Sie sind auf Seite 1von 17

World Development 101 (2018) 37–53

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

World Development
journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/worlddev

State Capacity and Health Outcomes: Comparing Argentina’s and Chile’s


Reduction of Infant and Maternal Mortality, 1960–2013
Daniel Brieba
School of Government of the Universidad Adolfo Ibáñez, Chile

a r t i c l e i n f o s u m m a r y

Article history: There is substantial quantitative evidence linking higher state capacity to better health outcomes, but
Accepted 25 August 2017 scant attention has been paid to the specific mechanisms through which this causal influence operates.
Available online 23 September 2017 The problem is compounded by the considerable diversity of ways in which the influence of the state on
development outcomes has been conceptualized, making it hard for practitioners to extract policy lessons
Key words: from this literature. In this study, I seek to help to address both of these problems through a historical-
state capacity comparative examination of the ways in which state capacity affected infant and maternal mortality
infant mortality
reduction in Argentina and Chile over the last half century. I show that Chile’s greater investment in
maternal mortality
Chile
health-specific state capacities was behind the remarkable historical ‘‘reversal of fortune” between these
Argentina two countries in terms of infant and maternal mortality levels from 1960 to the present, as well as behind
governance Chile’s notorious reduction in the territorial inequality of these outcomes. I show the key difference
between the two countries was the quality, reach, and homogeneity of their respective public health sys-
tems. From a theoretical standpoint, I argue that the notions of bureaucratic quality and infrastructural
power are both necessary and complementary perspectives through which to conceptualize state capacity
and understand its causal influence over health and other desirable developmental outcomes. In turn, this
suggests that a useful way to specify calls for better ‘‘governance” and to achieve better long-run health
performance may be to invest in the public health system’s technical (bureaucratic) autonomy and in its
system-wide planning and coordination capacities.
Ó 2017 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.

1. Introduction demographic, or cultural factors. States, therefore, seem to auton-


omously matter for development.
Despite the growing recognition that achieving desirable devel- Detailed historical or comparative evidence of how their influ-
opmental outcomes depends in part on having good economic and ence unfolds, however, is mostly lacking. This is problematic inas-
political institutions, there remains much discussion as to which much as without attention to mechanisms it is difficult to
institutions matter most for achieving these outcomes and on persuasively make the case that the observed conditional correla-
how, concretely, they matter. In recent years, considerable cross- tions are, in fact, causal relationships. Moreover, this ‘‘statist” field
national quantitative evidence has been produced supporting the still lacks conceptual unity—as the myriad competing explanatory
idea that variations in state capacity (broadly defined) are respon- terms just mentioned show. Both problems are linked, inasmuch as
sible for significant differences in the degrees of achievement of without the careful examination of processes and mechanisms it is
desirable social and developmental outcomes, such as lower pov- hard to further the concept- and theory-building process required
erty (e.g., Henderson, Hulme, Jalilian, & Phillips, 2007); higher to evaluate the different conceptualizations and operationaliza-
long-run economic growth (e.g., Dincecco & Katz, 2016); higher tions of state influence that are available. In short, if we want to
educational achievements (e.g., Rajkumar & Swaroop, 2008), and theorize and explain how states actually affect development out-
better health (e.g., Holmberg & Rothstein, 2011), among others. comes, we need to take a closer look at the processes involved.
Though under varying terminology—such as control of corruption, The aim of this study is to contribute to this task through a com-
quality of government, bureaucratic autonomy, infrastructural parative, historical study of the relationship between state capacity
power, and governance, to name a few—this literature has shown and two specific health outcomes—infant and maternal mortality—
that state capacity impacts outcomes independently of other in Argentina and Chile. This is a particularly fruitful area in which
influences, such as how democratic the regime is or economic, to trace the ways in which state action affects outcomes, because

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.worlddev.2017.08.011
0305-750X/Ó 2017 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.
38 D. Brieba / World Development 101 (2018) 37–53

most infant and maternal deaths outside the developed world are by impartiality in the exercise of political power—that assumes a
avoidable from a medical point of view and are so at a fairly low sufficient underlying mechanism through which states achieve
cost (McGuire, 2006). As Argentina’s first Health Minister famously good outcomes (Fukuyama, 2013; Rothstein & Teorell, 2008). Yet
said, ‘‘Health is a political decision” (Iglesias, 2009). Thus, there are others focus on specific capabilities in the exercise of power—such
few other development outcomes where deliberate and specific as military force, law-enforcement, or tax extraction—but without
public action can have such dramatic and visible effects as it can relating them to a broader notion of a state’s overall policy-
have on infant and maternal mortality. implementation potential and what may affect it, thus making
In turn, the comparison of Argentina and Chile is particularly them less useful for theory-building (see Cingolani, Thomsson, &
instructive because it starkly illuminates the impact that investing Crombrugghe, 2015).
in state capacities in the health sector can make. In a nutshell, I will There are, however, two well-established theoretical traditions
argue that Chile’s greater investment in health-specific state capac- that seek to explain which kinds of states will be more effective
ities1 was a key element behind the remarkable historical ‘‘reversal than others at policy implementation. The first tradition points to
of fortune” (Acemoglu, Johnson, & Robinson, 2002) between these what we may call the quality of the bureaucracy, with quality refer-
two countries in terms of infant and maternal mortality levels from ring to the degree to which it conforms to key aspects of a modern,
1960 to the present. It was also behind Chile’s notorious reduction in rational, rule-based bureaucracy as originally defined by Weber
territorial inequality in mortality rates, an outcome of intrinsic nor- (1922/2013). One concern coming from this approach is with the
mative importance but not usually considered in the empirical state absence of corruption as a necessary feature of a good bureaucracy,
capacity literature. Thus, the evidence provided will allow us to since Weberian bureaucrats do not use their public powers for pri-
observe in some detail the mechanisms through which state capacity vate gain or for the arbitrary benefit of a particular social group
in a specific sector actually translated into better outcomes, and (Evans, 1995; Rothstein & Teorell, 2008). Bureaucracies also need
what this implies for discussions about how best to conceptualize to be highly competent and professional in the fulfillment of their
state capacity as an explanatory variable. In particular, I will argu tasks, and therefore the meritocratic hiring and promotion of
e—firstly—that a major source of differences in state capacity in bureaucrats is seen as crucial for well-performing bureaucracies
health between countries is the development and quality of their (e.g., Geddes, 1996; Rauch & Evans, 2000). High performance also
public health systems; and—secondly—that from a theoretical stand- requires important degrees of technical or bureaucratic autonomy,
point, the notions of bureaucratic quality and infrastructural power (to so that technical rationality (as opposed to short-term political or
be defined in the next section) are both necessary and complemen- electoral considerations) drives the design and implementation of
tary perspectives through which to conceptualize state capacity and policy (Cingolani et al., 2015). In this last sense, autonomy is
understand its causal influence.2 important in a way not foreseen by Weber: instead of complete
The rest of this paper is organized as follows. In the next section, obedience and subordination, high bureaucratic performance actu-
the literature on state capacity and health outcomes is reviewed. In ally requires granting top bureaucrats a degree of freedom in the
the third section, the methodological logic of the comparison of choice of means through which to achieve politically mandated
these two cases is explained. In the fourth, the historical context policy ends (Fukuyama, 2013). Thus, bureaucracies that are clean,
of the comparison is presented and the differences in outcomes meritocratic, and autonomous are expected to increase the state’s
between the two countries are laid out. The fifth and sixth sections capacity to provide public goods.
examine the Chilean and Argentinean cases, respectively, while the A second tradition of state capacity has focused less on the anal-
last two sections discuss the findings and conclude. ysis of state structures per se, and more on the nature of state–so-
ciety relations. The key concept in this tradition is the notion of
2. State capacity and health outcomes infrastructural power, which can be defined as ‘‘the capacity of the
state to actually penetrate civil society and implement its actions
(a) State capacity, bureaucratic quality, and infrastructural power across its territories” (Mann, 2008, p. 355).3 In turn, this largely
depends on the infrastructures of control at the state’s disposal,
Though many terms have been used to denote the degree to understood as all the ‘‘routinized media through which information
which states are able to effectively implement policy decisions, I and commands are transmitted” (Mann, 2008, p. 358). Networks of
will here use state capacity to cover all of these. Given this focus information, transportation, and communication are therefore cru-
on implementation, state capacity is preferable to terms such as cial for the logistics of policy implementation and enforcement.
governance—of wide use in the literature concerned with health More broadly, two related aspects of infrastructural power are
outcomes—inasmuch as this latter term is more imprecise and worth emphasizing here. Firstly, it implies a basic centralization
wider in scope, often bundling together state-related and regime- of political power, in the sense that authority radiates outward from
related issues (e.g., Kaufmann, Kraay, & Mastruzzi, 2011), or else a political center that can coerce populations, extract resources
referring to civil society or transnational actors (Fukuyama, from it and enforce its laws and policies over it.4 Secondly, the ter-
2016). Other terms, such as ‘‘quality of government” are similar ritorial penetration of the state, so as to control all populations, is a
to state capacity in intent, but are defined in a way—in this case, key aspect of the concept. Infrastructural power emphasizes the fun-
damentally spatial nature of political relations, and therefore the pos-
1
Investment in state capacity refers to the allocation of scarce resources (such as
sibility of subnational variation in their shape and depth. As Soifer &
money, time, political capital, and expertise) to the development of the state’s ability vom Hau (2008, p. 222) have pointed out, ‘‘[t]he ability of states to
to implement policy in a given policy area. Thus, though it may include financial carry out their projects is territorially organized and crucially shaped
investments (such as, in the case of health, construction of hospitals, or the hiring of by the organizational networks that they coordinate, control and con-
doctors), it also includes investments in organizational development, logistics,
struct”. Thus, territorial organizational linkages are key: when state
protocols, information sharing, and all kinds of regularized procedures that allow a
state to better implement policy. In particular, organizing (and reorganizing) the organizations at the local level are coopted by powerful local elites,
functioning of a public health system is an investment in this sense. the infrastructural power of the state is diminished (e.g., Soifer, 2015).
2
It should be noted that state capacity is considered a proximate cause of
differential health outcomes, since state capacity itself is partly determined by a
3
series of political, economic, and historical factors (e.g. Besley & Persson, 2011; Soifer, It is to be distinguished from ‘‘despotic” power, which refers to the range of
2015). In other words, this study aims to study the specific ways in which state decisions rulers can take without consulting civil society groups (Mann, 2008, p. 355).
4
capacity affects outcomes, not to ascertain what causes state capacity in the first This is of course compatible with decentralized governance structures, such as
place. federal systems (Ziblatt, 2008).
Table 1
Conceptualizations and operationalizations of the influence of state-centric variables on selected health outcomes

Farag Sajedinejad, Majdzadeh, Muldoon Klomp Rajkumar Baldacci, Lazarova Hallerod Holmberg Dietrich Cingolani Siverson Dawson Ziblatt (2008) McGuire
et al. Vedadhir, Tabatabaei, et al. and De and Clements, (2006) et al. and and et al. (2015) and (2010) (2006)
(2012) and Mohammad (2015) (2011) Haan Swaroop Gupta, and Cui (2013) Rothstein Bernahrd Johnson
(2008) (2008) (2008) (2011). (2016) (2014)
Concept Governance Quality of Government State Bureaucratic Corruption Rule of Infrastructural Institutional
Indicators capacity Autonomy Law Power Quality
Government X (X) (X) X X X
effectiveness
Corruption (X) X (X) X (X) (X) X X X X
Meritocratic/ (X) X X X X
bureaucratic quality

D. Brieba / World Development 101 (2018) 37–53


Bureaucratic autonomy XX
Fiscal (tax) X X
Rule of law/Law and (X) (X) (X) X X X XX X
order
State fragility X
Property rights (X) X
protection
Regulation (X) (X) (X)
Legislator effectiveness (X)
Democratic (X) (X)
Accountability
Political Stability/ (X)
Absence of Violence
Strength of Legal Rights (X)
Index
Selected health Infant Maternal Mortality Infant Indiv Child Child Infant Child Life Infant Child DALY Child Hospital Child
outcomes explained mortality mortality health mortality mortality mortality health expectancy mortality mortality mortality spending mortality
by paper deprivation
Child Maternal Health Child Tuberculosis Infant health
mortality mortality care mortality prevalence clinics
sector
Child Maternal
mortality mortality

Note: The second row names the main state-centric explanatory variable the author(s) identify as a source of better health outcomes. The first column lists the different indicators of that main variable that each paper employs. (X)
means indicators are grouped by the author(s) into a single, combined measure. XX means it is the sole intended indicator for the main explanatory variable (in which case the other Xs are controls or complementary state-centric
explanatory variables included in the study).

