Sie sind auf Seite 1von 22

Conjoint Analysis in Consumer Research: Issues and Outlook

Author(s): Paul E. Green and V. Srinivasan


Source: Journal of Consumer Research, Vol. 5, No. 2 (Sep., 1978), pp. 103-123
Published by: Oxford University Press
Stable URL: https://www.jstor.org/stable/2489001
Accessed: 12-01-2019 13:08 UTC

JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide
range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and
facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at
https://about.jstor.org/terms

Oxford University Press is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access
to Journal of Consumer Research

This content downloaded from 195.43.22.140 on Sat, 12 Jan 2019 13:08:34 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
Con joint Analysis in Consumer Research:
Issues and Outlook
PAUL E. GREEN
V. SRINIVASAN*

Since 1971 conjoint analysis has been applied to a wide variety of problems
in consumer research. This paper discusses various issues involved in imple-
menting conjoint analysis and describes some new technical developments
and application areas for the methodology.

The modeling of consumer preferences among by Luce, a mathematical psychologist, and Tukey, a
T multiattribute alternatives has been one of the statistician (Luce and Tukey 1964). Shortly thereafter,
major activities in consumer research for at least a a number of theoretical contributions (Krantz 1964;
decade. Undoubtedly, the expectancy-value class of Tversky 1967) and algorithmic developments (Kruskal
attitude models (Fishbein 1967; Rosenberg 1956) has 1965; Carroll 1969; Young 1969) appeared.
occupied more researchers' time and journal pages Conjoint measurement, as practiced by mathematical
than any other approach. However, a more recent con- psychologists, has primarily been concerned with the
tender, conjoint analysis, shows indications of coming conditions under which there exist measurement scales
into its own as a practical set of methods for predicting for both the dependent and independent variables,
consumer preferences for multiattribute options in a given the order of the joint effects of the inqdependent
wide variety of product and service contexts. variables and a prespecified composition rule. Com-
The purpose of this paper is to trace the development puter programs have been developed and applied in ex-
of conjoint methodology and relate it to relevant topics amining whether a set of data meets the necessary
in applied psychology, decision theory, and economics. conditions for applying various composition rules (e.g.,
We then discuss the merits and demerits of the alter- additive) hypothesized by the researcher (Ullrich and
natives that have been proposed for implementing the Painter 1974; Barron 1977). However, applications by
different steps in conjoint analysis. Next, we focus on psychometricians and consumer researchers have em-
reliability and validity testing of the methodology. The phasized the scaling aspects -finding specific numeri-
discussion then proceeds to applications of conjoint cal scale values, assuming that a particular composition
analysis to the evaluation of products and services in rule applies, possibly with some error. Accordingly,
the public and private sectors. The paper concludes it now seems useful to adopt the name, "conjoint analy-
with a brief discussion of some new developments in sis," to cover models and techniques that emphasize
methodology and application areas. the transformation of subjective responses into esti-
Readers who are unfamiliar with conjoint analysis mated parameters.
may want to read Green and Wind (1975) before at- While conjoint methodology was discussed briefly in
tempting a detailed study of this paper.' the working paper by Green and Rao (1969) and the
book by Green and Carmone (1970), the first detailed,
CONJOINT ANALYSIS IN REVIEW consumer-oriented paper did not appear until 1971
(Green and Rao). Following this, a spate of papers
While the foundations of the field go back to at least
dealing with either algorithms or applications (Green,
the 1920s, it is generally agreed that 1964 marks the
Carmone, and Wind 1972; Srinivasan and Shocker
start of conjoint measurement, with the seminal paper
1973b; Johnson 1974; Westwood, Lunn, and Beazley
* Paul E. Green is S.S. Kresge Professor of Marketing, Wharton
1974) appeared in a variety of journals. Theoretical
School, University of Pennsylvania, Philadelphia, PA 19104, and justification for the multiattribute modeling of consumer
V. Srinivasan is Professor of Marketing and Management Science, preferences was provided in the growing literature on
Graduate School of Business, Stanford University, Stanford, CA
94305. The authors wish to thank all those contributors to the field
who were kind enough to send various bibliographic materials re- 1 For a technical description of parameter estimation algorithms
lating to conjoint anal-ysis. The authors also extend their apprecia- with illustrations, the reader is urged to see the excellent review
tion to John Hauser, Subrata Sen, and the referees for helpful com- of conjoint analysis by Rao (1977). A monograph-length treatment
ments on an earlier version of this paper. of conjoint analysis and related procedures for analyzing multiat-
tribute data can be found in the text by Green and Wind (1973).

103 ? JOURNAL OF CONSUMER RESEARCH * Vol. 5 * September 1978

This content downloaded from 195.43.22.140 on Sat, 12 Jan 2019 13:08:34 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
104 THE JOURNAL OF CONSUMER RESEARCH

the Fishbein-Rosenberg class of expectancy-value both parameter estimation and model testing (e.g., to
models and the new economic theory of consumer see if certain theoretically predicted interaction effects
choice (Lancaster 1971; Ratchford 1975). However, occur) in such content areas as information integration,
economists have generally been most interested in the attitude change theory, person perception, decision
aggregate implications of multiattribute utility struc- theory, and consumer behavior.
tures and less concerned with estimation of individual In terms of methodology, functional measurement
utility functions per se. proceeds similarly to clinical judgment modeling and
As Wilkie and Pessemier (1973) have observed, conjoint analysis. For example, a researcher may be
expectancy-value models draw upon a compositional interested in how a subject judges the friendliness of
or build-up approach in which the total utility for some a person described in terms of levels on two factors,
multiattribute object is found as a weighted sum of the say, boldness and laziness. Each of the two factors in
object's perceived attribute levels and associated value the experiment would consist of a set of levels, and all
ratings,-as separately (and explicitly) judged by the levels of the first factor would be crossed with all levels
respondent. In contrast, conjoint methodology is based of the second. Overall friendliness ratings are then
on a decompositional approach, in which respondents decomposed by ANOVA procedures to yield a scale
react to a set of "total" profile descriptions. It is the value for each level of each of the two factors. More-
job of the analyst to find a set of part worths for the over, assuming that replicate judgments are available,
individual attributes that, given some type of composi- the researcher can check for the significance of inter-
tion rule (e.g., an additive one), are most consistent action effects.
with the respondent's overall preferences. Furthermore, A very different set of procedures has been devel-
a key distinction between these two approaches lies oped by Keeney and Raiffa (1976) for multiattribute
in the predominant purpose for which each approach is utility estimation in normative contexts. The form of
used. Users of conjoint analysis have generally empha- the utility function is derived deductively from a set
sized predictive validity and regarded explanation of assumptions. The parameters of the utility function
largely as a desirable (but secondary) objective, while are obtained from tradeoff judgments and from pref-
the converse has generally been true for the expectancy- erences for alternative gambles (lotteries). The data
value theorists. collection is considerably more complex than conjoint
Conjoint analysis, both in spirit and computational analysis. Although the utility function approach em-
detail, is closely related to two other developments in ploys decompositional modeling in several parts of its
applied psychology-the modeling of clinical judgments implementation (Hauser and Urban 1977), it is not an
and functional measurement. estimation procedure in that virtually no measurement
Since 1960, the modeling of clinical judgments has error is assumed (in contrast to the just described statis-
been the principal pursuit of a group of behavioral tical approaches).
scientists initially identified with the Oregon Research In what follows, we use the term conjoint analysis
Institute (Dawes and Corrigan 1974). This approach has broadly to refer to any decompositional method that
involved decompositional modeling of subjects' re- estimates the structure of a consumer's preferences
sponses to profile descriptions representing such diverse (e.g., part worths, importance weights, ideal points)
topics as gastric ulcer symptoms (Hoffman, Slovic, given his/her overall evaluations of a set of alternatives
and Rorer 1968), psychological test scores (Goldberg that are prespecified in terms of levels of different at-
1968), and student applications for graduate study tributes. This type of estimation has been referred to
(Dawes 1971). Multiple regression has been the main as "external analysis" in the psychometric literature
technique for parameter estimation in these models, (Carroll 1972).
although analysis of variance (ANOVA) has been
applied occasionally. ISSUES IN IMPLEMENTING
In clinical judgment modeling the dependent variable
CONJOINT ANALYSIS
is, for instance, an admissions officer's overall evalua-
tion of the likelihood of success in graduate study of an Because of the substantial amount of among-person
applicant described in terms of the predictors: individ- variation in consumer preferences, conjoint analysis is
ual Graduate Record Examination score, undergrad- usually carried out at the individual level. The form of
uate grade-point average, and rating of the undergrad- the preference model (composition rule) is generally
uate institution's quality. The standardized partial assumed to be the same for all individuals, but the
regression coefficients (or beta weights) are often inter- parameters of the model are permitted to vary across
preted as measures of the relative importance of pre- the sample of individuals from the relevant target popu-
dictors in estimating the dependent variable. lation.
Functional measurement, as originally proposed by Several alternate means exist for identifying the
Anderson (1970), also employs a decompositional ap- attributes which are relevant to consumers in forming
proach utilizing, in this case, ANOVA and full factorial their preferences (Alpert 1971). A preliminary data
designs. Functional measurement has been used for collection effort, questioning consumers regarding at-

This content downloaded from 195.43.22.140 on Sat, 12 Jan 2019 13:08:34 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
CONJOINT ANALYSIS IN CONSUMER RESEARCH 105

tributes important to them, usually helps in identifying TABLE

those attributes that are most frequently regarded as STEPS INVOLVED IN CONJOINT ANALYSIS
relevant'(Braun and Srinivasan 1975). Kelly's (1955)
repertory grid, focus group interviews, or judgments Step Alternative methods
of product managers, retailers and others knowledge-
1. Selection of a model of Vector model, ideal-point model,
able about the product/service and its uses can be used
preference part-worth function model,
for this purpose. The more difficult and often subjective mixed model
task is to reduce the number of attributes to a manage-
2. Data collection method Two-factor-at-a-time (trade-off
able size so that the estimation procedures are reliable
analysis), full-profile (concept
while at the same time accounting for consumer pref- evaluation)
erences sufficiently well.
3. Stimulus set construc- Fractional factorial design,
The various steps in conjoint analysis and the alter-
tion for the full-profile random sampling from multi-
native methods of implementing each of the steps are method variate distribution
summarized in the table. We d'iscuss each of these steps
4. Stimulus presentation Verbal description (multiple cue,
in turn and indicate the empirical results, if any, that are
stimulus card), paragraph de-
available for comparing the alternatives. There is con- scription, pictorial or three-di-
siderable scope for empirical research in this area to mensional model representation
determine the methods that are most appropriate for
5. Measurement scale for Paired comparisons, rank order,
each of the steps. the dependent vari- rating scales, constant-sum
Among the numerous combinations of methods that able paired comparisons, category
can be chosen for the different steps, some of the com- assignment (Carroll, 1969)
binations are not feasible and these will be pointed out 6. Estimation method MONANOVA, PREFMAP, LINMAP,
in the ensuing discussion. To date, most applications of Johnson's nonmetric tradeoff
conjoint analysis have utilized only a few of the many algorithm, multiple regression,
LOGIT, PROBIT
possible combinations. By focusing attention on the
steps themselves, better overall combinations may
emerge. A worthwhile goal for empirical research is to
{w } will, in general, be different for different indi-
identify the combination of methods that provides the
maximum predictive validity for a given amount of viduals in the sample. Geometrically, the preference sj
respondent time (or research buLdget). Of course, the can be represented as the projection of the, stimulus
best combination will probably depend on factors such point {yj, } on the vector { wp } in the t-dimensional
attribute space.
as the type of product/market, the number of relevant
attributes, the type of respondent, and so on. Future
The ideal-point model posits that the preference sj is
studies might entail several combinations, each dealing negatively related to the squared (weighted) distance dj2
with a separate part of the data collection and analysis. of the location {yj, } of the jth stimulus from the
individual's ideal point {xp}, where dj2 is defined as

