catastrophism of our times
centric process; there is a dialectic. In the modern world, extra- is that this ―middle run‖ appears to be shrinking. And fast. ―The
human nature evolves much faster than the social relations that models aren't fast enough right now,‖ as Mark Serreze told the
seek to govern it. These evolutionary responses are of course coe- 2007 meeting of the American Geophysical Union – referring to
volutionary; but the biophysical moment is increasingly unpredict- the unexpectedly rapid retreat of Arctic ice (Amos, 2007; see
able and indeed defies efforts to discern impending qualitative Lindsay, et al., 2009). Serreze‘s comment applies well to the
shifts with any degree of certitude (Sheffer, et al., 2001). breadth of environmental studies today. Our models just aren’t
As capital comes to circulate through (and not merely around) moving fast enough. It is for this reason that I have emphasized the
biophysical circuits, the faster these ecological revolutions move insufficiency of approaches that begin from a separation of what
from liberating to imprisoning accumulation. Herein lies the polit- we know cannot be separated. If neoliberalism as ecological re-
ical ecology of Nature as ―opportunity‖ and ―obstacle‖ – an enab- gime has reached its signal crisis – driving input prices upwards as
ler of, and hindrance to, capital accumulation – in successive eco- the value composition of food, energies, and raw materials moves
logical regimes (Mann, 1990; Henderson, 1999; Boyd, Prudham, closer to the systemwide average – this may or may not pose a
Ecology & the Accumulation of Capital, 45

problem. The past two centuries have witnessed a succession of coal‖ – involves a chain of production that promises still more
ecological regimes that have run ahead of the curve in the delivery (and differentially toxic) forms of waste? 60
of relatively cheap inputs, energy, food, and labor power. That ca-
pitalism has depended on accessible frontiers to deliver the goods On Limits and Crises
is no secret. To this point, we have focused on the enduring prob-
lematic posed by Luxemburg – the role of external frontiers in For Raymond Williams, capitalism emerges through the relation
making the relative ecological surplus. What we have neglected is between humanity and the rest of nature. Green social theory has
the obverse of the land and labor frontier – the waste frontier. gone far in making this clear. But this offers only a point of entry
Simply put, every commodity frontier (for energy, for materials) is into the questions of crises and limits in actually existing capita l-
simultaneously a waste frontier. ism. How do we move forward? I should like to draw this discus-
Nowhere is this logic more in evidence than in climate change. sion to a close by offering two propositions, one conceptual and
Indeed, I think it is precisely because capitalism represents a pecu- one empirical.
liar organisation nature (internalising labor power, externalising First, surplus value and the relative ecological surplus are not
the other parts of nature) that global warming is heating up. identical, but mobilize in dialectically uneven fashion. Joseph
Schumpeter once quipped that the sky may prove to be the most Schumpeter once quipped that the blessing and the curse of Marx-
important ―frontier‖ of capitalism (1942: 117). And there is little ism was that ―sociology and economics pervade each other‖
question today that CO2 emissions constitute a massive appropria- (1942: 45). The ―economic‖ category, labor, and the ―sociologi-
tion of the atmosphere as waste frontier. Indeed, the atmosphere cal‖ category, proletariat were but distinct angles of vision of the
has been inadvertently produced as a form of socialized nature by same process. Naturally, the socio-technical dynamics of ―labor,‖
the forces of capital accumulation. The waste frontier moved to an at the point of production, and the ―proletariat,‖ within society,
increasingly central position in world accumulation after the cannot be reduced to each other; but neither can they be adequate-
Second World War – this had everything to do with the qualitative ly explained without each other. Can we not say much the same
transformations of postwar capitalism, above all the synthetics about surplus value and the relative ecological surplus? (And are
revolution. But there was also a powerful quantitative moment. not the dialectics surplus value/proletariat-reserve army and sur-
The geometrical expansion of commodity production demanded plus value/ecological surplus, themselves engaged in a dialectical
the radical extension of the waste frontier to the global atmos- waltz of sorts?) When Marx glibly opined that the accumulation of
phere. Thus, global warming may be understood as the (non- capital is the proletarianization of labor, we may join the chorus in
linear) result of capital‘s inner logic to minimize costs (drive down saying the accumulation of capital is the proletarianization of labor
the costs of constant capital by deploying cheap energy for more is the enclosure of nature.
costly labor), and by continually striving to open new waste fron- Here is a vital opportunity to underscore the class-relational
tiers, to externalize the cost of dumping greenhouse gases into the nature of the value theory built out in this essay. There is a n im-
air. Is it happenstance that every large-scale alternative to the oil- portant distinction to be made between the history of class strug-
centered energy regime today – agrofuels, nuclear energy, ―clean gles in the modern world, and the durable ―stakes of the game‖

60
Wind and solar energy are, meanwhile, experiencing a dramatic contraction
of investment (see Taylor, 2009; Macalister, 2009).
Ecology & the Accumulation of Capital, 46

that have been struggled over since the long 16th century. 61 The global ecological fixes expand opportunities for appropriation
history of class struggles in the capitalist era is manifestly a history faster than they demand capitalisation, the ecological surplus e x-
of conflict over the terms of Theophrastus‘ oikeios – the relation- pands and world accumulation revives. Capitalisation remains in-
ship simultaneously within and between the human species and its dispensable, but can do its work only to the extent that a rising
environments. The stakes of the game have, with increasing force quantum of biophysical nature can attach to the same level of cap i-
since the early modern era, found their gravitational center in the tal investment. Thus emerges an inner contradiction of the specif-
contested longue durée movement of commodification. Commodi- ically capitalist oikeios – the rising capitalisation of world nature.
fication has been savagely imposed and fiercely resisted, the orga- As capitalisation rises, the relative ecological surplus tends to fall,
nisation of production struggled over at every turn, by planters, which can only be counteracted by liberating new reservoirs of
industrialists, slaves, proletarians, peasants and capitalist farmers, socialised natures for the accumulation process. The punch line is
merchants, financiers, state machineries and colonial empires. (To that, just as the neoclassical notion of ―substitutability‖ represents
name a few.) At the core of all these struggles is, as every Marxist a succession of specifiable, exhaustible (and therefore irreversible)
knows, the struggle over the rate of surplus value. (Knowing this movements, so does the capitalisation of socialised nature
hardly absolves one of analysis, of course, it only clarifies the represent a series of specifiable, exhaustible (and therefore irre-
game, and the stakes involved.) Schumpeter‘s quip illuminates the versible) enclosures. The relative ecological surplus falls in rela-
enduring contribution of Marx‘s political economy. Class struggle, tion to the rise of commodified nature. This is one of the chief
the commodity form, and the transformation of the oikeios (hu- ways that capitalism not only ―develops,‖ but ages. Today, there
mans transform nature and in so doing ―change [their] own na- surely remain ecological spaces relatively untouched by the vi-
ture‖62 ) are dialectically, if not quite systematically, combined in olence of the commodity form. But their relative weight in the
the theory of value. Just as the history of class struggle in the feud- world-system is incomparably lower today than it was in 1873, or
al era emerges in and through the contest over the rate of seig- even 1973.
neurial levy, so the struggles of capitalism unfold in and through How might we begin to move from value theory to the history
the contest over the production of surplus value. And it is precisely of capitalism, from capital to capitalism? If the construct of ―eco-
this value form that constitutes the gravitational field of capitalism logical regime‖ is to prove useful, it must be more than a large de-
as world-ecology. scriptive category (pace Beddoe, et al., 2009). In what sense can
As we know, capitalism ―as world-ecology‖ has been, for the this perspective explain something of the rise and future demise of
better part of two centuries, characterised by abundance, not scar- the modern world-system? For some measure of guidance, we
city. Since the 1830s, the underproductionist crisis tendency has might turn to Giovanni Arrighi‘s systemic cycles perspective
been checked by the capacity of capitalist and territorialist age n- (1994), and Harvey‘s theory of the spatial fix (1982).
cies to secure a relative ecological surplus through global expan- Let us begin with Arrighi‘s theory of historical capitalism.
sion. Put schematically, such expansion qua global ecological fix¸ Crucial to Arrighi‘s scheme is the notion that ascendant world
works moves horizontally (new continents absorbed) and vertical- powers have risen to global preeminence through varied ―organi-
ly (new mineral veins tapped or coalfields mined). So long as these zational revolutions‖ in the structures of capitalist and territorial
power. Crucial for the argument developed here is that such revo-
61
lutions achieve their qualitative shifts in response to – and on the
To borrow a phrase fro m Bourdieu (1990: 110).
62 basis of – the accumulating (quantitative) contradictions of the
Marx, 1976: 283.
Ecology & the Accumulation of Capital, 47