39
40 D. Brieba / World Development 101 (2018) 37–53

Both the bureaucratic quality and the infrastructural power per- Talk of ‘‘good governance” or high ‘‘government effectiveness” risks
spectives have significant overlapping implications (e.g., both being largely empty if we cannot pinpoint what it actually means
agree that a corrupt bureaucracy weakens state capacity), but are in concrete settings. This dearth of attention to mechanisms con-
nevertheless distinct. For instance, a society in which bureaucra- trasts with democracy-centered accounts of infant mortality reduc-
cies have fewer roads, communication, or information networks tion, where historical and comparative accounts have provided
at their disposal will have more trouble enforcing policies, inde- much-needed examination of the specific political contexts in which
pendently of the bureaucracies’ quality. Likewise, a high-quality policy decisions and programs were implemented in different coun-
bureaucracy can autonomously influence policy priorities and tries over time, thus illuminating the multiple ways in which that
improve policy design, and they are therefore not mere imple- link may (or not) materialize (McGuire, 2001; Mcguire, 2010).
menters of policies, as the infrastructural power perspective
assumes (Soifer & vom Hau, 2008). 3. Methods and case selection

(b) State capacity and health outcomes: a review To complement the literature just reviewed and improve on our
understanding of the specific ways in which state capacity affects
There is substantial cross-national, quantitative evidence that health outcomes, this study examines the nature of this causal con-
suggests that state capacity affects various health outcomes, such nection. Concretely, it hypothesizes that the quality of the public
as infant mortality (e.g., Farag et al., 2012; Lazarova, 2006); mater- health system is a major link between them. To scrutinize this
nal mortality (e.g., Muldoon et al., 2011); child mortality (e.g., claim, I use a comparative-historical design which combines
Dawson, 2010; Rajkumar & Swaroop, 2008); child health depriva- cross-case comparison and within-case process tracing in order
tion (Halleröd, Rothstein, Daoud, & Nandy, 2013); and disability- to both confirm a hypothesized relationship, and to trace the speci-
adjusted life years (Siverson & Johnson, 2014), among others. fic mechanisms through which that relationship may have oper-
Moreover, as some authors have emphasized (e.g., Dietrich & ated in a particular historical setting.5
Bernhard, 2016; Rothstein, 2015), the evidence for this link seems Though the study of a single case can illuminate the mecha-
to be stronger than for the more-studied influence of democracy on nisms through which a certain cause produces certain effects, there
health outcomes. is considerable payoff from studying two cases simultaneously in
Despite these largely consistent findings, however, the dominant order to increase our confidence that the hypothesized mecha-
picture in the health/state capacity literature is of conceptual and nisms are, in fact, responsible for the observed effects
indicator heterogeneity. As can be seen in Table 1, there is (Rueschemeyer, 2003). In this context, the choice of Argentina
considerable variation in the way the state’s influence on health out- and Chile as the case studies follows a ‘‘most similar systems
comes has been conceptualized, with terms such as ‘‘governance”, design” (Przeworski & Teune, 1970), where the countries are sim-
‘‘quality of government”, ‘‘corruption”, or ‘‘rule of law”, among ilar regarding many causal conditions affecting infant and mater-
others, being ascribed the key explanatory role. Surprisingly, how- nal mortality, but nevertheless differ on the outcome.
ever, these different conceptualizations have sometimes been oper- Indeed, these countries share important historical conditions
ationalized using the same underlying indicators. For instance, as that are expected to influence welfare outcomes such as health.
Table 1 shows, both studies focusing on governance and those For instance, the literature on welfare expansion in Latin America
focusing on the quality of government often rely on the same World classifies Argentina and Chile as part of the ‘‘pioneer” social security
Bank’s Worldwide Governance Indicators (such as government developers in the region (Mesa-Lago, 1978) and, along with Uru-
effectiveness) to measure the influence of the state on outcomes. guay, Costa Rica, and sometimes Brazil, as within the regional group
Conversely, sometimes the same concept is operationalized in quite of most-developed welfare states (e.g., Pribble, 2011; Segura-
different ways: we see that ‘‘governance” can actually mean absence Ubiergo, 2007). In turn, Mahoney (2010) locates both Argentina
of corruption, government effectiveness, bureaucratic quality, or and Chile within the group of Latin American countries that
some ad-hoc combination of disparate indicators (e.g., Klomp & De achieved better educational and health outcomes due to their his-
Haan, 2008). More generally, we can observe substantial divergence torical combination of higher incomes and low initial levels of
in concepts and indicators, along with scant cross-work consistency indigenous populations (which led over time to more inclusive
between the concept of choice and its operationalization, even if social policy). These countries also share relatively low levels of eth-
some individual works do display considerable theoretical aware- nic fragmentation, a condition associated with higher welfare gen-
ness in this regard (e.g., Cingolani et al., 2015; Ziblatt, 2008). erosity (Alesina & Glaeser, 2004; Jensen & Skaaning, 2015). Thus,
While perhaps useful enough for detecting general associations comparing Argentina and Chile is to compare two cases that share
between state capacity and health outcomes, such a state of affairs not only broad similarities as neighboring countries, but specific
is unhelpful for thinking about causal mechanisms or assessing their and well-recognized past and present similarities as welfare leaders
existence. Indeed, these works either do not mention any possible in the Latin American region and comparable economic and socio-
mechanisms through which state capacity affects health outcomes, demographic traits. Just as importantly, as we will see below, in
or else hypothesize surprisingly indirect avenues of influence for almost all standard predictors of lower infant mortality not directly
it—such as through citizens’ willingness to pay more taxes when dependent on the actual performance of the public health sector
there is less corruption (Holmberg & Rothstein, 2011), or through (such as GDP per capita, income inequality, education, and even
higher health market efficiency and civil society strength when the health spending) Argentina and Chile either showed roughly similar
rule of law is high (Dawson, 2010). Even those works that most figures, or else Argentina’s were in fact better6.
coherently focus on the quality and/or autonomy of the bureaucracy
(e.g., Cingolani et al., 2015) do not elaborate on the specific causal 5
Naturally, this approach trades off breadth for depth, meaning its aim is to
processes that translate nationwide bureaucratic quality into better generate a deeper understanding of the mechanisms involved – whose generaliz-
health outcomes. The public health system as such—the main public ability to other cases and periods must then be separately assessed.
6
actor responsible for achieving better health outcomes—is largely There is also an element of the ‘‘least likely case” design (Gerring, 2007),
invisible in these works. At most, corruption in the health sector inasmuch as, given Argentina’s better numbers on many of these indicators, its
performance should actually have been better than Chile’s if state capacity did not
and its mechanisms have been better mapped (Lewis, 2006; Vian, matter. In other words, the fact that Chile performed better in spite of lower income,
2008); but as we saw, corruption does not exhaust the hypothesized lower health spending, and higher inequality than Argentina, makes Chile a
influence of the bureaucracy (or infrastructural power) on outcomes. ‘‘confirmatory” case for the importance of state capacity as an explanatory variable.
D. Brieba / World Development 101 (2018) 37–53 41

(a) (b)

Figure 1. Progress of infant and maternal mortality reduction in Argentina and Chile, 1960–80 (a) and 1980–2013 (b). Note: The right-hand axis reflects maternal mortality
ratios, while the left-hand axis reflects infant mortality rates. The maternal mortality ratio value for Argentina in 1970 is the 1968–1970 average, as reported in Marconi
(1994). Other sources are those reported in Table 2, plus DEIS Argentina (2011), Donoso (2015) and official mortality statistics.

Table 3
Infant Mortality Rate, Maternal Mortality Ratio, and Poverty Rates in Argentina and
Chile, and their provincial/regional coefficient of variation
Table 2
Argentina Chile Difference
Infant and Maternal Mortality in Argentina and Chile: evolution over time, 1960–
2013 Unweighted provincial/regional Infant 11.3 7.6
Mortality Rate 2010–13 (standard (2.3) (0.6)
Period Argentina Chile
deviation)
Infant Mortality Rate in 1960; 2013 1960 62 120
IMR 2010–13 Coefficient of Variation 0.21 0.07 64%*
2013 10.8 7
Unweighted provincial/regional Maternal 50.6 22.5
Yearly rate of decrease 1960–80; 1960–80 3.1% 6.5%
Mortality Ratio 2004–13 (standard (26) (8.3)
1980–2013 1980–2013 3.3% 4.4%
deviation)
IMR Ranking in Latin America in 1960 3 10
MMR 2004–13 Coefficient of Variation 0.51 0.37 29%
1960; 2013 2013 5 2
Maternal Mortality Ratio in 1960 110 275 Unweighted average of provincial/regional 14.4% 22.0%
1960; 2013 2013 32 16 poverty rates (c.2010)
Yearly rate of decrease 1960–80; 1960–80 2.2% 8.0% Poverty Coefficient of Variation 0.38 0.44 15%
1980–2013 1980–2013 2.3% 3.5% *
Note: = significant at 1% (see footnote n.10). N = 15 for Chile and N = 24 for
MMR Ranking in Latin America 2012 5 2
Argentina. Poverty rate for Chile is for 2011; for Argentina it is from the 2010
2012
census. Poverty rates between the two countries are not comparable since they use
Sources: Mazzeo (2014), Jiménez and Romero (2007), Pan American Health different methodologies. Infant mortality is accumulated by region from 2010 to
Organization [PAHO] (2015), Guzmán, Rodríguez, Martínez, Contreras, and 2013 (and the much more infrequent maternal deaths from 2004 to 2013) to obtain
González (2006), Pate, Collado, and Solís (2001), Koch (2013), DEIS Argentina more precise estimates of regional values, since some Chilean regions are thinly
(2014), Chilean National Institute of Statistics (2016), and Burgos (2015). populated. Sources: Argentine Ministry of Economy (2014), DEIS Argentina (2014),
Chilean Ministry of Social Development (2014, p. 25), Chilean National Institute of
Statistics (2016), DEIS Chile (n.d.-a), and DEIS Chile (n.d.-b).

Figure 2. Life expectancy in Argentina, Chile, Latin America & the Caribbean (LAC), and USA, 1960–2013. Data from The World Bank (2016).
42 D. Brieba / World Development 101 (2018) 37–53

