Sie sind auf Seite 1von 176

High Speed Rail

London to the West Midlands and Beyond


HS2 Demand Model Analysis

February 2010
While High Speed Two (HS2) Limited has made every effort to ensure the information in this document is accurate, HS2 Ltd does
not guarantee the accuracy, completeness or usefulness of the information contained in this document and it cannot accept
liability for any loss or damages of any kind resulting from reliance on the information or guidance this document contains.

© Copyright, High Speed Two (HS2) Limited, 2009.

Copyright in the typographical arrangements rests with HS2 Limited.

This publication, excluding logos, may be reproduced free of charge in any format or medium for non-commercial research,
private study or for internal circulation within an organisation. This is subject to it being reproduced accurately and not used in
a misleading context. The title must be acknowledged as copyright and the title of the publication specified.

For any other use of this material please contact HS2 Limited on 020 7944 4908, or by email at HS2Enquiries@hs2.gsi.gov.uk,
or by writing to HS2, 3rd Floor, 55 Victoria Street, London, SW1H 0EU.

Further copies of this report can be obtained from www.hs2.org.uk.

ISBN: 978-1-84864-075-7

Unless specified, all maps, tables, diagrams and graphs in this report are a product of HS2 and its consultants.
HS2 Demand Model Analysis: Contents

Contents
Chapter 1: Introduction and Background Data........................................................................................... 5
1.1 Introduction to this report..................................................................................................6
1.2 Acknowledgements............................................................................................................6
1.3 The Demand for Transport and Context for HS2................................................................7
1.4 Demand and Appraisal – Helping with Scheme Design...................................................13
Chapter 2: Demand Model Structure and Development.......................................................................... 17
2.1 Introduction.......................................................................................................................18
2.2 PLANET Long Distance.....................................................................................................19
2.3 PLANET South and Midlands............................................................................................22
2.4 Heathrow Access Model...................................................................................................23
2.5 International Rail Model...................................................................................................24
2.6 Additional Modelling Evidence.........................................................................................25
Chapter 3: Our Assumptions and Approach............................................................................................. 26
3.1 Introduction.......................................................................................................................27
3.2 Demand Growth Assumptions..........................................................................................27
3.3 Passenger Preferences and the Treatment of HSR in the Demand Model.....................30
3.4 Measuring Reliability Impacts of HSR..............................................................................32
3.5 Premium Fares Model......................................................................................................34
3.6 Applying the HS2 Service Specification............................................................................36
3.7 Economic Appraisal..........................................................................................................37
Chapter 4: Central London Station Location............................................................................................ 39
4.1 Introduction.......................................................................................................................40
4.2 Choosing a London Station Location................................................................................40
4.3 Analysis of Euston.............................................................................................................43
Chapter 5: London Interchange Station Location.................................................................................... 46
5.1 Introduction.......................................................................................................................47
5.2 Options for a London Interchange Station.......................................................................47
5.3 The Potential Markets for a London Interchange Station................................................49
5.4 Comparison of Heathrow and Old Oak Common Interchange Stations..........................55
Chapter 6 - Intermediate Station Location.................................................................................................. 60
6.1 Introduction.......................................................................................................................61
6.2 Determining a Location....................................................................................................61
Chapter 7 - Central Birmingham Station Location........................................................................................ 66
7.1 Introduction.......................................................................................................................67
7.2 The Impact of HS2.............................................................................................................67
Chapter 8 - Birmingham Interchange Station Location................................................................................. 69
8.1 Introduction.......................................................................................................................70
8.2 Option Sifting....................................................................................................................70
8.3 An Interchange near Birmingham International..............................................................72
8.4 Demand and Benefits of Birmingham Interchange.........................................................73

3
HS2 Demand Model Analysis

Chapter 9 - Connections to High Speed One.................................................................................................. 77


9.1 Introduction.......................................................................................................................78
9.2 Our Approach to Modelling International Demand..........................................................78
9.3 Analysis of Different International Connections and Services.........................................81
9.4 Appraisal of Journey Time Benefits.................................................................................85
9.5 International Connections as Part of a Wider Network...................................................87
Chapter 10 - The Overall Business Case for HS2.......................................................................................... 89
10.1 Introduction.......................................................................................................................90
10.2 Passenger Demand for HS2.............................................................................................90
10.3 HS2 Appraisal Costs.........................................................................................................95
10.4 Appraisal of Benefits from HS2........................................................................................99
10.5 Wider Economic Impacts of HS2.................................................................................... 102
10.6 Impact of HS2 on Carbon Emissions.............................................................................. 108
10.7 HS2 Value for Money....................................................................................................... 111
Chapter 11 - A Long Term Strategy for High Speed Rail..............................................................................114
11.1 Introduction..................................................................................................................... 115
11.2 Long Distance travel in Great Britain............................................................................. 116
11.3 Long Term High Speed Networks.................................................................................. 118
11.4 Wider Networks - Modelling Approach.......................................................................... 122
11.5 Demand and Benefits of a Long Term Strategy............................................................. 124
11.6 Benefit Cost Ratios of a Wider Network......................................................................... 129
11.7 Limitations of Our Analysis and Further Work............................................................... 129
11.8 Extensions to Manchester and Leeds............................................................................ 130
Appendix 1: Transport Economic Efficiency Tables..................................................................................140
Appendix 2: Sensitivity Tests on HS2 Central Case...................................................................................153
A2.1 Testing Our Assumptions................................................................................................ 154
A2.2 Changing the forecast level of demand for long distance rail trips............................... 154
A2.3 Changing Background Demand Growth and Prices on Non-Rail Modes...................... 157
A2.4 Premium Fares............................................................................................................... 158
A2.5 Comparison with a classic line....................................................................................... 160
A2.6 Reliability........................................................................................................................ 161
Appendix 3: High Speed Rail and Spatial Patterns and Strategies in Cities and Regions..........................163
A3.1 Introduction..................................................................................................................... 164
A3.2 Why Does Spatial Impact (Land Use Change) Matter?.................................................. 165
A3.3 How Might HS2 Affect Land Use?................................................................................... 166
A3.4 The Evidence of Land Use Change and HSR.................................................................. 167
A3.5 Conclusions.................................................................................................................... 168
A3.5 References...................................................................................................................... 170
Appendix 4 : Service Specification for Wider Network Tests.....................................................................171

4
Chapter 1:
Introduction and Background Data
HS2 Demand Model Analysis

1.1 Introduction to this report


1.1.1 High Speed Two Ltd was established in January 2009 to develop proposals for a new high speed
railway line between London and the West Midlands and to consider the case for high speed rail
services linking London, northern England and Scotland.

1.1.2 This report provides further detail on the approach and forecasts of demand used to support ‘High
Speed Rail: London to the West Midlands and Beyond’ (henceforth ‘HS2’s report’). It explains how
demand forecasting and appraisal has been used to inform and support the design of the preferred
scheme, and provides detail on the expected demand and economic impact of a new high speed
rail line.

1.1.3 Chapter 1 provides the context for HS2 by showing the underlying demand for transport and explains
how we used analysis and appraisal to inform the design of HS2. Chapters 2 and 3 consider the
modelling approach and the key assumptions that underpin our results, as well as the implications
of some of these for the overall results. Chapters 4 to 9 then set out the results of our analysis and
the implications for the component parts of the scheme:
• A Central London station.
• A Heathrow/Crossrail Interchange station.
• A Central Birmingham station.
• An interchange or parkway station in the West Midlands.
• The case for an intermediate station between London and the West Midlands.
• The case for a link between HS1 and HS2 and the likely passenger market for international rail
connections.

1.1.4 Chapter 10 draws this together into an overall assessment of the preferred scheme that is set out in
HS2’s Business Case. The report concludes with a strategic level analysis of the possible long term
strategy and the implications of this for extensions to Leeds and Manchester.

6
Chapter 1: Introduction and Background Data

1.2 Acknowledgements
1.2.1 Throughout the year we have worked closely with a number of organisations whose specialist and
local knowledge has helped to inform our investigation. We have sought to ensure a proper process
of quality assurance is in place to validate our approach and results. This has been particularly
important given the UK’s relative inexperience in appraising and delivering domestic high speed
rail projects – although we have been able to draw on the UK’s growing experience in the delivery
of other major projects.

1.2.2 We are grateful to Prof. Robert Cochrane, Prof. Stephen Glaister CBE, Prof. Peter Mackie, Prof
Henry Overman, Dr David Simmonds and Prof. Roger Vickerman who as members of our Analytical
Challenge Panel provided independent expert scrutiny on the modelling and appraisal of HS2. Their
advice has been invaluable as we formulated our approach and findings. However, our findings are
ours alone. There is no intention that the Challenge Panel should be seen as accountable for the
conclusions that, ultimately, we alone have reached.

1.2.3 We have also commissioned specialist consultancy advice on a range of topics. Those who have
advised us are listed below and their reports make up several of the supporting documents
published alongside the report.

WS Atkins plc Demand Modelling and Appraisal


  Sinclair Knight Merz Pty Ltd - (subcontracted by WS Atkins)
  Arup Group Ltd
  John Bates
Dr Dan Graham & Patricia Melo Advice on the assessment of wider economic impacts

Reg Harman Advice on the spatial impacts of high speed rail

7
HS2 Demand Model Analysis

1.3 The Demand for Transport and Context for HS2


1.3.1 The demand for transport has grown substantially over time. As people become richer they tend to
travel further and more often and, as the transport network has grown, so it has become easier to
travel. The total distance travelled by passengers on all modes has grown by 36% in the last 20 years
as shown in figure 1.3a.

Figure 1.3a - Passenger Travel (All Modes) 1980 - 2007

900

800

700

600
Billion Passenger km

500

400

300

200

100

0
1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006
Year
Total Passenger Travel Cars, Vans and Taxis Other

Source: Department for Transport (DfT) – Transport Trends

1.3.2 This growth has been driven primarily by increasing car traffic – which accounts for almost 85% of
the overall distance travelled. However in the last 15 years or so, there has also been rapid growth
in the number of passengers, and distance travelled, on the UK’s railways. The number of passenger
km on rail has increased by just over 70% during this period, compared to less than 15% for cars as
shown in Figure 1.3b.

8
Chapter 1: Introduction and Background Data

Figure 1.3b - Total Passenger Travel by Rail 1980 - 2008

60.0

50.0

40.0
Billion Passenger km

30.0

20.0

10.0

0.0
1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005
Year


Source: Office of the Rail Regulator (ORR) – National Rail Trends

1.3.3 Similarly, long distance trips of over 50 miles have been growing in line with recent trends, with
an increase of more than 30% since 2002. This rapid growth is forecast to continue, with trips into
and out of London being particularly important. Table 1.3 summarises the growth forecast using
standard industry tools (Passenger Demand Forecasting Handbook (PDFH), version 4.1). These form
the basis of the forecasts we have used in our modelling and the assumptions underpinning this are
outlined in Chapter 3.

9
HS2 Demand Model Analysis

Table 1.3 – Forecast growth in long distance travel

Passenger Demand per weekday


2008 2033 % Growth
to and from Central London
Demand Demand 2008-2033
(two way flow)

Birmingham 5,700 13,300 130%


Manchester 5,300 14,200 170%
Leeds 4,400 12,200 180%
Glasgow 800 2,200 180%
Liverpool 2,100 5,400 160%
Newcastle 2,400 6,600 180%
Edinburgh 1,700 5,500 220%

Source: Atkins Baseline forecasting report (PLD)

1.3.4 Such substantial increases in demand will increase passenger flows and crowding on the West
Coast Main line (WCML). In 2008 there were approximately 45,000 long distance passengers per day
using inter-city trains on the southern section of the WCML, with an average train loading across
the whole day of 51%. By 2033 long distance demand on the WCML is expected to more than double.
Although the Pendolino trains currently running on the WCML would have been lengthened to 11
cars, the average train loading would have increased to around 80%. This is an average figure, with
trains during the peak times likely to have even higher loadings.

1.3.5 The following maps show the number of long distance trips on the WCML in 2008 and the increase in
those volumes by 2033. Figure 1.3e shows the load factor on long distance journeys on the WCML by
2033 based on our reference case assumptions about what would happen in the future without HS2.

1.3.6 HS2 offers the opportunity not only to speed up journeys for passengers along the line of the WCML,
but also to provide substantial additional capacity to Birmingham and on long distance trains
north of Birmingham. And the capacity released by HS2 can be reused to reduce crowding on short
distance services into London.

10
Chapter 1: Introduction and Background Data

Figure 1.3c - WCML Long Distance Daily Rail Trips in 2008


(GLQEXUJK
(GLQEXUJK
*ODVJRZ
*ODVJRZ Long distance daily trips on the


WCML in 2008








1HZFDVWOH
1HZFDVWOH




<RUN
<RUN

/HHGV
/HHGV
+XOO
+XOO
1R:LQGRZ

0DQFKHVWHU
0DQFKHVWHU

/LYHUSRRO
/LYHUSRRO
6KHIILHOG
6KHIILHOG







 6WRNHRQ7UHQW
6WRNHRQ7UHQW
6WRNHRQ7UHQW
1RWWLQJKDP
1RWWLQJKDP


 /HLFHVWHU
/HLFHVWHU
3HWHUERURXJK
3HWHUERURXJK


%LUPLQJKDP
%LUPLQJKDP

%DVH)ORZ9ROXPH/HJHQG 

0RUH7KDQ
WR 
WR 2[IRUG
2[IRUG
WR
/HVVWKDQ
/RQGRQ
/RQGRQ
&DUGLII
&DUGLII %ULVWRO
%ULVWRO
5HDGLQJ
5HDGLQJ

Source: Atkins PLANET Long Distance

11
HS2 Demand Model Analysis

Figure 1.3d - WCML Long Distance Daily Rail Trips in 2033


Edinburgh
Edinburgh
Glasgow
Glasgow
Forecast of long distance daily
Glasgow
trips on the WCML in 2033

8,867
8,867

Newcastle
Newcastle

12,162
12,162

York
York

Leeds
Leeds
Leeds
Hull
Hull
No Window

Manchester
Manchester

Liverpool
Liverpool
Sheffield
Sheffield

8,730
8,730
21,688
21,688

46,213
46,213 Stoke-on-Trent
Stoke-on-Trent
Nottingham
Nottingham

65,958
65,958 Leicester
Leicester
4,857
4,857 Peterborough
Peterborough

Birmingham
Birmingham

41,843
41,843

105,490
105,490

DM Flow Volume Legend


More Than 30,000
20,000 to 30,000
10,000 to 20,000 Oxford
Oxford
3,000 to 10,000
106,111
106,111
Less than 3,000
London
London
Cardiff
Cardiff Bristol
Bristol
Reading
Reading
Reading

Source: Atkins PLANET Long Distance

12
Chapter 1: Introduction and Background Data

Figure 1.3e - WCML Long Distance Load Factors in 2033


Edinburgh
Edinburgh
Glasgow
Glasgow
Forecast of laverage daily load factors
62
62 on long distance WCML services in 20033
55
55

56
56

Newcastle
Newcastle

77
77

York
York

86
86
Leeds
Leeds
Hull
Hull
No Window

Manchester
Manchester

Liverpool
Liverpool Sheffield
Sheffield
Sheffield
60
60
60
68
68 64
64

85
85
Stoke-on-Trent
Stoke-on-Trent
Nottingham
Nottingham

78
78
Leicester
Leicester
76
76 Peterborough
Peterborough

Birmingham
Birmingham

81
81
79
79

Do Minimum Crowding Legend


(Volume over seats) 80
80
More than 80%
60% to 80% Oxford
Oxford

40% to 60%
20% to 40%
London
London
0 to 20% Cardiff
Cardiff Bristol
Bristol
Reading
Reading

Source: Atkins PLANET Long Distance

13
HS2 Demand Model Analysis

1.4 Demand and Appraisal – Helping with Scheme Design


1.4.1 The appraisal of transport impacts is a powerful tool not only to aid the justification of a scheme
but also to support its design to ensure it maximises value for money. There are many trade-offs
in designing a scheme, with individual components impacting on each other, and impacting on the
overall experience of transport users. HS2 is no exception. For example, whether to include an
intermediate station involves trading off the benefits to local passengers against costs of building
the station (and re-routing the line), delays for other passengers and impacts on the capacity of
the line. Appraisal techniques can help to weigh these costs and benefits. Box 1 provides a brief
background to appraisal and what it attempts to capture.

1.4.2 We have sought throughout the process to ensure our assessment of the benefits of HS2
appropriately reflects the evidence available, and to weigh these against costs and environmental
impacts to ensure that the resulting scheme maximises value for money. This has had implications
in a number of areas, including:
• Location of stations. The location of a station will affect its accessibility, and so the attractiveness
of a station for long distance passengers. This in turn has implications for demand, revenues and
benefits which need to be weighed against the cost and constructability of these stations.
• Inclusion of non-core stations. We were asked to consider the potential for intermediate stations
and interchange stations along the line of route, where these added to the business case.
Appraisal helps to weigh the benefits and costs of such stations, and whether they can improve
the business case for HS2.
• Line of route and service patterns. By considering the impact on demand and benefits of
different journey times we ensured an appropriate trade-off between the cost of the overall HS2
route against the journey time offered by different elements of the scheme. This also helped
to inform the service patterns and line of route, with fast links to London being identified as a
key factor.
• The use of released capacity. We examined how line capacity on the existing West Coast Main
Line might be re-used to provide further benefits.

14
Chapter 1: Introduction and Background Data

Box 1 - What is Appraisal?


Appraisal is an important tool to help Government assess the input of policies and investment.
It helps support policy development and ensures the proper use of public resources.
The guidance for appraisal across Government is set out in ‘The Green Book: Appraisal and
Evaluation in Central Government’ (HMT, 2003). Transport has a long history in appraisal, and
DfT sets out its own guidance on appraising transport schemes which applies Green Book
principles to transport investment. This guidance is set out in WebTAG (available on the DfT
website).
WebTAG provides a methodology to assess all of the impacts of a transport scheme – both
positive and negative. These range from impacts on transport users through to impacts on local
communities (e.g. noise or air quality changes), environmental effects on landscape and the
global effects - Greenhouse Gas emissions and climate change.
The focus of this technical annex is on the assessment of impacts on transport users, most of
which can be modelled, quantified and valued. Our Appraisal of Sustainability addresses the
wider impacts covered by WebTAG.
WebTAG’s assessment of impacts on transport users considers the whole journey experience.
It includes:
•  how long a journey takes, including the impact of congestion and delays on the road network
•  the financial costs (fares, fuel)
•  the other costs imposed during a journey e.g. having to stand on public transport
Each of these impacts has a value to transport users – they would prefer to have faster journeys
or less crowding on trains. Transport appraisal attempts to quantify the impacts of a transport
scheme and so the value of these benefits to transport users. In the appraisal of HS2 we
consider the potential for:
•  faster, more reliable and less crowded journeys using HS2
•  less crowding from use of released capacity on the classic rail network
•  the reduction in congestion (and so faster car trips) for all car users as a result of mode shift
Throughout the analysis in this technical annex we consider the trade-offs for different users
under different options. For example we consider the time penalty (cost of a slower journey) of
stopping at a station compared to the benefits (e.g. faster journeys) of those who would have
access to HS2 as a result of the station. In identifying and quantifying these trade-offs we can
design a scheme which maximises the benefits of HS2 across all transport users and society
in general.

15
HS2 Demand Model Analysis

1.4.3 We took an incremental approach to analysis and appraisal, building on the evidence base and
modelling capabilities as they were developed to enable early decisions to be made and effective
prioritisation of work. There were three clear stages to this work.

Stage One: High Level Demand Analysis


1.4.4 During the first few months of the project, we used existing data and evidence sources to help
provide an initial high level or strategic understanding of the key issues. Known as a ‘Ready
Reckoner’, this simple analysis allowed us to quickly gain a high level understanding of current and
future demand. It allowed us to conduct:
• A high level assessment of the patterns of demand for long distance trips. This included analysis of:
i. The overall pattern of long distance trips, particularly between London and other major cities
in the north of the UK.
ii. Where trips started or ended within London and the West Midlands.
iii. The most suitable locations for intermediate stations between Birmingham and London, and
their potential to capture demand.
• Simple tests on the likely level of demand between different locations that might be generated
by HS2. This analysis was undertaken using simple elasticities with respect to journey times and
other variables.
• Simple analysis of what the key drivers of the HS2 business case were most likely to be.

1.4.5 This high level analysis provided early support for decisions taken around:
• The need for a city centre terminus at either end of HS2.
• The locations to consider in further detail for an intermediate station.
• The need to utilise capacity on the line (a few trains per hour would not be sufficient to generate
a business case).
• The potential areas to consider in the Longer Term Strategy network designs.

16
Chapter 1: Introduction and Background Data

Stage Two: Early Modelling


1.4.6 Early model runs using development or prototype versions of the demand model also allowed high
level analysis of the potential case for HS2, and gave an early indication of the key drivers of benefits.
This assessment provided robust evidence to support comparative analysis of different options, and to
provide useful information on emerging patterns of demand and benefits. Particular analysis included:
• Analysis of the impact of journey time benefits. Early tests suggested that reducing journey
times by one minute would provide benefits of around £300-600m (present value discounted over
60 years in 2009 prices) on a fully utilised high speed line. Box 1 highlights that people value
faster journeys, and using initial projections of demand we were able to estimate this overall
figure for the likely value HS2 passengers as a whole would place on slight changes to journey
times. This supported decisions taken on the line of route demonstrating the importance of
journey times for comparison against costs (e.g. tunnelling) and environmental constraints.
It also showed the potential disbenefits of stopping trains at intermediate and interchange
stations.
• Analysis of the service pattern of HS2 trains. Simple extrapolation (based on wait times) tested
the strategic implications of increasing/reducing frequencies to different stations.
• Analysis of the pattern of benefits from different stations. The analysis helped to identify the
importance of stations served by HS2, with Birmingham, Manchester, Liverpool and Glasgow
representing the bulk of demand and benefits on the west coast main line.
• Comparison of different options for the design of HS2. This provided comparisons of the
relative benefits of different locations for interchange stations in London and Birmingham, and
an intermediate station. This analysis allowed us to focus our design efforts in advance of final
model tests.

Stage Three: Detailed Modelling


1.4.7 The final version of the model was then used to provide an overall assessment of the preferred
scheme, as well as to confirm the incremental impacts of the key components of the scheme.
Several model runs were undertaken, including:
• HS2 central case (‘Day One’ scenario, with all preferred components included).
• No interchange station at Old Oak Common.
• Alternative options for a London Interchange Station in the vicinity of Heathrow.
• No Interchange station at Birmingham International.
• A test of the impact of running at classic line speeds (125mph).

1.4.8 The economic results of these tests are described later in this report with the full results provided
in the Appendices.

17
Chapter 2:
Demand Model Structure
and Development
Chapter 2: Demand Model Structure and Development

2.1 Introduction
2.1.1 This chapter sets out the development of our modelling capability to allow us to understand and
test the costs and benefits of the components of the scheme as well as the overall results for the
preferred package. To understand the business case for high speed rail, we employed Atkins Group
Ltd to help develop a modelling and forecasting framework consisting of the following elements:
• PLANET Long Distance. An update of an existing model (PLANET Strategic) which was developed
by the Strategic Rail Authority (SRA) for their 2001 high speed line study, and has been used
for several other rail studies since. PLANET Long Distance considers the multi-modal demand
(including domestic aviation) for long distance (greater than 50 miles) trips and is used to forecast
HS2 demand.
• PLANET South. Based on an existing model, this focuses on demand for rail trips across London
and the South East and has been used for analysis of schemes such as Thameslink. PLANET
South allows the impact of short distance trips using long distance services and commuter
services on the WCML to be understood, and is particularly important for understanding how best
to use capacity on the WCML released by HS2.
• PLANET Midlands. A model similar to PLANET South, but focussed on rail demand in the West
Midlands.
• Heathrow Access Model. This model, based on BAA’s London Airport Surface Access Model
(LASAM), forecasts the demand for passengers accessing Heathrow Airport for international
flights and the potential of high speed rail (HSR) to capture this demand. As well as modelling
surface access to Heathrow, this model also forecasts air transfers in which passengers fly to
or from Heathrow on domestic flights in order to change onto onward international flights (inter-
lining). Domestic (point to point) air trips are not included within this part of the model as they
are captured within PLANET Long Distance.
• International Rail Model. A separate model has been developed to forecast the demand for
international rail journeys in order to examine the case for connecting HS2 to HS1.

2.1.2 With the exception of the international model, all these models were combined into a single
framework to allow integrated analysis of high speed rail and appraisal of HS2 and its components.
The rest of this chapter provides more detail about the structure and design of this modelling
framework and the analytical approach that was used. A more complete description of the modelling
approach including reports on the methodology, forecasting approach and validation of the model is
published in separate documentation produced by Atkins.

19
HS2 Demand Model Analysis

2.2 PLANET Long Distance


2.2.1 PLANET Long Distance forms the heart of the forecasting approach used to model high speed rail
and has a number of characteristics, including:

• Long Distance. The model has a specific focus on long distance travel (over 50 miles)
• National. The model covers the whole of mainland Great Britain. However the model has been
primarily designed for analysing a high speed line from London to the North and so the South
West, West, Wales and Northern Scotland are less well represented.
• Multi-modal. The model covers domestic trips by air, rail and car. Apart from airport access
(see section 2.4) coach is not included as a separate mode as it is not considered that much
coach demand would want to transfer to high speed rail. This is demonstrated by coach
passengers already preferring to trade slower journey times compared to rail for cheaper tickets.
• Segmented. The model segments people by the type of journey they are making and whether
they have access to a car or not.
• Network based. There is a representation of the national car, rail and air networks. Transport
users can therefore choose not only which mode they take, but which route best fits their
preferences.
• All day model. Long distance demand and capacity is averaged across the whole day.
• Incremental model. Forecasts are based on changes to externally generated trip matrices.

2.2.2 PLANET Long Distance models the number of trips made by each mode and for each journey
purpose between different areas of the country. The model divides the country into 235 geographic
areas or zones, with each zone equivalent to districts or aggregations of districts. For example, the
32 boroughs of Greater London are aggregated into 7 geographical sector zones (plus Heathrow
as an explicit zone). Rural Cumbria on the other hand retains its constituent districts. This is done
to group zones into patterns of similar access and egress (such as Camden and Islington London
Boroughs in north London), while acknowledging that east and west Cumbria may have very
different access and egress, despite the far smaller population and trip activity in each district.
This is shown in Figure 2.2.

20
Chapter 2: Demand Model Structure and Development

Figure 2.2 – PLANET Long Distance Zones

Box 2 - What is Generalised Journey Time?


The generalised journey time or cost of travelling represents the total inconvenience of
travelling between any two places expressed in common units of time or money. In the case
of rail, this includes the total time taken for the journey including any time getting to and from
stations or time spent waiting for a train. It also includes additional penalties if an interchange
is required (in PLANET Long Distance this is equivalent to half an hour journey time penalty),
for having to wait for a train, or if the train is crowded. This represents the fact that people would
prefer not to change trains, and dislike waiting for a train and having to spend time on crowded
trains. In addition the generalised journey time includes the financial cost of a making a journey,
expressed in units of time. The conversion between time and money requires an understanding
of the people put on being able to save time, a concept known as their value of time.

21
HS2 Demand Model Analysis

2.2.3 To model how journeys are routed across the network, PLANET Long Distance calculates what
is known as the generalised time of travelling between each pair of zones by any mode or route.
Trips are then assigned to trains or routes on the network in a way which tries to minimise the
generalised journey time of a trip.

2.2.4 The model can predict not only the level of demand between zones but the flows between stations
and the level of demand on specific sections of the rail, air and road network. To forecast the impact
of a new high speed rail line, the model calculates the change in generalised costs between pairs of
zones as a result of the faster journeys offered by high speed rail. It then applies this change in costs
to forecast the change in demand for each mode. This works in three concurrent stages:
• The change in generalised cost of travel across all modes (the ‘composite cost’) is used to
forecast the change in the total number of trips undertaken. Any new or additional trips are
generally referred to as trip generation, and represent journeys that would not have been
undertaken by any mode in the absence of high speed rail.
• The model forecasts people’s preferred mode of travel using a probability based approach
known as a hierarchical logit function. The logit function determines the probability of someone
choosing one mode or another based on the differences in generalised costs.
• These mode shares are then allocated to the rail, air and road network by choosing a route with
the lowest generalised journey time. This allows a degree of re-routing to occur in the light of
different journey times and levels of crowding.

2.2.5 The work we commissioned delivers a significant update to the previous version of the model used
by the SRA in their 2001 High Speed Rail Study. This work has included:
• Updating the base year trip matrices to 2008, by incorporating more recent data on rail and air
demand, as well as some limited new data on roads.
• Updating our assumptions about the future shape of the road, rail and air networks to represent
the most recent DfT assumptions on the provision of network capacity.
• Providing a station choice model for the London and Birmingham areas, designed to address how
the accessibility of different station locations has an impact on demand. The station accessibility
data is provided by Transport for London’s (TfL) model of public transport access, RailPlan, and
West Midlands Policy Response Integrated Strategy Model (PRISM 1). It should be noted that this
means that the London station choice model is entirely based on public transport access costs,
while the Birmingham station choice model is entirely based on car access costs. These choices
reflect the data available. This means the results of these elements of the modelling require
careful interpretation.

1 www.prism-wm.com/

22
Chapter 2: Demand Model Structure and Development

2.2.6 In addition to updating the functionality and data in the model as described above, we also
significantly changed the way the model was used compared with previous studies. We took the
decision that high speed rail has essentially the same characteristics as classic rail (apart from
being quicker and more reliable), and hence in our approach high speed rail is treated in exactly the
same way as classic rail services. A further discussion on the reasons for this decision can be found
in Chapter 3.

2.2.7 The changes have focused on updating demand and network data and improving model functionality.
We have not sought to re-calibrate the model and the parameters which determine forecasts of
mode choice and trip generation are largely taken from the previous version of the model originally
developed for the 2001 SRA study. In the time available for model development, it was not possible
for us conduct any new research or survey work on how travellers might be expected to respond to
high speed rail.

2.2.8 With this in mind we have deliberately followed a cautious approach in our analysis and have
wherever possible made assumptions that would be unlikely to overstate the demand for high speed
rail. However, we do recognise that further research into some of our assumptions, and in particular
the trip generation parameters, could help refine the detail of some areas of our analysis. Overall,
the performance of the model has been compared against other forecasting approaches, and found
to be broadly similar.

23
HS2 Demand Model Analysis

2.3 PLANET South and Midlands


2.3.1 Unlike PLANET Long Distance, PLANET South and Midlands are rail only models, with relatively
simple capabilities for analysing the potential for mode shift. Like the Long Distance model they
include a representation of the rail network and train services, but focus on short distance trips and
rail services within the South and Midlands respectively. Both of these models have recently been
updated as part of work for the DfT and we have not sought to further update the models (other than
to integrate them within the wider modelling framework).

2.3.2 There are three critical differences between the structure of these models and PLANET Long Distance:
• The models estimates demand in the am peak only.
• The models calculate mode shift by an elasticity response, so there is a fixed relationship
between changes in generalised journey time and demand on the railway. The models do not
have an explicit mode choice model as in PLANET Long Distance.
• The models have a more detailed understanding of where people are travelling to and from
(due to much smaller zones).

2.3.3 The integration of PLANET South and Midlands in the PLANET Long Distance framework was
important as it allows the interaction of long distance and short distance journeys to be understood.
In particular, PLANET South allows better modelling of any WCML released capacity used for short
distance commuting. PLANET South was also used to understand the impact of HS2 on the London
Underground Network.

24
Chapter 2: Demand Model Structure and Development

2.4 Heathrow Access Model


2.4.1 The final element integrated into the HS2 demand model is based on BAA’s London Airport Surface
Access Model (LASAM) and models the potential for HS2 to deliver improved access to Heathrow.
Although based on the hierarchy, parameters and data of the LASAM model, the revised model
has been developed independently and is significantly simplified to allow it to run in a spreadsheet
modelling air transfers and HSR as access modes.

2.4.2 This delivers a separate mode choice model for analysing and forecasting the number of passengers
accessing Heathrow airport for international flights. The model covers all surface modes, including
some such as coach that are not in PLANET. These extra modes have been included because they
play a more important role in accessing Heathrow than they do for other types of long distance
journey. The Heathrow model also forecasts air transfers in which passengers fly to or from
Heathrow in order to change onto onward international flights. Domestic (point to point) air trips
are not included within this model as they are captured within PLANET Long Distance.

2.4.3 The Heathrow model is focussed on the areas of the country that are most likely to be most affected
by the high speed rail networks we have considered. These areas are shown in Figure 2.4 below and
include cities in the North West, North East and Scotland. It is important to note that the model does
not analyse the potential market to Heathrow from areas to the west. This means for instance, that
the model does not forecast the demand to Heathrow from (for example) Reading using a London
Interchange Station connected to the Great Western Mainline (GWML).

