Date: 8/13/18
MLA Citation: Focus, Aug 29 2018 Podcasts Research Global. “In a Globalized
World, Strong Intellectual Property Laws Matter.” Knowledge@Wharton,
knowledge.wharton.upenn.edu/article/globalization-and-its-impact-on-inequality-for-companies/.
Assessment:
Last year as an ISM I student, I focused on the future impacts of technology and
innovation on trademark law. This year as an ISM II student, even though I am continuing the
topic of trademark law, I am planning to explore the future economic growth of trademark law
and trademark law firms themselves. Keeping this in mind, I searched for material online that
would serve as good initial research of my focus area for this year. The aforementioned article I
came across provided thorough explanation of how firms across the world will have to
strengthen their intellectual property rights (such as trademark laws) to prosper in increasingly
globalized markets. While this notion may seem obvious, there is actually a lot of debate among
emerging world economies on whether to strengthen their IP rights, and this article strongly
The biggest takeaway from this article was that a lot of world nations are currently
discussing whether to strengthen their intellectual property rights. This came off as a surprise to
me, because it seems obvious to improve IP rights if one wants to ally and trade efficiently with
a domestic or even foreign entity. However, the more I progressed throughout the article, I came
to a realization that improving such rights actually involves a lot of development and
implementation on part of a nation’s legal institutions, as well as cooperation with said nation’s
bureaucracy. All such efforts will ultimately add up in time and more importantly, money. Thus
it makes sense why an emerging economy would be hesitant to contribute expenditures to such a
task.
I found the content within the article quite relevant to what I plan to focus on this year.
Along with studying the future economic growth of trademark law, I am planning to look into
the growth of trademark law firms. The article was especially relevant in this context, because it
spent a good amount of time discussing the potential growth of firms within nations. I realized
that in consideration of American firms, improving intellectual property rights is already a given.
The question for American firms, however, is how exactly can they improve their IP rights and
I plan to utilize the content of this article as foundational material for the rest of this year.
This article gave a thorough generalization of the future impacts of economies on trademark law
and how firms within countries can improve their intellectual property rights. As of now, the
next step for me is to devise the specifics of my study focus for this year. I may potentially
incorporate some of my findings from last year on technology and innovation, to analyze how
such factors contribute to the economic growth of trademark law and trademark law firms.
One of the quotes that heavily impacted my area focus last year was by Bill Gates,
“Intellectual property has the shelf life of a banana”. Essentially, this quote means that the world
of intellectual property is in constant evolution and adaptation to the latest innovation and market
shifts. Last year, I explored how the field of trademark law will adapt with the changes in
technology and innovation. This year, it only makes sense that I look into how this field will
evolve with market and economic changes. Ultimately, this article served as great foundational
The paper seeks to answer this question: When globalization opens up a country’s
economy, does it hurt or help local firms, especially weaker businesses? The paper
is based on the research of Wharton management professor Exequiel (Zeke)
Hernandez and Wharton doctoral candidate Sarath Balachandran. Hernandez
recently spoke to Knowledge@Wharton about their findings.
Knowledge@Wharton: Can you tell us about your paper? What did you set out
to discover in your research?
Hernandez: The broad goal we had was to essentially tackle this debate: If
policy efforts open up an economy to global markets, will globalization help
or hurt companies from countries that adopt those kinds of policies? Now
that is a huge question that can’t be answered in just one study. So for this
project we just took a narrow slice of that question.
We explore the efforts that countries have made to reform and improve their
intellectual property (IP) rights laws [as part of its globalization efforts]. Has
this helped companies have more opportunities … to establish alliances or
partnerships with companies from other countries?
First of all, these alliances or partnerships are really crucial for firms from
pretty much any country, but especially for firms from emerging markets
that tend to have weak intellectual property rights [laws]. And the reason is
that these alliances help firms access foreign markets to sell their products,
and they also help firms access new technologies and capabilities that then
help them upgrade their knowledge and their products. And so, they help
them become stronger firms.