Thus controlling by design many factors that could also have and a higher correlation between poverty and poor health out-
explained differences in outcomes, examining the parallel comes at the provincial level.
evolution of each country’s health system provides a strong com- In Table 3 below, I show the current variance of infant and
parative setting in which to trace the specific mechanisms through maternal mortality rates, plus the variance in poverty rates, by
which state capacity variation may have translated into differential Argentinean provinces and Chilean regions. As can be seen, vari-
health outcomes. ance in mortality is lower in Chile—significantly so for infant mor-
tality—while the variance in poverty is similar.10 This suggests that
Chile is not territorially more homogeneous than Argentina in terms
4. Evolution of outcomes: a historical comparison of general socioeconomic disadvantage, and yet its infant and
(probably) maternal mortality outcomes nevertheless are.11
(a) Outcomes Significantly, Chile’s lower inequality in health outcomes was
not always so. In Figure 3, I show the evolution over time of the coef-
(i) Levels ficient of variation of each country’s IMR, by subnational units. I
In both infant and maternal mortality, the half-century show two series for Argentina: a shorter series with data since
(1960–2013) dynamic between Argentina and Chile is one of a 1980 in which the country’s 24 provinces are considered separately,
‘‘reversal of fortune”, whereby Chile went from having much and a longer series in which those same 24 provinces are grouped
higher mortality rates in 1960 to considerably lower ones in into six geographically contiguous macro-regions. Both series are
2013. As can be seen in Figure 1, in 1960 Chile had roughly twice contrasted with data for Chile’s 13 traditional regions.12 We can
Argentina’s infant mortality rate (IMR), with 120 deaths per see that Chile’s territorial inequality in the late ‘60s and early ‘70s
1,000 live births. Its maternal mortality ratio (MMR) of 275 mater- was similar to Argentina’s, but has consistently gone down since then.
nal deaths per 100,000 live births was also very high, and about 2.5 By the 1990s, it was clearly below its neighbor’s, regardless of which
times higher than Argentina’s at the time. By 1980, however, Chile Argentinean series (provincial or macro-regional) is considered.
had caught up with Argentina on both counts, and then leaped Moreover, in Argentina the provincial ranking in IMRs has been
ahead by a considerable relative margin (though of course at quite stable over time, with broadly the same provinces as best and
much-reduced absolute levels; see also Table 2). Indeed, Mcguire bottom performers over the decades. Indeed, the 2010–13 Argen-
(2010, p. 95) reports that Chile had the fifth fastest percent reduc- tinean provincial IMRs still correlated at 0.69 with their own
tion in the world in infant mortality between 1960 and 2005. 1980–84 values (statistically significant at 1%; see Figure 4). In
Relative differences between the two countries peaked around Chile, on the other hand, sustained equalization of regional out-
2002–03, but even in 2013 Argentina’s IMR was more than 50% comes over time meant that by 2010–13 historical regional hierar-
higher than Chile’s, and its MMR was at least twice as high.7,8 In chies had been largely erased.
fact, Chile’s 2013 infant and maternal mortality figures were close Finally, while (as we saw) variation in the territorial distribu-
to those of the much-wealthier United States—a country it had actu- tion of poverty in the two countries is roughly similar, in Argen-
ally surpassed in terms of overall life expectancy9 (see Figure 2). tina—but not in Chile—provincial poverty rates are highly and
significantly correlated with infant mortality rates and with
maternal mortality ratios (see Table 4 and Figures 5 and 6).
(ii) Geographical inequalities and the clustering of disadvantage As can be seen, in Chile all correlations are close to zero, while
Beyond improving overall health levels, reducing health they are consistently high and significant in Argentina. Thus, in
inequalities is an important policy goal in its own right (Marmot, Argentina health-related inequalities are much more driven by
2005). Territorial variation in outcomes is a distinct dimension of general socioeconomic disadvantage than in Chile13. Since poorer
inequality, inasmuch as health care is a public (and private) service provinces are also those with higher infant and maternal mortality,
that is spatially provided to people (Castro-Landman, 2015). In this health and socioeconomic disadvantages cluster together territori-
sense, important differences arise between the two countries, with ally in ways that do not occur in Chile, where not even maternal
Argentina having higher territorial health inequality (as reflected and infant mortality outcomes are correlated.14
in the distribution of infant and maternal mortality outcomes),
higher persistence in the territorial pattern of that inequality, 10
The ‘‘unmet basic needs” poverty measure used here for Argentina, based on 2010
census data, is more appropriate than income poverty measures because estimations
7
Data used in this work relies on official statistics from each country, or on works of the latter in Argentina are based on urban areas only (and which, in any case, show
that in turn are based on those statistics. This official data, based on vital registries, is lower interprovincial variance).
11
generally considered of good quality. For instance, McGuire’s careful analysis (2010, p. The difference between coefficients of variation was tested using both the Feltz
121) concludes that in both countries the data ‘‘are complete and accurate enough to be and Miller (1996) and the Krishnamoorthy and Lee (2014) statistical tests. The latter
used in the depiction of levels and changes of infant mortality during the period from 1960 is particularly useful in small samples. Both are included in the ‘‘cvequality” package
to 200500 . A recent report by the World Health Organization [WHO] and other for R (Marwick & Krishnamoorthy, 2016). Both tests were significant at 1% for the
international organizations (2014, p. 47) concurs on their completeness. Even so, difference between infant mortality rate coefficients of variation, and not significant
there may be some degree of omission of maternal deaths in Argentina. Recent for maternal mortality and poverty coefficients. However, given the very small
international estimates of maternal mortality around the world put Argentina’s MMR number of maternal deaths in many regions, regional/provincial MMRs are measured
at roughly triple Chile’s ratio, instead of merely twice Chile’s ratio if we follow imprecisely. If we take the regional MMRs over the entire 2000–13 period (which
national statistics (WHO, 2014, p. 31; Kassebaum et al., 2014, p. 989). On the whole, allows to register at least 5 total maternal deaths in each region or province), then the
however, using both countries’ official data seems reliable enough for depicting the coefficient of variation drops to 0.32 in Chile and climbs to 0.52 in Argentina, and this
broad historical changes in levels and trends in mortality that are of interest here, and difference is marginally significant (p = 0.09) using the Krishnamoorthy and Lee
is in fact the more conservative strategy given that this paper will argue for the (2014) test.
superior performance of Chile’s health system. It is therefore safe to say that Chile’s 12
Two more regions were created in Chile in the late 20000 s. To maintain
current MMR is no more than half of Argentina’s, if not in fact lower. comparability, I calculated mortality rates as per the old 13 regions even after this
8
The unusually high 2009 value in Argentina’s MMR was officially ascribed to the administrative change.
13
impact of the H1N1 virus (Argentine Ministry of Health, n.d., p. 10). Aside from that As a further check, I correlated poverty and infant mortality rates at the provincial
value, the trend in Argentina’s MMR since the mid-19900 s until about 2010 was level in Chile, thus increasing the number of Chilean subnational units from 15 to 40.
essentially flat. The correlation coefficient decreased from 0.09 to 0.09.
9 14
The U.S. had an IMR of 6 in 2012 and an MMR of 15.3 in 2013. Data for the U.S. are By some accounts, in Chile this lack of association between socioeconomic
from PAHO (2015) for infant mortality and Kassebaum et al. (2014) for maternal disadvantage and the IMR could by 2010 even be observed at the municipal level (the
mortality (the MMR figure here reported discounts late maternal deaths, which are smallest territorial unit), after a sustained descent in correlation between the two
not included in the Chilean or Argentinean figures). variables at this level since 1990 (Castro-Landman, 2015).
D. Brieba / World Development 101 (2018) 37–53 43

Figure 3. Coefficient of Variation of the Infant Mortality Rate in Argentina and Chile, 1950–2013. Note: Values for the Argentinean macro-regional series are single data points
at 10-year intervals from 1950 to 2010. Both other series are composed of yearly data. N = 6 for Argentinean macro-regions (Buenos Aires City, Pampa, Patagonia, Cuyo,
Northeast and Northwest), N = 24 for Argentinean provinces, and N = 13 for Chilean regions. Source: Author’s calculations based on data in: Mazzeo (2014), DEIS Argentina
(2011), DEIS Argentina (2014), De Icaza (1985, p. 17) for Chile 1965–1982, and Chilean National Institute of Statistics (2016) for Chile 1983–2013.

Figure 4. Correlations of Regional/Provincial IMRs over time, Argentina and Chile. Note: the continuous lines represent Argentinean and Chilean regional correlations over
time with a c.1970 baseline of regional IMRs. In Argentina, correlations are at single data points at 10-year intervals with their 1970 values (N = 6). In Chile the baseline is the
1970–74 regional IMRs (N = 13). The dotted lines represent Argentinean and Chilean regional IMR correlations over time with their own respective 1980–84 values (N = 24 in
Argentina and N = 13 in Chile). Sources: see Figure 3.

Table 4
Correlation coefficients between infant mortality rates, maternal mortality ratios, and poverty rates in Argentinean provinces and Chilean regions

Poverty Argentina IMR Argentina Poverty Chile IMR Chile


*
IMR Argentina 0.78 –
MMR Argentina 0.71* 0.80*
IMR Chile 0.09 –
MMR Chile 0.08 0.13

Note: *Significant at 1%. N = 24 for Argentina and N = 15 for Chile. Source: Author’s calculations based on data sources and periods detailed in Table 3.

Taken together, these results strongly suggest a process of (b) Toward an explanation
sustained descent in territorial health inequality in Chile, which
substantially equalized infant and maternal mortality outcomes, Chile therefore achieved a ‘‘reversal of fortune” with its neigh-
and made them largely independent of history and of territorial bor in terms of maternal and infant mortality levels, while also
socioeconomic disadvantage. In contrast, in Argentina the reduc- markedly bringing down territorial inequalities. Moreover, as
tion in territorial inequality has been slight, current inequalities Table 5 below shows, these results were achieved with many
are larger and reflect historical patterns, and infant and maternal ‘‘usual suspects” of cross-national differences in infant and mater-
mortality are strongly correlated with poverty and with each other, nal mortality levels being about equal between both countries, or
thus configuring clear clusters of historically rooted territorial else actually benefiting Argentina—sometimes by significant
disadvantage. margins. For instance, Chile caught up in infant mortality with
44 D. Brieba / World Development 101 (2018) 37–53

Figure 5. Infant mortality rate (a) and maternal mortality ratio (b) against poverty rate in Argentina, by province. Source: author’s calculations, based on data sources detailed
in Table 2.

Figure 6. Infant mortality rate (a) and maternal mortality ratio (b) against poverty rate in Chile, by region. Source: author’s calculations, based on data sources detailed in
Table 2.

Table 5
Non health-sector variables affecting infant and maternal mortality, Argentina and Chile 1960–2010

1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010


GDP per capita ARG 6043 7617 8496 6928 8908 12340
CHI 3687 4429 4957 5520 9339 12525
Gini index of income inequality ARG 36 43 44 50 42
CHI 46 53 55 55 51 (2009)
Pubic health care spending as% of GDP ARG 3.6 3.6 4.3 5.0 4.2
CHI 2.1 2 3.3 3.3
Total Health care spending as% of GDP ARG 7.7 6.4 7.8 9.2 6.6
CHI 5.5 5.5 6.4 7.0
Total Health care spending per capita ARG 587 544 540 820 814
CHI 273 304 598 877
Female secondary enrollment, gross (%) ARG 47 60 73 (1988) 88 94
CHI 48 67 79 87 96
Safe water access (%) ARG 55 67 (1985) 94 96 98
CHI 59 91 (1985) 90 95 98
Urban sanitation (%) ARG 34 93 (1985) 90 93 95
CHI 31 75 (1985) 91 95 99

Notes: GDP per capita is at purchasing power parity, constant 2005 international dollars (RGDPCH variable), from Heston, Summers, and Aten (2012). Gini index is from
Mcguire (2010) until 2000, and from UNU-WIDER. (2015) for 2010. Public and total health care spending data are from Mcguire (2010) for data until 1990, and from the
World Health Organization (2016) thereafter. Total health care spending per capita is GDP per capita (row 1) times total healthcare spending percentage (row 4). Female
secondary enrollment data are from The World Bank (2016). Safe water access and urban sanitation are from Mcguire (2010) until 1980, and from The World Bank (2016)
thereafter.

Argentina by about 1980, at a time when it had less than 60% of Argentina on health (and continues to spend less public money on
Argentina’s income per capita. In other words, Chile’s mortality it). In such a context, some modest and/or temporary differences
catch-up preceded its income catch-up by over 15 years, suggesting in Chile’s favor (as in female secondary schooling and safe water
no straightforward ‘‘wealthier is healthier” (Pritchett & Summers, access) do not seem able to explain such significant differences in
1996) narrative can account for it.15 Chile also suffers from much performance. Thus, if on almost all standard predictors of infant
higher income inequality and, until very recently, spent far less than mortality Argentina performed as well as or better than Chile, one
would have expected the former to outperform the latter, and not
15
In 1960, Argentina had 1.64 times Chile’s GDP per capita and only 51% of its IMR.
the reverse. So how were Chile’s better outcomes achieved? Though
By 1980, Argentina had 1.71 times Chile’s GDP per capita but 106% of its IMR. without doubt many factors affected each country’s performance,
D. Brieba / World Development 101 (2018) 37–53 45

Table 6 By the 1970s, the SNS covered around 70% of the population, par-
Main forms of intervention to reduce infant and maternal mortality, by phase of ticularly the middle class and the poor.16
reduction
The initial organizational efforts of the SNS extended into sev-
Type of mortality eral distinct tasks. Firstly, the SNS secured for itself bureaucratic
Infant Maternal autonomy through an inclusive governing board (Mardones-
Phase Early Sanitation; Safe water; Female education;
Restat & Azevedo, 2006) and, more importantly, through the
Vaccinations; Female education; Family planning; mutual support—across party lines—of the high-level public health
Family planning; Nutrition; Skilled Skilled delivery professionals that were at the core of the project (Jiménez, 2001).
delivery (post-neonatal deaths The SNS leadership was thus a technocratic elite of Rockefeller
predominate)
Foundation-trained doctors unified around a state organization.
Late High-quality prenatal care; High-quality prenatal
Intensive neonatal care (neonatal care; Emergency This autonomy allowed for technical rather than political
deaths predominate) obstetric care decision-making: while the SNS doctors wanted a service with a
strong focus on prevention and the primary level, politicians and
Source: compiled by author based on Koch et al. (2012), Jiménez and Romero (2007),
and Moore, Castillo, Richardson, and Reid (2003). Neonatal deaths are those that the public at large wanted to privilege hospitals and curative med-
occur within 28 days of the infant’s birthdate, and tend to be associated with ical care. According to Jiménez (2001), the founding fathers of the
endogenous causes (such as congenital malformations). Post-neonatal deaths are Service were able to defend this ‘‘uncomprehended” vision against
those that occur after 28 days but before a year since the infant’s birthdate, and adverse political winds; indeed, they accumulated considerable
tend to be associated with exogenous causes (such as infections due to poor
nutritional or sanitary conditions).
power and were often at odds with government authorities who
resented the Service’s autonomy (Labra, 2002).
In second place, the SNS worked toward ensuring an adequate
the explanation, I will argue, lies to a significant degree in the perfor- supply of health professionals for the public health system. Firstly,
mance of the respective public health sector systems. it implemented in 1957 the Rural Practitioners Program, which
To see how this may be so, it is useful to break down the anal- provided financial, scholarship, and civil service career path incen-
ysis of long-term reductions in infant and maternal mortality into tives for recently graduated physicians to work in rural and under-
two phases: an early phase in which major reductions can be served areas for three or more years. This program is to this day the
achieved through an emphasis on primary health care and broad main mechanism through which scarce medical resources are
preventive public health interventions, and a slower, advanced deployed to the remotest areas of the country (Mardones-Restat
phase in which timely access to (often advanced) curative care & Azevedo, 2006). The SNS also developed a cooperation program
becomes more relevant (Jiménez & Romero, 2007, p. 459). Table 6 with universities to increase the supply of doctors and particularly
sums up some of the interventions that are more relevant in each other health professionals. During 1965–70 seven Nurse Schools,
phase. five Midwives’ Schools, and four Nutrition Schools were created
I will argue, then, that a key reason why Chile performed better in various universities throughout the country, with an emphasis
than Argentina is that the Chilean state invested much more heav- on joint education of different health professionals (Mardones-
ily in its health capacities from the mid-20th century onward, Restat & Azevedo, 2006; Szot, 2002).
through the creation and improvement of a public health system In third place, the SNS established regulations to achieve stan-
that had greater reach, homogeneity, and quality. The Chilean dardization and uniformity across the territory. It created a techni-
state’s greater build-up of its delivery capacities in the health sec- cal council that drew up the ‘‘technical norms for application at every
tor made a difference in both the early and late phases of infant and level of the service’s structure”, thus introducing ‘‘a number of
maternal mortality reduction. In the early phase, because it important changes (. . .) in health practices as a consequence of the
allowed better implementation, coordination and coverage of unification of public health services” (Mardones-Restat & Azevedo,
those broad public health interventions relevant for reducing 2006, p. 507). The formulation of standardized medical protocols
mortality. I thus stress the organizational underpinnings of those with national applicability is a regular feature of Chile’s public
interventions. In the later phase, I will argue that state capacity health system to this day.
mattered because the superior organization of its public health This was closely linked with (fourthly) the progressive develop-
system allowed for better delivery of curative care within a system ment of a national network for health care delivery, which fol-
that was more coordinated and efficient. lowed a strict geographical organization of services defined by
Regional Health Zones, each under the charge of a medical Direc-
tor. Within these zones, rural posts, local health centers, and hos-
5. Chile pitals worked in coordination (Goic, 2015). Finally, a strong
emphasis was placed on primary health centers as a key location
The creation in 1952 of the Servicio Nacional de Salud (SNS) or for delivering many of the SNS’ services in an integrated and mutu-
National Health Service marked a watershed in Chile’s health sec- ally reinforcing way (Jiménez, 2001; Goic, 2015).
tor history, since the Service provided the backbone to Chile’s pub- At the beginning, territorial differences in coverage of basic
lic health system as it would develop to this day—major public and medical services were acute: for instance, in 1957–59 the highest
private health sector reforms in the 1980s notwithstanding. The infant mortality health zones had a median of barely 31% of profes-
name was hardly a coincidence: Chilean doctors had been inspired sionally attended deliveries, while the lowest mortality zones
by (and visited) the then recently created UK National Health (such as Santiago) had a median of 92% (Behm et al., 1970). Thus,
Service (Labra, 2002; Molina, 2010). Chile had created a Health the expansion of the health network into the countryside and the
Ministry in 1924 and the state already played a significant role in provision of services to the urban poor were key efforts of the
the provision and coordination of health services before 1952 SNS in the 1960s and 1970s (McGuire, 2001, p. 1684). This physical
(Mardones-Restat & Azevedo, 2006). However, the SNS brought expansion, coupled with systematic and active outreach efforts so
all other public and semi-public health providers under its aegis,
including previously autonomous 16 health services, plus workers’ 16
Technically, and unlike the British NHS, the Chilean SNS was only for those poor
insurance schemes and medical facilities, thus avoiding duplica- and middle-class people formally employed and contributing through their wages; in
tion and instituting from the start a unified and strongly central- practice and informally, however, the uninsured also had access to it (Labra, 2002, p.
ized public health system (Jiménez de la Jara, 2001; Labra, 2002). 1044).
46 D. Brieba / World Development 101 (2018) 37–53