previous era. For instance, the crises generated in successive ac- sue successive ―environmental regimes.‖ By deepening and widen-
cumulation cycles have called forth organizing centers of progres- ing the scope of commodification through new forms of gover-
sively greater geographical breadth – from the Genoese city-state nance, organizational change, and technical innovation – not to
of the 16th century to the American continental-state of the long mention the expansion of the system‘s socially necessary division
20th .63 That these movements may be propelled by an important of labor – these organizational revolutions solve (for a time) the
ecological moment, is neither acknowledged, nor ruled out. problems of the older ways of organizing world-ecology. Above
At the same time, Harvey‘s theory of spatial fix (1982) sug- all, they overcome looming agricultural and extractive bottlenecks
gests two further connections of the greatest significance. First is to accumulation. Successive industrial and agricultural revolutions
the contention that the financial expansions so central to Arrighi‘s are only their most conspicuous form. To echo Harvey, I would
perspective, are dialectically connected with ―accumulation by say that these globalizing ecological revolutions at first liberate
dispossession‖ (Harvey, 2003). Second, in Harvey‘s broader accumulation. Was not this the world- historical accomplishment of
theory of spatial fix, the initial flexibility, and acceleration, of British hegemony in the ―first‖ 19th century (c. 1763-1848)? Over
turnover time achieved through a ―built environment‖ favorable to time, however, these new ways of producing nature – through po-
capital in one era, becomes a fetter upon accumulation in the next. litical regulation, built environments, industrial organization, agri-
In this way, ―environments are created that simultaneously facili- cultural innovation and so forth – begin to generate contradictions.
tate but imprison the future paths of capitalist development‖ (Har- The relative ecological surplus falls as the capitalisation of world
vey, 1991: 218, emphasis added). nature rises. This undercuts the basis of expanded accumulation,
Integrating such a sociological sensibility to world-historical starting the world-ecological cycle all over again.
environmental change, we can put our finger on something impor- Successive phases of capitalism, led if not determined by suc-
tant about modern environmental history. Mobilising a theory of cessive world powers, organize nature-society relations in a man-
ecological revolution as organizational revolution, and a geograph- ner appropriate to the ecological conditions and challenges they
ical, ―built environment,‖ perspective on successive ecological re- confronts. In an important early debate in political ecology, Ted
gimes, we can begin to draw together Harvey and Arrighi, to see Benton argued for precisely such a historical specification of na-
two things. First, successive phases of capitalism have unfolded ture-society relations. Drawing our attention to the ―specific co m-
through revolutions in the accumulation process, and the nature- plexes of natural conditions‖ on the one hand, and the ―specific
society relations within its gravitational field. These are ecological structure[s] of natural/social articulation,‖ Benton rightly pointed
revolutions, their signal accomplishment, the radical extension of out what is too often forgotten today, namely that what constitutes
the ecological surplus relative to the historically specifiable a limit in one mode of production (or phase of capitalism) ―may
movement of world accumulation. It is only from the standpoint of not constitute a limit for another‖ mode of production (or phase of
the oikeios (ecological regimes) that these revolutions – constitut- capitalism) (1989: 77, 79). Thus may we begin to think of succes-
ing the deep structure of historical capitalism – can be seen to is- sive phases of capitalism as creating, and created by, an increa-
singly capitalised world-ecology. The historical limits of early ca-
63
Not to mention geographical depth, as modes of extractive have plunged ever pitalism‘s ecological regime – for example, agricultural exhaustion
deeper into the earth itself. Geographical expansion itself co mprises both hori- and relative energy scarcity throughout central and western Europe
zontal and vertical movements, the latter overlapping, but not to be confused, – had been reached by the middle of the 18th century; these were
with the socio-spatial intensification of rising capital intensity at a systemwide
level.
Ecology & the Accumulation of Capital, 48

ecohistorical limits to capital accumulation as it was then orga- sizing its double (not dual) character: capitalism as world-
nized. Clearly, they were not absolute limits. economy and capitalism as world-ecology (Moore, 2003c). But we
What Benton does not offer – this is where Arrighi‘s approach cannot be content with adding more signifiers. The formulation of
becomes exceedingly useful – is a spatialized sociology of how capitalism‘s double character is useful only if it leads somewhere –
these limits have been transcended over the course of modern not merely placing concepts of environmental transformation and
world history. What I am proposing is an ecohistorical twist on governance alongside those of social change, but reworking the
Arrighi‘s fruitful notion that phases of world development pivot on fundamental categories of (so-called!) ―social‖ change from the
―particular organizational structure[s], the vitality of whic h [is] standpoint of the historically existing relations of nature and socie-
progressively undermined by the expansion itself‖ (1994: 226). ty.
From this standpoint, ―increasingly vicious competition,‖ between This approach, I think, moves us beyond the worn notion of
capitals and between states, eventually reaches a boiling point, ―ecological crisis‖ as slogan, and in the direction of a formulation
with the ensuing crisis of profitability resulting in the demise of of modern ecological crisis as explanatory concept – one the em-
the very ―organizational structures on which the preceding materi- phasizes the irreducibly plural notion of crisis: 1) plural through
al expansion‖ was based (1994: 226). If we bring biophysical time (many temporalities); 2) plural across space (many geogra-
process into such a world- historical frame, it becomes clear that phies); and 3) plural across the nature-society dialectic (many so-
something more than competition undermined the great phases of cio-ecological crystallizations), from the apparently ―social‖ crises
world economic growth – one can think of successive ―golden of finance and empire to the apparently ―ecological‖ crises of soil
ages‖ of capitalism – 1450 to 1530, 1848 to 1873, 1947 to 1973. exhaustion and deforestation.
Put simply, in this undermining movement, we have seen recur- It is a re-reading of this grand signifier, ―ecological crisis,‖ I
rently two things – an absolute exhaustion of those ―organizational hope, that offers a more historical, and, therefore a more hopeful
structures‖ specific to the accumulation regime, and a relative ex- and democratic, means of thinking through the problem of ecology
haustion of the ecological spaces articulated with the old regime of and questions of ecological crisis as constitutive of capitalism and
accumulation. Here is a way to talk about limits without invoking its successors.
neo-Malthusian conceptions of ecological limits – a still present
danger (even from those on the left) revealed in recent discussions References
of peak oil.
By locating today‘s biophysical transformations within long- Abel, Wilhelm (1980 [1966]). Agricultural Fluctuations in Europe: From the
run and large-scale patterns of recurrence and evolution in the Thirteenth to the Twentieth Centuries. Olive Ordish, trans. New Yo rk: St. Mar-
modern world, we might begin to illuminate the distinctiveness of tin‘s Press.
the present crisis. It is for sure a crisis of neoliberalism‘s environ- Altieri, M iguel A., and Peter Rosset (1999). ―Ten Reasons Why Biotechnology
mental regime. But is it also a turning point in capitalism as eco- Will Not Ensure Food Security, Protect the Environ ment and Reduce Poverty in
logical regime? To answer, among the necessary steps is to situate the Developing World,‖ AgBioForum 2 (3-4), 155-162.
ecological relations internal to our historical political economy;
and above all, to situate our historical political economy within the Altvater, Elmar (2007). ―The Social and Natural Environ ment of Fossil Cap ital-
ism,‖ in Leo Panitch and Colin Leys , eds., Coming to Terms with Nature: So-
longue durée of the capitalist oikeios. If there is something we cialist Register 2007. London: Merlin Press.
might call a modern world-system, then, I have insisted on empha-
Ecology & the Accumulation of Capital, 49

