Sie sind auf Seite 1von 10

informs ®

Vol. 24, No. 3, Summer 2005, pp. 508–517


issn 0732-2399  eissn 1526-548X  05  2403  0508 doi 10.1287/mksc.1040.0106
© 2005 INFORMS

Modeling Movie Life Cycles and Market Share


Andrew Ainslie
UCLA Anderson School of Management, 110 Westwood Plaza, Room B412, University of California, Los Angeles,
Los Angeles, California 90095, andrew.ainslie@anderson.ucla.edu

Xavier Drèze
Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania, 3730 Walnut Street, Suite 700, Philadelphia, Pennsylvania 19104,
xdreze@wharton.upenn.edu

Fred Zufryden
Marshall School of Business, Marketing Department, Accounting Building 301G, University of Southern California,
Los Angeles, California 90089-0443, fred.zufryden@marshall.usc.edu

W e examine box-office sales in the context of a market share model. This is accomplished by developing
a combination of a sliding-window logit model and a gamma diffusion pattern in a hierarchical Bayes
framework. We show that accounting for the full choice set available every week not only increases the fit of
weekly movie sales but also leads to parameter estimates that depict a richer picture of the movie industry. We
show that movie studios appear to have a good understanding of the products they produce, knowing when
to support them and when not to. We also show that the effect of the number of opening week screens is
overestimated in traditional models. Our research indicates that actors have a direct and directors an indirect
effect on consumers’ movie choice. Releasing a movie contemporaneously with other movies of the same genre
adversely affects box-office performance all around. Releasing a movie against movies of the same Motion
Picture Association of America (MPAA) rating hurts its sales in the beginning, but there is a displacement effect,
which leads to a less severe sales loss in the long run.
Key words: entertainment marketing; motion picture distribution and exhibition; movie choice; new product
research
History: This paper was received November 21, 2003, and was with the authors 4 months for 2 revisions;
processed by Pradeep Chintagunta.

1. Introduction Given the size of the bets made by each studio


The American public has long had a fascination with when they produce and release movies, their mar-
movies. With 449 new movies released, $9.5 billion keting budgets, and the frequency with which new
in domestic box-office sales, and 1.6 billion tickets movies are released (nine every week on average for
sold, 2003 was a record year (MPAA 2004). Movie 2003, MPAA 2004), one would assume that studios
production costs for the studios that are members have become proficient at predicting movie success.
of the MPAA1 leveled around $60 million per movie Thus, it might be expected that studios would use
in the last couple of years, but marketing costs are tools similar to those of Gillette or 3M to predict sales
still rising. These costs add an average of $39 million before launching one of their products. However, sur-
per movie. Recent films such as The Matrix Reloaded prisingly, Hollywood has not put much stock in sales
and Spider-Man II have production costs of more than prediction models, arguing that movies are artistic
$100 million (www.IMDb.com). The expenditures on creations that cannot be modeled. The movie indus-
production represent a significant investment that the try believes more in instinct and analysis by anecdote
studios seek to recoup, first through domestic and (Red Herring 1998).
international box-office release, and then through the Studios do, however, recognize the impact of com-
sales of prerecorded tapes and DVDs (the Home petition. The release dates of many movies are pushed
Video market). Cable and broadcast TV can also be back, or brought forward, to avoid coming out
sizable sources of revenue. The U.S. box-office rev- simultaneously with competing movies that may be
enue typically establishes the “value” of the movie for stronger players (Eonline 2002). This behavior has
the other markets. been shown to be optimal from a theoretical stand-
point by Krider and Weinberg (1998) in the presence
1
MPAA member companies account for almost half of the movies of a strong seasonal pattern. However, there has been
released in a given year. little published empirical research incorporating the
508
Ainslie, Drèze, and Zufryden: Modeling Movie Life Cycles and Market Share
Marketing Science 24(3), pp. 508–517, © 2005 INFORMS 509