as to reach pregnant women in even the remotest areas of the fertility rate plunged from a very high 4.8 children per woman to
country, allowed Chile to increase the rate of deliveries attended 2.7, while much-wealthier Argentina’s rate (which did not imple-
by trained health staff from 38% in 1954 to 91% in 1980 ment a family planning program) was largely stable during the
(Mardones-Restat, 1962; Mcguire, 2010; World Food Program same period, going from 3.1 to 3.3 (Mcguire, 2010, p. 321). The
[WFP], 2008, p. 59). introduction of this fertility program also coincided with a halving
The network of primary health clinics contributed crucially to of both abortion-related and overall maternal mortality rates dur-
the health of mothers and infants through the delivery of a diverse ing 1965–71, and continued and sustained decreases thereafter
but coordinated and integrated range of services. Indeed, by the (Koch et al., 2012).
1970s the services delivered at the primary level for mothers and In this effort, midwives were from the start in charge of provid-
infants included ‘‘periodic check-ups for women before, during and ing contraceptive and family planning advice to mothers in hospi-
after delivery; children’s check-ups; diagnosis and prevention of sick- tals and local health clinics. Additionally, through their provision of
ness in mothers and infants; vaccinations; health and nutritional edu- prenatal control services, they were crucial for linking poorer Chi-
cation for mothers; programs encouraging breast-feeding, responsible lean women with the health system in a trust-building relationship
parenting and birth-control; and nutritional interventions” (Idiart, (Zárate & González, 2015, pp. 217–219; Zárate & Godoy, 2011, p.
2013, p. 66; see also Goic, 2015). These services were delivered 146). More broadly, the presence of midwives at local clinics has
by interdisciplinary health teams that included doctors, nurses, been historically key for providing high-quality prenatal care to
midwives, nutritionists, social workers, and eventually (since the Chilean women. In fact, a decades-old policy of hiring and relocat-
1990s) physiotherapists. ing midwives across the country meant that by 1992 midwives
The high impact of Chile’s primary health centers was most were ‘‘. . .one of the professional health cadres most closely correlated
clearly seen in the nutritional and health care programs of the with the geographic distribution of the population”, delivering 80% of
SNS. Since 1954, a free powdered milk program in Chilean public all births in that year and carrying out ‘‘. . .over 90% of prenatal,
ambulatory clinics (the Programa Nacional de Alimentación Comple- puerperium care, and family planning and gynecological services”
mentaria, or PNAC) had been available for pregnant mothers and (Ruiz-Rodrigues, Wirtz & Nigenda, 2009, pp. 151–153). This study
children under six. The milk was only part of a more comprehen- argued, moreover, that the combination of the geographical orga-
sive package of services related to mother and infant care, and nization of Chile’s health system, the integrated package of services
was delivered to mothers in return for attending pregnancy or delivered at the primary level and the territorial distribution of
infant check-ups. The program also included nutritional education midwives were three key factors in explaining Chile’s success in
for mothers, delivered by nutritionists and social workers both at maternal mortality reduction.
clinics and in people’s homes, as part of the general outreach effort During the 1990s, besides additional (and highly successful)
of local health centers (WFP, 2008; Idiart, 2013). By the mid-1970s, programs for combating infant mortality at the primary level
a national nutrition surveillance system had also been imple- (see Jiménez & Romero, 2007), progress was also made in the treat-
mented, registering personal and nutritional data of all infants at ment of highly complex neonatal and obstetric conditions, which
primary health center check-ups. This system allowed real-time are dealt with at the hospital level. Neonatal treatment initiatives
monitoring and thus timely action. For instance, in 1983 the mili- included universal access to surgical correction of congenital heart
tary dictatorship reversed its initial decision to cut by 30% the defects; a national surfactant program (to treat respiratory distress
amount of milk given to children when the system detected an syndrome); and a major upgrading of neonatal intensive care units
immediate hike in malnutrition (WFP, 2008, p. 53; Goldsmith- [NICUs] (Jiménez & Romero, 2007). At least one NICU was estab-
Weil, 2017, p. 5617). Because through this system nearly all poor lished in each regional health service, all similar in standards of
children were registered and were thus findable by the SNS, it was care and equipment, and all following the centrally determined
also possible to give targeted additional aid to those with more staffing and training requirements. NICUs were themselves reorga-
advanced malnutrition, including—as a last resource—their intern- nized into three levels of (increasing) complexity, with the reorga-
ment in specialized centers until fully recovered (Foxley & nization occurring simultaneously throughout the country, in line
Raczynski, 1984). The results of these complementary strategies with the ‘‘strong focus on uniform nationwide implementation of
were remarkable: malnutrition in under-6s dropped from 37% to less health policies that characterizes the Chilean health system”
than 3% during 1960–2000, with most of the reduction occurring (González et al., 2006, p. e953). Standardized protocols were devel-
before 1980 (Jiménez & Romero, 2007). oped for referrals from other hospitals to ones with NICUs, as well
Active steps were also taken to combat maternal mortality. The as for treatment of respiratory distress syndrome and of very-low
first major initiative in this regard was the introduction in 1965 of birthweight newborns. The strict regionalization of perinatal ser-
a family planning program. Its main purpose was to reduce the vices also meant that high-risk pregnancies, women with a prena-
amount of illegal and unsafe abortions, which were responsible tal diagnosis of intrauterine growth restriction, and those with
at the time for half of all maternal deaths and which consumed preterm labor were all delivered (by protocol) at the highest com-
(because of emergency treatments to save mothers) half of Chilean plexity regional hospitals, which, being in major urban centers,
hospitals’ total blood supply (Casas, 2004, p. 430). The family plan- actually delivered 68% of all births (González et al., 2006). As a
ning program was so effective that already by 1968 about 10% of result, the neonatal mortality rate fell from an already low 8.3 in
fertile-age women in Chile were using some form of contraception, 1990 to 5.7 in 2000, while maternal mortality plunged from an
and about 20% were doing so by 1972 (Adriazola, 1980). These MMR of 42.5 to 19.3 in the same period. By this century, the distri-
numbers were by far the highest in Latin America, along with Costa bution of maternal deaths had a completely changed profile, with
Rica’s (Rosselot, 1971). Remarkably, during 1965–80 Chile’s total abortion-related cases practically disappearing and a much greater
weight of indirect causes of death (Aedo et al., 2010; Donoso,
17
As Goldsmith-Weil (2017) notes, the military tried again in 1985 to cut back 2015).
heavily on milk spending, but the resistance of program beneficiaries and of Though the rate of descent of infant mortality slowed down
influential doctors close to the regime (who had championed the fight against after the early 2000s, its territorial inequality kept falling. This
malnutrition) made the dictatorship backtrack and allow the program to continue. may have been helped by a major health reform in the mid-
Though by then the largest advances against malnutrition had already been made, the
measure would have probably had deleterious consequences – even if a serious
2000s that sought to deepen citizens’ access to health care—the
rebound in malnutrition might have prompted either the military or the 1990 ‘‘Plan AUGE”—and which innovated by legally guaranteeing timely
democratic government to reinstate the decades-old program. and universal access to a specific, high-priority set of medical
D. Brieba / World Development 101 (2018) 37–53 47