25
HS2 Demand Model Analysis

Figure 2.4 - HS2 Route and Areas Likely to be Affected by HS2

2.4.4 The PLANET Long Distance model automatically feeds the Heathrow spreadsheet model with
information on costs of travelling by each mode to allow it to calculate revised mode shares. The
demand information from the Heathrow access model (based on the costs from PLANET) is fed back
into the PLANET models to allow an assessment of overall rail loadings and calculation of crowding
effects as a result of all demand on HS2.

26
Chapter 2: Demand Model Structure and Development

2.5 International Rail Model


2.5.1 A model for forecasting the potential demand for international rail trips was separately developed
by our consultants, SKM. Data was collected from a number of existing routes in which rail and air
compete in order to understand rail’s mode share in relation to journey time. The model used this
data to forecast the likely rail share between a number of UK and continental cities as shown in
Table 2.5. This model has not been integrated into the wider HS2 framework, but is used in separate
analysis. More detail on this model is provided in Chapter 9.

Table 2.5 - Cities within the International Rail Model


UK Europe

Manchester Paris

Birmingham Frankfurt

Edinburgh Amsterdam

Glasgow Brussels

East Midlands Cologne

Liverpool Lyon

Newcastle

2.6 Additional Modelling Evidence


2.6.1 Our modelling suite provides the level of granularity necessary to support the design of the overall
scheme and provide a business case. It is designed to model the key issues, including station
locations, released capacity, mode shift and the overall demand for long distance travel from
Birmingham and beyond.

2.6.2 Our modelling suite is not particularly well suited to modelling localised impacts, particularly
around station access and egress. Such impacts are likely to have complex interactions with short
distance traffic and demand, and be affected by localised differences in the transport network. We
therefore asked Transport for London (TfL) and the West Midlands transport agencies to support
our work using their own more detailed models. Some early work has been undertaken using TfL’s
Railplan model in London and PRISM in the West Midlands, and although this work is ongoing, it has
helped inform our proposals.

27
Chapter 3:
Our Assumptions and Approach
Chapter 3: Our Assumptions and Approach

3.1 Introduction
3.1.1 The HS2 demand model provides a framework for analysing the potential impacts of HS2. However the
assumptions used in the modelling are key to the overall conclusions and the strength of the overall
business case. There are two critical issues which will affect both forecasts and appraisal of HS2:
• Demand Growth – The PLANET Long Distance model forecasts on an incremental basis. This
means it takes forecasts of demand which are calculated outside of the model and estimates
the changes to demand as a result of introducing HS2. This means the demand for HS2 is
heavily dependent on the assumptions underpinning the forecasts that are input into the model
(the reference case). If there is high demand for travel (across all modes) in the reference case
then there is a greater potential market for high speed rail to capture, conversely if there is low
demand for travel then there is a smaller market.
• Passenger perceptions of HSR – The way in which passengers view HSR, whether they have
an inherent preference for high speed trains and the way they trade off time, money and other
characteristics will affect both the number of passengers and potentially the benefits they
receive.

3.1.2 We have generally tried to be conservative in our treatment of these issues and have followed advice
on best practice, but there is also a significant degree of uncertainty. This chapter sets out the
assumptions on which we have based our analysis, and the basis for these assumptions. More detail
on some of these assumptions is provided in the supporting technical documentation produced by
Atkins.

3.2 Demand Growth Assumptions


3.2.1 PLANET Long Distance forecasts the future demand for high speed rail in three stages, as
summarised in the diagram below. The model is an incremental demand model which means that
the model first requires demand in the future year reference case to be determined. These forecasts
are largely exogenous (i.e. they are calculated outside PLANET Long Distance) and can be thought
of as the growth in demand that will happen independently of HS2. This growth is driven by changes
in population and employment, and in particular, people’s propensity to make more frequent and
longer trips as they get richer. The model then calculates how these forecasts change given a
change in journey times or cost. This process is summarised in Figure 3.2.

29
HS2 Demand Model Analysis

Figure 3.2 - PLANET Long Distance Forecasting Approach

Future year
2008 data The demand for HS2
exogenous or background
on the number of calculated as a
growth forecasts for road,
long distance road, change to future year
air and rail demand
rail and air trips background growth
provided by DfT

Base Year demand data


3.2.2 The starting point for forecasting future demand is observations on how long distance trips are
currently made and distributed in the 2008 base year. Data has been collected showing the number
of trips over 50 miles made between each pair of zones in the model split by mode and journey
purpose (leisure, commuting and business), with some additional breakdowns of whether a car is
available to undertake the trip. The data has been collated from a number of different sources:
• Data on domestic air trips has been extracted from Civil Aviation Authority survey data. This data
is considered robust and is consistent with data used by the Department for Transport’s aviation
model.
• Rail trips have been derived from a combination of the LENNON ticket sales database and the
National Rail Travel Survey (NRTS). NRTS has been used to understand how people access and
egress stations, and to infill areas where the ticket sales database is known to be weak.
• Unfortunately there is no robust national dataset providing the origins and destinations of long
distance car trips. Data on car trip matrices has therefore been derived from regional Multi-Modal
Studies, with some updates using the Highway’s Agency North of Thames Highway Model and the
West Midlands PRISM model. While this remains one of the best available sources of car trip data
on a national basis, the accuracy of the data still remains much weaker than that for rail or air,
and considerable uncertainty remains about the accuracy of the demand matrix for this mode.

Demand Growth on Air and Road Networks


3.2.3 The base year demand matrices for road and air are then uplifted to represent the expected growth
that will occur in each of these modes. This exogenous growth is independent of any subsequent
changes that are made to the rail network such as high speed rail. Growth in road and air traffic has
been based on the Department for Transport’s most recently published forecasts; the road forecasts
are based on the 2008 Road Transport Forecasts2 and the air forecasts are based on the 2009 Air
Passenger Demand and CO2 forecasts.3

2 DfT 2008 Road Transport Forecasts - http://www.dft.gov.uk/pgr/economics/ntm/roadtransportforcasts08/


3 DfT 2009 Air Passenger Demand and CO2 forecasts – http://www.dft.gov.uk/pgr/aviation/atf/co2forecasts09/

30
Chapter 3: Our Assumptions and Approach

3.2.4 These air and road traffic forecasts have been produced by the National Transport Model (NTM) and
air traffic model (SPASM), and the underlying assumptions used by these models and PLANET are
generally consistent with one another. For instance all the models are based on the same TEMPRO
planning data. The forecasts also include assumptions about the future road and air networks.
The NTM assumes that investment in the road network continues at current trends, while the air
traffic model assumes that Heathrow has a third runway. These assumptions are described in the
supporting documents produced by Atkins.

Demand Growth on Rail Network


3.2.5 The exogenous rail growth has been calculated using the standard industry and Government
recommended approach in WebTAG known as PDFH (Passenger Demand Forecasting Handbook).
This methodology uses a set of fixed relationships between demand and various drivers such as
fares, employment, GDP/GVA and population which have been derived from econometric analysis of
past rail growth. In keeping with WebTAG the relationship between rail growth and fare is taken from
PDFH edition 4.0, whilst all other relationships come from edition 4.1.

3.2.6 There are, however, a number of issues with this approach:


• Unlike the road or air forecasts, PDFH uses fixed income elasticities. This means that for every
1% growth in GDP there is a constant percentage increase in rail demand. Using this approach
implies rail demand will grow indefinitely (in line with GDP). There is no slowing of growth,
market maturity or saturation effect. Over an appraisal period of 60 years this can have a very
strong influence on the appraisal results. To proxy for market maturity and the long term lack of
certainty in the forecasting methodology, the Department recommends capping demand growth
at a future date after scheme opening. The cap is usually applied at 2026, reflecting 10 or more
years of demand growth after scheme opening. However as HS2 will not be opening until the end
of 2025 we have decided to cap demand at 2033.
• PDFH v4.1 income elasticities have a distance term and hence can therefore become very high
for very long distance trips. Following advice from the Department PDFH elasticities have been
capped so that even for the very longest distance flows they are limited. For example PDFH v4.1
suggests rail demand between Aberdeen to London will grow by 3.7% for every 1% increase in
GDP (elasticity of 3.7). Following DfT advice this has been capped at 2.8% growth for every 1%
increase in GDP (an elasticity of 2.8).

3.2.7 These elasticities are applied to estimates of population and employment that have been supplied
by DfT’s TEMPRO4 model. All rail fares are assumed to grow at RPI+1 until 2033, while GDP
forecasts are in line with the latest Treasury forecasts, but not the current DfT WebTAG guidance. We
anticipate DfT will update its forecasts and guidance in due course, but for now it leads to a slight
inconsistency, with DfT projections (including those used by HS2 to project air and car demand)
using higher GDP projections.

4 http://www.dft.gov.uk/tempro/

31
HS2 Demand Model Analysis

3.2.8 The demand model uses these exogenous forecasts as the basis for projecting the incremental
impact of HS2. It is also clear that these assumptions are important in generating the strength of
the business case. For this reason further sensitivity tests have been undertaken on the impact of
different levels of demand. These results are reported in Appendix 2.

3.3 Passenger Preferences and the Treatment of HSR in the


Demand Model
3.3.1 Demand models are an attempt to forecast the preferences and behaviour of the travelling public,
given a change in the transport network. The choices people make are based on a wide variety of
factors, and individuals’ preferences will vary compared to the average transport user. Indeed their
preference may also vary depending on circumstance – the importance of time and reliability when
travelling to catch a flight will be very different to a day trip to the seaside.

3.3.2 Most transport models which explicitly forecast mode choice (e.g. PLANET Long Distance) are
probability based models.5 They calculate the probability someone will use a particular mode to
undertake a trip. So even if rail is faster, cheaper or more reliable for a particular trip, it does not
mean everyone will use rail. Put another way the model captures both the things we can identify and
understand in choices, but also allows for variations that we cannot directly observe. The model is
therefore calculating two different things:
• The generalised cost of a mode given average preferences.
• The variation in individuals’ tastes and how this affects the distribution of choices.

3.3.3 This works well for determining people’s choices between existing modes – car, rail, air. In this case
we can observe people’s existing behaviour – how they trade off time or the inherent attractiveness
of one mode over another – on the basis of the actual choices they are seen to make, as well as by
asking people directly through surveys. However, we cannot observe their behaviour for high speed
rail, since it does not currently exist in this country (or has not been in place for long enough) so we
can only ask people what they think they might do.

3.3.4 Past surveys have suggested the way people might behave on high speed rail is different to the way
they treat classic rail. The surveys used to develop the original PLANET model, used by the SRA in
2001 for example suggested passengers placed a value on high speed rail over and above the time
savings compared to classic rail.

5 These are models with techniques such as the hierarchical logit model used in PLANET Long Distance, rather than elasticity based models such as PLANET
South and Midlands.

32
Chapter 3: Our Assumptions and Approach

3.3.5 There is a variety of reasons why people may prefer travelling by high speed rail as opposed to using
classic rail or another mode. These include:
• High speed rail offers a faster journey.
• High speed trains are more reliable.
• High speed trains are more luxurious.
• The experience of travel on high speed rail is somehow more enjoyable, with for instance better
ticketing, pre-booked seats, better stations etc.
• There are fundamental differences between the characteristics of high speed rail users and
classic rail users, in particular the way in which they value time savings.

3.3.6 A review of the evidence from the SRA survey work suggested that passengers’ preferences could have
been overstated, with the value of reliability a particular issue as the study took place shortly after the
Hatfield incident when rail reliability was exceptionally low. We have also taken a conservative view
that the quality of rolling stock and stations should not differentiate high speed rail, as in the future
the differences between the perceived quality of high speed and classic rail stations and trains could
be very small. Neither is there reason to believe that in the absence of premium fares (see section 3.5)
the average high speed rail passenger would be somehow different from the average long distance
passenger on the classic rail network. In particular there is no reason to believe that the average high
speed rail passenger will value time savings more highly on high speed rail.

3.3.7 We therefore concluded that in our analysis of high speed rail we would only consider the impact
of time savings and reliability on demand. As a result high speed and classic rail passengers are
treated in exactly the same way within the PLANET Long Distance model. Whilst reliability benefits
could have been modelled through adjusting mode choice parameters in PLANET Long Distance,
it was felt more appropriate and transparent to model this by adjusting journey times (see section
3.4). This means HSR is not treated as a new mode and there is no mode choice hierarchy between
classic rail and HSR. Similarly there is no difference in peoples’ perceived preferences for HSR
compared to classic rail and users’ value of time remains the same whether they travel on classic or
high speed rail.

3.4 Measuring Reliability Impacts of HSR


3.4.1 Capturing reliability impacts in our modelling creates a particular challenge. Other schemes (at a
detailed level of design) might use explicit models of rail performance – which vary according the
precise detail of the scheme, the capacity and demand on the local railway network. Such modelling
is not appropriate for the stage of design of HS2.

3.4.2 However it is clear from international experience that high speed lines can offer very high levels of
reliability compared to a mixed use railway such as the WCML, and that this can have a significant
impact on demand. The design of the line has also built in costs to ensure the reliability of the line

33
HS2 Demand Model Analysis

– for example timetabling has been undertaken assuming trains run slower than the maximum line
speed to allow for trains to catch up most small delays. As we measure the disbenefits of these
increased journey times, it is therefore important that the off-setting benefits of reliability are also
understood.

3.4.3 Our approach to modelling reliability is fairly simplistic and involves making adjustments to
the journey times as a proxy for changes in reliability. Our approach considers the potential
improvement in reliability that HS2 can deliver by examining one measure of reliability – average
minutes lateness (AML). Improvements in AML as a result of HS2 are then converted into an
equivalent journey time saving based on evidence in PDFH and WebTAG, which suggests that
passengers value 1 minute average lateness as equivalent to 3 minutes of journey time. This
‘artificial’ reduction in journey time is then input into the model to forecast the change in demand
due to reliability improvements.

Day One Central Case


3.4.4 We have used DfT’s Network Modelling Framework6 to forecast the average delay expected on the
WCML in 2020 without high speed rail. This forecasts that performance on the WCML will mean 91%
of trains arriving within 10mins of their scheduled time with an AML of 2-5mins. Consistent with
international practice, HS2 is expected to operate at much higher levels of reliability than can be
achieved on the classic network. For dedicated services on the high speed line the AML is expected
to be less than half a minute.

3.4.5 HS2 hybrid services running on both the high speed and classic network will have some benefit
from running partly on a more reliable network, but will still experience delay when running on the
classic line. There is greater uncertainty about the impact on reliability of these journeys since:
• We have not currently used evidence on where trains are delayed – whether this is on the section
to Lichfield which HS2 bypasses, or sections further to the north.
• There are likely to be compound effects – a short delay on a train leaving London may mean it
misses its path further along the line, resulting in further delays. Hence small improvements in
reliability on one section of a line could have larger improvements in overall reliability.
• The impact of HS2 may be complex. The approach to timetabling on HS2 may allow for fast
running and further catch-up time. However capacity constraints may mean that a train which
misses its slot on HS2 has a greater impact on the reliability of the line.

3.4.6 We have assumed that the reliability of HS2 hybrid services is proportional to the distance run on
HS2. Table 3.4a below shows the expected performance and equivalent journey time reduction for
services on HS2. This means that the modelled journey time between London and Birmingham is
reduced from 49 minutes to 41 minutes, with the demand forecasts based on this reduced journey
time. A sensitivity test on the impact of these assumptions is included in Appendix 2.

6 http://www.dft.gov.uk/about/strategy/whitepapers/whitepapercm7176/railwhitepapersupportingdocs/pdfnetowrkmodelframe1.pdf

34
Chapter 3: Our Assumptions and Approach

Table 3.4a – Reliability Benefits of HS2


Equivalent Journey
Forecast AML with
HS2 Service Group AML Classic Rail Change in AML Time Reduction
HS2
(i.e. 3 times AML)
London - Birmingham 2.6 0.1 2.5 8

London - Preston 4.8 2.8 2.0 6

London– Manchester 2.9 1.9 2.0 6

London– Liverpool 3.0 1.0 2.0 6

London - Scotland 4.4 2.4 2.0 6

Day One Extension to Leeds and Manchester


3.4.7 If the Day One high speed network were extended from the West Midlands to serve Manchester
and/or the East Midlands, Sheffield and Leeds then journeys to these destinations would also
benefit from improved reliability. The impact this has on the journey time of each link of the network
is shown in Table 3.4b. It is assumed that the time savings are distributed across the network in a
manner roughly proportional to distance.

Table 3.4b – Reliability Benefits of HS2 extended to Leeds and Manchester


Equivalent Journey
HS2 Service Group AML Classic Rail AML HS2 Change in AML
Time Reduction
London - East Midlands/
1.8 0.1 1.7 5
Sheffield
London - Leeds 2.0 0.1 1.9 6

London - Birmingham 2.6 0.1 2.5 8

London - Manchester 2.9 0.1 2.8 8

London - Liverpool 3.0 0.2 2.8 8

London - Scotland 4.4 1.6 2.8 8

35
HS2 Demand Model Analysis

3.5 Premium Fares Model


3.5.1 Section 3.4 of this chapter outlines our approach to modelling the preference of HSR passengers
compared with classic rail. This approach considers the way the average passenger trades-off time,
money and other costs of travel. It acknowledges that there will be a variation in these preferences
across individuals by working out the probability of any journey being undertaken on a particular
mode. This works well so long as the variation in preferences is essentially random, which is likely
as long as the characteristics of high speed rail and classic rail are the same. However, if the
scheme results in the selection of a group of people with a particular set of characteristics (for
example if the people who would tend to use a scheme are of above or below average income) this
assumption may not be valid.

3.5.2 Premium fares are an example of this. If a premium fare were charged on HS2, passengers would
have to trade-off time and money – whether to pay more money and get a time saving or stay on
classic rail and pay less money but incur a slower journey. Those with a low value of time will tend to
use classic rail since they do not value the time saving sufficiently to warrant paying the extra fare.
This is not a random variation, rather it reflects the different characteristics of passengers. With a
premium fare, by definition, the average high speed rail user will value time savings more highly
than the average classic rail user.

3.5.3 Ideally we would capture and model this variation, but the design of our base model does not allow
this, since the value of time of both high speed and classic rail users is assumed to be equal. In
addition to this, our decision to treat HSR the same as classic rail meant that the existing model
structure prevented analysis of fare premiums over and above those charged on classic rail – the
two fares are the same for the purposes of the model.

3.5.4 For these reasons we have developed an alternative modelling approach for modelling premium
fares on high speed rail using PLANET Long Distance. It still assumes an individual sees high speed
rail as the same type of mode as classic rail, but rather than assuming that the value of time of
rail users is a single average, the approach now assumes there is a range of individuals each with
different values of time. In this approach the introduction of a premium fare leads to those with low
values of time choosing classic rail and those with high values of time choosing high speed rail.

3.5.5 The distribution of value of time is drawn from evidence from the National Rail Travel Survey,7 with
income used as a proxy for value of time. The resulting model has allowed us to model the impact of
premium fares. However it has not been applied to analysis of our central case since this does not
include premium fares. The Distributed Value of Time model is not appropriate in this case since it
will simply assign all rail users undertaking journeys served by HS2 onto HS2 trains – overstating
the likely shift from rail. It was therefore only used for tests of premium fares.

7 http://www.dft.gov.uk/pgr/statistics/datatablespublications/railways/

36
Chapter 3: Our Assumptions and Approach

3.5.6 We report the results of sensitivity tests on premium fares in Appendix 2. Our investigations have so
far identified that, while there may be some scope for premium fares on HS2 to improve affordability,
these fares structures are likely to be complex and need more assessment than is possible in the
time available. For this reason our central case does not include premium fares, and so does not
apply the Distributed Value of Time model. However this is an issue that could be investigated in
more detail in the future.

3.6 Applying the HS2 Service Specification


3.6.1 The service pattern that we have modelled is included in the HS2 report and summarised in Figure
3.6. It represents an indicative outline of the possible service specification for the purposes of the
demand model.

Figure 3.6 – HS2 Service Specification

Running on HS2
Additional peak hour service
Running on classic line
Glasgow Central
HS2 station
Existing classic rail station

Preston
Liverpool Lime Street Wigan
Runcorn Manchester Piccadilly
Crewe Warrington Stockport
Stafford Wilmslow

Birmingham Fazeley Street


Birmingham Interchange

Old Oak Common

London Euston

3.6.2 The development of the service specification is indicative to allow the development of the business
case. It is a credible service plan tested against the capacity of HS2 and the WCML on which some
classic compatible trains would run on. It also includes an assessment of the potential for released
capacity. However it has not been subject to any degree of timetable validation, and there is the
potential for further iterations as the project develops. Any such changes may change both the costs
and benefits in this report.

37
HS2 Demand Model Analysis

3.6.3 The application of this specification is limited slightly by the nature of PLANET Long Distance. In
particular PLANET Long Distance is an all day model, working on average capacity and demand
across the whole day. However the crowding function takes account of the variation of demand
across the day. For example, an average load factor of 60% across the day would imply crowding
during the peaks. The model therefore applies some crowding penalty even though on average
trains are not crowded.

3.6.4 The service specification assumes 400m trains will run between Birmingham and London during the
peak hours. However simply adding this additional capacity would be assumed to be spread across
the day, and would potentially over-state the level of crowding. For this reason we have assumed (for
the purposes of modelling only) that all trains to Birmingham are 400m trains throughout the day.

3.6.5 This will mean that average load factors on Birmingham trains will be slightly understated, but
this is likely to provide a more representative picture of the crowding impacts on HS2, with capacity
targeted over the most crowded times. Yield management would also help to spread demand and
reduce crowding.

3.7 Economic Appraisal


3.7.1 We have broadly followed DfT’s transport appraisal guidance (WebTAG). The results presented in this
report are all present values, discounted over 60 years (unless otherwise stated). We have deviated
from this guidance in three areas.
• Firstly our reference year is 2009, and not 2002. This is a presentational change, and all present
value costs and benefits can be converted to 2002 using a constant factor to allow comparison
with other schemes. These adjustments do not change the BCRs.
• Secondly we have considered the evidence on Wider Economic Benefits. We have applied DfT’s
draft guidance on WEBs, however we have also looked at whether there are further impacts that
HS2 may generate that are not captured in this methodology. This is discussed in more detail in
Chapter 10.
• Finally, when considering the benefits to transport users under scenarios with premium fares we
have applied different values of time to those outlined in WebTAG. In this circumstance the equity
weighted values that are used by WebTAG can cause misleading results.

3.7.2 If premium fares were charged on HS2, users would have to trade-off the value of the time saving
against the additional cost of the fare. Users with a high value of time will be better off paying the
premium and gaining the time saving. However applying an equity weighted value of time could give
the opposite impression (Box 3 provides an example of this).

38
Chapter 3: Our Assumptions and Approach

Box 3: How to Appraise Time Savings in the Presence


of Premium Fares
The introduction of HSR could represent an additional route choice over the existing WCML
services. In this case, those that shift will value the time saving by enough to outweigh any
additional fare costs. In other words their welfare will improve. However using a standard value
of time may suggest the opposite.
Take the following example:
•  A high speed line saves 30 minutes and the fare is £25 higher
• Person A is travelling for business purposes by rail and has a value of time of £70 per hour, so
will switch to the high speed line – and be £10 better off
• However using the WebTAG standard value of £36.96 per hour, it appears that this person is
£6.52 worse off
So in this case a WebTAG consistent appraisal would suggest HSR has a disbenefit to transport
users (when in fact users have benefitted).

3.7.3 All of these changes are necessary for analysis of specific issues relating to HS2 and the questions
we have addressed. However the core analysis and conclusions are all based on appraisal results
that are consistent with existing Government guidance.

39
Chapter 4:
Central London Station Location
Chapter 4: Central London Station Location

4.1 Introduction
4.1.1 This chapter sets out the analysis that helped us choose the preferred location for a terminal station
in London. Our analysis focussed on resolving three main issues:
• The basic accessibility of different station locations, in particular the differences in demand
between inner and outer London stations.
• The impact of HS2 on the number of people using the preferred station location, both for classic
and the high speed rail.
• The impact of HS2 on the local transport network dispersing passengers to and from the
preferred station location.

4.1.2 Our modelling and analysis draws from data within Railplan to estimate the patterns of demand
across London – where typical day trips start and finish within London – and the accessibility of
potential HS2 stations when using public transport (as the main access mode).

4.2 Choosing a London Station Location


4.2.1 We took an early decision that termini stations should be located in Central London (i.e. within Zone
1 on the London Underground Network). This decision was informed by examining the size of the
markets for long distance trips starting or ending in London. This showed that:
• Approximately half of long distance trips from London originate from central London. This market
was also the focus of rail demand, and therefore particularly important for HS2.
• The average access time/cost for passengers in London to reach an Outer London station using
public transport would be significantly longer than most central London stations. Whilst some (in
the vicinity of the station) would gain, many would lose. On average this would largely off-set any
gains from faster journeys on high speed rail.

4.2.2 Table 4.2a below sets out the number of trips from London to the West Midlands, by origin in 2008.
Over half of all trips (and 90% of rail trips) start within central London. This represents a core
market for high speed rail, particularly as we would expect to capture the majority of rail trips (in the
absence of premium fares). Trips that start in Outer London are dominated by car trips. Whilst this
reflects an opportunity for HS2 to deliver mode shift, it also reflects the diverse range of origins and
destinations. Car is likely to be more attractive for trips which start or finish a significant distance
from a train station at either end.

41
HS2 Demand Model Analysis

Table 4.2a - 2008 Annual Trips between London and Birmingham (2 way)
2008 Annual Demand Central London Outer London

Rail 6,570,000 740,000

Highway 1,980,000 5,290,000

Total 8,550,000 6,030,000

4.2.3 The importance of city centre to city centre travel in the rail market suggested it would be important
for HS2 to serve this core market effectively, since it was likely that the bulk of demand on HS2
would be drawn from existing rail trips. While the market to and from outer London should not be
ignored, our analysis suggested any terminus station should provide good access to the existing rail
market from central London. A central London station would tend to provide good access to this
market. However, it was unclear whether a terminus outside of central London would achieve this.

4.2.4 We considered evidence from TfL’s RailPlan model on the accessibility of different station locations
to assess how well each potential station might serve this core market. Of the non central station
locations considered by HS2, and along the line of route to Birmingham, Old Oak Common provides
the greatest accessibility, particularly with the potential for additional Crossrail and GWML
connectivity. Hence it appears to be the best potential candidate for a terminus if HS2 were limited
to non Central London stations only. Despite the potential for enhanced Crossrail services at Old Oak
Common, the station would be significantly less accessible than a central London terminus. For the
average trip using public transport to access HS2 and starting in London, the ‘cost penalty’ for going
to Old Oak Common compared to Euston is equivalent to almost a 30 minute time penalty.

4.2.5 This time penalty represents a significant additional cost on a journey from Inner London. Table 4.2b
below considers a simplified journey from inner London to Birmingham to demonstrate the impact
of the difference in access costs between Euston and Old Oak Common for the average passenger.
The table shows that a terminus station at Old Oak Common would reduce the benefits of HS2 per
passenger by over two thirds compared to a station at Euston, and as a result was likely to severely
limit demand and economic benefits. This does not consider the potential for access via car and taxi.
This may be more attractive for a station outside of central London.

Table 4.2b - Generalised Journey Time of a Trip from Inner London to Birmingham
Total Generalised
Mode Access Penalty Rail Journey Time
Journey Time
Existing Rail 44 85 129

HS2: Euston 44 50 94

HS2: Old Oak Common 74 44 118

42
Chapter 4: Central London Station Location

4.2.6 However, within this average there are some passengers in West London who would see significant
gains; it is those in the south and north of London who would find accessing a terminus at Old Oak
Common more difficult. Figure 4.2 shows that large areas of London would have better access to
Old Oak Common than to a Euston station. However Euston has better access for the core markets
within central and inner London – thus has better average accessibility for this core market.

Figure 4.2: Map Showing Areas Best Served by Stations at Old Oak Common and Euston
when Using Public Transport

4.2.7 This suggests a station outside Central London may still have a role as an interchange, allowing
even better overall access for passengers travelling to and from London. However, as a terminus
it is unlikely to be attractive. On this basis locations outside of Central London were not pursued in
detail as terminus stations, whilst the most accessible Central London stations remained terminus
options for HS2.

43
HS2 Demand Model Analysis

4.3 Analysis of Euston


4.3.1 For reasons outlined in the Summary Report, we recommend that Euston is part of the preferred
scheme. In the main the decision between central London stations was driven by environmental,
cost and engineering issues since the demand at most of the potential Central London stations sites
is likely to be similar. The impact of HS2 at Euston has been carefully analysed as described in Table
4.3a below.

Table 4.3a – Summary of Daily Demand at Euston


2033 reference year 2033 without 2033 with
Daily Demand 2008 Base year
Do Minimum Old Oak Common Old Oak Common

All day: National Rail


52,000 125,000 175,000 139,000
at Euston

AM peak 3 hours using


22,000 39,000 64,000 45,000
National Rail at Euston

Expected to use LUL


14,000 24,000 39,000 28,000
AM peak 3 hours

Source: All Day demand from PLANET Long Distance. This represents all rail trips (both long and short distance)
made on long distance trains. It therefore excludes short distance trips made on short distance services.
Am peak 3 hours demand from PLANET South. This includes all rail trips (both long and short distance) made on all
services (both long and short distance).
LUL demand is 62% of PLANET South data, as described in the footnote and is therefore includes the demand from
all rail trips both long and short distance.

4.3.2 The PLANET models indicate that in 2008 52,000 national rail passengers arrived or departed
Euston Main Line Station each weekday on long distance services. In the three-hour am peak from
7 to 10 am around 22,000 passengers arrived or departed on both long distance and short distance
services. From survey data,8 we know that in the peak period 60-70% of Euston mainline passengers
use the underground, which would correspond to 14,000 passengers.

4.3.3 While Euston Underground station is not currently the most heavily used London Underground
station, many trains passing through the station are still very crowded during the three-hour a.m.
peak. We have used the HS2 demand model (PLANET South) to look at the impact of HS2 on the
Underground. This model tends to overestimate the number of passengers using the Underground,
in part because it does not include taxis as a mode of dispersal. We are working with TfL to conduct
further detailed modelling of the impacts of HS2 around Euston, however for now PLANET South
provides a reasonable view of the impacts on the Underground network.

8 2001 London Area Transport survey (LATS) and 2008 RODS data indicates across the whole day 50% of Euston Mainline passengers use the Underground and
in the morning peak 62%. PLANET South indicates a much higher proportion of passengers. However PLANET South tends to overestimate the number of
passengers using the underground, in part because it does not include taxis as a mode of dispersal.

44
Chapter 4: Central London Station Location

4.3.4 PLANET South suggests the most heavily crowded trains are southbound on Northern and Victoria
lines where even now there are currently more than 2 passengers for every seat. The average
loading on all London Underground services going through Euston in the 3 hour morning peak is
138% as shown in Table 4.3b below.

Table 4.3b – Average Loadings on all LUL Services to and from Euston Underground Station in the
7-10am Morning Peak
2033 With HS2 2033 With HS2
2008 Without HS2 2033 Without HS2
without OOC with OOC
Average LUL Load Factor (Volume/
138% 185% 194% 191%
Seats) 7 – 10 am peak

4.3.5 This situation will continue and get worse, even without HS2. Whilst capacity on the Northern and
Victoria lines is expected to increase by around 20% (an extra 40,000 seats at Euston during the
a.m. peak) by 2018, demand on the Underground will have grown by 34% by 2021 and 61% by 2033.
Thus in the absence of further capacity enhancements, crowding on the Underground is forecast to
increase by 2033.

4.3.6 This increase is driven by several factors, many of which are related to growth in London’s economy
(which drives growth in use of the Underground network by London passengers). However, one
further element is that more people will want to travel to and from national rail stations due to the
high growth in national rail demand. At Euston, the number of passengers arriving or departing the
station – even without HS2 – is forecast to grow by 60% by 2021 and 143% by 2033. This means that
by 2033, even without HS2 there will be around 10,000 additional national rail passengers using the
underground network at Euston.

4.3.7 HS2 will add further demand. Our central case – which includes an interchange at Old Oak Common
- would result in almost 140,000 passengers arriving at or departing from Euston each day on long
distance services – an increase of 14,000 passengers compared to the case without HS2. These
passengers are made up of almost 100,000 passengers using HS2 and around 40,000 using residual
long distance classic rail services. This is equivalent to around 6,000 extra passengers during the
course of the 3 hour morning peak, of which 65% are likely to use the Underground network. This
would represent an increase of just 3% in the number of passengers on Underground trains at
Euston and increase the average load on a train to 1.91 passengers per seat (from 1.85) as shown in
Table 4.3b.

4.3.8 Overall our analysis suggests that despite the major investment provided by the PPP, by 2033
there will be increased crowding on Underground services through Euston – and it is likely further
investment may be needed to manage this. The addition of HS2 will put some further pressure on
the Underground network, but the impact is relatively small compared to the total numbers of other
underground passengers travelling through Euston. Our modelling suggests crowding on services
through Euston Underground Station will increase by 3% as a result of HS2.

