Sie sind auf Seite 1von 16

Construction Management and Economics

ISSN: 0144-6193 (Print) 1466-433X (Online) Journal homepage: http://www.tandfonline.com/loi/rcme20

An analysis of construction productivity in


Malaysia

Fah Choy Chia , Martin Skitmore , Goran Runeson & Adrian Bridge

To cite this article: Fah Choy Chia , Martin Skitmore , Goran Runeson & Adrian Bridge (2012) An
analysis of construction productivity in Malaysia, Construction Management and Economics, 30:12,
1055-1069, DOI: 10.1080/01446193.2012.711910

To link to this article: https://doi.org/10.1080/01446193.2012.711910

Published online: 10 Aug 2012.

Submit your article to this journal

Article views: 1054

Citing articles: 6 View citing articles

Full Terms & Conditions of access and use can be found at


http://www.tandfonline.com/action/journalInformation?journalCode=rcme20
Construction Management and Economics (December 2012) 30, 1055–1069

An analysis of construction productivity in Malaysia


FAH CHOY CHIA1*, MARTIN SKITMORE2, GORAN RUNESON3 and ADRIAN BRIDGE2
1
Department of Built Environment, Universiti Tunku Abdul Rahman, Jalan Genting Klang, Setapak, Kuala
Lumpur, Malaysia
2
Science and Engineering Faculty, Queensland University of Technology, Brisbane, Australia
3
Faculty of Design, University of Technology, Architecture and Building, Sydney, Australia

Received 2 April 2012; accepted 10 July 2012

The construction industry is an industry of major strategic importance. Its level of productivity has a signifi-
cant effect on national economic growth. Productivity indicators are examined. The indicators consist of
labour productivity, capital productivity, labour competitiveness, capital intensity and added value content
of data, which are obtained from the published census/biannual surveys of the construction industry between
the years 1999 and 2011 from the Department of Statistics of Malaysia. The results indicated that there is
an improvement in the labour productivity, but the value-added content is declining. The civil engineering
and special trades subsectors are more productive than the residential and non-residential subsectors in
terms of labour productivity because machine-for-labour substitution is a more important process in those
subsectors. The capital-intensive characteristics of civil engineering and special trade works enable these sub-
sectors to achieve higher added value per labour cost but not the capital productivity. The added value per
labour cost is lower in larger organizations despite higher capital productivity. However, the capital intensity
is lower and unit labour cost is higher in the larger organizations.

Keywords: Construction industry, gross output, Malaysia, productivity, value added.

Introduction are analysed at the sectoral and subsectoral levels.


The productivity indicators are benchmarked to 1996
A country’s growth in productivity is important to in order to establish the grounds for the changes
maintain or increase its international competitiveness according to the types of construction and size of
and standard of living. It is the key determinant of organizations.
long-run growth which leads to higher prosperity. This paper is divided into five sections. The first
The construction industry is an industry of major section examines the issue of productivity measure-
strategic importance. Its level of productivity has a ment. The second section provides a brief account of
significant effect on national economic growth. Gains the productivity indicators considered, sources of data
from higher construction productivity flow across the and the method of computation used. The third
economy, because all industries are reliant on con- section presents the results from the analysis of the
struction to some extent as part of their business productivity indicators, while the fourth section pro-
investment. There is a unidirectional causality from vides some theoretical perspectives concerning the
annual construction growth to annual GDP growth productivity indicators. The final section concludes
for the long period of 1970 to 2009 in Malaysia with the main findings and their implications.
(Chia, 2012).
In this paper, the data available from various cen- Productivity measurement
sus/survey reports of the construction industry
between the years 1996 and 2009 published by the Productivity has been defined generally as a ratio of a
Department of Statistics Malaysia from 1999 to 2011 measure of output to a measure of some or all of the

*Author for correspondence. E-mail: chiafc@utar.edu.my

Construction Management and Economics


ISSN 0144-6193 print/ISSN 1466-433X online Ó 2012 Taylor & Francis
http://www.tandfonline.com
http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/01446193.2012.711910
1056 Chia et al.

resources used to produce this output (Grimes, construction sector. Identifying and capturing changes
2007). There are many different measures of produc- in the quality of services is difficult in both concept
tivity, the choice of which depends on the purpose of and practice. Although some adjustments for quality
the productivity measurement and availability of data. are captured in the price data used to deflate current
Broadly, productivity measures can be classified as price estimates, the difficulties involved are such that
single factor productivity measures or multi-factor the final measure of industry output may not
productivity measures (Organisation for Economic adequately capture all the changes (Pink, 2007).
Co-operation and Development, 2001). Labour The value-added measure is more meaningful in
productivity and capital productivity are the two most the presence of outsourcing and is generally favoured
common examples of single factor productivity for estimating labour productivity (Cobbold, 2003).
measures. The value-added-based measure excludes intermedi-
Labour productivity is a partial productivity mea- ate inputs. This is in effect a total measure of produc-
sure and reflects the combined influence of a host of tivity, converted into a partial measure by deducting
factors (Organisation for Economic Co-operation and the value of raw materials, bought-out goods and
Development, 2001). It is typically measured as out- services from both the numerator and the denomina-
put per person employed or per hour worked. Capital tor to give a measure of value added during the
productivity is usually defined as the output of or production process (Grimes, 2007). By excluding
return on capital invested. Two basic measures of intermediate inputs, value-added-based estimates of
output are gross output and value-added output. The productivity growth ignore the effect of productivity
former measure includes intermediate inputs (materi- improvements gained through the more efficient use
als, energy and services used in the process of produc- of intermediate inputs to capital and labour.
tion) while the latter measure excludes those inputs Overall, it would appear that gross output and
(Cobbold, 2003). value-added-based productivity measures are useful
The gross output-based productivity measure complements. When technical progress affects all fac-
provides a more complete picture of the production tors of production proportionally, the former is a bet-
process by including intermediate inputs as a source ter measure of technical change. Value-added-based
of industry growth. It reflects a variety of influences, productivity measures are more meaningful in the
including changes in efficiency, economies of scale, presence of outsourcing and provide an important
variations in capacity utilization and measurement indication of the productivity improvement in an
error, as well as disembodied technological change industry for the economy as a whole. They indicate
(Schreyer, 2001). how much an industry generates extra delivery to final
Increasing or decreasing labour productivity esti- demand per unit of primary inputs. When it comes to
mates based on gross output may not reflect a change labour productivity, value-added-based measures are
in technology or efficiency, but rather reflect substitu- less sensitive to change in the degree of vertical inte-
tion between labour and intermediate inputs. The gration than gross output-based measures (Schreyer,
gross output-based productivity measures are more 2001).
sensitive to substitution between factor inputs and While productivity refers to the physical relation-
intermediate inputs, particularly through outsourcing. ship between inputs and outputs generally, this is not
Outsourcing leaves gross output little affected, but the way it is measured, especially over longer periods
reduces labour input (Cobbold, 2003). Furthermore, of time. Output and the composition of input mix
outsourcing activities previously conducted in-house change over time. It is difficult to establish a rate of
will cause gross output per unit of labour input to conversion between labour and capital in order to
increase even though the amount of labour used to compare them on equal terms. The solution is to use
produce the output may not have changed (Organisa- the prices of outputs and inputs. The level of prices is
tion for Economic Co-operation and Development, influenced by a nation’s economy, the industry’s effi-
2001). ciency and the difficulties in its operating environ-
In addition, the inclusion of intra-industry flows of ment as perceived by the entrepreneurs involved.
intermediate products would involve double counting These change over time. A high output may simply
on both the input and output side of an industry pro- be a measure of the level of inefficiency or an indica-
duction function. Double counting as output and tion of high prices in general (Ofori, 1990).
intermediate inputs tends to obscure the extent of This method works well where the value of outputs
technological change or changes in efficiency taking can be measured independently from the value of dif-
place in the industry as a whole (Schreyer, 2001). ferent inputs. However, in the building industry, there
The measurement of output poses problems in is no obvious way of measuring output independently
relation to changes of quality, particularly in the from the input. Rather the actual value of output has
Construction productivity 1057