interventions, including some related to pregnant mothers and historical characteristic of health services in Argentina would be
newborns (Donoso, 2005). For instance, after AUGE there was a the confrontation between technical and political rationality
significant improvement in the early (antenatal) detection of (Belmartino, 2005, p. 162).
congenital heart defects in infants, as well as in these infants’ In terms of the primary health level, Argentina’s health system
survival rates (Concha, Pastén, Espinosa, & López, 2008). On the has traditionally suffered from an ‘‘extreme curative bias” (Lloyd-
other hand, further maternal mortality reduction was being Sherlock, 2005, p. 1894) that has prioritized hospitals and complex
challenged by the higher pregnancy risks of increasingly delayed technology over preventive health initiatives (see also Mcguire,
motherhood; indeed, Chile’s percentage of mothers aged 35 or 2010).
more was the highest in South America (Donoso & Carvajal, This weakness in preventive and primary care could be clearly
2012; Ramírez, Nazer, Cifuentes, Águila, & Gutiérrez, 2012). seen in the defective implementation of purportedly core pro-
To deal with this stagnation in the MMR leading specialists in grams, such as the National Mother and Infant Program (PNMI),
the field were recommending, among many specific measures, which was broadly similar to the Chilean PNAC in seeking to pro-
the reinforcement of care in the 5% of deliveries that took place vide integrated care to mothers and infants along with a strong
in remote areas of the country, as well as revision of some medical nutritional component. This program had been credited with a
practices such as overuse of cesarean sections (González et al., sharp reduction in infant mortality in Argentina in the 1940s, but
2013). by the late 1990s it was devoting more than 90% of its budget
solely to milk, as opposed to just 49% in 1965 (Mcguire, 2010,
6. Argentina pp. 129–130). The program had also suffered over the decades
from cutbacks and instability in its budget and in technical
In Argentina the crucial reform period was the first democratic resources (Idiart, 2013, pp. 65–66).
Perón presidency, when Dr. Ramón Carrillo became the country’s To reverse these deficits, in the 1990s a more targeted but
first Minister of Public Health in 1949. Under his leadership plans broadly similar program (PROMIN) was introduced. However,
were drawn up to create a universal insurance system, centralize PNMI was not discontinued, so that tensions arose between the
the administration of the health system and increase its articula- staff of the two programs, which ‘‘were poorly coordinated and com-
tion, increase installed capacity, develop planning capacities for peted for employees and beneficiaries” (Mcguire, 2010, p. 140).
the system as a whole, and develop ambulatory preventive and McGuire also reports high levels of financial instability in both pro-
curative medical attention through local health centers serving grams, unhelpful splits in authority over design, hiring, and actual
specific populations (Mcguire, 2010, p. 131; Perrone & Teixidó, implementation between the national and provincial health min-
2007). This conception was remarkably similar to the (contempo- istries, and lack of outreach efforts and tools with which to target
raneous) Chilean one. However, these plans could not be realized the poorest. As a result, there was both overlap between programs
because the Ministry’s initial success in expanding public hospital and substantial under-coverage, with some people receiving dupli-
coverage ‘‘. . .led to rivalry with the labor unions and the Ministry of cated benefits and some none at all (Idiart, 2013, p. 78). Thus, while
Labor and Welfare, with each side aspiring to establish the dominant PNMI was reaching only 30–35% of its theoretical target, Chile’s
national health-care system” (Lloyd-Sherlock, 2006, p. 357). It soon programs were reaching between 70% and 95% (Mcguire, 2010).
became clear that the labor unions (a key Perón constituency) had Moreover, and unlike the Chilean PNAC, the PNMI lacked an accu-
won. Their victory meant that the principle of a work-related or rate registry of beneficiaries. Monitoring capacity at the national
Bismarckian social health insurance system for the middle classes, central level was weak, meaning that both inter-institutional and
operating in parallel to the public sector, was established. In this inter-provincial coordination deficits were recurrent, and that
context the latter’s funding was scaled back and by the 1990s implementation at the local level was highly heterogeneous and
the quality of its provision had suffered significant deterioration dependent on local conditions (Idiart, 2013, pp. 74–75). Finally,
(Lloyd-Sherlock, 2006). By the end of the 1990s, almost half of neither PNMI nor PROMIN were linked to education programs,
Argentineans, but particularly the poor, relied on the public health and therefore their approach was less integrated. While Chile’s
system for medical coverage (Mcguire, 2010, p. 132). PNAC ‘‘effectively subordinat[ed] milk distribution to primary health
To this split between public and social insurance schemes a ter- care aims”, beneficiaries of the PNMI referred to it as the ‘‘milk
ritorial fragmentation would be added, as in the 1950s and 1960s program” and did not ‘‘even recognize the curative and preventive
the federal government reversed Dr. Carrillo’s centralization poli- health care component, which is purportedly the fundamental pillar
cies and started a ‘‘devolution” program of public hospitals to the and goal” of the program (Idiart, 2013, p. 70). Therefore, as
respective provinces, which in any case have the constitutional Mcguire (2010, p. 141) concludes, it is likely that Chile’s greater
mandate in this policy area (Perrone & Teixidó, 2007). As health success in reducing infant mortality was partly due to the better
provision became a provincial responsibility, federal resources implementation and higher coverage of its nutritional and
injected into the system eventually became marginal and the 24 mother-and-infant public health programs. Thus, despite the
provincial health systems largely autonomous. The Argentinean similar policy content and timing between the Chilean and
health system was thus territorially and organizationally frag- Argentinean programs, their impact differed substantially.
mented, both in terms of provision and insurance, with a veritable More broadly, however, Argentinean primary health care has
mosaic of institutions on all sides curtailing ‘‘. . .the establishment of suffered from several institutional weaknesses. Firstly, since public
a unified, efficient, universal health system” (Pan American Health health care is not a federal responsibility, there is significant vari-
Organization [PAHO] 2010, p. 41). ability in quantity and quality of provision across the system.
Partly because of these processes, ‘‘the federal Ministry of Health Therefore, while in some provinces health infrastructures, systems,
(MOH) [became] a relatively marginal figure in national health policy” and programs have been developed, in others almost the entire
(Lloyd-Sherlock, 2005, p. 1895), with scant capacity to define health budget goes to personnel expenses (Lloyd-Sherlock, 2005,
sanitary priorities, coordinate efforts, or strengthen provincial p. 1896).
capacities (Tobar, 2002). Moreover, and unlike in Chile, there was Secondly, fragmentation and overlap of services between pro-
a split between doctors—trained to cure illness—and the actual vinces and municipalities are frequent, with no clear intergovern-
organization of the health system, which was left to politicians, mental division of responsibilities. For instance, in the year 2005,
local authorities, and medical administrators (De Mucio, Fescina, of the 6433 primary health centers in the country, 54% were oper-
Schwarcz, Garibaldi, & Méndez, 2011, p. 26). Consequently, a ated by provincial authorities and 45% by municipalities (Stolkiner,
48 D. Brieba / World Development 101 (2018) 37–53

Comes, & Garbus, 2011). Moreover, the opening of new primary coexisted with a lack of guidelines and training for their use, high
health centers has not always followed a planning-based logic in infection rates in the services that housed them, irrational organiza-
either geographical or health-need terms (Tobar, Montiel, Falbo, tion of neonatologists’ working conditions, and a pervasive lack of
& Drake, 2006, p. 8). This has led to an overlap of services in some qualified nurses (De Sarasqueta, 2001b). Nursing shortages are
areas and under-coverage in others in a dynamic often related to indeed a problem: while countries such as the UK, Canada, and the
short-term political reasons, such as territorial competition USA have roughly between three and five nurses per doctor, and
between provincial and city authorities to provide services, or Chile roughly one nurse per doctor, Argentina has five doctors per
the need to strengthen clientelistic loyalties in certain areas, as nurse (Bernztein & González, 2011). Thus, deficits in human
Enria and Staffolani (2004) show for the city of Rosario. resources and in the basic quality of health services undermined
Thirdly, the system suffers from lack of coordination between the advantages of having a high density of neonatology specialists
the primary health centers and the hospitals, with modalities of and equipment.
articulation being heterogeneous and depending more on local ini- The analysis of maternal mortality also suggests problems with
tiative than on an established norm (Stolkiner et al., 2011, p. 2812– uneven access to essential medical services amidst wider deficits in
2814). Finally, there is a lack of health planning capacities in the health system organization. The main problem is the existence of
local health centers. These often lack epidemiological and georefer- too many small and mid-sized maternities that do not comply with
enced information systems and, crucially, they function (at least in basic standards of maternal care. In fact, a study found that in
practice) on the basis not of catchment areas but of spontaneous 2010–11 only 44% of all maternities fully complied with the mini-
demand, which means that people are often not registered in a par- mal Ministry of Health conditions for providing adequate maternal
ticular center and information on their health status is not care during deliveries, but there was 11% of compliance in the
recorded (Paganini et al., 2010; Tobar et al., 2006). The centers smallest maternities and 97% compliance in the largest. There
themselves vary widely in their staffing levels and composition, was also wide variation in the territorial organization of materni-
in their capacity for conducting basic diagnoses, and in their avail- ties by province, with an average of 4200 deliveries per maternity
ability of equipment and materials (PROAPS-Remediar, 2007). in the province of Tucumán and of only 89 in La Pampa (Speranza,
Argentinean practitioners and researchers are well aware of the Lomuto, Santa María, Nigri, & Williams, 2011). An excessive num-
health care system’s organizational deficits. For instance, a group ber of maternities translated into a national average of only 600
of physicians pointed out that the main cause of relatively high deliveries per maternity, as opposed to 1000 in Chile. The problem
infant mortality because of acute respiratory infection (ARI) was with smaller maternities is that they usually lack on-duty obstetric
‘‘the poor quality” of health care services for infancy (Speranza, specialists or essential supplies, such as blood for transfusions or
Orazi, Manfredi, & Sarasqueta, 2005, p. 282). They noted, among ambulances. Indeed, a study covering six Argentinean provinces
other failures, a lack of appropriate risk assessment of patients; found that maternal death was nine times likelier in a small hospi-
treatment focused only on dealing with the stated reason for the tal than in larger ones. The study also detected ‘‘lack (. . .) of staff
appointment; lack of medical files for patients (that included treat- proficiency in the management of obstetric emergencies”, as well as
ment, evolution, later check-ups, and past referrals to hospitals); ‘‘delays in referrals and lack of coordination within the health-care
and deficient conditions for the referral of seriously ill cases network response”, and therefore recommended a reorganization
because of poor coordination between primary health centers of the system so as to promote timely referrals (Ramos,
and hospitals. Another study found wide variability among pro- Karolinski, Romero, & Mercer, 2007, pp. 618–619).
vinces in the way they diagnosed and treated ARI cases in primary Nonetheless, in the last decade some promising signs of change
health centers, with chances of being diagnosed bronchiolitis vary- began to occur at both the primary and hospital-based levels. In
ing by up to a factor of four, and with a (mistaken) antibiotics pre- 2005, a new infant and maternal health program—Plan Nacer—
scription being handed out anywhere between 12% and 71% of was introduced in the poorer Northeastern and Northwestern
times in dealing with this condition (Bernztein, Drake, & Elordi, regions of the country, and due to its success was then rolled out
2008). Thus, calls were being made to imitate the successful nationally at the end of 2007. The key innovation of the program
Chilean experience based on a uniform protocol for treatment of is that the federal government delivers funds to provinces accord-
ARI (Speranza et al., 2005). ing to the degree of actual coverage of the target population, while
The hospital-based level of care was also burdened with several provinces pay health centers according to medical services actually
problems. Firstly, public hospitals suffer from substantial manage- performed and sanitary goals (such as high rates of early detection
ment inefficiencies18 (Belmartino, 2005; Cavagnero, 2008), even as of pregnancies or of regular checkups of infants) actually reached.
hospital staffing is a ‘‘key source of patronage” in many provinces This has led to outreach efforts and to the creation of a national
(Lloyd-Sherlock, 2005, p. 1898). Moreover, planning deficits are rife. database with patient information and services delivered. An
For instance, the descent of neonatal infant mortality in Argentina impact evaluation conducted by the World Bank for seven of the
has been due to the same investments in high-technology equip- original provinces to implement the program found that Plan
ment and curative services than in Chile, such as mechanical respi- Nacer had been effective in reducing neonatal mortality (Gertler,
ration equipment, lung surfactant, and a growth in availability of Giovagnoli & Martínez, 2014).
neonatology specialists and NICUs (De Sarasqueta, 2001a; Speranza New investments in capacity were also begun in obstetric and
& Kurlat, 2011). However, lack of territorial planning led to an anar- neonatal interventions. In 2010, a national network of hospitals
chic (and territorially biased) growth in NICUs: while in Chile’s pub- was organized to operate congenital heart malformation in infants,
lic health system there are 28—one per regional health service—for after coverage of this condition was included in Plan Nacer. Cover-
16 million people, in Argentina’s public health system there are age was later also given to other congenital malformations, to
223 for 38 million people, plus a further 250 in private facilities high-risk pregnancies, and to the follow-up of premature new-
(Bernztein & González, 2011, p. 33). Moreover, as a well-known borns. In 2013, a major perinatal information system was imple-
Argentinean neonatologist noted, ‘‘fascination” with new equipment mented, providing real-time information not just on obstetric
and neonatal outcomes but also on a host of specific medical inter-
18
ventions at the hospital level in over 100 of the largest public
For instance, a study estimated that Argentina could have maintained its level of
hospital inpatient services with 27% less beds than it actually had, and that with the
maternities (Karolinski et al., 2013). Most significantly, in 2009
same level of physicians it should have been able to undertake between 20% and 40% the Ministry of Health begun to promote, after an agreement taken
more appointments, depending on the province (Belmartino, 2005, p. 159). with the provinces in the Federal Health Council—which groups
D. Brieba / World Development 101 (2018) 37–53 49