45
Chapter 5:
London Interchange Station Location
Chapter 5: London Interchange Station Location

5.1 Introduction
5.1.1 This section of the report outlines the analysis that underpins our recommendations for a London
interchange station. It starts by setting out the options that were considered for modelling, before
moving on to consider the implications of a station at these locations for the core markets that an
interchange would serve. We conclude by summarising the key points behind our decision to include
Old Oak Common in the core HS2 scheme.

5.2 Options for a London Interchange Station


5.2.1 We started from a list of 11 potential station locations running approximately along the line of the
GWML between approximately Old Oak Common in the east, through to Heathrow in the west.
Following an assessment of the environmental and engineering implications of these stations 7
options were sifted out. The remaining options were considered in more detail through modelling
work. These were:
• Old Oak Common.
• Heathrow Terminal 5.
• Heathrow Terminal 6.
• Iver.

5.2.2 We further simplified the modelling of the three Heathrow options (terminals 5 and 6, and Iver) using
a single ‘modelling construct’. This assumed the best elements of all of these stations, including:
• Direct (cross platform) connectivity with GWML.
• Connectivity with Heathrow airport terminals equivalent to that offered by a station at the Central
Terminal Area.
• Connections to Crossrail, Heathrow Express and the Piccadilly line via the Central Terminal Area,
providing dispersal options to London.
• A parkway station with direct access to the M25 for HS2 passengers travelling to and from
locations outside of London.

5.2.3 This provides a ‘best case’ for Heathrow, and allows us to consider the potential size of each
component of demand. In practice no single Heathrow station option can provide all of these
elements:

• A
station at Heathrow terminal 5 would provide connectivity to the airport, to London via a
connection with Crossrail, Heathrow Express and the Piccadilly line, and parkway access.
However it would not have a connection to the GWML.

47
HS2 Demand Model Analysis

• A station at Terminal 6 is likely to provide connections to the airport, as well as London via
Crossrail and Heathrow Express. It is unlikely to have a connection to the Piccadilly line, nor have
direct access to GWML or a parkway.
• A station at Iver would have connections to GWML, and potentially to a parkway. However – whilst
a link to the airport could be established – it is unlikely to have connectivity equivalent to a station
on the airport. Similarly this is unlikely to have connections to the Piccadilly line or Heathrow
Express, and only limited Crossrail services.

5.2.4 In addition to these locations, there were three different ways a Heathrow station could be served – a
through, a loop and a spur station (see Figure 5.2). Each of these options has different implications
for the capacity of HS2, and the journey times for HS2 passengers – particularly those travelling to
London.

Figure 5.2 – Options for Serving Heathrow

A loop allowing a
through service
via Heathrow

A spur for trains


accessing Heathrow

The main route


via Heathrow

A station at or
near Heathrow

48
Chapter 5: London Interchange Station Location

5.2.5 In the case of a spur solution, one complete train path into London would be lost by every train
serving and terminating at Heathrow via the spur. Since the majority of passengers are travelling to
London, a spur option is unattractive, as the value of the capacity foregone, threatening for instance
the ability to provide a reasonable service to Birmingham or to run service between London and
Leeds via the East Midlands and Sheffield as part of a wider network, would significantly exceed the
capital cost saving of up to £1.5 bn. A spur option was therefore not considered further.

5.2.6 With a loop option, not all trains would stop at Heathrow. The assessment of HS2’s engineers is that
with optimised service patterns around the loop it would be possible to deliver this with no impact
on the capacity of the line. With a through station, a choice would need to be made on stopping
patterns:
• If all trains stop at the through station, there will be no impact on the capacity of the line. There
will, however, be significant time penalties for those passengers (the majority) travelling beyond
the through station.
• In the case of selective stopping, there will be an impact on capacity since a train slowing down
to stop at a station will have an impact on any train behind that is running at full speed (and
similarly on a further path when accelerating away from the station). This could reduce the
capacity of the line by up to one train for each train stopping at the station. It would, however,
permit a service pattern in which not all HS2 passengers suffered the time penalty of stopping at
Heathrow (though this would also reduce the number of services for those who do wish to use a
Heathrow station).

5.2.7 For the purposes of this analysis, we have focused on a through station at Heathrow where all HS2
trains stop as a comparison to a station at Old Oak Common. We are currently conducting further
analysis on Heathrow stations, including further tests of a loop stations and through stations
with selective stopping. We will publish this analysis in due course. However for the purposes of
this paper we limit the comparison of a through and loop station to a strategic comparison of the
alternatives.

5.3 The Potential Markets for a London Interchange Station


5.3.1 Reflecting our remit, we have assumed the two main objectives for a London interchange would be to:
• Provide good access for HS2 passengers to London, whilst relieving pressure at Euston.
• Provide access to Heathrow airport for HS2 passengers.

5.3.2 In addition to this, for the purposes of appraisal, we have to consider the benefits of connections to
the GWML, and to the road network that facilitate journeys to outside Greater London. The following
sections take each of these markets in turn, considering the market potential as well as the
implications of the Old Oak Common and Heathrow stations.

49
HS2 Demand Model Analysis

Improving Access to London


5.3.3 The largest market that is forecast to use HS2 is people travelling to and from locations within the
Greater London area. London already dominates the rail market – accounting for almost 80% of trips
by rail between the wider south east and the West Midlands, North West and Scotland. We forecast
this trend to continue, with over 100,000 HS2 passengers travelling to and from London each day in
2033. In our central case around 80% of passengers on HS2 are travelling to and from locations in
Greater London.

5.3.4 An interchange station would have different impacts on these passengers depending on where they
are travelling to or from. Some would see improved access times as a result of the interchange
station, particularly those travelling to and from West London. However those who do not use the
interchange station will experience journeys that are 4 minutes longer as a result of stopping at
Old Oak Common and 9 minutes longer at Heathrow – reflecting the longer route needed to serve a
Heathrow station.

Table 5.3a - Number of HS2 Passengers Travelling to and from Greater London at Different HS2
Station Locations
Daily Demand Interchange Station Euston Total

HS2 with no London Interchange 0 113,000 113,000

HS2 with OOC 31,000 84,000 115,000

HS2 with LHR Through 14,000 79,000 93,000

Note: This only includes HS2 trips whose ultimate origin or destination is in Greater London

5.3.5 Table 5.3a shows how many passengers using HS2 are accessing Greater London, and which HS2
station these passengers use. It suggests that a station at Old Oak Common would increase the total
number of passengers travelling to and from London on HS2 compared to having no interchange.
This means that the benefits of improved accessibility would more than outweigh the costs of slower
journeys for those travelling on to Euston.

5.3.6 A Heathrow station on the other hand would reduce the number of passengers on HS2 travelling
to and from London. This reflects the additional time penalties imposed on passengers travelling
to Euston – reducing demand at the Euston station – as well as the longer journey times on public
transport between a Heathrow station and many locations in Central London.

Relieving Dispersal at Euston


5.3.7 Chapter 4 has outlined the pressures on the Underground network at Euston, both with and without
HS2. It also outlines the impact of HS2 at Euston in our central case – including Old Oak Common.
We consider here further the role of the interchange in relieving pressure at Euston.

50
Chapter 5: London Interchange Station Location

Table 5.3b - Number of HS2 passengers using Euston Station


Daily Demand HS2 Passenger arriving and departing Euston

HS2 with no London Interchange 134,000

HS2 with OOC 95,000

HS2 with LHR Through 88,000

Note: This data represents all HS2 trips passing through Euston.

5.3.8 Table 5.3b shows the number of HS2 passengers arriving at and departing from Euston each day
under each scenario. The difference with Table 5.3a is that this now includes trips which may start or
end outside London, but travel via Euston. In addition to the HS2 passengers using Euston, there are
approximately 40-45,000 passengers on the residual long distance classic rail services using Euston.

5.3.9 In our central case (including Old Oak Common) this represents an increase of 14,000 passengers
through the day compared to no HS2 (6,000 passengers during the three morning peak hours).
The net effect of this would be to increase passengers and crowding on London Underground lines
running through Euston by around 3% during the morning peak.

5.3.10 Without a London interchange station, the number of passengers at Euston and on the Underground
network would be increased. Compared to our central case (which includes Old Oak Common),
there would an additional 35,000-40,000 HS2 passengers per day using Euston and an additional
11,000 using the underground in the am three hour peak. Overall this would almost quadruple the
impact of HS2 on the underground network at Euston. However even this significant growth would
only represent an increase in the level of crowding on the Underground at Euston of just 5%, since
Euston passengers make up a relatively small proportion of the total number of passengers on the
Underground network at this point.

5.3.11 A station at Heathrow would serve to reduce the number of passengers arriving or departing at
Euston up to 46,000 passengers per day. However it would do so almost entirely as a result of
longer journey times discouraging passengers using HS2 to travel to and from London, rather than
improving the dispersal of London passengers.

Access to Heathrow
5.3.12 The potential market for trips on HS2 accessing Heathrow comes from three sources:
• Surface access trips to and from Heathrow to access international flights;
• Air trips to access international flights (interlining);
• Potential for Heathrow to gain market share from competitor airports as a result of improved
accessibility.

51
HS2 Demand Model Analysis

5.3.13 This does not include domestic air passengers as these people are treated as either accessing
London, or other locations in the UK (both of which are considered separately).

5.3.14 Our modelling is designed to cover the market potential of a full high speed network, serving
both the North East and North West, as well as Scotland. Our data suggests that there are around
8,000 surface access trips per day in 2007/8 (2.5m trips per year) to and from Heathrow that might
be captured by such a network. These trips start and finish from an area north of Birmingham,
including Manchester and Glasgow, but also places like Newcastle and Edinburgh.

5.3.15 In addition to this there are around 4,000 interlining or air transfer trips made per day (1.2m trips
per year) by air between Heathrow and Glasgow and Manchester airports in 2008. A further 3,000
interlining trips per day (800,000 trips per year) come from Newcastle and Edinburgh which would
be covered by a wider network. Trips from Glasgow and Manchester airports form part of the
potential market for access to Heathrow with just HS2, while Newcastle and Edinburgh more likely
to be captured by a wider high speed network

5.3.16 A further 5,000 trips per day start or finish in an area in the region of an intermediate station.
However these are unlikely to be a potential market given that the core HS2 proposition does not
include an intermediate station.

5.3.17 This suggests that based on 2007/8 data, the market potential for existing trips that access
Heathrow from the areas served by a full high speed network is around 15,000 trips per day
(4.5m trips per year). This compares to around 145,000 trips per day forecast to use HS2 to and
from London in 2033, and 220,000 that would use a full High Speed Network (see chapter 11).

5.3.18 In practice HS2 will not be able to capture all of this potential demand. The service on the first leg of
HS2 will only provide journey time benefits to the North West and Glasgow. A large area of the North
East and Scotland – which is included in the market potential above – would not benefit from the
scheme. As a result the number of passengers that could use HS2 to travel to and from Heathrow is
likely to be much lower.

5.3.19 Our model suggests a station at Heathrow would deliver the greatest demand for access to
Heathrow, with around 2,000 passengers per day using HS2 to access the airport for international
flights. This means that even a station at Heathrow which is deliberately modelled to maximise the
attractiveness for airport passengers would represent less than 2% of the traffic on HS2.

5.3.20 This modelling assumes that HS2 will not increase the total number of passengers accessing
Heathrow. It is possible that by boosting accessibility to Heathrow, HS2 will make Heathrow more
competitive with other UK and European airports and therefore change the distribution or number
of passengers to the airport. It is difficult to assess the size of the potential for this shift. BAA in
its submission to HS2 suggested there were around 13,000 trips per day (4m trips per year) from
UK regional airports to European airports for onward connections to international flights. This is a
potential market that could transfer to Heathrow if HS2 significantly improved access to the airport.

52
Chapter 5: London Interchange Station Location

In addition, data from the CAA suggests that the market from the West Midlands and beyond for
Gatwick and Stansted combined is around 12,000 trips per day (3.7m trips per year).

5.3.21 If we include both of these, then the potential market to Heathrow would amount to around 43,000
trips per day (12.8m trips per year). Even if HS2 were to capture all of these trips, it would represent
around 20% of trips on HS2 – comparable to the number of passengers accessing UK destinations
outside London, but only around one third of the number of passengers travelling to and from
London – HS2’s core market. In practice it is unlikely HS2 would deliver such a significant change,
since it does not directly serve large parts of the markets considered (e.g. Newcastle and the North
East). A wider high speed network may capture a higher proportion of this market, but even then
it would be heavily dependent on the competitive responses of airlines and airport operators both
within the UK and Europe.

Trips to and from Locations Outside of London


5.3.22 HS2 passengers would have a variety of different origins and destinations. We have already seen that
the majority of passengers would travel to and from the Greater London area. However a significant
number (almost 20%) would be travelling to and from locations outside of London. An interchange
station would enhance access for these passengers. For example someone travelling between
Reading and Manchester would have a journey of just under three and a half hours. With HS2 and
an Old Oak Common interchange this could fall to just over two hours with one interchange. This is
likely to be a more attractive proposition, particularly in the absence of premium fares.

5.3.23 However the design of the HS2 model raises two issues related to the size of this market. In
particular it assumes all fares between different places in the country are the same regardless
of the route taken. In practice the fare paid by passengers from places like Bristol and the South
West, using the GWML and then HS2 to reach Manchester and beyond is likely to be higher than the
equivalent Cross County trip. This difference in fare would act to discourage passengers from using
HS2, but is not taken into account by our modelling. There is also significant crowding on Cross
County routes by 2033, which increases the propensity of passengers to switch to using HS2.

5.3.24 As a result the flow of passengers using HS2 from locations in the South West is probably
overstated. This is likely to be greater at a Heathrow station than at Old Oak Common. Heathrow,
being further west, reduces the journey time of passengers in Bristol still further and – in line with
the modelling assumptions – would encourage even more trips to and from these areas. Figure 5.3
shows the difference in the destinations of passengers using a Heathrow station compared to Old
Oak Common. So a Heathrow station increases the number of HS2 trips to Reading and places close
to London (green areas), but it also increases the number of HS2 trips to more distant locations,
including Bristol and the South West. These are the areas that are most likely to be over-stated by
the model.

53
HS2 Demand Model Analysis

Figure 5.3 - Change in Number of Passengers on HS2 by Destination when Using a Heathrow
Station Compared to Old Oak Common

5.3.25 We can also see from this map the negative impact that a Heathrow station has on trips to inner
London, which now suffer from an increased journey time as a result of the longer route needed to
serve Heathrow.

54
Chapter 5: London Interchange Station Location

5.4 Comparison of Heathrow and Old Oak Common


Interchange Stations
5.4.1 We have so far considered three options for such an interchange station:
• No Interchange Station – Direct, fast trains all the way to Euston Station
• An interchange station at Old Oak Common – with direct connections to GWML and Crossrail. It is
assumed all trains on HS2, GWML, Heathrow Express and Crossrail stop at this station
• A Through Station in the Heathrow area – this would mean a revised line of route to run via
the Heathrow station (resulting in longer journey times to Euston). The station is a ‘modelling
construct’ with an assumed cross-platform interchange to GWML, Crossrail, Heathrow Express
and Heathrow Airport. Again all trains on HS2, GWML, Crossrail and Heathrow Express are
assumed to stop at this station. This station would also offer car parking for passengers to drive
to the station.

5.4.2 Table 5.4 shows the numbers of passengers using Euston and the interchange station under each
option.

Table 5.4 - Distribution of HS2 Passengers using Interchange and Euston Stations
London Interchange Passengers going to or from

Daily Demand Greater London Airport Access Other Total

No Interchange 0 0 0 0

Old Oak Common 31,000 1,000 17,000 50,000

Heathrow through 14,000 2,000 24,000 40,000

Euston Passengers going to or from Total HS2


Passenger
Daily Demand Greater London Airport Access Other Total to London

No Interchange 113,000 1,000 20,000 134,000 134,000

Old Oak Common 84,000 0 11,000 95,000 145,000

Heathrow through 79,000 0 9,000 88,000 129,000

55
HS2 Demand Model Analysis

5.4.3 An interchange station would have a number of benefits and disbenefits:


• HS2 passengers not using the station would face a longer journey time as the train stops at the
station. This would add between 4 minutes at Old Oak Common and 9 minutes9 at Heathrow.
• Some HS2 passengers travelling to/from London would gain from reduced journey times. In
particular the Crossrail links and frequency at OOC would reduce end to end journey times for
several areas in West and East London.
• Passengers on GWML, Crossrail and Heathrow Express would face longer journeys into
Paddington as a result of stopping at Old Oak Common; GWML passengers would face this
disbenefit for an interchange at Heathrow too.
• HS2 passengers from areas to the west and south west of London would see shorter journeys
and easier access to reach HS2 services via GWML. The interchange station means these
passengers avoid the trip into Paddington and across London to reach Euston.
• Improved access for passengers travelling to Heathrow for international flights. At Old Oak
Common this is in the form of Crossrail and Heathrow Express links to the airport, while a HS2
station at Heathrow is modelled as being ‘on airport’.
• For a Heathrow station there are additional benefits for people who would access the station by
car.

5.4.4 Whether an interchange station is attractive depends on the balance of these various impacts.
The balance at an interchange station at Old Oak Common would be overall positive. Despite the
significant time penalties of stopping HS2 and GWML trains at the interchange station, the benefits
of improved accessibility for HS2 passengers would more than outweigh this. Overall the station
increases demand on HS2 by over 7% compared to having no interchange station and delivers net
benefits worth around £2bn.

5.4.5 Comparing a station at Heathrow to Old Oak Common shows a very different pattern of impacts. In
the case of Heathrow:
• There are additional disbenefits for people who use Euston. This is because the route to serve
Heathrow is longer and at lower speed (due to tunnel section). A trip to Euston would be up to 5
minutes longer than the equivalent trip via Old Oak Common.
• Heathrow is also less accessible than Old Oak Common for passengers travelling to and from
locations in Central London. The station is served by limited Crossrail services and the Piccadilly
line, and is further away from Central London. Old Oak Common on the other hand has very high
frequency Crossrail services with much shorter journeys into the centre of London.

9 The main HS2 report states the penalty for stopping trains at Heathrow via a through station is 7minutes whereas in this report we use a 9 minute penalty. This
difference is due to late engineering work which has suggested our early estimates of the journey time were overstated by 2 minutes.
We have not in the time available re-run the model with this revised journey time, and hence the results presented in this Chapter are on the basis of a 9 minute
journey time. We are conducting further analysis on Heathrow which we will publish in due course. However, we do not believe this change in journey time will
substantively change our conclusions.

56
Chapter 5: London Interchange Station Location

• However a Heathrow station does improve journey times for passengers travelling to Heathrow,
and transferring to/from HS2 to/from locations to the west and south west of London. The station
is further to the west, and therefore journey times from a Heathrow station to, say, Reading on
the GWML would be significantly faster than the equivalent journey from Old Oak Common.

5.4.6 These differences are reflected in the modelled number of passengers using HS2, and the places
they are travelling to and from. With an interchange at Heathrow, the number of passengers using
Euston falls by almost 7% because journey times from Euston to Birmingham and beyond would be
longer on a route serving Heathrow. This reduces the attractiveness of HS2 for mode shift (whether
from classic rail or car), as well as reducing the number of new trips generated by the scheme.

5.4.7 The number of passengers travelling to and from locations in Greater London using the Heathrow
station is also less than half the number at Old Oak Common since the station is far less accessible
for London than Old Oak Common. The average end to end journey time for London passengers is
longer using the Heathrow interchange, and this has a significant impact on the attractiveness of the
station. This is partially off-set by around 6,000 more passengers using the Heathrow interchange
to leave/join HS2 from locations to the west and south west of London, who have shorter journey
times on the GWML. However the greater number of passengers going to locations outside London
is not enough to offset the loss of passengers travelling to and from London. As a result the overall
number of passengers on HS2 with a Heathrow interchange falls by over 10% compared with an HS2
with no interchange. This also has the impact of reducing revenues by some £1.3bn.

5.4.8 There are some uncertainties in the precise benefits of the station at Heathrow. Our model will
understate some of the benefits since it is designed to focus on HS2 passengers. As a result it does
not model the demand or benefits of a Heathrow station for people in (say) Reading who might use
the station to get to Heathrow via the GWML.

5.4.9 However there are some areas where the modelling overstates the benefits of a Heathrow station.
Firstly, as discussed in Section 5.3, the model may not accurately reflect fares for passengers
choosing between direct rail routes and travelling via London. In particular the model assumes all
routes have the same fare – so Bristol to Manchester costs the same regardless of whether a direct
cross-country train is used or travelling via London on HS2. The latter route is likely to cost more in
practice.

5.4.10 In addition the Heathrow station is designed as a ‘modelling construct’ to identify the maximum
demand in each of the markets considered above. It assumes the station is located at Heathrow
central terminal area (to maximise connectivity for Heathrow passengers, but also has cross-
platform connections to Crossrail and Piccadilly lines), and has a direct (cross-platform) interchange
with the GWML. In practice a Heathrow station is unlikely to deliver all of these connections.

57
HS2 Demand Model Analysis

5.4.11 Overall therefore our conclusion is that a station at Heathrow is less attractive than a station at
Old Oak Common. Our modelling suggests that overall there would be significant disbenefits of a
Heathrow station compared to Old Oak Common. This is because:
• A station at Heathrow would cost significantly more than the equivalent station at Old Oak
Common. This is equivalent to £2-3bn (PV, 2009 prices).
• There is a significant reduction in revenues as a result of lower patronage. This would be
equivalent to adding £1.3bn to the cost to government of HS2.
• Overall a station at Heathrow would reduce benefits to HS2 passengers by £2.6bn compared to
a station at Old Oak Common. This reflects the fact that the benefits to GWML passengers are
not sufficient to offset the additional journey time penalties and longer access times for those
travelling to Euston, and more generally to Greater London.

5.4.12 This suggests that a through station at Heathrow is not attractive for the purposes of HS2. Our
model does not, though, have the capability to investigate the benefits of improved connectivity
between the airport and passengers in the South East and South West through, for instance,
improved connections to the GWML and other rail links such as Airtrack which could be delivered
without the need for HS2 to serve a Heathrow station.

5.4.13 We are continuing to investigate the implications of a station in the Heathrow area to allow a greater
understanding of how the impact of issues such as the over-estimation of trips from the South West,
and a loop station rather than a through station may have on the business case. We will publish this
work in due course, but based on our current understanding of the issues we do not expect this to
change the business case substantially.

5.4.14 We also expect the conclusion to hold for a loop as well as a through station. While a loop would
have the advantage of not having any journey time penalty for those on direct trains to London (i.e.
not using the loop):
• Service frequencies would be substantially reduced at the Heathrow station, making it less
attractive than Old Oak Common as an interchange for passengers from Reading and other
locations outside London.
• It would not have the accessibility of a station at Old Oak Common for passengers travelling to
and from London.

58
Chapter 6:
Intermediate Station Location
HS2 Demand Model Analysis

6.1 Introduction
6.1.1 An intermediate station would generate benefits for local passengers by providing fast services into
London and Birmingham. In the same way as HS2 can achieve a step change in connectivity for long
distance trips, so an intermediate station could provide a step change for shorter distance trips,
particularly commuting trips into London.

6.1.2 This chapter sets out the analysis we used to determine whether an intermediate station would add
to the overall business case for HS2. Our approach to intermediate stations consisted of three stages
of work:
• We used analysis from the ‘ready reckoner’ to consider which locations were most likely to
generate significant demand and benefits from an intermediate station.
• Partial model runs were undertaken to look at the potential benefits to passengers using the
intermediate station.
• Additional analysis considered whether these benefits were sufficient to outweigh the disbenefits
to longer distance passengers on HS2.

60
Chapter 6: Intermediate Station Locaation

6.2 Determining a Location


6.2.1 During the early stages of route design there was a wide range of potential locations for an
intermediate station. This included towns within a corridor ranging from Oxford in the south
to Luton, Bedford and Kettering in the North. An initial assessment of the level of demand was
undertaken for a number of these potential locations as shown in Figure 6.2 below.

Figure 6.2 – Potential location of Intermediate Stations

6.2.2 It became clear that the principal demand would be on commuting trips into London. Whilst there
would be some demand for trips into Birmingham, these were much smaller than those to London.
For example, the number of passengers during peak hours on the WCML and Chiltern lines into
Birmingham is 40% lower than the equivalent flows into London. For this reason, the analysis is
restricted to passenger flows between an intermediate station and London. Table 6.2a below gives
the annual number of trips between London and the locations considered.

61
HS2 Demand Model Analysis

Table 6.2a – 2004 Annual Rail Demand between London and Potential Intermediate Station Locations
2008 Annual Rail Demand 2008 Annual Rail Demand
Location Location
to\from London to\from London
Aylesbury Vale 0.8m Warwick 0.8m

Bicester 0.6m Luton 3.3m

Banbury 0.6m Kettering 0.5m

Milton Keynes 2.1m Bedford 1.8m

Coventry 0.7m Northampton 1.9m

Rugby 0.5m Oxford 1.5m

Source: PLANET Long Distance

6.2.3 From this list, three locations were considered for further work – Aylesbury, Bicester and Milton
Keynes. These three locations offered the greatest opportunities for demand on a high speed line –
either with significant demand today, or significant potential for time savings (and therefore demand
growth). A station at Oxford was also considered, however the environmental and engineering
challenges in serving such a station were significant, and for this reason the station at Bicester
was used as an alternative site – offering potential connections with Oxford and other Chiltern Line
locations.

6.2.4 These locations were also representative of the various options which remained for consideration
after initial sifting of routes. Route options that might have served Luton, Bedford and Kettering
were sifted out at an early stage and therefore not pursued for demand modelling purposes. If
we had found a compelling case for an intermediate station, we might have reviewed these route
options (given the size of the potential market, particularly at Luton). However in practice the
conclusions drawn below would apply to any intermediate station.

Benefits to Local Passengers


6.2.5 The four locations were modelled using PLANET South. We assumed 400m (1,100 seat capacity)
high speed trains running from these locations, with time savings of up to 30 minutes over current
journey times to London. Table 6.3 gives the results of modelling conducted using PLANET South
on the shortlisted station locations. The results suggested that – even with significant time savings
– there would be insufficient demand from Aylesbury to support an intermediate station. However
there could be significant demand from a station at either Milton Keynes or Bicester. In both
locations, but particularly at Bicester, links with the wider rail network were important in generating
demand from the station.

62
Chapter 6: Intermediate Station Locaation

Table 6.2b - Passenger Volumes and Transport User Benefits from High Speed Rail at Intermediate
Station Locations, Excluding Impacts on Other HS2 Passengers

Aylesbury Milton Keynes Bicester


Demand in 2033 (passengers in am peak only)
1,950 8,700 6,400

User Benefits (£m) 90 330 420


Am Peak Hours
Revenue (£m) -1 230 200

User Benefits (£m) 310 1,680 2,210


All Day
Revenue (£m) -70 1,040 970

6.2.6 The table shows the benefits from the stations would also be significant, with both Milton Keynes
and Bicester offering benefits of £500-600m for peak services, rising to £2.6-3.4bn if services
continue throughout the day. The revenues from these stations would more than cover the costs
of constructing the station. However this analysis ignores the impact of an intermediate station on
other HS2 passengers (and vice versa).

Impacts on Wider HS2 passengers


6.2.7 Stopping at an intermediate station would have several impacts on long distance HS2 passengers
that are the core of HS2 demand:
• T
rains which stop at an intermediate station would add up to 5 minutes onto the journey time to
Birmingham and beyond as trains decelerate from top speed, stop at the station and accelerate
back to speed. This would reduce the demand and of trips on HS2 over longer distances.
• H
S2 trains would be relatively crowded, particularly in the peaks. This means that in order to
meet demand at the intermediate station, there would either be very high levels of crowding, or
the train would need to arrive with empty seats. This would limit the number of seats available to
long distance passengers and is an inefficient use of capacity.
• A
nd stopping a train at an intermediate station can have a dramatic effect on the total number of
train paths available on HS2 as they decelerate and accelerate away from the station stop.

6.2.8 We have not explicitly modelled the cost of the time penalty, but it is relatively simple to identify the
potential size of this impact. There are two measures that can be used:
• A
station stop would effectively increase journey times between London and locations north of
the intermediate station by 5 minutes. Using average values of time, the value of the 5 minute
time penalty for stopping a train of 500 passengers would be equivalent to a cost of around £8m
(PV 2009). This is equivalent to £800m if three trains per hour in each direction stop throughout
the day

63
HS2 Demand Model Analysis

• Data from early model runs suggests the impact of a 1 minute longer journey would be to reduce
the benefits of HS2 by around £300-600m. This suggests stopping every train would have a
disbenefit of £1.5-3bn. Stopping three trains per hour is equivalent to around 25% of trains, which
suggests a disbenefit of around £0.375-0.75bn.

6.2.9 Using either method it is clear that the cost to through passengers is likely to be significant, but this
penalty alone does not outweigh the benefits to local passengers at the intermediate station. This
suggests that if we could provide sufficient capacity to an intermediate station without impacting on
the capacity of the main line then an intermediate station could be attractive.

6.2.10 However in practice the impacts of an intermediate station on capacity are likely to make such a
station unattractive. Two points are of particular importance:
• T
rains using HS2 are forecast to be relatively full with long distance passengers (particularly
during peak hours). Hence the additional demand from an intermediate station would either
create significant additional crowding, or require additional services to be run – for which there is
insufficient capacity.
• Trains stopping at the intermediate station would result in the loss of up to 1 train path per train
stopping. So stopping three trains per hour would effectively consume 20% of the capacity of HS2.

6.2.11 These impacts on capacity have significant implications for the design of a wider high speed
network. In particular it would effectively preclude the extension of HS2 to serve Leeds and other
new markets to the east of the country. As discussed in chapter 11, the potential benefits for such an
extension are likely to significantly outweigh the benefits of an intermediate station.

6.2.12 As a result we concluded that an intermediate station would have a detrimental impact on the case
for high speed rail, particularly in the long run.

64
Chapter 7:
Central Birmingham Station Location
HS2 Demand Model Analysis

7.1 Introduction
7.1.1 This chapter summarises the demand and appraisal analysis underlying our recommendation on
the location of a station in Birmingham city centre. The preferred station site is at Fazeley Street,
adjacent to the existing Moor Street station and immediately to the north of the WCML leading into
New Street station.

7.1.2 All of the station locations considered by HS2 were close to central Birmingham in a similar location
with similar access characteristics. Birmingham New Street would offer benefits in terms of
improved interchange opportunities, but the engineering challenge, and the impact on capacity on
the classic rail network meant this option was not taken forward. Our demand modelling was not
sensitive enough to pick up differences in demand that might result from other station locations, and
therefore wider engineering and environmental considerations drove the choice of station. Analysis
of demand was instead used to determine the overall market for a central Birmingham HS2 station,
as well as the impact of HS2 on existing rail services serving Birmingham.

7.2 The Impact of HS2


7.2.1 In the absence of HS2, rail demand at Birmingham New Street and Moor Street is set to grow
between now and 2033 by around 65%, increasing from 141,000 to 232,000 users per day. This
represents boarders, alighters and interchange passengers, but not through passengers on all short
and long distance services.

7.2.2 Table 7.2 outlines the impact of HS2 at the major Birmingham Stations – both classic and high speed
rail. Building HS2 into Birmingham Fazeley Street would see Fazeley Street used by 31,000 HS2
passengers per day in 2033 in our central case. Around 25-30%10 of these passengers would use
classic rail services into New Street or Moor Street in order to access HS2 services. The rest would
access Fazeley Street by walking, using non rail public transport or car. Our models are not detailed
enough to understand the impact of HS2 on the local road or bus networks, although we do not
consider that this issue will have a significant impact on the choice of central Birmingham station
location.

7.2.3 We forecast that New Street would see a net reduction of 36,000 passengers per day which would
help overcrowding at New Street as well as the surrounding local transport network. Moor Street
would see a net increase of 3,000 passengers per day. The change in demand at New Street and
Moor Street is driven by the following behaviours:
• Reduced demand as a result of passengers transferring from classic rail long distance services
onto HS2 services using Fazeley Street or Birmingham Interchange.
• Increased demand as a result of new HS2 passengers using local rail services in order to access
Fazeley Street.

10 The National Rail Travel Survey suggests that 30% of New Street Passengers use local rail services to access or egress the station. PLANET is forecasting 25%.

66
Chapter 7: Central Birmingham Station Location

• I ncreased demand as a result of new classic rail passengers on services on the classic rail
network using capacity released by HS2.

Table 7.2 – All day Demand at Birmingham Stations with and without HS2
Daily Boardings and Alightings 2033 Without HS2 2033 With HS2 with 2033 With HS2 without
(including interchanges) Parkway Parkway
Moor Street 19,000 22,000 24,000

New Street 213,000 177,000 179,000

International 28,000 14,000 16,000

HS2 Fazeley Street 0 31,000 50,000

HS2 Parkway 0 23,000 0

TOTAL 259,000 268,000 268,000

Note: This data is a combination of long distance all day demand extracted from PLANET Long Distance and PLANET
Midlands short distance demand from the 7-10am morning peak. We have applied a factor of 3 to convert the peak
demand to all day demand and produce total all day demand.