Let’s say a firm from Chile can use a partnership with a firm from the U.S. to
sell in the American market and it can develop a new technology or product
from what it learns from that partnership. It is clear that having more access
to these partnerships is good for the Chilean company, but the question is,
once Chile improves its IP laws, is it the stronger firms in Chile or the weaker
ones that will benefit?
The question is important because inequality is not just about people, but it’s
also about companies. So for example, we care a lot about markets
functioning competitively, [which cannot happen if one or a few companies
dominate the economy]. … In an economy in which few firms control valuable
resources, such as the alliances that I just mentioned, that could be harmful.
All of this plays into the importance of the law as a way to make the playing
field level for both individuals and firms.
Hernandez: There are a lot of different changes that countries can make to
globalize their markets. … T
he reason we chose intellectual property rights is
that it is actually one of the most important barriers for companies and for
countries in order for them to participate in the global economy.
Let’s say you are a French technology company, and you are considering
partnering with an Indian or a Chinese firm to sell your product in India or in
China. Now if the IP laws of those countries are weak you would be concerned
about whether your technology, the trademark, or brand that makes your
company valuable, are protected. If your Indian and Chinese partner does
something to, say, expropriate or harm your intangible assets, what recourse
would you have? The answer is you have almost no recourse if the IP laws are
weak.
Hernandez: The Matthew Effect [which is named after the parable of the
talents from the Gospel of Matthew in the Bible] is a phenomenon that has
been found in many different settings. … In social science, what has been
shown is that essentially an economic actor that starts out with more
resources — say it’s capital or social connections or any other asset — over
time that actor will accumulate additional resources at a faster rate than an
actor that starts out with fewer resources. And that leads to a very uneven
distribution of resources. So the rich are getting richer, the poor getting
poorer.
Now this applies to our study because we are interested in whether changes in
IP laws strengthen or weaken this Matthew Effect when it comes to the ability
of companies to access more foreign partnerships with companies. So you
could imagine that the IP laws could have two competing outcomes, and it’s
not really clear beforehand which will happen.
The first outcome, or the first scenario, is one that actually strengthens the
Matthew Effect. What that means is that the strong get stronger, which in our
case is that firms that already were able to establish international
partnerships now can do it even more after their country improves its IP laws.
And that could happen because, say, these firms are more capable, they are
more desirable to the foreign partners, and a dynamic like that would lead to
an increase in inequality among firms in the economy when it comes to
accessing these foreign partnerships.
The other scenario is the opposite, it’s that the Matthew Effect becomes
weakened. So here the firms that had a hard time accessing international
partnerships benefit the most from the improvement in IP laws, maybe
because they lacked the reputation or connections beforehand to attract
foreign partners, and the better IP laws now provide a mechanism for them to
mitigate the concerns of foreign partners in entering into alliances with these
so-called weaker firms. And it is clear that a dynamic like this would lead to a
decrease in inequality, because the playing field now becomes more level.
Knowledge@Wharton: What were your main hypotheses, and what was the
source of your data?
In terms of the data, we actually went back about 20 years to the 1990s. And
the reason we chose that period is because it was an era of tremendous
globalization. In fact, that is the era that seeded everything that happened
that is now being debated [in our current political environment]. But it was an
era of liberalization, and many countries specifically made efforts to improve
their intellectual property laws so that their companies could participate in
international markets.
None of these even today have what we would call an ideal level of IP
protection, but during that time they made a significant step improvement.
So we identified these 13 countries, and then what we did is gathered data on
all of the alliances that firms from these 13 countries established, both before
and after the changes in the IP laws. That allowed us to have a very simple
research design, which was simply to assess if the number and quality of the
alliances they established with foreign companies changed after the
improvement in the IP laws compared to the period before.
In other words, the benefit was strongest for the weak, which led to the
Matthew Effect being weaker, resulting in a more even distribution, or more
level playing field, in terms of access to foreign partnerships.