Amin, Samir (2008). ―Financial crisis? Systemic crisis?‖ paper presented at The
School of Oriental and African Studies, Un iversity of London, November 26. Bairoch, Paul (1989). ―Les trois révolutions agricoles du monde développé :
rendements et productivité de 1800 à 1985,‖ Annales: Économies, Sociétés, Ci-
Amos, Jonathan (2007). ―Arctic summers ice-free ‗by 2013‘,‖ BBC News, 12 vilisations 44(2), 317 – 353.
December.
Bank for International Settlements (2006). 76th Annual Report. Basil: Switze r-
Amsden, Alice H. (1990). ―Third World Industrialization: ‗Global Ford ism‘ or a land. www.bis.org/publ/arpdf/ar2006e.ht m
New Model?‖ New Left Review I/182.
Baran, Pau l A., and Paul M. Sweezy (1966). Monopoly Capital. New York:
Anderson, Perry (1974a). Passages from Antiquity to Feudalism. London: New Monthly Review Press.
Left Books.
Barlow, Maude (2008). ―Blue Covenant: The Alternative Water Future,‖
Anderson, Perry (1974b). Lineages of the Absolutist State. London: New Left Monthly Review 60(3), 125-141.
Books.
Barnes, Donald Grove (1930 [2006]). A History of English Corn Laws: From
Angus, Ian (2008). ―Food Crisis, Part, I: The Historical Failu re of the Capitalist 1660-1846. Abingdon, UK: Routledge.
Model,‖ International Viewpoint 400.
Barnet, Richard J., and James Cavanagh (1994). Global dreams: Imperial cor-
Araghi, Farshad. (1995). ―Global Depeasantization, 1945-1990,‖ The Sociologi- porations and the new world order. New York: Simon & Schuster.
cal Quarterly 36(2), 337-368
Barraclough, Geoffrey (1967). An Introduction to Contemporary History. New
Araghi, Farshad. (2000). ―The Great Global Enclosure of Ou r Times: Peasants
Yo rk: Penguin.
and the Agrarian Question at the End of the Twentieth Century.‖ In Fred Mag-
doff, John Bellamy Foster, and Frederick H. Buttel, eds. Hungry for Profit. New Barry, John (1999). Environment and Social Theory. New Yo rk: Routledge.
Yo rk: Monthly Review Press, 145-160.
Beddoes, Rachael, Robert Costanza, Joshua Farley, et al. (2009). ―Overco ming
Armijo, L.E. (2007). ―The BRICs Countries (Brazil, Russia, India, and China) Systemic Roadblacks to Sustainability: The Evolutionary Redesign of
as Analytical Category: M irage or Insight?‖ Asian Perspective 31(4), 7-42.
Worldviews, Institutions, and Technologies,‖ Proceedings of the National
Academy of Sciences 106(8), 2483-2489.
Arrighi, Giovanni (1994). The Long Twentieth Century: Money, Power, and the
Origins of Our Times. London: Verso.
Benton, Ted (1989). ―Marxis m and Natural Limits: An Eco logical Crit ique and
Reconstruction,‖ New Left Review I/178, 51-86.
Arrighi, Giovanni & Jason W. Moore (2001). ―Capitalist Development in World
Historical Perspective.‖ In Robert Albritton, et al., eds., Phases of Capitalist De-
Benton, Ted (2001). ―Marx, Malthus, and the Greens: A Reply to Pau l Bu rkett,‖
velopment: Booms, Crises, and Globalization. New York: Palgrave, 56-75 Historical Materialism 8, 309-332
Arrighi, Giovani, Beverly J. Silver, and Benjamin D. Brewer (2003). ―Industrial
Berkes, Fikret, John Co lding, and Carl Folke, eds. (2003). Navigating social-
convergence, globalizat ion, and the persistence of the North-South divide,‖ Stu- ecological systems: Building resilience for complexity and change. Cambridge:
dies in Comparative International Development 38(1). Cambridge Un iversity Press.
Atkin, M ichael (1992). The international grain trade. Cambridge: Woodhead. Berlan, Jean-Pierre, and Richard C. Lewontin (1986a). ―Technology, Research,
Authers, John (2008). ―Long View: Classic films shed light on commodities and the Penetration of Capital: The Case of U.S. Agriculture,‖Monthly Review
boom,‖ Financial Times, May 9. 38(3), 21-34.
Ecology & the Accumulation of Capital, 50

Braun, Bruce (2006). “Towards a New Earth and a New Humanity: N a-


Berlan, Jean-Pierre, and Richard C. Lewontin (1986b). ―The Po lit ical Econo my ture, Ontol ogy, Politics,” in Derek Greg ory… eds., Harvey essays.
of Hybrid Co rn,‖Monthly Review 38(3), 35-47.
Braverman, Harry (1974). Labor and Monopoly Capital: The Degradation of
Bernstein, Henry (2001). ― ‗The Peasantry‘ in Global Cap italism: Who, Where Work in the Twentieth Century. New York: Monthly Rev iew Press.
and Why?‖ in Leo Panitch and Co lin Leys, eds. Socialist Register 2001. Lon-
don: Merlin, 25-51. Brenner, Robert (1976). ―Agrarian Class Structure and Economic Develop ment
in Pre-Industrial Eu rope,‖ Past & Present.
Bernstein, Henry (2002). ―Land Reform: Taking a Long(er) View,‖ Journal of
Agrarian Change 2(4), 433-463. Brenner, Robert P. 2001. ―The Low Countries in the Transition to Capitalism,‖
Journal of Agrarian Change 1, 2, Apr.,169-241.
Bina, Cyrus (1990). ―Limits of OPEC Pricing: OPEC Profits and the Nature of
Global Oil Accu mulation,‖ OPEC Review 14(1), 55-73. Brockway, Lucile H. (1979). Science and Colonial Expansion: The Role of the
British Royal Botanical Gardens. New York: Academic Press.
Birol, Fatih (2004). ―Analysis of the Impact of High Oil Prices on the Global
Economy,‖ International Energy Agency, Paris. Broswimmer, Franz (1991). ―Botanical Imperialis m: The Stewardship of Plant
Genetic Resources in the Third World,‖ Critical Sociology 18(1), 3-18.
Blackburn, Robin (1997). The Making of New World Slavery. New York: Ve rso.
Bro wn, Paul (2005). ―GM Crops Created Superweeds, Say Scientists: Mo dified
Blackburn, Robin (2008). ―The Subprime Crisis,‖ New Left Review II/ 50, 63- Rapeseed Crosses with Wil Plant to Creat Tough Pesticide-Resistant Strain,‖
106. The Guardian (25 July).

Blaikie, Piers, and Haro ld Brookfield (1987). Land Degradation and Society. Bro wn, Lester (2006). Plan B 2.0: Rescuing a Planet Under Stress and a Civli-
London: Methuen. zation in Trouble. New Yo rk: W.W. Norton.

Bourdieu, Pierre (1990). In Other Words. Stanford: Stanford University Press. Bro wn, Stephen P.A., Raghav Virmani and Richard Alm (2008). ― Crude Awa-
kening: Beh ind the Surge in Oil Prices ,‖ Economic Letter[Federal Reserve Bank
Boyd, William, W. Scott Prudham, & Rachel A. Schurman (2001). ―Industrial of Dallas] 3(5).
Dynamics and the Problem of Nature,‖ Society and Natural Resources 14, 555-
570. Buck, Dan (2007). ―The Ecological Question: Can Capitalis m Prevail?,‖ Va-
riant 28, 22-25.
BP (2009). BP Statistical Review of World Energy. No p lace: BP.
Bunker, Stephen G. (1985). Underdeveloping the Amazon. Urbana: University
Braudel, Fernand (1981). The Structures of Everyday Life: The Limits of the of Illinois Press.
Possible. Sian Reynolds, trans. New Yo rk: Harper & Row.
Bunker, dematerialization thesis
Braudel, Fernand (1982). The Wheels of Co mmerce. Sian Reynolds, trans. New
Yo rk: Harper & Ro w. Bunker, Stephen G., and Paul S. Ciccantell (2005). Globalization and the Race
for Resources. Baltimo re: The Johns Hopkins University Press.
Braun, Bruce, & Noel Castree, eds. (1998). Remaking Reality: Nature at the
Millennium. New York: Routledge. Buntrock, Gerrit (2007). ―Cheap no more,‖ The Economist (Dec. 6).