the heads of provincial health authorities and the Federal Ministry democratic pressures. Despite Mcguire’s (2010) contention that it
–, the regionalization of perinatal health services at the provincial is democracy and its pro-poor incentives that lead to greater
level. This would establish, as in Chile, a coordinated network of investments in infant mortality reduction, in these cases state
risk-differentiated maternities in each province. Although the capacity played an independent (and partly self-reinforcing) role.
process has been slow and faced political difficulties—not least Significantly, the key bill which created the Chilean SNS in 1952
the need to close down many maternities –some important by unifying health services was hardly the product of popular
provinces (such as Buenos Aires) had made important headway. pressures: indeed, it was legislatively ‘‘almost contraband” since
Complementary efforts were also being made to move deliveries only doctors cared for it, and it thus ‘‘did not have much support,
to maternities that satisfied minimal obstetric conditions, thus but neither did it finally meet opposition” (Jiménez, 2001, p. 489).
increasing deliveries in ‘‘safe” maternities from 83% in 2010 to These same doctors were then able to defend a health-system
91% in 2014 (Speranza, 2015). design based on primary health centers, rather than on hospital
investment, against popular and politicians’ pressures to the con-
trary. Equivalently, in Argentina it was not during authoritarian
7. Discussion regimes but during the democratic Perón government, and amidst
strong pressure to secure popular support, that Dr. Carrillo’s plans
The preceding analysis has shown that differences in the quality for a universalist, regionalized and pro-poor health system
of public health services between Argentina and Chile were signif- (remarkably similar to the Chilean one) were undone by bureau-
icant and enduring, at both the primary and hospital-based levels cratic division within the government and the power of organized
of care. This happened even though the policy orientation of both labor. So all in all, the greater influence and involvement of techno-
countries regarding mother and infant health was broadly similar cratic elite groups—notably doctors—in the politics of health in
over both phases of mortality reduction: health-and-nutrition pro- Chile, able to operate along technical rather than political lines,
grams for mothers and infants since the mid-20th century and seems to be a strong complementary explanation to democracy
investment in advanced neonatal care since the 1980s–1990s.19 and the dynamics of electoral competition as a source of health
We must therefore look at the underlying organizational character- state capacity.
istics of these countries’ public health systems to understand why A related point can be made regarding the recent literature that
the quality of implementation of substantially the same policies has studied the political causes behind the recent push in Latin
was so different. America toward more universalistic and equitable health care. In
In this vein, three interrelated organizational factors help addition to the intensity of electoral competition, these studies
explain these differences in performance and their endurance over have identified factors such as the role of programmatic parties
time. The first was the considerably greater strength of the primary (Pribble, 2013), leftist governments (Huber & Stephens, 2012),
health center in Chile as a key node between the public health sys- social mobilization from below (Garay, 2016), and techno-
tem and the community, and particularly the poor. The primary political alliances (Ewig, 2016), among others, as shaping the scope
health center was the main organizational locus of the family plan- and nature of these coverage-expanding, pro-equity health
ning, nutritional, pregnancy check-up, and infancy check-up ser- reforms. Important as these factors may be in increasing the cover-
vices. The second factor was the greater planning and age and reducing the segmentation of health insurance (the main
coordination capacities of the Chilean public health system as a focus of this literature20), over the long run health outcomes do
whole, as seen in its geographically defined system of referrals not depend only on such factors. A system could be egalitarian, gen-
between establishments of differing levels of complexity and in erous, and universal in its insurance coverage, and yet have acute
its ability to better match the supply of health-sector human territorial inequities in the quality of doctors, be poorly organized
resources with the public health system’s demand. The third was and coordinated, and spend its money on hospitals (wanted by vot-
the better territorial coverage (avoiding gaps and duplication) ers) rather than on a more effective and cheaper network of primary
and relatively greater standardization of health services across health centers. Thus, explaining outcomes also requires looking at
geographical spaces seen in the Chilean case. how medical services themselves are organized, distributed, coordi-
All three are related to (without being the inevitable conse- nated, and delivered. In the specific case of Argentina and Chile, I
quence of) the regionalization of health services applied in Chile argue that it was precisely these organizational differences in their
since 1952. In turn, regionalization was in Chile a strategic choice respective public health systems—rather than (unclear) differences
implemented by the SNS, the actor without which the entire Chi- in insurance generosity or coverage– that were crucial over the long
lean story in this field cannot be understood. Thus, the creation run, and help explain why lower spending Chile has nevertheless
of the SNS was a critical juncture in Chilean public health history achieved better outcomes. More generally, Chile’s better infant and
that constituted a key investment in state capacity. By unifying maternal mortality performance over many decades cannot easily
organizations, standardizing protocols, centralizing policies and be pinned down to any single period, party coalition, government,
decision-making, monitoring compliance, and sustaining policies or reform beyond the creation of the SNS itself. Thus, state capacity
over time, it allowed for a decided, coherent and persistent drive is a distinct and complementary perspective from which to analyze
for infant and maternal mortality reduction in a way not seen in and explain differences in health outcomes.21
Argentina. This latter country’s experience, on the other hand,
bears out De Sarasqueta’s claim (cited in De Mucio et al., 2011, p.
26) that ‘‘. . .in the origin of mortality and morbidity poor organization 20
A partial exception is Ewig (2016), who develops a multidimensional measure of
is as important as the lack of clinical competence”. equity that includes aspects related to geographical access and actual outcomes, as
It is important to note that these differences in investment in well as of coverage and stratification in benefits.
21
state capacity were not merely the by-product of differing This is not to deny that state capacity itself may be influenced by political factors
such as those mentioned above. Indeed, politicians motivated (for whatever reason)
to deliver better health care to their voters may well choose to invest in improving the
19
The main exception to this similarity in programs was Chile’s family planning public health system as a way to do so – though such reforms may be less visible or
program, which had no counterpart in Argentina. Other interventions, such as popular with voters than those that increase coverage or funding. For the purposes of
investment in safe water and sanitation, or the expansion of secondary female the present argument, the point is simply that, just as with democracy, the influence
schooling, were implemented in both countries in a broadly parallel fashion. of state capacity is not reducible to these other factors, even if it may well be partly
Furthermore, both Plan AUGE in Chile and Plan NACER/SUMAR in Argentina share a shaped by them (since the construction of state capacity is itself a long-run political
focus on early detection and treatment of newborns’ neonatal complications. process).
50 D. Brieba / World Development 101 (2018) 37–53

This leads back to the question of how best to understand and the federal government was powerless to sever the link between
conceptualize state capacity as an explanatory variable for devel- the underlying provincial socioeconomic realities and their health
opmental outcomes. The historical-comparative exercise here outcomes. In this sense, the reactivation of the Federal Health
undertaken suggests that both bureaucratic quality and infrastruc- Council at the end of the 2000s, and its agreement to regionalize
tural power are relevant and complementary perspectives for all provincial health services, bodes well for Argentina’s health
understanding state influence on such outcomes. As we saw, future. It also shows that even under Argentina’s dysfunctional
bureaucracy-centered approaches include concerns with corrup- form of federalism (Ardanaz, Leiras, & Tommasi, 2014) investments
tion, with meritocratic recruitment and with the relative auton- in national health state capacity are possible when the federal gov-
omy of the bureaucracy from high-level politicization. The ernment assumes a sustained leadership role in the coordination
evidence here reviewed suggests that probably in all three aspects and technical guidance of provincial health services.
the Chilean health bureaucracies performed better; indeed, from In sum, while an infrastructural power perspective would
early on the SNS’ technical competence and its planning approach emphasize differences in central authority, enforcement, informa-
to public health issues had made it a ‘‘paradigmatic” model in Latin tion, reach, and coordination, a bureaucratic quality perspective
America (Labra, 2002, p. 1043). Nonetheless, the key long-term his- would emphasize that these features themselves were, in part,
torical difference was surely the top-level bureaucratic autonomy achieved through the creation, on the Chilean side, of a specific
of the Chilean SNS, which allowed it to create and sustain over time bureaucratic body that was politically autonomous and technically
a health system based on technical rather than short-term political oriented.
criteria, as evidenced by regionalization of the Service and its focus
on preventive primary health. This autonomy was, we saw, a speci- 8. Conclusion
fic goal of the doctors that founded and directed the Service in its
first years, and—despite significant changes in the organization of Although there is wide agreement that ‘‘good governance”,
the SNS and the health system at large during the military dictator- ‘‘government effectiveness”, or simply state capacity matter for
ship (1973–90)22—the primacy of technical criteria has been largely achieving desirable health outcomes, the processes and mecha-
maintained over time.23 By contrast, we saw that political and nisms through which this occurs have been mostly unexplored
technical rationality have been at odds in Argentina, with such key empirically. In this work, I have tried to show that the characteris-
elements as the location of health centers and the staffing of hospi- tics and organization of the public health system may be a major
tals being decided on electoral and clientelistic considerations. path through which this influence unfolds. Thus, in spite of having
Bureaucratic autonomy was thus—in line with Cingolani et al.’s much worse initial outcomes, its greater poverty, and historically
(2015) findings—a crucial source of state capacity. much lower public and overall health spending, Chile achieved bet-
In turn, the infrastructural power perspective highlights that, ter infant and maternal mortality results than Argentina—in both
beyond the quality of the bureaucracy as such, implementation absolute levels and in terms of territorial equality—because of the
depends on effective state penetration throughout territories and better overall functioning of its public health system. The main les-
on the logistics of information-gathering, coordination, enforce- son of this study is thus simple enough: having a high-coverage,
ment, and control. In these respects, the difference between Chile well-organized, territorially homogeneous public health system is
and Argentina was considerable. Because Chile—a highly central- a major root of ‘‘government effectiveness” in this area, and the pos-
ized country—managed to unify and integrate all previously exist- session of such a system is (health-specific) state capacity—or at
ing public or semi-public health providers under the SNS’ sole least a major component thereof. In turn, the construction of such
command-and-control structure, public resources could then be a system requires investing in autonomous high-quality bureaucra-
deployed with greater efficiency and as needed to all parts of the cies, on the one hand, and in infrastructural power (to logistically
territory. The mandatory standardization of medical norms and coordinate and enforce policy), on the other. Thus, while public
protocols, the assignment of doctors, midwives, and nurses to health systems are clearly a health-specific manifestation of state
remote geographical areas and the organized expansion of services capacity, the broader point this research suggests is that bureau-
into the countryside and urban shantytowns were a product of this cratic quality and infrastructural power may be useful ways to the-
hierarchical, centralized, and authoritative organizational struc- orize and explain the influence of state capacity on many different
ture. This allowed considerable homogenization of services across social and development outcomes. Certainly, further research
regions and facilitated regionalization, a policy that requires signif- should evaluate the generalizability of this explanatory approach
icant investment in protocols and coordination of services. to other geographical areas, periods, and policy areas.
In Argentina, on the other hand, the combination of federalism Finally, this study suggests three policy lessons, from a state
and the lack of a strong central health authority translated into dis- capacity perspective, for the improvement of health outcomes in
parate and idiosyncratic provincial health systems, without any developing countries. Firstly, Chile’s experience shows that even
kind of unity or countrywide coordination in terms of protocols, countries with high and persistent income inequality can nonethe-
organization of human resources, or joint planning. Unsurprisingly, less reduce other key inequalities for human development, such as
variations in provincial poverty rates translated rather closely into health-related ones, if they invest in the appropriate state capaci-
corresponding variations in infant and maternal mortality risk, as ties to that effect. Secondly, this study emphasizes the importance
of investing in public health systems, in as much as such a system
will be able to better implement and deliver a wider range of speci-
22
The military dictatorship de-concentrated the National Health Service (SNS) into fic health policies, thus improving overall effectiveness and effi-
27 regional health services, thus becoming the National System of Health Services ciency (WHO, 2000). This is true both for countries still going
(SNSS), without a central governing board. The military also transferred primary
through the first (accelerated) phase of infant and maternal mor-
health centers unilaterally to the 341 municipalities, maintaining their geographical
logic but placing them outside the direct control of the national government. tality reduction, where investments in a system of primary health
Nonetheless, the Ministry of Health retained its financial, normative, supervisory, centers may be crucial, and also for countries entering the
evaluative, coordination, and directive roles over the whole system (see Annick, advanced (slower) phase, where the organization and adequate
2002).
23
coordination of curative and high-technology medical services
This was clearly seen in the last major health reform (AUGE), where the selection
of the conditions to be covered by the program followed strict medical criteria related
become more important. And thirdly, it suggests that challenges
to their contribution to the burden of disease and the effectiveness of available of state capacity in health should not be reduced only to issues
treatments, as well as participatory inputs. of controlling corruption in the health sector. Important as that
D. Brieba / World Development 101 (2018) 37–53 51