Preference Models dj2= E W1(yj - X )2. (3)


p=l1

First, let Thus, stimuli which are closer to the ideal point (smaller
p = 1, 2, ... ., t (1) dj2) will be the more preferred ones (larger sj). It turns
denote the set of t attributes or factors that have been out that the simultaneous estimation of { wp } and {xp }
chosen. Next, letyjp denote the level of thepth attribute is feasible for the weighted Euclidean measure of distance
for thejth stimulus. We first consider the case where yjp as specified in equation (3). If, however, the exponent 2
is inherently a continuous variable (e.g., travel time or in equation (3) is replaced by a general Minkowski
price). The case of categorical (or polytomous) at- metric r, the estimation of {xp } becomes very difficult.
tributes will be considered later. The vector model of Fortunately, however, the Euclidean metric is often a
preference, referred to as the Composite Criterion close enough approximation to the general Minkowski
Model by Srinivasan and Shocker (1973b) and Parker metric (Green 1975).
and Srinivasan (1976), posits that the preference sj for The part-worth function model posits that
the jth stimulus is given by
Si = E fp(yjp), (4)
p=1
sj= I wpyjp, (2)
p=1
wherefp is the function denoting the part worth
where the {wp } are the individual's weights ferent for the levels
t of yjp for the pth attribute. In p
attributes. Thus, the vector model is identical in mathe- fp(yjp) is estimated only for a selected set of l
matical form to the Fishbein-Rosenberg class of multi- yjp (usually three or four), with the part worth f
attribute models. -As remarked earlier, the weights mediate yjp obtained by linear interpolation. T

This content downloaded from 195.43.22.140 on Sat, 12 Jan 2019 13:08:34 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
106 THE JOURNAL OF CONSUMER RESEARCH

FIGURE of the shape of the preference model is greater as we go


ALTERNATIVE MODELS OF PREFERENCE from the vector to the ideal point to the part-worth func-
tion models; however, the reliability of the estimated
I Vector Model 11 Ideal Point Model III Part-Worth Function Mlodel

Preferencea
parameters is likely to improve in the reverse order.
Consequently, from the point of view of predictive
validity, the relative desirability of the three models
is not clear. Thus a priori notions of the shape of the
part-worth function could help us in the choice of an
appropriate model. One may always prefer greater
p 0~~~~~~~~~ durability (vector), smaller waiting time (vector), but
ideal pointo. x may prefer moderate levels of sweetness or size of auto-
Level of attribute p Level of attribute p Chosen level s of attribute p
mobile (ideal point). However, one may prefer maxi-
mum temperature levels for both iced and hot tea (Car-
a Preference for different levels of attribute p while holding the values for the
roll 1972) and have a lower preference for in-between
other attributes constant.
temperature levels (part-worth function). If the attrib-
ute is categorical, (e.g., mode of travel-auto versus
part-worth function is represented as a piecewise linear carpool versus public transit; type of educational insti-
curve. To determine the part worth for a value of yj,
tution-junior college, private university, state uni-
outside the range of estimation, extrapolation of the versity), we are forced to use the part-worth function
piecewise linear function would be needed and the model. It is, of course, probable that for some attributes
validity of this procedure is questionable. (Hence, the the vector model would be the best while for some
researcher should try to employ the full range of the others the ideal-point or part-worth models may be
attribute, wherever practical.) Still, the part-worth more appropriate.
function approach has received wide acceptance due, We may combine the features of the three models
in part, to the ready interpretability of the graphi- to formulate a mixed model. It is well known (e.g.,
celly displayed attribute part-worth functions. The Green and Tull 1978, pp. 297-8) that a polytomous
three models of preference are illustrated in the figure. attribute with k levels can be converted into (k - 1)
The part-worth function model provides the greatest dummy variables, where the ith dummy variable takes
flexibility in allowing different shapes for the prefer- the value 1 for the ith level and 0 otherwise. (The
ence function along each of the attributes. In particular, kth level serves as the reference.) Thus the part-worth
by defining fp(yjp) = - wp(y' - xp)2 we get the ideal- model can be converted to the vector model with the
point model and by setting fp(yjp) = wpyjp we obtain use of dummy variables. (The situation is analogous
the vector model. Similarly, the ideal-point model is to the analysis of factorial experiments through multi-
more flexible than the vector model since it can be ple regression.) Similarly, if we consider the compo-
shown (Carroll 1972) that the vector model is a specialnent of the ideal-point model along the pth attribute
case of the ideal-point model as xp -> oo. Intuitively,and relate the squared distance to preference by a nega-
as xp -> + 00, preference along the pth dimension in- tive sign, we obtain
creases as yjp increases (since the ideal is at plus infin-
fP(Yjp) = -Wp(yjp2 -2Xpyjp + X 2). (5)
ity) and this is essentially the same as the vector model
with w > 0. Equation (5) may be rewritten as,
Although the part-worth function model seems to be
the most attractive in terms of being compatible with fp(yjp) = ap + bpyjp2 + cpyjp, (6)
any arbitrary shape for the preference function, this wherea = -WPXP2, bp = -wp andc = 2wpx Thus,
benefit comes at the cost of having to estimate addi- the essential nature of the ideal-point model can be
tional parameters (thereby lowering their reliability) captured in the vector model by considering the
and the need to approximate intermediate values by pseudo-attribute yjp2 in addition to yjp (Carroll 1972).
linear interpolation. In particular, estimation of the Furthermore, iffp(yjp) is substantially nonlinear (con-
vector model involves only the t parameters {wp}. For
vex or concave), it may also be capable of being par-
the ideal-point model, 2t parameters have to be esti- simoniously represented by equation (6). It may also
mated, namely {wp} and {xp}. If there are q levels, say,
be worthwhile to consider higher order polynomial
for each of the t attributes then (q - I)t parameters terms, such as yjp3. Pekelman and Sen (1978) show that
have to be estimated for the part-worth function model. if the utility function has the form given in equation (6),
Replacing fp(yjp) by fp(yjp) + ap does not alter the then the estimation of that function would give better
model in equation (4) in any essential way so that the predictive results than a part-worth function approach
part worth for level 1, say, can be taken to be zero with-combined with linear interpolation. However, if the
out any loss of generality. Consequently, only (q - 1) functional form is likely to be very different from equa-
parameters need to be estimated for the pth attribute. tion (6), the part-worth function approach may be
To summari-ze the discussion so far, the flexibility appropriate.

This content downloaded from 195.43.22.140 on Sat, 12 Jan 2019 13:08:34 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
CONJOINT ANALYSIS IN CONSUMER RESEARCH 107

A mixed model that may capture the advantages of an attribute while holding other attributes constant,
of all three models can be implemented by the notation, (ii) there are errors in the measurement of attribute
T levels (possibly because of perceptual differences
Sj= E VqZjq, (7) across consumers), and (iii) the attributes tend to be
q=1
correlated. Thus, even if the respondent's information
where T is the total number of pseudo-attributes (also processing strategy and decision model are complex,
the total number of estimated parameters) and the the compensatory model can usually produce good
{Zjq} are defined from the yj,, as follows: predictions, assuming that this is the main concern
of the researcher. Furthermore, the ideal-point and the
1. attributes where the preference is expected to be
part-worth function models are more general than the
monotone and approximately linear: zj is defined
linear-compensatory model, in that only additivity, not
to be equal to yj;
linearity, is assumed (i.e., only interaction terms are
2. attrnbutes for which the preference is expected to be
omitted). Consequently the predictive validity of these
either substantially nonlinear (convex or concave) models can be expected to be very good.
or of the ideal-point type: for each attribute p, two
In situations where specific interaction effects can be
z variables, one equal to y and the other equal to y2,
expected a priori, these could be captured in the mixed
are defined;
model by adding pseudo-attributes of the form z = YY2.
3. attributes which are categorical, or the preference In some other situations, interaction effects can be
function is not well approximated by equation (6): taken into account by combining two categorical at-
for each attribute p with k levels, (k - 1) dummy vari-
tributes into one. For example, the researcher may
able would be defined.
believe that car roominess and gas mileage may inter-
If the dependent variable (overall preference) is meas- act in the following way:
ured on an interval scale and multiple regression is used
* A respondent generally prefers a roomier car to a
as the estimation procedure, then statistical testing of
cramped one.
equation (7) could guide us in the choice of vector ver-
sus ideal point versus part-worth model for the pth * A respondent generally prefers higher gas mileage to
attribute, e.g., if the coefficient of the y2 term is not lower gas mileage.

significant then the vector model could be chosen * However, a roomy car with high gas mileage is evalu-
over the ideal-point model. ated much higher than the sum of the separate part
Much empirical research has examined whether con- worths.
sumers actually use the linear-compensatory model
If so, the researcher can construct a four-level factor
(i.e., the vector model) rather than the seemingly sim-
from the two two-level factors and test his surmise
pler evaluation models such as the lexicographic and
using the main-effect estimates of the four-level
conjunctive (cut-off) rules (Russ 1971; Wright 1975;
superfactor.
Hansen 1976). (Actually, the lexicographic model is a
special case of the vector model in equation (2) where
the weight for the most important attribute is con-
Data Collection Alternatives
siderably larger than the second most important attri-
bute whose weight, in turn, is considerably larger than Data collection procedures in conjoint analysis have
the third most important attribute, etc.) This research largely involved variations on two basic methods:
has found that some consumers use each of the models,
but generally prefer those requiring simpler processes. * the two-factor-at-a-time procedure, and
However, for predictive validity this problem is not as * the full-profile approach.
serious as it may initially seem. This is because the
compensatory model of conjoint analysis can approxi- The two-factor-at-a-time procedure, also referred to as
mate the outcomes of other kinds of decision rules quite the "trade-off procedure" (Johnson 1974), considers
closely. In fact, a recent study by Berl, Lewis, and factors (attributes) on a two-at-a-time basis. The re-
Morrison (1976) of high school seniors' choice of col- spondent is asked to rank the various combinations
leges showed that the linear compensatory model was of each pair of factor levels from most preferred to least
more consistent with the respondents' actual behavior preferred. Panel I of the exhibit shows an illustration
than the lexicographic and conjunctive rules. of the approach, as applied to consumer evaluations
Dawes and Corrigan (1974), Rorer (1971), and Green of steel-belted radial replacement tires.
and Devita (1975b) discuss the general conditions The two-factor-at-a-time procedure is simple to ap-
under which linear-compensatory models perform ply and reduces information overload on the part of the
well. Three of these conditions prevail in many situa- respondent. It also lends itself easily to mail question-
tions in the context of modeling preferences for real naire form, since no special props are needed. How-
brands/services: (i) the preference function is mono- ever, in actual problems, it displays a number of
tone (increasing or decreasing) over increasing levels limitations:

This content downloaded from 195.43.22.140 on Sat, 12 Jan 2019 13:08:34 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
108 THE JOURNAL OF CONSUMER RESEARCH