Burke 2008. Energy regimes in worl d history


Ecology & the Accumulation of Capital, 51

Clark, Brett, and Richard York (2005a). “Carbon Metabolism: Global Cap ital-
Burkett, Paul (1999). Marx and Nature. New Yo rk: St. Mart in‘s Press. ism, Climate Change, and the Biospheric Rift,” Theory and Society 34, 391-428.

Burkett, Paul (2003a). ―Nature and Value Theory: Airing Out the Issues,‖ Clark, Brett, and Richard Yo rk (2005b). MR.
Science & Society 67(4), 452-462.
Clark, Gregory (1991). ―Yields Per Acre in Eng lish Agriculture, 1250-1860:
Burkett, Paul (2003b). ―The Value Problem in Eco logical Econo mics,‖ Organi- Ev idence fro m labour Inputs,‖ Economic History Review 44(3), 445-460.
zation & Environment 16(2), 137-167.
Clausen, Rebecca, and Brett Clark (2005). ―The Metabolic Rift and Marine
Burkett, Paul (2005). ―Entropy in Ecological Econo mics: A Marxist Interven- Ecology: An Analysis of the Ocean Crisis Within Capitalist Production,‖ Or-
tion,‖ Historical Materialism 13(1), 117–152. ganization & Environment 18(4), 422-444.

Business Week (1997). ― The Biotech Century,‖ Business Week , 10 March. Cleaver, Harry M., jr. (1972). ―The Contradictions of the Green Revolution,‖
The American Economic Review 62(1/2), 177-186.
Bukharin, Nikolai (1929 [1915]). Imperialism and World Economy. New York:
International Publishers. Costanza and Patten 1995.

Byres, Terence J. (2005). ―Neo liberalism and Primit ive Accumulation in Less Costanza, Robert, Lisa Grau mlich, W ill Steffen, eds. (2007a). Sustainability or
Developed Countries,‖ in Alfred Saad-Filho and Deborah Johnson, eds., Neoli- collapse? An integrated history and future of people on earth . Cambridge: The
beralism: A Critical Reader. London: Pluto, 83-90. MIT Press

Cameron, Rondo (1993). A Concise Economic History of the World. Oxford: Costanza, Robert, Lisa Grau mlich, Will Steffen, Carole Cru mley, John Dearing,
Oxford Un iversity Press. Kathy Hibbard, Rik Leemans, Charles Red man, and David Schimel (2007b).
―Sustainability or Co llapse: What Can We Learn fro m Integrating the History of
Canizares-Esguerra, Jorge (2004). ―Iberian Science in the Renaissance: Ignored Hu mans and the Rest of Nature?‖ Ambio 36, 7, 522-527.
How Much Longer?‖ Perspectives on Science 12(1), 86-124.
Cronon, William (1983). Changes in the Land. New Yo rk: W.W. Norton.
Catton, William (1982). Overshoot: The Ecological Basis of Revolutionary
Change. Urbana: University of Illinois Press. Cronon, William (1991). Nature’s Metropolis: Chicago and the Great West.
New York: W.W. Norton.
Caulcutt, Clea (2009). ― ‗Superweed‘ exp losion threatens Monsanto heartlands,‖
France 24 (19 April). Crosby, Alfred W., Jr. (1972). The Columbian Exchange: Biological and Cul-
tural Consequences of 1492. Westport, CT: Greenwood Press.
Chakrabortty, Aditya (2008). ―Secret Report: Biofuel Caused Food Crisis,‖ The
Guardian (3 July). Crosby, Alfred W., Jr. (1986). Ecological Imperialism. Cambridge: Camb ridge
University Press.
Chandler, Alfred D., jr. (1977). The Visible Hand: The Managerial Revolution
in American Business. Camb ridge, MA: Harvard Un iversity Press. Danaher, Kev in (1989). ―US food power in the 1990s,‖ Race & Class 30(3).

Clark, Brett, and Richard Yo rk (2008). ―Rifts and Shifts: Getting to the Root of Davis, Devra (2007). The Secret History of the War on Cancer. New York: Ba-
Environmental Crises,‖ Monthly Review 60(6), 13-24. sic Books.
Ecology & the Accumulation of Capital, 52

Davis, Mike (2001). Late Victorian Holocausts: El Nino Famines and the Mak-
ing of the Third World. London: Verso. Foster, John Bellamy (1994). The Vulnerable Planet: A Short Economic History
of the Environment. New York: Monthly Review Press.
Davis, Mike (2005). A Monster at Our Door: The global threat of avian flu.
New York: The New Press. Foster, John Bellamy (1999). ―Marx‘s Theory of Metabolic Rift: Classical
Foundations for Environ mental Sociology.‖ American Journal of Sociology
Day, John W., jr., Charles A. Hall , Alejandro Yáñez-A rancibia , Da- 105, 2, Sept., 366-405.
vid Pimentel, Carles Ibáñez Martí , William J. M itsch (2009). ― Ecology in Times
of Scarcity,‖ BioScience 59(4), 321–331. Foster, John Bellamy (1997). ―Crisis of the Earth …‖

Dickens, Peter (1992). Society and nature: towards a green social theory. Phil- Foster, John Bellamy (2000). ―Capitalis m‘s Environ mental Crisis – Is Technol-
adelphia: Temp le University Press. ogy the Answer?‖ Monthly Review 52(7).

Dowd, Douglass C. (1989). The Waste o f Nations. Boulder, CO: Westview Foster, John Bellamy (2001). ―Env iron mental Po litics: Analyses and Altern a-
Press. tives,‖ Historical Materialism 8, 461-477

Du ménil, Gérard, and Do minique Lévy (2004). ―Neoliberal Inco me Trends: Foster, John Bellamy (2002). ―Eco logy and Capitalism: The Nature of the Con-
Wealth, Class and Ownership in the USA,‖ New Left Review II/ 30, 105-133. tradiction,‖ Monthly Review 54(4).

Dunayevskaya, Raya (1982). Rosa Luxemburg, women's liberation, and Marx's Foster, John Bellamy (2008). ―Peak Oil and Energy Imperialis m,‖ Monthly Re-
philosophy of revolution. Urbana: University of Illinois Press. view 60(3), 12-33.

Dunn, Richard S. (1972). Sugar and Slaves: The Rise of the Planter Class in the Foster, John Bellamy (2009). A Failed System: The World Crisis of Capitalist
English West Indies 1624-1713. New York: W.W. Norton. Globalization and its Impact on Ch ina,‖ Monthly Review 60(10).

Earth Policy Institute (2006). Grain Indicator Data. Washington, D.C.: Earth Foster, John Bellamy, Brett Clark, and Richard York (2008a). Ecology: The
Policy Institute. Moment of Truth. Special Issue of Monthly Review 60(3).

Elvin, Mark (2003). Retreat of the Elephants: An Environmental History of Foster, John Bellamy , Brett Clark, and Richard York (2008b). Beyond Capital-
China. New Haven: Yale University Press. ist Ecology. Special Issue of Monthly Review 60(6).