focus undoubtedly is, it should not obscure the large payoffs that Concha, F., Pastén, N., Espinosa, V., & López, F. (2008). Impacto de la Implementación
del Plan AUGE en la Detección Antenatal de Cardiopatías Congénitas. Revista
may be gained from investing in greater technical autonomy at
Chilena de Obstetricia Y Ginecología, 73(3), 163–172. https://doi.org/10.4067/
the top for key health bureaucracies, as well as in system-wide S0717-75262008000300005.
planning and coordination capacities, so as to effectively ensure Dawson, A. (2010). State capacity and the political economy of child mortality in
all citizens’ right to adequate health care. developing countries revisited: From fiscal sociology towards the rule of law.
International Journal of Comparative Sociology, 51(6), 403–422. https://doi.org/
10.1177/0020715210387522.
Acknowledgments De Icaza, R. (1985). Estimaciones de la Mortalidad Infantil Mediante la Aplicación de
la Técnica Coale-Trussell. ECLAC. Retrieved from http://repositorio.cepal.org/
bitstream/handle/11362/20822/D-11716.00_es.pdf?sequence=1
The author would like to thank Tim Power, Alan Angell, and De Mucio, B., Fescina, R., Schwarcz, A., Garibaldi, M. C., & Méndez, G. (2011).
David Doyle at the University of Oxford, as well as Pedro Zitko Regionalización de la Atención Perinatal. Argentinean Ministry of Health/PAHO.
and three anonymous reviewers, for their valuable comments De Sarasqueta, P. (2001a). ¿Cuál es el modelo? Revista Del Hospital Materno Infantil
Ramón Sardá, 20(2), 50–51.
and suggestions to previous drafts of this paper. All interpretations De Sarasqueta, P. (2001b). Mortalidad neonatal y posneonatal en recién nacidos de
and remaining errors are naturally my own. This research did not peso menor a 2.500 g en la República Argentina (1990–1997). Arch. argent.
receive any specific grant from funding agencies in the public, pediatr, 99(1), 58–61.
DEIS Argentina (2011). Estadísticas Vitales. Información Básica - Año 2010. Argentine
commercial, or not-for-profit sectors, though the author would like Ministry of Health.
to thank the generous contribution of the University of Oxford’s DEIS Argentina (2014). Estadísticas Vitales. Información Básica - Año 2013. Argentine
Clarendon Fund to the completion of his doctoral thesis, on which Ministry of Health.
DEIS Chile (n.d.-a). Defunciones y Mortalidad Materna, según región. Chile
this work is partly based. 2000–2010. Retrieved July 9, 2016, from http://deis.minsal.cl/vitales/
vitales2010/Mortalidad_Materna/Defunciones_Mortalidad_Materna_region_
References 2000_2010.htm.
DEIS Chile (n.d.-b). Indicadores Básicos de Salud. Chile 2010–2014. Retrieved July
31, 2017 from http://www.deis.cl/wp-content/uploads/2017/07/IBS-2010-
Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S., & Robinson, J. (2002). Reversal of Fortune: Geography and
2014.xlsx.
Institutions in the Making of the Modern World Income Distribution. The
Dietrich, S., & Bernhard, M. (2016). State or Regime? The Impact of Institutions on
Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117(4), 1231–1294. https://doi.org/10.1162/
Welfare Outcomes. The European Journal of Development Research, 28(2),
003355302320935025.
252–269. https://doi.org/10.1057/ejdr.2014.70.
Adriazola, G. (1980). Experiencia en planificación familiar y salud pública en Chile.
Dincecco, M., & Katz, G. (2016). State Capacity and Long-run Economic Performance.
Revista Peruana de Ginecología y Obstetricia, 25(2), 15–20.
The Economic Journal, 126(590), 189–218. https://doi.org/10.1111/ecoj.12161.
Aedo, S., Barquín, C., Mazzei, M., Lattus, J., Varas, J., Cano, F., & Rubio, J. (2010).
Donoso, E. (2005). Mortalidad Perinatal en las Américas. Revista Chilena de
Transición epidemiológica de la mortalidad materna. Revista de Obstetricia Y
Obstetricia Y Ginecología, 70(5), 279–280. https://doi.org/10.4067/S0717-
Ginecología Hospital Santiago Oriente Dr. Luis Tisné Brousse, 5(1), 9–16.
75262005000500001.
Alesina, A., & Glaeser, E. L. (2004). Fighting poverty in the US and Europe: a world of
Donoso, E. (2015). Tras el cumplimiento del 5 Objetivo del Milenio: mortalidad
difference. Oxford University Press.
materna en Chile, 2012. Revista Chilena de Obstetricia Y Ginecología, 80(1), 7–11.
Annick, M. (2002). The Chilean Health system: 20 years of reform. Salud Publica de
https://doi.org/10.4067/S0717-75262015000100001.
Mexico, 44(1), 60–68.
Donoso, E., & Carvajal, J. (2012). El cambio del perfil epidemiológico de la
Ardanaz, M., Leiras, M., & Tommasi, M. (2014). The Politics of Federalism in
mortalidad materna en Chile dificultará el cumplimiento del 5 objetivo del
Argentina and its Implications for Governance and Accountability. World
Milenio. Revista Médica de Chile, 140(10), 1253–1262. https://doi.org/10.4067/
Development, 53, 26–45. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.worlddev.2013.01.004.
S0034-98872012001000003.
Argentine Ministry of Economy. (2014). Necesidades Básicas Insatisfechas (NBI).
Enria, G., & Staffolani, C. (2004). Obstáculos sociales y de organización para la
Información censal del año 2010. Retrieved from http://www2.mecon.gov.ar/
planificación estratégica en la Atención Primaria de la Salud (APS). Anuario
hacienda/dinrep/Informes/archivos/NBIAmpliado.pdf.
Fundación Dr. J. R. Villavicencio, XII, 029–034.
Argentine Ministry of Health. (n.d.). Análisis de la Mortalidad Materno Infantil.
Evans, P. B. (1995). Embedded Autonomy. Princeton, N.J: Princeton University Press.
República Argentina 2003-2012. (p. 298). Retrieved from http://www.msal.gob.
Ewig, C. (2016). Reform and Electoral Competition: Convergence Toward Equity in
ar/images/stories/bes/graficos/0000000616cnt-analisis_mortalidad_materno_
Latin American Health Sectors. Comparative Political Studies, 49(2), 184–218.
infantil_argentina-2003-2012.pdf.
https://doi.org/10.1177/0010414015600467.
Baldacci, E., Clements, B., Gupta, S., & Cui, Q. (2008). Social Spending, Human
Farag, M., Nandakumar, A. K., Wallack, S., Hodgkin, D., Gaumer, G., & Erbil, C. (2012).
Capital, and Growth in Developing Countries. World Development, 36(8),
Health expenditures, health outcomes and the role of good governance.
1317–1341. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.worlddev.2007.08.003.
International Journal of Health Care Finance and Economics, 13(1), 33–52.
Behm, H., Marchant, L., Marin, M., Mussiet, D., Ortiz, S., Tapia, R., & Taucher, E.
https://doi.org/10.1007/s10754-012-9120-3.
(1970). Mortalidad infantil en Chile: Tendencias recientes. Cuadernos Médico-
Feltz, C. J., & Miller, G. E. (1996). An asymptotic test for the equality of coefficients of
Sociales, 11(3), 5–13.
variation from k populations. Statistics in Medicine, 15(6), 647–658.
Belmartino, S. (2005). A decade of health care reform in Argentina. Salud Colectiva,
Foxley, A., & Raczynski, D. (1984). Vulnerable groups in recessionary situations: The
1(2), 155–171. https://doi.org/10.1590/S1851-82652005000200003.
case of children and the young in Chile. World Development, 12(3), 223–246.
Bernztein, R., Drake, I., & Elordi, S. (2008). Variability in the management of
https://doi.org/10.1016/0305-750X(84)90061-5.
bronchiolitis in the public first level of attention in Argentina. Archivos
Fukuyama, F. (2013). What Is Governance? Governance, 26(3), 347–368. https://doi.
Argentinos De Pediatría, 106(3), 205–211. https://doi.org/10.1590/S0325-
org/10.1111/gove.12035.
00752008000300004.
Fukuyama, F. (2016). Governance: What Do We Know, and How Do We Know It?
Bernztein, R., & González, G. (2011). Controversias en la planificación estratégica
Annual Review of Political Science, 19(1), 89–105. https://doi.org/10.1146/
para la reducción de la mortalidad materno-infantil y por cáncer cérvico-
annurev-polisci-042214-044240.
uterino en Argentina. Rev. argent. salud publica, 2(9), 30–36.
Garay, C. (2016). Social policy expansion in Latin America. Cambridge University
Besley, T., & Persson, T. (2011). Pillars of prosperity: the political economics of
Press.
development clusters. Princeton University Press.
Geddes, B. (1996). Politician’s Dilemma: Building State Capacity in Latin America.
Burgos, A. (2015). Políticas públicas en América Latina para la reducción de la
Berkeley: University of California Press.
mortalidad materna, 2009–2014. Serie Población y Desarrollo, N 112, ECLAC.
Gerring, J. (2007). Is There a (Viable) Crucial-Case Method? Comparative Political
Casas, L. B. (2004). Women and Reproduction: From Control to Autonomy - The Case
Studies, 40(3), 231–253. https://doi.org/10.1177/0010414006290784.
of Chile. American University Journal of Gender, Social Policy & the Law, 12, 427.
Gertler, P. J., Giovagnoli, P. I., & Martinez, S. (2014). Rewarding provider
Castro-Landman, R. (2015). Indicios de igualdad demográfica en Chile: el caso de la
performance to enable a healthy start to life: evidence from Argentina’s Plan
mortalidad infantil. Papeles de Población, 21(83), 189–201.
Nacer. World Bank Policy Research Working Paper #6884.
Cavagnero, E. (2008). Health sector reforms in Argentina and the performance of the
Goic, A. (2015). El Sistema de Salud de Chile: una tarea pendiente. Revista Médica de
health financing system. Health Policy, 88(1), 88–99. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.
Chile, 143(6), 774–786. https://doi.org/10.4067/S0034-98872015000600011.
healthpol.2008.02.009.
Goldsmith-Weil, J. (2017). Using Critical Junctures to Explain Continuity: The Case
Chilean Ministry of Social Development. (2014). Casen 2013. Situación de la
of State Milk in Neoliberal Chile. Bulletin of Latin American Research, 36(1),
pobreza en Chile. Presentación de la nueva metodología de medición
52–67. https://doi.org/10.1111/blar.12516.
de la pobreza y síntesis de los principales resultados. Retrieved from
González, R., Koch, E., Poblete, J. A., Vera, C., Muñoz, H., Carroli, G., ... Klassen, P. F.
http://observatorio.ministeriodesarrollosocial.gob.cl/documentos/Casen2013_
(2013). Consenso salud materna para Chile en el nuevo milenio. Revista Chilena
Situacion_Pobreza_Chile.pdf.
de Obstetricia Y Ginecología, 78(2), 142–147. http://doi.org/10.4067/S0717-
Chilean National Institute of Statistics. (2016). Estadísticas Vitales. Anuario 2014.
75262013000200013.
Cingolani, L., Thomsson, K., & Crombrugghe, D. D. (2015). Minding Weber More
Gonzalez, R., Merialdi, M., Lincetto, O., Lauer, J., Becerra, C., Castro, R., ... Villar, J.
Than Ever? The Impacts of State Capacity and Bureaucratic Autonomy on
(2006). Reduction in Neonatal Mortality in Chile Between 1990 and 2000.
Development Goals. World Development, 72, 191–207. https://doi.org/10.1016/
Pediatrics, 117(5), e949–e954. http://doi.org/10.1542/peds.2005-2354.
j.worlddev.2015.02.016.
52 D. Brieba / World Development 101 (2018) 37–53