a close relationship with the cost of input. Hence, in years 1999 and 2011. DOSM conducts a biennial
the building industry, productivity increases when Construction Industry Survey and quinquennial Cen-
times are good and profit is up, and decreases when sus of Construction Industry. The surveys/censuses
times are bad and profit is low. In the long run, there cover 25 industries in the construction sector (based
are very small changes (Runeson, 2000). on the Malaysia Standard Industrial Classification,
The construction sector relies on inputs from the 2000). The respondents are the establishments pri-
manufacturing sector, which has adopted many man- marily engaged in construction activities, with a value
agement improvement techniques to reduce error of construction work of RM500 000 and above. The
rates and sub-standard production rejections, such as surveys collect information pertaining to growth, com-
just-in-time production, or computer-aided design position and distribution of output, value added,
and manufacturing. Such improved efficiencies may employment and other variables of the sector. The
be able to increase the quality of output without biennial survey was last carried out in 2010 for refer-
changing the inputs used in the production process. ence year 2009.
Productivity can be measured at the industry, pro- The Construction Industry Survey and Census of
ject and task levels. The usefulness of any productiv- Construction Industry contain data on value of gross
ity measurement framework for policy-makers and output, cost of input, total number of persons
industry practitioners alike depends crucially on the engaged, salaries and wages paid and value of assets
extent to which it enables the identification of the owned. The statistics are grouped by work state, legal
underlying drivers of productivity (Crawford and status, ownership, output size group, employment size
Vogl, 2006). The industry-level productivity measures group, assets size group and type of construction. All
can be used to determine whether the productivity of the values from the surveys/censuses are deflated to
the construction industry as a whole is improving or year 2000 prices using the Implicit Price Deflators for
declining over time. Lagging indicators are needed to construction obtained from the National Accounts
track industry trends for several years to help identify (Department of Statistics, Malaysia, 2008, 2009a).
the root causes of improvement or decline (The The construction sector comprises two categories,
National Academy of Sciences, 2009). This informa- namely general construction and special trade. The
tion is useful in developing industry-wide strategies general construction category comprises the subsec-
for the improvement of policies, procedures, practices tors of residential construction, non-residential con-
and research. For example, it makes it possible to struction and civil engineering construction, while the
track the impact of greater use of prefabricated com- special trade category involves activities such as metal
ponents, interpretable technologies and automated work, electrical, plumbing, sewerage and sanitary,
equipment (The National Academy of Sciences, refrigeration and air-conditioning, painting, carpentry,
2009). The industry-wide information would permit tiling and flooring, and glass (Department of Statis-
comparison of productivity improvements across tics, Malaysia, 2011). The number of organizations
countries, in order to identify the superior methodolo- by construction subsectors and employment size
gies and sharing the knowledge whereby those mea- group included in the survey and census reports are
sures could be important for the international provided in Tables 1 and 2 respectively.
comparison of performance (The National Academy There is a substantial difference in coverage
of Sciences, 2009). The two main reasons for com- between the censuses (approximately 10 000 firms)
paring productivity at the sectoral level across coun- and the surveys (approximately 5000). The major dif-
tries are: there is a need to understand the ference is at the level of smaller firms. Post hoc tests
determinants of long-term trends in international consisting of pair-wise comparisons will be used to
competitiveness and standards of living, and as a compare all different combinations of the different
response to the resurgence of growth theory and the size groups in order to validate the significance of the
need to verify the speed of international convergence results (Morgan et al., 2004).
in per capita income (Malley et al., 2003). The definitions of productivity indicators computed
for this study follow those adopted by the Malaysia
Productivity Corporation (National Productivity
Research method Corporation, 2005) which include:

The productivity indicators were computed from the (1) Labour productivity. This comprises two indica-
data obtained from two industry censuses (i.e. years tors:
1996 and 2005) and six industry surveys (i.e. years
1998, 2000, 2002, 2004, 2007 and 2009) published (a) Added value per employee (added value/
by the Department of Statistics, Malaysia (DOSM) in number of employees), reflecting the
1058 Chia et al.

Table 1 Number of organizations by construction subsectors (Department of Statistics, Malaysia, 1999, 2000, 2002, 2004,
2006, 2007, 2009b, 2011)

Establishment 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2005 2007 2009


Civil engineering 3538 1511 1487 1238 1374 3613 1738 1474
Non-residential 1897 972 1073 978 814 1624 874 1218
Residential 2246 1024 975 853 904 1725 1091 1088
Special trade 3074 1661 1533 1259 1358 3385 1840 1984
Total 10755 5168 5068 4328 4450 10347 5543 5764

Table 2 Number of organizations by employment size group (Department of Statistics, Malaysia, 1999, 2000, 2002, 2004,
2006, 2007, 2009b, 2011)

Establishment 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2005 2007 2009


Fewer than 5 2084 100 73 42 102 1559 154 158
5–9 2222 417 426 256 343 2395 598 535
10–19 1952 977 1023 704 778 2238 1138 1150
20–29 950 669 647 577 566 965 719 1708
30–49 1038 830 867 749 715 1047 869
50–99 1138 886 928 865 853 968 877 1581
100–149 704 655 422 392 392 388 359
150–199 204 214 195 233 203
200–499 473 448 361 399 371 392 414 410
500–999 126 121 81 89 102 116 140 222
More than 1000 68 65 36 41 33 46 72
Total 10755 5168 5068 4328 4450 10347 5543 5764