FAO [Food and Agriculture Organization] (2004). The State of Food and Agri- Foster, John Bellamy (2000). Marx’s Ecology: Materialism and Nature. New
culture 2003-2004. Agricultural Biotechnology: Meeting the Needs of the Poor? Yo rk: Monthly Review Press.
Ro me: Food and Agriculture Organization.
Foster, John Bellamy (2002). Ecology Against Capitalism. New York: Monthly
FAO (2009). FAO Food price index (FFPI). access: Review Press.
http://maps.grida.no/go/graphic/fao-food-price-index-ffp i
Foster, John Bellamy , & Fred Magdoff (1998). ―Lieb ig, Marx, and the Deple-
Fit zgerald, Deborah (2003). Every Farm a Factory. New Haven: Yale Universi- tion of Soil Fertility: Relevance for Today‘s Agriculture,‖ Monthly Review
ty Press. 50(3), 32-45

Foster, John Bellamy (1992). ―The Absolute General Law of Environ mental Foster, John Bellamy , and Fred Magdoff (2009). The Great Financial Crisis:
Degradation Under Capitalis m,‖ Capitalism Nature Socialism 3, 2, June, 77-96. Causes and Consequences. New York: Monthly Rev iew Press.
Ecology & the Accumulation of Capital, 53

Griffin, Keith (1974).The political economy of agrarian change: An essay on


Foster, John Bellamy, & Brett Clark (2004). ―Ecological Imperialism: The the green revolution. London: Macmillan
Curse of Capitalis m,‖ Socialist Register 2004. London: Merlin Press, 186-201.
Gu rian-Sherman, Doug (2009). Failure to Yield: Evaluating the Performance of
Freeman, Richard (2005). ―What Really Ails Europe (and A merica): The Genetically Engineered Crops. Cambridge, MA: Union of Concerned Scientists.
Doubling of the Global Workforce,‖ The Globalist (June 3).
Hall, Charles A.S. and John W. Day, jr. (2009). ―Revisiting the Limits to
Fried mann, Harriet, & Philip D. McMichael (1989). ―Agriculture and the state Growth After Peak Oil,‖ American Scientist 97(May-June), 230-237.
system: the rise and demise of national agricu ltures, 1870 to the present,‖ Soci-
ologia Ruralis 29(2), 93-117. Harman, Chris (2007). ―The Rate of Profit and the World Today,‖ International
Socialism 115.
Fried mann, Harriet (1993). ―The Po lit ical Economy of Food: A Global Crisis,‖
New Left Review I/ 197, 29-57. Harvey, David (1982/1999). The Li mits to Capital. New York: Verso.

Fried mann, Harriet (1994). ―Premature Rigor,‖ Review of International Political Harvey, David (1985). Consciousness and the Urban Experience. Baltimo re:
Economy, 552-561. The Johns Hopkins University Press.

Fried mann, Harriet (2004). ―Food Security as the Basis for Hu man Wellbeing: Harvey, 1991. “Geography,” Dictionary of Marxist Thought.
Putting Livelihoods and Habitats at the Centre of a Post-Neoliberal Agenda,‖
paper presented to the Civil Society Foru m at the UNCTA D meeting, São Pau- Harvey, David (1996). Justice, Nature, and the Geography of Difference. Ox-
lo, 14-16 June. ford: Blackwell.

Fried mann, Harriet (2005a). ―Fro m colonialis m to green capitalism: social Harvey, Dav id (2000). Spaces of Hope. Berkeley: University of Californ ia
movements and emergence of food regimes,‖ Research in Rural Sociology and Press.
Development 11, 227-64.
Harvey, Dav id (2001). Spaces of Capital: Towards a Critical Geography. New
Fried mann, Harriet (2005b). ―Feeding the Empire: Pathologies of Globalized Yo rk: Routledge.
Agriculture,‖ in Leo Panitch and Colin Leys , eds., Socialist Register 2005: The
Empire Reloaded. London: Merlin, 2004. Harvey, David (2003). The New Imperialism. Oxford : Oxford Univ. Press.

Giddens, Anthony (1981). A Contemporary Critique of Historical Materialism. Harvey, David (2005). A Brief History of Neoliberalism. Oxford: Oxfo rd Uni-
Berkeley: University of California Press. versity Press.

Glenna, Leland (2003). ―Farm Crisis or Agricultural System Crisis? Defining Harvey, David (2006). Spaces of global capitalism: towards a theory of uneven
National Problems in a Global Economy,‖ International Journal of Sociology of geographical development. London: Verso.
Agriculture and Food 11, 15-30.
Harvey, David (2009). ―Is This Really the End of Neoliberalis m?,‖ Counter-
Go wdy, John and Ro xana Juliá (2007). ―Technology and petroleum e xhaustion: punch 13-15 March. [counterpunch.org]
Ev idence fro m t wo mega-oilfields,‖ Energy 32(8), 1448-1454.
Heinberg, Richard (2003). The Party’s Over: Peak Oil and the Fate of Industri-
GRA IN (2008). Seized! The 2008 land grab for food and financial security. al Societies. Gabrio la Island, BC: New Society Press.
Barcelona: GRA IN. [http://www.grain.org/go/landgrab]
Ecology & the Accumulation of Capital, 54

Henderson, George (1999). California and the Fictions of Capital. Oxfo rd: Ox- Jaffe, Anne Myers (2004). International Oil Market Outlook: Trends in Saudi
ford Un iv. Press. Arabia Paramount. Houston: The James Baker III Institute for Public Po licy,
Rice Un iversity.
Hobsbawm, Eric J. (1975). The Age of Capital 1848-1875. New York: Meri-
dian. Jaffe, Anne Myers, and Ronald Soligo (2007). The International Oil Compa-
nies. Houston: The James Ba ker III Institute for Public Policy, Rice University.
Hochschild, Arlie Russell (2002). ―The Co mmodity Frontier,‖ Working Paper
No. I. Center for Working Family, Univ. of California, Berkeley. Jevons, William Stanley (1865 [1906]). The Coal Question: An Inquiry Con-
cerning the Progress of the Nation, and the Probable Exhaustion of Our Coal
Hone, Angus (1973). ―The Primary Co mmod ities Boo m,‖ New Left Review 81, Mines. Third ed ition, rev ised. London: Macmillan.
first series, 82-92.
Jevons, William Stanley (2001). ―On the Economy of Fuel,‖ Organization &
Hornborg, Alf (2006). ―Footprints in the Cotton Fields: The Industrial Revolu- Environment 14(1), 99-104.
tion as Time -Space Appropriation and Environmental Load Displacement,‖
Ecological Economics 59(1), 74-81. Johnson, Keith (2009). ―Oil Prices: Demand is Dead, Long Live Demand,‖
wsj.co m, July 27.
Hovis, Logan and Jeremy Mouat (1996). ―Miners, Engineers, and the Transfor-
mat ion of Work in the Western Mining Industry, 1880- 1930,‖ Technology and Jorgenson, Andrew K. (2003). ―Consumption and Environmental Deg radation:
Culture, 37(3), 429-456 A Cross-National Analysis of the Ecological Footprint,‖ Social Problems 50(3),
374-394.
Hoyos, Carola (2009). ―Total says oil output near peak,‖ Financial Times (Feb.
15). Kautsky, Karl (1988 [1898]). The Agrarian Question. 2 vols. Pete Burgess,
trans. London: Zwan.
Hughes, J. Donald (1994). Pan’s Travail: Environmental Problems of the An-
cient Greeks and Romans. Baltimo re: The Johns Hopkins University Press. Kendall, Henry W., and David Pimentel (1994). ―Constraints on the Expansion
of the Global Food Supply,‖ Ambio 23(2), 198-205.
Hughes, J. Donald (2001). An Environmental History of the World. New York:
Routledge. Kenney, Martin, Linda M. Lobao, James Curry, W. Richard Goe (1989). ―Mid-
western Agriculture in US Fordis m: Fro m the New Deal to economic restructur-
Hyams, Edward (1952). Soil and Civilisation. New York: Thames & Hudson. ing,‖ Sociologia Ruralis 29 (2), 131-148.