7.2.4 The impact of an HS2 Birmingham Interchange station near Birmingham International reduces the
number of passengers using Fazeley Street. Without the interchange station an extra 19,000 people
per day would use Fazeley Street. As described in chapter 2, the station choice model determines
the demand for each station based only on car accessibility. This means that Fazeley Street, which
is more accessible by public transport than the interchange station, may get more passengers than
our modelling suggests.

Summary
7.2.5 An HS2 station at Fazeley Street would be used by 31,000 passengers per day (boarders and
alighters), with 25-30% accessing this station by rail. New Street would see a net reduction of 36,000
passengers per day while Moor Street would see a net increase of 3,000 passengers per day.

67
Chapter 8:
Birmingham Interchange Station
Location
Chapter 7: Central Birmingham Station Location

8.1 Introduction
8.1.1 This chapter summarises the analysis underlying the recommendation of the HS2 report to include
an interchange station near Birmingham International Airport. Its structure mainly follows the work
as it evolved over time. Section 8.2 summarises the early analytical approach that identified potential
locations for an interchange station on the outskirts of Birmingham and also covers the selection of
a shortlist of options. Section 8.3 outlines the selection of a location near Birmingham International
Airport and section 8.4 the business case.

8.2 Option Sifting


8.2.1 Initially we examined a number of potential interchange stations around the outskirts of Birmingham
from the north-west (Walsall/ Wolverhampton) to the south as far as Warwick Parkway. These
locations were selected to investigate different types of potential markets, rather than reflecting
preferred locations or route choices. The aim of this analysis was to understand whether different
parkway locations, particularly to the North or West of Birmingham, would have a significant enough
impact on demand to overcome separately identified engineering and environmental issues.

8.2.2 Table 8.2 shows the number of people living within a 45 minute car journey time of different areas of
Birmingham, as well as the number of car trips made between London and that catchment area. The
former measure gives an indication of the potential for demand on HS2, the latter represents one
measure of existing demand and the potential for mode shift. The largest populations are generally
found around locations to the north and west of Birmingham including sites close to Wolverhampton,
Walsall, Dudley and Castle Bromwich. Although areas to the south east of Birmingham have
somewhat lower population densities, there are many more car trips to and from London, in part
because accessing London is much easier.

69
HS2 Demand Model Analysis

Table 8.2: Population and Car Journeys to London within 45 minutes of potential interchange station
locations

Area 2001 Population Car Trips to or from London Daily

Solihull 817,000 810

Birmingham International 1,058,000 1210

Warwick 612,000 980

Birmingham SE 927,000 1030

Birmingham South 1,252,000 1060

Coventry North 660,000 780

M42 North east 960,000 670

Castle Bromwich 1,303,000 530

Wolverhampton 1,292,000 360

Walsall 1,253,000 370

M54 North 1,000,000 420

Dudley 1,214,816 380

Source: West Midlands PRISM Model

8.2.3 Analysis of existing rail journeys from the West Midlands to London and the South East reveals a
similar pattern: generally the zones to the south east of Birmingham have the strongest existing
demand. This picture is even stronger if we only consider those travellers who access the station by
car. Our analysis at this stage was therefore suggesting two distinct areas of demand:
• To the north and west of Birmingham, there was a large potential market and also the scope that these
areas would gain significant time savings on a rail journey to London (in some cases up to 1 hour).
• To the south and east there was a good existing market and scope for mode shift – but perhaps
slightly lower benefits per trip.

8.2.4 Engineering work on the Birmingham central station and line of route, suggested that any route
options through Birmingham and on to the potential parkway locations to the North West would at
best be extremely expensive (see HS2’s report). Whilst the area to the North West of Birmingham
has higher population and potential demand, simple elasticity11 based demand analysis did not
suggest sufficient evidence to suggest benefits would be enough to overcome the cost and technical
challenges of reaching a station in these locations. Therefore interchange stations to the north west
of Birmingham were not taken forward for more detailed consideration.

11 The application of elasticities has limitations in cases when there are large changes in journey times – as would potentially be the case here. However,
demand would need to be very high (compared to the south and east) to overcome the substantial difficulties with a line of route to serve the interchange
locations to the north and west of Birmingham.

70
Chapter 8: Birmingham Interchange Station Location

8.2.5 On the basis of the demand analysis, and following stakeholder consultations, three locations were
identified for more detailed analysis – Solihull, near Birmingham International Airport, and Water
Orton. All of these lie to the East and South East, coinciding with the M42/M6 corridor and providing
good connections to the road network. These connections were particularly important to improving
both the accessibility of the station and the potential for mode shift.

8.3 An Interchange near Birmingham International


8.3.1 To test the relative merits of the three shortlisted stations in terms of demand, we used a near
final version of the model to test each option. Subsequent to this work, the model underwent
further improvements in the way the London station location is represented. However, in terms of
calculating the relative demand or benefits between the three Birmingham interchange options,
there should be little difference between the interim version used and the final model.

8.3.2 For comparative purposes, we used an indicative train service specification that assumed only
services between Birmingham and London stop at the interchange station, with all other HS2
trains passing through non-stop. This is not to say there is no case for stopping other trains at the
interchange, rather that in the time available for testing between different station locations we did
not include these markets. We also did not allow passengers to travel between the interchange
station and central Birmingham.

8.3.3 The demand and benefits of all three locations are remarkably similar. On the measure of overall
benefits, the highest is less than 2% above the lowest. Even on the individual measures of leisure
or business time savings and revenue the largest differences do not exceed 10%. Against the
uncertainties generally involved in modelling, these differences are not significant. The three
stations would be seen as near perfect substitutes from a demand and benefits aspect.

8.3.4 This insight allowed us to focus on engineering and environmental considerations in order to identify
the optimal location for a potential Interchange station. As outlined in HS2’s report, the work on
preferred line of route led to the exclusion of the Solihull corridor. A station at Water Orton would be
consistent with the line of route. However, constructing a station close to the proposed delta junction
would most likely incur much larger costs than choosing Birmingham International Airport instead.

8.3.5 Birmingham International Airport was therefore selected as the best candidate. It also provided the
best fit with development aspirations in the area and was strongly supported by stakeholders. These
aspirations may also enhance the economic case that we have modelled for an HS2 interchange
station in this area.

71
HS2 Demand Model Analysis

8.4 Demand and Benefits of Birmingham Interchange


8.4.1 Having identified the best location for a Birmingham Interchange at a location near Birmingham
International Airport, we tested its overall contribution to the business case and whether an
interchange station should be part of the preferred scheme. The interchange station benefits
passengers who have easier access to an interchange than a central Birmingham station. Some
interchange passengers would not choose to travel on HS2 in the absence of a station, while some
passengers would instead use central Birmingham but suffer a slower journey. In addition, the
journey time to London is assumed to be nine minutes shorter from the Interchange than from the
central station.

8.4.2 On the other hand stopping trains at an interchange creates a longer journey time for through
passengers not using the station. We have estimated trains from London to central Birmingham will
take five minutes longer if they stop at Birmingham Interchange on the way, as the trains would not
be travelling at top speed at this point.

8.4.3 The modelling suggests that the balance between these two opposing effects is positive. The
overall benefit to users is likely to be just less than £1bn, in present value terms. It not only benefits
passengers using HS2 but increases demand for HS2 services and so delivers additional revenue
worth £300m to off set the costs of building the station.

8.4.4 We estimate that 40-50% of people travelling to or from Birmingham would be using the interchange
station. Figure 8.4a below shows the origin/destination for which travellers prefer it over the central
station in blue.

72
Chapter 8: Birmingham Interchange Station Location

Figure 8.4a – Proportion of Passengers Choosing to use Fazeley Street and Birmingham
Interchange by Area

7DPZRUWK

:ROYHUKDPSWRQ

1XQHDWRQ

+6&HQWUDO
+6&HQWUDO

+63DUNZD\
+63DUNZD\

3URSRUWLRQRI3DVVHQJHU'HPDQG
35,60=RQHV
0RUHWKDQYLD+6&HQWUDOVWDWLRQ
WR
&RYHQWU\
WR
WR
WR
WRYLD+63DUNZD\VWDWLRQ
WR
WR
WR

0RUHWKDQ

8.4.5 This shows that some travellers choose the interchange station even though they are starting from/
travelling to a location fairly close to the central station as their total journey time is optimised.
Figures 8.4b and 8.4c show the minimum access time to a high speed station without and with
an interchange station at Birmingham International. These show the significant improvements to
accessibility for residents in the districts to the East of central Birmingham. The interchange station
is accessible in close to 30 minutes for residents in a wider corridor from Rugby and Coventry in the
south east to Hednesford and Burton upon Trent in the north.

73
HS2 Demand Model Analysis

Figure 8.4b – Minimum Access Time to Fazeley Street by Origin Zone

74
Chapter 8: Birmingham Interchange Station Location

Figure 8.4c – Minimum Access Time to Fazeley Street or Parkway by Origin Zone

8.4.6 As outlined above, the area around Birmingham International Airport exhibits strong highway
demand to London. The model suggests a slight decrease in the flow of car journeys between
the two areas due to introducing the interchange station. This difference in road trips implies for
example around 300 fewer car journeys on the M1 on an average day

8.4.7 Our proposals for the interchange station include car parking and new connections onto the
strategic road network (see HS2 main Report and Arup supporting documentation). Our estimate
is that in 2033, the interchange station would attract a net addition of 1500-2000 cars trips to the
area during the morning peak hour. The highway impacts of this have been modelled using the West
Midlands’ multi-modal transport model PRISM. The results do not appear to indicate a significant
worsening in performance in addition to that caused by background growth.

75
HS2 Demand Model Analysis

Appraisal of Birmingham Interchange


8.4.8 HS2’s report sets out an estimated construction cost of £465m for the interchange station. For the
appraisal, this figure was adjusted to £535m to include optimism bias, market prices and discounted
to a 2009 present value. In addition, station operating and maintenance costs were estimated at
around £76m (PV, 2009) to make a total present value of costs of £611m. Finally, the increased
spending on rail fares and reduction in car fuel consumed would lead to a loss in indirect tax of
around £17m.

8.4.9 Net of changes in revenue, the present value of costs comes to around £340m (£611m construction
and operating costs offset by £271m revenue). With benefits of just under £1bn, the benefit cost ratio
is 2.9 (excluding WEBS). This delivers a robust business case for including an interchange station in
the preferred scheme.

76
Chapter 9:
Connections to High Speed One
HS2 Demand Model Analysis

9.1 Introduction
9.1.1 We were asked to review options for linking HS2 with HS1. This chapter sets out the methodology
and assumptions used to analyse the different options under consideration. The analytical approach
that has been developed for this purpose is far simpler than the approach used for analysing other
elements of HS2 as set out elsewhere in this report. In this case the approach is designed to provide
an indicative estimate of the potential demand for international travel via different types of HS1
connections and services, and the likely business case of each option.

9.2 Our Approach to Modelling International Demand


9.2.1 Our approach to forecasting the potential rail demand for international trips has been developed
by the consultancy SKM and implemented within a spreadsheet model. The approach uses data
collected from a number of different domestic and international rail corridors to understand the rail
market share for different journey times (particularly drawing on work by Steer Davies Gleave12).
Figure 9.2 shows each of these data points as dots, from which a single functional relationship (logit
curve) was derived between journey time and mode share and as shown by the curve.

12 Steer Davies Gleave (2006) Air and Rail Competition and Complimentarity. Prepared for European Commission DG TREN

78
Chapter 9: Connections to High Speed One

Figure 9.2 – Relationship between Rail Journey Time and Market Share

Rail share of Total Market


100%
pre 2000
90%
2000-2004

80% 2005-2009

not high speed


70%
logit curve
Rail market share

60%

50%

40%

30%

20%

10%

0%
0 50 100 150 200 250 300 350 400 450 500
Rail Journey Time (mins)

9.2.2 The data points and corresponding logit curve in Figure 9.2 are based only on the rail journey time,
and hence take no account of elements of generalised cost such as frequency, crowding, fare or
check in time. The calibration of the logit curve is based on existing markets in which rail and air
successfully compete. We assume therefore that relative fares between rail and air do not change
with the introduction of HS2 and are similar to other markets where rail and air compete. We also
do not take account of differences in service frequency that might occur in the scenarios considered
below, although we note the implications in our conclusions.

9.2.3 There is rather more ambiguity as to whether implicit within the logit curve is the inclusion of a
check in time for international services. Many of the data points in Figure 9.2 are based on domestic
markets where check in time does not exist. This does not relate to whether a passenger has to
check in for international services at some point on their journey - in all scenarios we assume they
do – rather whether this time should be included or excluded in the calculations used in the logit
model for forecasting rail mode share.

79
HS2 Demand Model Analysis

9.2.4 To reflect this uncertainty we have undertaken a range of sensitivity tests in which we vary the check
in time of both the reference case (without HS2) and the HS2 scenario under test. The numbers we
report here use a mid point based on a check in time of 30mins, with the low end of a range based
on a check in time of 65minutes and the high end based on 0 minutes. This variation in check in time
can make a significant difference to the demand, roughly doubling the number of international rail
trips.

9.2.5 The model for estimating the demand for international rail travel then makes use of the logit
relationship derived in Figure 9.2 by applying the following approach:
• The current end to end rail journey times between several major UK and continental cities
were calculated and are shown in Table 9.2a below. These cities were chosen as they were
felt to represent the biggest potential markets for international rail travel that might use HS2.
The overall journey times were calculated from existing timetables and included the time spent
on board a train, as well as a 40 minute penalty for making an interchange in London and a
15 minute penalty for making an interchange on the continent. As already described we also
included a 30minute check in time penalty within a range of 0-65minutes.
• Using these journey times, rail’s likely overall share of the market was estimated using the logit
function shown in Figure 9.2. For instance, if the overall rail journey time between two places is
200 minutes then we would expect rail trips to constitute half of the total rail/air market.
• Forecast data on the expected size of the future air market between each of the modelled city
pairs was provided by DfT and taken from their air passenger forecasting model.
• Applying rail’s market share to the total air market establishes the size of the rail market.
This is converted to a daily total using an annualisation factor of 300. In the absence of HS2
(our reference case) the expected number of daily rail trips between various city pairs is
shown in Table 9.2b. It can be seen that the total number of international rail trips between the
continent and Birmingham, Manchester, Liverpool and Glasgow is approximately 1,700 trips
per day (in both directions). The biggest markets by a considerable margin are Birmingham
and Manchester to Brussels and Paris, with Paris being double the market than Brussels and
Birmingham a slightly larger market than Manchester.
• The impact of different high speed rail connections can then be modelled by adjusting the rail
journey times to reflect different types of international connection or service and seeing how the
size of the rail market will change. It is worth noting that in this approach improved rail journey
times will capture a bigger proportion of the air market, but the approach will not grow the
overall size of the market.

80
Chapter 9: Connections to High Speed One

Table 9.2a -Current End to End Rail Journey Times without HS2 (Reference Case)
Rail Journey Time (mins) Amsterdam Brussels Paris Cologne Frankfurt Lyon

Birmingham 491 274 289 480 565 551

Manchester 535 318 333 524 609 595

Liverpool 535 318 333 524 609 595

Edinburgh 677 460 475 666 751 737

Glasgow 677 460 475 666 751 737

Table 9.2b - 2033 Daily 2-way International Rail Trips without HS2 (Reference Case)

Daily TOTAL
Amsterdam Brussels Paris Cologne Frankfurt Lyon
Demand (Range)

820
Birmingham 20 350 440 0 10 0
(490-1260)

680
Manchester 20 200 460 0 0 0
(410-1060)

190
Liverpool 10 0 180 0 0 0
(110-290)

40
Edinburgh 0 10 30 0 0 0
(20-50)

0
Glasgow 0 0 0 0 0 0
(0-10)

TOTAL 50 560 1,100 0 10 0 1,730


(Range) (30-80) (340-870) (660-1710) (0-0) (10-20) (0-0) (1040-2680)

81
HS2 Demand Model Analysis

9.3 Analysis of Different International Connections and


Services
9.3.1 We reviewed four scenarios for connecting HS2 with HS1:
• Running direct international high speed services between Birmingham, Paris and Brussels via
a connection between HS1 and HS2. Potentially these direct services could also run to other
destinations North of Birmingham.
• Running direct international high speed services between Old Oak Common and Paris and
Brussels via a connection between HS1 and HS2. This would allow all HS2 passengers (not
just those from Birmingham) an easy interchange onto HS1 services at Old Oak Common, and
potentially a higher frequency international service.
• Not doing anything to improve connectivity between HS2 and HS1, and simply allowing
passengers to transfer between Euston and St. Pancras by existing means (walk, tube, bus, or
taxi).
• A ‘people mover’ between Euston and St Pancras to make the transfer between these stations
quicker and easier than at present. This might also benefit domestic passengers if it aided
dispersal at the station.

9.3.2 The key variables for modelling each of these scenarios are our assumptions on the time taken to
interchange between HS2 and HS1, the frequency of train services and variation in journey time. For
all the scenarios it is assumed that there is a 30 minute reduction in journey time between London
and the North as a result of HS2 trains travelling faster than the existing classic line. In addition,
each scenario makes different assumptions about the size of the London interchange penalty. Table
9.3a below summarises how the existing rail journey times in Table 9.2a would change in each of
these scenarios. We have not tried to accurately reflect the different advantages or disadvantages
of different frequency levels expected under each scenario or the small variations in journey time
provided by different route alignments for the connection between HS2 and HS1.

Table 9.3a – Journey Time Savings for Different Types of HS2-HS1 Services Compared to the
Reference Case without HS2

Saving on existing Total saving on


Saving on existing rail
Scenario interchange penalty existing rail journey
journey Time (mins)
(mins) time (mins)

Direct international services 30 40 70

HS1 Interchange at Old Oak Common 30 30 60

Walk between Euston and St Pancras 30 0 30

Euston to St Pancras People Mover 30 20 50

82
Chapter 9: Connections to High Speed One

9.3.3 For the first scenario, in which fast non-stop dedicated services run straight between Birmingham
and Paris and Brussels, our modelling estimates that by 2033 this would attract around 900
passengers to and from Paris and 700 passengers to and from Brussels per day, as shown in Table
9.3b. Even if the existence of a high speed service generated significant additional international
travel, demand is unlikely to be enough to offer a reasonably frequent service which will further
penalise the attractiveness of this option.

9.3.4 If hybrid direct international services ran on HS2 and then on classic lines to other destinations such
as Manchester, Liverpool and Scotland this might generate a further 1,500 passengers to Paris and
500 passengers to Brussels in each direction per day.

Table 9.3b - 2033 Daily 2-way International Rail trips with Direct HS2-HS1 Services

Daily TOTAL
Amsterdam Brussels Paris Cologne Frankfurt Lyon
Demand (Range)

1,640
Birmingham 60 680 880 0 20 0
(1100-2290)

1,560
Manchester 50 440 1,050 10 10 0
(1010-2220)

430
Liverpool 30 0 410 0 0 0
(280-620)

80
Edinburgh 0 10 60 0 0 0
(50-120)

10
Glasgow 0 10 0 0 0 0
(10-20)

TOTAL 140 1,140 2,400 10 30 10 3,720


(Range) (90-220) (760-1590) (1570-3390) (10-10) (20-50) (0-10) (2440-5260)

9.3.5 For the second scenario, in which some HS1 trains run direct between Old Oak Common rather than
St. Pancras and Paris and Brussels, our modelling suggests that by 2033 this would attract 2,200
passengers to and from Paris and 1100 passengers to and from Brussels per day as shown in Table
9.3c. Although the demand from Birmingham would be less than in the first scenario, more UK
destinations would have access to Old Oak Common using HS1 domestic trains and hence overall
demand for international services would be higher. It is also likely that Old Oak Common would offer
a higher international train frequency than would be possible running direct international trains
from Birmingham.

9.3.6 This analysis does not include demand from non-HS2 users, particularly from West London and the
Thames Valley, who might find Old Oak Common easier to access than St Pancras. Such services
could be expected to attract some of the market that would otherwise have flown from Heathrow, as
well as some who would otherwise have travelled from St. Pancras.

83
HS2 Demand Model Analysis

Table 9.3c - 2033 Daily 2-way International Rail trips with a Change at Old Oak Common

Daily TOTAL
Amsterdam Brussels Paris Cologne Frankfurt Lyon
Demand (Range)

1,520
Birmingham 100 630 810 0 10 0
(1000-2140)

1,400
Manchester 40 400 950 10 10 0
(900-2030)

390
Liverpool 20 0 370 0 0 0
(250-560)

70
Edinburgh 0 10 50 0 0 0
(40-110)

10
Glasgow 0 10 0 0 0 0
(10-20)

TOTAL 120 1,050 2,180 10 30 0 3,400


(Range) (70-190) (690-1480) (1410-3130) (0-10) (20-40) (0-10) (2190-4860)

9.3.7 For the third scenario, in which people to walk, or use existing public transport to interchange
between Euston and St Pancras, our modelling suggests in 2033 this would attract 1,600 passengers
using HS2 to or from Paris and 800 to or from Brussels as shown in Table 9.3d. Although walking
between Euston and St Pancras would attract a high journey time penalty, especially with luggage,
St Pancras is likely to offer more frequent HS1 services to the continent than would be available
from Old Oak Common.

Table 9.3d - 2033 Daily 2-way International Rail Trips with a Walk between St. Pancras and Euston

Daily TOTAL
Amsterdam Brussels Paris Cologne Frankfurt Lyon
Demand (Range)

1,160
Birmingham 0 490 620 0 10 0
(730-1710)

1,010
Manchester 30 290 680 0 10 0
(620-1510)

280
Liverpool 10 0 260 0 0 0
(170-420)

50
Edinburgh 0 10 40 0 0 0
(30-70)

10
Glasgow 0 0 0 0 0 0
(0-10)

TOTAL 80 790 1,600 0 20 0 2,500


(Range) (50-120) (500-1170) (990-2380) (0-10) (10-30) (0-0) (1550-3720)

84
Chapter 9: Connections to High Speed One

9.3.8 The final scenario, in which a light-rail link or people mover from Euston to St Pancras is provided,
would increase the demand closer to the levels of an interchange at Old Oak Common as shown in
table 9.3e.

Table 9.3e - 2033 Daily 2-way International Rail Trips with a People Mover between St. Pancras and
Euston

Daily TOTAL
Amsterdam Brussels Paris Cologne Frankfurt Lyon
Demand (Range)

1,390
Birmingham 0 580 750 0 10 0
(900-2000)

1,260
Manchester 30 360 850 10 10 0
(800-1850)

350
Liverpool 20 0 330 0 0 0
(220-510)

60
Edinburgh 0 10 50 0 0 0
(40-90)

10
Glasgow 0 0 0 0 0 0
(10-10)

TOTAL 110 960 1,980 10 20 0 3,100


(Range) (60-170) (620-1380) (1260-2870) (0-10) (10-30) (0-10) (1960-4460)

9.4 Appraisal of Journey Time Benefits


9.4.1 Along with our modelling of demand, the appraisal of benefits also follows a simple approach.
We have estimated the benefits of each scenario by comparing the change in journey times and
demand with our reference case in which HS2 is not built. Standard appraisal approaches were
applied to value this time saving and estimate the average benefit per passenger,13 which were then
discounted over 60 years to give a present value. The results of this are summarised in Table 9.4,
with the range reflecting different assumptions about check in times as described in 9.2.4.

13 The benefits have been calculated using the ‘rule of half’ to estimate the welfare benefits from the time saving that would be generated by these trips. This
implicitly assumes that there is a linear relationship between the cost of travel and demand, and that for some passengers the value of the trip may not equal
the full time saving. The approach is described in more detail in DfT’s WebTag guidance : http://www.dft.gov.uk/webtag/documents/expert/unit3.5.3.php

85
HS2 Demand Model Analysis

Table 9.4 – Summary of Benefits for Different Types of HS2–HS1 Services


Total Daily Demand 60 Year Appraisal of
Scenario (two way flow between all Benefits 2009 prices
destinations with range) (with range)
1,600 £300m
Direct international services to Birmingham
(1000-2140) (£200-£450)

Direct international services to Birmingham, 3,700 £650m


Manchester, Liverpool and Scotland (2440-5260) (£400-£950)

3,400 £500m
HS1 Interchange at Old Oak Common
(2190-4860) (£350-£750)

2,500 £220m
Walk between Euston and St Pancras
(1550-3720) (£150-£350)

3,100 £410m
Euston to St Pancras People Mover
(1960-4460) (£250-£600)

9.4.2 Depending on the choice of alignment, the capital costs of a direct link vary from £1-3.5bn. It is
unlikely that any option will cover the capital costs, and once operating costs are included the benefit
cost ratio is likely to be significantly below 1. The strongest case is likely to be a connection with a
people mover at Euston, which could add around £250-600m of benefits at much lower cost.

9.4.3 As described, these results are based on fairly simplistic analysis. The analysis does not include the
impact of:
• How overall market for international travel might change as a result of new rail services. This
means there is no ‘generated demand’, which might cause the demand and benefits to be
somewhat underestimated.
• The considerable differences in frequency of international services likely to operate under
each scenario. It is unlikely for instance that the frequency of direct international services from
Manchester or Birmingham will ever be as high as from London. This could overestimate the
demand and benefits for the scenarios running direct international services.
• The potential for non-HS2 passengers to use international trains from Old Oak Common or use
a people mover between Euston and St. Pancras. This could underestimate the demand and
benefits of these scenarios.
• How international air and rail fares might change compared to existing levels, or how airlines
might respond to this increased competition.

9.4.4 Nevertheless this analysis does provide a good indication of the likely levels of demand for
international rail travel north of London. Whilst more refined analysis may change the forecast
number of HS2 passengers making international trips, there would need to be significantly higher
demand to deliver a positive business case. Given the overall market this would seem unlikely and
we therefore consider our approach robust to support the broad conclusions that have been drawn.

86
Chapter 9: Connections to High Speed One

9.5 International Connections as Part of a Wider Network


9.5.1 The business case for running international services on HS2 would be improved if HS2 was part of
a wider high speed network to other parts of the UK. Assuming a best case scenario in which high
speed international trains serve all of the UK cities directly, the total international demand would be
4,300 passengers per day as shown in Table 9.5 below. This would generate benefits in the region of
£550-£1,200m.

Table 9.5 - 2033 Daily 2-way International Rail Trips with Direct International Services on a Wider
HS2 Network

Origin/ TOTAL
Amsterdam Brussels Paris Cologne Frankfurt Lyon
Destination (Range)

1,640
Birmingham 60 680 880 0 20 0
(1100-2290)

1,870
Manchester 60 520 1,260 10 20 0
(1250-2590)

520
Liverpool 30 0 490 0 0 0
(350-730)

250
Edinburgh 10 40 190 0 0 0
(160-360)

40
Glasgow 10 20 0 0 0 0
(20-60)

TOTAL 180 1,260 2,830 10 40 10 4,300


(Range) (110-280) (850-1740) (1880-3930) (10-20) (20-50) (0-10) (2870-6030)

Summary
9.5.2 Based on current travel patterns and behaviours, the passenger market wishing to use a
link between HS1 and HS2 would be relatively small. Even under a wider network with direct
international services the benefits are unlikely to outweigh the costs. We recognise the uncertainty
in aviation policy in the long term and the difficulty in forecasting the airlines’ reaction to a rail
link, both of which could change the future size of the market. However there would need to be a
significant increase in demand to change the conclusions outlined here.

87
Chapter 10:
The Overall Business Case for HS2
Chapter 10: The Overall Business Case for HS2

10.1 Introduction
10.1.1 We have in previous chapters set out the analysis that supports the decisions taken by HS2 and the
overall design of the scheme. This chapter draws together these elements to consider the strength
of the business case for the preferred scheme. It begins by setting out our forecasts of demand for
HS2, before moving on to consider the costs and benefits of the scheme. It concludes by looking at
the overall value for money, attempting to weigh the substantial financial and economic impacts
against the environmental and social impacts that will also occur.

10.2 Passenger Demand for HS2


10.2.1 We set out in Chapter 1 our view of the world in 2033 without HS2. This shows substantial growth in
demand for long distance rail trips and substantial increase in crowding on the WCML. Between 2008
and 2033 we forecast that demand on the WCML will double, mainly driven by people’s propensity to
travel further and more frequently as they grow wealthier. Table 10.2a sets out the forecast change in
demand without HS2 between London and the key cities that would be served by HS2.

Table 10.2a - Number of Daily Passengers to and from London without HS2
To/from London 2008 2033

Birmingham 8,300 20,500

Manchester 7,300 20,300

Liverpool 2,900 8,200

Glasgow 1,400 6,000

10.2.2 With HS2, journeys between London and Birmingham, Manchester, Liverpool and Glasgow would be
up to 30 minutes faster than current services. A new high speed line would also allow a more frequent
and reliable service, with greater rail capacity provided to Birmingham (particularly in the peak).

10.2.3 These improvements in travel time and experience would attract significant numbers of passengers
onto the high speed trains. Around 145,000 would use HS2 itself – providing faster journeys to
London. A further 15,000-20,000 passengers would use classic compatible trains without travelling
on the high speed line itself. These journeys are between places such as the north of England and
Scotland where HS2 classic compatible services replace the existing classic rail service.

10.2.4 Figures 10.2a and 10.2b below, show the change in long distance passenger flows when HS2 is
operational and the percentage loading factors on the long distance trains along the WCML and HS2.
North of Birmingham the demand for WCML and HS2 are combined – as both will use the same
tracks. Here we see significant increases in passenger flows along the WCML. There would also be a
significant net increase in long distance flows using the WCML and HS2 south of Birmingham. Overall
the number of passengers on this corridor would increase by around 61,000 (a 57% increase). This
is made up of a reduction of some 84,000 trips on the WCML into London and an increase of 145,000
trips on HS2. The HS2 services would be well used with average load factors above 60%.

89
HS2 Demand Model Analysis

Figure 10.2a – Change in Long Distance Daily Rail Trips Resulting from HS2 in 2033

Edinburgh
Edinburgh Change in long distance daily trips after the
Glasgow
Glasgow introduction of HS2, in 2033

13,850
13,850

Newcastle
Newcastle

16,810
16,810

York
York

Leeds
Leeds
Hull
Hull

22,302
22,302

Manchester
Manchester

Liverpool
Liverpool Sheffield
Sheffield
28,395
28,395
6,779
6,779
-19,115
-19,115

Stoke-on-Trent
Stoke-on-Trent
67,473
67,473 Nottingham
Nottingham

Leicester
Leicester
-45,227
-45,227 Peterborough
Peterborough

Birmingham
Birmingham

Change in volume (Day 1c vs. DM) Legend


More than 20,000
145,391
145,391
20,000 to 10,000 -84,326
-84,326
10,000 to 3,000 Oxford
Oxford
3,000 to -3,000
-3,000 to -10,000
London
London
-10,000 to -20,000 Cardiff
Cardiff Bristol
Bristol
Less than -20,000 Reading
Reading

90
Chapter 10: The Overall Business Case for HS2

Figure 10.2b – 2033 Rail Load Factors with HS2

Edinburgh
Edinburgh Forecast daily load factors on long
Glasgow
Glasgow distance services after the
60
60
43
43 introduction of HS2, in 2033

43
43

Newcastle
Newcastle

52
52

York
York

Leeds
Leeds
Hull
Hull

69
69
69
Manchester
Manchester

Liverpool
Liverpool Sheffield
Sheffield

45
45 77
77

62
62
Stoke-on-Trent
Stoke-on-Trent
Nottingham
Nottingham

Leicester
Leicester
53
53 Peterborough
Peterborough
35
35

Birmingham
Birmingham

61
61
Day 1c Crowding Legend
(Volume over seats) 30
30
More than 80%
Oxford
Oxford
60% to 80%
40% to 60%
20% to 40% London
London
0 to 20% Cardiff
Cardiff Bristol
Bristol
Reading
Reading

91
HS2 Demand Model Analysis

10.2.5 These flows represent a substantial increase in passengers, particularly over longer distances.
For example the number of rail passengers travelling between Scotland and London increases
by almost 60% (with over 11,000 passengers using HS2 and a reduction of around 4,000 Classic
rail passengers). And flows on the WCML south of Glasgow more than double. Such substantial
increases could be driven by two impacts:
• Faster journeys and more access to other locations will attract more people to travel, and travel
more often (trip generation);
• Reductions in journey times may make rail more competitive with other modes (particularly air
travel in the case of Scotland), driving modal shift.

10.2.6 Table 10.2b shows the increase in the number of rail trips (both HS2 and Classic rail) to London.
There is an increase of around 7,200 trips between Scotland and London (both directions). The
majority of these trips (59%) would otherwise have used air to travel. Only around 2,800 of these
trips are new trips that are generated by the journey time savings from HS2.