amount of wealth created by the organiza- indicates high returns to individual work-
tion relative to its number of employees. A ers and vice versa.
high ratio indicates the favourable effects (c) Unit labour cost (labour cost/total output),
of the labour factor in the wealth creation measuring the relationship between labour
process. cost and total output. A high ratio indi-
(b) Total output per employee (total output/ cates high labour cost.
number of employees), measuring the size
of output generated by the organization. (3) Capital productivity (added value/fixed assets).
This indicates the degree of utilization of tangi-
(2) Labour cost competitiveness. This measures com- ble fixed assets. A high ratio indicates an
petitiveness in terms of labour cost and indi- efficient utilization of assets.
cates the comparability of the industry in (4) Capital intensity (fixed assets/number of
producing products or services at the lowest employees). This is the ratio measuring the
possible labour cost. This comprises three com- amount of fixed assets allocated to each
petitiveness ratios: employee and is used to determine whether an
industry is relatively capital intensive or labour
(a) Added value per labour cost (added value/ intensive. A high ratio indicates high capital
labour cost), indicating how competitive intensity while a low ratio means dependence
the activity is in terms of labour cost. A on labour-intensive methods.
low ratio indicates high labour cost which (5) Added value content (added value/total output
does not match with the creation of added 100). This ratio is used to gauge the degree of
value. utilization of bought-in materials and services
(b) Labour cost per employee (labour cost/num- and changes in the price differentials between
ber of employees), measuring the average products and purchases. A high ratio indicates
remuneration per employee. A high ratio the efficient usage of purchases or favourable
Construction productivity 1059

price differentials. A low ratio means high cost investment had resulted in a reduction of the unit
of bought-in materials and services, poor prod- labour cost by 14%. On the other hand, annual
uct quality and low price competition. labour cost had increased from RM15 642 per
employee in 1996 to RM29 895 per employee in
This study looks at the industry-level productivity, 2009. Nevertheless, the added value per labour cost
therefore only the average productivity is considered. was reduced by 10% (from 1.70 in 1996 to 1.52 in
Average productivity can be used to gain a perspective 2009). The overall effect is added value content con-
on the issue of the industry. Other productivity such tracted from 38.48% in 1996 to 30.08% in 2009.
as marginal productivity which measures how much ANOVA was used to compare the productivity
output the company gains with one extra unit of input indicators across the different construction subsectors
will not be discussed here. and organizational size groups. The results indicate
significant differences in the productivity indicators of
the construction subsectors except the added value
Results content (Table 5). It means the null hypothesis of no
difference in all the productivity indicators (other than
The labour productivity measure by total output added value content) between the different construc-
recorded RM151 111 per employee in 2009, which is tion subsectors can be rejected.
2.2 times the RM69 013 in 1996 (Table 3). Follow-up tests were conducted to evaluate pair-
However, the labour productivity measure by value wise differences among the means. As the Levene’s
added is RM45 452 in 2009 which is only 1.7 times tests for most of the productivity indicators (except
the RM26 555 in 1996. Although the capital intensity the unit labour cost) are not significant, the popula-
in 2009 (RM20 033) is almost twice the size of the tion variances of all the productivity indicators (other
value in 1996 (RM10 049), capital productivity only than the unit labour cost), for each group of the sub-
increased by 14% for the period (from 2.56 in 1996 sectors are approximately equal. Tukey’s test, a com-
to 2.93 in 2009). However, the deepening of capital mon post hoc test to use when variances are equal,

Table 3 Productivity indicators of the Malaysian construction sector 1996–2009 at constant 2000 prices

Productivity indicators 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2005 2007 2009
Total output per employee (RM) 69013 73338 86947 90764 105805 104643 117322 151111
Added value per employee (RM) 26555 28318 31820 32089 36372 36840 34972 45452
Added value per labour cost (Pure Number) 1.70 1.61 1.67 1.62 1.69 1.75 1.40 1.52
Labour cost per employee (RM) 15642 17642 19020 19789 21461 21075 25037 29895
Unit labour cost (Pure Number) 0.227 0.241 0.219 0.218 0.203 0.201 0.213 0.198
Capital productivity (Pure Number) 2.56 2.19 2.18 2.38 2.47 2.72 2.48 2.93
Capital intensity (RM/employee) 10049 12982 14585 13367 15310 14518 16222 20033
Added value content (%) 38.48 38.61 36.60 35.35 34.38 35.21 29.81 30.08

Source: Computed from various issues of Census/Survey of Construction Industry (DOS 1999, 2000, 2002, 2004, 2006, 2007, 2009b,
2011).

Table 4 Indices of productivity indicators of the Malaysian construction sector 1996–2009 at constant 2000 prices
(1996 = 100)

Productivity indicators 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2005 2007 2009
Total output per employee 100.0 106.3 126.0 131.5 153.3 151.6 170.0 219.0
Added value per employee 100.0 106.6 119.8 120.8 137.0 138.7 131.7 171.2
Added value per labour cost 100.0 94.5 98.5 95.5 99.8 103.0 82.3 89.6
Labour cost per employee 100.0 112.8 121.6 126.5 137.2 134.7 160.1 191.1
Unit labour cost 100.0 106.1 96.5 96.2 89.5 88.9 94.2 87.3
Capital productivity 100.0 85.5 85.1 92.7 96.4 105.9 96.7 114.2
Capital intensity 100.0 129.2 145.1 133.0 152.4 144.5 161.4 199.4
Added value content 100.0 100.3 95.1 91.9 89.3 91.5 77.5 78.2
1060 Chia et al.

Table 5 Mean and one-way ANOVA F-test statistic (F-ratio) of productivity indicators of construction sub-sectors by types
of work, 1996–2009 at 2000 prices (Department of Statistics, Malaysia 1999, 2000, 2002, 2004, 2006, 2007, 2009b, 2011)

Civil engineering Non-residential Residential Special trades


Productivity indicators works works works works F Sig.
Added value per 34073 27268 27582 30946 7.34 0.001
employee
Total output per 97216 78501 79415 91864 6.10 0.003
employee
Added value per labour 1.75 1.55 1.52 1.61 5.23 0.005
cost
Labour cost per 19462 17591 18100 19236 3.12 0.042
employee
Unit labour cost 0.20 0.23 0.23 0.21 4.85 0.008
Capital productivity 2.04 2.84 2.94 2.06 22.35 0.000
Capital intensity 16913 9721 9409 15277 29.51 0.000
Added value content 35.09 35.00 35.23 33.78 0.29 0.830

was selected for the follow-up comparisons on all the subsector (RM79 415) and non-residential subsector
productivity indicators other than the unit labour (RM78 501) as shown Table 5. Similarly, the aver-
cost. The Games-Howell test, which is used for post age labour productivity measured in the value added
hoc comparisons when the Levene test indicates that of the civil engineering subsector (RM34 073) is
the variances are unequal, was selected for the follow- higher than the residential subsector (RM27 582)
up comparison on the unit labour cost (Table 6). and non-residential subsector (RM27 268) (Table 5).
Pair-wise comparisons of significantly different However, the capital productivity of both residential
items are presented in Table 7. With respect to the (2.94) and non-residential (2.84) subsectors is
labour productivity measured both in total output and greater than the civil engineering subsector (2.04),
added value, capital productivity, capital intensity and despite a much higher level of capital investment
added value per labour cost, significant differences (RM16 913) in the civil engineering subsector than
were found between the civil engineering and residen- in the residential (RM9409) and non-residential
tial subsectors as well as between the civil engineering (RM9721) subsectors. Nevertheless, the civil engi-
and non-residential subsectors. In addition, significant neering subsector still achieved a higher added value
differences in capital productivity and capital intensity per labour cost (1.75) than the residential (1.52)
exist between the special trades and residential sub- and non-residential (1.55) subsectors.
sectors and also special trades and non-residential The capital productivity of both residential (2.94)
subsectors. The significant difference in unit labour and non-residential (2.84) subsectors is higher than in
cost occurs between the civil engineering and non-res- the special trades subsector (2.06) despite a much
idential subsectors only (Table 7). greater level of capital investment (RM15 277) in the
The average labour productivity measured in special trades subsector than the residential
terms of gross output of the civil engineering subsec- (RM9409) and non-residential (RM9721) subsectors
tor (RM97 216) is higher than the residential (Table 5).