individual effects of competing movies in the model- study the timing game. They propose an ingenious
ing of box-office receipts. This is likely because of the approach for handling seasonality through accelera-
nature of the business (e.g., a rapid diffusion process, tion and deceleration of time.
over a very short period, as hundreds of movies enter Nevertheless, to date, with the exception of Swami
and exit the market every year), which makes such et al. (1999), published studies still model box-office
modeling efforts difficult. performance of movies in isolation of the other con-
Sawhney and Eliashberg (1996) developed the current movie releases. To address this issue, and to
BOXMOD model, where they decompose the con- further our understanding of the movie business, we
sumer’s movie selection in two steps: (1) the con- propose to study box-office performance in a setting
sumer makes the decision to see a movie and (2) the where moviegoers choose which movie to see among
consumer acts on this decision. By modeling the all the movies present at the box office at any point
time to decide and the time to act as exponential in time. Framing the problem in market share terms
decays, a three-parameter model is derived from a has important ramifications for the model specifica-
general gamma. They then perform a metaanalysis tions. We do not limit ourselves to only studying the
on the three parameters to study factors that drive large movies, but also consider smaller ones. Thus,
movie sales (e.g., MPAA rating and movie genre). An the model must be flexible enough to fit both sleeper-
important contribution of their work is the distinc- and blockbuster-type movies. Indeed, using Sawhney
tion between blockbusters and sleepers. The classi- and Eliashberg’s (1996) taxonomy, 36% of the movies
fication as a sleeper or blockbuster movie is made in our database are sleepers. We also incorporate the
on the basis of the diffusion pattern and not on the effects of seasonality and handle heterogeneity in the
actual box-office earned (i.e., some sleepers actually path followed by movies’ market shares.
earn more than some blockbusters). Blockbuster-type We develop our model in the next section of this
movies have an exponential-decaying sales pattern, paper. We then calibrate the model using a compre-
with the opening week grossing the largest sales. hensive movie database. This empirical analysis is fol-
Sleeper-type movies build sales gradually and gener- lowed by a discussion of findings and managerial
ally peak 3 to 6 weeks after launch. implications.
Shugan (1998) looks at box-office performance
based on the team that participated in the creation of
2. A Flexible Bayesian Model for
the movie (i.e., writers, directors, actors). His goal is
to help studios predict box-office sales early on dur- Predicting Movie Sales
ing the production process—a time at which the final- We combine a random effects logit model with a
ized product is not available, but the track record of gamma diffusion pattern, adapting each part to fit
the production team is known. Based on the past box- our goal. To account for the short life of movies, the
office performance of the movies in which the pro- logit model incorporates an indicator variable Iit  for
duction team was involved, Shugan (1998) predicts each movie that is set to one during weeks for which
opening day box office with an R2 of 0.59 and total a particular movie appears in theaters, and 0 other-
box office with an R2 of 0.34. wise (i.e., before the movie is released or after it has
Some researchers have concentrated on postlaunch been pulled out of the theaters). We describe this as
profitability. Swami et al. (1999) study the allocation a sliding-window logit model, in that it is essentially a
of multiplex screens to movies so as to maximize dis- logit model that allows for a different product set in
tributor profits. Neelameghan and Chintagunta (1999) each period. Finally, we include an outside good to
and Elberse and Eliashberg (2003) study the inter- account for those consumers who choose not to go to
national diffusion of movies. An important contribu- the movies at any given time. As we will show, an
tion of the latter work is making the screen allocation outside good allows us to incorporate seasonal effects
(i.e., breadth of diffusion) endogenous. directly into the market share model. We assume an
There has also been some theoretical work on extreme value error term on the attractiveness of each
the competitive aspect of movie release. Krider and movie (i.e., Uit = Vit + it with errors distributed i.i.d.).
Weinberg (1998) investigate film release strategies This leads to the following logit formulation for the
based on the assumption of exogeneity of the highly market share of a movie:
seasonal nature of the movie business (sales peak dur- eVit Iit
ing the summer months and during the holiday sea- Mit =   (1)
eVOt + j eVjt Ijt
son) coupled with the shortness of movies’ life cycles.
In particular, they suggest that strong movies should For the outside good it is
compete head to head during peak weeks, while weak
movies should delay their release if they are facing eVOt
Mot =   (2)
strong competition. Radas and Shugan (1998) also eVOt + j eVjt Ijt
Ainslie, Drèze, and Zufryden: Modeling Movie Life Cycles and Market Share
510 Marketing Science 24(3), pp. 508–517, © 2005 INFORMS

where weekly box-office sales. We define the weekly demand


Mit = expected market share of movie i in week t, for the outside good as:2
Mot = expected market share of the outside good in

I
week t, SOt = S − Sit Iit 
Vit = deterministic component of the market attrac- i=1
tiveness of movie i in week t, where
Iit = indicates whether movie i is screened in week t Sit = box-office sales for movie i in week t,
(1 if it is, and 0 otherwise), S = an arbitrary large maximum potential demand
VOt = deterministic component of the market attrac- for movies.
tiveness of the outside good in week t. We then set an autoregressive model (with K 52-week
To model the deterministic component of market lags) to estimate the attractiveness of the outside good
attractiveness of each movie Vit , we take inspira- in a way that accounts for potential seasonality
tion from BOXMOD but strive for clear interpretabil-  
ity of the parameters. BOXMOD is a variant of the K
SOt−k∗52
VOt =  + k ln  (4)
general gamma model (Sawhney and Eliashberg 1996, k=1 S
McGill and Gibbon 1965). In BOXMOD, the param-
Our final model is then
eters (, the time to decide and , the time to act),
 /
although appealing from a consumer behavior stand- i ms witi ms i ms e1−wit /i ms Iit
point, are of limited practical use to managers and Mit =  j ms /j ms 1−w /
 (5)
eVOt + j j ms wjt e jt j ms
Ijt
difficult to interpret when the dependent variable is
market attractiveness rather than sales. To remedy where we use the subscript ms to refer to the market
this while retaining the proven ability of gamma func- share model.
tions to describe the diffusion patterns of movies, we To link the three movie-level parameters i ms ,
begin with a gamma distribution. When used in dif- i ms , and i ms  to movie characteristics, we set up a
fusion settings, the gamma is generally parameter- hierarchical regression on the three parameters using
ized as a mix of continuous Xi  and categorical variables
(Genre and Studio, see §3 for a list of the covari-
1 i −1 −t/i
Ni  t e ates). To allow for the fact that some of the categorical
i i  i  variables have a large number of levels (e.g., there
where Ni is total demand for the movie are 22 different studios), we use the massively cat-
egorical methodology described in Steenburgh et al.
We reparameterize this as follows: (2003) to handle the hierarchical regression. In our
estimation, we normalize i ms so that it represents
i t i /i e1−t/i  the expected market share of movie i in its open-
where ing week (see the technical appendix at http://mktsci.
1 pubs.informs.org). Thus, we constrain i ms to lie
i = Ni  and between 0 and 1, and i ms to be positive in the regres-
i i  i e1/i sion structure by applying appropriate transforma-
i = i − 1i  tions to them. Hence, our hierarchical regression has
the following structure:
We then incorporate this as the deterministic compo-  
nent of the movie attractiveness formulation i∗ ms = ln i ms /1 − i ms  
i∗ ms = i ms 
Uit = Vit + it 
  /  (3) ∗i ms = lni ms 
Vit = ln i witi i e1−wit /i    (6)
i∗ ms
where wit represents the number of weeks in release  ∗ 
 i ms  = Xi ms + Studio
i ms + Genre
i ms + !ms 
of movie i in time period t (i.e., wit = 1 during the
first week of release). In this representation, i is the ∗i ms
expected attractiveness of the movie in its opening In this formulation, the three parameters have a
week, i indicates when peak attractiveness occurs direct interpretation: Recall that i ms is the attrac-
(i.e., the modal value of this distribution), and i is a tiveness of the movie in its opening week; i ms is
speed parameter representing how fast attractiveness
builds and decays. 2
See the Technical Appendix available on the Marketing Science
To model the demand for the outside good, we website (http://mktsci.pubs.informs.org) for complete details about
take advantage of the highly seasonal pattern of total the operationalization of the outside good.
Ainslie, Drèze, and Zufryden: Modeling Movie Life Cycles and Market Share
Marketing Science 24(3), pp. 508–517, © 2005 INFORMS 511