Table 10.2b Increase and Source of Rail Trips (Both High Speed and Classic rail) to and from London
as a Result of HS2

Increase in Rail Source of Additional Rail Passengers


Daily Demand To/From
Passengers (HS and
London
Classic) Car Air Generation

Scotland 7,200 1% 59% 40%

North West 15,900 6% 17% 76%

West Midlands 12,200 24% 0% 76%

10.2.7 At first glance it appears surprising that there would be such a large mode shift from Glasgow,
given that HS2 trains would still take 4 hours to reach Glasgow and gain only a relatively small
improvement in journey times of 30 minutes. However international and historical experience of HSR
suggests that journey times of around 4 hours are where the rail market share is most sensitive to
changes in rail journey times. Chapter 9 describes some of this evidence, which also underpins our
model of international rail demand. This data suggests that for journey times within the range of 1 ½
hours to 5 hours, a ten minute time saving would increase the market rail market share by 3-4%.

10.2.8 Applying this data to the market between Glasgow and London suggests a reduction in rail journey
time from 4 ½ hours to around 4 hours would imply rail market share would rise from around 28%
without HS2 to about 38% - an increase of over one third. In practice the rail market share for
Scotland without HS2 is forecast to be 34%, slightly higher than the historical and international
average for journey’s over this distance. Our modelling forecasts this will increase to around 50% -
an increase which is broadly in line with the increases that have been seen in past schemes.

92
Chapter 10: The Overall Business Case for HS2

10.2.9 Trip generation becomes more important for journeys over shorter distances, where air is a less
important mode. These new trips account for over 75% of the increase in demand for rail travel
between London and the West Midlands and North West resulting from the introduction of HS2.
However, whilst trip generation is a more significant part of the increase in rail demand, Table 10.2c
shows that this represents just 20-30% of passengers on HS2. Over these distances, shift from
existing classic rail services becomes a more significant factor in HS2 demand. On average around
two thirds of passengers between London and the West Midlands and North West would otherwise
have travelled by classic rail.

Table 10.2c: HS2 Daily Demand to/from London


Source of HS2 Passengers
Daily Demand Total HSR
Classic Rail Road Air Generated
28,000 3,000 0 9,200
West Midlands 40,100
70% 7% 0% 23%
38,800 1,000 2,700 12,200
North West 54,700
71% 2% 5% 22%
4,100 100 4,200 2,800
Scotland 11,300
36% 1% 38% 25%
5,500 5,000 0 2,600
Rest of the Country 9,100
61% 55% 0% 29%
76,400 9,000 7,000 26,800
Total 115,200
66% 8% 6% 23%

10.2.10 People would travel on HS2 for a range of reasons. Faster journeys would attract more business
travel. Our modelling suggests one third of HS2 passengers would be undertaking business trips,
with a 10% overall increase in the number of long distance business trips as a result of HS2. The
majority of passengers (70%) would be people travelling for other purposes, with leisure trips likely
to be particularly important.

10.3 HS2 Appraisal Costs


10.3.1 For appraisal purposes, we consider all types of costs and need to be able to represent them in a
single figure, the Present Value of Costs (PVC). For this purpose we discount all future expenditure
back to 200914 and keep all prices constant at 2009 level. The same approach is taken for benefits
as well as revenues. The document ‘HS2 Cost and Risk Model’ provides the full detail on how the
various costs and rates have been derived. Here we focus on how these have been converted into an
appraisal PVC.

14 The green book discount rate is 3.5% for the first 30 years, falling to 3% for the next 30. In agreement with DfT we assume the 30 year period begins with
scheme opening (in 2026). Thus the 3.5% rate is used for all costs/benefits accruing before 2056, 3% thereafter.

93
HS2 Demand Model Analysis

HS2 Capital Costs


10.3.2 Paragraph 2.4.1 of the ‘HS2 Cost and Risk Model’ shows the central estimate of construction costs
for HS2 to be £12.3 billion (2009 prices) including quantitative risk assessment. Section 7 of the
same document explains the reasoning behind applying a further optimism bias of 34.3% to this
which brings the total cost of construction to £16.5bn.

10.3.3 Figure 1 of Ernst & Young’s report ‘Financial considerations – a report for HS2’ shows how this
total cost is split over the years preceding the opening of HS2 (assumed to be December 2025).
Discounting this profile of costs, the 2009 present value of all construction costs is £11.4 billion.

10.3.4 In line with WebTAG guidance15 we have converted this figure into the market price unit of account.
This represents an adjustment for taxation and government funding to ensure that costs are on
a comparable basis to the benefits estimated by the demand model. The final PV for appraisal
purposes is £13.7 billion.

10.3.5 In addition to the initial costs of construction, some elements of HS2 infrastructure would need
substantial renewal and reconstruction during the 60 year period over which we appraise HS2. The
overall impact of the following assumptions is to increase the capital costs of the scheme by £1.1bn
(PV, 2009 prices).
• Civils and structures– Asset life greater than 60 years, and therefore no renewal costs during the
appraisal period
• Railway systems – 100% renewal after 30 years
• Control systems – 100% renewal after 15 years
• Stations – complete renewal of some elements of construction after 40 years
• Depots – 50% renewal after 30 years

10.3.6 Paragraph 4.3.1 of the ‘HS2 Cost and Risk Model’ provides the cost of rolling stock including risk
and optimism bias as £2.84billion. The rolling stock is expected to have a useful life of 35 years. To
appraise the full costs over the 60 year appraisal period, we have assumed that the full stock will be
replaced after 35 years at the same cost in real terms.

10.3.7 As a 2009 present value converted into market prices rolling stock capital costs add a total of £3.0
billion, bringing the total Capital Costs to £17.9bn (PV, 2009 prices).

15 http://www.dft.gov.uk/webtag/docs/expert/affordability/3.8.1.pdf

94
Chapter 10: The Overall Business Case for HS2

HS2 Operating and Maintenance Costs


10.3.8 As outlined in the ‘HS2 Cost and Risk Model’(see table in paragraph 5.1), the annual maintenance
and operating costs for the track is estimated as £180,000 per route kilometre. Optimism bias of
41% is applied on top of this, giving total annual track operation cost of £46 million. Over 60 years
and in market prices this amounts to £0.8 billion (PV, 2009 prices).

10.3.9 The same table summarises operating and maintenance costs for the four stations forming part of
HS2. The total 2009 PV of maintenance and operation costs for stations is almost £400 million.

10.3.10 The service specification of HS2 implies a total of around 102,000 train kilometres a day. This is
a combination of 85,000 km served by 200 m long classic compatible trains and around 17,000
km served by either 200m or 400m high speed captive trains. Demand for High Speed services to
Birmingham is estimated to be sufficiently strong to justify running 400m trains for some time of the
day. As set out in section 3.6, we have modelled more 400m trains to ensure a better representation
of capacity and crowding in the model. However, for the purposes of our cost calculations we have
assumed that 50% of services between London and Birmingham would operate two train sets.

10.3.11 To convert the daily service pattern to an annual supply total, a factor of 350 has been used. This
was estimated comparing weekday to weekend service patterns on the WCML between London and
Birmingham. Applying the maintenance rate set out in section 5 of ‘HS2 Cost and Risk Model’ and
allowing for 41% optimism bias brings the annual stock maintenance costs to £180 million. The 60
year PV at market prices is £3.3 billion.

10.3.12 Turning to train operating costs, the cost and risk model quotes the traction power component as
£2.80. Adding staff and other costs means the total per km operating costs for a 200m train are
£4.14. Given that a 400m train does not need two drivers, the operating costs are less than double
that of a single set, at £7. 50 per km (we ignore the small reduction to traction power).

10.3.13 Allowing for 41% optimism bias, the total annual train operating costs amount to around £220
million. As a 60 year PV at market prices, this represents £4.0 billion (PV, 2009 prices).

95
HS2 Demand Model Analysis

Classic Rail Savings


10.3.14 Most of the services specified to run on HS2 are replacing classic rail services on the West Coast
Main Line (WCML). While some of the released capacity is being re-used for local services, the
introduction of HS2 would result in some operating cost savings on the WCML. Our modelling of how
released capacity might be used to best reflect demand patterns has not been optimised. However,
we estimate that the net reduction in train km for Pendolinos would be around 5 million km a year
while the additional services specified for Desiros would be approximately 3 million km a year.

10.3.15 We have used the variable cost module of DfT’s Network Modelling Framework (NMF) to estimate
the total variable costs per train km for the types of rolling stock involved based on the NMF’s 2020
forecast. The net annual saving would be estimated as slightly over £50million. Over 60 years, and in
market prices, this amounts to a total saving of just under £1 billion (PV, 2009 prices).

HS2 Appraisal Cost Summary


10.3.16 Table 10.3 below summarises all the cost items discussed above.

Table 10.3 – Summary of HS2 Costs


£ billion (2009 prices)
Capital Expenditure
Construction 13.7
Rolling Stock 3.0
Renewals 1.1
TOTAL Capital Costs 17.9
Operating & Maintenance
Track 0.8
Stations 0.4
Train Maintenance 3.3
Train Operation 4.0
Classic Line Savings -1.0
Total Operating & Maintenance Costs 7.6
TOTAL COSTS (PVC) 25.5

96
Chapter 10: The Overall Business Case for HS2

10.4 Appraisal of Benefits from HS2


10.4.1 Our appraisal of benefits is based on, and consistent with, DfT’s WebTAG appraisal guidance.
Estimates of generalised costs from the HS2 demand model are used to calculate the benefits to
transport users, and changes in the number of car vehicle km and air passenger movements are
used to estimate the value of other impacts such as accidents, air quality and noise for which there
are established monetary values.

10.4.2 A high speed line would offer benefits from faster, more reliable, more frequent and, in many cases,
less crowded services. On this basis we estimate that HS2 would generate benefits of some £32.3bn
(PV) and increase net rail revenues by almost £15bn over the course of the 60 year appraisal period.

10.4.3 Almost 90% (£28.7bn) of these benefits come to transport users. These benefits are driven by time
savings and improved reliability offered by HS2. These are worth over £13bn in total. HS2 would also
deliver some £5bn of benefits through reduced crowding. This includes almost £800m of reduced
crowding on short distance trips in the South and Midlands as a result of re-use of capacity freed up
on the WCML. The remainder of the benefits to transport users come from reduced waiting time and
improved access to stations, as well as benefits to road users of lower congestion.

10.4.4 These benefits are spread across much of the UK. The three largest economic centres in the country
– London, Birmingham and Manchester – representing almost a quarter of the UK’s employment,
would benefit directly from the scheme. In particular connectivity between these cities would be
significantly improved. The benefits would not be limited to areas directly served by HS2. Passengers
from a wide catchment would be likely to access high speed services, using both road and classic
rail to access the high speed stations.

10.4.5 Around two thirds of the benefits come from people using the classic compatible services to and
from places further north than Birmingham. Figure 10.4 below shows the distribution of benefits
according to where trips start. Of course where a trip starts may not represent where the benefits
are experienced, but it provides some indication of who will gain as a result of HS2.

97
HS2 Demand Model Analysis

Figure 10.4 - Benefits of HS2 by Origin of Trip in 2033

98
Chapter 10: The Overall Business Case for HS2

10.4.6 Figure 10.4 shows that the benefits of HS2 accrue all along the line of the WCML. Trips starting in
London, Birmingham, Manchester, Glasgow and Liverpool drive much of the benefits, reflecting the
major centres of population and economic activity. However the benefits stretch all along the WCML,
and are particularly clustered around stations which will be served by HS2 Classic Compatible
trains, including Warrington, Preston and Crewe.

Table 10.4 - Benefits of HS2 by Region and Purpose


Regional User Benefits Business Other
London 36% 36%
South East 6% 5%
West Midlands 19% 18%
North West 22% 22%
Scotland 8% 7%
Other 11% 11%

10.4.7 Table 10.4 above gives the regional breakdown of benefits to long distance trips starting in different
regions (looking at the benefits according to where a trip finishes would give a similar pattern of
benefits). Trips starting in London and the South East account for the largest share of benefits
and there are significant benefits from trips starting in the West Midlands. Around one third of the
benefits accrue to trips starting north of Birmingham with the North West the biggest beneficiary.

10.4.8 Business passengers would gain the most value from HS2, representing over 60% of the benefits. This
is despite representing only around 30% of trips and largely reflects the high value that business users
and their employers attach to having faster journeys. Other users of HS2 would also gain significantly
from improved journey times, reliability, and relieved crowding delivering benefits worth over £11bn.

Benefits by Transport Mode


10.4.9 As would be expected, the benefits would not be spread evenly across the transport modes as the
vast majority of benefits are experienced by the HS2 passengers themselves.
• HS2 Passengers. These gains are mainly driven by improved journey times, with reliability and
reduced crowding also generating significant benefits.
• Passengers on the Classic Line. Taking long distance journeys onto HS2 would free up capacity
on the WCML. This would reduce crowding substantially and greater frequency would be offered
on local and regional services where appropriate. Re-use of capacity by short distance services
would be expected to deliver benefits of around £2-4bn.
• Road Users. Around 11,000 long distance car trips would be likely to transfer to HS2. This would
lead to a reduction in congestion but the net impact of this is relatively small. For example traffic
flows on the southern section of the M1 would fall by around 2%. However across all road users,
this adds up to some £2bn in benefits.

99
HS2 Demand Model Analysis

10.4.10 While the majority of transport users would benefit from the introduction of HS2, some passengers
could experience longer or less frequent services – particularly those on the GWML who would have
an extra stop at Old Oak Common or people travelling from some stations on the WCML. Also some
services could see increased crowding with more passengers using rail and underground services to
connect to high speed services. These impacts and the disbenefits they generate are outweighed by
the large benefits to be gained by HS2, and might also be minimised by further detailed development
of the classic rail timetable and train service specification.

10.5 Wider Economic Impacts of HS2


10.5.1 The benefits of HS2 considered so far have mainly been those traditionally estimated in transport
appraisal such as time savings, crowding and reliability. There is an increasing volume of evidence
that transport interventions can generate further benefits, mainly to the productivity of the economy.
These Wider Economic Impacts (WEIs) include the benefits from improved linkages between
different firms and between firms and their workers, which can lead to economies of scale, and
other efficiencies. Further potential impacts may be realised if HS2 results in changes in the spatial
pattern of economic activity in the UK.

10.5.2 DfT has been developing a methodology to assess the first of these WEIs for a number of years.
Guidance is due to form a part of the Department’s WebTAG guidance on appraisals from next year
– and as such will form a requirement for appraisals to assess these impacts. The new methodology
addresses the questions of benefits arising from the consequences of market imperfections –
concentrating on the net monetary benefits to the economy as a whole that are not captured in
Transport Economic Efficiency analysis. There are three broad components of these benefits:
• Agglomeration Benefits. These are the benefits of improved linkages between firms.
• Labour Market impacts. These are mainly derived from benefits to commuters which may
encourage more people into the labour force, or encourage those who already have jobs to work
more. This will boost the level of productivity in the economy. A further possible impact – people
moving to more productive jobs – has not been explicitly calculated by HS2 as this requires
modelling of land use change.
• Imperfect competition. This impact reflects the fact that in a world of market imperfections,
increases in production (output) will lead to benefits since consumers value the extra goods
and services by more than the costs of production. This leads to further benefits not captured in
conventional appraisal.

100
Chapter 10: The Overall Business Case for HS2

10.5.3 In many cases, it is increases in agglomeration which offer the most significant benefits. The model
of agglomeration which DfT use is based on the potential spillover effects from the increased
proximity of firms (either through lower cost or faster transport between those firms). Improving
accessibility within a city – making firms closer together – leads to agglomeration benefits
(improvements in productivity). However the scale of this impact falls the further apart firms are –
so reducing journey time between two firms from 1 hour to 40 minutes will have little impact, while
reducing it from 30 minutes to 10 minutes will have much larger impacts.

10.5.4 In this sense HS2 would seem to deliver limited agglomeration benefits since the scheme (on its
own) would do little to improve accessibility within a city. And recent evidence on the ‘decay function’
suggests firms in London and Birmingham would remain too far apart – even with high speed – to
enjoy significant agglomeration benefits. In addition, whilst better access to work opportunities
can lead to improvements in the operation of the labour market (the “more people in work” effect),
it seems unlikely that the levels of commuting over HS2 itself would be sufficient for this to be a
significant source of benefits.

10.5.5 There would still be some benefits, particularly from the potential use of released capacity on WCML
to improve commuting services into London and Birmingham, as well as some road decongestion
benefits. However the initial view of these impacts is that they would not add significantly to the
business case.

10.5.6 HS2 and a wider HSR network would nonetheless represent a step change in connectivity between
cities. We need to be confident that the approach developed by DfT (which is focused on connectivity
within cities) captures all of the wider impacts of HSR. For this reason HS2 has also considered two
further aspects of Wider Economic Impacts:
• Inter-city connectivity – considering both theory and evidence that transport investments may
have agglomeration impacts over a wider area.
• The potential for land use change to drive benefits at local, regional and national levels.

Applying WebTAG Guidance - Wider Economic Impacts


10.5.7 Table 10.5 provides a summary of both the traditional appraisal impacts and the additional Wider
Economic Impacts, as estimated using this draft guidance.

101
HS2 Demand Model Analysis

Table 10.5 - Benefits of High Speed 2 Using DfT’s Transport Appraisal and Wider Economic Impacts
Guidance
Benefits Welfare (£m)

A) Conventional Appraisal

Time Savings (including crowding)

Business user savings £17,600

Commuting & Leisure user savings £11,100

Other Benefits

Other User Impacts (Accidents, Air Quality, Noise) £44

Total transport user benefits - conventional appraisal £28,700

B) Wider Economic Impacts

Labour Market Impacts

Increase in labour force participation £0

People working longer £0

Move to more productive jobs Not Included

Exchequer consequences of increased GDP £0

Agglomeration benefits £2,000

Increased competition £0

Imperfect competition £1,600

Additional to conventional appraisal £3,600

C) Total (excluding financing, social & environmental costs & benefits) £32,300

All in £m, appraised over 60 year time period, discounted to 2009 values, 2009 prices

10.5.8 Section A of table 10.5 summarises the results of the more conventional appraisal of transport user
benefits outlined in WebTAG. These have been described in more detail in the previous section.
Section B outlines each of the components of Wider Economic Impacts that represent additional
benefits, as calculated using the draft guidance from DfT.

10.5.9 Calculating Wider Economic impacts is not clear cut for such a large infrastructure project as
HS2. Labour market impacts are minimal since HS2 is unlikely to benefit significant numbers of
commuters. The opportunity to move to more productive jobs may be more significant but we have
not been able to consider it systematically in the time available – although we note the potential of
land use change below.

102
Chapter 10: The Overall Business Case for HS2

10.5.10 There are also challenges to applying the guidance on agglomeration to a transport model which
has greatest detail in long distance rail trips, when most agglomeration impacts are driven by short
distance (and often car) trips. The HS2 model is not a local highway model, it focuses only on long
distance trips (with short distance trips ‘pre-loaded’ onto the road network). As a result we have
had to use various different approaches to estimate the agglomeration benefits of HS2. Our central
estimate suggests benefits of around £2bn, within the range of £1bn and £4.5bn. A further £1.6bn in
benefits occurs as a result of increasing output of imperfectly competitive markets.

10.5.11 Overall we estimate Wider Economic Impacts based on DfT’s draft guidance would add a further
£3.6bn (11%) to the benefits of HS2 (within the range £2.6bn to £6.1bn).

Inter-city Connectivity
10.5.12 The existing DfT guidance focuses on the role of transport in improving connectivity within an
agglomeration or region. However HS2 will fundamentally improve connectivity between regions
and cities and may have different impacts. There are also some indications to suggesting spillover
effects from investments over a far large distance than those suggested by DfT’s distance decay
functions.

10.5.13 We asked Daniel Graham and Patricia Melo (from the Centre of Transport Studies, Imperial College
London) to consider the potential for further benefits, and to confirm whether these are additional
to the more traditional benefits measured in transport appraisal. The aim of the study was not to
quantify potential impacts, but to look at what mechanisms of agglomeration (from existing theory)
might work over longer distances, consider whether they exist and whether they are significant in
scale. The results of this work are detailed in a separate paper, but broadly suggest:
• The theory of agglomeration does not preclude the generation of externalities over wider
distances (and specifically between key cities). These would be driven principally by labour
market effects and knowledge spillovers.
• Empirical studies estimating the spatial distribution of agglomeration effects consistently find
evidence of sharp decay. However, results also show that smaller agglomeration effects can be
available over longer distances. For instance, Rosenthal and Strange (2008)16 find significant
effects up to 100 miles (160 kilometres), while Rice et al. (2006)17 find that the impact of economic
mass is still statistically significant up to 80 minutes driving time from source.
• For HS2, agglomeration effects are likely to be relatively small overall, and particularly in relation
to the transport user benefits.

10.5.14 While this suggests there may be some additional benefits that are not included in our estimates of
wider economic impacts, it is unlikely that they will change the conclusions presented in this report.

16 Rosenthal, S. and W. Strange (2008). The attenuation of human capital spillovers: a Manhattan skyline approach. Journal of Urban Economics, 64, 373-389.
17 Rice, P., A. J. Venables, and E. Patacchini (2006). Spatial determinants of productivity: analysis for the regions of Great Britain. Regional Science and Urban
Economics 36, 727-752.

103
HS2 Demand Model Analysis

Land Use Change


10.5.15 We have also considered the impacts of changes in spatial patterns of economic activity that might
result from HS2. These could include firms relocating to take advantage of the new high speed line.
There are many examples where there have been substantial changes in the structure and land use
of cities served by HSR. For example:
• Lyon has seen the virtual relocation of its commercial district to the area around the TGV station
• Lille has had significant success in regenerating the area around the TGV station, with businesses
attracted to the strong international links

10.5.16 However the benefits of such changes (and particularly whether they can be added to an appraisal)
are less clear. We have been unable to undertake significant research in this area, and to do so
would probably have needed a level of detail in both design and policy that would not have been
appropriate at this stage. However we have reviewed some of the international experience and
literature, as well as drawing heavily on the experience and knowledge of Roger Vickerman
(Professor of European Economics and Dean of the University of Kent at Brussels) and Reg Harman
(Interfaces).

10.5.17 A more detailed summary of the findings of this work can be found at Appendix 3. However the
conclusions of this review can be summarised as:
• Integration is Key. Simply building a station or link to the high speed network is not enough.
For success to be achieved the station has to be integrated in to the local transport network, but
perhaps more importantly integrated into the wider strategic plans of local agencies.
• Wider Strategies. As the Eddington Study identifies, there are many factors which are more
important in regeneration than transport alone. It not surprising therefore that wider strategies
on land use planning and even education and skills may be needed to successfully integrate a
station into the local economy and ensure that potential benefits are realised.
• Role as a hub. Whilst not always the case, there are examples of success where the high speed
rail station also has hub-like connectivity with good links to the local/regional rail network as
well as the high speed network. Thus the station becomes a focus for the regional economy as
well as a wider market supported by high speed.
• This is not all win-win. Although there are many examples where growth and regeneration has
been delivered around a high speed rail station, this may be to the detriment of the surrounding
region.

10.5.18 The evidence suggests that HSR has the potential to deliver significant benefits for local and
regional economies. However it is not clear that this leads to significant impacts at the national level
– with many jobs simply being displaced from other areas.

104
Chapter 10: The Overall Business Case for HS2

10.5.19 Our conclusions from this work suggest that during the course of designing HS2, it will be essential
that the scheme is not treated purely as a transport scheme but is integrated into local and regional
strategies. However, whilst HS2 has the potential to have significant local and regional impacts, the
impact on national productivity is less clear.

Summary
10.5.20 The evidence we have seen suggests that, overall, wider economic impacts are likely to be a relatively
small part of the business case for HS2 at a national level (adding perhaps 10-15% to the benefits).
However at a local level the impacts could be much more significant. There is evidence from around
the world of high speed rail stations supporting the growth, regeneration and even relocation of
urban centres. Locating a high speed station at Old Oak Common, for example, could be a catalyst for
the development of other rail links and with them improved connectivity and regeneration.

10.5.21 Such growth would not flow automatically from the provision of a new station. In order for successful
change to be delivered the detailed design of stations in London and Birmingham would need to
make sure that they include:
• Integration of the high speed network within the long term vision of the city being served. A new
service ought to be actively supported by other policies to improve the local economy.
• Integration with the local transport network.
• Strong local leadership to drive change and take account of local needs.

10.5.22 HS2 would also be one of the largest construction projects ever undertaken in the UK, with the
potential to create up to 10,000 construction jobs, and a further 2,000 permanent jobs through
maintenance and operation.

10.6 Impact of HS2 on Carbon Emissions


10.6.1 The assessment of the impact of HS2 on carbon emissions is covered in the Appraisal of Sustainability
(AoS), and was conducted by Booz and Temple Group using data provided from the HS2 demand
model. However we have also undertaken further calculations of carbon implications to help us to
better understand the sensitivity of these results to key assumptions – and the implications for our
conclusions. The results are all set out in the Appraisal of Sustainability and the HS2 Report. However
for completeness we report here the methodology used to underpin the analysis that we have conducted.

10.6.2 The conclusion of our analysis, and that presented in the AoS is that HS2 is unlikely to have a
significant impact on overall emissions from transport. There is significant uncertainty surrounding
the impact, and the assessment is particularly sensitive to assumptions around the carbon intensity
of electricity and the response of the aviation industry as a result of HS2. However even taking this
into account, we estimate HS2 will result in somewhere between a small (0.3%) increase in transport
emissions through to a small (0.3%) decrease. Given the range of uncertainty – and the likely small
impact of HS2 – we have not quantified the value of carbon emissions in the business case.

105
HS2 Demand Model Analysis

Emissions from Rail


10.6.3 The impact of HS2 on rail emissions is three fold:
• There would be an increase in emissions as a result of HS2 trains consuming electricity
• There would be a reduction in the number of Pendolinos on the WCML, as these trains are
replaced with HS2 trains
• However the additional trains used on the released capacity would result in additional emissions
from both electricity, and a small number of diesel trains.

10.6.4 The energy consumption of HS2 trains has been modelled explicitly using information on the line
of route including speeds and acceleration patterns, gradients, tunnels. A train running along
the length of the line consumes around 4.4MWh (Megawatt hours), which is equivalent to 25 KWh
(Kilowatt hours) per km.

10.6.5 For classic compatible trains running beyond the high speed line, their performance is assumed
to be comparable to that of a 9-car Pendolino. A recent energy metering trial suggests this is
equivalent to 14.3KWh per train km. This suggests that HS2 trains – both HS captive and classic
compatible fleets - will consume just over 850GWh (Gigawatt hours) per year. To offset this, we
estimate there would be a reduction of around 5.4m train kilometres travelled by Pendolinos, saving
some 77GWh per year.

10.6.6 To convert this to carbon emissions requires an understanding of the carbon intensity of electricity.
This is a key assumption, but is also highly uncertain. The carbon intensity currently stands at just
over 0.5kgCO2 per KWh. However it is expected to decline significantly in the future. Government
projections suggest it should fall to just under 0.4kgCO2 per KWH by 2025, but beyond this there is
no firm commitment.

10.6.7 In practice carbon intensity is likely to fall further if the UK is to achieve its targets on climate
change. The Committee on Climate Change has suggested it will need to fall to less than 0.1kgCO2
per KWh by 2050 to achieve the targets set out in the Climate Change Act. However since this is not
current government policy we have been relatively cautious in our central case. We have applied a
factor of 0.385kgCO2 per KWh, but have applied a wide range to this assumption. The upper bound
is today’s emissions levels, but at the lower bound HS2 could (at least in theory) be supplied entirely
from renewable sources. This is likely to be an extreme assumption but is the theoretical limit of
emissions.

106
Chapter 10: The Overall Business Case for HS2

10.6.8 On the basis of these assumptions we estimate


• HS2 trains will emit around 0.33 MtCO2 (Million tonnes of Co2) per year (within the range 0 to a
0.43MtCO2 increase in emissions per year);
• The reduction in Pendolinos will save 0.03MtCO2 per year (within the range 0 to a 0.04 MtCO2
saving per year);
• The re-use of capacity will increase emissions by 0.02 MtCO2 per year (within the range of an
increase of 0.01 to 0.02 MtCO2 per year).

10.6.9 The increase in emissions from trains used for released capacity has been estimated using data
from DfT’s NMF model which estimates the average emissions per km of electric and diesel trains
on the classic network. This does not as standard report energy consumed, but has been adjusted to
allow different assumptions on carbon intensity of electricity. At the current level of carbon intensity
of electricity, this model suggests the average train emits just over 5kgCO2 per train km, which
forms the starting point for the range of impacts above.

Mode shift from road


10.6.10 HS2 would deliver a reduction in road journeys, particularly on key routes from Birmingham and
Manchester. Our demand model estimates there will be almost 22 million fewer car km in 2033 as a
result of HS2. This could reduce carbon in two ways:
• The reduction in car trips results in a direct reduction in emissions as that journey is undertaken
on HS2;
• Reduction in congestion speeds traffic up, which would have an indirect effect on cars that
remain on the road network. This generally improves fuel consumption (and reduces emissions),
although in some cases the opposite is true.

10.6.11 We have not calculated the impact of the latter. Given the scale of change in road km (less than 1% of
all car km in 2008), congestion effects are unlikely to have significant impacts on fuel efficiency.

10.6.12 WebTAG provides estimates of fuel consumption depending on the mix of cars (petrol/diesel) and
the speed the car was travelling at. This can be converted into a range of emissions per car km –
ranging from 0.4 kgCO2 per km at low speeds, through to 0.16 kgCO2 per km at just over 60mph. This
means the reduction in carbon emissions as a result of mode shift from car is within the range 0.002
MtCO2 to 0.006 MtCO2 per year.

107
HS2 Demand Model Analysis

Mode Shift from Air


10.6.13 The impact of mode shift from air is the single biggest uncertainty in our estimates of carbon
emissions. The HS2 demand model suggests that HS2 would lead to around 11% fewer domestic
air passengers. However this in itself does not deliver a reduction in carbon emissions. It is how
the airlines respond to this change in demand that would determine the impact of HS2 on aviation
emissions.

10.6.14 Airlines could respond by reducing service frequencies, or flying smaller planes. They could even
respond by withdrawing routes altogether, perhaps with the opportunity of ‘code sharing’ with HS2
(as, for example, Air France do on routes to Brussels). Alternatively they might not respond at all –
choosing to maintain current service levels in order to maintain a service for interlining passengers
(who tend to be higher value customers for airlines).

10.6.15 We have estimated a range of emissions reductions based on:


• Airlines respond by reducing the size of planes and frequencies such that emissions per
passenger are maintained. Thus the 11% fall in air passengers would reduce domestic aviation
emissions by the same proportion. Based on data of domestic aviation emissions18 this is
equivalent to a reduction of around 0.4MtCO2 per year in 2033.
• Airlines do not respond at all, and there is no reduction in aviation emissions as a result of HS2.

10.6.16 We have not considered in this range the potential for airlines to re-use slots freed up at airports as
a result of a reduction in the number of domestic flights. If airports slots are re-used for flights to
new destinations, then this would have implications for the emissions from aviation.

Summary of HS2 Carbon Impact


10.6.17 The impact of HS2 on UK carbon emissions is uncertain, and highly dependent on assumptions
of the carbon intensity of electricity which the scheme uses, and of the response from airlines to
changes in passenger numbers as a result of HS2. Despite this, it would seem that the impact of
HS2 on UK carbon emissions is likely to be small. We estimate that this impact is equivalent to a
range of -0.3% to +0.3% of all UK transport emissions. Our central estimate is a net reduction in
emissions of less than 0.1MtCO2 (less than 0.1% of UK transport emissions). This suggests HS2
would not be a major factor in managing carbon in the transport sector.

18 Taken from ‘UK Aviation: Carbon Reduction Futures’ DfT (2009)

108
Chapter 10: The Overall Business Case for HS2

10.7 HS2 Value for Money


Overview
10.7.1 In the preceding sections we have outlined the substantial benefits as well as costs of HS2. In this
section we draw this together to consider the strength of the overall business case, and whether the
benefits justify the costs. Table 10.7 summarises all of the key impacts that can easily be quantified
and valued in monetary terms.

Table 10.7 – Appraisal Summary Table of HS2


Quantified Costs and Benefits of HS2 (PV 2009 discount year and prices)
Business Other
  (1)  Transport User Benefits
£17.6bn £11.1bn
  (2)  Other Benefits (excl. Carbon) Less than £0.1bn

    Net Transport Benefits (PVB)


  (3)  = (1) + (2) £28.7bn

  (4)  Wider Economic Impacts (WEIs) £3.6bn

    Net Benefits incl WEIs


  (5)  = (3) + (4) £32.3bn

  (6)  Capital Costs £17.8bn

  (7)  Operating Costs £7.6bn

    Total Costs
  (8)  = (6) + (7) £25.5bn

  (9)  Revenues £15bn

(10)  Indirect Taxes -£1.5bn

    Net Costs to Government (PVC)


(11)  = (8) – (9) – (10) £11.9bn

    NATA BCR
2.4
(12)  = (3)/(11)

    BCR with WEls


2.7
(13)  = (5)/(9)

10.7.2 The net transport benefits (shown as item 3 in the table) would be worth almost £29bn. Benefits
to business and other transport users make up the bulk of this (£17.6bn and £11.1bn respectively),
with small further benefits (less than £0.1bn) from reductions in accidents, noise and air pollution
from lower road traffic. A further £3.6bn could be added through Wider Economic Impacts (item 4).
This means the total benefits of the scheme are estimated to be £32.3bn

109
HS2 Demand Model Analysis

10.7.3 Against these benefits, the costs of high speed two are substantial. Over the 60 years of an appraisal,
costs would be almost £25.5bn. The bulk of these are capital costs (£17.8bn). The remainder (about
30% of costs) are the net impact on operating costs, covering both HS2 trains and the classic network.