EXHIBIT representative of the real life behavior of the individual


ALTERNATIVE DATA COLLECTION METHODS where he/she may have more time and motivation to
deliberate on the choice from among a small set of
I. Two-Factor-at-a-Time II. Full-Profile Approach
alternatives.
Approach (Sample stimulus card)
Because of the information overload problem,
Tread life the full-profile procedure is generally confined to, at
Brand most, five or six factors in any specific sort. If a larger
Tire 30,000 40,000 50,000 SEARS
number of factors is entailed- some industrial studies
brand miles miles miles Tread Life
50,000 MILES
have included 25 or more factors, each at from two to
Goodyear 8 4 1 a Sidewall six levels-the analyst is more or less forced to incor-
Goodrich 12 9 5 WHITE porate "bridging-type" factors. The idea here is to
Firestone 11 7 3 Price
prepare several card decks in which the full set of fac-
Sears 10 6 2 $55
tors is first split into subsets of five or six factors each.
a1 denotes the best-liked combination and 12 Each card deck is then composed of factor combina-
denotes the least-liked combination for a hypo-
tions that involve, say, five factors, only. In each case
thetical respondent.
one or two factors are common across decks so that
they provide a basis for linking part-worth functions
across the various subsets of factors. (For an illustra-
* By decomposing the overall set of factors to two-
tion, see Hopkins, Larreche, and Massy 1977, p. 371.)
at-a-time combinations, there is some sacrifice in
The full-profile approach-when implemented by
realism. Moreover, respondents are usually unclear
as to what should be assumed about the t-2 factors various kinds of fractional factorial designs (to be dis-
that are not being considered in a specific evaluation cussed later)-entails fewer judgments to be made by
task. For instance, in Panel I of the exhibit it is the respondent, although each single judgment is more
reasonable to expect that as the tread life increases complex. As per later discussion on response (or de-
the price of the tire is also likely to increase. pendent) variable data, the two-factor-at-a-time pro-
Consequently, when the attributes of a product or cedure provides only a set of rank orders while the full-
service are correlated (e.g., for technological reasons) profile approach can employ either a rank order or rat-
what the rank order in a particular table corresponds
ings (e.g., on a seven-point scale from "least liked" to
to is not clear.
"most liked"). Such flexibility in scaling seems desir-
* With, say, only six factors, each at four levels, the able. In the full-profile approach, each stimulus card
respondent could be asked to fill out 15 tables, each can potentially be assigned any level on a continuous
consisting of 16 cells. While partially balanced incom- attribute. However, in the two-factor-at-a-time ap-
plete block designs (Green 1974) or related procedures proach, each continuous attribute is assigned only a few
(Johnson and VanDyk 1975) can be used to reduce the
levels because of the need to construct manageable
number of two-way tables, the total number of re-
trade-off tables. (This is also true for the full-profile
quired judgments is still quite large.
approach using fractional factorial designs.)
* There is some tendency for respondents either to The main argument that seems to favor the full-profile
forget where they are in the table or to adopt pat- approach is that it gives a more realistic description of
ternized types of responses, such as always attending stimuli by defining the levels of each of the factors and
to variations in one factor before considering the
possibly taking into account the potential environmental
other (Johnson 1976).
correlations between factors in real stimuli. On the
* The procedure appears to be most suited to verbal other hand, it has the disadvantage of making the task
descriptions of factor combinations, rather than pic- difficult for the respondent by having to consider
torial or other kinds of iconic representations. For several factors at one time. Based on these two
example, a study of package designs in which color, considerations, we would speculate that in contexts
logo, size, and shape can be simultaneously varied
where the environmental correlation between factors is
and portrayed graphically would not lend itself well to
large and the number of factors on the stimulus card is
this approach.
small (but greater than two), the full-profile approach is
The full-profile approach (also referred to as the con- likely to be better in terms of predictive validity.
cept evaluation task) utilizes the complete set of fac- However, if the environmental correlation between the
tors, as shown by the illustrative stimulus card for a factors is small and the number of factors on the
four-factor design in Panel II of the exhibit. The major stimulus card is large, the two-factor-at-a-time ap-
limitation of this approach is the possibility of informa- proach is likely to be better.
tion overload and the resulting temptation on the part Four empirical studies have compared the two ap-
of the respondent to simplify the experimental task by proaches to data collection. Montgomery, Wittink, and
ignoring variations in the less important factors or by Glaze (1977), in a study of job choice by MBAs, found
simplifying the factor levels themselves. The conjoint that the two-factor-at-a-time approach yielded higher
results obtained under such conditions may not be predictive validity than the full-profile approach.

This content downloaded from 195.43.22.140 on Sat, 12 Jan 2019 13:08:34 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
CONJOINT ANALYSIS IN CONSUMER RESEARCH 109

Similarly, Alpert, Betak, and Golden (1978) found that rather than n - T, the degrees of freedom.) However,
the goodness-of-fit to input data was better for the two- a respondent typically takes about 20-30 minutes for
factor-at-a-time approach in their study of commuters' n = 25 in a five attribute, full-profile rank ordering task.
choice of transportation modes. However, Jain, Acito, Given the usual considerations of maintaining the re-
Malhotra, and Mahajan (1978) found that the two meth- spondent's interest in the task, it is often difficult to
ods yielded approximately the same level of cross- increase n much above 30.
validity in the context of choosing checking accounts In deciding the range of variation of attribute levels
offered by various banks. Also, Oppedijk van Veen and and interattribute correlation (e.g., between auto ver-
Beazley (1977) found that the utilities determined by the sus bus and travel time to work, or between horsepower
two methods were roughly similar in the context of a rating and gas mileage of cars), two conflicting con-
durable good product class. siderations are relevant. The use of stimulus descrip-
The first two studies used eight and nine attributes, tions similar to those that currently exist (similar in
respectively, and the resulting information overload terms of ranges of attribute levels and environmental
may have biased the results against the full-profile ap- correlations) will increase believability and hence
proach. In comparison, the third and fourth studies validity of the preference judgments. On the other
used five and three attributes respectively. In all four hand, if we make the ranges for attribute levels much
studies, the problem contexts were such that there were larger than reality and/or decrease the magnitude of
no substantial environmental correlations across interattribute correlations to zero (as is implied by
factors. (In any event, the full-profile approaches used orthogonal designs), we may decrease believability and
orthogonal designs that exhibited no interattribute cor- hence validity. But orthogonal designs and/or larger
relations.) Thus the results are not inconsistent with the ranges for attribute values have the advantage of im-
conjecture advanced earlier comparing the effec- proving the accuracy of the parameter estimates for a
tiveness of the two alternative data collection given level of validity for the preference judgments.
procedures. Thus, the extreme strategy of using descriptions similar
to those that exist has the disadvantage of loss of ac-
curacy in estimation while the alternate extreme strat-
Stimulus Set Construction for the Full-Profile
egy of using an orthogonal design and/or ranges for
Method attribute values much larger than reality has the dis-
The number of brands in a product class that a re- advantage of decreasing the validity of the respondent's
preference judgments.
spondent may be familiar with is,usually small. Further-
more, real brands and services are usually not distinc- We would recommend, therefore, that the ranges
tive enough to provide reliable estimates of parameters. be made larger than reality, but not so large as to be
For these reasons, conjoint analysis is usually done unbelievable. Further, we would recommend making
with hypothetical stimulus descriptions. This has the interattribute correlations in the hypothetical descrip-
additional advantage of enabling us to compare pre- tions smaller (in absolute value) than the environmental
dicted behavior with the actual behavior of the re- correlations that exist in real stimuli, but not to make
spondents towards real brands or services. In con- them so small as to be unbelievable. However, if the
structing the stimulus profiles for the full-profile ap- environmental interattribute correlations are small to
proach several questions arise: start with, there will be virtually no loss in believability
by using orthogonal designs, and there is everything
1. How many stimuli do we need to use?
to gain in terms of accuracy of the estimated
2. What should be the range of attribute variation and parameters.
interattribute correlation in constructing the stimuli?The hypothetical stimulus descriptions can be con-
structed in either of two ways. The more popular
3. How should the stimuli themselves be constructed?
method has been to define a number of levels (say, three
The number of stimuli should obviously depend on or four) for each of the attributes over the range of at-
the number of estimated parameters. From multiple tribute variation. The researcher should pretest the
regression theory (Darlington 1968), we know that the levels of the continuous factors to insure that they are
expected mean squared error of prediction is given by far enough apart to be considered as realistically dis-
(1 + Tin )o.2 where T is the number of estimated param- tinct. For categorical attributes the feasible levels are
eters, n is the number of stimuli to be evaluated, and readily available but the selection of which levels are
o.2 is the unexplained (error) variance in the model. ''representative" of the factor often requires careful
Thus the ratio (nIT) should be as large as possible to study. If a full factorial design is used, the number of
minimize the increment to prediction error over and possible stimuli quickly becomes very large (e.g., with
above the error (cr2) that is unavoidable. For a given three attributes at three levels each and two attributes
T, as n increases from 2T to 5T the prediction error at two levels each, the total number of possible de-
decreases by 20 percent. (As the formula indicates, scriptions is 33 x 22 = 108). Green (1974) has suggested
it is more appropriate to think in terms of the nIT ratio the use of various types offractionalfactorial designs

This content downloaded from 195.43.22.140 on Sat, 12 Jan 2019 13:08:34 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
110 THE JOURNAL OF CONSUMER RESEARCH

to reduce the number of combinations to a manageable of travel) could also be handled in the above framework
size while at the same time maintaining orthogonality. by defining a proxy continuous random variable and a
These types of designs assume away most (sometimes cut-off value (e.g., if x 2 0, then auto, if x < 0, then
all) interaction effects, which is realistic given the type bus). For categorical variables with more than two
of preference models discussed earlier. For instance, categories, the values could be randomly drawn from
the preceding numerical example with five attributes a discrete distribution. If this categorical attribute is
can be reduced to an orthogonal main-effects plan with to be correlated with other continuous attributes, dif-
only 18 stimuli (Green and Wind 1975, p. 108). ferent sets of parameters for the multivariate distribu-
A discussion of various kinds of fractional factorials, tion would have to be defined, depending on the value
including both orthogonal and nonorthogonal designs, assigned to the categorical attribute.
can be found in the paper by Green, Carroll, and Thus, if the attributes are to be correlated in the stim-
Carmone (1978). This paper describes both main-ef- ulus set, the random sampling procedure just described
fects plans, in which no interactions can be separately provides a systematic, although cumbersome pro-
estimated' and less restrictive plans (such as Resolu- cedure. By creating random descriptions in excess of
tion IV and Compromise designs) that permit estima- the required number n, it is possible to delete descrip-
tion of all main effects and selected two-factor inter- tions which are dominated (i.e., have a less desirable
actions, without an inordinate increase in the number attribute level on each of the attributes) by other stim-
of stimuli. This paper also shows how various basic uli. By trial and error, it is generally possible to con-
designs can be modified to handle different combina- struct the n descriptions so that none of the stimuli
tions of factor levels. In addition, a number of refer- dominates any of the remaining (n - 1) descriptions
ences to the specialized literature in this area are (Parker and Srinivasan 1976). Although this procedure
included. is time consuming, it may still be desirable from the
If there is a substantial amount of environmental point of view of getting maximum potential information
correlation between some of the attributes, an orthog- from the respondent's evaluative judgments.
onal design can produce some stimuli which may not To illustrate this point, consider a two-attribute
be believable. If the environmental correlations are product class with three levels for each attribute. As-
very high (e.g., 0-55 mph acceleration time, gas mile- sume that the part-worth function is monotone (increas-
age, horsepower rating, and top speed), the researcher ing or decreasing) over the three levels, e.g., as might
may wish to prepare a composite factor covering all be the case with attributes such as tread mileage, price,
four subfactors whose separate levels show various or waiting time. Without loss of generality, let us as-
gradations of performance-mileage. Each level of the sume that greater levels are preferred to stnaller levels
composite would reflect the subfactor correlations that on the attribute. Then in the (3 x 3) orthogonal design
exist technologically so that a 300 hp engine does not with nine descriptions it can be shown that only nine
coexist with a 35 mpg fuel consumption. However, of the 36 potential paired comparisons have any infor-
with this approach, it is no longer possible to separate mation content. For example, the (1,1) and (3,3) de-
the effects of the subfactors contained in the composite. scriptions provide no information at all; they are, by the
If one wishes to capitalize on the high efficiency of monotonicity assumption, the worst and the best stim-
orthogonal arrays and other fractional factorials, factor uli. Furthermore, the pairs comparing, say, the stim-
independence is to be sought wherever possible. If ulus (3,2) to the stimuli (3,1), (2,2), (2,1), (1,2) and(1,1)
some of the profiles turn out to be unbelievable, other also convey no information.
orthogonal displays can be tried by permuting sets of The random sampling procedure seems to be well
factor levels. Finally, if worse comes to worst, a few suited to estimating ideal-point type models, as por-
profiles may have to be deleted or modified to in- trayed by equation (3). For example, in the frac-
corporate correlated factor levels. However, methods tional-factorial type approach, that uses only a few
such as the two-factor-at-a-time approach are less levels for each attribute, it is difficult to distinguish
amenable to the correlated-factor approach, since all well between alternative ideal-point locations that lie
combinations of factor levels are typically displayed between the adjacent levels used in the design. In the
for evaluation. random sampling procedure, many levels of the attribute
An alternate procedure for creating the stimulus are likely to be used so that a finer discrimination re-
descriptions is that of random sampling from a multi- garding the ideal-point location can be made.
variate distribution. Assuming for the moment that The fractional-factorial type design, on the other
all the attributes are continuous, a multivariate distribu- hand, is considerably easier to develop. If no attribute
tion can be defined given the means, standard devia- correlations are desired, it is likely to produce more
tions (derived from the ranges), and interattribute cor- accurate parameter estimates. It involves no limiting
relations. The stimulus descriptions could then be ran- assumption such as multivariate normality which needs
domly drawn from a multivariate normal distribution to be assumed in the random sampling approach.
(Naylor, Balintfy, Burdick, and Chu 1966, pp. 97-9). Finally, if the relative importances of the attributes
Dichotomous attributes (e.g., auto versus bus as mode are to be obtained, the orthogonal design produces less

This content downloaded from 195.43.22.140 on Sat, 12 Jan 2019 13:08:34 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
CONJOINT ANALYSIS IN CONSUMER RESEARCH 111

ambiguous answers than the correlated factors number, so that parameter estimates are likely to be
approach. very inaccurate when estimated at the individual level.
Based on these considerations, we would speculate Pictorial representation using various kinds of visual
that the fractional-factorial designs are better (in terms props or three dimensional models provides several
of predictive power) than the random sampling ap- important advantages over verbal profiles:
proach if the environmental interattribute correlations
* Information overload is reduced since the respondent
are not high. The random sampling approach is likely is not required to read and then visualize large quan-
to be better if the attribute correlations are high or if tities of information.
most of the attribute part-worth functions are mono-
tone with changes in attribute levels and ordinal overall * Higher homogeneity of perceptions of such things as
car roominess or trunk capacity is obtained across
preference judgments are obtained.
respondents.