the location of peak attractiveness; and i ms is the genre, and distributor. As mentioned previously, we
build/decay rate. We also have a direct interpreta- model genre and distributor differently from previous
tion of the effect of the regressor variables on these researchers in that we make use of the massively cat-
three parameters. Further, we can test for the pres- egorical methodology by Steenburgh et al. (2003) to
ence of competitive effects by comparing the hyper- estimate the impact of each genre and distributors.
Studio Genre
parameters ms  ms  ms  obtained in our market To both mitigate the problem of the “independence
share model (6) with the hyperparameters obtained of irrelevant alternatives” property inherent in logit
from the following model (henceforth called the models and directly incorporate the effect of competi-
demand model), where weekly box-offices sales Sit  tion from closer substitutes, we constructed two com-
are regressed for each movie independently of other petitive variables, N Genre and N MPAA, which reflect
movies. Note that in Equation (7) and elsewhere, the the number of movies of the same genre and the num-
subscript d denotes that the parameters refer to the ber of movies with the same MPAA rating that were
demand specification of the model as opposed to launched at the same time as the movie of considera-
the market share model tion. A negative coefficient on these variables would
 /i d 1−w / allow for the impact of close substitutes on the util-
Sit = i d witi d e it i d
+ itd (7)
ity of a movie, thus reducing the relative attractive-
with ness of two or more movies of the same genre/rating
that run concurrently. While arguably ad hoc, this is a
i∗ d = lni d 
more parsimonious method than using a nested logit
i∗ d = i d  model, because we would need two layers of nest-
ing, and 65 times as many hierarchical coefficients
∗i d = lni d 
  (13 genres ∗ 5 MPAA ratings).
i∗ d (8) Finally, to help differentiate between potential
 ∗  Studio Genre blockbusters and sleepers, we included the reel length
 i d  = Xi d + i d + i d + !d 
∗i d of the movie (runtime, in minutes) and a dummy vari-
able that indicates whether a movie is a rerelease (i.e.,
itd ∼ i.i.d. N 0 "d2  is in a second or third run). Indeed, “art” movies tend
to be longer than blockbusters and rereleases do not
We can compare parameters across models because
have the same appeal as new ones. We did not include
the inclusion of an outside good in the logit specifi-
a categorical variable for MPAA rating as its inclusion
cation makes Sit and Mit perfectly correlated. Hence,
in the analysis did not yield any significant param-
the difference (across models) in relative order of the
eters. We should also note that media expenditures
hyperparameters (within model) can be attributed to
were missing for 32% of the movies in our data set.
the coexistence of other movies at the box office.
We addressed this limitation by using the Expectation
Maximization algorithm (Dempster et al. 1977) to “fit”
3. Empirical Analysis covariates to the missing data. We also used total box
Data were collected for all movies released domes- office for all movies for the four years preceding our
tically between March 31, 1995, and June 25, 1998. data set as lagged variables for seasonality.
During this period, 825 movies were released in the
United States. We collected weekly box-office sales 3.1. Estimation Method
(Sit , in dollars) for each movie as well as a set Both the market share (5) and the demand (7) mod-
of descriptive variables (obtained from EDI Nielsen, els were estimated using a Markov Chain Monte
LNA, and IMDb.com). Our covariates are similar Carlo (MCMC) algorithm, as briefly described in the
to the ones used in past research (e.g., Zufryden Appendix and more fully in the Technical Appendix
1996, Neelameghan and Chintagunta 1999, Lehmann to this paper available at http://mktsci.pubs.informs.
and Weinberg 2000, Elberse and Eliashberg 2003); we org. The first seven weeks of the data set were
make use of media expenditures, screens,3 critics rat- ignored, as the box-office figures for these weeks were
ing, actor and director Star Power,4 sequel, movie incomplete (i.e., movies released the week prior to
March 31, 1995, would still be in the theater at the
3
We only include the number of opening weekend screens in our beginning of our data set but were not known to us).
model. We do not take into account how the number screens evolve This left us with 162 weeks of usable data. We should
over time.
also note that the number of moviegoers in a given
4
Earlier paper (e.g., Sawhney and Eliashberg 1996) traditionally week is extremely large (in excess of 107 on a busy
used a dummy variable to indicate the presence or absence of a
major star in the movie. We make use of the more recent (1998)
weekend). Hence, instead of modeling this directly as
Hollywood Reporter Star and Director Power indices that provided a logit model, we use a Poisson transform approxi-
ratings on a 1 to 100 scale. mation (Baker 1995; Technical Appendix). Finally, the
Ainslie, Drèze, and Zufryden: Modeling Movie Life Cycles and Market Share
512 Marketing Science 24(3), pp. 508–517, © 2005 INFORMS