10.7.4 DfT consider the value for money of a scheme in terms of the value of benefits per pound of
Government spending. The cost of the scheme is not the same as Government spending since
increasing revenues on the rail network (worth £15bn) would offset the costs. Changes in indirect tax
revenue also need to be accounted for here. HS2 would reduce these revenues by £1.5bn as a result
of a reduction in the number of long distance car trips. The net cost to Government would be £11.9bn.

10.7.5 The Benefit Cost Ratio (BCR) is the net benefits divided by this net cost to Government. On this basis
the BCR would be 2.4. Adding in the Wider Economic Impacts generated by HS2, the BCR increases
to 2.7. This means the scheme would deliver £2.70 in benefits for every £1 spent by Government.

110
Chapter 11:
A Long Term Strategy for
High Speed Rail
HS2 Demand Model Analysis

11.1 Introduction
11.1.1 This chapter describes the work underlying the recommendations on the development of a high
speed line beyond the West Midlands as set out in chapter 6 of the main report. We have looked at
three possible configurations for full high speed networks as well as addressing the question of
possible next steps following the London to West Midlands line.

11.1.2 In order to meet these two objectives, we have approached them from different analytical directions.
For the wider network question, we have started from a ‘blank sheet’, essentially assuming the
entire network was built at once. What we have assessed here are the benefits from new high speed
services (mainly on a dedicated high speed network). We have not attempted to optimise the use
of the new infrastructure which would in large sections be used below capacity. For these tests we
assume classic rail services are unchanged from a world without any high speed rail.

11.1.3 The basis of these tests is necessarily strategic. We have not sought to optimise network designs or
service specifications. Instead the tests provide a high level assessment of the case for a wider high
speed rail network, as well as a comparison of the relative strength of the three configurations that
we have considered.

11.1.4 The question of extending HS2, however, required us to start from the central case for HS2 outlined
in Chapter 10 (henceforth ‘Day One’ scenario). In these tests covering possible extensions of HS2 to
Manchester and to Leeds we were interested in the incremental benefits of extending HS2, and so
the tests had to be consistent with the Day One scenario. This means time savings are incremental
to those delivered on Day One where classic compatible services would already deliver significant
time savings to Manchester, Liverpool and Glasgow, as well as improved reliability. Classic rail
services are assumed to be the same as in the Day One scenario, including the re-use of released
capacity on the WCML. All these aspects add significantly to the direct benefits of providing high
speed services between London and Birmingham. The different starting points for these tests mean
they cannot be directly compared to the results of the wider network tests.

11.1.5 The remainder of this chapter starts with an outline of the markets that the wider network would be
serving. From there it moves on to summarising our approach to analysing the three full networks in
demand modelling terms before the results of this are presented in the third part. The final section
discusses the implications for potential next steps, the possible increments on a high speed line to
the West Midlands.

112
Chapter 11: A Long Term Strategy for High Speed Rail

11.2 Long Distance travel in Great Britain


11.2.1 This section briefly presents the market for long distance travel in Great Britain and sets out the
context for analysing a high speed network. It concludes with a description of the three full networks
that we chose to analyse.

11.2.2 Our remit asked us specifically to look at the


potential for high speed rail to serve three of the
largest English conurbations – Greater Manchester,
West Yorkshire, and the North East – and Scotland.
To these we also added the East Midlands and
South Yorkshire, both of which potentially lie on an Scotland
easterly line of route towards Yorkshire. 5.1m

11.2.3 They are major centres of populations, exhibiting North


East

significant passenger flows to and from London


2.5m

on today’s conventional rail network. Together, the


regions which support these conurbations account North
Yorks &
Humber
5.0m
West
for over 60% of the total English population, with 6.8m
Scotland adding a further substantial market. West
East
Mids
Mids 4.5m
5.3m
11.2.4 The remit focused on the potential extension of the
London
core HS2 route to form a wider network, and as 7.4m
such did not include links to other conurbations – in
the South, South West and East of England or South
Wales – which would not form natural extensions of Source: ONS popluation estimates, 2005
HS2, but rather require wholly separate high speed
lines out of London. So while these lay outside the scope of our work in 2009, this is not to say that
they may not be justified.

11.2.5 We undertook some early high level analysis based on existing long distance flows between main
cities within our remit to identify where the main demand for long distance rail travel lies. Table 11.2
shows the daily trips to or from London to the major cities in the UK (from Planet Long Distance
base year).

113
HS2 Demand Model Analysis

Table 11.2 – Population and Long Distance Demand to London in 2008

PUA Daily Return Trips to Inner London


Primary Urban Area (PUA)
Population (000) Rail Highway Air
Milton Keynes 219 4,698 474 0
Birmingham 2,279 4,296 1,458 0
Manchester 1,760 3,338 81 311
Northampton1 196 2,970 570 0
Oxford 144 2,592 308 0
Leeds 729 2,180 116 12
Nottingham 610 1,293 274 0
Leicester 431 1,263 334 2
Newcastle 802 1,221 5 143
Liverpool 765 1,118 6 63
York 187 1,044 29 1
Coventry 304 1,006 195 0
Sheffield 769 1,009 122 0
Edinburgh 468 863 10 727
Preston1 339 648 31 21
Derby 234 612 131 2
Doncaster 290 507 47 0
Glasgow 1,037 425 21 709
Stoke1 363 411 286 4

1 Flow from PUA overestimated (PLANET zone larger than PUA).

11.2.6 The flows from Milton Keynes, which is relatively close to London, are dominated by commuting
trips. Our work on intermediate stations (see Chapter 6) suggests that while such markets may
generate benefits for local passengers the impact on wider HS2 passengers, as well as the
impact on capacity of the most heavily utilised part of the network, means they are unattractive.
Birmingham, Manchester and Leeds have the highest demands for cities further than 150km from
London and produce the most passenger kilometres.

114
Chapter 11: A Long Term Strategy for High Speed Rail

11.2.7 Flows from Edinburgh and Glasgow appear to be less strong; however a new high speed line would
represent a step change in connectivity which might significantly increase demand. Both stations
could also provide access to travellers from wider Scotland and could create a strong competitor
to air passengers, which adds to the potential market for high speed rail. For those reasons, both
stations were taken forward for consideration.

11.2.8 The case for a further network is not simply limited to links to London; links between other cities
may be important and drive additional demand on HS services. Analysing the existing flows
highlighted significant cross-country demand between Glasgow and Edinburgh with around 14,000
daily return trips as well as on the corridor between Liverpool, Manchester and Leeds.19

11.2.9 This analysis suggested a number of key cities for a wider network within the constraints of our
remit and consistent with emerging thoughts on potential lines of route. These were Birmingham,
Manchester and Leeds with additional potential for stations around Newcastle, Sheffield and within
the East Midlands as well as Scotland. We did not include Bristol, Cardiff or Brighton, which are
clearly outside our remit.

11.2.10 Long distance travel is forecast to triple by 2033: there would be more than 7 million trips per day
that exceed 50 miles across the regions under consideration here. Out of those, around 5m trips
would be intra-regional (start and end within the same Government office region). Of the remaining
2 million trips per day, 360,000 (or 15%) either start or end in London. Looking only at air and rail
modes, we forecast about 500,000 daily inter-regional long distance trips by 2033, out of which
270,000 or 56% involve London at either end.

19 5,000 to 6,000 daily returns between Manchester and Leeds – Liverpool to Manchester is less than 50miles, thus no long distance trips are shown, nevertheless
flows are significant.

115
HS2 Demand Model Analysis

11.3 Long Term High Speed Networks


11.3.1 We have identified three possible national network configurations that would cover these markets to
varying degrees. These are outlined below. All three build on the preferred scheme for HS2 between
London and the West Midlands. We have not fully optimised these networks but have developed
them to help understanding the relative merits of different basic approaches.

An ‘Inverse A’ Configuration

Glasgow Edinburgh

Newcastle
Lancashire Teeside Interchange
Interchange

Liverpool Leeds
Manchester
South Yorkshire
Interchange

East Midlands
Interchange

Birmingham Birmingham Interchange

HS2

Heathrow Interchange London

Inverse ‘A’ Configuration


11.3.2 The Inverse A configuration is an adaptation of networks which have been examined in past studies.
It is the most comprehensive network that could be supported by the capacity of HS2, relying as it
does on one route north from London.

11.3.3 The Inverse A aims to maximise benefits to the widest number of people by offering direct London
access to each of the conurbations in our remit, as well as Merseyside (via the existing classic line),
East Midlands and South Yorkshire. The transpennine link between Manchester and Leeds would
carry only east-west flows, with services to and from London travelling either side of the Pennines.
This configuration would also unlock potential for a network of high speed inter-regional services.

116
Chapter 11: A Long Term Strategy for High Speed Rail

A ‘Reverse S’ Configuration

Glasgow Edinburgh

Newcastle

Teeside Interchange

Leeds
Manchester

Birmingham Birmingham Interchange

HS2

Heathrow Interchange London

Reverse ‘S’ Configuration


11.3.4 Similar network configurations have also formed the subject of investigation in the past. The
network provides connections to all the major conurbations detailed in the remit, using a linear
route which would minimise the total amount of construction. Under this scenario, all trains north of
Manchester would need to cross the Pennines. This would increase journey times between London
and Leeds, Newcastle and Scotland, compared to the alternative configurations.

11.3.5 In Scotland a number different permutations exist for serving Edinburgh and/or Glasgow. In each of
the configurations, we assume separate legs serving Edinburgh and Glasgow and have not modelled
the benefits of a link between the cities.

117
HS2 Demand Model Analysis

A ‘Reverse E’ Configuration

Glasgow Edinburgh

Newcastle

Teeside Interchange

Liverpool
Leeds
Manchester
South Yorkshire
Interchange

East Midlands
Interchange

Birmingham Birmingham Interchange

HS2

Heathrow Interchange London

Reverse ‘E’ Configuration


11.3.6 The Reverse E configuration builds upon HS2 to the east of the Pennines. Unlike the Inverse A and
Reverse S configurations, this network does not extend from the northern limit of HS2, which would
remain connected to the West Coast Main Line.

11.3.7 Because HS2 extends beyond Birmingham, the best journey times to Manchester and Liverpool
under this scenario would remain those achieved with classic-compatible HS2 trains,
running on the West Coast Main Line. The purpose of the high speed connections to Manchester and
Liverpool would be to enhance regional links across the Pennines, but we have not modelled this.

11.3.8 Such a line could also be used to achieve better high speed journey times to the North West but
only with a more central alignment of HS2 (towards Leicester rather than Birmingham). However,
this would rule out a Heathrow connection, entail longer journey times to Birmingham, and compare
poorly with journey times to the North West in the Inverse A. With a more central alignment of HS2,
the ‘Reverse E’ would become more akin to the proposal put forward by the 2M group of London
Councils (known as ‘High Speed North’). As our remit was to consider the development of HS2
beyond the West Midlands, we have not investigated the 2M proposals in detail.

118
Chapter 11: A Long Term Strategy for High Speed Rail

11.4 Wider Networks - Modelling Approach


11.4.1 Given the strategic nature of this work, we have taken a cautious approach to the modelling in terms
of taking broadly conservative assumptions on benefits and using high end estimates on costs. This
section starts by setting out some general modelling assumptions specific to the analysis of the
wider networks. The text then describes our thinking on journey times and service patterns for the
individual networks and especially on the importance of London bound journey times.

Modelling assumptions for the three strategic networks


11.4.2 In order to model the maximum capacity a new line could support we have assumed 400m trains to
be used for every route and throughout the day. This reduced the need for model runs by minimising
the crowding impacts, and so maximising the potential benefits of the service specifications
modelled. In the real world, demand on some routes and/or during some periods might be weaker
so 200m trains would be sufficient. This could lead to savings in operating costs – though it might
also impact on the benefits reported in this document.

11.4.3 Similarly we have not endeavoured to re-design the classic railway services for this strategic review
as we have done for HS2. Instead we assume an entirely new high speed network with classic rail
services continuing as in the reference scenario. We have also not tested the implications of the
limited number of hybrid services on the existing trains running on the classic line (in the Reverse E
and Reverse S).

11.4.4 The tests of the wider network configurations also ignore the potential for high speed rail to deliver
reliability improvements over the existing classic network. Nor have we considered the potential for
wider economic impacts that a comprehensive high speed network might deliver.

11.4.5 Outside London and the West Midlands, the demand model is of a strategic nature and lacks the
granularity required to model in detail the access and egress to newly designed high speed rail
stations. We have instead used existing stations with their local accessibility settings as they exist in
the Planet Long Distance model.

11.4.6 Compared to our approach to appraising the line to the West Midlands, most of these assumptions
will result in a more conservative estimate of the business case for a full network. Optimisation of
the business case may find opportunities for cost savings and changes to the benefits. Generally this
analysis provides a robust indication of the relative strengths of the business cases for each of the
networks considered, but all could be refined further with more detailed design work.

119
HS2 Demand Model Analysis

Importance of Journey Times to London


11.4.7 Following on from the analysis of existing long distance flows referred to above we used an early
version of the demand model, to estimate the potential merits of the three network designs as well
as various sensitivity tests on the Inverse A. These runs used notional, but realistic, service patterns.

11.4.8 The model outputs were used to analyse the marginal benefit of additional trains (and thus higher
frequency) or faster journeys between the various destinations. The aim was to provide an overview
of the key factors driving the business case – frequency against faster journeys; which stations were
the most important for delivering benefits.

11.4.9 The results of this analysis highlighted the importance of London flows as opposed to cross-county
trips: it suggested that travellers get larger benefits overall from faster journeys to and from London
rather than from more frequent, stopping services that also connect stations outside London
to each other. With this insight, we adjusted our initial service specifications so that there were
fewer stopping services and more faster, more direct trains to London. While some destinations
have fewer trains per hour, most places gain significantly due to the faster journey. Details on the
modelled service patterns are contained in Appendix 4.

11.4.10 While we believe the final service specifications represent a credible, realistic base for comparing
the different network configurations at this strategic level, more iterations of this type of
optimisation process could identify changes that could improve the use of the available track
capacity further.

11.4.11 The main difference between the Inverse A and the Reverse E configuration is that in the latter high
speed trains to Manchester would need to run via the East Midlands and South Yorkshire. Compared
to the hybrid services connecting London to Manchester via the HS2 on Day One, no further time
saving would be achieved. The modelling therefore assumes the day one services to continue in this
scenario. The Reverse S does not serve the East Midlands and South Yorkshire (and so misses many
of the benefits for passengers in these areas).

11.4.12 Compared to the Inverse A, the London to Scotland services are half an hour slower in the E and
slightly more so in the S. Newcastle and the North East benefit from some of the Scotland services
stopping there under the E and the S, which offers some compensation for the slower journey times.

120
Chapter 11: A Long Term Strategy for High Speed Rail

11.5 Demand and Benefits of a Long Term Strategy


11.5.1 Of the three networks, the Inverse A offers the best business case. It is the most extensive of the
networks and thus has the highest costs. The benefits and revenues from a wider coverage and
faster journeys to and from London, however, more than compensate for this, leading to a higher
ratio of benefits to costs (BCR) than either the Reverse E or the Reverse S.

11.5.2 This section first covers in some detail the results from the demand model in terms of demand and
revenue as well as benefits. A brief summary of the costs follows before the third section brings the
two together into the BCRs. A final section discusses the main caveats and limitations of the current
work.

Demand
11.5.3 With over 440,000 daily passengers forecast to use high speed services in the Inverse A, this
configuration clearly creates the highest demand. The total flow on the Reverse E would be just over
400,000 or nearly 10% less. The Reverse S would attract about a fifth less than that, around 325,000
trips per day in 2033.

11.5.4 Table 11.5a shows trips to and from London – which account for roughly half of the total –ordered by
the region in which the trip starts or finishes.

Table 11.5a Daily High Speed Rail Demadnd to and from London with a wider HSL network
Daily HS2 Demand to/from London Inverse A Reverse S Reverse E

Scotland 43,000 40,000 38,000

North East 24,000 22,000 23,000

North West 53,000 51,000 43,000

Yorkshire & Humberside 39,000 26,000 38,000

West Midlands 39,000 39,000 39,000

East Midlands 20,000 3,000 20,000

Total 219,000 181,000 203,000

11.5.5 The Reverse S does not serve the East Midlands, so has only a minimal demand flow from here
with some passengers using Birmingham Interchange station. The network also provides a poorer
service to Yorkshire, which results in lower demand there as well. The journey times to the North
East and Scotland are somewhat slower than in the Inverse A so the Reverse S exhibits lower
demand from here as well.

121
HS2 Demand Model Analysis

11.5.6 The Reverse E does not improve the journey experience of travellers between London and the North
West over and above what they would get from HS2 to Birmingham. This limits the number of rail
trips between London and the North West (in effect the level of demand would be no higher than the
HS2 central case had these tests been conducted on a comparable basis – which they are not).

11.5.7 Any of the three networks would revolutionise the London to Scotland rail market, and bring it into
direct competition with the air market. Indeed nearly 50% of additional rail travellers are shifting
from air. This represents a reduction in air journeys by around 60% between the regions for all the
modelled scenarios. This kind of effect is generally expected for rail journey times getting close to
three hours.

Benefits
11.5.8 The Inverse A provides the biggest benefits and generates the largest additional revenue. This
is followed by the Reverse E. The difference reflects better journey times to the North West and
Scotland where the Inverse A is the fastest and most comprehensive network. The Reverse S is
estimated to bring lower benefits and revenues mainly because it does not serve the East Midlands
and South Yorkshire.

11.5.9 Most of the benefits occur in improved time savings and travel experience on the rail network.
Around 6% of the benefits arise through improved travel conditions on the road network as a
consequence of mode shift. The following maps illustrate the rail benefits by originating district
under the three network configurations.

122
Chapter 11: A Long Term Strategy for High Speed Rail

Figure 11.5 - Benefits by Trip Origin for the Three Network Configurations

Reverse S
Reverse E
Inverse A

123
HS2 Demand Model Analysis

11.5.10 The regional results suggest journey times to London are important for the benefits of high speed
rail to Scotland. The Reverse E loses more than 30% of Scottish benefits compared to the Inverse A,
the Reverse S over 35%.

11.5.11 The North West is clearly best served by the Inverse A: Preston is not covered by the other networks
while Liverpool gets slower journey times to London in the alternatives. While the Reverse S offers
better London connections than the Reverse E, the latter provides better cross-country connectivity
to the region. This offsets the disadvantage of slower journeys to London to some extent.

11.5.12 As expected, the North East, Yorkshire and Humber as well as the East Midlands regions receive
broadly comparable benefits under the A and the E while the missing leg via the East Midlands
severely disadvantages the Reverse S.

11.5.13 Figure 11.5 also highlights the importance of areas that are not directly served by the high
speed networks. For example the improvements to Glasgow and Edinburgh under the Inverse A
are sufficiently strong for travellers from all over Scotland to re-route via high speed – thereby
benefitting from the changes. This effect is less pronounced in the other two configurations.

Costs
11.5.14 The costs have been estimated based on the rates and assumptions used for HS2. This section
provides a brief overview of how we estimated the drivers behind each cost category. The resulting
appraisal costs are provided in the summary Table 11.5b. As before, in line with WebTAG20 guidance
we have for appraisal purposes converted the costs into the market price unit of account. We have
discounted them to 2009.

20 http://www.dft.gov.uk/webtag/docs/expert/affordability/3.8.1.pdf

124
Chapter 11: A Long Term Strategy for High Speed Rail

Table 11.5b: Appraisal Costs, £billion in 2009 Prices


Costs Inverse A Reverse E Reverse S

Capital Expenditure

   Construction £46.5bn £43.6bn £39.4bn

   Rolling Stock £8.3bn £8.8bn £7.3bn

Total £54.7bn £52.4bn £46.7bn

Opex & Maintenance

   Track £3.5bn £2.9bn £2.4bn

   Stations £0.6bn £0.6bn £0.4bn

   Train Maintenance £12.3bn £12.0bn £10.9bn

   Train Operation £17.0bn £16.1bn £14.9bn

Total £33.5bn £31.6bn £28.6bn

TOTAL COSTS (PVC) £88.3bn £84.0bn £75.4bn

11.5.15 These costs are based on a strategic assessment of route and operating requirements and follow
closely the treatment of costs for HS2. We have developed broad infrastructure cost assumptions
based on basic unit rates derived from our work on HS2 and calculated using assumptions about the
composition of certain routes (e.g. the difficulty of the terrain).

11.5.16 The rolling stock requirements are approximated following a similar but simplified approach as for
HS2. The calculations take maintenance requirements into account. The inverse A requires a total of
330 high speed captive train sets. No classic compatible services are assumed to run in the Inverse
A service specification. The Reverse E and S both need a fleet of 245 high speed captive train sets
complemented by 59 classic compatible sets for the Reverse E and 26 for the Reverse S.

11.5.17 For stations, cost assumptions are based on a high level estimation of the likely number of platforms
and station staff required for the number of trains and passengers expected at each of the stations.
We have assumed that the stations at Manchester and Leeds would involve similar costs to those
estimated for Birmingham Fazely Street in HS2. For Liverpool, Glasgow and Edinburgh we use Old
Oak Common as a guide while for Newcastle and the interchange stations, Birmingham interchange
is the comparator.

125
HS2 Demand Model Analysis

11.6 Benefit Cost Ratios of a Wider Network


11.6.1 The table below shows all benefits, revenues and costs for the three networks and summarises
them in the benefit cost ratio. The values are present values expressed in 2009 prices and
discounted over the 60 year appraisal period.

Table 11.6 - Appraisal Summary Table for Wider Network


2009 PV £billion Inverse A Reverse E Reverse S

   Transport User Benefits £102.5bn £86.8bn £73.5bn

   Other Benefits (excl Carbon) £0.6bn £0.4bn £0.4bn

Net Transport Benefits £103.1bn £87.3bn £73.9bn

   Capital Costs £54.7bn £52.4bn £46.7bn

   Operating Costs £33.5bn £31.6bn £28.2bn

Total Costs £88.3bn £84.0bn £75.4bn

   Revenues £48.4bn £42.1bn £38.1bn

   Indirect Tax -£4.9bn -£4.4bn -£3.9bn

Benefit Cost Ratio 2.3 1.9 1.8

11.6.2 The analysis suggests there is a good case for a wider high speed network. The Inverse A performs
the most strongly of the three networks considered, despite being the most costly. The wider
coverage and faster journey times deliver benefits which more than offset this additional cost.

11.6.3 The values would no doubt change if further work on engineering options and benefits were carried
out. However, at this stage it does not appear likely that any of these changes would affect any one
of the networks significantly differently from the others, though the inverse A might offer more
options for released capacity on the East Cost Mainline (ECML) and the Midlands Mainline (MML).
Overall the conclusion that the Inverse A performs the best of the three networks considered due
to its better journey times and wider coverage is considered to be robust.

126
Chapter 11: A Long Term Strategy for High Speed Rail

11.7 Limitations of Our Analysis and Further Work


11.7.1 The purpose of our work on the wider network was to undertake a strategic assessment of the
longer term strategy rather than to optimise the shape and design of such a network. We have
shown that out of the three networks tested, the Inverse A performs best in terms of the indicative
benefit cost ratio. However, it is reasonable to expect that the business case for the networks could
be substantially improved following a more detailed consideration of issues such as:
• Optimal capacity - As outlined above, we have assumed the maximum capacity that could be
provided. While this assumption may provide strong benefits, it also implies higher operating
costs and rolling stock requirements. We have not optimised service patterns to demand, or
considered in detail the business case for incremental sections of line (other than Manchester
and Leeds below).
• Released capacity – Similarly we have not attempted to re-optimise the use of the classic rail
network.
• Reliability – On the HS2 route, this contributes around 10% to its business case. A wider network
would, if anything, be expected to bring larger improvements to reliability as fewer hybrid
services reduce the potential for importing delays from the classic rail network.
• Wider impacts – Wider impacts amount to almost 15% on top of the conventional benefits of
HS2. The more extensive networks discussed here might be expected to generate even more
significant indirect impacts on the economy.

11.7.2 From our analysis we can conclude that a wider network could provide good value for money and
that the Inverse A provides the best case of the options considered. However this does not mean that
the networks we have considered are the optimal solutions. We have not considered, for example a
combination of classic line upgrades, hybrid running and some entirely new, high speed links. Whilst
this may deliver lower benefits it could be at a much lower costs, thereby offering a better overall
business case. More work would be required to fully understand the impact on a business case of
these kinds of options.

11.8 Extensions to Manchester and Leeds


11.8.1 Having concluded that a network configuration with branches to the east and west of the Pennines
performs best of those we tested, we looked at the strategic case for incremental components of
this configuration, focussing on the likely next steps building on the base that HS2 provides.

127
HS2 Demand Model Analysis

11.8.2 Extending HS2 to Manchester would be an obvious and fairly low cost next step. Greater Manchester
is the next largest urban conurbation in the UK, and the area is already benefitting from classic
compatible trains serving it in the Day One scenario. This would mean an extension to Manchester
would have relatively low additional operating costs. An extension to Leeds on the other hand would
bring the experience of high speed travel to wholly new areas, potentially unlocking large demand
from Leeds, Sheffield and the East Midlands.

11.8.3 This section summarises the work done on possible extensions to Manchester and Leeds via an
eastern alignment. The modelling undertaken for this section is closer to the analysis of HS2 and
differs in some key points from the approach used for the wider networks above. These differences
are summarised first before the results of the two scenarios are summarised individually.

Modelling Approach
11.8.4 In contrast to the wider network analysis presented above, we have modelled the extensions to
Manchester and Leeds building on from the HS2 Day One scenario. This means that high speed
services to Birmingham and Manchester have already replaced the current WCML Pendolino
services and some of the released capacity has been re-used in the London and Birmingham areas.
We have not, however, made any further changes to the pattern of using the released capacity as
derived for the Day One specification.

11.8.5 An extension to Manchester would most likely include an interchange station similar to that near
Birmingham International Airport. While we have made an allowance for such a stop in our journey
time assumption to Manchester central, our modelling does not capture this demand and we have
not included the likely benefits of it. This results in some disbenefits to areas around Wilmslow and
Stockport where the hybrid Manchester bound trains stop on Day One and would potentially use an
interchange station if the modelling was able to include this.

11.8.6 We have followed the same approach on reliability as in Day One and adjusted the assumptions to
reflect the likely further improvements to Manchester and Leeds respectively.

11.8.7 For seat capacity we use the same assumption as for the Day One specification. This means that
we have allowed for some 400m trains at certain times of day, running on the dedicated high speed
network, but only 200m classic compatible trains. As in the wider networks above, we have not
considered any new stations but used existing stations instead.

Manchester
11.8.8 Extending HS2 from the West Midlands to Manchester is estimated to bring reductions in journey
times from London to Manchester of 20 minutes on top of what is already achieved on Day One.
London based hybrid services to Scotland, Preston and Liverpool save another 13 minutes over the
Day One service specification. The only other change to the Day One specification is the addition of
three trains per hour connecting Birmingham to Manchester, taking 54 minutes to complete the
journey.

128
Chapter 11: A Long Term Strategy for High Speed Rail

11.8.9 The precise line of route chosen has a direct impact especially on the hybrid services. The high level
analysis undertaken at this stage suggests a route approaching Manchester centre from the east
has significant engineering advantages. However, it requires a fairly long line south of the city to
reconnect to the WCML. The length of line connecting services to the WCML limits the benefits of the
extension to places beyond Manchester.

11.8.10 If a more westerly alignment of the route could be identified, the journey times to Liverpool, Preston
and Scotland would be further improved. Such a design, however, might compromise a later
extension through the Pennines towards Leeds. The modelling undertaken here is based on the
easterly approach but further testing would be needed if a detailed line of route were developed.

11.8.11 Table 11.8a shows the daily passenger flows on high speed services between London and the
regions. Scotland and the North West are clearly seeing an increase in trips to or from the capital. In
total there are forecast to be just under 10% more users compared to Day One.

Table 11.8a – Daily Passenger Flows between London and the Regions for HS2 Manchester Extension
Daily Demand to/from London HS2 Day One Manchester Extension Difference

Scotland 11,300 15,100 3,800

North East 0 0 0

North West 54,700 58,900 4,200

Yorkshire and Humberside 5,200 6,100 900

West Midlands 40,100 40,500 400

East Midlands 1,200 1,300 100

Total 112,600 121,800 9,200

11.8.12 In addition to the increase in demand to and from London, the journey time and capacity
improvements between Birmingham and Manchester result in 6,000 trips per day between the West
Midlands and the North West on high speed services as well as around 1,400 daily tips between the
West Midlands and Yorkshire & Humber. Less than half of these are switching from classic rail.

11.8.13 The extension benefits:


• the additional users who would not have travelled in the Day One scenario. These users also
generate additional revenue.
• those who were already using hybrid services from and to London under Day One who are now
reaching their destinations faster.
• Travellers switching from classic to high speed services on the cross country services who now
benefit from shorter journey times.

129
HS2 Demand Model Analysis

11.8.14 Figure 11.8a shows rail benefits by trip origin and how they change between Day One and a
Manchester extension. It shows that the areas that benefit from the Manchester extension are the
same as those under Day One, but that the benefits are increased.

Figure 11.8a - Rail Benefits by Trip Origin for HS2’s Day One Scenario
and the Manchester Extension
Day One Manchester Extension

11.8.15 The incremental benefits and revenues of the Manchester extension over those of Day One are
shown in Table 11.8b below together with a summary of the additional costs. The values are shown
discounted to 2009 values and prices.

130
Chapter 11: A Long Term Strategy for High Speed Rail

Table 11.8b – Incremental Benefits and Costs for HS2 Extension to Manchester
Quantified Costs and Benefits PV 2009 discount year and prices £ billion

   Transport User Benefits £8.1bn

   Other Benefits (excl Carbon) £0.0bn

Net Transport Benefits £8.1bn

   Capital Costs £4.8bn

   Operating Costs £2.5bn

Total Costs £7.3bn

   Revenues £4.0bn

   Indirect Tax -£0.4bn

Benefit Cost Ratio 2.2

11.8.16 On the cost side, a substantial part of the operating costs is already included in Day One costs.
The classic compatible trains operating between London and Manchester from Day One are actually
more expensive to run than single high speed captive train sets. Running 400m trains during peak
hours, however, adds to the rolling stock and running costs, more than offsetting that cost saving.

11.8.17 The additional rolling stock capital expenditure contributes £550m to the present value of costs
(PVC). Discounted to 2009 and expressed in market prices, the infrastructure costs for extending the
high speed line is estimated to total £4.8bn. Operating costs over 60 years would be expected to add
£2.5bn to the PVC which sum to £7.3bn in total.

11.8.18 Based on the quantified impacts above, the indicative business case for a Manchester extension is
good with about £2.20 worth of benefits for every pound of net expenditure.

Leeds
11.8.19 While an extension to Manchester would essentially bring further improvements to regions already
benefitting from hybrid services on Day One, an extension to Leeds would bring the experience of
high speed rail travel to the eastern half of the country.

11.8.20 Fastest journey times to London on this route would be 53 minutes for Nottingham, 1h15 for
Sheffield and 1h20 in the case of Leeds. For all these connections, the time savings exceed
50 minutes. Hybrid trains to Newcastle bring a reduction of 15 minutes against the current fastest
services. In addition cross country connections between Birmingham and Leeds would fall to
65 minutes and between Birmingham and Newcastle to 2h20 – savings of more than 50 minutes
in each case.

131
HS2 Demand Model Analysis

11.8.21 As shown in Table 11.8c below, in terms of high speed trips to or from London, the extension to
Leeds adds a significant number of trips to the Eastern regions where we would not expect HS2
to have much impact. In total, an additional 70,000 trips per day would be likely to flow in and out
of London.

Table 11.8c – Daily Passenger flows between London and the regions for HS2 Leeds extensions
Daily Demand to/from London HS2 day1 Leeds Extension Difference

Scotland 11,300 11,300 0

North East 0 15,400 15,400

North West 54,700 55,100 400

Yorkshire and Humberside 5,200 39,400 34,200

West Midlands 40,100 40,700 600

East Midlands 1,200 20,400 19,200

Total 112,600 182,400 69,800

11.8.22 In terms of cross country flows, the Leeds extension is forecast to carry around 8,000 passengers
per day between West and East Midlands and a similar number between the West Midlands and
Yorkshire & Humber. Around 60% of these high speed journeys replace trips on the classic network.
Between the West Midlands and the North East, 75% of the 3,000 trips per day come from classic
rail.