* The task itself is more interesting and less fatiguing.


Stimulus Presentation
* The stimuli are more realistic.
To date, the presentation of the hypothetical stimuli
in the full profile approach has involved variations and Alpert, Betak, and Golden (1978) report that a com-
combinations of three basic approaches: bination of pictures and words produced roughly the
same results as the purely verbal approach, but the
* verbal description (multiple cue stimulus card),
respondents took less time to complete the pictorial
* paragraph description, and task. The primary disadvantage of the pictorial ap-
* pictorial representation.2 proach is the increased cost and time on the part of the
researcher in preparing the stimulus descriptions.
The two-factor-at-a-time approach has primarily used Furthermore, there is a danger in the picture displaying
the verbal description approach. However, pictorial information different than the researcher intended
representation has been used in a few cases. For in- (e.g., styling of the car may be conveyed in addition to
stance, Alpert, Betak, and Golden (1978) use pictures roominess). The pictorial approach is usually admin-
with different numbers of drops of gasoline to indicate istered by mail or personal interview. Data collection
the different levels of gasoline consumption of alterna- by time-shared computer terminals cannot, in general,
tive modes of transportation. employ this approach except through the use of
Panel II of the exhibit illustrates the verbal descrip- sketches in cathode ray terminals or by providing the
tion approach. In a typical task, the respondent is given pictures to the respondents as props to be used in con-
n stimulus cards, each card defining the levels of each junction with a time-shared terminal. However, the
of the t attributes. The respondent is asked to either pictorial approach has been successfully used on
rank order them or rate them on a scale. The main ad- several occasions involving mailed props, followed by
vantage with this procedure is its simplicity and the telephone interviews.
efficiency with which the data can be collected. Based on these considerations, we feel that the
Acito (1977) has found that the measured importance verbal and, particularly, the pictorial approaches are
of an attribute is to some extent affected by the order or likely to be the best methods of presenting stimulus
position of the attribute on the stimulus card. To reduce descriptions, assuming individual-level parameter
this potential bias, the order of the attributes is usually estimates are to be obtained. Choice of the pictorial
randomized over respondents. To reduce confusion, approach depends upon the nature of the product class
the order of attributes is kept the same for all the stim- (the importance of imagery) and cost considerations.
ulus cards given to any one respondent. Of course, the
stimulus cards themselves are shuffled thoroughly
Measurement Scale for the Dependent
before giving them to a respondent.
Variable
Some researchers, such as Hauser and Urban (1977),
have adopted the paragraph description approach. The The various alternatives for defining a measurement
advantage of this approach is that it provides a more scale for the dependent variable can be roughly clas-
realistic and complete description of the stimulus (simi- sified as nonmetric (paired comparisons, rank order)
lar to concept testing in new product development) and or metric (rating scales assuming approximately inter-
has the advantage of simultaneously testing advertising val scale properties, or ratio scales obtained by con-
claims. A significant drawback of this procedure is that stant-sum paired comparisons [Torgerson 1958, pp.
it limits the total number of descriptions to a small 105-12]). Depending on the purpose of the study, the
measurement can be either in terms of overall prefer-
ence or intention to buy (likelihood of purchase). The
2 We expect, however, that future applications of conjoint analy-
sis, particularly in packaged goods (such as foods and beverages),
latter criterion is particularly suited to studies of new
will increasingly employ actual products, factorially composed using product classes and services that consumers do not
fractional designs from a set of physical/chemical attributes. purchase currently.

This content downloaded from 195.43.22.140 on Sat, 12 Jan 2019 13:08:34 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
112 THE JOURNAL OF CONSUMER RESEARCH

In comparing the metric with the nonmetric meas- as much as 25-30 percent without appreciable loss
urement scales, it should be noted that even though the in accuracy. While practical experience with the
dependent variable is nonmetric, the estimated param- method is still meager, it looks potentially promising
eters tend to satisfy close to interval-scaled proper- for applications amenable to this type of data collec-
ties, for typical values of n and T, the number of esti- tion procedure. However, the relative efficiency of the
mated parameters (Colberg 1978). The main advantage interactive paired-comparison methods vis-a-vis the
of the metric methods is the increased information con- rank-order procedure is still not known.
tent potentially present in these scales. However, One of the advantages of the rating-scale approach
based on results in nonmetric multidimensional scaling is that it can potentially be administered by mail. On
(Green and Carmone 1970, p. 36) we would expect the the other hand, the rank-ordering task usually entails
differential advantage of the metric scale to diminish a personal interview since the procedure requires a
as the nIT ratio becomes large. The nonmetric meth- considerable amount of explanation (such as first sort-
ods, on the other hand, have the following advantages: ing the cards into two or more piles, corresponding
to the more preferred versus the less preferred ones;
* Ranked data are likely to be more reliable, since it is
then sorting the cards in each pile from most preferred
easier for a respondent to say which he/she prefers
more as compared to expressing the magnitude of his/ to least preferred; and finally merging the different
her preference. piles of cards and checking the final rank order).
Another way of obtaining interval-scale judgments is
* Data analysis based on a nonmetric dependent vari-
the so-called "dollar metric" approach (Pessemier,
able allows the part-worth functions to be combined
Burger, Teach, and Tigert 1971). In this method, the
in either an additive or multiplicative manner. This is
respondent compares stimuli A and B and if he/she
because estimation of an additive model with a non-
metric dependent variable is also consistent with a prefers A to B, states how much the price of A has to
multiplicative model, since the logarithmic trans- increase until he/she will be indifferent between A and
formation is just one of the permissible monotone B. The results of such paired comparisons are aggre-
transformations of the dependent variable. gated to obtain an intervally scaled dollar metric of
preference. This is a very slow procedure compared to
1- With the two-factor-at-a-time approach the nonmetric
the rating method; furthermore, the results may be in-
method is more appropriate than the metric method.
The metric scale value for the dependent variable will fluenced by the social biases involved in using dollar
necessarily depend on the levels of the (t - 2) missing differences as a response measure.
factors, whereas the rank order of the cells in a trade- The constant-sum method of obtaining ratio-scaled
off table need not depend on the levels of the missing judgments in an interactive mode with a time-shared
factors, except if the attributes are correlated. terminal has been compared (Hauser and Shugan 1977)
to simply using the ordinal component of data obtained
The paired-comparison approach is the least effi- from paired comparisons. As might be expected, the
cient, in terms of information obtained per unit time, ratio-scaled data provided better predictive results
of all the methods. Its only advantages seem to be the than the paired comparisons per se. However, this
increased reliability of the averaged rank order and the comparison is misleading. For a given amount of re-
ability to test for intransitivities in the respondent's spondent's time, a very large number of paired com-
expressed preferences. All things considered, how- parisons can be obtained (e.g., by the use of rank order)
ever, we conjecture that the rank-order approach will as compared to the small number of constant-sum
fare better in terms of predictive validity than the directpaired comparisons. Consequently, for a given amount
paired-comparisons approach for a given amount of the of respondent's time, the relative desirability of the two
respondent's time. methods is still unclear.
In collecting data by means of paired comparisons, Given the conflicting considerations involved in the
one generally collects more data than needed. Recog- choice of a metric versus nonmetric dependent vari-
nizing the potential redundancy of paired-comparisons able, additional empirical studies are needed to com-
data, a number of researchers (Johnson 1976; Shugan pare these alternative methods.
and Hauser 1977) have proposed interactive computer
approaches for obtaining preference data. Johnson's
Estimation Methods
procedure, in particular, has been designed to obtain
conjoint analysis data from computer terminals placed Parameter estimation methods in conjoint analysis
in shopping malls and other high density locations. can be roughly classified into three categories:
This proprietary procedure, the technical details of
1. Methods which assume that the dependent variable
which are not available, is a sequential method in that is, at most, ordinally scaled. Methods in this class
it uses the results of earlier evaluations to select sub- are MONANOVA (Kruskal 1965), PREFMAP
sequent stimulus pairs, so that redundancy is kept to (Carroll 1972), Johnson's nonmetric tradeoff pro-
a minimum. Based on still early results, it appears that cedure (Johnson 1973; Nehls, Seaman, and Mont-
the number of paired comparisons may be reduced by gomery 1976), and LINMAP (Srinivasan and

This content downloaded from 195.43.22.140 on Sat, 12 Jan 2019 13:08:34 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
CONJOINT ANALYSIS IN CONSUMER RESEARCH 113

Shocker 1973a, 1973b; Pekelman and Sen 1974). For the important advantage of providing standard errors
a more exhaustive list of this class of algorithms, see for the estimated parameters. None of the procedures
Rao (1977). in (1) has this advantage. However, the overall statisti-
2. Methods which assume that the dependent variable cal significance of MONANOVA can be roughly as-
is intervally scaled. Methods in this class are ordinary certained using the computer simulation results ob-
least squares (OLS) regression (Johnston 1972, Chap. tained under the assumption of a random rank order
5), and minimizing sum of absolute errors (MSAE) for the dependent variable (Acito 1978). The MSAE
regression (Srinivasan and Shocker 1973a, pp. procedure, on the other hand, is more robust than the
358-60). OLS method (Blattberg and Sargent 1971) and, further-
3. Methods which relate paired-comparison data to a more, permits us to impose a priori constraints on the
choice probability model. Methods in this class are estimated parameters.
LOGIT (McFadden 1976; Ben-Akiva 1973; Gensch, The probabilistic approaches, (3), explicitly model
Golob, and Recker 1976; Green and Carmone 1977; the errors that may be present in the preference func-
Punj and Staelin 1978) and PROBIT (Goldberger tions, thereby leading to a deductive development of
1964, pp. 250-1; Rao and Winter 1977). the choice model. The LOGIT approach has the ad-
vantage that the estimation procedure produces global
In the class of algorithms designed for an ordinal- maximum likelihood estimates (McFadden 1976).
scaled dependent variable, MONANOVA is restricted However, the use of the LOGIT model involves the
to the part-worth function model (equation 4). The re- "independence of irrelevant alternatives" assumption,
maining approaches can be used for the vector or part- which may not be a realistic assumption in many con-
worth function models. For the ideal-point model, sumer behavior contexts. Briefly, if two substantially
LINMAP is best suited since the use of other ap- different services, say automobiles (A) and public tran-
proaches may lead to negative weights and resulting sit (B), have choice probabilities of 0.75 and 0.25, re-
interpretation difficulties (Srinivasan and Shocker spectively, and another mode of public transit (C), very
1973a, p. 338). The algorithms differ from each other similar to B, is introduced, then the LOGIT model
in their operational definitions of the poorness-of-fit leads to choice probabilities of 0.6, 0.2, and 0.2, respec-
index, analogous to (1 - R2) in multiple regression tively, for A, B, and C. Thus the total probability for
studies, and the optimization method used to determine public transit has risen which is intuitively unappealing.
parameter estimates to achieve the minimum poorness- Since the two transit modes, B and C, are very similar,
of-fit. While there is no a pripori way to choose betweenthe introduction of C should draw its ch6ice probability
the different poorness-of-fit definitions, empirical pre- largely from B rather than A.
dictive validity tests could guide us in this direction. The PROBIT procedure is particularly suited to
LINMAP differs from the others in that it uses linear cases where a dichotomous intention-to-buy scale is
programming as compared to classical calculus meth- used as the dependent variable (Rao and Winter 1977).
ods employed by the other approaches. The use of The estimation procedure, however, cannot guarantee
linear programming enables LINMAP to obtain global global maximum likelihood estimates.
optimum parameter estimates, while the other ap- The probabilistic choice models such as LOGIT and
proaches cannot be guaranteed to achieve global PROBIT assume that the paired comparisons are
optimums. In LINMAP, attribute weights can be con- probabilistically independent. If the dependent vari-
strained to be nonnegative, part-worth functions can be able data are obtained directly as paired comparisons,
constrained to be monotone or of the ideal-point type, this may be a realistic assumption. (However, we have
while such constraints cannot be imposed for the other argued earlier that this is an inefficient way of collect-
approaches. Such constraints, as imposed on the basis ing data.) If the data are obtained as a rank order and
of prior knowledge, can be useful in improving the then converted to the equivalent n(n - 1)/2 paired
accuracy of the parameter estimates when the (nIT) comparisons, this assumption is not realistic.3 The
ratio is small-assuming, of course, that the prior asymptotic estimates of standard errors are not likely
knowledge is correct. Finally, the usage of sum-of- to be valid either. (In any event, the limited number of
absolute-errors as the poorness-of-fit measure, rather stimuli usually used in consumer research studies casts
than the sum-of-squared-errors, tends to produce more doubt on the appropriateness of such asymptotic sta-
robust estimates, i.e., the estimated parameters are not
tistics.) Despite these, limitations, however, the
as much affected by outliers or large errors in the input probabilistic choice models appear to have substantial
data (Blattberg and Sargent 1971). On the other hand, predictive validity.
when the nIT ratio is small, the use of linear program- The choice between the nonmetric, (1) and (3), and
ming sometimes produces alternate optimums (i.e., metric methods, (2), should logically depend on the
different sets of estimated parameters have the same
minimal poorness-of-fit), which is intuitively
unappealing. I However, Punj and Staelin (1978) utilize a procedure based only
Among the-metric methods, the OLS procedure has on the n - 1 independent choices that mitigates this problem.