We felt it was important to actually see if the increase was also one in quality,
and who got a bigger increase in quality as a result of these IP reforms. In
terms of measurement, [quality] is always a little bit hard to capture at the
firm level. So what we did is we used some of the attributes of the countries of
the foreign partners as proxies [for the quality of the partners that firms
could access across countries].
We used three measures. One measure is the extent to which a country makes
high technology exports. Another is the number of science and technology
publications in the country. What those two measures have in common is
they capture the technological sophistication of the firms from that country,
at least on average. And then a third measure is simply the variety or diversity
of countries from which firms can find partners. This gets at the ability to
access diverse knowledge and ideas through the alliances that these firms
establish.
Knowledge@Wharton: Can you talk about the different types of alliances that
the companies can enter?
Hernandez: You are referring to a part of the paper where we try to see if the
IP reforms led the weak versus the strong companies to increase across
specific types of alliances — say partnerships that are about doing R&D, or
partnerships that are about marketing or manufacturing. We didn’t really
have any hypotheses about this; we just wanted to see if the increase in the
number of these different types was different for the strong versus the weak
forms.
It turns out that there is no difference, meaning that the weak firms sort of
consistently increased more than the strong firms in accessing all kinds of
partnerships. So it seems to be that there is some across-the-board benefit of
getting access to partnerships for the weaker firms.
We find that the weak firms benefit more from the changes in IP laws in a
relative sense. That means that relative to the strong firms, the increase in
quantity and quality of alliances is greater, but not that the strong firms are
hurt. And that is not just important for understanding, say, the distributional
aspects of our results. But I think it also is realistic because these so-called
strong firms were strong for a reason. And IP reforms don’t weaken those
capabilities that made them attractive as foreign partners, it just … creates
opportunities for the weak firms. So I suppose that is good news all around.
Hernandez: The biggest limitation of our work, especially if you think of
where we started, was this huge question of the inequality of firms. We really
have tackled only a very narrow part of that. And so our claims are also very
narrow. Specifically, what we can say is IP laws benefit the weakest firms the
most, although they benefit all firms on average when it comes to accessing
something very specific, which is foreign alliance partners.
We are really not saying much about a lot of other consequences that IP laws
can have, which would have to do with the technological capabilities of firms,
their patenting, their ability to create novel products, etc. I am certain that IP
laws have some effects that are good and some effects that are not so clearly
positive for the economy as a whole. Perhaps there are some consumers that
are hurt by IP laws in some cases. And so our findings have to be interpreted
as really a small piece of a much larger puzzle.
Knowledge@Wharton: At the end of the day, what are you hoping to do with
this research? Are you hoping to influence public policy, for example perhaps
encourage governments of emerging countries to adopt strong property
rights laws? What are you hoping to achieve?
Hernandez: The short answer is yes. I hope that the research that we do is
impactful. Let’s start with the policy implications. What we found — coupled
with a lot of other research that is out there on IP laws — is that emerging
countries on net are much better off with strong rather than weak IP rights.
Perhaps to a Western audience [from countries that already have strong IP
rights] that sounds like an obvious statement, but there is a lot of debate in
emerging economies on whether it is worth formalizing IP rights or not. And
I think, again, we are one small piece of the puzzle that says that, yes, on net
you are better off doing that.
Hernandez: I would say two things. Let’s stay more on the policy side for the
first one. With the caveat that our paper is addressing a narrow part of a
bigger debate, I think it adds one fact in favor of policies that expose firms to
global markets and global competition. In this era of protectionism and
skepticism about globalization, empirical facts like these are actually quite
relevant.
From the standpoint of firms and managers, our study gives them a reason to
at least understand that these kinds of policies that expose them to
globalization can be good in the long run, and that they don’t necessarily
have to have zero sum benefits, that in fact it can make them more
competitive. Now of course we need more research to get at that, but I think
we start pointing in that direction.