11.8.23 The high speed extension to Leeds benefits:


• Existing rail travellers between London and the eastern regions through improved services.
• A significant number of cross country rail users that experience similar improvements.
• Additional rail users who would have either used other modes or not travelled under Day One.

11.8.24 Figure 11.8b below highlight the focus of benefits on rail users in regions not significantly benefiting
from the line to the West Midlands. The large majority of districts that benefit are located towards
the east of those benefitting on Day One. In addition, the benefits to cross country travellers starting
their journeys in the West Midlands are clearly visible.

132
Chapter 11: A Long Term Strategy for High Speed Rail

Figure 11.8b - Rail Benefits by Trip Origin for HS2 Day One Scenario and the Leeds Extension
Day One Leeds Extension

11.8.25 Table 11.8d summarises the benefits, revenues and costs that are estimated additional to those for
the route to the West Midlands.

Table 11.8d – Incremental Benefits and Costs for HS2 extension to Leeds
Quantified Costs and Benefits PV 2009 discount year and prices £ billion

   Transport User Benefits £30.4bn

   Other Benefits (excl Carbon) -£0.1bn

Net Transport Benefits £30.3bn

   Capital Costs £6.4bn

   Operating Costs £7.3bn

Total Costs £13.6bn

   Revenues £13.9bn

   Indirect Tax -£1.5bn

Benefit Cost Ratio 24.8

133
HS2 Demand Model Analysis

11.8.26 While the new route is longer, it is expected to be comparatively cheaper to construct due to the
likely easier topography around potential line of route. In total we estimate the cost of construction
to be similar to that of the Manchester extension. However, the additional rolling stock would be
entirely additional to the Day One scenario, adding substantially to capital expenditure.

11.8.27 The substantial additional number of trips is also expected to generate significant revenue flows.
Indeed, based on this illustrative modelling, the revenues come close to paying for the costs of the
extension over a 60 years appraisal period resulting in a high benefit cost ratio.

11.8.28 The overall magnitude of benefits compared to the costs suggests a strong business case for the
Leeds extension.

134
Appendix 1:
Transport Economic Efficiency Tables
HS2 Demand Model Analysis

A1.1 Introduction
A1.1.1 This appendix provides the Transport Economic Efficiency (TEE) tables for tests undertaken using
the final version of our demand model. These are the
• Central case (Day One scenario)
• Classic line alternative
• Central case without reliability
• Central case without a station at Old Oak Common
• Central case without a Birmingham Interchange station
• Central case with a station at Heathrow
• Wider Networks – The Inverse A
• Wider Networks – The Reverse E
• Wider Networks – The Reverse S
• HS2 Extensions – Manchester
• HS2 Extensions – Leeds

A1.1.2 The TEE tables compare each of these scenarios against the ‘do minimum’ reference case,
essentially a world without high speed rail. All data are presented in present values and 2009 prices.

A1.1.3 It should be noted that the Day One results have been subject to a final minor amendment that has
not been applied to the other tests yet. As a result the benefits set out in Figure A1.1 are not directly
comparable with the other TEE tables. Where appropriate, consistent comparisons have been set
out in Chapter 11 (Leeds and Manchester extensions) and Appendix 2 (sensitivity tests).

136
Appendix 1: Transport Economic Efficiency Tables

Figure A1.1 – Day One Central Case (Chapter 10)


TEE/Public Accounts Table All Outputs Day One

Table 1: Economic Efficiency of Transport System (£mill, revenues are scored as positives, costs as negatives)

Total Other Rail


Consumers user benefits
- travel time saving 10,345 512 9,833
- Vehicle opcost 179 179 -
- user charges - 18 - 18 0
- during construction & maintenance - - -
Net (1) 10,506 673 9,833

Business
User benefits
- Travel time 17,404 1,279 16,125
- Vehicle opcost - 7 - 7 -
- user charges - 7 - 7 0
- during construction & maintenance - - -
Net (2) 17,390 1,326 16,125

Private sector provider impact


- revenue 15,003 - 15,003
- opcost - 7,602 - - 7,602
- investment cost - 17,850 - - 17,850
- grant/subsidy 25,452 - 25,452
- revenue transfer - 15,003 - - 15,003
Sub total (3) - - -

Other impacts
- Developer contribution (4) - -

Net business impact (5 = 2+3+4) 17,390 1,326 16,125

Total, PV of transport econ eff. Benefits (6 = 1+5) 27,896

Table 2 Public Accounts (£mill costs should be recorded as a positive number, surpluses as a negative one)
All Modes Other Rail
Total
Local Government funding
- Direct Revenue - - -
- Op costs -
- Investment costs -
- Developer and other contributions -
- Grant/Subsidy (k)* -
- Revenue transfer -
Net (7) - - -

Central Government funding


- Direct Revenue - - -
- Op costs -
- Investment costs* -
- Developer and other contributions -
- Grant/Subsidy (k)* 25,452 25,452
- Indirect Tax Revenues (i) 1,465 32 1,433
- Revenue transfer - 15,003 - - 15,003
Net (8) 11,913 32 11,881

Total PV of costs (9 =7+8) 11,913

Table 3: Analysis of Monetised Costs and Benefits (AMCB)


Total
Noise 3
Local air quality 5
Greenhouse
Journey gases(incl. rolling stock quality, and in vehicle
ambience
crowding) 768
Accidents (incl. safety) 36
Consumer users (sub-total 1, Table 1) 10,506
Business users and providers (sub-total 5, Table 1) 17,390
Reliability (incl. performance & reliability) -
Option values -
Interchange (station quality and crowding) -

PVB (a = sum of all benefits) 28,708

PVC (b = sub-total 9, Table 2) 11,913

Overall impact, total


- NPV (a-b) 16,794
- BCR (a/b) 2.41

- Revised BCR (a-i)/(b-i) 2.61

137
HS2 Demand Model Analysis

Figure A1.2 - Classic Line Alternative (Appendix 2, Section 5)


TEE/Public Accounts Table All Outputs Classic Line Alternative

Table 1: Economic Efficiency of Transport System (£mill, revenues are scored as positives, costs as negatives)

Total Other Rail


Consumers user benefits
- travel time saving 6,570 430 6,140
- Vehicle opcost 157 157 -
- user charges - 21 - 21 0
- during construction & maintenance - - -
Net (1) 6,706 566 6,140

Business
User benefits
- Travel time 15,001 989 14,012
- Vehicle opcost - 9 - 9 -
- user charges - 7 - 7 0
- during construction & maintenance - - -
Net (2) 14,985 973 14,012

Private sector provider impact


- revenue 12,131 - 12,131
- opcost - 7,068 - - 7,068
- investment cost - 15,250 - - 15,250
- grant/subsidy 22,318 - 22,318
- revenue transfer - 12,131 - - 12,131
Sub total (3) - - -

Other impacts
- Developer contribution (4) - -

Net business impact (5 = 2+3+4) 14,985 973 14,012

Total, PV of transport econ eff. Benefits (6 = 1+5) 21,691

Table 2 Public Accounts (£mill costs should be recorded as a positive number, surpluses as a negative one)
All Modes Other Rail
Total
Local Government funding
- Direct Revenue - - -
- Op costs -
- Investment costs -
- Developer and other contributions -
- Grant/Subsidy (k)* -
- Revenue transfer -
Net (7) - - -

Central Government funding


- Direct Revenue - - -
- Op costs -
- Investment costs* -
- Developer and other contributions -
- Grant/Subsidy (k)* 22,318 22,318
- Indirect Tax Revenues (i) 1,315 33 1,282
- Revenue transfer - 12,131 - 12,131
Net (8) 11,502 33 11,469

Total PV of costs (9 =7+8) 11,502

Table 3: Analysis of Monetised Costs and Benefits (AMCB)


Total
Noise 3
Local air quality 5
Greenhouse
Journey gases(incl. rolling stock quality, and in vehicle
ambience
crowding) 735
Accidents (incl. safety) 37
Consumer users (sub-total 1, Table 1) 6,706
Business users and providers (sub-total 5, Table 1) 14,985
Reliability (incl. performance & reliability) -
Option values -
Interchange (station quality and crowding) -

PVB (a = sum of all benefits) 22,471

PVC (b = sub-total 9, Table 2) 11,502

Overall impact, total


- NPV (a-b) 10,969
- BCR (a/b) 1.95

- Revised BCR (a-i)/(b-i) 2.08

138
Appendix 1: Transport Economic Efficiency Tables

Figure A1.3 - Central Scenario without Reliability Adjustment (Section 3.4)


TEE/Public Accounts Table All Outputs No Reliability

Table 1: Economic Efficiency of Transport System (£mill, revenues are scored as positives, costs as negatives)

Total Other Rail


Consumers user benefits
- travel time saving 7,595 487 7,108
- Vehicle opcost 184 184 -
- user charges - 20 - 20 0
- during construction & maintenance - - -
Net (1) 7,759 650 7,108

Business
User benefits
- Travel time 18,148 1,173 16,975
- Vehicle opcost - 7 - 7 -
- user charges - 7 - 7 0
- during construction & maintenance - - -
Net (2) 18,134 1,159 16,975

Private sector provider impact


- revenue 14,056 - 14,056
- opcost - 7,602 - - 7,602
- investment cost - 17,850 - - 17,850
- grant/subsidy 25,452 - 25,452
- revenue transfer - 14,056 - - 14,056
Sub total (3) - - -

Other impacts
- Developer contribution (4) - -

Net business impact (5 = 2+3+4) 18,134 1,159 16,975

Total, PV of transport econ eff. Benefits (6 = 1+5) 25,892

Table 2 Public Accounts (£mill costs should be recorded as a positive number, surpluses as a negative one)
All Modes Other Rail
Total
Local Government funding
- Direct Revenue - - -
- Op costs -
- Investment costs -
- Developer and other contributions -
- Grant/Subsidy (k)* -
- Revenue transfer -
Net (7) - - -

Central Government funding


- Direct Revenue - - -
- Op costs -
- Investment costs* -
- Developer and other contributions -
- Grant/Subsidy (k)* 25,452 25,452
- Indirect Tax Revenues (i) 1,496 35 1,461
- Revenue transfer - 14,056 - 14,056
Net (8) 12,891 35 12,857

Total PV of costs (9 =7+8) 12,891

Table 3: Analysis of Monetised Costs and Benefits (AMCB)


Total
Noise 3
Local air quality 6
Greenhouse
Journey gases(incl. rolling stock quality, and in vehicle
ambience
crowding) 767
Accidents (incl. safety) 39
Consumer users (sub-total 1, Table 1) 7,759
Business users and providers (sub-total 5, Table 1) 18,134
Reliability (incl. performance & reliability) -
Option values -
Interchange (station quality and crowding) -

PVB (a = sum of all benefits) 26,708

PVC (b = sub-total 9, Table 2) 12,891

Overall impact, total


- NPV (a-b) 13,816
- BCR (a/b) 2.07

- Revised BCR (a-i)/(b-i) 2.21

139
HS2 Demand Model Analysis

Figure A1.4 - Central Scenario without Old Oak Station (Chapter 5)


TEE/Public Accounts Table All Outputs No Old Oak Station

Table 1: Economic Efficiency of Transport System (£mill, revenues are scored as positives, costs as negatives)

Total Other Rail


Consumers user benefits
- travel time saving 7,794 520 7,274
- Vehicle opcost 157 157 -
- user charges - 19 - 19 0
- during construction & maintenance - - -
Net (1) 7,932 658 7,274

Business
User benefits
- Travel time 18,434 1,184 17,249
- Vehicle opcost - 8 - 8 -
- user charges - 7 - 7 0
- during construction & maintenance - - -
Net (2) 18,419 1,169 17,249

Private sector provider impact


- revenue 13,468 - 13,468
- opcost - 7,502 - - 7,502
- investment cost - 17,194 - - 17,194
- grant/subsidy 24,696 - 24,696
- revenue transfer - 13,468 - - 13,468
Sub total (3) - - -

Other impacts
- Developer contribution (4) - -

Net business impact (5 = 2+3+4) 18,419 1,169 17,249

Total, PV of transport econ eff. Benefits (6 = 1+5) 26,351

Table 2 Public Accounts (£mill costs should be recorded as a positive number, surpluses as a negative one)
All Modes Highway/Air Rail
Total
Local Government funding
- Direct Revenue - - -
- Op costs -
- Investment costs -
- Developer and other contributions -
- Grant/Subsidy (k)* -
- Revenue transfer -
Net (7) - - -

Central Government funding


- Direct Revenue - - -
- Op costs -
- Investment costs* -
- Developer and other contributions -
- Grant/Subsidy (k)* 24,696 24,696
- Indirect Tax Revenues (i) 1,444 36 1,407
- Revenue transfer - 13,468 - 13,468
Net (8) 12,672 36 12,635

Total PV of costs (9 =7+8) 12,672

Table 3: Analysis of Monetised Costs and Benefits (AMCB)


Total
Noise 3
Local air quality 6
Greenhouse
Journey gases(incl. rolling stock quality, and in vehicle
ambience
crowding) 958
Accidents (incl. safety) 41
Consumer users (sub-total 1, Table 1) 7,932
Business users and providers (sub-total 5, Table 1) 18,419
Reliability (incl. performance & reliability) -
Option values -
Interchange (station quality and crowding) -

PVB (a = sum of all benefits) 27,358

PVC (b = sub-total 9, Table 2) 12,672

Overall impact, total


- NPV (a-b) 14,687
- BCR (a/b) 2.16

- Revised BCR (a-i)/(b-i) 2.31

140
Appendix 1: Transport Economic Efficiency Tables

Figure A1.5 - Central Scenario without Birmingham Interchange Station (Chapter 8)


TEE/Public Accounts Table All Outputs No Birmingham Interchange

Table 1: Economic Efficiency of Transport System (£mill, revenues are scored as positives, costs as negatives)

Total Other Rail


Consumers user benefits
- travel time saving 7,896 486 7,411
- Vehicle opcost 190 190 -
- user charges - 20 - 20 0
- during construction & maintenance - - -
Net (1) 8,067 656 7,411

Business
User benefits
- Travel time 19,326 1,191 18,135
- Vehicle opcost - 7 - 7 -
- user charges - 7 - 7 0
- during construction & maintenance - - -
Net (2) 19,311 1,176 18,135

Private sector provider impact


- revenue 14,726 - 14,726
- opcost - 7,526 - - 7,526
- investment cost - 17,315 - - 17,315
- grant/subsidy 24,841 - 24,841
- revenue transfer - 14,726 - - 14,726
Sub total (3) - - -

Other impacts
- Developer contribution (4) - -

Net business impact (5 = 2+3+4) 19,311 1,176 18,135

Total, PV of transport econ eff. Benefits (6 = 1+5) 27,378

Table 2 Public Accounts (£mill costs should be recorded as a positive number, surpluses as a negative one)
All Modes Other Rail
Total
Local Government funding
- Direct Revenue - - -
- Op costs -
- Investment costs -
- Developer and other contributions -
- Grant/Subsidy (k)* -
- Revenue transfer -
Net (7) - - -

Central Government funding


- Direct Revenue - - -
- Op costs -
- Investment costs* -
- Developer and other contributions -
- Grant/Subsidy (k)* 24,841 24,841
- Indirect Tax Revenues (i) 1,558 33 1,526
- Revenue transfer - 14,726 - 14,726
Net (8) 11,673 33 11,640

Total PV of costs (9 =7+8) 11,673

Table 3: Analysis of Monetised Costs and Benefits (AMCB)


Total
Noise 3
Local air quality 5
Greenhouse
Journey gases(incl. rolling stock quality, and in vehicle
ambience
crowding) 770
Accidents (incl. safety) 37
Consumer users (sub-total 1, Table 1) 8,067
Business users and providers (sub-total 5, Table 1) 19,311
Reliability (incl. performance & reliability) -
Option values -
Interchange (station quality and crowding) -

PVB (a = sum of all benefits) 28,193

PVC (b = sub-total 9, Table 2) 11,673

Overall impact, total


- NPV (a-b) 16,519
- BCR (a/b) 2.42

- Revised BCR (a-i)/(b-i) 2.63

141
HS2 Demand Model Analysis

Figure A1.6 - Central Scenario with a Heathrow Through Station (Chapter 5).
(Costs based on a Station at Iver)
TEE/Public Accounts Table All Outputs With Heathrow Station

Table 1: Economic Efficiency of Transport System (£mill, revenues are scored as positives, costs as negatives)

Total Other Rail


Consumers user benefits
- travel time saving 7,465 501 6,965
- Vehicle opcost 210 210 -
- user charges - 21 - 21 0
- during construction & maintenance - - -
Net (1) 7,655 690 6,965

Business
User benefits
- Travel time 18,152 1,343 16,809
- Vehicle opcost - 9 - 9 -
- user charges - 4 - 4 0
- during construction & maintenance - - -
Net (2) 18,139 1,330 16,809

Private sector provider impact


- revenue 13,731 - 13,731
- opcost - 7,702 - - 7,702
- investment cost - 20,401 - - 20,401
- grant/subsidy 28,103 - 28,103
- revenue transfer - 13,731 - - 13,731
Sub total (3) - - -

Other impacts
- Developer contribution (4) - -

Net business impact (5 = 2+3+4) 18,139 1,330 16,809

Total, PV of transport econ eff. Benefits (6 = 1+5) 25,794

Table 2 Public Accounts (£mill costs should be recorded as a positive number, surpluses as a negative one)
All Modes Other Rail
Total
Local Government funding
- Direct Revenue - - -
- Op costs -
- Investment costs -
- Developer and other contributions -
- Grant/Subsidy (k)* -
- Revenue transfer -
Net (7) - - -

Central Government funding


- Direct Revenue - - -
- Op costs -
- Investment costs* -
- Developer and other contributions -
- Grant/Subsidy (k)* 28,103 28,103
- Indirect Tax Revenues (i) 1,447 30 1,417
- Revenue transfer - 13,731 - 13,731
Net (8) 15,819 30 15,789

Total PV of costs (9 =7+8) 15,819

Table 3: Analysis of Monetised Costs and Benefits (AMCB)


Total
Noise 3
Local air quality 5
Greenhouse
Journey gases(incl. rolling stock quality, and in vehicle
ambience
crowding) 832
Accidents (incl. safety) 34
Consumer users (sub-total 1, Table 1) 7,655
Business users and providers (sub-total 5, Table 1) 18,139
Reliability (incl. performance & reliability) -
Option values -
Interchange (station quality and crowding) -

PVB (a = sum of all benefits) 26,668

PVC (b = sub-total 9, Table 2) 15,819

Overall impact, total


- NPV (a-b) 10,849
- BCR (a/b) 1.69

- Revised BCR (a-i)/(b-i) 1.75

142
Appendix 1: Transport Economic Efficiency Tables

Figure A1.7 - Wider Network Tests – The Inverse A (Chapter 11)


TEE/Public Accounts Table All Outputs Inverse A

Table 1: Economic Efficiency of Transport System (£mill, revenues are scored as positives, costs as negatives)

Total Other Rail


Consumers user benefits
- travel time saving 26,369 1,433 24,936
- Vehicle opcost 811 811 -
- user charges - 19 - 19 0
- during construction & maintenance - - -
Net (1) 27,161 2,225 24,936

Business
User benefits
- Travel time 75,307 4,238 71,069
- Vehicle opcost 35 35 -
- user charges - 7 - 7 0
- during construction & maintenance - - -
Net (2) 75,335 4,266 71,069

Private sector provider impact


- revenue 48,361 - 48,361
- opcost - 33,548 - - 33,548
- investment cost - 54,732 - - 54,732
- grant/subsidy 88,281 - 88,281
- revenue transfer - 48,361 - - 48,361
Sub total (3) - - -

Other impacts
- Developer contribution (4) - -

Net business impact (5 = 2+3+4) 75,335 4,266 71,069

Total, PV of transport econ eff. Benefits (6 = 1+5) 102,496

Table 2 Public Accounts (£mill costs should be recorded as a positive number, surpluses as a negative one)
All Modes Other Rail
Total
Local Government funding
- Direct Revenue - - -
- Op costs -
- Investment costs -
- Developer and other contributions -
- Grant/Subsidy (k)* -
- Revenue transfer -
Net (7) - - -

Central Government funding


- Direct Revenue - - -
- Op costs -
- Investment costs* -
- Developer and other contributions -
- Grant/Subsidy (k)* 88,281 88,281
- Indirect Tax Revenues (i) 4,928 66 4,862
- Revenue transfer - 48,361 - 48,361
Net (8) 44,848 66 44,782

Total PV of costs (9 =7+8) 44,848

Table 3: Analysis of Monetised Costs and Benefits (AMCB)


Total
Noise 6
Local air quality 11
Greenhouse
Journey gases(incl. rolling stock quality, and in vehicle
ambience
crowding) 509
Accidents (incl. safety) 76
Consumer users (sub-total 1, Table 1) 27,161
Business users and providers (sub-total 5, Table 1) 75,335
Reliability (incl. performance & reliability) -
Option values -
Interchange (station quality and crowding) -

PVB (a = sum of all benefits) 103,097

PVC (b = sub-total 9, Table 2) 44,848

Overall impact, total


- NPV (a-b) 58,250
- BCR (a/b) 2.30

- Revised BCR (a-i)/(b-i) 2.46

143
HS2 Demand Model Analysis

Figure A1.8 - Wider Network Tests – The Reverse E (Chapter 11)


TEE/Public Accounts Table All Outputs Reverse E

Table 1: Economic Efficiency of Transport System (£mill, revenues are scored as positives, costs as negatives)

Total Other Rail


Consumers user benefits
- travel time saving 23,721 1,262 22,459
- Vehicle opcost 735 735 -
- user charges - 19 - 19 0
- during construction & maintenance - - -
Net (1) 24,438 1,979 22,459

Business
User benefits
- Travel time 63,538 3,783 59,755
- Vehicle opcost 27 27 -
- user charges - 7 - 7 0
- during construction & maintenance - - -
Net (2) 63,559 3,804 59,755

Private sector provider impact


- revenue 42,123 - 42,123
- opcost - 31,638 - - 31,638
- investment cost - 52,377 - - 52,377
- grant/subsidy 84,015 - 84,015
- revenue transfer - 42,123 - - 42,123
Sub total (3) - - -

Other impacts
- Developer contribution (4) - -

Net business impact (5 = 2+3+4) 63,559 3,804 59,755

Total, PV of transport econ eff. Benefits (6 = 1+5) 87,996

Table 2 Public Accounts (£mill costs should be recorded as a positive number, surpluses as a negative one)
All Modes Other Rail
Total
Local Government funding
- Direct Revenue - - -
- Op costs -
- Investment costs -
- Developer and other contributions -
- Grant/Subsidy (k)* -
- Revenue transfer -
Net (7) - - -

Central Government funding


- Direct Revenue - - -
- Op costs -
- Investment costs* -
- Developer and other contributions -
- Grant/Subsidy (k)* 84,015 84,015
- Indirect Tax Revenues (i) 4,356 54 4,302
- Revenue transfer - 42,123 - 42,123
Net (8) 46,248 54 46,194

Total PV of costs (9 =7+8) 46,248

Table 3: Analysis of Monetised Costs and Benefits (AMCB)


Total
Noise 5
Local air quality 9
Greenhouse
Journey gases(incl. rolling stock quality, and in vehicle
ambience
crowding) 369
Accidents (incl. safety) 63
Consumer users (sub-total 1, Table 1) 24,438
Business users and providers (sub-total 5, Table 1) 63,559
Reliability (incl. performance & reliability) -
Option values -
Interchange (station quality and crowding) -

PVB (a = sum of all benefits) 88,442

PVC (b = sub-total 9, Table 2) 46,248

Overall impact, total


- NPV (a-b) 42,194
- BCR (a/b) 1.91

- Revised BCR (a-i)/(b-i) 2.01

144
Appendix 1: Transport Economic Efficiency Tables

Figure A1.9 - Wider Network Tests – The Reverse S (Chapter 11)


TEE/Public Accounts Table All Outputs Reverse S

Table 1: Economic Efficiency of Transport System (£mill, revenues are scored as positives, costs as negatives)

Total Other Rail


Consumers user benefits
- travel time saving 19,608 1,007 18,601
- Vehicle opcost 564 564 -
- user charges - 19 - 19 0
- during construction & maintenance - - -
Net (1) 20,152 1,551 18,601

Business
User benefits
- Travel time 53,357 2,988 50,369
- Vehicle opcost 16 16 -
- user charges - 4 - 4 0
- during construction & maintenance - - -
Net (2) 53,369 3,000 50,369

Private sector provider impact


- revenue 38,113 - 38,113
- opcost - 28,631 - - 28,631
- investment cost - 46,728 - - 46,728
- grant/subsidy 75,359 - 75,359
- revenue transfer - 38,113 - - 38,113
Sub total (3) - - -

Other impacts
- Developer contribution (4) - -

Net business impact (5 = 2+3+4) 53,369 3,000 50,369

Total, PV of transport econ eff. Benefits (6 = 1+5) 73,521

Table 2 Public Accounts (£mill costs should be recorded as a positive number, surpluses as a negative one)
All Modes Other Rail
Total
Local Government funding
- Direct Revenue - - -
- Op costs -
- Investment costs -
- Developer and other contributions -
- Grant/Subsidy (k)* -
- Revenue transfer -
Net (7) - - -

Central Government funding


- Direct Revenue - - -
- Op costs -
- Investment costs* -
- Developer and other contributions -
- Grant/Subsidy (k)* 75,359 75,359
- Indirect Tax Revenues (i) 3,920 43 3,877
- Revenue transfer - 38,113 - 38,113
Net (8) 41,166 43 41,123

Total PV of costs (9 =7+8) 41,166

Table 3: Analysis of Monetised Costs and Benefits (AMCB)


Total
Noise 4
Local air quality 7
Greenhouse
Journey gases(incl. rolling stock quality, and in vehicle
ambience
crowding) 304
Accidents (incl. safety) 50
Consumer users (sub-total 1, Table 1) 20,152
Business users and providers (sub-total 5, Table 1) 53,369
Reliability (incl. performance & reliability) -
Option values -
Interchange (station quality and crowding) -

PVB (a = sum of all benefits) 73,886

PVC (b = sub-total 9, Table 2) 41,166

Overall impact, total


- NPV (a-b) 32,720
- BCR (a/b) 1.79

- Revised BCR (a-i)/(b-i) 1.88

145
HS2 Demand Model Analysis

Figure A1.10 - HS2 Extension to Manchester (Chapter 11)


TEE/Public Accounts Table All Outputs Manchester Extension

Table 1: Economic Efficiency of Transport System (£mill, revenues are scored as positives, costs as negatives)

Total Other Rail


Consumers user benefits
- travel time saving 10,072 625 9,447
- Vehicle opcost 257 257 -
- user charges - 20 - 20 0
- during construction & maintenance - - -
Net (1) 10,309 862 9,447

Business
User benefits
- Travel time 26,193 1,718 24,475
- Vehicle opcost - 2 - 2 -
- user charges - 7 - 7 0
- during construction & maintenance - - -
Net (2) 26,184 1,709 24,475 -

Private sector provider impact


- revenue 19,055 - 19,055
- opcost - 10,103 - - 10,103
- investment cost - 22,653 - - 22,653
- grant/subsidy 32,756 - 32,756
- revenue transfer - 19,055 - - 19,055
Sub total (3) - - -

Other impacts
- Developer contribution (4) - -

Net business impact (5 = 2+3+4) 26,184 1,709 24,475

Total, PV of transport econ eff. Benefits (6 = 1+5) 36,493

Table 2 Public Accounts (£mill costs should be recorded as a positive number, surpluses as a negative one)
All Modes Other Rail
Total
Local Government funding
- Direct Revenue - - -
- Op costs -
- Investment costs -
- Developer and other contributions -
- Grant/Subsidy (k)* -
- Revenue transfer -
Net (7) - - -

Central Government funding


- Direct Revenue - - -
- Op costs -
- Investment costs* -
- Developer and other contributions -
- Grant/Subsidy (k)* 32,756 32,756
- Indirect Tax Revenues (i) 1,971 36 1,935
- Revenue transfer - 19,055 - 19,055
Net (8) 15,672 36 15,637

Total PV of costs (9 =7+8) 15,672

Table 3: Analysis of Monetised Costs and Benefits (AMCB)


Total
Noise 3
Local air quality 6
Greenhouse
Journey gases(incl. rolling stock quality, and in vehicle
ambience
crowding) 750
Accidents (incl. safety) 40
Consumer users (sub-total 1, Table 1) 10,309
Business users and providers (sub-total 5, Table 1) 26,184
Reliability (incl. performance & reliability) -
Option values -
Interchange (station quality and crowding) -

PVB (a = sum of all benefits) 37,292

PVC (b = sub-total 9, Table 2) 15,672

Overall impact, total


- NPV (a-b) 21,620
- BCR (a/b) 2.38

- Revised BCR (a-i)/(b-i) 2.58

146
Appendix 1: Transport Economic Efficiency Tables

Figure A1.11 - HS2 Extension to Leeds (Chapter 11)


TEE/Public Accounts Table All Outputs Leeds Extension

Table 1: Economic Efficiency of Transport System (£mill, revenues are scored as positives, costs as negatives)

Total Other Rail


Consumers user benefits
- travel time saving 16,818 951 15,867
- Vehicle opcost 473 473 -
- user charges - 20 - 20 0
- during construction & maintenance - - -
Net (1) 17,271 1,403 15,867

Business
User benefits
- Travel time 41,690 2,803 38,887
- Vehicle opcost 15 15 -
- user charges - 7 - 7 0
- during construction & maintenance - - -
Net (2) 41,698 2,811 38,887

Private sector provider impact


- revenue 28,937 - 28,937
- opcost - 14,857 - - 14,857
- investment cost - 24,215 - - 24,215
- grant/subsidy 39,072 - 39,072
- revenue transfer - 28,937 - - 28,937
Sub total (3) - - -

Other impacts
- Developer contribution (4) - -

Net business impact (5 = 2+3+4) 41,698 2,811 38,887

Total, PV of transport econ eff. Benefits (6 = 1+5) 58,969

Table 2 Public Accounts (£mill costs should be recorded as a positive number, surpluses as a negative one)
All Modes Other Rail
Total
Local Government funding
- Direct Revenue - - -
- Op costs -
- Investment costs -
- Developer and other contributions -
- Grant/Subsidy (k)* -
- Revenue transfer -
Net (7) - - -

Central Government funding


- Direct Revenue - - -
- Op costs -
- Investment costs* -
- Developer and other contributions -
- Grant/Subsidy (k)* 39,072 39,072
- Indirect Tax Revenues (i) 3,071 46 3,024
- Revenue transfer - 28,937 - 28,937
Net (8) 13,206 46 13,159

Total PV of costs (9 =7+8) 13,206

Table 3: Analysis of Monetised Costs and Benefits (AMCB)


Total
Noise 4
Local air quality 7
Greenhouse
Journey gases(incl. rolling stock quality, and in vehicle
ambience
crowding) 863
Accidents (incl. safety) 52
Consumer users (sub-total 1, Table 1) 17,271
Business users and providers (sub-total 5, Table 1) 41,698
Reliability (incl. performance & reliability) -
Option values -
Interchange (station quality and crowding) -

PVB (a = sum of all benefits) 59,896

PVC (b = sub-total 9, Table 2) 13,206

Overall impact, total


- NPV (a-b) 46,690
- BCR (a/b) 4.54

- Revised BCR (a-i)/(b-i) 5.61

147
HS2 Demand Model Analysis

A2.1 Testing Our Assumptions


A2.1.1 Analysis demonstrates that, under our central assumptions, HS2 would deliver strong benefits
and a good overall business case. As far as possible we have sought to base our central case on
conservative assumptions. This appendix reports the results of some of the critical sensitivity tests
we have undertaken.

A2.1.2 The results presented here use the final version of the model that has been developed for us.
However since finalising the model runs there has been a minor correction made to the estimation
of benefits – specifically the weightings applied to crowding and other elements of generalised
journey time. This has resulted in small changes in the overall benefits of the scheme, but should
not affect the pattern of benefits across different tests. The results presented in Chapter 10 have
been updated to reflect these changes. However we have not yet updated the sensitivity tests
outlined below. This should not change the relative comparison between model runs.

A2.2 Changing the forecast level of demand for long distance


rail trips
A2.2.1 Chapter 3 outlines the assumptions we have used about growth in transport demand without
HS2. These assumptions are based on standard forecasting approaches used in the rail industry
(in particular the Passenger Demand Forecasting Handbook). However we also highlight the
uncertainties and limitations in these approaches.

A2.2.2 Our model considers the impact of HS2 in two modelled years – 2021 and 2033. We can view these
as the impact of HS2 given two different levels of underlying demand (D1 and D2). The model then
estimates the annual benefits of HS2 at each of these two levels of demand. For the purposes of
appraisal we need to calculate the Present Value of benefits by discounting over 60 years. To do
this we need a time profile of benefits, which is calculated through extrapolation. Essentially this is
shown by the blue line in figure A2.1. This assumes:
• The level of benefits associated with the level of demand D1 (the pink dotted line) is achieved
at 2021.
• The Level of benefits associated with the level of demand D2 (the yellow dotted line) is achieved
at 2033.
• The level of demand in years between 2021 and 2033 are calculated using linear extrapolation
between these two points.
• The level of benefits in years after 2033 is capped at the 2033 level.21

21 Whilst the benefits in terms of time savings, crowding etc are held fixed, the values applied to these are assumed to grow in line with WebTAG guidance. Hence
there is some growth in benefits beyond 2033. However this a function of the appraisal guidance and not changes in modelled output.