This content downloaded from 195.43.22.140 on Sat, 12 Jan 2019 13:08:34 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
114 THE JOURNAL OF CONSUMER RESEARCH

scale properties of the dependent variable. The simula- procedures (2) seem to perform slightly better if the
tion studies by Cattin and Wittink (1976) and Carmone, preference model is approximately compensatory. If
Green, and Jain (1978) have found that the OLS regres- the model is approximately lexicographic, the non-
sion applied to integer ranks (the rank ordered depend- metric methods seem to do slightly better. Based on
ent variable is redefined as a pseudo-interval-scaled these results, we would recommend that researchers
variable, taking values 1, 2, . . , n depending on the estimate parameters using both a metric and a non-
rank given that stimulus) produces solutions that are metric method as a rough check on the robustness of
very close, in terms of predictive validity, to those their results, at least until more empirical evidence on
obtained by the more expensive nonmetric algorithms. their correspondence has been assembled.
However, by employing integer ranks as the dependent
variable, the usual standard errors and statistical tests RELIABILITY AND VALIDITY TESTS
are not strictly valid.
Cattin and Wittink (1976) report that the results from While some researchers have been careful to test
OLS and MONANOVA are virtually indistinguish- the reliability and/or validity of conjoint analysis, a
able: the difference in predictive validity is, at most, large number of applications of conjoint analysis have
0.003 in terms of Pearson's rho. In other words, be- ignored these issues. We will now discuss methods for
cause of local optimum problems with MONANOVA, assessing reliability and validity with the hope that
it may produce solutions which are only marginally future applications will incorporate at least some of
different from OLS. The difference between OLS on these tests.4
the one hand and LOGIT and LINMAP on the other is
about 0.03 units in terms of Pearson's rho, with OLS Tests of Reliability
being the better approach when the attribute weights
Tests of reliability can be carried out either at the
are normally distributed (compensatory model) and
level of input judgments of the respondent or at the
LINMAP and LOGIT being the preferred methods
level of estimated parameters. To obtain the reliability
when the attribute weights exhibit a lexicographic
of a respondent's input judgments, the researcher can
structure. In general, this simulation study found that
ask for preference judgments on a second set of stim-
the methods differed by only very small amounts in
ulus cards which contain a subset of the original set of
their predictive validities.
stimulus cards. This needs to be done only for a sub-
A few empirical (as opposed to simulation) studies
sample of the respondents after the respondent has
have compared alternative estimation procedures.
completed some intervening task, such as supplying a
Hauser and Urban (1977, p. 600) report that the mono-
set of demographic data. The repeated evaluations can
tonic methods have a slightly better fit to saved data
be used in determining the test-retest reliability of the
than OLS. (The dependent variable was a rank order.)
input preference judgments.
Hauser and Shugan (1977) state that the MSAE regres-
If we view conjoint analysis as an instrument to
sion performs better than OLS because of its ability to
measure the parameters of the preference model, then
incorporate constraints on the estimated parameters.
the alternate forms method with spaced testing may be
(The dependent variable in this case was intervally
more appropriate (Parker and Srinivasan 1976). After
scaled.) Montgomery, Wittink, and Glaze (1977) report
completing a conjoint analysis task, a subset of the
that the predictive validity of OLS was better than that
respondents can be approached after a period of time
of MONANOVA. The dependent variable was a rank
and asked to perform the rank ordering or rating task
order but the small nIT = 32/19 ratio is likely to have
on a second set of stimuli. The second stimulus set
biased this result in favor of OLS. Fidler and Thomp-
("alternate form") would also have n descriptions from
son (1977) report that LINMAP and a PROBIT-like
the same factor levels as the first set but would avoid
procedure yielded roughly the same validity and sub-
duplication of stimuli from the initial set. This could be
stantive conclusions. McCullough (1978) reports that
done by using a second fractional-factorial design from
Johnson's nonmetric procedure and MONANOVA
the same factor levels or by randomly drawing a second
predict at roughly the same level of validity and better
set of n descriptions from the multivariate distribution.
than a Fishbein-Rosenberg type multiattribute model.
Product moment correlations of the estimated param-
Rao and Solgaard (1977) report that MONANOVA,
eters from the two tasks provides a measure of reli-
Johnson's nonmetric procedure, LINMAP, and CCM
ability, sometimes referred to as the coefficient of
(Carroll 1969) yield roughly the same level of cross
equivalence.
validity. Jain et al. (1978) report that MONANOVA,
The second method of reliability testing is more
Johnson's nonmetric procedure, LINMAP, LOGIT,
rigorous than the first one, in that it takes into account
and OLS yield roughly the same level of cross-validity,
with LOGIT and LINMAP being the slightly preferred
procedures. 4 Our discussion emphasizes predictive validity rather than valida-
Overall, the estimation methods do not seem to dif- tion of the actual decision process which, in large measure, is
fer very much in their predictive validities. The metric not known.

This content downloaded from 195.43.22.140 on Sat, 12 Jan 2019 13:08:34 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
CONJOINT ANALYSIS IN CONSUMER RESEARCH 115

four sources of error: inaccuracies in the input data, can only be expected to predict responses in "steady
variability in the set of constructed stimuli, errors in state," assuming that consumers become knowledge-
the estimation procedure, and lack of stability (varia- able about the new stimulus.
tions from one time period to another). By contrast,
the first method focuses only on the first source of Additional Considerations in Reliability/
error.
Validity Testing
If paired comparison preference judgments are ob-
Tests of Validity
tained directly, one can also test for intransitivities.
The internal validity of conjoint analysis can be re- Hauser and Shugan (1977) have developed measures
ported in terms of the correlation (Pearson's or Spear- of intransitivity for interval and ratio-scaled prefer-
man's rho depending on the scale properties of the de- ence data obtained through constant-sum paired com-
pendent variable) between the input versus estimated parisons. In addition, consistency can be tested at the
values of the dependent variable. If Pearson's rho is aggregate level in terms of market shares. For example,
used, it is desirable to adjust the correlation for the in a conjoint analysis study designed by one of the
number of estimated parameters, as in the coefficient authors for a large transportation company, data were
of multiple determination (R2) adjusted for degrees of available on market share, by supplier, for various pairs
freedom. of cities served by the company. Shares of choices,
Data used for the reliability tests also provide a estimated at the individual level and then aggregated,
method of cross-validation. The parameters of the agreed closely enough with the actual market share
preference function estimated from the first set of data to provide reasonable assurance of the model's
preference data can be used to predict the preferences validity in the aggregate. Similar tests have been carried
for the second set. The predicted preferences can be out by Fiedler (1972), Davidson (1973), and Punj and
correlated to the actual to obtain a measure of cross- Staelin (1978).
validity. The procedure can then be reversed by pre- Scott and Wright (1976) suggest some additional
dicting from set 2 to set 1, thus completing a double consistency checks to test whether the estimated param-
cross-validation. eters make sense. First, the signs of the estimated
While internal validity tests the goodness of the parameters should agree with a priori expectations,
model, cross-validation also takes into account the based on prior theory or reasoning. Second, the param-
predictive ability of the model. But neither method tests eters derived for different subpopulations should
the external validity of the niodel. Since conjoint analy- differ in the direction that would be expected from prior
sis studies are usually carried out using hypothetical theory or reasoning. In addition, the "face validity"
stimulus descriptions, we can test for external validity of the results can be checked by comparing a respond-
by comparing predictions against a respondent's actual ent's subjective estimates (self-reports) with estimated
behavior with respect to real stimuli. This method, parameters. A somewhat unobtrusive method of test-
referred to as predictive validity by Parker and ing for face validity is to aggregate respondents' spon-
Srinivasan (1976, p. 1,017), involved predicting the taneous verbalizations during the interview regarding
respondent's rank order of the n real stimuli (choice the factors or attributes important to them and compar-
set) using the estimated preference function. The re- ing them against aggregated results from estimated
spondent's actual choices will fall somewhere in this model parameters (Parker and Srinivasan 1976, p.
rank order (I to n). The closer the number is to 1, the 1,013).
better is the external validity for that respondent. By To get some feel for the cost/benefit of conjoint
repeating the predictions for each of the respondents in analysis, its predictions can be compared against
the sample, we obtain a frequency distribution of the "naive" models which do not involve any data collec-
number of respondents choosing the first, second, tion. For instance, if the vector model of preference
. . ., nth most preferred stimuli. The median of the is a reasonable approximation and the attributes are
distribution can be compared to 1 (best) and (n + 1)/2 reoriented, if necessary, so that higher attribute levels
(random model) to get a measure of the external valid- are more preferred, and the attributes are standardized
ity. The obtained frequency distribution (which should to unit standard deviation, then a unit weighting model
be skewed positively) can be tested for statistical (i.e., each weight wp in equation (2) is set equal to unity)
significance against a uniform distribution (random is often a good contender for a naive model (Dawes and
model) by the Kolmogorov-Smirnov statistic. Corrigan 1974). Alternately, the most important at-
One of the important uses of conjoint analysis is to tribute from a priori considerations (e.g., price) can be
predict the behavior of the respondents toward new used to define a naive preference model in which the
stimuli. The most rigorous tests for conjoint analysis weight for the most important attribute is unity, while
predict the reaction of a respondent toward a new stim- all other attributes are assigned zero weights. An exten-
ulus and compare it with actual behavior. However, sion of this would be a lexicographic naive model with
since conjoint analysis is, at best, a static analysis, it the ordering of attributes obtained from prior judg-