Guzmán, J. M., Rodríguez, J., Martínez, J., Contreras, J. M., & González, D. (2006). The Marwick, B., & Krishnamoorthy, K. (2016). Cvequality: Tests for the Equality of
Demography of Latin America and the Caribbean since 1950. Population Coefficients of Variation from Multiple Groups. R package version (1), 2.
(English Edition, 2002-), 61(5/6), 519–620. Mazzeo, V. (2014). La mortalidad infantil en Argentina. Análisis de sus cambios y de
Halleröd, B., Rothstein, B., Daoud, A., & Nandy, S. (2013). Bad Governance and Poor las diferencias regionales. Población y Desarrollo - Argonautas y caminantes, 10,
Children: A Comparative Analysis of Government Efficiency and Severe Child 9–20. https://doi.org/10.5377/pdac.v10i0.1734.
Deprivation in 68 Low- and Middle-income Countries. World Development, 48, McGuire, J. W. (2001). Social Policy and Mortality Decline in East Asia and Latin
19–31. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.worlddev.2013.03.007. America. World Development, 29(10), 1673–1697. https://doi.org/10.1016/
Henderson, J., Hulme, D., Jalilian, H., & Phillips, R. (2007). Bureaucratic Effects: S0305-750X(01)00062-6.
‘Weberian’ State Agencies and Poverty Reduction. Sociology, 41(3), 515–532. McGuire, J. W. (2006). Basic health care provision and under-5 mortality: A Cross-
https://doi.org/10.1177/0038038507076620. National study of developing Countries. World Development, 34(3), 405–425.
Heston, A., Summers, R., & Aten, B. (2012, November). Penn World Table Version 7.1. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.worlddev.2005.08.004.
Center for International Comparisons of Production, Income and Prices at the Mcguire, J. W. (2010). Wealth, Health, and Democracy in East Asia and Latin America.
University of Pennsylvania. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Holmberg, S., & Rothstein, B. (2011). Dying of corruption. Health Economics, Policy Mesa-Lago, C. (1978). Social Security in Latin America Pressure Groups, Stratification,
and Law, 6(4), 529–547. https://doi.org/10.1017/S174413311000023X. and Inequality. University of Pittsburgh Press.
Huber, E., & Stephens, J. D. (2012). Democracy and the Left. Social policy and inequality Molina, C. A. (2010). Institucionalidad Sanitaria Chilena, 1889–1989. Santiago Chile:
in Latin America. University of Chicago Press. Lom Ediciones.
Idiart, A. (2013). Institutional Capacities and Social Policy Implementation: Moore, D., Castillo, E., Richardson, C., & Reid, R. J. (2003). Determinants of health
Maternal Child Health and Nutrition Programmes in Argentina and Chile status and the influence of primary health care services in Latin America, 1990–
(1930–2000). Revista Ciencias de La Salud, 11(1), 59–82. 98. The International Journal of Health Planning and Management, 18(4), 279–292.
Iglesias, R. (2009). La salud es una decisión política. Revista Argentina de Cardiología, https://doi.org/10.1002/hpm.731.
77(2), 141–142. Muldoon, K. A., Galway, L. P., Nakajima, M., Kanters, S., Hogg, R. S., Bendavid, E., &
Jensen, C., & Skaaning, S. (2015). Democracy, ethnic fractionalisation, and the Mills, E. J. (2011). Health system determinants of infant, child and maternal
politics of social spending: Disentangling a conditional relationship. mortality: A cross-sectional study of UN member countries. Globalization and
International Political Science Review, 36(4), 457–472. https://doi.org/10.1177/ Health, 7, 42. https://doi.org/10.1186/1744-8603-7-42.
0192512113515816. Paganini, J. M., Etchegoyen, G. S., Bo, A., Rubio, A. M., Stival, J. J., Fredeimberg, A., . . .
Jiménez de la Jara, J. (2001). Mística, ciencia y política en la construcción de Zelayeta, A. (2010). Evaluación de sistemas de salud y la estrategia de APS. Rev.
sistemas de salud. La experiencia de Chile. Salud Pública de México, 43(5), 485– argent. salud publica, 1(2), 18–23.
493. Pan American Health Organization. (2010). Health in the Americas, 2007 (Vol. II).
Jiménez, J., & Romero, M. I. (2007). Reducing Infant Mortality In Chile: Success In Pan American Health Organization. (2015). Basic Indicators 2015. Retrieved from
Two Phases. Health Affairs, 26(2), 458–465. https://doi.org/10.1377/hlthaff. http://www.paho.org/hq/index.php?option=com_docman&
26.2.458. task=doc_download&gid=31791&Itemid=270&lang=pt.
Karolinski, A., Mercer, R., Salgado, P., Ocampo, C., Bolzán, A., Nieto, R., . . . González Pate, E., Collado, C., & Solís, J. (2001). Health equity and maternal mortality. In
Prieto, G. (2013). Primer informe nacional de relevamiento epidemiológico SIP- Equity and health: views from the Pan American Sanitary Bureau. Washington,
Gestión: desarrollo e implementación a escala nacional de un sistema de D.C.: Pan American Health Organization. Retrieved from http://citeseerx.ist.psu.
información en salud de la mujer y perinatal en Argentina. PAHO. Retrieved edu/viewdoc/download?doi=10.1.1.409.5912&rep=rep1&type=pdf#page=91.
from http://iris.paho.org/xmlui/handle/123456789/3463 Perrone, N., & Teixidó, L. (2007). Estado y Salud en la Argentina. Revista de La
Kassebaum, N. J., Bertozzi-Villa, A., Coggeshall, M. S., Shackelford, K. A., Steiner, C., Maestría En Salud Pública, 5(10).
Heuton, K. R., ... Lozano, R. (2014). Global, regional, and national levels and Pribble, J. E. (2011). Worlds Apart: Social Policy Regimes in Latin America. Studies
causes of maternal mortality during 1990–2013: a systematic analysis for the in Comparative International Development, 46(2), 191–216. https://doi.org/
Global Burden of Disease Study 2013. The Lancet, 384(9947), 980–1004. 10.1007/s12116-010-9076-6.
http://doi.org/10.1016/S0140-6736(14)60696-6. Pribble, J. E. (2013). Welfare and party politics in Latin America. Cambridge University
Kaufmann, D., Kraay, A., & Mastruzzi, M. (2011). The Worldwide Governance Press.
Indicators: Methodology and Analytical Issues. Hague Journal on the Rule of Law, Pritchett, L., & Summers, L. H. (1996). Wealthier is Healthier. The Journal of Human
3(2), 220–246. https://doi.org/10.1017/S1876404511200046. Resources, 31(4), 841–868. https://doi.org/10.2307/146149.
Klomp, J., & De Haan, J. (2008). Effects of Governance on Health: a Cross-National PROAPS-Remediar (2007). Caracterización de los centros de salud del país Retrieved
Analysis of 101 Countries. Kyklos, 61(4), 599–614. https://doi.org/10.1111/ from http://www.remediar.gov.ar/files/Catastro.pdf.
j.1467-6435.2008.00415.x. Przeworski, A., & Teune, H. (1970). The Logic of Comparative Social Inquiry. New York:
Koch, E. (2013). Impact of Reproductive Laws on Maternal Mortality: The Chilean Wiley-Interscience.
Natural Experiment. The Linacre Quarterly, 80(2), 151–160. https://doi.org/ Rajkumar, A. S., & Swaroop, V. (2008). Public spending and outcomes: Does
10.1179/0024363913Z.00000000022. governance matter? Journal of Development Economics, 86(1), 96–111. https://
Koch, E., Thorp, J., Bravo, M., Gatica, S., Romero, C. X., Aguilera, H., & Ahlers, I. (2012). doi.org/10.1016/j.jdeveco.2007.08.003.
Women’s Education Level, Maternal Health Facilities, Abortion Legislation and Ramírez, C., Nazer, J., Cifuentes, L., Águila, A., & Gutiérrez, R. (2012). Cambios en la
Maternal Deaths: A Natural Experiment in Chile from 1957 to 2007. PLoS ONE, 7 distribución etaria de las madres en Chile y en el Hospital Clínico de la
(5), e36613. https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0036613. Universidad de Chile y su influencia en la morbimortalidad neonatal. Revista
Krishnamoorthy, K., & Lee, M. (2014). Improved tests for the equality of normal Chilena de Obstetricia Y Ginecología, 77(3), 183–189. https://doi.org/10.4067/
coefficients of variation. Computational Statistics, 29(1–2), 215–232. https://doi. S0717-75262012000300003.
org/10.1007/s00180-013-0445-2. Ramos, S., Karolinski, A., Romero, M., & Mercer, R. (2007). A comprehensive
Labra, M. E. (2002). La reinvención neoliberal de la inequidad en Chile: el caso de la assessment of maternal deaths in Argentina: translating multicentre
salud. Cad. saúde pública, 18(4), 1041–1052. collaborative research into action. Bulletin of the World Health Organization, 85
Lazarova, E. A. (2006). Governance in Relation to Infant Mortality Rate: Evidence (8), 615–622. https://doi.org/10.1590/S0042-96862007000800014.
from Around the World. Annals of Public and Cooperative Economics, 77(3), Rauch, J. E., & Evans, P. B. (2000). Bureaucratic structure and bureaucratic
385–394. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-8292.2006.00311.x. performance in less developed countries. Journal of Public Economics, 75(1),
Lewis, M. (2006). Governance and corruption in public health care systems (No. 49–71. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0047-2727(99)00044-4.
Working Paper #78). Center for Global Development. Rosselot, J. (1971). Salud maternoinfantil en Latinoamérica. Boletín de La Oficina
Lloyd-Sherlock, P. (2005). Health sector reform in Argentina: a cautionary tale. Sanitaria Panamaericana, 70(5), 407–421.
Social Science & Medicine, 60(8), 1893–1903. https://doi.org/10.1016/ Rothstein, B. (2015). Guilty as Charged? Human Well-Being and the Unsung
j.socscimed.2004.08.032. Relevance of Political Science. In G. Stoker, J. Pierre, & B. G. Peters (Eds.), The
Lloyd-Sherlock, P. (2006). When Social Health Insurance Goes Wrong: Lessons from Relevance of Political Science. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan.
Argentina and Mexico. Social Policy & Administration, 40(4), 353–368. https:// Rothstein, B., & Teorell, J. (2008). What Is Quality of Government? A Theory of
doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-9515.2006.00494.x. Impartial Government Institutions. Governance, 21(2), 165–190. https://doi.org/
Mahoney, J. (2010). Colonialism and Postcolonial Development. Spanish America in 10.1111/j.1468-0491.2008.00391.x.
Comparative Perspective: Cambridge University Press. Rueschemeyer, D. (2003). Can One or a Few Cases Yield Theoretical Gains? In J.
Mann, M. (2008). Infrastructural Power Revisited. Studies in Comparative Mahoney & D. Rueschemeyer (Eds.), Comparative Historical Analysis in the
International Development, 43(3–4), 355–365. https://doi.org/10.1007/s12116- Social Sciences. Cambridge, U.K.; New York: Cambridge University Press.
008-9027-7. Ruiz-Rodríguez, M., Wirtz, V. J., & Nigenda, G. (2009). Organizational elements of
Marconi, E. (1994). Uso de las estadísticas vitales en programas de prevención de las health service related to a reduction in maternal mortality: The cases of Chile
muertes maternas. Notas de Población, 60, ECLAC. and Colombia. Health Policy, 90(2–3), 149–155. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.
Mardones-Restat, F. (1962). Mortalidad infantil y nivel de vida. Revista Mensaje, 106, healthpol.2008.09.006.
20–23. Sajedinejad, S., Majdzadeh, R., Vedadhir, A., Tabatabaei, M. G., & Mohammad, K.
Mardones-Restat, F., & Azevedo, A. (2006). The essential health reform in Chile: a (2015). Maternal mortality: a cross-sectional study in global health.
reflection on the 1952 process. Salud Pública de México, 48(6), 504–511. https:// Globalization and Health, 11, 4. https://doi.org/10.1186/s12992-015-0087-y.
doi.org/10.1590/S0036-36342006000600009. Segura-Ubiergo, A. (2007). The political economy of the welfare state in Latin America:
Marmot, M. (2005). Social determinants of health inequalities. The Lancet, 365 globalization, democracy, and development. Cambridge University Press.
(9464), 1099–1104. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0140-6736(05)71146-6.
D. Brieba / World Development 101 (2018) 37–53 53

Siverson, R. M., & Johnson, R. A. I. (2014). Politics and Parasites: The Contribution of Tobar, F., Montiel, L., Falbo, R., & Drake, I. (2006). La Red Pública de Atención
Corruption to Human Misery. International Studies Quarterly, 58(1), 199–206. Primaria de Salud en Argentina. Diagnósticos y desafíos. Buenos Aires. Retrieved
https://doi.org/10.1111/isqu.12052. from http://www.federicotobar.com.ar/nf_pdf5/La_Red_Publica.pdf
Soifer, H. D. (2015). State Building in Latin America. New York, NY: Cambridge UNU-WIDER. (2015, September). World Income Inequality Database (WIID3c).
University Press. Retrieved from https://www.wider.unu.edu/project/wiid-world-income-inequality-
Soifer, H., & Hau, M. vom (2008). Unpacking the Strength of the State: The Utility of database.
State Infrastructural Power. Studies in Comparative International Development, 43 Vian, T. (2008). Review of corruption in the health sector: theory, methods and
(3–4), 219–230. https://doi.org/10.1007/s12116-008-9030-z. interventions. Health Policy and Planning, 23(2), 83–94. https://doi.org/10.1093/
Speranza, A. M. (2015). Estrategia para la disminución de la morbimortalidad heapol/czm048.
maternoinfantil: Regionalización perinatal. Presented at the 37th Argentinean Weber, M. (1922/2013). Economy and Society. (G. Roth & C. Wittich, Eds.) (Reprint
Congress of Pediatrics. Retrieved from http://www.sap.org.ar/docs/congresos_ edition). University of California Press.
2015/37%20CONARPE/speranza.regionalizacionperinatal.pdf. World Food Program (2008). Hacia la erradicación de la desnutrición infantil en
Speranza, A. M., & Kurlat, I. (2011). Regionalización del cuidado perinatal: una América Latina y el Caribe Retrieved from http://bvssan.incap.int/local/File/
estrategia para disminuir la mortalidad infantil y la mortalidad materna. Rev. PubNut-Per%C3%BA/texcom/nutricion/LOW/LOW.html.
argent. salud publica, 2(7), 40–42. World Health Organization (2000). The world health report 2000 - Health systems:
Speranza, A. M., Lomuto, C., Santa María, C., Nigri, C., & Williams, G. (2011). improving performance. WHO. Retrieved from: http://www.who.int/whr/2000/en/.
Evaluación de Maternidades Públicas Argentinas, 2010–2011. Revista Argentina World Health Organization. (2016, July). Global Health Expenditure Database - NHA
Salud Pública, 2(9), 43–47. indicators. Retrieved from http://apps.who.int/nha/database
Speranza, A. M., Orazi, V., Manfredi, L., & Sarasqueta, P. de (2005). Programa World Health Organization, UNICEF, United Nations Population Fund, World Bank,
Nacional de Infecciones Respiratorias Agudas Bajas. Hospitalización abreviada: & United Nations Population Division (2014). Trends in maternal mortality: 1990
Un modelo de atención basado en evidencias altamente efectivo para descender to 2013: estimates by WHO, UNICEF, UNFPA, The World Bank and the United
la mortalidad infantil. Arch. argent. pediatr, 103(3), 282–287. Nations Population Division. World Health Organization.
Stolkiner, A., Comes, Y., & Garbus, P. (2011). Scope and potential of Primary Zárate, M. S., & Godoy, L. (2011). Madres y niños en las políticas del Servicio
Healthcare in Argentina. Ciência & Saúde Coletiva, 16(6), 2807–2816. https://doi. Nacional de Salud de Chile (1952–1964). Hist. ciênc. saúde-Manguinhos, 18
org/10.1590/S1413-81232011000600019. (Suppl. 1), 131–151.
Szot, J. (2002). Reseña de la salud pública materno-infantil chilena durante los Zárate, M. S., & González, M. (2015). Planificación familiar en la Guerra Fría chilena:
últimos 40 años: 1960–2000. Revista Chilena de Obstetricia Y Ginecología, 67(2), política sanitaria y cooperación internacional, 1960–1973. Historia Crítica, 55,
129–135. https://doi.org/10.4067/S0717-75262002000200009. 207–230. https://doi.org/10.7440/histcrit55.2015.09.
The World Bank. (2016, June). World Development Indicators. Retrieved from Ziblatt, D. (2008). Why Some Cities Provide More Public Goods than Others: A
http://data.worldbank.org/products/wdi Subnational Comparison of the Provision of Public Goods in German Cities in
Tobar, F. (2002). How do we heal the Argentine health care system? Revista 1912. Studies in Comparative International Development, 43(3–4), 273–289.
Panamericana de Salud Pública, 11(4), 277–282. https://doi.org/10.1590/S1020- https://doi.org/10.1007/s12116-008-9031-y.
49892002000400018.

Das könnte Ihnen auch gefallen