International Energy Agency (2008). World Energy Outlook 2008. Paris: Ki mmel 1987. Disheveled i mprov.
IEA/OECD.
Kolakowski, Leszek (1978). Main Currents of Marxism (New Yo rk: Oxford
International Energy Agency [IEA] (2009). Oil Market Report (11 February). University Press.
Paris: IEA/OECD.
Kolko, Joyce (1988). Restructuring the World Economy. New Yo rk: Pantheon.
International Monetary Fund (2006). World Economic Outlook 2006.
Kloppenburg, Jack R. jr. (1988). First the Seed: The Political Economy of Plant
International Monetary Fund (2008). World Economic Outlook 2008. Biotechnology 1492-2000. Cambridge: Cambridge Un iversity Press.
Ecology & the Accumulation of Capital, 55

Krausmann, Fridolin, Marina Fischer-Ko walski, Heinz Schanl, and Nina Eisen-
menger (2008). ―The Global Socio metabolic Transition,‖ Journal of Industrial MacLennan, Caro l, and Richard Walker (1980). ―Crisis and Change in U.S.
Ecology 12(5/ 6), 637-656. Agriculture,‖ in Roger Burbach and Patricia Flynn, eds., Agribusiness in the
Americas. New York: Monthly Rev iew Press , 21-40.
Landes, David S. (1969). The Unbound Prometheus: Technological Change and
Industrial Development in Western Euopre from 1750 to the Cambridge: Ca m- Magdoff, Harry (1969). The Age of Imperialism. New Yo rk: Monthly Review
bridge University Press. Press.

Leakey Richard E., and Roger Lewin (1995). The Sixth Extinction: Patterns of Mandel, Ernest (1975). Late Capitalism. London: New Left Books.
Life and the Future of Humankind. New Yo rk: Anchor.
Mann, Susan (1990). Agrarian Capitalism in Theory and Practice. Chapel Hill:
Lefebvre, Henri (1991). The Production of Space. Oxfo rd: Blackwell. Univ. of No rth Carolina Press.

Levins, Richard, and Richard C. Lewontin (1986). The Dialectic Biologist. Marx, Karl (1967). Capital. 3 vols. Frederick Engels, ed. New Yo rk: Interna-
Cambridge, MA: Harvard Un iversity Press. tional Publishers.

Lewontin, Richard C. (2001). ―‖Genes in the Food!,‖ New York Review of Marx, Karl (1971a). Theories of Surplus Value: Volume IV of capital. Three
Books 48(10, June 21). volumes. Moscow: Progress Publishers

Lewontin, R.C. (2000). ―The Maturing of Capitalist Agriculture: The Farmer as Marx, Karl (1971b). Wage-Labor and Capital. New York: International Pub-
Proletarian,‖ in Fred Magdoff, John Bellamy Foster, & Frederick H. Buttel, eds. lishers.
Hungry for Pro fit: The Agribusiness Threat to Farmers, Food, and the Envi-
ronment. New York: Monthly Rev iew Press, 93-106. Marx, Karl (1973). The Grundrisse. Mart in Nicolaus, trans. New York: Vintage.

Li, Minqi (2005). ―The Rise of China and the Demise of the Capitalist World- Marx, Karl (1976a). Capital. Vol. I. Ben Fo wkes, trans. New York: Vintage.
Economy : Exploring Historical Possibilities in the 21st Century,‖ Science &
Society 69(3), 420– 448 Marx, Karl (1976b). ―Results of the Immediate Process of Production.‖ In Capi-
tal, Vo l. I. New Yo rk: Vintage, 949-1084.
Lindsay, R.W., J. Zhang, A. Sch weiger, M. Steele, & H. Stern (2009). ―Arct ic
Sea Ice Retreat in 2007 Follows Thinning Trend,‖Journal of Climate 22, 165- Marx, Karl (1981). Capital. Vo l. III. New York: Penguin.
176.
Masuda, T., and P.D. Go ldsmith (2008). ―World Soybean Production: Area
Liu, Jianguo, et al. (2007) ―Co mplexity of Coupled Hu man and Natural Sys- Harvested, Yield, and Long-Term Projections,‖ working paper, National Soy-
tems,‖ Science 317, 1513-1516. bean Research Laboratory, Un iversity of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign.

Lloyd-Jones, Roger (1990). ―The Long Wave and the British Industrial Mattick, Paul (1969). Marx and Keynes: The Limits o f the Mixed Economy.
Revolution,‖ Journal of Interdisciplinary History 20(4), 581-605. Boston: Extending Horizons Books/Porter Sargent Publisher Boston.

Lu xembu rg, Rosa (1968). The Accumulation of Capital. New York: Monthly McMichael, Ph ilip D. (1998). ―Global food politics.‖ Monthly Review 50 (3),
Review Press. 97-111.

Macalister, Terry (2009). ―Clean energy at a crossroads,‖ The Guardian, 15 McMichael, Philip D. (2004). Development and Social Change: A Global Pers-
February. pective. Thousand Oaks, CA : Sage.
Ecology & the Accumulation of Capital, 56

McMichael, Ph ilip. (2008). ―In the short run are we all dead? A perspective on Moore, Jason W. (2007). Ecology and the Rise of Capitalism. Ph.D. d isserta-
the development climate,‖ paper presented to The Longue Durée and World- tion. Depart ment of Geography, University of California, Berkeley.
Systems Analysis Conference, Binghamton University, 24-25 October. [Available at: http://sites.google.com/site/jasonwmooresite/]

McMichael, Ph ilip (2009a). ―A food regime genealogy,‖ Journal of Peasant Moore, Jason W. (2008). ―Ecological Crises and the Agrarian Question in
Studies (36)1, 139-169. World-Historical Perspective,‖ Monthly Review 60(6), 54-63.

McMichael, Philip. (2009b). ―The World Food Crisis in Historical Perspective,‖ Moore, Jason W. (2010a). ―‗A msterdam is Standing on Norway‘, Part I: The
Monthly Review 61(3). Political Eco logy of Spanish Imperialis m in the Rise of the Capitalist North
Atlantic, 1492-1648,‖ Journal of Agrarian Change 10(1).
McNeill, J.R. (2000). Something New Under the Sun: An Environmental History
of the Twentieth-Century World. New York: W.W. Norton. Moore, Jason W. (2010b). ―‗A msterdam is Standing on Norway‘, Part II: Dutch
Power and the Environmental History of the Cap italist North Atlantic, 1568-
McNeill, J.R. (2008). ― Global Environ mental History in the Age of Fossil Fuels 1800,‖ Journal of Agrarian Change 10(2).
(1800-2007),‖ http://www.cartografareilpresente.org/article254.ht ml.
Morelli, Carlo (2008). ―Behind the world food crisis,‖ International Socialism
Meadows, Donella H., Dennis L. Meadows, Jorgen Randers, and William W. 119.
Behrens III (1972). The Limits to Growth. New York: Signet/Mentor.
Mouawad, Jad (2005). ―A global shortage of tools for the oil industry,‖ Interna-
Mintz, Sidney W. (1985). Sweetness and Power: The Place of Sugar in Modern tional Herald Tribune, October 27.
History. New York: Penguin.
Mouawad, Jad (2008). ―U.S. expert says traditional factors responsible for oil
Monbiot, George (2006). Heat: How to stop the planet burning. London: Allen prices,‖ International Herald Tribune, June 25.
Lane.
Mouawad, Jad (2008). ―Energy majors awash in money but not oil,‖ Interna-
Moore, Barrington, jr. (1966). The Social Origins of Dictatorship and Democ- tional Herald Tribune, August 19.
racy: Lord and Peasant in the Making of the Modern World. Boston: Beacon.
Mouawad, Jad (2008). ―Oil‘s stunning retreat: How long can it last?‖ Interna-
Moore, Jason W. (2000). ―Environmental Crises and the Metabolic Rift in World- tional Herald Tribune, October 28.
Historical Perspective,‖ Organization & Environment 13, 2, 123-158.
Mouawad, Jad (2008). ―Return of trip le-dig it oil prices seen,‖ International He-
Moore, Jason W. (2002). ―The Crisis of Feudalism: An Environmental History,‖ rald Tribune, November 9.
Organization & Environment 15(2002): 296-317.
Mouawad, Jad (2009). ―Uncertainty Clouds Outlook for Oil Sector,‖ New York
Moore, Jason W. (2003a). ―Nature and the Transition fro m Feudalis m to Capi- Times, 19 May.
talis m,‖ Review 23(2), 97-172.
Murgai, Rinku, Mubarik Ali, and Derek Byerlee (2001). ―Productivity Growth
Moore, Jason W. (2003b). ―The Modern World-System as Environ mental Histo- and Sustainability in Post-Green Revolution Agriculture: The Case of the Indian
ry? Ecology and the Rise of Capitalis m,‖ Theory & Society 32, 3, 307-377. and Pakistani Punjabs,‖ World Bank Research Observer 16(2), 199.218.