Table 6 Tests of homogeneity of variance of the productivity indicators of construction subsectors by types of work, 1996–
2009 in 2000 prices

Productivity indicators Levene statistic df1 df2 Sig.


Added value per employee 2.621 3 28 0.070
Total output per employee 0.953 3 28 0.429
Capital productivity 0.595 3 28 0.623
Capital intensity 2.064 3 28 0.128
Added value per labour cost 0.133 3 28 0.940
Wages per employee 1.453 3 28 0.249
Unit labour cost 4.589 3 28 0.010
Added value content 0.567 3 28 0.641
Construction productivity 1061

Table 7 Selected results of multiple comparisons of productivity indicators of construction subsectors by types of work,
1996–2009 at 2000 prices

Dependent variable (I) Types of works (J) Types of works Mean difference (I – J) Std. error Sig.
Added value per employee Civil engineering works Non-residential works 6805⁄ 1672 0.002
Added value per employee Civil engineering works Residential works 6491⁄ 1672 0.003
Total output per employee Civil engineering works Non-residential works 18715⁄ 5307 0.008
Total output per employee Civil engineering works Residential works 17801⁄ 5307 0.012
Capital productivity Non-residential works Civil engineering works 0.81⁄ 0.15 0.000
Capital productivity Residential works Civil engineering works 0.91⁄ 0.15 0.000
Capital productivity Non-residential works Special trades works 0.79⁄ 0.15 0.000
Capital productivity Residential works Special trades works 0.88⁄ 0.15 0.000
Capital intensity Civil engineering works Non-residential works 7193⁄ 997 0.000
Capital intensity Civil engineering works Residential works 7505⁄ 997 0.000
Capital intensity Special trades works Non-residential works 5556⁄ 997 0.000
Capital intensity Special trades works Residential works 5868⁄ 997 0.000
Added value per labour cost Civil engineering works Non-residential works 0.20⁄ 0.06 0.017
Added value per labour cost Civil engineering works Residential works 0.23⁄ 0.07 0.006
Unit labour cost Civil engineering works Non-residential works –0.02# 0.01 0.012

Notes: ⁄The mean difference is significant at the 0.05 level using Tukey’s HSD test.
#
The mean difference is significant at the 0.05 level using the Games-Howell test.

Finally, the unit labour costs of the civil engineer- tests are significant for all the productivity indicators,
ing (0.20) and non-residential subsectors (0.23) equal variances were not assumed among the four
(Table 5) are significantly different. groupings (Table 9). Hence, Games-Howell tests
All the productivity indicators (except added value were used for post hoc comparisons.
content) are significantly different between organiza- Pair-wise comparisons of significantly different items
tion sizes. Table 8 shows that the labour productivity are presented in Table 10. The labour productivity and
in smaller size organizations is higher than in the larger organization size were not significantly different. How-
organizations. However, larger organizations are more ever, capital productivity, capital intensity, added value
capital productive than smaller ones. The capital per labour cost, labour cost per employee and unit
intensity of smaller organizations is higher. Neverthe- labour cost were significantly different between the
less, employees still earned more in the larger organiza- large and medium, large and small, large and micro,
tions. The unit labour cost is higher in the larger and medium and small organizations. The added value
organizations. As a result, the added value per labour per labour cost and unit labour cost between medium
cost is higher in the smaller size organizations. and micro, as well as small and micro size organizations
Follow-up tests were conducted to evaluate pair- were significantly different. The labour costs per
wise differences among the productivity indicators employee between medium and micro size establish-
according to the organization size. As the Levene’s ments were also significantly different (Table 10).

Table 8 Mean and one-way ANOVA F-test statistic (F-ratio) of productivity indicators of construction subsectors by size
of organization, 1996–2009 at 2000 prices (Department of Statistics, Malaysia 1999, 2000, 2002, 2004, 2006, 2007, 2009b,
2011)

Productivity indicators Micro Small Medium Large F Sig.


Added value per employee 36020 29624 29694 31116 2.828 0.044
Total output per employee 122692 94961 85467 88767 4.472 0.006
Added value per labour cost 2.93 2.01 1.73 1.56 53.046 0.000
Labour cost per employee 12337 14756 17165 19960 30.023 0.000
Unit labour cost 0.12 0.16 0.20 0.23 57.099 0.000
Capital productivity 0.95 1.28 1.83 3.06 33.558 0.000
Capital intensity 54575 23971 16227 10377 31.643 0.000
Added value content 33.04 32.44 35.09 35.22 1.727 0.168
1062 Chia et al.

Table 9 Tests of homogeneity of variance of productivity indicators of construction subsectors by size of organization,
1996–2009 at 2000 prices

Productivity indicators Levene statistic df1 df2 Sig.


Added value per employee 10.854 3 78 0.000
Total output per employee 17.169 3 78 0.000
Capital productivity 5.821 3 78 0.001
Capital intensity 87.221 3 78 0.000
Added value per labour cost 29.385 3 78 0.000
Wages per employee 5.005 3 78 0.003
Unit labour cost 4.893 3 78 0.004
Added value content 8.763 3 78 0.000

Table 10 Selected results of multiple comparisons of productivity indicators of construction subsectors by size of
organization 1996–2009 at 2000 prices

Dependent variable (I) Size of organization (J) Size of organization Mean difference(I – J) Std. error Sig.
#
Capital productivity Medium Small 0.55 0.12 0.000
Capital productivity Large Micro 2.11# 0.35 0.000
Capital productivity Large Small 1.79# 0.23 0.000
Capital productivity Large Medium 1.24# 0.22 0.000
Capital intensity Micro Large 44197.40# 12133.71 0.033
Capital intensity Small Medium 7744.23# 2417.15 0.024
Capital intensity Small Large 13594.03# 2386.16 0.000
Capital intensity Medium Large 5849.80# 877.02 0.000
Added value per labour cost Micro Small 0.92# 0.21 0.012
Added value per labour cost Micro Medium 1.20# 0.21 0.003
Added value per labour cost Micro Large 1.37# 0.21 0.001
Added value per labour cost Small Medium 0.28# 0.04 0.000
Added value per labour cost Small Large 0.45# 0.05 0.000
Added value per labour cost Medium Large 0.17# 0.04 0.000
Labour cost per employee Medium Micro 4828.11# 1216.19 0.018
Labour cost per employee Medium Small 2408.42# 839.61 0.044
Labour cost per employee Large Micro 7623.51# 1228.92 0.001
Labour cost per employee Large Small 5203.82# 857.95 0.000
Labour cost per employee Large Medium 2795.40# 462.58 0.000
Unit labour cost Small Micro 0.05# 0.01 0.025
Unit labour cost Medium Micro 0.09# 0.01 0.000
Unit labour cost Medium Small 0.04# 0.01 0.000
Unit labour cost Large Micro 0.11# 0.01 0.000
Unit labour cost Large Small 0.06# 0.01 0.000
Unit labour cost Large Medium 0.02# 0.01 0.000

Notes: #The mean difference is significant at the 0.05 level using the Games-Howell test.