number of lags used to estimate the demand of the Table 1 Model Fit Comparison—MAPE for All Four Models
outside good was set to three,5 and the maximum
Out of sample:
demand for movies S  was set to 1.2∗ , the largest
Total Week-by-week Opening One week ahead
weekly value of the data set.6 When fitting the lags, BO (%) BO (%) week (%) BO (%)
care was taken to ensure that holiday weeks matched
BOXMOD 721 10429 18123 51498
from one year to another.
Bass 623 6303 13579 9959
The MCMC algorithm ran for a burn-in period Gamma demand 603 4764 3874 7515
of 30,000 iterations and an estimation period of 60,000 Gamma market 366 4032 3326 7362
iterations. We checked the stability of the param- share
eters by comparing parameter estimates from the
first 20,000 postburn-in draws with those obtained in opening week (MAPE of 38.7% versus 181.2% and
the last 20,000 draws. Because the very small movies 135.8%). Moreover, when we use our adapted gamma
showed particularly noisy sales patterns with very within the market share model specification, the fit was
few weeks in the theater (often less than three), we further improved; providing a significant reduction
restricted our analysis to the movies that constituted in MAPE of 40%–50% when compared to Bass and
the top 95% of box-office sales (404 movies).7 BOXMOD (3.66% versus 6.23% and 7.21%). Thus, in
To test the soundness of our model, we also fit- terms of all statistics, our adapted gamma on its own
ted Bayesian versions of both the Bass model and shows a substantially better model fit, and using a
BOXMOD (i.e., allowing for a hierarchical regression market share model further improves the results.
structure across movies using the same regressors as The benefits of using a market share model can
the ones used for our model). In addition, to ensure be illustrated using a couple of examples. Figure 1
that the results were not spurious (e.g., because of shows the fit of both the demand and the market
overfitting of the data), we performed an out-of- share model for Star Kid (a typical Blockbuster diffu-
sample analysis, where we dropped the last 52 weeks sion pattern). Although the demand model fits the
of the data set and re-estimated the model using only data reasonably well, it tends to underestimate the
weeks 1 to 110. We then used the estimates produced decay in the first week and overestimate the decay
by this estimation, as well as the covariates for the in the subsequent week. In contrast, the market share
movies present in week 111, to predict sales by movie model offers a close fit, indicating that the change in
for week 111. This procedure was repeated week by decay rate can be explained by the impact of the other
week for the last 52 weeks of the data set (e.g., to movies released in theaters at the same time as Star
predict week 112, we used all data up to week 111). Kid. Figure 2 shows similar effects for a Sleeper movie
The fit statistics for both the 162-week models and the (Sliding Doors). Here, we can see that the trough in
out-of-sample models, reported in Table 1, provide week 4 and the peak in week 5 are not random varia-
support for our model. tions, but rather changes in sales that can be explained
when one takes all of the competing movies into
3.2. Model Fit account throughout the life of the movie. The market
In this section, we demonstrate the effect of both shares are driven by the strength of both the movie
modeling market share, and of using our adapted and of other movies available to the moviegoer over
gamma to describe the evolution of market share. time.
First, we consider the performance of BOXMOD, Bass, Detailed fit statistics for the hierarchical regressions
and our adapted gamma within the context of the are shown in Table 2. To better understand the role of
demand model. In terms of total box office, we find the various regressors, we computed conditional R2
that our adapted gamma performs marginally bet- values for the categorical variables and for screens, as
ter than Bass and BOXMOD (mean absolute predic- well as for the continuous variables as a whole (i.e.,
tion error (MAPE) of 6.03% versus 6.23% and 7.21%, including screens).8 We report on the interpretation of
respectively, as shown in Table 1). However, in terms these fit statistics in the next section. Parameter esti-
of weekly estimates, our demand model significantly mates are shown in Table 3. Note that the studios are
outperforms the other two models—especially for the sorted in decreasing order of ms intercept shifts. Fur-
ther, we do not report the parameter estimates for the
5
There were negligible differences in fit between 3 and 4 lags. Genre categorical variable as it has very few signifi-
Hence, we chose the 3-lag model for reasons of parsimony. cant parameters. A complete set of results is available
6
We tried different S but found the estimates to be insensitive to from the authors for the interested reader.
the actual value used.
7 8
As a test of reliability, we kept the full data set and verified that The conditional R2 shows the improvement in R2 when the vari-
the results from the two data sets were not markedly different. This able, or a set of variables, is added to the regression (i.e., conditional
was largely found to be the case. Hence, we only report the results on the other variables being already accounted for). It is akin to a
for the 95% data set herein. type III sums-of-square in traditional regression.
Ainslie, Drèze, and Zufryden: Modeling Movie Life Cycles and Market Share
Marketing Science 24(3), pp. 508–517, © 2005 INFORMS 513