Moore, Jason W. (2003c). ―Cap italism as World-Eco logy: Braudel and Marx on Nellemann, C., M. MacDevette, T. Manders, B. Eickhour, B. Svihus, A.G.
Environmental History.‖ Organization & Environment 16/4, 431-458. Prins, and B.P. Kaltenborn, eds. (2009). The Environmental Food Crisis: The
Ecology & the Accumulation of Capital, 57

Environment’s Role in Averting Future Food Crises. Oslo: Birke land Trykkeri Perelman, Michael (1996). ―Marx and Resource Scarcity,‖ in Ted Benton, ed.,
AS for the United Nat ions Environ mental Programme. The Greening of Marxism. New York: Gu ilford Press, 64-80.

Niazi, Tarique (2004). ―Rural Poverty and the Green Revolut ion: The Lessons Perkins, John H. (1997) Geopolitics and the green revolution: wheat, genes, and
fro m Pakistan,‖ Journal of Peasant Studies 31(2),242-260. the cold war. Oxford : Oxford Un iversity Press.

O‘Connor, James (1998). Natural Causes: Essays in Ecological Socialism. New Polanyi, Karl (1957). The Great Transformation: The Political and Economic
Yo rk: Guilford Press. Origins of Our Time . Boston: Beacon.

OECD (2008). Rising Agricultural Prices: Causes, Consequences and Res- Pomeranz, Kenneth. 2000. The Great Divergence: China, Europe, and the Mak-
ponses. Paris: OECD. ing of the Modern World Economy. Princeton: Princeton University Press

OECD/FA O (2008). OEC D-FAO Agricultural Outlook 2008-2017. Paris and Ponting, Clive (1991). A Green History of the World. New York: St. Martin‘s
Ro me: OECD and FAO. Press.

O'Rourke, Kev in H. (1997). ―The European Grain Invasion, 1870-1913,‖ The Phillips, Kevin (2008). Bad Money: Reckless Finance, Failed Politics, and the
Journal of Economic History 57(4), 775-801. Global Crisis of American Capitalism. New York: Vintage.

Overton, Mark (1996). Agricultural Revolution in England: The Transformation Pimentel, David, L. E. Hu rd , A. C. Bellotti, M . J. Forster, I. N. Oka, O. D.
of the Agrarian Economy, 1500-1850. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Sholes, and R. J. Whit man (1973). ―Food Production and the Energy Crisis,‖
Science 182 (4111, 2 November), 443-449.
Palaniappan, Meena and Peter H. Gleick (2008). ―Peak Water,‖ in Peter H.
Gleick, ed., The World’s Water 2008-2009. Washington, D.C.: Island Press. Pimentel, Dav id, Sean Williamson, Courtney E. Alexander, Omar Gon zalez-
Pagan, Cait lin Kontak, and Steven E. Mulkey (2008). ―Reducing Energy Inputs
Patel, Raj (2007). Stuffed and Starved: The Hidden Battle for the World Food in the US Food System,‖ Human Ecology 36, 459–471.
System. New York: Melville House Publishing.
Pimentel, Dav id, Alison Marklein, Megan A. Toth, Marissa N. Karpoff, Gillian
Pearce, Fred (2006). When the Rivers Run Dry: Water—The Defining Crisis of S. Paul, Robert McCormack, Joanna Kyriazis, & T. Krueger (2009) ―Food Ver-
the Twenty-First Century, Boston: Beacon Press. sus Biofuels: Environ mental and Economic Costs,‖ Human Ecology 37, 1–12.

Pechlaner, Gabriela, and Gerardo Otero (2008). ―The Third Food Regime: Neo- Podobnik, Bruce (2006). Global energy shifts: Fostering sustainability in a tur-
liberal Globalis m and Agricu ltural Biotechnology in North A merica,‖ Sociolo- bulent age. Philadelphia: Temp le University Press.
gia Ruralis 48 (4), 351 - 371.
Pomeranz, Kenneth. 2000. The Great Divergence: China, Europe, and the Mak-
Peluso, Nancy (1992). Rich Forests, Poor People. Berkeley: University of Cali- ing of the Modern World Economy. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
fornia Press.
Pred, Allan (1995). ―Out of Bounds and Undisciplined: Social Inquiry and the
Perelman, Michael (1977). Farming for Pro fit in a Hungry World: Capital and Current Mo ment of Danger,‖ Social Research 62(4), 1065-1091.
the Crisis in Agriculture. Montclair, NJ: Allanheld, Osmun.
Rajala, Richard A. (1998). Clearcutting the Pacific rain forest: production,
Perelman, Michael (1985). ―Marx, Malthus, and the Organic Co mposition of science, and regulation. Vancouver: University of Brit ish Colu mb ia Press.
Capital,‖ History of Political Economy 17(3), 461-490.
Ecology & the Accumulation of Capital, 58

Redclift, Michael, and Ted Benton, eds. Social theory and the global environ- Shah, Tushaar, Aditi Deb Roy, Asad. Qureshi, and Jin xia Wang (2003). ―Sus-
ment. New Yo rk: Routledge. taining Asia‘s Groundwater Boo m: An Overview of Issues and Evidence,‖ Nat-
ural Resources Forum 27(2), 130–41.
Research Unit on Political Economy (2008). ―India‘s Runaway Gro wth: Disto r-
tion, Disarticulation, and Exclusion,‖ Aspects of India’s Economy 44-46 (special Shaikh, Anwar (2004). ―The Power of Profit,‖ Social Research 71(2).
issue).
Shand, Hope (2003). ―New Enclosures: Why Civ il Society and Go vern ments
Retort (2005). Afflicted Powers: Capital and Spectacle in a New Age of War. Need to Look Beyond Life Patenting,‖ CR: The New Centennial Review 3(2),
London: Verso. 187-204.

Richards, John F. (2003). The Unending Frontier: An Environmental History of Shiva, Vandana (1991). The Violence of the Green Revolution: Third World
the Early Modern World. Berkeley: University of Californ ia Press. Agriculture, Ecology and Politics. London: Zed.

Roberts, Paul Craig (2008). ―Why Oil Prices Are So High,‖ Counterpunch (11 Shiva, Vandana (1997). ―The Enclosure of the Co mmons,‖ Third World Resur-
June). gence 84.

Ross, Eric B. (2000). ―The Malthus Factor: Poverty, Politics and Population in Shoumatoff, Alex (2008). ―The Arct ic Oil Rush,‖ Vanity Fair (May).
Capitalist Development,‖ Briefing 20. Do rset, UK: The CornerHouse.
[www.icaap/cornerhouse] Silver, Beverly J. (2003). Forces of Labour: Workers’ Movements and Globali-
zation Since 1870. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Rostow, W.W. (1938). ―Investment and the Great Depression,‖ The Economic
History Review 8(2), 136-158. Silver, Beverly J., and Eric Slater (1999). ―The Social Orig ins of World Heg e-
monies,‖ in Giovanni Arrighi, Beverly J. Silver, et al., Chaos and Governance
Roubini, Nouriel (2009). ―Green Shoots or Yello w Weeds?,‖ Forbes.com, 14 in the Modern World System. Minneapolis: Univ. o f Minnesota Press.
May.
Simp kins, Jason (2009). ―The ‗Cheap Oil Era‘ is Ending Soon…,‖ Money
Ruddiman, William F. (2003). ―The Anthropogenic Greenhouse Era Began Morning 10 January. [http://www.money morn ing.com/ 2009/01/10/cheap-oil-
Thousands of Yea rs Ago,‖ Climatic Change 61, 261-293. era/]

Ruttan, Vernon W. (2002). ―Productivity Growth in World Agriculture: Sources Slicher van Bath, B.H. (1963). The Agrarian History of Western Europe, 500-
and Constraints‖ Journal of Economic Perspectives 16(4), 161– 184. 1850 A.D. Olive Ordish, trans. New Yo rk: St. Mart in‘s Press.