Discussion kilometres Penang Bridge, the RM20.1 billion, Putra-


jaya administrative capital and the RM6 billion, Pet-
From the end of the 1980s to the end of the 1990s, ronas Twin Towers. Most of the large infrastructure
the Malaysian economy was driven by the implemen- projects were already completed by the turn of the
tation of mega building and infrastructure expansion millennium.
projects, such as the RM3.42 billion, 494 kilometres The Construction Industry Surveys/Census over
North–South Highway, the RM9 billion, Kuala Lum- the period of 1996 to 2009 shows that construction
pur International Airport, the RM740 million, 13.5 labour productivity first peaked in 2004. It subse-
Construction productivity 1063

quently declined in 2005 and 2007 before it showed 0.1% (Tables 3 and 4). Similarly, of the four subsec-
some recovery in 2009. This is partly attributed to tors, the added value content of this subsector
the reduction of construction employment as a result encountered the most severe contraction of 25.8%.
of the measures to control the influx of illegal foreign This is mainly due to the high cost of bought-in off-
workers under the Amnesty Programme in 2004 site manufactured components.
(Bank Negara Malaysia, 2006). By the end of 2009, The special trades subsector is the second most
capital intensity had doubled the 1996 value (Tables capital-intensive subsector after civil engineering. The
3 and 4). However, there is a declining trend of capital intensity of the special trades subsector was
added value content, the added value content in 2009 approximately 1.6 times that of the residential or non-
being only 78% of what had been achieved in 1996, residential subsector, but with capital productivity of
reflecting the high cost of bought-in services or mate- only 0.7 times the two subsectors. The capital inten-
rials. The price of steel bars increased three times in sity has grown by 188.5% from 1996 to 2009, but its
2006 by a total of 45% and the price of cement was capital productivity declined by 13.5%. This subsec-
revised at the end of 2006. tor consists of a large variety of trades ranging from
The civil engineering subsector is more productive labour-intensive activities, such as painting and deco-
in terms of labour productivity and is also more capital rating, to capital-intensive activities such as renting of
intensive than the residential and non-residential sub- construction equipment. In addition, it also includes
sectors. Machine-for-labour substitution has been a such trades as ‘heating, ventilation, air-conditioning
more important process in civil engineering. However, and refrigeration work’, which form the bulk of the
it is less competitive in capital productivity than the contract sum. The more technically sophisticated
residential and non-residential construction subsec- demands of construction products and the construc-
tors. The rise of capital intensity (60.3%) of the civil tion processes will continuously drive the demand for
engineering subsector between the years 1996 and the highly specialized nature of much of the work.
2009 was faster than the growth of capital productivity The sector recorded the second highest output per
(27.2%), which implies that there is room for better employee (RM91 864) among the subsectors and
utilization of capital assets in the civil engineering 123.1% improvement from 1996 to 2009, but the
subsector. In addition, the labour productivity of civil added value content showed a relatively slower
engineering recorded a 91% improvement when mea- growth of 87.77%. With 188.5% and 110.8% respec-
sured as gross output compared with 53% when mea- tively, the capital intensity and labour cost per
sured as value added (Appendix 1). This is a typical employee of the special trades subsector shows the
example explained by Runeson (2000) where ‘most of greatest improvement (Table A1).
process-changes are not considered productivity The results of pair-wise comparisons of labour pro-
improvements in the building industry but are classi- ductivity according to the organization sizes are not
fied as part of the manufacturing industries’ (p. 84). It statistically significant. The capital productivity of the
is due to the peculiarities of the standard industrial larger size organizations, however, was higher than
classification (SIC), as the substitution of labour with that of smaller size organizations. This reflects a more
capital causes a substantial increase in unaccounted efficient utilization of capital by the larger organiza-
labour requirements on site. tions. Larger firms are likely to be more technologi-
The residential subsector had the greatest improve- cally advanced and systematically managed, and to
ment in labour productivity (Tables 3 and 4). The gain the advantages of specialization and of risk-
labour saving Industrialized Building System (IBS), spreading by diversification to obtain technical and
which encourages greater automation and mechaniza- managerial economies of scale in a number of markets
tion, was introduced into the residential subsector, (such as residential and civil engineering) at the same
with the government pledging to use it to construct time (Hillebrandt, 2000). The labour cost per
100 000 units of affordable houses in its 2005 Budget employee of the larger size organizations was higher
and all new government building projects were than that of the smaller size organizations. This is
required to have at least 50% of IBS content (Con- consistent with Gruneberg and Ive’s (2000) notion of
struction Industry Development Board, 2007). The an implied bargain that workers in larger firms will
exemption of construction levy on contractors using work with above average intensity in return for above
IBS in 50% of the building components was average wages. The larger firms are able to achieve
announced in 2007. Consequently, capital investment higher work intensity, or greater non-capital-embod-
intensified by 143.5% from 1996 to 2009, unit labour ied efficiency and appear to enjoy much higher levels
cost substantially reduced by 23.9% and capital pro- of productivity (Gruneberg and Ive, 2000).
ductivity increased by 10.5%. However, the added The argument of Gruneberg and Ive implies that
value per labour cost only improved marginally by higher productivity is expected in the larger organiza-
1064 Chia et al.