This content downloaded from 195.43.22.140 on Sat, 12 Jan 2019 13:08:34 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
116 THE JOURNAL OF CONSUMER RESEARCH

ments.5 For an illustration of these tests against more and Cavadias (1974), Wind and Spitz (1976), and
naive models, see Parker and Srinivasan (1976, pp. Hopkins, Larreche, and Massy (1977).
1,015- 17). Parker and Srinivasan (1976) address the problem of
Published empirical results on the predictive validity determining the number, locations, and physical and
of conjoint analysis are encouraging (e.g., Fiedler 1972, operational characteristics of a set of health care fa-
condominiums; Davidson 1973, air transportation; cilities to be added to an existing health care delivery
Parker and Srinivasan 1976, primary health care facili- system so as to maximize the incremental benefit to the
ties; Montgomery, Wittink, and Glaze 1977, job choice community, subject to a cost (budget) constraint. The
by MBAs; Scott 1977, solar heating for homes). conjoint analysis study used the mixed model of equa-
Furthermore, the reliability and cross validity reported tion (7) with travel time (hours) to the facility as one of
by Parker and Srinivasan (1976) are high. The only the attributes. Each respondent's estimated preference
reported study we know of which showed extremely function was then transformed into a benefit function
poor predlctions is that by Bither and Wright (1977) expressing the individual's benefit in dollars/year for
in the context of selection of a set of movies dealing an existing or potential health care facility. Briefly,
with golfing demonstrations. this involved multiplying each of the estimated weights
{Vq} in equation (7) by a common positive number,
chosen so that the transformed weight for the travel
APPLICATIONS OF CONJOINT ANALYSIS time attribute coincides with the annual dollar cost for
the respondent's household to travel to a health facility
The typical output from conjoint analysis is a set of
that is one hour away.
estimated parameters of the preference model for each
For example, suppose there are currently only three
individual in the sample. A direct use of these results
facilities in the area with benefits for individual i of $50!
is to describe the degree to which each of the attributes
is considered important by the respondent sample. If
year, $200/year, and $150/year. Then assuming that
individual i chooses the most preferred facility, his/her
the vector model of equation (2) or ideal-point model
benefit from the existing system is $200/year, cor-
of equation (3) is used, the weights {wi,j for individualresponding to his/her choosing Facility 2. If we now add
i are first standardized by multiplying wi,, by the stand-
a fourth facility whose benefit for this individual is $275/
ard deviation sp for attribute p -similar to the deter-
year, then his/her incremental benefit is $75/year (i.e.,
mination of standardized regression weights (beta
he/she would, in "steady state," choose Facility 4 so
weights) in multiple regression-and then normalized
that the new benefit is $275/year). If, howeVer, Facility
so that the attribute importances sum to unity. If the
4's benefit was only $175/year then the incremental
part-worth function model of equation (4) is used, the
benefit for this individual is zero-he/she would stay
range of the values for the part-worth function over the
with Facility 2 so that his/her benefit has not changed.
levels of attribute p serves as a measure of importance
The total incremental benefit for adding Facility 4 to the
for attributep . Again, the ranges are normalized so that
community can be obtained by aggregating the indi-
the t attribute importances sum to unity. The resulting
vidual incremental benefits, after differentially weight-
distributions (over the respondent sample) of im-
ing different socioeconomic segments of the popula-
portances may be summarized in terms of the means
tion, and then multiplying by the population/sample
and standard deviations for each of the t attributes. If
size ratio. Some optimization procedure can then be
the ideal-point model of equation (3) is used, the dis-
used to determine a set of additional facilities that
tribution of ideal points can be plotted for each of the
would be feasible (i.e., total cost stays within the bud-
attributes.
get) and would maximize the total incremental benefit
In addition to this "descriptive" use of conjoint
to the community.
analysis, its "normative" uses are described next for
In an ongoing study by one of the authors, poten-
both public and private sector applications.
tial energy policies (such as gasoline surcharges, transit
subsidies) are being evaluated in terms of their impact
Public Sector Applications on gasoline conservation. By developing a conjoint
analysis model with mode of travel (car versus carpool
Conjoint analysis offers a tremendous potential for versus public transit), time of travel, gasoline price, etc.
conducting cost/benefit analysis for many public policy as attributes, it is possible to predict whether changes
decisions. We discuss this here in the contexts of plan- in attributes, such as gasoline cost increased by a gas
ning rural primary health care delivery and evaluating tax or waiting time decreased by transit improvements,
the implications of energy policies for work-trip gas- would change the modal choice of the respondent, and
oline conservation. For additional applications in the if so, what the resulting gasoline conservation would
public sector area, see McClain and Rao (1974), Whit- be. The social costs of such policies can also be evalu-
ated by a procedure similar to that in the health care
5 For an illustration of these tests against naive models, see Parker study.
and Srinivasan (1976, pp. 1015-17). In short, conjoint analysis offers an excellent oppor-

This content downloaded from 195.43.22.140 on Sat, 12 Jan 2019 13:08:34 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
CONJOINT ANALYSIS IN CONSUMER RESEARCH 117

tunity for consumer researchers to provide valuable evaluation of new product or service concepts. If aug-
cost/benefit analysis inputs for public policy decisions. mented by cost data, this approach can also be ex-
tended to determine "optimal" new product/service
Private Sector Applications ideas by searching the product space, taking into ac-
count existing brands/services in the market place and
While no precise figures are available, it is estimated the possible effect of the cannibalization of one's own
that several hundred conjoint analysis studies have brands by the new entry. Shocker and Srinivasan
been conducted by corporate marketing research (1977b) have reviewed such approaches and their ap-
groups and consulting firms. The applications have plications to product concept evaluation and
spanned a wide variety of products/services: consumer generation.
nondurables and durables, industrial goods, financial Another important use of conjoint analysis is in the
and other services, transportation, etc. context of guiding strategies for market communica-
In most private sector applications of conjoint analy- tion. For instance, an analysis of the attribute impor-
sis, some type of consumer choice simulation is carried tances and the relative position of the firm's brand vis-
out to see what share of choices would be generated a-vis the firm's competitors can help in the develop-
by each of several product/service profiles if they were ment of suitable advertising strategies (Boyd, Ray, and
competing with each other in the market place. (The Strong 1972).
word "simulation" is used here to mean prediction of Conjoint analysis is also useful in market segmenta-
individual choices under hypothetical scenarios and tion. The idea is to divide a heterogenous population
subsequent aggregation of choices -it does not neces- of consumers into more homogenous segments so that
sarily mean Monte-Carlo probabilistic simulation.) different marketing strategies can be tailored to differ-
The typical consumer choice simulator is quite ent segments of consumers to achieve maximum mar-
simple in construction. Each individual's utility func- keting results. Cluster analysis can be employed to
tion and background description (current purchase group respondents with similar "importances," for t
behavior, socioeconomic, demographic, and psycho- attributes, into clusters. The clusters, in turn, can be
graphic characteristics) are entered into the simulator. cross-tabulated against various background variables,
Each of, say, six competitive products or services is such as demographics, psychographics, product and
entered as a full-profile description. Then, for each media usage. Alternatively, the "importances" can be
individual, in turn, a utility is computed for each of the employed as a set of predictor variables in a multiple
competing items. The individual is assumed to choose discriminant analysis in which subjects have been
that item displaying the highest utility to him. Elabora- previously classified into groups on the basis of some
tions on this theme incorporate various probability- other criterion, such as brand choice or product-class
of-choice rules, based on the utilities of all contending consumption levels.
items. (See Shocker and Srinivasan 1977b for a detailed For such market segmentation studies, one could
discussion.) The first-choice frequencies for each also use the predicted, or input, preferences for the n
item are then simply added and expressed relatively. stimuli as the segmentation variables instead of "im-
Many variations on this simple procedure have been portances." However, we have found that in many
used in proprietary studies. For example, one may wish applications it is the importances rather than the pref-
to employ the respondents' background data to obtain erences which are more discriminating. The reason
consumer segments; shares of choices are then cross- for this is that within a specific attribute, e.g., tread life
classified by these prior-defined segments. If profile or price, there is often high agreement on at least the
data on current market brands are also available, it is ordering of levels, e.g., more tread life is preferred to
a simple matter to examine brand switching behavior less. However, the importance of the factor, tread life,
as new items are entered into the existing array, either i.e., the relative part-worth range, is often more sensi-
as replacements for current items or as net additions to tive to individual variation.
the product/service set.
More sophisticated choice simulators can also be
constructed with additional features, such as:
NEW DEVELOPMENTS

* a provision for describing new item profiles in terms of In the relatively short time that conjoint analysis
probability distributions over factor levels, rather has been in use, a number of new developments have
than as a deterministic level for each factor; already appeared. Some of these are briefly described
here.
* a provision for simulating trial and repeat purchase,
conditioned on assumptions about the relative
amounts of sales effort and consumer satisfaction-in- Preference Models for Collections of Items
use associated with each item.
Most of the conjoint methodologies and their applica-
Not surprisingly, one of the more important uses tions have been in the context of choosing a single
of conjoint analysis in the private sector has been in the item from a product (service) class. However, Green,

This content downloaded from 195.43.22.140 on Sat, 12 Jan 2019 13:08:34 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
118 THE JOURNAL OF CONSUMER RESEARCH

Wind, and Jain (1972) have examined whether the total Multi-Stage Consumer Decision Processes
preference for, say, an entree-dessert combination can
be decomposed, via an additive model, into the pref- Srinivasan (1978) observes that protocol analyses of
erence for an entree plus the preference for a dessert. consumer decision processes indicate that for many
Green and Devita (1974, 1975a) discuss a method of respondents the processing strategy seems to change
taking into account two-factor interaction effects in the during the task, starting from an initial strategy aimed
context of menu choice through MDPREF (Carroll at narrowing the choice to a small subset (through proc-
1972). Farquhar and Rao (1976)-see also Rao (1973) esses approximating conjunctive type rules) and ending
-consider the choice of subsets such as TV programs, in a detailed examination to choose the most
liquor assortments, etc., by their "balance model." preferred item through processes approximating com-
They model the utility for a set of n stimuli as com- pensatory rules. He models a multi-stage decision proc-
posed of (i) preference components relating to total ess as a sequence of linear models of the form of equa-
attribute'level (over the n stimuli) on each of the t at- tion (7), where the weights change from one stage to the
tributes and (ii) preference components relating to the next (several of the weights in each stage may be zero).
standard deviation of attribute levels (within the n In an m-stage model, the ith stage preference function
stimuli) for each of the t attributes. The latter terms (i = 1,2, . . . , m) discriminates only among stimuli
correspond to the preference for "balance" or which are tied by each of the previous stages 1,2,
''counterbalance," depending on whether variability is i - 1. Assuming that each attribute has only a small
desirable or undesirable. number of levels, this model includes the compensatory
McAlister (1978) considers the same problem of (m = 1), lexicographic (each stage has only one weight
choice of subsets but models the overall preference positive with all other weights equal to zero), conjunc-
for a set of magazines (say) using a part-worth function tive and disjunctive rules, and any combination
thereof as special cases. Srinivasan provides a pro-
approach, where the argument in the part-worth func-
tion for attribute p is its total attribute level over the cedure to estimate the stage weights from rank-order
subset of magazines. By assuming that the part-worth preference judgments using LINMAP (Shocker and
function is approximated by linear and quadratic terms Srinivasan 1977a). The multi-stage model seems to
offer the potential of taking us one step closer to actual
(to model attribute satiation), she is able to use
consumer decision processes.
LINMAP to estimate the parameters. McAlister
(1978) also examines a second context of choice of sub-
sets where the consumption is limited to only one of Componential Segmentation
the elements in the subset (e.g., a student may apply
to several universities but enrolls in only one of the As remarked earlier in the context of private sector
schools which offer admission). She models this con- applications, one of the uses of conjoint analysis has
text by embedding preferences for individual items in been in the development of market segments. A recent
a decision tree. development, known as componential segmentation
(Green 1977; Green, Carroll, and Carmone 1976, 1977;
Green and DeSarbo 1977), takes a further step in this
Incorporating Interaction Effects in direction. Traditionally, market segments have been
defined as groups of consumers whose responses to
Preference Models
some market stimulus exhibit relatively little within-
Green, Carroll, and Carmone (1978) have developed group variation but considerable among-groups varia-
an algorithm that incorporates selected interaction tion. In contrast, componential segmentation places
terms after main effect terms have been estimated. emphasis on the interaction of a stimulus profile with
This algorithm appears to be most useful in cases in- a person profile; that is, the concern here is less with
volving a large number of factors, thus precluding the market partitioning and more with predicting how a
use of full factorial designs. respondent, characterized by a particular set of at-
The authors use various kinds of fractional factorials tribute levels, will respond to a set of stimuli, each of
that permit the researcher to estimate all main effects which represents a particular profile of factor levels. It
at the individual level and selected two-factor inter- is the joint effect of the two sets of attribute and factor
actions at the group (or subgroup) level, without neces- levels that results in response.
sitating an unwieldy number of stimuli for respondent As an illustration, consider the earlier example in
evaluation. The assumption is that the researcher will which consumers are choosing among alternative steel-
be primarily interested in interaction effects at the belted replacement tires, varying by brand, tread life,
group (rather than individual) level. Under this assump- price, and sidewall color. Illustratively, the consumers
tion, the algorithm is able to take advantage of the addi- are assumed to vary by sex, type of car ownership, and
tional degrees of freedom gained by pooling over age of car owned. Traditional segmentation procedures
groups of respondents. might first group the consumers by type of tire owned