Figure 1 Model Fit for a Blockbuster-Type Movie: Star Kid Table 2 Measures of Hierarchical Variable Fit
$3,000,000 Demand Market share
Predicted (Demand Model)
$2,500,000 Predicted (Choice Model)
First week Peak Speed First week Peak Speed
Actual Box Office
d d d ms ms ms

$2,000,000 Hierarchical R2 0792 0671 0623 0614 0414 0211


2
Conditional R
$1,500,000 All continuous 0489∗ 0417 0543 0223 0163 0124
(including
$1,000,000 screens)
Genre 0013 0021 0210 0005 0009 0017
$500,000 Studio 0016 0018 0050 0096 0033 0084
Screens 0333 0309 0051 0147 0084 0005
$0 MAPE (Total BO) 6.03% 3.66%
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

0.489 indicates that removing the continuous variables from the regres-
Weeks in Release
sion would lead to an R2 of 0792 − 0489 = 0303.

3.3. Estimation Results and Interpretation continuous variables are significant in the demand
First, let us look at the hierarchical R2 and conditional model while 25 are in the market share model.
R2 (Table 2). We first note that, although the hierar- To better understand why screen loses half of its
chical regressions fit better in the demand model than predictive power when incorporated in the choice
in the market share model, the MAPE values (both model, we need to consider the timing game played
in and out of sample) are better for the market share by studios. As mentioned earlier, studios release
model. This indicates that the demand model might big movies during “big weekends.” Further, studios
attribute effects to the covariates that should, instead, avoid going head to head against big movies. This
be attributed to competitive pressures or seasonality. means that when they are launched, the big movies
Second, we see an interesting pattern in the con- have little competition, and thus can garner a large
ditional R2 associated with the continuous variables. proportion of the available screens. This creates a cor-
Looking at the opening week sales parameter relation between screens and total movie demand as
(d and ms ), for instance, the continuous variables big movies are launched during big weeks with a
uniquely contribute to 62% of the explained vari- large number of screens. For our data, the correla-
ance (0.489/0.792) in the demand model, while in tion is 0.14 p = 00038. Thus, in the demand model,
the market share model, they only contribute to 36% Screens accounts not only for the true effect of screens,
of the explained variance (0.223/0.614). In particu- but also for some seasonality effect, thereby inflating
lar, the Screens variable uniquely accounts for 42% its importance. When used in the choice model, the
of the explained variance in the demand model and effect of seasonality is already accounted for by the
only 24% in the market share model. In contrast, the outside good, and thus the effect of Screens is much
Studio categorical variable would be viewed as super- closer to its true effect. This shows that looking at
fluous in the demand model, but important in the movie releases independently from the other movies
market share model. Similar patterns can be found in available to consumers may be misleading.
the hierarchical regressions for the other two param- Opening week screens and media spending are fac-
eters. It can also be found looking at the continu- tors that strongly affect moviegoers, and that movie
ous variables. Only 18 of the 33 coefficients on the studios can still influence close to the release date.
One possible argument is that a studio could try to
recoup its losses by hyping a bad movie and releasing
Figure 2 Model Fit for a Sleeper-Type Movie: Sliding Doors
it in as many theaters as possible. However, this is
$2,000,000 a short-term strategy that might backfire in the long
Predicted (Demand Model)
Predicted (Choice Model)
run if unhappy theater operators refuse to give wide
$1,500,000
Actual Box Office distribution to subsequent movies from the hyping
studio. In our model, we see positive coefficients for
$1,000,000
Media on all three parameters. Thus, an increase in
media spending is positive on all fronts. It leads to
$500,000
higher opening week sales, longer legs, and slower
sales decay. Nelson (1975) argues that advertising
$0
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 should be a credible source of information, in that it
Weeks in Release is only worth advertising if the product is truly of
Ainslie, Drèze, and Zufryden: Modeling Movie Life Cycles and Market Share
514 Marketing Science 24(3), pp. 508–517, © 2005 INFORMS