tions. In addition, the finding that unit labour cost of IBS encourages greater automation and mechaniza-
in the larger size organizations did not decrease, con- tion, and a significant reduction in the unit labour
tradicts the common belief that large companies cost. There is an increase in the earnings of construc-
move on a decreasing cost curve over time and tion workers. The increasing utilization of intermedi-
through different technologies. It is because the firm ate inputs prefabricated off site is evidenced with
may face a rising long-run average cost curve in that lower labour productivity measured in added value
some inputs cannot be increased except at a higher compared with that measured in gross output. The
price. If the firm has a large share of the market, the situation of decline in added value per labour cost
ability to purchase supplies of materials in bulk could be reversed if there is an improvement of capital
might offset any increases due to other factors such productivity, which requires further enhancement of
as purchases from the sources further afield or from capital utilization and management of capital assets.
more expensive operations when demand is large. The special trades subsector and smaller size orga-
When a firm becomes big, it tends to be less flexible nizations that operate as subcontractors most of the
due to its increased bureaucracy, encouraging inertia time have significantly higher capital intensity in com-
and resistance to change (Chau et al., 2005). A firm parison with other subsectors. Large organizations
operating in a limited geographical area may well generally resort to a greater use of subcontractors to
find that to substantially increase its turnover reduce the overhead burden. The need for firms to be
involves extending its catchment area, and hence its flexible in terms of volume of trade has also resulted
costs of transport and supervision as travelling time in work practices that rely on a major part of their
increases. Similarly, the geographical spread of work being done through subcontracting. The
demand for projects may not coincide with the avail- increased technical sophistication of the demands of
ability of manpower, either because of increased the construction industry will continuously drive the
transport costs or because of the bargaining power demand for the highly specialized works. The special
of the operatives (Hillebrandt, 2000). Company poli- trades subsector is expected to expand; however,
tics and the indivisible nature of ‘entrepreneurial there is a need to enhance the capital productivity.
ability’ in the decision-making process are often The very nature of small firms and the employment
counterproductive (Hillebrandt, 2000), which is of a flexible workforce enable them to achieve higher
likely to be proportionate to the size of the firm added value per labour cost.
(Chau et al., 2005). In addition, the construction Malaysia launched its Economic Transformation
industry is very management intensive compared to Programme (ETP) in 2010 which is expected to pro-
the manufacturing industry. There are many layers vide a boost of 30% to 50% towards the volume of
of management involved even on a fairly small resi- construction work over the next decade. This will
dential project which may only be noticed in large provide an opportunity for the construction sector to
factories where there are routines for most of the adopt productivity enhancing technologies and meth-
processes. As a result, diseconomies of scale are ods of construction to improve its competitiveness in
more likely to happen in the construction industry. the future by optimizing resource utilization, adopting
Additionally, the free-enterprise spirit and no-non- good practices along with advanced construction
sense approach to doing business is inherent in small techniques.
firms. Small businesses have a natural tendency The industry-level statistics and measures are
towards diversity and flexibility (Beck and Demirguc- lagging indicators that are not very time sensitive,
Kunt, 2004). Consequently, smaller size organizations therefore the value of this study to individual project
are able to achieve higher added value with the same owners and contractors is limited. However, the
unit of labour cost. findings would serve as a good reference for policy-
makers, government agencies and researchers in
understanding the success or failure of the industries,
Conclusion improvements and inefficiencies of the past policies.

The survey/census data between 1996 and 2009 point


to a trend of continuous decline in the value-added
References
content of the Malaysian construction sector, although
there was an improvement in capital invest-
Bank Negara Malaysia (2006) Annual Report 2005, Central
ment——mainly from the civil engineering and special Bank of Malaysia, Kuala Lumpur.
trade subsectors, and smaller size organizations. Beck, T. and Demirguc-Kunt, A. (2004) SMEs, Growth,
Machine-for-labour substitution has been a more and Poverty, National Bureau of Economic Research,
important process in civil engineering. The adoption Cambridge.
Construction productivity 1065

Chau, K.W., Poon, S.W., Wang, Y.S. and Lu, L.L. (2005) Grimes, C.F. (2007) Employee Motivation, the Organisational
Technological progress and the productive efficiency of Environment and Productivity, Accel-Team.Com, Accel-
construction firms in Hong Kong, 1981–2001. Journal of Team, Cumbria.
Construction Research, 6(2), 195–207. Gruneberg, S.L. and Ive, G.J. (2000) The Economics of the
Chia, F.C. (2012) Construction and economic develop- Modern Construction Firm, Macmillan, London.
ment: the case of Malaysia. International Journal of Con- Hillebrandt, P.M. (2000) Economic Theory and the Construc-
struction Management, 12(1), 23–35. tion Industry, Palgrave Macmillan, Basingstoke.
Cobbold, T. (2003) A Comparison of Gross Output and Malley, J., Muscatella, A. and Woitek, U. (2003) New
Value-added Methods of Productivity Estimation, Productiv- international comparisons of productivity performance at
ity Commission, Canberra. the sectoral level. Journal of the Royal Statistical Society:
Construction Industry Development Board (2007) Construc- Series A (Statistics in Society), 166(1), 85–204.
tion Industry Master Plan Malaysia 2006–2015, Construc- Morgan, G.A., Leech, N.L., Gloeckner, G.W. and Barrett,
tion Industry Development Board, Kuala Lumpur. K.C. (2004) SPSS for Introductory Statistics: Use and Inter-
Crawford, P. and Vogl, B. (2006) Measuring productivity pretation, 2nd edn, Lawrence Erlbaum Associates, Mah-
in the construction industry. Building Research & Informa- wah, NJ.
tion, 34(3), 208–19. National Productivity Corporation (2005) Productivity Report
Department of Statistics, Malaysia (1999) Census of 2004, National Productivity Corporation, Petaling Jaya,
Construction Industries, 1997, DOSM, Kuala Lumpur. Malaysia.
Department of Statistics, Malaysia (2000) Survey of Ofori, G. (1990) The Construction Industry: Aspect of its
Construction Industries 1999, DOSM, Kuala Lumpur. Economics and Management, Singapore University Press,
Department of Statistics, Malaysia (2002) Survey of Singapore.
Construction Industries 2001, DOSM, Kuala Lumpur. Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development
Department of Statistics, Malaysia (2004) Survey of (2001) Measuring Productivity: Measurement of Aggregate
Construction Industries 2003, DOSM, Kuala Lumpur. and Industry-level Productivity Growth, Organisation for
Department of Statistics, Malaysia (2006) Survey of Economic Co-operation and Development, Paris.
Construction Industries 2005, DOSM, Putrajaya. Pink, B. (2007) Experimental Estimates of Industry Multifactor
Department of Statistics, Malaysia (2007) Economic Census Productivity, Australian Bureau of Statistics, Canberra,
2006 Construction, DOSM, Kuala Lumpur. Australia.
Department of Statistics, Malaysia (2008) Annual National Runeson, G. (2000) Building Economics, Deakin University
Accounts——Gross Domestic Product (GDP) 2000–2007, Press, Victoria.
DOSM, Putrajaya. Schreyer, P. (2001) The OECD productivity manual: a
Department of Statistics, Malaysia (2009a) Annual National guide to the measurement of industry-level and aggregate
Accounts——Gross Domestic Product (GDP) 2000–2008, productivity. International Productivity Monitor, 2(Spring),
DOSM, Putrajaya. 37–51.
Department of Statistics, Malaysia (2009b) Survey of The National Academy of Sciences (2009) Advancing the
Construction Industries 2008, DOSM, Putrajaya. Competitiveness and Efficiency of the US Construction
Department of Statistics, Malaysia (2011) Survey of Industry, The National Academies Press, Washington,
Construction Industries 2010, DOSM, Putrajaya. DC.
1066 Chia et al.