This content downloaded from 195.43.22.140 on Sat, 12 Jan 2019 13:08:34 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
CONJOINT ANALYSIS IN CONSUMER RESEARCH 119

and then see (e.g., by means of discriminant analysis) like, or allocations of magazine space to various kinds
whether the a priori defined segments differ in terms of of editorial matter and advertisements.
other consumer background variables. In contrast,
componential segmentation decomposes total vari- Conjoint Analysis in the Modeling of
ability in preferences for alternative product descrip-
Perceptions Data
tions (each involving a profile of brand, tread life, price,
and sidewall color) by alternative respondents (each Until recently conjoint analysis has been restricted
involving a profile of sex, type of car, and age of car) to the analysis of preference (and other kinds of
into three components: (i) variability due to product dominance) data. If the analyst wished to explore con-
attributes, (ii) variability due to person attributes and sumers' perceptions of products or services, he/she
(iii) variability due to interaction between person and usually fell back on the apparatus of multidimensional
product attributes. The first component, in a sense, scaling, with its associated problems of dimension
explains the variation in preference for different levels interpretation and the like.
of product attributes for the average respondent and More recently, conjoint analysis has been extended
should be of interest in product planning. The second to the modeling of similarities data (Green and
component is usually not of interest, since it is simply DeSarbo 1978). To illustrate the approach, assume that
due to different respondent profiles having a different a researcher is interested in consumers' perceptions of
mean scale value for preferences. (Thus, if the data various vacation sites, e.g., London, Bermuda, Las
were standardized so that each respondent gave the Vegas, Honolulu, etc. A set of six factors (say) are
same average preference rating for the n profiles, this selected that are capable of describing vacation sites
component would be zero.) The third component is due in general, such as (i) food quality, (ii) sightseeing
to interaction effects between stimulus and respondent opportunities, (iii) outdoor sports, (iv) night life/enter-
profiles and, therefore, provides a direct measure of tainment, (v) chance to meet new friends, and (vi)
segmentability of the market. It may show, for in- trip cost. Next assume that each factor is described
stance, that compact car owners attach more impor- in terms of three levels (e.g., superb, good, or fair food
tance to tire price than owners of medium and big cars. quality). An orthogonal main effects plan of 18 stimulus
This could suggest that a firm has to be considerably cards can be constructed from the 36 full factorial. The
more price competitive in the compact car segment, but respondent is then shown a card on which each refer-
could use a product differentiated, high-price strategy ence site, such as London, appears and is asked to sort
for the medium and big car segment. the profiles along, say, a 9-point scale according to how
Extensions of componential segmentation to three- similar each of the profiles is to each selected location
way (respondents by scenarios by products) and (e.g., London). The similarities data are analyzed for
higher-way matrices are also possible, thus providing each site separately via some type of nonmetric or
a means for operationalizing the concept of situation metric conjoint algorithm. However, in this situation
dependence (Belk 1975) as it may interact with the the analysis produces part-similarity functions (analo-
stimulus attributes under evaluation by different types gous to part-worth functions) and factor saliences (rela-
of respondents. tive ranges of the part-similarity functions).
The results from such an analysis can be pooled over
Preferences for Alternative Allocations of those who chose London (based on an earlier ques-
tion) as the most preferred place to visit versus those
Scarce Resources
who chose some other vacation site. Green and De-
Recently conjoint analysis has been applied to study Sarbo (1978) found, for instance, that London
consumers' preferences for alternative allocations of choosers attached higher salience to sightseeing, while
some scarce resource, such as money or time. One others attached higher salience to outdoor sports and
pilot study (Carroll, Green, and DeSarbo 1978) con- total trip cost.
sidered preferences for alternative allocations of leisure Although not described here, the part-similarity
time for different levels of (i) watching TV, (ii) recrea- functions can, in turn, be transformed into respond-
tional reading, (iii) sports activity, (iv) hobbies, and (v) ents' subjective probability distributions relating to the
socializing. The same type of approach can also be used uncertainty of perceptions of London along each of the
to find consumer utilities for such things as alternative factors. This information together with the respond-
household budget allocations, or allocations of house- ent's preference function (as developed from a con-
hold savings across such investments as insurance, joint analysis of the respondent's preference data)
common stocks, municipal bonds, etc. If time (rather could be valuable in developing communication
than money) is the scarce resource, possible applica- campaigns to correct misperceptions and attract more
tions can involve such things as preferences for TV visitors to London. The implications of this extended
news shows regarding the amount of time spent on conjoint methodology should be of considerable inter-
national news, local news, weather, sports, and the est in positioning products and services.

This content downloaded from 195.43.22.140 on Sat, 12 Jan 2019 13:08:34 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
120 THE JOURNAL OF CONSUMER RESEARCH

CONCLUDING REMARKS College Selection," in Cognition and Social Behavior,


eds. J. S. Carroll and J. W. Payne, Hillsdale, NJ:
The wide support by academic and industry re- Lawrence Elbaum Associates, 203-19.
searchers over a relatively short time (since 1971) is an Bither, Stewart W., and Wright, Peter (1977), "Preferences
indication of the potential of conjoint analysis in pro- Between Product Consultants: Choices vs. Prefer-
viding a useful methodology for representing the ence," The Journal of Consumer Research, 4, 39-47.
structure of consumer preferences and some ability for Blattberg, Robert, and Sargent, Thomas (1971), "Regression
with Non-Gaussian Stable Disturbances: Some
predicting consumers' behavior towards new stimuli.
Sampling Results," Econometrica, 39, 501-10.
Much empirical work needs to be done to identify the
Boyd, Harper W., Jr., Ray, Michael L., and Strong, Edward
combination of alternatives in each of the various steps
C. (1972), "An Attitudinal Framework for Advertising
of conjoint analysis to achieve maximum predictive Strategy," Journal of Marketing, 36, 27-33.
validity for a given problem definition and research Braun, Michael A., and Srinivasan, V. (1975), "Amount of
budget. The answers could, of course, depend on situa- Information as a Determinant of Consumer Behavior
tional factors such as type of product-market, number Towards New Products," 1975 Combined Proceedings,
of relevant attributes, etc. Researchers are urged to pay Chicago: American Marketing Association, 373-8.
considerably greater attention to testing reliability and Carmone, Frank J., Green, Paul E., and Jain, Arun K.
validity in their applications. Although conjoint analy- (1978), "The Robustness of Conjoint Analysis: Some
Monte Carlo Results," Journal of Marketing Research,
sis has been extensively applied mainly in the private
15, 300-3.
sector, it has a large potential for public sector applica-
Carroll, J. Douglas (1969), "Categorical Conjoint Measure-
tions as well. As the last section of the paper indicated,
ment," Meeting of Mathematical Psychology, Ann
conjoint analysis is far from being a settled, cut-and- Arbor, MI.
dried methodology. Many opportunities still exist for (1972), "Individual Differences and Multidimensional
extending present techniques and applying them to a Scaling," in Multidimensional Scaling: Theory and
greater variety of substantive problems in consumer Applications in Behavioral Sciences, Vol. I, eds. R. N.
behavior. Shepard, et al., New York: Seminar Press, 105-55.
, Green, Paul E., and DeSarbo, Wayne S. (1978),
"Optimizing the Allocation of a Fixed Resource: A
[Received August 1977. Revised March 1978.]
Simple Model and Its Experimental Test," Working
Paper, Bell Laboratories, Murray Hill, NJ.
Cattin, Philippe, and Wittink, Dick R. (1976), "A Monte-
REFERENCES Carlo Study of Metric and Nonmetric EsAtimation Meth-
ods for Multiattribute Models," Research Paper No.
Acito, Franklin (1977), "An Investigation of Some Data 341, Graduate School of Business, Stanford University.
Collection Issues in Conjoint Measurement," in 1977 Colberg, Roger T. (1978), "A Monte Carlo Evaluation of
Educators' Proceedings, Chicago: American Marketing Metric Recovery of Conjoint Measurement Algo-
Association, 82-5. rithms," Research Paper, College of Business Admin-
(1978), "A Monte Carlo Investigation of Conjoint istration, University of Nevada-Reno.
Measurement Under Random Data Conditions for Darlington, Richard B. (1968), "Multiple Regression in
Various Orthogonal Designs," Working Paper, School Psychological Research and Practice," Psychological
of Business, Indiana University. Bulletin, 69, 161-82.
Alpert, Mark I. (1971), "Definition of Determinant At- Davidson, J. D. (1973), "Forecasting Traffic on STOL,"
tributes: A Comparison of Methods," Journal of Market- Operational Research Quarterly, 24, 561-9.
ing Research, 8, 184-91. Dawes, Robyn M. (1971), "A Case Study of Graduate
Betak, John F., and Golden, Linda, L. (1978), "Data Admissions: Application of Three Principles of
Gathering Issues in Conjoint Measurement," Working Human Decision Making," American Psychologist,
Paper, Graduate School of Business, The University of 26, 180-8.
Texas at Austin. , and Corrigan, Bernard (1974), "Linear Models in
Anderson, Norman H. (1970), "Functional Measurement Decision Making," Psychological Bulletin, 81, 95-106.
and Psychophysical Judgment," Psychological Review, Farquhar, Peter H., and Rao, Vithala, R. (1976), "A Balance
77, 153-70. Model for Evaluating Subsets of Multiattributed Items,"
Barron, F. Hutton (1977), "Axiomatic Conjoint Measure- Management Science, 22, 528-39.
ment," Decision Sciences, 8, 48-59. Fidler, Eduard, J., and Thompson, Gerald L. (1977), "An
Belk, Russell W. (1975), "Situational Variables and Con- Experiment on Executive Decision Making," Manage-
sumer Behavior," The Journal of Consumer Research, ment Science Research Report No. 407, Graduate
2, 157-64. School of Industrial Administration, Carnegie-Mellon
Ben-Akiva, Moshe (1973), "Program for Maximum Likeli- University.
hood Estimation of the Multinomial Logit Model," Fiedler, John A. (1972), "Condominium Design and Pricing:
Cambridge, MA: Massachusetts Institute of Tech- A Case Study in Consumer Trade-off Analysis," in
nology, Department of Civil Engineering. Proceedings (Third Annual Conference), ed. M.
Berl, Janet, Lewis, Gordon, and Morrison, Rebecca Sue Venkatesan, Chicago: Association for Consumer Re-
(1976), "Applying Models of Choice to the Problem of search, 279-93.

This content downloaded from 195.43.22.140 on Sat, 12 Jan 2019 13:08:34 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
CONJOINT ANALYSIS IN CONSUMER RESEARCH 121