Table 3 Parameter Estimates

Demand model Market share model

First week Peak Speed First week Peak Speed


d d d ms ms ms

Continuous

Media 0098 0054 0270 0150 0199 0127
Screens 0865 −0822 0149 0629 −0857 0104
TVGen 0026 0070 0133 0098 0281 0013
Actor Star Power −0004 0045 0041 0011 −0139 0074
Director Star Power 0084 −0028 −0003 0015 0111 −0045
Runtime 0014 0071 0040 −0045 0061 0056
NGenre −0018 0003 −0051 −0082 −0076 0008
NMPAA −0029 0056 −0013 −0160 0082 −0042
Sequel 0038 −0009 0010 0063 0017 −0009
Rerelease −0010 −0081 −0160 −0098 −0333 −0047
Intercept 15534 1114 0281 −4100 0601 0684
Studio
TRIMARK 0197 −0303 −0043 1221 −0214 0071
TWENTIETH CENTURY FOX 0214 −0087 −0128 1046 −0457 −0077
NEW LINE 0245 −0179 −0045 0960 −0360 −0008
UNIVERSAL 0157 −0277 −0116 0958 −0492 −0068
MGM/UA −0022 −0076 −0288 0950 −0254 −0358
PARAMOUNT 0154 −0138 −0122 0887 0130 −0341
DREAMWORKS SKG 0129 0147 −0022 0887 0052 −0031
WARNER BROTHERS 0112 −0031 −0198 0883 −0178 −0239
POLYGRAM 0257 −0297 −0003 0825 −0134 0033
BUENA VISTA 0172 −0258 −0141 0781 −0289 −0198
SONY PICTURES 0058 −0056 −0118 0684 0140 −0382
ORION 0000 −0139 −0198 0681 −0796 0298
SAVOY 0264 −0298 −0041 0680 −0493 0322
MIRAMAX 0013 −0066 −0025 0169 −0071 0232
MACGILLIVRAY FREEMAN FILM −0040 −0016 0169 0125 −0043 −0014
ARTISAN ENTERTAINMENT −0262 0212 −0073 −0105 −0046 0098
GOLDWYN ENTERTAINMENT −0154 −0008 0114 −0412 0163 0359
FOX SEARCHLIGHT −0215 0334 0229 −0437 0591 0340
GRAMERCY −0368 0455 0006 −0477 0280 0010
SONY CLASSICS −0241 −0058 0112 −2117 0415 0050
FINE LINE −0284 0570 0580 −3269 1266 0107
OCTOBER FILMS −0387 0569 0349 −4918 0790 −0206

Underlined coefficients are significant at the 0.05 level.

good quality; otherwise a poor experience will reduce impact occurs here not because of repeat purchase but
future period sales, thereby making the cost of adver- because of favorable word of mouth.
tising too high. Unsurprisingly, heavy media expendi- In the case of Studio, one would view the movie
ture leads to higher opening week sales—but contrary studios as undifferentiated entities in the demand
to the “hyping” argument above, we find that media model as opposed to their differential impacts in
expenditure also leads to improvement in sales over a model accounting for seasonality and competi-
the remaining period. If one computes a media arc- tion. One must be careful when interpreting the Stu-
dio intercepts (see bottom of Table 3). In traditional
elasticity by simulating the impact of a 10% increase
logit analysis the brand intercepts are often inter-
in media spending for any one movie (holding the
preted as brand preference indicators. A high coeffi-
other movies constant), we see an increase in opening cient for a brand intercept; say, Tide, indicates that
week sales of 3.07%, (std. dev. 1.18%) and an increase ceteris paribus consumers prefer Tide. This interpre-
in total box office of 6.61% (std. dev. 2.60%). Hence, tation hardly applies in the movie studio context
the long-term effects of advertising are larger than the as moviegoers seldom make a movie choice based
short-term effects. This is in line with Nelson’s (1975) on the studio that released the movie. We see the
argument—the studios understand which movies to Studio intercepts more as indicators of the inter-
advertise heavily and which not to. However, the nal competencies of each studio and their ability to
Ainslie, Drèze, and Zufryden: Modeling Movie Life Cycles and Market Share
Marketing Science 24(3), pp. 508–517, © 2005 INFORMS 515