Appendix

Table A1 Productivity indicators and productivity index (1996 = 100) according to construction subsectors of
1996–2009 at constant 2000 prices

1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2005 2007 2009


Civil engineering
Total output per employee (RM) 82054 86199 103409 107529 118013 106957 122171 156924
Added value per employee (RM) 31873 33129 38944 37512 40166 37817 37105 48849
Added value per labour cost (Pure Number) 1.86 1.75 1.90 1.74 1.81 1.81 1.45 1.65
Labour cost per employee (RM) 17138 18968 20478 21527 22158 20931 25507 29609
Unit labour cost (Pure Number) 0.2089 0.2200 0.1980 0.2002 0.1878 0.1957 0.2088 0.1887
Capital productivity (Pure Number) 2.23 1.80 1.78 2.27 2.12 2.29 1.99 2.84
Capital intensity (RM/employee) 13852 18447 21940 16335 19667 17704 21494 22206
Added value content (%) 38.84 38.43 37.66 34.89 34.04 35.36 30.37 31.13
Non-residential
Total output per employee (RM) 64059 67119 76613 73466 93689 95462 108232 147637
Added value per employee (RM) 24612 26214 28034 26982 31928 34938 32113 42662
Added value per labour cost (Pure Number) 1.62 1.56 1.63 1.55 1.59 1.66 1.35 1.43
Labour cost per employee (RM) 15158 16795 17217 17402 20137 21051 23718 29735
Unit labour cost (Pure Number) 0.2366 0.2502 0.2247 0.2369 0.2149 0.2205 0.2191 0.2014
Capital productivity (Pure Number) 2.87 2.81 2.96 2.37 2.61 3.43 3.87 3.30
Capital intensity (RM/employee) 8329 9373 9480 11250 12720 10901 9539 16658
Added value content (%) 38.42 39.06 36.59 36.73 34.08 36.60 29.67 28.90
Residential
Total output per employee (RM) 54060 60263 75397 81715 98420 104258 115243 147424
Added value per employee (RM) 21943 24394 27019 29132 35042 35572 33739 44396
Added value per labour cost (Pure Number) 1.51 1.46 1.46 1.52 1.66 1.69 1.34 1.52
Labour cost per employee (RM) 14488 16745 18547 19140 21131 21030 25098 29293
Unit labour cost (Pure Number) 0.2680 0.2779 0.2460 0.2342 0.2147 0.2017 0.2178 0.1987
Capital productivity (Pure Number) 3.19 2.62 2.71 3.00 3.36 3.45 3.08 3.52
Capital intensity (RM/employee) 6676 9364 9979 9608 10832 11040 12591 16260
Added value content (%) 40.59 40.48 35.84 35.65 35.60 34.12 29.28 30.11
Special trade
Total output per employee (RM) 68485 76689 91949 102975 112025 112350 123287 152774
Added value per employee (RM) 24562 27992 32471 35133 37727 39337 36515 46091
Added value per labour cost (Pure Number) 1.66 1.58 1.61 1.62 1.66 1.83 1.41 1.47
Labour cost per employee (RM) 14826 17718 20165 21677 22677 21451 25835 31254
Unit labour cost (Pure Number) 0.2165 0.2310 0.2193 0.2105 0.2024 0.1909 0.2095 0.2046
Capital productivity (Pure Number) 2.59 2.11 1.93 1.96 2.19 2.29 2.06 2.24
Capital intensity (RM/employee) 9196 13357 16809 17777 17918 18395 20343 26535
Added value content (%) 35.86 36.50 35.31 34.12 33.68 35.01 29.62 30.17
Indices of productivity indicators (1996 = 100)
Civil engineering
Total output per employee 100.0 105.1 126.0 131.0 143.8 130.3 148.9 191.2
Added value per employee 100.0 103.9 122.2 117.7 126.0 118.6 116.4 153.3
Added value per labour cost 100.0 93.9 102.3 93.7 97.5 97.1 78.2 88.7
Labour cost per employee 100.0 110.7 119.5 125.6 129.3 122.1 148.8 172.8
Unit labour cost 100.0 105.4 94.8 95.8 89.9 93.7 100.0 90.3
Capital productivity 100.0 80.9 79.5 101.9 95.2 102.4 89.0 127.2
Capital intensity 100.0 133.2 158.4 117.9 142.0 127.8 155.2 160.3
Added value content 100.0 98.9 97.0 89.8 87.6 91.0 78.2 80.1
(Continued)
Construction productivity 1067

Table A1 (Continued)
1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2005 2007 2009
Non-residential
Total output per employee 100.0 104.8 119.6 114.7 146.3 149.0 169.0 230.5
Added value per employee 100.0 106.5 113.9 109.6 129.7 142.0 130.5 173.3
Added value per labour cost 100.0 96.1 100.3 95.5 97.7 102.2 83.4 88.4
Labour cost per employee 100.0 110.8 113.6 114.8 132.8 138.9 156.5 196.2
Unit labour cost 100.0 105.7 95.0 100.1 90.8 93.2 92.6 85.1
Capital productivity 100.0 98.1 103.2 82.9 91.1 119.7 135.1 115.3
Capital intensity 100.0 112.5 113.8 135.1 152.7 130.9 114.5 200.0
Added value content 100.0 101.7 95.2 95.6 88.7 95.3 77.2 75.2
Residential
Total output per employee 100.0 111.5 139.5 151.2 182.1 192.9 213.2 272.7
Added value per employee 100.0 111.2 123.1 132.8 159.7 162.1 153.8 202.3
Added value per labour cost 100.0 96.2 96.2 100.5 109.5 111.7 88.8 100.1
Labour cost per employee 100.0 115.6 128.0 132.1 145.8 145.2 173.2 202.2
Unit labour cost 100.0 103.7 91.8 87.4 80.1 75.3 81.3 74.1
Capital productivity 100.0 82.1 84.9 94.2 105.5 108.2 96.7 110.5
Capital intensity 100.0 140.3 149.5 143.9 162.2 165.4 188.6 243.5
Added value content 100.0 99.7 88.3 87.8 87.7 84.1 72.1 74.2
Special trade
Total output per employee 100.0 112.0 134.3 150.4 163.6 164.1 180.0 223.1
Added value per employee 100.0 114.0 132.2 143.0 153.6 160.2 148.7 187.7
Added value per labour cost 100.0 95.4 97.2 97.8 100.4 110.7 85.3 89.0
Labour cost per employee 100.0 119.5 136.0 146.2 152.9 144.7 174.2 210.8
Unit labour cost 100.0 106.7 101.3 97.2 93.5 88.2 96.8 94.5
Capital productivity 100.0 81.3 74.6 75.5 84.5 88.3 79.7 86.5
Capital intensity 100.0 145.2 182.8 193.3 194.8 200.0 221.2 288.5
Added value content 100.0 101.8 98.5 95.1 93.9 97.6 82.6 84.1

Source: Computed from Malaysia Construction Industry Census 1996 and 2005 and Malaysia Construction Industry Survey 1998, 2000, 2002,
2007 and 2009.
1068 Chia et al.