Saad-Filho, Alfredo and Deborah Johnston, eds. (2005) Neoliberalism: A Criti- Smil, Vaclav (2004). China’s Past, China’s Future: Energy, Food, Environ-
cal Reader. London: Pluto Press. ment. New Yo rk: Routledge.

Scheffer, Marten, Steve Carpenter, Jonathan A. Foley, Carl Fo lke, & Brian Smith, Neil (1984). Uneven Development: Nature, Capital, and the Production
Walker (2001). ―Catastrophic Shifts in Ecosystems,‖ Nature 413 (October 11): of Space. Oxford: Basil Blac kwell.
591-596.
Smith, Neil (2007). ―Nature as Accumulation Strategy,‖ in Leo Panitch and
Schumpeter, J.A. (1942/1954). Capitalism, Socialism, and Democracy. London: Colin Leys, eds., Coming to Terms with Nature: Socialist Register 2007. Lon-
George Allen & Unwin. don: Merlin Press, 16-36.
Ecology & the Accumulation of Capital, 59

Snow, C.P. (1964). The Two Cultures: And a Second Look . Cambridge: Ca m- Tomich, Dale (1990). Slavery in the circuit of sugar. Balt imore: Johns Hopkins
bridge University Press. University Press.

Sonnenfeld, David A. (1992). ―Mexico‘s ‗Green Revolution,‘ 1940 -1980: To- Tucker, Richard P. (2000). Insatiable Appetite: The United States and Ecologi-
wards an Environmental History,‖ Environmental History11(1), 51-65. cal Degradation of the Tropical World. Berkeley: University of Californ ia
Press.
Steinberg , Ted (2004). ―Do wn, Down, Down , No More: Environ mental History
Moves beyond Declension ,‖ Journal of the Early Republic 24(2), 260-266. Van Zanden, J.L. (1991). ―The First Green Revolution: The Gro wth of Produc-
tion and Productivity in European Agriculture, 1870-1914,‖ Economic History
Strauss, Mark (2000). ―When Malthus Meets Mendel: Can Biotechnology End Review 44(2), 215-239.
Hunger?‖ Foreign Policy 119 (Su mmer), 105-112.
Vandore, Emma (2009). ―IEA : Investment cut could mean higher oil,‖ Asso-
Swyngedouw, Eric (1999). ―Modernity and Hybrid ity: Nature, Regeneracionis- ciated Press (22 May).
mo, and the Production of the Spanish Waterscape, 1890-1930,‖ Annals of the
Association of American Geographers 89(3), 443-465. Vlachou, Andriana (2002). ―Nature and Value Theory,‖ Science & Society,
66(2),169-201.
Tanzer, M ichael, and Stephen Zorn (1985). Energy Update: Oil in the Late
Twentieth Century. New Yo rk: Monthly Review Press. Wackernagel, Mathis, and William Rees (1996). Our Ecological Footprint:
Reducing Human Impact on the Earth. Gabrio la Island, BC: New Society Press.
Taylor, Frederick Winslow (1911). The Principles of Scientific Management.
New York: Harper & Brothers. Wackernagel, Mathis, Niels B. Schulz, et al. (2002). ―Tracking the Ecological
Overshoot of the Human Economy,‖ Proceedings of the National Academy of
Taylor, Paul (2009). ―Funds to fuel green energy run dry,‖ Reuters, February 9. Science 99(14), 9266-9271.

The Economist (2009). ―Buying farmland abroad: Outsourcing‘s third wave,‖ Walker, Richard A. (1998). ―The Global Agitator, or Cap italism's Recurrent
The Economist 21 May. Self-Criticis m,‖ Working Paper, Depart ment of Geography, University of Cali-
fornia, Berkeley. [http://geography.berkeley.edu/ProjectsResources/
The Times (2008). ―Oil Crisis is a desperate cry for capital,‖ The Times (Johan- Publications/Global_ Economic_Crisis.ht ml]
nesburg), 23 March.
Walker, Richard A. (2004). The Conquest of Bread: 150 Years of Agribusiness
Thomas, Brin ley (1982). ―Feeding England during the Industrial Revolution: A in California. New York: The New Press.
View fro m the Celtic Fringe,‖ Agricultural History 56(1), 328-342.
Wallerstein, Immanuel (1974). The Modern World-System I: Capitalist Agricul-
Tilman, David, Kenneth G. Cassman, Pamela A. Matson, Rosamond Naylor, ture and the Origins of the European World-Economy in the Sixteenth Century.
and Stephen Polasky (2002). ―Agricultural Sustainabilty and Intensive Produ c- New York: Academic Press.
tion Practices,‖ Nature 418, 671-677.
Wallerstein, Immanuel (2004). ―After Develop ment and Globalizat ion, What?‖
Tilly, Charles (1984). Big structures, large processes, huge comparisons. New Social Forces 83(3), 321-336.
Yo rk: Russell Sage.
Watts, Michael (2001). ―Black Acts.‖ New Left Review 9 (May-June), 125-139.
Tilly, Charles (1990). Coercion, Capital, and European States. Cambridge,
MA: Basil Blackwell. Watts, Michael (2006). ―Empire of Oil: Capitalist Dispossession and the Scramble
for Africa,‖ Monthly Review 58(4), 1-17.
Ecology & the Accumulation of Capital, 60

Young, Robert M. (1985). ―Is Nature a Labour Process?‖ in Les Levidow and
Webb, Walter Prescott (1964). The Great Frontier. Austin: University of Texas Robert M. Young, editors, Science, Technology, and the Labour Process: Marx-
Press. ist Studies, Volu me 2. London: Free Association Books, 206-232.

Weis, Tony (2007). The Global Food Economy. London: Zed.

Weiskell, Timothy (1981). ―Food, Famine and the Frontier Mentality,‖


Worldview 24 (12), 14-16.

Whitney, Milton (1925). Soil and Civilization: A modern concept of the soil and
the historical development of agriculture. New York: D. Van Nostrand Compa-
ny.

Williams, Ray mond (1980). Problems in Materialism and Culture. London:


Verso.

Wolf, Eric R. (1969). Peasant Wars of the Twentieth Century. New Yo rk: Har-
per & Row.

Wolf, Eric R. (1972). ―Ownership and Polit ical Eco logy,‖ Anthropological
Quarterly 45(3), 201-205

Wolf, Eric R. (1982). Europe and the People without History. Berkeley: Univ.
of Californ ia Press.

World B ank (2007). World Development Report 2009: Agriculture for Devel-
opment. Oxford: Oxford University Press for The World Bank.

World Bank (2009). Global Economic Prospects 2009. Washington, D.C: The
World Ban k.

Wright, Angus (1990). The Death of Ramón Gonzalez: The Modern Agricultur-
al Dilemma. Austin: University of Texas Press.

Yong Xue, Yong (2005). ―Treasure Nightsoil as if it were Go ld: Econo mic and
Ecological Links between Urban and Rural Areas in Late Imperial Jian gnan,‖
Late Imperial China 26(1), 41– 71

Yo rk, Richard, Eugene A. Rosa, & Tho mas Dietz (2003). ―Footprints on the
Earth: The Environ mental Consequences of Modernity.‖ American Sociological
Review 68(2), 279-300.

Das könnte Ihnen auch gefallen