leverage them. With this point of view, we make the At the other end of the spectrum, October Films
following two observations. seems to behave extremely opportunistically, releas-
First, the larger movie studios often have two dis- ing its movies in the least competitive weeks (it has an
tinct divisions: one for the mainstream releases and extremely low market share intercept, but its demand
one for the smaller art-type movies. For instance, intercept is not significantly lower than the other stu-
Fox Filmed Entertainment releases movies both under dios in its peer group). Although these findings may
its 20th Century Fox label (mainstream release) and not prove that Krider and Weinberg (1998) are correct
its Fox Searchlight label (independent and foreign in an absolute sense, they indicate that Hollywood
movies). Similarly, we find New Line and Fine Line behaves in accordance with their model.
and MGM/UA and Goldwyn Entertainment. Look- An interesting pattern emerges when comparing
ing at the Studio intercepts in the bottom of Table 3, the Star Power coefficients across the demand and
we see that these large studios have entirely different the market share model. For actors, the coefficients
parameters for their mainstream and their art labels. in the demand model are not significant. This proba-
The mainstream labels have large positive first week bly does not mean that actors do not matter, but more
intercepts (i.e., large opening weeks), negative peak likely that studios support their actors in proportion
intercepts (i.e., blockbuster type), and negative decay to their star power, leading to no marginal impact of
rate intercepts (i.e., quick decay rate), while the art the star. Indeed, the correlations between the Actor
labels have intercepts of opposite signs (i.e., sleepers Star Power index and the media and screen allocation
with small opening weeks and more gradual change variables are 0.41 and 0.25, respectively. We see much
in sales from week to week). This suggests clear and lower correlations for the Director’s Star Power index
successful strategic decisionmaking by the studios. (0.32 and 0.00), which indicates that studios support
Second, we can compare the studio intercepts in the directors less than actors. The reasons for this differ-
market share and the demand model for the open- ence in support may be found in the results of the
ing week parameter (ms and d , respectively). This market share model. Indeed, we see a negative peak
will indicate whether the studios are successful in coefficient and a positive decay coefficient for actors
their release timing. Indeed, take the hypothetical sit- (i.e., more blockbuster-type diffusion patterns), while
uation of two studios (A and B) that have identi- we see the opposite for directors (i.e., more sleeper-
cal opening week parameters in the market share type diffusion). Actors have a direct effect on movie
model (i.e., msA = msB ), but have different param- attendance, leading viewers to watch the movie ear-
eters in the demand model (say dA > dB ). This lier in its release, while directors have a more indi-
would imply that, holding everything else constant, rect effect on consumers: good directors make good
studios A and B produce movies of the same quality, movies, good movies have positive word of mouth,
but that studio A is better at timing its releases than positive word of mouth delays peak sales. This is
studio B, because it generates more revenues from corroborated by the larger correlation between Direc-
movies with the same market attractiveness. This tor Star Power and movie rating (0.38) than between
allows us to apply the theoretical findings of Krider Actor Star Power and rating (0.21).
Finally, consider the N Genre and N MPAA vari-
and Weinberg (1998). They show that in a highly sea-
ables. In the market share model, we find that releas-
sonal world, studios should release their big movies
ing a movie in a week when other movies of the
in direct competition to their competitors’ big movies
same genre or the same MPAA rating are released
and release their small movies in less intense weeks.
negatively affects initial sales. This is to be expected.
With this framework in mind, we can see that among
However, looking at the peak parameters paints an
the big studios, 20th Century Fox and New Line seem
interesting picture. N Genre has a negative peak coef-
to time their release more effectively. They have posi-
ficient while N MPAA has a positive coefficient. Thus,
tive and significant intercepts in both the market share
releasing a movie against other movies of the same
and the demand model. In contrast, MGM/UA and
genre adversely affects box-office performance, both
Universal seem to be too ambitious and release their
in the short and the long term; however, releasing a
movies against bigger ones and lose out (they have
movie against movies of the same MPAA rating hurts
positive and significant market share intercepts, but
its sales in the beginning, but there is a displacement
their demand intercepts are not). A clear distinction
effect such that in the long run, the sales loss is less
can be made between New Line and Universal in
severe.
that they have almost identical first week parameters
in the market share model, but New Line’s demand
parameter is significantly larger than zero while Uni- 4. Conclusion
versal’s is not. This suggests that New Line is more The goal of this paper is to study box-office sales in a
adept at launching its movies. market share context rather than studying movies in
Ainslie, Drèze, and Zufryden: Modeling Movie Life Cycles and Market Share
516 Marketing Science 24(3), pp. 508–517, © 2005 INFORMS

isolation of each other. To do so, we propose a sliding- is available online at the Marketing Science website at
window logit model combined with a gamma diffusion http://mktsci.pubs.informs.org. We limit our discussion to
pattern, with parameters modified to enhance inter- the specification of the various distributions used. In §1.1,
pretability. This is implemented in connection with we describe the conditional distributions of i d , i d ,
a hierarchical Bayes framework, with massively cat- and i d . These distributions are nonconjugate and thus are
egorical variables, to both pool information across handled through a Metropolis step. We describe the dis-
tribution of the parameters of the hierarchical regression
movies and extract information from the large num-
( dStudio and dGenre ) in §1.2 and §1.3. As these distributions
ber of studios involved with movie release. are conjugate, we handle them with a Gibbs step. For nota-
Using this approach, we show that properly ac- tional convenience, we define m as the number of movies
counting for the set of movies available at the box in the data set m = 404 and we use i to index movies,
office at any given time not only provides a better fit t to index time (162 weeks), and d to refer to the demand
of the data, but also leads to a better understanding of model.
the drivers of movie market share. We find that stu-
dios seem to be proficient at choosing which movies 1.1. Conditional Distribution of i d , i d , i d
or actors to push. We find that advertising spend- In §3 of the paper, we defined the demand model (in Equa-
ing follows Nelson’s (1975) concept of advertising as tion (7)) as:
information. We also show that the large studios are
 /i d 1−w /
correct in their product segmentation of mainstream Sit = i d witi d e it i d + itd 
versus artistic movies, and that many studios behave
Given this specification, the likelihood function for movie i
in accordance with Krider and Weinberg’s view (1998)
is given by:
of release timing. We demonstrate that the impact of
screens on movie sales may be lower than previously Li d  i d  i d 
thought, as screens act as a proxy for seasonality in 
  I

models that do not incorporate competition. ∼ exp −Sit − Sit 2 /2"d2 it
We demonstrate that actors have a direct effect on t
    
   
consumer choice by leading viewers to see a movie ∗
id ∗
id ∗
id ∗
id
earlier in its release, while directors have a more indi-  1  ∗   ∗  −1  ∗   ∗ 
· exp  
− 2  id  −  id  Vd  id  −  id 
rect effect on consumers. Finally, our model shows ∗
id ∗ ∗
id ∗
that releasing a movie against other movies of the id id

same genre hurts sales all around; releasing a movie where


against movies of the same MPAA rating hurts in the  ∗ 
i d
beginning, but there is a displacement effect, whereby  ∗  Studio Genre
the long run loss of sales is less severe.  i d  = zi d + i d + i d 