Fishbein, Martin (1967), "A Behavior Theory Approach to , and Rao, Vithala R. (1971), "Conjoint Measure-
the Relations between Beliefs about an Object and the ment for Quantifying Judgmental Data," Journal of
Attitude towards the Object," in Readings in Attitude Marketing Research, 8, 355-63.
and Theory Measurement, ed. M. Fishbein, New York: , and Tull, Donald S. (1978), Research for Marketing
John Wiley & Sons, Inc., 389-99. Decisions (4th Edition), Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-
Gensch, Dennis H., Golob, Thomas F., and Recker, Wilfred Hall, Inc.
W. (1976), "Regression is Inappropriate for Analyzing and Wind, Yoram (1973), Multiattribute Decisions
Cross-Sectional Data," in 1976 Educators' Proceed- in Marketing: A Measurement Approach, Hinsdale,
ings, Chicago: American Marketing Association, 120-4. IL: The Dryden Press.
Goldberg, Lewis R. (1968), "Simple Models or Simple Proc- , and Wind, Yoram (1975), "New Way to Measure
esses? Some Research on Clinical Judgments," American Consumers' Judgments," Harvard Business Review, 53,
Psychologist, 23, 483-96. 107-17.
Goldberger, Arthur S. (1964), Econometric Theory, New , Wind, Yoram, and Jain, Arun K. (1972), "Prefer-
York: John Wiley & Sons, Inc. ence Measurement of Item Collections," Journal of
Green, Paul E. (1974), "On the Design of Choice Experi- Marketing Research, 9, 371-7.
ments Involving Multifactor Alternatives," The Journal Hansen, Fleming (1976), "Psychological Theories of Con-
of Consumer Research, 1, 61-8. sumer Choice," The Journal of Consumer Research,
(1975), "Marketing Applications of MDS: Assess- 3, 117-42.
ment and Outlook," Journal of Marketing, 39, 24-31. Hauser, John R., and Shugan, Steven M. (1977), "Efficient
(1977), "A New Approach to Market Segmentation," Measurement of Consumer Preference Functions: A
Business Horizons, 20, 61-73. General Theory for Intensity of Preference," Working
, and Carmone, Frank J. (1970), Multidimensional Paper 602-001, Graduate School of Management, North-
Scaling and Related Techniques in Marketing Analysis, western University.
Boston: Allyn and Bacon. , and Urban, Glen L. (1977), "A Normative
, and Carmone, Frank J. (1977), "A BIB/Logit Ap- Methodology for Modeling Consumer Response to In-
proach to Conjoint Analysis," Working Paper, Wharton novation," Operations Research, 25, 579-619.
School, University of Pennsylvania. Hoffman, Paul J., Slovic, Paul, and Rorer, L. G. (1968),
Carmone, Frank J., and Wind, Yoram (1972), "Sub- "An Analysis of Variance Model for the Assessment of
jective Evaluation Models and Conjoint Measurement," Configural Cue Utilization in Clinical Judgment,"
Behavioral Science, 17, 288-99. Psychological Bulletin, 69, 338-49.
Carroll, J. Douglas, and Carmone, Frank J. (1976), Hopkins, David S. P., Larreche, Jean-Claude, and Massy,
"Superordinate Factorial Designs in the Analysis of William F. (1977), "Constrained Optimization of a
Consumer Judgments," Journal of Business Research, University Administrator's Preference Function," Man-
4, 281-95. agement Science, 24, 365-77. e
Carroll, J. Douglas, and Carmone, Frank J. (1977), Jain, Arun K., Acito, Franklin, Malhotra, Naresh, and
"Design Considerations in Attitude Measurement," in Mahajan, Vijay (1978), "A Comparison of Predictive
Moving A Head with Attitude Research, eds. Y. Wind and Validity of Alternative Methods for Estimating Param-
M. G. Greenberg, Chicago: American Marketing eters in Preference Models," Working Paper, School
Association, 9-18. of Management, State University of New York, at
Carroll, J. Douglas, and Carmone, Frank J. (1978), Buffalo.
"Some New Types of Fractional Factorial Designs for Johnson, Richard M. (1973), "Varieties of Conjoint Meas-
Marketing Experiments," in Research in Marketing, urement," Working Paper, Market Facts, Inc.,
Vol. I, ed. J. N. Sheth, Greenwich, CT: JAI Press. Chicago.
, and DeSarbo, Wayne S. (1977), "Demographic (1974), "Trade-off Analysis of Consumer Values,"
Stereotypes and Brand Preferences: An Application of Journal of Marketing Research, 11, 121-7.
Componential Segmentation," Working Paper, Wharton (1976), "Beyond Conjoint Measurement: A Method
School, University of Pennsylvania. of Pairwise Tradeoff Analysis" in Advances in Con-
, and DeSarbo, Wayne S. (1978), "Additive Decom- sumer Research, Vol. III, ed. B. B. Anderson, Proceed-
position of Perceptions Data Via Conjoint Analysis," ings of Association for Consumer Research, Sixth
The Journal of Consumer Research, 5, 58-65. Annual Conference, 353-8.
, and Devita, Michael T. (1974), "A Complementarity , and VanDyk, Gerald J. (1975), "A Resistance
Model of Consumer Utility for Item Collections," The Analogy for Efficiency of Paired Comparison Designs,"
Journal of Consumer Research, 1, 56-67. unpublished paper, Market Facts, Inc., Chicago.
, and Devita, Michael T. (1975a), "An Interaction Johnston, J. (1972), Econometric Methods (2nd Edition),
Model of Consumer Utility," The Journal of Consumer New York: McGraw-Hill Book Co.
Research, 2, 146-53. Keeney, Ralph L., and Raiffa, Howard (1976), Decisions
and Devita, Michael T. (1975b), "The Robustness with Multiple Objectives: Preferences and Value Trade-
of Linear Models Under Correlated Attribute Condi- offs, New York: John Wiley & Sons, Inc.
tions," 1975 Educators' Conference, Chicago: Ameri- Kelly, George A. (1955), The Psychology of Personal Con-
can Marketing Association, 108-11. structs, New York: W. W. Norton & Co., Inc.
, and Rao, Vithala R. (1969), "Nonmetric Approaches Krantz, David H. (1964), "Conjoint Measurement: The
to Multivariate Analysis in Marketing," Working Paper, Luce-Tukey Axiomatization and Some Extensions,"
Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania. Journal of Mathematical Psychology, 1, 248-77.

This content downloaded from 195.43.22.140 on Sat, 12 Jan 2019 13:08:34 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
122 THE JOURNAL OF CONSUMER RESEARCH

Kruskal, Joseph B. (1965), "Analysis of Factorial Experi- sis," in Multivariate Methods for Market and Survey
ments by Estimating Monotone Transformations of the Research, ed. J. N. Sheth, Chicago: American Market-
Data," Journal of the Royal Statistical Society, Series ing Association, 257-86.
B, 27, 251-63. , and Solgaard, Hans S. (1977), "An Empirical Evalua-
Lancaster, Kelvin (1971), Consumer Demand: A New tion of Alternative Multiattribute Utility Models,"
Approach, New York: Columbia University Press. Working Paper, Graduate School of Business and Public
Luce, R. Duncan, and Tukey, John W. (1964), "Simulta- Administration, Cornell University.
neous Conjoint Measurement: A New Type of Funda- and Winter, Frederick W. (1977), "Application of the
mental Measurement," Journal of Mathematical Multivariate Probit Model for Market Segmentation and
Psychology, 1, 1-27. Product Design," Working Paper 388, School of Busi-
McAlister, Leigh (1978), "Choosing Multiple Items from a ness Administration, University of Illinois at Urbana.
Homogenous Product Class," unpublished doctoral Ratchford, Brian T. (1975), "The New Economic Theory for
dissertation, Graduate School of Business, Stanford Consumer Behavior: An Interpretive Essay," The
University. Journal of Consumer Research, 2, 65-78.
McClain,,John O., and Rao, Vithala R. (1974), "Trade- Rorer, Leonard G. (1971), "A Circuitous Route to Boot-
offs and Conflicts in Evaluation of Health Systems strapping," in Conference on Personality Measurement
Alternatives: A Methodology for Analysis," Health in Medical Education, eds. H. B. Haley, A. G. D'Costa,
Services Research, 9, 35-52. and A. M. Schafer, Washington, D.C.: Association of
McCullough, James M. (1978), "Identification of Preference American Medical Colleges.
Through Conjoint Measurement: A Comparison of Data Rosenberg, Milton J. (1956), "Cognitive Structure and At-
Collection and Analytical Procedures," Working Paper, titudinal Affect," Journal of Abnormal and Social
College of Business Administration, The University of Psychology, 53, 367-72.
Arizona. Russ, Frederick A. (1971), "Consumer Evaluation of Al-
McFadden, Daniel (1976), "Quantal Choice Analysis: A ternative Product Models," unpublished doctoral dis-
Survey," Annals of Economic and Social Measurement, sertation: Carnegie-Mellon University.
5, 363-90. Scott, Jerome E. (1977), "Demand Curve and Utility Estima-
Montgomery, David B., Wittink, Dick R., and Glaze, tion in Industrial Markets," Paper MPB 18.4, Atlanta:
Thomas (1977), "A Predictive Test of Individual Level Joint National ORSA/TIMS meeting.
Concept Evaluation and Trade-off Analysis," Research , and Wright, Peter (1976), "Modeling an Organiza-
Paper No. 415, Graduate School of Business, Stanford tional Buyer's Product Evaluation Strategy: Validity and
University. Procedural Considerations," Journal of Marketing Re-
Naylor, Thomas, H., Balintfy, Joseph L., Burdick, Donald search, 13, 211-24.
S., and Chu, Kong (1966), Computer Simulation Tech- Shocker, Allan D., and Srinivasan, V. (1977a), "LINMAP
niques, New York: John Wiley & Sons, Inc. (Version II): A FORTRAN IV Computer Program for
Nehls, Lyle, Seaman, Bruce, anid Montgomery, David B. Analyzing Ordinal Preference (Dominance) Judgments
(1976), "A PLI Program for Trade-Off Analysis," via Linear Programming Techniques and for Conjoint
Cambridge, MA: Marketing Science Institute. Measurement," Journal of Marketing Research, 14,
Oppedijk van Veen, Walle M., and Beazley, David (1977), 101-3.
"An Investigation of Alternative Methods of Applying , and Srinivasan, V. (1977b), "Multi-Attribute Ap-
the Trade-off Model," Journal of the Market Research proaches for Product Concept Evaluation and Genera-
Society, 19, 2-9. tion: A Critical Review," Research Paper No. 326 (Rev.),
Parker, Barnett R., and Srinivasan, V. (1976), "A Consumer Graduate School of Business, Stanford University.
Preference Approach to the Planning of Rural Primary Shugan, Steven M., and Hauser, John R. (1977), "P.A.R.I.S.:
Health Care Facilities," Operations Research, 24, An Interactive Market Research Information System,"
991-1025. Working Paper 602-002, Graduate School of Manage-
Pekelman, Dov, and Sen, Subrata (1974), "Mathematical ment, Northwestern University.
Programming Models for the Determination of Attribute Srinivasan, V. (1978), "A Model and Estimation Procedure
Weights, Management Science, 20, 1217-29. for Multi-Stage Decision Processes," Working Paper,
, and Sen, Subrata (1978), "Improving Prediction in Graduate School of Business, Stanford University.
Conjoint Measurement," Working Paper, Graduate , and Shocker, Allan D. (1973a), "Linear Program-
School of Management, The University of Rochester. ming Techniques for Multidimensional Analysis of Pre-
Pessemier, Edgar A., Burger, Philip, Teach, Richard, and ferences," Psychometrika, 38, 337-69.
Tigert, Douglas (1971), "Using Laboratory Brand , and Shocker, Allan D. (1973b), "Estimating the
Preference Scales to Predict Consumer Brand Pur- Weights for Multiple Attributes in a Composite Criterion
chases," Management Science, 17, B371-85. Using Pairwise Judgments," Psychometrika, 38, 473-93.
Punj, Girish N., and Staelin, Richard (1978), "The Choice Torgerson, Warren S. (1958), Theory and Methods of Scal-
Process for Graduate Business Schools," Journal of ing, New York: John Wiley & Sons, Inc.
Marketing Research, 15 (forthcoming). Tversky, Amos (1967), "A General Theory of Polynomial
Rao, Vithala R. (1973), "On Models for Scaling Second Conjoint Measurement," Journal of Mathematical
Choice Data," Working Paper, Graduate School of Psychology, 4, 1-20.
Business and Public Administration, Cornell Ullrich, James R., and Painter, John R. (1974), "A Conjoint
University. Measurement Analysis of Human Judgment," Organ-
(1977), "Conjoint Measurement in Marketing Analy- izational Behavior and Human Performance, 12, 50-61.

This content downloaded from 195.43.22.140 on Sat, 12 Jan 2019 13:08:34 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
CONJOINT ANALYSIS IN CONSUMER RESEARCH 123

Westwood, Dick, Lunn, Tony, and Beazley, David (1974), Wind, Yoram, and Spitz, Lawrence, K. (1976), "An Analyt-
"The Trade-off Model and Its Extensions," Journal of ical Approach to Marketing Decisions in Health Care
the Market Research Society, 16, 227-41. Organizations," Operations Research, 24, 973-90.
Whitmore, G. A., and Cavadias, G. S. (1974), "Experi- Wright, Peter (1975), "Consumer Choice Strategies: Sim-
mental Determination of Community Preferences for plifying vs. Optimizing," Journal of Marketing Re-
Water Quality-Cost Alternatives," Decision Sciences, search, 12, 60-7.
5, 614-31. Young, Forrest W. (1969), "Polynomial Conjoint Analysis
Wilkie, William L., and Pessemier, Edgar A. (1973), "Issues of Similarities: Definitions for a Special Algorithm,"
in Marketing's Use of Multi-Attribute Attitude Research Paper No. 76, Psychometric Laboratory,
Models," Journal of Marketing Research, 10, 428-41. University of North Carolina.

This content downloaded from 195.43.22.140 on Sat, 12 Jan 2019 13:08:34 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms

Das könnte Ihnen auch gefallen