148
Appendix 2:
Sensitivity Tests on HS2 Central Case
HS2 Demand Model Analysis

Figure A2.1 - Illustration of Extrapolation In Sensitivity Tests

120

100

80
Annual Benefits

60

40

20

0
2021 2026 2031 2036 2041 2046 2051 2056 2061 2066 2071
Year
D1 Central case Half Growth Rate D2 Cap at 2026

A2.2.3 We can easily adjust these assumptions. For example, if demand growth were slower, then this
would mean the benefits associated with the level of demand D1 would still occur, it is just that
they would arrive a few years later. This is illustrated by the purple line in figure A2.1. The benefits
associated with the level of demand D1 would still be reached, but this would be at 2036 instead
of 2021. And the benefits associated with D2 would not be reached until 2056. We can extrapolate
between these points to estimate the impact of slower growth on the PVB of HS2.

A2.2.4 By using this technique we can approximate any growth rate, and any level of cap up to 2033 without
the need for large numbers of model runs which were not possible in the time available. The
linearity of the extrapolation means this is only an indicative estimate (since there are several non-
linearities such as crowding factors), but it provides some idea of how sensitive the results are to the
assumptions.

150
Appendix 2: Transport Economic Efficiency Tables

Figure A2.2 - Sensitivity Test with Fixed Demand Cap and Lower Growth Rates

Sensitivity Test with Fixed Demand Cap and Lower Growth Rates
3

2.5

1.5
BCR

0.5

0
0% 10% 20% 30% 40% 50% 60% 70% 80% 90%
Reduction in growth rate

A2.2.5 Figure A2.2 shows how sensitive the business case is to the assumptions on the growth in
background demand for rail travel. It assumes that background demand will still reach the level we
currently forecast for 2033, but assumes this will be achieved at a later date (i.e. slower growth).
If growth were just 25% slower than currently projected (i.e. 2.7% per annum instead of 3.6% per
annum), the BCR for scheme opening at the end of 2025 (excluding wider economic impacts) would
drop below 1.5.

A2.2.6 As long as background demand growth continues, a lower rate of growth would raise questions
about when rather than if the scheme would be value for money. It might suggest the scheme should
open later than 2025, but there would still be a good business case at some point in the future.

A2.2.7 What is more significant is whether there will ever be sufficient demand to justify HS2. Our central
case assumes demand will not grow beyond 2033, but we have looked at what would happen if
market saturation occurred at a lower level of demand. We have investigated this by applying the cap
at earlier rates.

151
HS2 Demand Model Analysis

Figure A2.3: Sensitivity Test with Fixed Growth Rate and Lower Demand Cap

Sensitivity Test with Fixed Growth Rate and Lower Demand Cap
3

2.5

1.5
BCR

0.5

0
2021 2022 2023 2024 2025 2026 2027 2028 2029 2030 2031 2032 2033
Year of Cap

A2.2.8 Figure A2.3 shows what the BCR would be if growth in background demand were capped at various
years up to 2033. It shows that to achieve a BCR above 1.5, background growth in demand must
continue at current rates until at least 2027. This represents an increase of at least double today’s
levels.

A2.2.9 Both of these sensitivity tests demonstrate that the business case will be dependent on realising
the level of demand growth forecast in our central case. Overall a 10% reduction in demand on HS2
would reduce the BCR (excluding wider economic impacts) to 2 and a reduction of just over 20%
would reduce it to below 1.5.

152
Appendix 2: Transport Economic Efficiency Tables

A2.3 Changing Background Demand Growth and Prices on


Non-Rail Modes
A2.3.1 We have not been able to conduct specific model tests of different demand growth or pricing
assumptions on non-rail modes. However the business case is likely to be less sensitive to changes
in the assumptions on other modes. Overall mode shift accounts for a relatively small proportion of
the passengers on HS2, and therefore a relatively small proportion of the benefits.

A2.3.2 If demand growth for car and air travel were lower, then this would tend to reduce the potential
market from which HS2 could draw. It would reduce the number of passengers on HS2. However
the impact is likely to be small due to the composition of demand on HS2. Thus since 6% of HS2
passengers come from road, a 10% reduction in road demand could be expected to result in 0.6%
reduction in demand on HS2. A similar figure would be true for air demand.

A2.3.3 Changing prices will have more complex interactions, but may not change the overall market that
HS2 can draw from. A passenger who chooses to switch to HS2 without road pricing would most
likely continue to use HS2 in the presence of road pricing. Indeed the higher price of car travel is
likely to increase the number of passengers on HS2. Again this is likely to be a relatively marginal
effect. For example a 10% increase in the price of fuel would correspond to around a 3% fall in
traffic, with a corresponding increase of less than 1% in the level of demand on HS2.

A2.3.4 A third runway at Heathrow is included in our central case. If this were not constructed, there might
be additional demand for long distance rail trips as pricing and capacity constraints reduce the
number of domestic air trips. DfT forecasts suggest that without a third runway, air demand would
fall by just under 7%. If domestic air demand saw the same reduction, and assuming all of these
trips transferred to HS2, this would increase HS2 demand by less than 5%.

153
HS2 Demand Model Analysis

A2.4 Premium Fares


A2.4.1 We modelled our central case on the basis of the same fares for high speed rail and classic rail
users. We have also considered the scope for using premium fares on high speed services. The
impacts of premium fares are many and complex. It is not the case that a simple percentage
premium is applicable across all routes. Instead there would need to be careful management of
revenue strategies – similar to those already seen on long distance services – to maximise use of
capacity.

A2.4.2 The HS2 Model Development Report (Atkins, 2009) provides a summary of the tests undertaken.
It shows a summary of the revenue impacts of different levels of premium fares for London-
Birmingham and London-Manchester routes (See Figure A2.4).

Figure A2.4 – Impact of premium fares of revenues for specific routes

Business: London-Manchester Business: London-Birmingham

50,000 14,000
12,000
40,000
10,000
30,000 8,000
20,000 6,000
4,000
10,000
2,000
0 0
0% 7% 14% 21% 0% 10% 20% 30%

Leisure: London-Manchester Leisure: London-Birmingham

30,000 14,000
25,000 12,000
10,000
20,000
8,000
15,000
6,000
10,000 4,000
5,000 2,000
0 0
0% 7% 14% 21% 0% 10% 20% 30%

Source: Atkins (2009).

154
Appendix 2: Transport Economic Efficiency Tables

A2.4.3 The percentage fare premium varies according to the route and journey purpose since it was clear a
fixed percentage increase on all routes lead to fares that were too high on very long distance routes.

A2.4.4 Figure A2.4 shows the change in revenues on different routes and journey purposes as a result
of different levels of premium fare. Business generally is less price elastic, and so this leads to a
tendency for fare premiums to increase revenues. However even here, the potential may be for only
relatively small premiums. For example Manchester business flows (see top left chart in figure A2.4)
show a relatively small increase in revenues up to a 7% fare premium. Beyond this, revenues fall as
fares increase further.

A2.4.5 It is not possible at this stage of development to hypothesise the detailed nature of such a strategy.
More work is needed in this area. However our preliminary conclusions are:
• The scope for premium fares is more pronounced in the business market than the more price
sensitive leisure market.
• Small increases in fares may lead to a reduction in revenue, but larger increases may increase
net revenue. This is because the first passengers priced off will tend to be new traffic generated
by high speed rail (who drive new revenues). At higher fare levels passengers tend to switch to
classic rail and so some rail fare revenue is maintained.
• Competition is key. The availability of non-premium service alternatives would make a big
difference to the scope to generate additional revenues through premium fares.
• Pricing may be an effective tool to manage crowding problems. The demand model suggests
there is strong demand and some crowding on certain routes – particularly those to Scotland.
In the absence of a wider network (where more capacity could be provided), premium fares may
offer a tool to manage the crowding levels on these services.

A2.4.6 All these conclusions point to the need for more detailed modelling of fares strategies, considering
the different potential markets service patterns and peak/off-peak pricing potential.

155
HS2 Demand Model Analysis

A2.5 Comparison with a classic line


A2.5.1 We also examined, as an alternative, the case for a new line running at conventional speed. Our
appraisal of a classic line was high level and based on analytical constructs; we applied generalised
cost and journey time assumptions to our preferred line of route. If Government wished to proceed
with a conventional speed line instead of a high speed line, much more work would be required on
route options and design, including consideration of intermediate stations.

A2.5.2 A new classic line would generate some cost savings over our central case, with some savings on
construction and other capital costs. We concluded that the cost of constructing the scheme to
conventional speed only might save about 9% of the costs of the high speed line. Given the cost of
the classic compatible trains would be much higher than conventional speed trains, a further cost
saving would be expected. We assumed that operating and maintenance costs would be comparable.
An overall cost saving of the order of £3bn would therefore be possible with a classic line.

A2.5.3 However this cost saving would only be achieved with a significant time penalty for HS2 passengers.
Travelling from London to Birmingham, following the same service pattern as the high speed
preferred package, would take an extra 15 minutes, based on standard maximum speeds on the UK
network and the acceleration performance of a standard reference train. This would halve the time
saving from a high speed train.

A2.5.4 This would reduce the number of people travelling on the line by 20% causing overall benefits to
fall by 23% or £6.7bn (see Table A2.5). Revenues would fall by around 19%, or £2.9bn, which means
that while construction, operating and maintenance costs would fall by around £3.5bn, the net cost
saving (revenues minus cost) would relatively small.

Table A2.5 - Benefits of the HS2 Central Case Compared to a New Classic Line
Quantified Costs and Benefits PV 2009 discount year and prices £ billion

   Transport User Benefits 6.7

   Other Benefits (excl Carbon) 0.0

Net Transport Benefits 6.7

   Capital Costs 3.0

   Operating Costs 0.5

Total Costs 3.5

   Revenues 2.9

   Indirect Tax -0.3

Benefit Cost Ratio (Relative BCR of HS2 over Classic Line Alternative) 7.3

156
Appendix 2: Transport Economic Efficiency Tables

A2.5.5 So upgrading the line to high speed would only have a relatively small cost to Government, but
would generate significant benefits (time savings) to passengers on HS2. As a result the classic line
alternative would have a worse business case than HS2 and the incremental case for high speed is
very strong.

A2.6 Reliability
A2.6.1 We have outlined in Chapter 3 how we have incorporated the potential benefits that high speed rail
might deliver from improved reliability. The improvement in reliability is converted in to journey time
savings, which are then subtracted from the actual journey times offered by HS2. This is a pragmatic
approach to estimating a key benefit of high speed rail.

A2.6.2 However, while it is important that we estimate the benefits of reliability, we need to understand how
significant the benefits are that it generates, and therefore how reliant the business case for HS2
is on these benefits. Table A2.6 outlines the results of a test which does not adjust journey times to
include reliability benefits.

Table A2.6 - Benefits from Improved Reliability


Quantified Costs and Benefits PV 2009 discount year and prices £ billion

   Transport User Benefits 2.5

   Other Benefits (excl Carbon) 0.0

Net Transport Benefits 2.5

   Revenues 1.0

   Indirect Tax -0.1

Benefit Cost Ratio (of HS2 without reliability benefits) 2.2

A2.6.3 Overall this reduces benefits by just under 10%, and would reduce the BCR to around 2.2 (excluding
wider economic impacts).

157
Appendix 3:
High Speed Rail and Spatial Patterns
and Strategies in Cities and Regions
Appendix 3: High Speed Rail and Spatial Patterns and Strategies in Cities and Regions

A3.1 Introduction
A3.1.1 The following paper summarises HS2’s understanding and interpretation of the literature on land
use change as a result of transport interventions, and in particular the international experience of
High Speed Rail. We are extremely grateful for the advice and comment of Roger Vickerman and Reg
Harman in putting this paper together. However the findings and conclusions of this paper are those
of HS2 alone.

A3.1.2 Transport can play an important role in defining the spatial patterns of economic activity across a
city or region. It is often a key part of the strategies developed by regional and city authorities to
shape the economy, environment and community within that area.

A3.1. 3 Spatial strategies may involve land use change which includes a wide range of different impacts.
It may relate to relocation of households (both new houses and people moving home), changes in
the type of business in an area, through to intensification of economic activity in that area. Changes
and improvements in the transport network can support and perhaps encourage land use change
through changing the accessibility of one area (or region) in relation to another. A more accessible
location is often more attractive to both households and businesses who are keen to access
employment, services and customers. And there is a feedback, with land use change affecting the
strength of the case for some transport schemes.

A3.1.4 Land use change can manifest itself in a variety of different ways, including:
• People moving house – e.g. taking advantage of new and faster links to move to a larger house
further from their job
• Firms may move to take advantage of new or improved transport opportunities to improve links
between their customers or suppliers

A3.1.5 High Speed Rail would represent a major intervention which could lead to land use change at a local,
regional and even national level. It has the potential to focus economic activity in the vicinity of a
station (and the surrounding city) which acts as a node for both regional and national networks. This
could trigger redistribution of activity from within the region and across the country.

A3.1.6 It is therefore important to consider the role of high speed rail in changing the spatial patterns and
the role of high speed rail within wider strategies. This appendix considers what such impacts might
be and what evidence exists. It concludes that the key for a high speed rail station being a catalyst
for significant local and regional development is the integration of that station into a coherent
wider spatial strategy for the city or region. However it also notes that this will not be a win-win
conclusion. Some areas within a wider region may lose out, and it is possible a region itself may lose
with some activity encouraged to relocate towards London. Whether such impacts materialise and

159
HS2 Demand Model Analysis

how significant they are will depend on the economic structure of the cities, as well as the actions of
regional and local planning authorities.

A3.2 Why Does Spatial Impact (Land Use Change) Matter?


A3.2.1 Land use patterns are determined by a multiplicity of decisions taken by many different agents. A
firm when choosing where to locate will consider many factors, including the price and availability
of suitable buildings, labour supply and skills base, and access to markets to sell their product.
Households choosing a home may trade off access to jobs (and the associated wage of those jobs)
against the size of house, attractiveness of an area, even the quality of local schools.

A3.2.2 Transport affects a number of these factors, particularly the accessibility of jobs (and labour
supply), goods and services and customers. Changes in the transport network, both in terms of
the connectivity and efficiency of that network, can affect location decisions and result in land use
change. However transport factors are more likely to affect where firms and households relocate,
once the decision to move has been made, than to initiate a decision to relocate. Even then, good
transport links may be seen as a bonus rather than a critical factor in location decisions.

A3.2.3 At a local level improving connectivity and accessibility can encourage businesses to locate in the
area, boosting the economy, increasing jobs and helping to regenerate depressed economies.
However many studies point out that, while transport is generally a very important factor in
this process, it is often other factors – such as the local skills base – that are also important in
regeneration. Transport can support growth, but it rarely ‘unlocks’ growth constraints on its own.

A3.2.4 At a regional level, improvements in transport may encourage the re-distribution of economic
activity – both within and across regions. A transport improvement may attract firms to relocate
from other areas. This is to the benefit of the receiving area, but to the detriment of the area losing
business. The net effect may still be positive where the transport scheme boosts productivity –
either through reducing business costs (e.g. time savings) or agglomeration impacts as a result of
increased density of firms – but there would clearly be winners and losers within this process.

A3.2.5 A region may gain from improved transport links encouraging firms to locate in that region, but the
transport intervention may also encourage firms away (as well as towards) the region receiving
that intervention. By improving links between (say) the West Midlands and London, firms in the
West Midlands might have the opportunity to relocate in London, whilst continuing to serve existing
customers in the West Midlands. Alternatively firms in London might expand into the West Midlands,
taking market share from existing West Midlands firms.

A3.2.6 Whether such movements occur is likely to depend on the nature of the transport intervention and
the economic geography of that area. So for example high speed rail has been demonstrated have
most significant impacts on the service sector. Therefore the scope for relocation of firms across and
between regions – as well as the draw of London – will be more significant for cities with a service
sector based economy.

160
Appendix 3: High Speed Rail and Spatial Patterns and Strategies in Cities and Regions

A3.2.7 At a local level, these changes may be significant. They cannot be ignored by high speed rail, and
the development of stations will need to take account of the spatial implications of these schemes.
However at a national level there is a danger that these changes in spatial patterns represent
movements of economic activity and jobs around the country (rather than adding to the overall job
market).

A3.2.8 This may not mean there is no (net) impact on the productivity and prosperity of the national
economy. If land use change leads to more clustering of firms and workers (say around stations
on the rail network), then this will tend to boost agglomeration and deepen labour markets.
Anything that reduces the barriers between firms, and between firms and their workers will tend
to benefit the national economy. However the effect may be much more significant in specific local
communities – particularly where regeneration is facilitated. It seems unlikely that these impacts
can be determined a priori without much more detailed work.

A3.3 How Might HS2 Affect Land Use?


A3.3.1 High speed rail would represent a step change in the connectivity between places served by the high
speed network. This could have many effects, over a wide geographical area. For example:
• The investment in a high quality station could encourage localised regeneration, with investment
making the station and potentially surrounding area more attractive. This is much more likely if it
fits in with the city strategy, for both local transport planning and land-use planning.
• At a regional level, improved links (particularly to London) could encourage firms to relocate
closer to a new high speed rail station – with benefits to the areas close to the station, perhaps to
the detriment of surrounding areas.
• At a national level, any increase in agglomeration (from intensified economic activity near the
station) will boost productivity and therefore GDP.

A3.3.2 Whether these occur, and how significant they are will depend on the detailed design of the scheme
– even down to the quality and design of the final high speed rail stations. They will also depend
crucially on the way high speed rail is integrated into the surrounding transport and economic
networks.

A3.3.3 HS2 has not attempted to explicitly model these impacts. At this stage we have limited our
analysis to a review of the experience of high speed rail in other countries in the development and
regeneration of cities, in order to identify the likely direction of these impacts, and to understand
what has and hasn’t worked. This does not suggest that these impacts are not important or that they
should not be modelled at a later stage of design (if appropriate). Rather it reflects a view that any
modelling at this stage would be subject to significant uncertainty.

161
HS2 Demand Model Analysis

A3.4 The Evidence of Land Use Change and HSR


A3.4.1 There are examples where high speed rail has resulted in significant effects from across the world,
but also many where those impacts have failed to materialise. Two of the most well known examples
are that of Lille and Lyon.
• The Lille conurbation has seen significant regeneration since the opening of TGV Nord in 1993.
Lille was a manufacturing city which suffered major decline during the 1960s but has since seen
a major drive for growth led by the city council and the other conurbation municipalities, together
with the Nord Pas de Calais regional council. Major development has occurred in the areas
surrounding the station but there has also been substantial regeneration at a range of locations
across the conurbation, linked by new transit lines.
• Lyon has seen the relocation of its commercial district across the city into to the area surrounding
the new Part-Dieu station. This is now the focus for most regional (TER) rail services,
strengthening the city’s already strong role as the regional commercial centre but also providing
good links to the TGV services for many other centres across the region.

A3.4.2 Examples where broadly similar benefits have been gained from redevelopment and upgraded local
transport exist across continental Europe, including Zaragoza and Cordoba (Spain), Köln (Germany),
Torino (Italy), Antwerpen (Belgium).

A3.4.3 However there have been some cases where a high speed rail connection has had very limited (and
even negative) impacts. These include:
• Vendome, where – despite plans for redevelopment of the area, the station is primarily used for
commuting to Paris and has lead to very little economic development in the area
• Haute Picardie, where there has been relatively limited economic development – and indeed use
of the high speed rail station.

A3.4.4 Lessons have been learned from these. The intermediate stations on the TGV link between Paris and
Strasbourg have seen much more careful planning of local transport links to the nearest regional
town, although even here there are big contrasts between the different locations.

162
Appendix 3: High Speed Rail and Spatial Patterns and Strategies in Cities and Regions

A3.4.5 Most research into the impact of high speed rail on local and regional economies has focused on
individual examples, such as those outlined above. The conclusions are often hard to generalise.
However some common themes come through. An observation made by both Bonnafous (1987) and
Willigers (2003) is that firms see high speed rail as a ‘bonus’. By giving confirmation of an ‘address
on the network’ and thus underwriting a sense of confidence in a region it helps to confirm a
decision to locate in a particular area, but other factors determine that decision. This adds further
evidence that simply building a new link or station is not sufficient to ensure success. Wider factors
within the local and regional economy need to be addressed – such as the skills base or local
infrastructure. The examples of where high speed rail has been a success have often seen a close
integration of policies on a wide range of local and spatial issues together with the construction of
high speed rail to deliver the outcomes that were desired.

A3.4.6 Bonnafous (1987) also suggests that the TGV has encouraged regional firms to fill niche markets
in Paris. In particular service sector and ‘consultancy’ type firms build on a familiarity with dealing
with small and medium sized firms to expand in to Parisian markets. But the opposite is not true,
with Parisian firms focusing on large firms and international markets rather than expanding into
markets around Lyon. This matches analysis in Harman (2006).

A3.4.7 In Japan, Sasaki et al (1997) suggest that high speed rail has the effect of dispersing investment and
economic activity from the ‘developed region’ towards the periphery. This result did not appear to be
to the detriment of the ‘developed region’, but there might be negative effects for regions that were
not connected to the core high speed network.

A3.4.8 In line with the general findings in the literature, Sasaki et al again suggests that while HSR may
have an effect, other factors such as the productive capability and skills of a regional economy will
also be important. They conclude that while HSR can help to redistribute economic activity it is
unlikely to solve regional inequalities.

A3.4.9 Most recently Greengauge 21 considered the scope for wider economic impacts including
the potential for land use change using a version of the DELTA model to model the impact of
accessibility change on employment in different zones. They conclude wider economic impacts could
add up to 20% benefits to the traditional transport appraisal. However the bulk of these impacts
came from the conventional assessment of Wider Economic Impacts, and not changes in land use
driven by high speed rail.

A3.4.10 It is clear from the evidence available that high speed rail has the potential to have significant effects
on land use and activity at a local and regional level. Whether these local and regional effects feed
into economic benefits at a national level is unclear – and there is a lack of evidence in this area.
However regardless of what the impact is, it is clear that HSR has been most successful where it has
formed a part of a wider package of measures.

163
HS2 Demand Model Analysis

A3.5 Conclusions
A3.5.1 High speed rail would represent a step change in the connectivity and speed of the transport
network. It would clearly have the potential to have significant impacts on the performance of
regional economies, and the distribution and nature of economic activity across and between
regions.

A3.5.2 The international experience shows that there are many reasons for the success or failure of
individual high speed rail stations – often specific to the local circumstances. However there are
some consistent messages in this literature:

• Integration is Key – Simply building a station or link to the high speed network is not enough.
For success to be achieved the station has to be integrated into the wider strategic plans of local
agencies, especially integration with the local transport network. There are many factors which
are more important in regeneration than transport alone. It not surprising therefore that wider
strategies on land use planning and even education and skills are needed to successfully integrate a
station into the local and regional economy.

• Role as a hub – Whilst not always the case, there are examples of success where the high speed rail
station also has hub-like connectivity with good links to the local/regional rail network as well as the
high speed network. Thus the station becomes a focus for the regional economy as well as a wider
market supported by high speed.

• This is not win-win – Although there are many examples where growth and regeneration has been
delivered around a high speed rail station, this may be to the detriment of the surrounding region.
Economic activity tends to move away from the peripheries and towards the high speed station or
hub. The extent to which this happens is not clear, nor the key factors that may affect it. One might
hypothesise the greater degree of competition there is between firms in the periphery and around
the station, the greater the loss to the surrounding area, but more research is needed here.

A3.5.3 It is clear from international experience that for high speed rail to deliver benefits at a local and
regional level there needs to be clear and strongly led spatial and economic planning strategies.
The appropriate design and connectivity of the high speed network will be important, but perhaps
more important is the integration of that network within the local and regional strategies. Where
high speed rail stations have been successful in driving regeneration and economic development,
there has been a clear long term vision for the city, and how high speed rail fits within that vision.
Strong leadership at a local level is needed to ensure the effective integration of local priorities with
national.

164
Appendix 3: High Speed Rail and Spatial Patterns and Strategies in Cities and Regions

A3.5.4 Wider policy formulation and implementation is also needed to ensure that (a) land use planning
facilitates land use change and (b) other policies are in place to ensure the necessary skills and
other factors exist to take advantage of this opportunity. Integration into the local transport network
as part of this will boost the case, with a suggestion that railway hubs help to integrate local,
regional and large scale markets – providing a focus to activity.

A3.5.5 The impact of a high speed rail station can clearly be significant at a local level. They therefore play
an important role within regional and local spatial strategies. However the degree to which they
boost productivity at a national level is far less certain. Such local and regional impacts are likely
to reflect a redistribution of economic activity rather than new activity. They are in essence the
manifestation of time savings that are already captured in transport appraisal.

A3.6 References
Bonnafous (1987), Regional Impacts of the TGV, Transportation vol. 14

Harman (2006), High speed trains and the development and regeneration of cities, Greengauge 21
(http://www.greengauge21.net/assets/European_Regeneration_Experience.pdf)

Sasaki, Okaski and Ando (1997), High-speed rail transit impact on regional systems: does the
Shinkansen contribute to dispersion?, Annals of Regional Science

Segal (2009), A Strategy for a High Speed Rail Network in Britain, Paper presented to the European
Transport Conference

Vickerman (2009), Indirect and Wider Economic Impacts of High Speed Rail, in de Rus et al (2009)
Economic Analysis of High Speed Rail in Europe, Fundacion BBVA

Vickerman (1997), High-speed rail in Europe: experience and issues for future development, The
Annals of Regional Science

Willigers (2003), High speed railway developments and corporate location decisions, Paper
presented at the 43rd ERSA Congress, Jyväskylä

165
Appendix 4:
Service Specification for
Wider Network Test
Appendix 4: Service Specification for Wider Network Tests

A4.1.1 This appendix contains the detailed service specifications we used for the demand modelling runs
informing the analysis behind the Longer Term Strategy (Chapter 6 of the main report). Chapter 11
describes our approach in detail.

A4.1.2 We calculated journey times for routes on the three networks as well as for the extensions to
Manchester and Leeds for modelling purposes. These are based on assumed speed profiles and
route distances and are generally conservative estimates. The benefits from journey time savings
can be very substantial, but we have avoided the temptation to ‘assume the best’. In reality, initial
optimum journey times will typically be restricted by a number of factors, such as tunnelling
prompted by specific environmental mitigation, linespeed restrictions to reduce noise impacts on
the local population and by constrained speeds on urban route sections.

A4.1.3 The figures below graphically represent the journey times and service patterns that we assumed
under each of the five scenarios. These are not optimised but rather reflect a plausible service
within the overall capacity of the line. They have not been subjected to the same level of scrutiny as
those developed for HS2. As explained in Chapter 11 the starting point and reference cases for the
two extension scenarios was the Day One scenario while the three wider networks are assessed
against the ‘do minimum’ scenario.

A4.1.4 In designing service patterns there will always be a delicate balance to be struck between on the one
hand stopping trains to widen accessibilty and improve connections, and on the other reducing the
number of stops to achieve better journey times. As explained in Chapter 11, we have undertaken
some analysis to improve this trade off. We do not purport, however, to have found the optimal
balance in this exercise.

167
168
Euston
 Birmingham
Central . . . . .

Old
Oak
Common Nottingham
Parkway . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

Birmingham
interchange South
Yorkshire
Parkway . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

Birmingham
Central Liverpool
Central

0:49
Manchester
Central . . . . . . Manchester
Central . . . . . . . . .

1:20 1:26 0:40


Liverpool
Central . . . . . . . . . . . . Leeds
Central . . . . .

1:36 0:50 1:05
Nottingham
Parkway . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Leeds
Parkway . . . . . . . .

South
Yorkshire
Parkway . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Teesside
Parkway . . . . . . . .
HS2 Demand Model Analysis

1:15
Leeds
Central . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Newcastle
Central

1:20 1:26 1:35 1:40 1:55 1:50


West
Yorkshire
Parkway . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Preston
Parkway . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

Teesside
Parkway . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Carstairs
Interchange . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . split split

Newcastle
Central . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Glasgow
Central . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

2:00 2:07 2:13 2:09 2:38


Preston
Parkway . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Edinburgh
Central . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

2:09 2:38
Carstairs
Interchange . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . split split

.
Glasgow
Central . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
Inverse A Service Specification

2:40 2:45
Edinburgh
Central . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

2:40 2:45
Euston
 Birmingham
Central . . . . .

Old
Oak
Common Nottingham
Parkway . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

Birmingham
interchange South
Yorkshire
Parkway . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

Birmingham
Central Liverpool
Central

0:49
Manchester
Central . . . . . . Manchester
Central . . . . . . . . .

1:40 1:15
Stafford . . . . . . . . . . . . Leeds
Central . . . . .

0:50 1:05
Crewe . . . . . . . . . . . . West
Yorkshire
Parkway . . . . . . . .

Warrington
Bank
Quay . . . . . . . . . . . . Teesside
Parkway . . . . . . . .

Runcorn . . . . . . . . . . . . Newcastle
Central

1:39 2:29 1:49


Liverpool
Central . . . . . . . . . . . . Newcastle
Interchange . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

1:50
Nottingham
Parkway . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Hawick
Parkway . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . split split

South
Yorkshire
Parkway . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Glasgow
Central . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

1:15 3:00 2:50


Leeds
Central . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Edinburgh
Central . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

1:20 1:26 1:35 3:00 2:50


West
Yorkshire
Parkway . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

.
Teesside
Parkway . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

Newcastle
Central . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

2:03 2:12 2:16


Reverse E Service Specification

Newcastle
Interchange . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

Wigan
North
Western . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

Preston
Parkway . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

Hawick
Parkway . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . split split


Appendix 4: Service Specification for Wider Network Tests

Glasgow
Central . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

3:10 3:20 4:00


Edinburgh
Central . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

3:10 3:20
Hybrid Services HS Captive Services

169
170
Euston
 Birmingham
Central .

Old
Oak
Common Manchester
Central .

0:40
Birmingham
interchange Leeds
Central . . . . . .

0:23
Birmingham
Central West
Yorkshire
Parkway . . . . . . . . . .

0:49
Manchester
Central . . . . . . Teesside
Parkway . . . . . . . . . .

1:20
Stafford . . . . . . . . . . . . Newcastle
Central . . . . . . . . . .

1:51
Crewe . . . . . . . . . . . . Hawick

Parkway . . . . . . . . . . .

Warrington
Bank
Quay . . . . . . . . . . . . Edinburgh
Central . . . . . . . . . . .
HS2 Demand Model Analysis

2:39
Runcorn . . . . . . . . . . . .

Liverpool
Central . . . . . . . . . . . .

1:50

Leeds
Central . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

1:35 1:40
West
Yorkshire
Parkway . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

Teesside
Parkway . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
.

Newcastle
Central . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

2:07
Newcastle
Interchange . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
Reverse S Service Specification

2:14
Wigan
North
Western . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

Preston . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

Hawick

Parkway . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . split split

Glasgow
Central . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

3:22 3:17 4:00


Edinburgh
Central . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

3:46 3:22 3:17

Hybrid Services HS Captive Services


Euston
 Birmingham
Central

Old
Oak
Common Manchester
Central

0:54
Birmingham
interchange

Birmingham
Central

0:49
Stafford . . . . . .

Crewe . . . . . .

Manchester
Piccadilly . . . . . .

1:20
Warrington
Bank
Quay . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

Runcorn . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

Liverpool
Lime
Street . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

1:37 1:50
Wigan
North
Western . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
Manchester Extensions Service Specification

Preston . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
Appendix 4: Service Specification for Wider Network Tests

Glasgow
Central . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

3:47
. . . . .
Hybrid Services HS Captive Services Peak Hour Only

171
. . . . .
172
Hybrid Services
HS Captive Services
Peak Hour Only
These Services are unchanged from Day One scenario Additional Services on Eastern Route

Euston
 Euston


Old
Oak
Common Old
Oak
Common

Birmingham
interchange Birmingham
interchange

Birmingham
Central Birmingham
Central

0:49
HS2 Demand Model Analysis

Stafford . . . . . . . . Nottingham
Parkway

Crewe . . . . . . . . South
Yorkshire
Parkway

1:15
Wilmslow . . . . . . . . Leeds
Central

1:20 1:26 1:35 1:05


Stockport . . . . . . . . West
Yorkshire
Parkway . . . . . . . . .

Manchester
Piccadilly . . . . . . . . Teesside
Parkway . . . . . . . . .

1:40 1:44
Warrington
Bank
Quay . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Newcastle
Central . . . . . . . . .

2:37 2:20
Runcorn . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

Liverpool
Lime
Street . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

1:50
Wigan
North
Western . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
Leeds Extension Service Specification and Background Data

Preston . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

1:48
Glasgow
Central . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

4:00

Das könnte Ihnen auch gefallen