A limitation of our paper is that we have not incor- ∗i d


porated endogeneity in a systematic manner (see,
for example, Elberse and Eliashberg 2003, Desiraju 1.2. Conditional Distribution of dStudio
et al. 2005 for a different diffusion process). This may We use a multidimensional version of the massively cate-
induce bias in some of our parameters. Our focus is gorical approach suggested in Steenburgh et al. (2003) to
on the issues of modeling market share, heterogeneity, allow for an intercept shift  dStudio  on each parameter at the
and interpretable diffusion models. Further, although studio level.
Let Studio = (i∗ d i∗ d ∗i d )T − iGenre − zi d be that com-
we model seasonal effects, we do not decompose i d d
ponent of the coefficients not attributable to the continuous
them into endogenous and exogenous effects, as is

variables or genre. Let Studio be a stacked matrix of Studio


done in a working paper by Einav (2003). This pre- d
 i d
across all movies. Further, let  s d = i=1 i d IStudioi =s be
Studio N Studio
vents us from making inferences regarding the origins
the sum of the vectors of these partial coefficients over all
of seasonality. movies produced by a particular studio, indexed here by s.
Finally, let the number of movies represented by studio s
Acknowledgments be ms . Then
The authors thank The UCLA Center for Communication Studio −1 −1 Studio
Policy for financial support and Olav Sorenson for his help s d ∼ N I3 × ms + Vd Studio  s d 

with the data. −1


I3 × ms + Vd −1
Studio  

Appendix. Model Specification 1.3. Conditional Distribution of dGenre


This proceeds exactly as for the studio coefficients in 1.2,
1. Demand Model except that the indexing is performed across movies that
All models were estimated using Markov chain Monte belong to each genre instead of across movies represented
Carlo simulation (MCMC). A complete model specification by each studio.
Ainslie, Drèze, and Zufryden: Modeling Movie Life Cycles and Market Share
Marketing Science 24(3), pp. 508–517, © 2005 INFORMS 517

2. Estimation for the Market Share Model Krider, R. E., C. B. Weinberg. 1998. Competitive dynamics and the
The estimation of the market share model is similar in introduction of new products: The motion picture timing game.
nature to the estimation of the demand model. The hierar- J. Marketing Res. 35(1) 1–15.
chical structure on the parameters i ms , i ms , and i ms is Lehmann, D. R., C. B. Weinberg. 2000. Sales through sequential
identical to the structure put on i d , i d , i d except that distribution channels: An application to movies and videos.
J. Marketing 64(July) 18–33.
we restrict i ms to be between 0 and 1 by using a logit
transform, rather than log, since it can be interpreted in McGill, W. J., J. Gibbon. 1965. The general-gamma distribution of
reaction times. J. Math. Psych. 2 1–18.
terms of expected market share. What is different here is
that we model market share rather than demand; we intro- Motion Picture Association of America (MPAA). 2004. U.S. enter-
tainment industry: 2003 MPA market statistics. www.mpaa.
duce an outside good; and we use a Poisson approximation org.
for the logit specification (see Baker 1995 and the Technical
Neelameghan, R., P. Chintagunta. 1999. A Bayesian model to fore-
Appendix at http://mktsci.pubs.informs.org). cast new product performance in domestic and international
markets. Marketing Sci. 18(2) 115–136.
References Nelson, P. J. 1975. The economic consequences of advertising. J. Bus.
48 213–241.
Baker, S. G. 1995. The multinomial-Poisson transformation. Statisti-
cian 43 495–504. Radas, S., S. M. Shugan. 1998. Seasonal marketing and timing new
product introduction. J. Marketing Res. 35(3) 296–315.
Dempster, A. P., N. M. Laird, D. B. Rubin. 1977. Maximum likeli-
hood estimation from incomplete data via the EM algorithm. Red Herring. 1998. Make movies, not war. http://www.redherring.
J. Roy. Statist. Soc. Ser. B 39 1–38. com/mag/issue50/war.html.
Desiraju, Ramarao, Harikesh Nair, Pradeep Chintagunta. 2004. Dif- Sawhney, M., J. Eliashberg. 1996. A parsimonious model for fore-
fusion of new pharmaceutical drugs in developing and devel- casting gross box-office revenues of motion pictures. Marketing
oped nations. Internat. J. Res. Marketing 21(4) 341–357. Sci. 15(2) 113–131.
Einav, L. 2003. Gross seasonality and underlying seasonality: Evi- Shugan, S. 1998. Forecasting failure and success of new films. Work-
dence from the U.S. motion picture industry. SIEPR Discussion ing paper, University of Florida, Gainesville, FL.
Paper 02-36, Stanford Institute for Economic Policy Research, Steenburgh, T. J., A. Ainslie, P. H. Engebretson. 2003. Massively
Stanford, CA. categorical variables: Revealing the information in zip codes.
Elberse, A., J. Eliashberg. 2003. Demand and supply dynamics for Marketing Sci. 22(1) 40–57.
sequentially released products in international markets: The Swami, S., J. Eliashberg, C. B. Weinberg. 1999. SilverScreener:
case of motion pictures. Marketing Sci. 22(3) 329–354. A modeling approach to movie screens management. Market-
Eonline. 2002. MPAA: Never say “goldmember” again. http:// ing Sci. 18(3) 352–372.
www.eonline.com/news/items/0,1,9459,00.html. Zufryden, F. 1996. Linking advertising to box office performance of
Gelman, A., J. Carlin, H. Stern, D. Rubin. 1995. Bayesian Data Anal- new film releases—A marketing planning model. J. Advertising
ysis. Chapman and Hall, London, UK. Res. 36(4).

Das könnte Ihnen auch gefallen