Table A2 Productivity indicators and productivity index (1996 = 100) according to establishment sizes of
1996–2009 at constant 2000 prices
1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2005 2007 2009

Micro
Total output per employee (RM) 49048 78454 137394 152411 249632 50227 112890 151482
Added value per employee (RM) 26680 28480 38749 41622 59146 19539 29784 44160
Added value per labour cost (Pure Number) 3.65 2.65 2.68 3.20 3.55 2.41 1.98 3.30
Labour cost per employee (RM) 7305 10749 14470 13010 16642 8100 15037 13381
Unit labour cost (Pure Number) 0.15 0.14 0.11 0.09 0.07 0.16 0.13 0.09
Capital productivity (Pure Number) 2.86 0.64 0.48 0.52 0.60 1.17 0.96 0.41
Capital intensity (RM/employee) 9631 44373 81542 80278 94984 15669 27057 83064
Added value content (%) 54.40 36.30 28.20 27.31 23.69 38.90 26.38 29.15
Small
Total output per employee (RM) 94264 134517 192910 226118 285147 145242 221901 219998
Added value per employee (RM) 37260 49209 64324 72338 79135 50784 61730 59202
Added value per labour cost (Pure Number) 4.05 3.92 4.10 3.98 4.46 4.11 3.70 3.83
Labour cost per employee (RM) 18505 25202 31530 36366 35464 24834 33315 30886
Unit labour cost (Pure Number) 0.39 0.37 0.33 0.32 0.25 0.34 0.31 0.28
Capital productivity (Pure Number) 4.28 2.28 2.38 2.27 2.25 2.66 2.17 2.11
Capital intensity (RM/employee) 17968 44680 54280 65529 71159 35666 50130 44131
Added value content (%) 79.26 83.18 66.96 64.01 55.72 70.00 56.07 53.84
Medium
Total output per employee (RM) 245143 266579 407753 451149 518879 460068 435032 206738
Added value per employee (RM) 94312 102857 150991 161177 174280 160035 135322 60318
Added value per labour cost (Pure Number) 6.73 6.69 8.70 8.62 9.27 9.14 7.78 3.58
Labour cost per employee (RM) 56101 61434 86826 93703 93990 87731 87208 33776
Unit labour cost (Pure Number) 0.91 0.92 1.07 1.05 0.91 0.96 1.01 0.33
Capital productivity (Pure Number) 9.11 6.61 8.72 8.94 9.65 9.93 8.14 2.78
Capital intensity (RM/employee) 42664 61941 88118 96313 91181 78783 74806 34142
Added value content (%) 153.71 154.15 185.27 178.71 168.22 174.05 155.70 58.42
Large
Total output per employee (RM) 254129 228645 277203 286721 271749 279721 269911 173562
Added value per employee (RM) 96064 86971 101041 101581 97540 99876 79610 52984
Added value per labour cost (Pure Number) 5.05 4.68 4.86 4.69 4.69 5.01 4.03 2.87
Labour cost per employee (RM) 57252 56107 62328 65000 62338 59891 59230 36941
Unit labour cost (Pure Number) 0.68 0.74 0.67 0.68 0.70 0.64 0.66 0.43
Capital productivity (Pure Number) 9.44 8.25 9.60 11.57 10.14 10.71 6.56 4.22
Capital intensity (RM/employee) 31827 31714 32993 29741 33541 26530 32625 19708
Added value content (%) 114.88 114.81 109.26 106.16 108.28 107.12 88.53 61.12
Indices of productivity indicators (1996 = 100)
Micro
Total output per employee 100.0 160.0 280.1 310.7 509.0 102.4 230.2 308.8
Added value per employee 100.0 106.7 145.2 156.0 221.7 73.2 111.5 165.5
Added value per labour cost 100.0 72.5 73.3 87.6 97.3 66.0 54.2 90.4
Labour cost per employee 100.0 147.2 198.1 178.1 227.8 110.9 205.8 183.2
Unit labour cost 100.0 92.0 70.7 57.3 44.8 108.3 89.4 59.3
Capital productivity 100.0 22.4 16.6 18.3 21.0 40.8 33.5 14.4
Capital intensity 100.0 460.7 846.7 833.5 986.2 162.7 280.9 862.5
Added value content 100.0 66.7 51.8 50.2 43.6 71.5 48.5 53.6
Small
Total output per employee 100.0 142.7 203.9 239.9 302.5 154.1 235.4 233.4
Added value per employee 100.0 132.1 172.6 194.1 212.4 136.3 165.7 158.9
(Continued)
Construction productivity 1069

Table A2 (Continued)
1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2005 2007 2009

Added value per labour cost 100.0 96.8 101.1 98.4 110.4 101.6 91.5 94.8
Labour cost per employee 100.0 136.2 170.4 196.5 191.6 134.2 180.0 166.9
Unit labour cost 100.0 95.6 83.8 82.0 64.0 86.9 78.0 71.7
Capital productivity 100.0 53.2 55.5 53.0 52.6 62.0 50.7 49.2
Capital intensity 100.0 248.7 302.1 364.7 396.0 198.5 279.0 245.6
Added value content 100.0 92.3 84.5 80.8 70.3 88.3 70.7 67.9
Medium
Total output per employee 100.0 108.7 166.3 184.0 211.7 187.7 177.5 84.3
Added value per employee 100.0 109.1 160.1 170.9 184.8 169.7 143.5 64.0
Added value per labour cost 100.0 99.4 129.4 128.1 137.8 135.8 115.6 53.2
Labour cost per employee 100.0 109.5 154.8 167.0 167.5 156.4 155.4 60.2
Unit labour cost 100.0 100.8 116.6 114.4 99.2 104.6 110.0 35.9
Capital productivity 100.0 72.6 95.8 98.2 106.0 109.1 89.4 30.6
Capital intensity 100.0 145.2 206.5 225.7 213.7 184.7 175.3 80.0
Added value content 100.0 100.3 120.5 116.3 109.4 113.2 101.3 38.0
Large
Total output per employee 100.0 90.0 109.1 112.8 106.9 110.1 106.2 68.3
Added value per employee 100.0 90.5 105.2 105.7 101.5 104.0 82.9 55.2
Added value per labour cost 100.0 92.6 96.2 92.8 92.9 99.2 79.8 56.9
Labour cost per employee 100.0 98.0 108.9 113.5 108.9 104.6 103.5 64.5
Unit labour cost 100.0 108.1 99.0 99.7 102.1 94.4 97.0 77.1
Capital productivity 100.0 87.4 101.7 122.6 107.5 113.4 69.4 44.7
Capital intensity 100.0 99.6 103.7 93.4 105.4 83.4 102.5 61.9
Added value content 100.0 99.9 95.1 92.4 94.3 93.2 77.1 53.2

Source: Computed from Malaysia Construction Industry Census 1996 and 2005 and Malaysia Construction Industry Survey 1998, 2000, 2002,
2007 and 2009.

Das könnte Ihnen auch gefallen